메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 1, 2010, Pages 3-45

Behavioral economics as applied to firms: A primer

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77951531595     PISSN: 15540189     EISSN: 15546853     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (58)

References (150)
  • 1
    • 70349469049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interactions between competition and consumer policy
    • See Armstrong for a review of some of this literature and its implications for consumer protection policy
    • See Armstrong for a review of some of this literature and its implications for consumer protection policy, Mark Armstrong, Interactions Between Competition and Consumer Policy, COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 4, 97-148 (2008).
    • (2008) COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L , vol.4 , pp. 97-148
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 2
    • 77951537602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (in press), for an account of economic models which assume profit-maximizing behavior by firms but bounded rationality on the part of consumers
    • See Spiegler for an account of economic models which assume profit-maximizing behavior by firms but bounded rationality on the part of consumers, RAN SPIEGLER, BOUNDED RATIONALITY AND INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (in press).
    • Bounded Rationality and Industrial Organization
    • Spiegler, R.1
  • 3
    • 34447630542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded rationality in industrial organization
    • (R. Blundell,W. Newey, & T. Persson, eds, As observed by Ellison, fifty years ago the focus was instead very much on non-optimizing behavior by firms rather than consumers
    • As observed by Ellison, fifty years ago the focus was instead very much on non-optimizing behavior by firms rather than consumers, Glenn Ellison, Bounded Rationality in Industrial Organization, ADVANCES IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS, 145, (R. Blundell,W. Newey, & T. Persson, eds,) (2006).
    • (2006) ADVANCES IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS: THEORY AND APPLICATIONS , vol.145
    • Ellison, G.1
  • 4
    • 77951564074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The recent financial crisis may well have stemmed in part from a variety of behavioral biases of some of the banks' executives. For instance, some managers may have been over-optimistic about the risks they were taking in their lending strategies, and there may have been a herd mentality among some managers, who imitated apparently successful lending strategies and who may have felt there was "safety in numbers."
    • The recent financial crisis may well have stemmed in part from a variety of behavioral biases of some of the banks' executives. For instance, some managers may have been over-optimistic about the risks they were taking in their lending strategies, and there may have been a herd mentality among some managers, who imitated apparently successful lending strategies and who may have felt there was "safety in numbers."
  • 5
    • 0001073135 scopus 로고
    • The use of knowledge in society
    • Hayek argued that a central merit of competitive markets, specifically price-taking behavior by consumers and firms, is that agents' strategies are then relatively simple. (Agents need to know only their endowments, preferences, and the market prices to optimize.), at §VI.
    • Hayek argued that a central merit of competitive markets, specifically price-taking behavior by consumers and firms, is that agents' strategies are then relatively simple. (Agents need to know only their endowments, preferences, and the market prices to optimize.) Frederick Hayek in The Use of Knowledge in Society, AMER. ECON. R. 35, 519-530 (1945), at §VI.
    • (1945) AMER. ECON. R. , vol.35 , pp. 519-530
    • Hayek, F.1
  • 6
    • 27744504177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Complexity and competition
    • Gale & Sabourian argue that in oligopolistic markets, where optimal strategies may be extremely complex, if agents incur "complexity costs" when they pursue complex strategies then the outcome might be more competitive than the standard theory suggests
    • Gale & Sabourian argue that in oligopolistic markets, where optimal strategies may be extremely complex, if agents incur "complexity costs" when they pursue complex strategies then the outcome might be more competitive than the standard theory suggests. Douglas Gale & Hamid Sabourian, Complexity and Competition, ECONOMETRICA 73, 739-769 (2005).
    • (2005) ECONOMETRICA , vol.73 , pp. 739-769
    • Gale, D.1    Sabourian, H.2
  • 7
    • 85045316431 scopus 로고
    • Rules of thumb for social learning
    • The take-up of technological improvements in agriculture provides useful evidence. Ellison & Fudenberg quote a historian of the English agricultural revolution as writing "land tilled in very ancient ways lay next to fields in which crop rotations were followed." They report that the agricultural practices known as the "new husbandry" diffused through England and France at the rate of just one mile per year
    • The take-up of technological improvements in agriculture provides useful evidence. Ellison & Fudenberg quote a historian of the English agricultural revolution as writing "land tilled in very ancient ways lay next to fields in which crop rotations were followed." They report that the agricultural practices known as the "new husbandry" diffused through England and France at the rate of just one mile per year. Glenn Ellison & Drew Fudenberg, Rules of Thumb for Social Learning, J. POL. ECON. 101, 612-643 (1993).
    • (1993) J. POL. ECON. , vol.101 , pp. 612-643
    • Ellison, G.1    Fudenberg, D.2
  • 8
    • 70349900278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are all managers created equal? A recent pair of papers by Goldfarb & Yang and Goldfarb & Xiao illustrate this. For instance, it appears that older and better-educated managers tended to enter markets with fewer competitors after the U.S. telecommunications market was deregulated in 1996
    • A recent pair of papers by Goldfarb & Yang and Goldfarb & Xiao illustrate this. For instance, it appears that older and better-educated managers tended to enter markets with fewer competitors after the U.S. telecommunications market was deregulated in 1996. Avi Goldfarb & Botao Yang, Are All Managers Created Equal?, J. MARKETING RES. 46, 612-622 (2009);
    • (2009) J. MARKETING RES. , vol.46 , pp. 612-622
    • Goldfarb, A.1    Yang, B.2
  • 10
    • 0345447671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Managing with style: The effect of managers on firm policies
    • See Bertrand & Schoar for an empirical analysis of the importance of "manager fixed effects." For instance, they find that managers with an MBA tend to follow strategies that are more aggressive. They find that managers differ in their attitude to mergers, dividend policy, and cost-cutting policy
    • See Bertrand & Schoar for an empirical analysis of the importance of "manager fixed effects." For instance, they find that managers with an MBA tend to follow strategies that are more aggressive. They find that managers differ in their attitude to mergers, dividend policy, and cost-cutting policy. Marianne Bertrand & Antoinette Schoar, Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies, Q. J. ECON. 118, 1169-1208 (2003).
    • (2003) Q. J. ECON. , vol.118 , pp. 1169-1208
    • Bertrand, M.1    Schoar, A.2
  • 11
    • 0036952097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Love or money? The effects of owner motivation in the California wine industry: Apparently, a proportion of wine producers in California do not care purely about the profit they generate, and instead enjoy producing high-quality, high-price wine. (Profit-maximizing wineries tend to offer lower quality wine.)
    • Apparently, a proportion of wine producers in California do not care purely about the profit they generate, and instead enjoy producing high-quality, high-price wine. (Profit-maximizing wineries tend to offer lower quality wine.) See Fiona Scott Morton & Joel Podolny, Love or Money? The Effects of Owner Motivation in the California Wine Industry, J. INDUS. ECON. 50, 431-456 (2002).
    • (2002) J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.50 , pp. 431-456
    • Morton, F.S.1    Podolny, J.2
  • 12
    • 77951519126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An interesting example of this was seen in the Genzyme-Novazyme merger-to-monopoly which was approved by the FTC in 2004. This was a merger of two firms both engaged in R & D for treating a rare disease, where the prime danger from the merger was whether the discovery of a successful treatment would be delayed relative to the duopoly outcome. One factor in the decision was that the proposed CEO of the merged entity had two children with the disease, who may therefore not have wished to delay discovery. See the statement by the then FTC chairman Timothy Muris, available at
    • An interesting example of this was seen in the Genzyme-Novazyme merger-to-monopoly which was approved by the FTC in 2004. This was a merger of two firms both engaged in R & D for treating a rare disease, where the prime danger from the merger was whether the discovery of a successful treatment would be delayed relative to the duopoly outcome. One factor in the decision was that the proposed CEO of the merged entity had two children with the disease, who may therefore not have wished to delay discovery. See the statement by the then FTC chairman Timothy Muris, available at www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/ murisgenzymestmt.pdf.
  • 14
    • 0002676891 scopus 로고
    • Industrial organization: A survey of laboratory research
    • (John Kagel & Alvin Roth eds.) For further details
    • For further details, see Charles Holt, Industrial Organization: A Survey of Laboratory Research, THE HANDBOOK OF EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS, §3 (John Kagel & Alvin Roth eds.) (1995).
    • (1995) THE HANDBOOK OF EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS , pp. 3
    • Holt, C.1
  • 15
    • 84927061852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a collection of papers discussing the use of experiments for competition policy, (Jeroen Hinloopen & Hans-Theo Normann eds.)
    • For a collection of papers discussing the use of experiments for competition policy, see EXPERIMENTS AND COMPETITION POLICY, (Jeroen Hinloopen & Hans-Theo Normann eds.) (2009).
    • (2009) EXPERIMENTS AND COMPETITION POLICY
  • 16
    • 38249032445 scopus 로고
    • A note on the use of businessmen as subjects in sealed offer markets
    • DeJong D., Forsythe R., Uecker W. For instance
    • For instance, see Douglas DeJong, Robert Forsythe, & Wilfred Uecker, A Note on the Use of Businessmen as Subjects in Sealed Offer Markets, J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. 9, 87-100 (1988).
    • (1988) J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. , vol.9 , pp. 87-100
  • 17
    • 77951555402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centre for Competition Policy Working Paper More recently, for an illustration of how competition agency practitioners behaved on average in a similar way to students in a particular regulatory decision problem
    • More recently, for an illustration of how competition agency practitioners behaved on average in a similar way to students in a particular regulatory decision problem, see Bruce Lyons, Gordon Menzies, & Daniel Zizzo, Professional Interpretation of the Standard of Proof: An Experimental Test on Merger Regulation, Centre for Competition Policy Working Paper 10-12 (2010).
    • Professional Interpretation of the Standard of Proof: An Experimental Test on Merger Regulation , vol.2010 , pp. 10-12
    • Lyons, B.1    Menzies, G.2    Zizzo, D.3
  • 18
    • 70350095847 scopus 로고
    • An updated review of industrial organization applications of experimental methods
    • (Richard Schmalensee & Robert Willig eds.
    • Charles Plott, An Updated Review of Industrial Organization Applications of Experimental Methods, THE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, Vol.II, at 1165, (Richard Schmalensee & Robert Willig eds.) (1989).
    • (1989) THE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION , vol.2 , pp. 1165
    • Plott, C.1
  • 19
    • 77951617055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In much empirical work on naturally occurring markets, marginal costs are inferred from observed data such as prices by assuming firms maximize their profit. At the end of this paper we discuss the dangers of this method when firms might potentially not be optimizers. The fact that marginal costs are rarely directly observable makes it hard to perform tests of the profit-maximization hypothesis, mimeo, is a rare example of such a test. He obtained data from a relatively "simple" firm which supplies bagels and donuts to businesses, and where marginal costs are known. He finds that the firm is extremely good at predicting demand for given prices, but apparently prices too low given the estimated demand elasticity. (Interestingly, the decision-maker for this firm is a well-trained economist, who has published in the Journal of Political Economy.)
    • In much empirical work on naturally occurring markets, marginal costs are inferred from observed data such as prices by assuming firms maximize their profit. At the end of this paper we discuss the dangers of this method when firms might potentially not be optimizers. The fact that marginal costs are rarely directly observable makes it hard to perform tests of the profit-maximization hypothesis. Steven Levitt in Bagels and Donuts for Sale: A Case Study in Profit Maximization, mimeo (2008), is a rare example of such a test. He obtained data from a relatively "simple" firm which supplies bagels and donuts to businesses, and where marginal costs are known. He finds that the firm is extremely good at predicting demand for given prices, but apparently prices too low given the estimated demand elasticity. (Interestingly, the decision-maker for this firm is a well-trained economist, who has published in the Journal of Political Economy.)
    • (2008) Bagels and Donuts for Sale: A Case Study in Profit Maximization
    • Levitt, S.1
  • 20
    • 13644283726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an account of the theory of collusion, assuming rational firms, Report for DG Competition, European Commission
    • For an account of the theory of collusion, assuming rational firms, see Marc Ivaldi, Bruno Jullien, Patrick Rey, Paul Seabright, & Jean Tirole, The Economics of Tacit Collusion, Report for DG Competition, European Commission, (2003).
    • (2003) The Economics of Tacit Collusion
    • Ivaldi, M.1    Jullien, B.2    Rey, P.3    Seabright, P.4    Tirole, J.5
  • 21
    • 77951517557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For instance, in the case of Bertrand price competition and homogenous products, the fully collusive outcome can be sustained in an infinitely repeated interaction with n symmetric suppliers if the discount factor δ satisfies δ > 1 - 1/n. With reasonable choices for the discount factor and say, monthly price adjustment, collusion should be possible in oligopolies consisting of a hundred firms
    • For instance, in the case of Bertrand price competition and homogenous products, the fully collusive outcome can be sustained in an infinitely repeated interaction with n symmetric suppliers if the discount factor δ satisfies δ > 1 - 1/n. With reasonable choices for the discount factor and say, monthly price adjustment, collusion should be possible in oligopolies consisting of a hundred firms.
  • 22
    • 0002221161 scopus 로고
    • A theory of oligopoly
    • George Stigler, A Theory of Oligopoly, J. POL. ECON. 72, 44-61 (1964).
    • (1964) J. POL. ECON. , vol.72 , pp. 44-61
    • Stigler, G.1
  • 23
    • 77951588847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cartel bargaining and monitoring: The role of information sharing
    • For instance, (Mats Bergman ed.)
    • For instance, see Margaret Levenstein & Valerie Suslow, Cartel Bargaining and Monitoring: The Role of Information Sharing, THE PROS AND CONS OF INFORMATION SHARING (Mats Bergman ed.), (2006).
    • (2006) THE PROS AND CONS OF INFORMATION SHARING
    • Levenstein, M.1    Suslow, V.2
  • 24
    • 77951536495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some experiments randomly match subjects in each period, so that firms play against different rivals in each period. However, real markets do not frequently operate like this, and so we mainly focus on experiments where subjects interact repeatedly in the same groups
    • Some experiments randomly match subjects in each period, so that firms play against different rivals in each period. However, real markets do not frequently operate like this, and so we mainly focus on experiments where subjects interact repeatedly in the same groups.
  • 25
    • 0348198214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two are few and four are many: Number effects in experimental oligopolies
    • For a brief survey, §§ 2 and 3
    • For a brief survey, see Steffen Huck, Hans-Theo Normann, & Jorg Oechssler, Two are Few and Four are Many: Number Effects in Experimental Oligopolies, J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. 53, 435-446 §§ 2 and 3 (2004).
    • (2004) J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. , vol.53 , pp. 435-446
    • Huck, S.1    Normann, H.-T.2    Oechssler, J.3
  • 26
    • 21144470305 scopus 로고
    • An experimental test of discount rate effects on collusive behavior in duopoly markets
    • Robert Feinberg & Thomas Husted, An Experimental Test of Discount Rate Effects on Collusive Behavior in Duopoly Markets, J. INDUS. ECON. 41, 153-160 (1993).
    • (1993) J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.41 , pp. 153-160
    • Feinberg, R.1    Husted, T.2
  • 27
    • 84986754870 scopus 로고
    • Defense of corporate Myopia
    • Feinberg argues that social welfare may sometimes be higher when firms' managers are relatively myopic or short-termist, perhaps because of high managerial turnover or the kinds of incentive schemes they are offered, since collusion thereby becomes harder to sustain. For the same reason, it seems plausible that shareholders who wish to achieve collusion would not wish to put in place a manager who was myopic or had hyperbolic time preferences
    • Feinberg argues that social welfare may sometimes be higher when firms' managers are relatively myopic or short-termist, perhaps because of high managerial turnover or the kinds of incentive schemes they are offered, since collusion thereby becomes harder to sustain. For the same reason, it seems plausible that shareholders who wish to achieve collusion would not wish to put in place a manager who was myopic or had hyperbolic time preferences. Robert Feinberg, In Defense of Corporate Myopia, MANAGERIAL AND DECISION ECON. 16, 205-210 (1995).
    • (1995) MANAGERIAL AND DECISION ECON. , vol.16 , pp. 205-210
    • Feinberg, R.1
  • 28
    • 77951571081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It might seem that this apparent falsification of rational play is not necessarily important in practice, as most real markets do not have a known "endpoint." Nevertheless, the unravelling argument applies even if the endpoint is uncertain, but it is known for sure that the interaction will have ceased by some date (e.g., if subjects in the laboratory do not believe that the experiment could possibly go on for more than a day, or if it is common knowledge that the world will have ended in 10 billion years
    • It might seem that this apparent falsification of rational play is not necessarily important in practice, as most real markets do not have a known "endpoint." Nevertheless, the unravelling argument applies even if the endpoint is uncertain, but it is known for sure that the interaction will have ceased by some date (e.g., if subjects in the laboratory do not believe that the experiment could possibly go on for more than a day, or if it is common knowledge that the world will have ended in 10 billion years).
  • 29
    • 77951569118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Supra note 19
    • Supra note 19.
  • 30
    • 77951556449 scopus 로고
    • As an aside, it is interesting in this regard to recall Robert Bork's assertion that any merger that left at least three rivals should be presumptively lawful. However, tacit collusion is not the only problem for concentrated markets; even the one-shot interaction could be insufficiently competitive when there are few firms
    • As an aside, it is interesting in this regard to recall Robert Bork's assertion that any merger that left at least three rivals should be presumptively lawful. However, tacit collusion is not the only problem for concentrated markets; even the one-shot interaction could be insufficiently competitive when there are few firms. See ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF (1978).
    • (1978) THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF
    • Bork, R.1
  • 31
    • 0034582353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price competition and market concentration: An experimental study
    • For instance
    • For instance, see Martin Dufwenberg & Uri Gneezy, Price Competition and Market Concentration: An Experimental Study, INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 18, 7-22 (2000);
    • (2000) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.18 , pp. 7-22
    • Dufwenberg, M.1    Gneezy, U.2
  • 32
    • 8644285127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price dispersion in the lab and on the internet: Theory and evidence
    • Michael Baye & John Morgan, Price Dispersion in the Lab and on the Internet: Theory and Evidence, RAND 35, 449-466 (2004);
    • (2004) RAND , vol.35 , pp. 449-466
    • Baye, M.1    Morgan, J.2
  • 33
    • 47649105377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laboratory evidence on the effectiveness of corporate leniency programs
    • and Jeroen Hinloopen & Adriaan Soetevent, Laboratory Evidence on the Effectiveness of Corporate Leniency Programs, RAND 39, 607-616 (2008).
    • (2008) RAND , vol.39 , pp. 607-616
    • Hinloopen, J.1    Soetevent, A.2
  • 34
    • 0002448413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Learning in cournot oligopoly: An experiment
    • Steffen Huck, Hans-Theo Normann, & Jorg Oechssler, Learning in Cournot Oligopoly: An Experiment, ECON. J. 109, C80-C95 (1999)
    • (1999) ECON. J. , vol.109
    • Huck, S.1    Normann, H.-T.2    Oechssler, J.3
  • 35
    • 0034582213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does information about competitors' actions increase or decrease competition in experimental oligopoly markets?
    • and Steffen Huck, Hans-Theo Normann, & Jorg Oechssler, Does Information About Competitors' Actions Increase or Decrease Competition in Experimental Oligopoly Markets?, INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 18, 39-57 (2000).
    • (2000) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.18 , pp. 39-57
    • Huck, S.1    Normann, H.-T.2    Oechssler, J.3
  • 36
    • 0036773943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imitation and belief learning in an oligopoly experiment
    • Theo Offerman, Jan Potters, & Joep Sonnemans, Imitation and Belief Learning in an Oligopoly Experiment, REV. ECON. STUDIES 69, 973-997 (2002).
    • (2002) REV. ECON. STUDIES , vol.69 , pp. 973-997
    • Offerman, T.1    Potters, J.2    Sonnemans, J.3
  • 37
    • 0031521686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government-assisted oligopoly coordination? A concrete case
    • An interesting real-world experiment is reported in Svend Albaek, Peter Mollgaard, & Per Overgaard, Government-Assisted Oligopoly Coordination? A Concrete Case, J. INDUS. ECON. 45, 429-443 (1997). The Danish antitrust authority changed policy so that transaction prices in the concrete market were published, and subsequently the average prices rose significantly. The authors argue that the most plausible reason is that this enabled the firms to coordinate their prices at a high level. (Pubitemid 127344709)
    • (1997) Journal of Industrial Economics , vol.45 , Issue.4 , pp. 429-443
    • Albaek, S.1    Mollgaard, P.2    Overgaard, P.B.3
  • 38
    • 75749122081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27, also investigated the case where rival outputs but not rival profits were reported, and found that the market was less competitive than when no firm-specific information was reported. It would be interesting in future work to see what happens when rival firms' profits (or even just the average profits achieved by firms) but not their actions were revealed. It is possible that firms with higher profits than average might keep their strategy unchanged, but firms who do poorly revise their strategies, in accordance with a model of satisficing behavior discussed in section V. Bigoni allows firms to choose the kinds of information they see (e.g., aggregate output of rivals, individual rival outputs, individual rival profits) when operating under a time constraint, mimeo
    • Offerman et al., supra note 27, also investigated the case where rival outputs but not rival profits were reported, and found that the market was less competitive than when no firm-specific information was reported. It would be interesting in future work to see what happens when rival firms' profits (or even just the average profits achieved by firms) but not their actions were revealed. It is possible that firms with higher profits than average might keep their strategy unchanged, but firms who do poorly revise their strategies, in accordance with a model of satisficing behavior discussed in section V. Bigoni allows firms to choose the kinds of information they see (e.g., aggregate output of rivals, individual rival outputs, individual rival profits) when operating under a time constraint, see Maria Bigoni, Information and Learning in Oligopoly: An Experiment, mimeo, (2008).
    • (2008) Information and Learning in Oligopoly: An Experiment
    • Bigoni M. Offerman1
  • 39
    • 77951521132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 26, find that when firms set prices rather than quantities, the revelation of firm-specific data reduces prices only slightly
    • Huck et al., (2000), supra note 26, find that when firms set prices rather than quantities, the revelation of firm-specific data reduces prices only slightly.
    • (2000)
    • Huck1
  • 40
    • 84878668295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transparency about past, present and future conduct
    • (Jeroen Hinloopen & Hans-Theo Normann eds.
    • Jan Potters, Transparency About Past, Present and Future Conduct, EXPERIMENTS AND COMPETITION POLICY (Jeroen Hinloopen & Hans-Theo Normann eds.) (2009).
    • (2009) EXPERIMENTS AND COMPETITION POLICY
    • Potters, J.1
  • 41
    • 34548348354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do antitrust laws facilitate collusion? Experimental evidence of costly communication in duopolies
    • Ola Andersson & Erik Wengstrom, Do Antitrust Laws Facilitate Collusion? Experimental Evidence of Costly Communication in Duopolies, SCANDINAVIAN J. ECON. 109, 321-339 (2007).
    • (2007) SCANDINAVIAN J. ECON. , vol.109 , pp. 321-339
    • Andersson, O.1    Wengstrom, E.2
  • 42
    • 77951532885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explicit collusion in naturally occurring markets appears to be feasible with large numbers of participants. For instance, in their study of 41 cartels in Europe, Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 17, find that 18 involved more than five firms
    • Explicit collusion in naturally occurring markets appears to be feasible with large numbers of participants. For instance, in their study of 41 cartels in Europe, Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 17, find that 18 involved more than five firms.
  • 43
    • 37949030047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Divide et Impera: Optimal Leniency Programs
    • Giancarlo Spagnolo, Divide et Impera: Optimal Leniency Programs, CEPR Discussion Paper 4840 (2004).
    • (2004) CEPR Discussion Paper 4840
    • Spagnolo, G.1
  • 44
    • 84867985181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leniency programs and cartel prosecution
    • Massimo Motta & Michele Polo, Leniency Programs and Cartel Prosecution, INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 21, 347-379 (2003).
    • (2003) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.21 , pp. 347-379
    • Motta, M.1    Polo, M.2
  • 47
    • 0000438997 scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory
    • 218
    • Armen Alchian, Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory, J. POL. ECON. 57, 211-222, at 218, (1950).
    • (1950) J. POL. ECON. , vol.57 , pp. 211-222
    • Alchian, A.1
  • 48
    • 0002908840 scopus 로고
    • Costly optimizers versus cheap imitators
    • For a model along these lines
    • For a model along these lines, see John Conlisk, Costly Optimizers Versus Cheap Imitators, J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. 1, 275-293 (1980).
    • (1980) J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. , vol.1 , pp. 275-293
    • Conlisk, J.1
  • 49
    • 0000315933 scopus 로고
    • Information and competitive price systems
    • The situation is somewhat related to Grossman & Stiglitz's analysis of the incentives for investors to become better informed about the return of an uncertain asset: If all investors choose to be better informed, the asset's price reflects the information, and there is no need for any individual investor to become informed if there is a cost to doing so
    • The situation is somewhat related to Grossman & Stiglitz's analysis of the incentives for investors to become better informed about the return of an uncertain asset: If all investors choose to be better informed, the asset's price reflects the information, and there is no need for any individual investor to become informed if there is a cost to doing so, Sanford Grossman & Joseph Stiglitz, Information and Competitive Price Systems, AMER. ECON. REV. 66, 246-253 (1976).
    • (1976) AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.66 , pp. 246-253
    • Grossman, S.1    Stiglitz, J.2
  • 50
    • 0000272277 scopus 로고
    • Equilibrium price dispersion
    • It is also related to Burdett & Judd's analysis of a consumer's incentive to search for a low price: If all consumers choose to search then the market is highly competitive, and there is no need for any individual consumer to search if there is a cost to doing so
    • It is also related to Burdett & Judd's analysis of a consumer's incentive to search for a low price: If all consumers choose to search then the market is highly competitive, and there is no need for any individual consumer to search if there is a cost to doing so, Kenneth Burdett & Kenneth Judd, Equilibrium Price Dispersion, ECONOMETRICA 51, 955-969 (1983).
    • (1983) ECONOMETRICA , vol.51 , pp. 955-969
    • Burdett, K.1    Judd, K.2
  • 51
    • 84960565609 scopus 로고
    • A simple model of herd behavior Banerjee & Bikhchandani, et al., consider a situation in which similar agents need to decide between two options (say, whether to adopt technology X or technology Y), and each agent has a private signal as to which option is better and can also observe the previous choices (but not the payoffs) made by other agents
    • (The order in which agents have to make their choice is pre-determined in these models.) Even if agents are completely rational, it is possible that they become locked into the wrong choice. For instance, if technology X is in fact superior, but by chance the first few agents have private signals which induce them to choose Y, then subsequent agents will infer that the superior action is likely to be Y despite their own private signals to the contrary. (If instead, agents could observe the private signals of the earlier adopters, this inefficient herding could not occur.)
    • Banerjee & Bikhchandani, et al., consider a situation in which similar agents need to decide between two options (say, whether to adopt technology X or technology Y), and each agent has a private signal as to which option is better and can also observe the previous choices (but not the payoffs) made by other agents. (The order in which agents have to make their choice is pre-determined in these models.) Even if agents are completely rational, it is possible that they become locked into the wrong choice. For instance, if technology X is in fact superior, but by chance the first few agents have private signals which induce them to choose Y, then subsequent agents will infer that the superior action is likely to be Y despite their own private signals to the contrary. (If instead, agents could observe the private signals of the earlier adopters, this inefficient herding could not occur.) Abhijit Banerjee, A Simple Model of Herd Behavior, Q. J. ECON 107, 797-817 (1992),
    • (1992) Q. J. ECON , vol.107 , pp. 797-817
    • Banerjee, A.1
  • 52
    • 27744568768 scopus 로고
    • A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as information cascades
    • and Sushil Bikhchandani, David Hirshleifer, & Ivo Welch, A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Information Cascades, J. POL. ECON. 100, 992-1026 (1992).
    • (1992) J. POL. ECON. , vol.100 , pp. 992-1026
    • Bikhchandani, S.1    Hirshleifer, D.2    Welch, I.3
  • 53
    • 77951543685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do we follow others when we should? A simple test of rational expectations
    • (forthcoming), for an analysis of data from several experiments on the Bikhchandani et al. model, Id
    • See Georg Weizsacker, Do We Follow Others When We Should? A Simple Test of Rational Expectations, AMER. ECON. REV. (forthcoming), for an analysis of data from several experiments on the Bikhchandani et al. model, Id .
    • AMER. ECON. REV.
    • Weizsacker, G.1
  • 54
    • 0025677813 scopus 로고
    • Herd behavior and investment
    • David Scharfstein & Jeremy Stein, Herd Behavior and Investment, AMER. ECON. REV. 80, 465-479 (1990).
    • (1990) AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.80 , pp. 465-479
    • David, S.1    Stein, J.2
  • 55
    • 77951590453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 466
    • Id. at 466.
  • 56
    • 77951607109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Within-industry timing of earnings warnings: Do managers herd?
    • The authors (Id.) quote Keynes as writing: "Worldly wisdom teaches that it is better for reputation to fail conventionally than to succeed unconventionally." Tse & Tucker empirically investigate the timing of earnings warnings, and find that a manger is more likely to issue an earnings warning if a peer has done so in the previous days. They conclude that the data are better explained by managers attempting to maintain their reputations than by the impact of a common shock, (forthcoming)
    • The authors (Id.) quote Keynes as writing: "Worldly wisdom teaches that it is better for reputation to fail conventionally than to succeed unconventionally." Tse & Tucker empirically investigate the timing of earnings warnings, and find that a manger is more likely to issue an earnings warning if a peer has done so in the previous days. They conclude that the data are better explained by managers attempting to maintain their reputations than by the impact of a common shock. Senyo Tse & Jennifer Wu Tucker, Within-Industry Timing of Earnings Warnings: Do Managers Herd? REV. OF ACCT. STUDIES (forthcoming).
    • REV. OF ACCT. STUDIES
    • Tse, S.1    Tucker, J.W.2
  • 57
    • 77951528334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes
    • It is important that firms experiment occasionally, otherwise the process will grind to a halt after one period when all firms imitate the most profitable firm in the first period (which is unlikely to have chosen the optimal price immediately), and then all prices are unchanged thereafter. An alternative framework is presented in Ellison & Fudenberg, supra note 4, §II where firms choose between one of two technologies, and the relative payoff from using one technology rather than the other is uncertain. If in any period firms choose the technology which performed best in the previous period, then the chosen technology will flip over time depending on which one happened to work best one period earlier. Thus, instead of converging to the consistent use of the superior technology, the outcome is merely that the better technology is used more frequently. The authors go on to investigate less naïve rules of thumb-where a firm conditions its choice on how many firms use that technology-which have superior efficiency properties. (The reason why market shares matter for firms is that they reveal information about the relative performance of the two technologies for more than just the single previous period.)
  • 58
    • 49549102441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Herding versus hotelling: Market entry with costly information
    • David Ridley analyzes a model in which a second firm sometimes decides to enter a market only if its rival has first entered, in order to save on the costs of acquiring its own market information. He provides some anecdotes about how competitors of McDonald's often locate near a new McDonald's franchise, and he quotes a manager of a coffee shop chain as saying: "The reason we want to open across the street from every Starbucks is they do a great job at finding good locations
    • David Ridley analyzes a model in which a second firm sometimes decides to enter a market only if its rival has first entered, in order to save on the costs of acquiring its own market information. He provides some anecdotes about how competitors of McDonald's often locate near a new McDonald's franchise, and he quotes a manager of a coffee shop chain as saying: "The reason we want to open across the street from every Starbucks is they do a great job at finding good locations." David Ridley, Herding Versus Hotelling: Market Entry with Costly Information, J. ECON. AND MGMT. STRATEGY 17, 607-631 (2008).
    • (2008) J. ECON. AND MGMT. STRATEGY , vol.17 , pp. 607-631
    • Ridley, D.1
  • 59
    • 0001728868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The evolution of walrasian behavior
    • Fernando Vega-Redondo, The Evolution of Walrasian Behavior, ECONOMETRICA 65, 375-384 (1997).
    • (1997) ECONOMETRICA , vol.65 , pp. 375-384
    • Vega-Redondo, F.1
  • 60
    • 0001872883 scopus 로고
    • Are profit-maximizers the best survivors?
    • Mark Schaffer, Are Profit-Maximizers the Best Survivors?, J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. 12, 29-45 (1989).
    • (1989) J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. , vol.12 , pp. 29-45
    • Schaffer, M.1
  • 61
    • 0000861816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why imitate, and if so, how? A boundedly rational approach to multi-armed bandits Karl Schlag proposes an alternative model of imitation which yields a contrasting long-run prediction. In Schlag's model, there are many distinct oligopolies, and a firm in one market imitates the best-performing firm in another oligopoly, not the best-performing rival in the same market (as in Vega- Redondo's model)
    • The result of this alternative specification is that firms move towards the Cournot- Nash equilibrium rather than the perfectly competitive outcome
    • Karl Schlag proposes an alternative model of imitation which yields a contrasting long-run prediction. In Schlag's model, there are many distinct oligopolies, and a firm in one market imitates the best-performing firm in another oligopoly, not the best-performing rival in the same market (as in Vega- Redondo's model). The result of this alternative specification is that firms move towards the Cournot- Nash equilibrium rather than the perfectly competitive outcome. Karl Schlag, Why Imitate, and If So, How? A Boundedly Rational Approach to Multi-Armed Bandits, J. ECON. THEORY 78, 130-156 (1998),
    • (1998) J. ECON. THEORY , vol.78 , pp. 130-156
    • Schlag, K.1
  • 62
    • 0001208741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Which one should i imitate?
    • and Karl Schlag, Which One Should I Imitate?, J. MATH. ECON. 31, 493-522 (1999).
    • (1999) J. MATH. ECON. , vol.31 , pp. 493-522
    • Schlag, K.1
  • 63
    • 34548025847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imitation: Theory and experimental evidence
    • for further discussion of the two approaches. In addition, Vega-Redondo's result that imitation leads to competitive outcomes does not necessarily hold when firms have longer memory. If, say, firms choose the most profitable action over the previous two periods, the Cournot equilibrium is then a stable outcome (although the perfectly competitive outcome remains stable as well)
    • See Jose Apesteguia, Steffen Huck, & Jorg Oechssler, Imitation: Theory and Experimental Evidence, J. ECON. THEORY 136, 217-235 (2007) for further discussion of the two approaches. In addition, Vega-Redondo's result that imitation leads to competitive outcomes does not necessarily hold when firms have longer memory. If, say, firms choose the most profitable action over the previous two periods, the Cournot equilibrium is then a stable outcome (although the perfectly competitive outcome remains stable as well).
    • (2007) J. ECON. THEORY , vol.136 , pp. 217-235
    • Apesteguia, J.1    Huck, S.2    Oechssler, J.3
  • 64
    • 0346640509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cournot versus walras in dynamic oligopolies with memory
    • See Carlos Alos-Ferrer, Cournot Versus Walras in Dynamic Oligopolies with Memory, INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 22, 193-217 (2004).
    • (2004) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.22 , pp. 193-217
    • Alos-Ferrer, C.1
  • 65
    • 0035545367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Non-nash equilibria of darwinian dynamics with application to duopoly
    • for more details
    • See Paul Rhode & Mark Stegeman, Non-Nash Equilibria of Darwinian Dynamics with Application to Duopoly, INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 19, 415-453 (2001) for more details.
    • (2001) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.19 , pp. 415-453
    • Rhode, P.1    Stegeman, M.2
  • 66
    • 0043209941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stochastically stable states in an oligopoly with differentiated products: Equivalence of price and quantity strategies
    • and Rhode & Stegeman Id. for a general argument. If firms are not symmetrically placed, then imitation may not tend towards competitive outcomes, nor is imitation equivalent to the maximization of relative profits
    • See Yasuhito Tanaka, Stochastically Stable States in an Oligopoly with Differentiated Products: Equivalence of Price and Quantity Strategies, J. MATH. ECON. 34, 235-253 (2000) and Rhode & Stegeman Id. for a general argument. If firms are not symmetrically placed, then imitation may not tend towards competitive outcomes, nor is imitation equivalent to the maximization of relative profits.
    • (2000) J. MATH. ECON. , vol.34 , pp. 235-253
    • Tanaka, Y.1
  • 67
    • 77955871478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imitation and the evolution of walrasian behavior: Theoretically fragile but behaviorally robust
    • (forthcoming
    • See, Jose Apesteguia, Steffen Huck, Jorg Oechssler, & Simon Weidenholzer, Imitation and the Evolution of Walrasian Behavior: Theoretically Fragile but Behaviorally Robust, J. ECON. THEORY (forthcoming).
    • J. ECON. THEORY
    • Apesteguia, J.1    Huck, S.2    Oechssler, J.3    Weidenholzer, S.4
  • 68
    • 70349510117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imitators and optimizers in cournot oligopoly
    • Burkhard Schipper, Imitators and Optimizers in Cournot Oligopoly, J. ECON. DYNAMICS AND CONTROL 33, 1981-1990 (2009).
    • (2009) J. ECON. DYNAMICS AND CONTROL , vol.33 , pp. 1981-1990
    • Burkhard Schipper1
  • 69
    • 77951554173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for further details about how imitators do almost as well against even the smartest opponents in a wide class of games. The main kind of game where imitators do poorly is something like "rock-paper-scissors," where a smart player can systematically trick the naïve imitator into always playing the wrong action. (These kinds of games do not seem common in market situations, however
    • See Peter Duersch, Jorg Oechssler, & Burkhard Schipper, Unbeatable Imitation, mimeo, (2009) for further details about how imitators do almost as well against even the smartest opponents in a wide class of games. The main kind of game where imitators do poorly is something like "rock-paper-scissors, " where a smart player can systematically trick the naïve imitator into always playing the wrong action. (These kinds of games do not seem common in market situations, however.)
    • (2009) Unbeatable Imitation
    • Duersch, P.1    Oechssler, J.2    Schipper, B.3
  • 73
    • 77951524378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 26
    • Huck et al., supra note 26.
    • Huck1
  • 74
    • 77951518593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27 at 989
    • Offerman et al., supra note 27 at 989.
  • 75
    • 76549106403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Envious CEOs Cause Merger Waves?
    • Goel & Thakor propose a model in which merger waves can be caused by concerns for relative compensation by CEOs. If CEO compensation is based in part on firm size, then if one merger occurs which boosts that CEO's pay, other CEO feel envious and set about finding their own take-over targets
    • Goel & Thakor propose a model in which merger waves can be caused by concerns for relative compensation by CEOs. If CEO compensation is based in part on firm size, then if one merger occurs which boosts that CEO's pay, other CEO feel envious and set about finding their own take-over targets. Anand Goel & Anjan Thakor, Do Envious CEOs Cause Merger Waves?, REV. FIN. STUDIES 23, 487- 517 (2010).
    • (2010) REV. FIN. STUDIES , vol.23 , pp. 487-517
    • Goel, A.1    Thakor, A.2
  • 76
    • 42449109174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the easterlin paradox and other puzzles
    • For instance, see Andrew Clark, Paul Frijters, & Michael Shields, Relative Income, Happiness, and Utility: An Explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and Other Puzzles, J. ECON. LIT. 46, 95-144 (2008).
    • (2008) J. ECON. LIT. , vol.46 , pp. 95-144
    • Clark, A.1    Frijters, P.2    Shields, M.3
  • 77
    • 84935633761 scopus 로고
    • Relative performance evaluation for chief executive officers
    • Robert Gibbons & Kevin Murphy, Relative Performance Evaluation for Chief Executive Officers, INDUS. AND LABOR REL. REV. 43, 30-51 (1990).
    • (1990) INDUS. AND LABOR REL. REV. , vol.43 , pp. 30-51
    • Gibbons, R.1    Murphy, K.2
  • 78
    • 0001609937 scopus 로고
    • Delegation and the theory of the firm
    • 143
    • John Vickers, Delegation and the Theory of the Firm, ECON. J. 95, 138-147, at 143, (1985).
    • (1985) ECON. J. , vol.95 , pp. 138-147
    • Vickers, J.1
  • 79
    • 77951613415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The impact of making the firm wish to maximize relative profits is that the firm then behaves as the Stackelberg leader, even though both firms in fact choose quantities simultaneously. It is important that rivals observe the incentive scheme so that they know the firm's objective and can react to it accordingly
    • The impact of making the firm wish to maximize relative profits is that the firm then behaves as the Stackelberg leader, even though both firms in fact choose quantities simultaneously. It is important that rivals observe the incentive scheme so that they know the firm's objective and can react to it accordingly.
  • 80
    • 17144412009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relative performance as a strategic commitment mechanism
    • Nolan Miller & Amit Pazgal, Relative Performance as a Strategic Commitment Mechanism, MANAGERIAL AND DECISION ECON. 23, 51-68 (2002).
    • (2002) MANAGERIAL AND DECISION ECON. , vol.23 , pp. 51-68
    • Miller, N.1    Pazgal, A.2
  • 81
    • 0011262047 scopus 로고
    • Relative performance evaluation of management
    • Vicente Salas Fumas
    • Vicente Salas Fumas, Relative Performance Evaluation of Management, INT'L J. OF INDUS. ORG. 10, 473-489 (1992).
    • (1992) INT'L J. OF INDUS. ORG. , vol.10 , pp. 473-489
  • 82
    • 0141766367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Using relative profit incentives to prevent collusion
    • Carl Lundgren, Using Relative Profit Incentives to Prevent Collusion, REV. INDUS. ORG. 11, 533-550 (1996).
    • (1996) REV. INDUS. ORG. , vol.11 , pp. 533-550
    • Lundgren, C.1
  • 83
    • 41449091490 scopus 로고
    • An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining
    • path-breaking experiment and the many papers which followed
    • See Güth et al.'s path-breaking experiment and the many papers which followed,Werner Güth, Rolf Schmittberger, & Bernd Schwarze, An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining, J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. 3, 367-388 (1982).
    • (1982) J. ECON. BEHAVIOR AND ORG. , vol.3 , pp. 367-388
    • Güth, W.1    Schmittberger, R.2    Schwarze, B.3
  • 84
    • 0000773694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation
    • for a review of this literature §IIIA
    • See Ernst Fehr & Klaus Schmidt, A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation, Q. J. ECON. 114, 817-868, §IIIA (1999) for a review of this literature.
    • (1999) Q. J. ECON. , vol.114 , pp. 817-868
    • Fehr, E.1    Schmidt, K.2
  • 85
    • 43949150167 scopus 로고
    • Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments
    • The proposer might offer a significant proportion of the prize to the responder because he is purely self-interested and is afraid of lower offers being rejected by spiteful responders, or because he cares directly for fair allocations and is willing to sacrifice some of the prize to achieve a more equitable outcome. A variant of the ultimatum game-the dictator game-can discriminate between these two hypotheses. The dictator game does not allow the responder to reject the offer. Experimental comparisons of the two games reveal that offers are considerably less generous (and often zero) in the dictator game than in the ultimatum game, suggesting that generosity on the part of many proposers is purely strategic. For more details
    • The proposer might offer a significant proportion of the prize to the responder because he is purely self-interested and is afraid of lower offers being rejected by spiteful responders, or because he cares directly for fair allocations and is willing to sacrifice some of the prize to achieve a more equitable outcome. A variant of the ultimatum game-the dictator game-can discriminate between these two hypotheses. The dictator game does not allow the responder to reject the offer. Experimental comparisons of the two games reveal that offers are considerably less generous (and often zero) in the dictator game than in the ultimatum game, suggesting that generosity on the part of many proposers is purely strategic. For more details, see Robert Forsythe, Joel Horowitz, N. E. Slavin, & Martin Sefton, Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments, GAMES AND ECON. BEHAVIOR 6, 347-369 (1994).
    • (1994) GAMES AND ECON. BEHAVIOR , vol.6 , pp. 347-369
    • Forsythe, R.1    Horowitz, J.2    Slavin, N.E.3    Sefton, M.4
  • 87
    • 77951547734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 60
    • Supra note 60.
  • 89
    • 77951522214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 62
    • Supra note 62.
  • 90
    • 77951574749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a model along these lines. However, we are aware of no experimental test of this hypothesis
    • See Doruk Iris & Luis Santos-Pinto, Tacit Collusion Under Fairness and Reciprocity, mimeo, (2009), for a model along these lines. However, we are aware of no experimental test of this hypothesis.
    • (2009) Tacit Collusion Under Fairness and Reciprocity, mimeo
    • Iris, D.1    Santos-Pinto, P.2
  • 92
    • 77951518594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 65, for further details and references
    • See §§ IIIB and IIIC of Fehr & Schmidt (supra note 65) for further details and references.
  • 93
    • 77951617054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 17, and, especially, Christopher Leslie
    • for further discussion of these points and illustrations of the role of trust and distrust in cartel stability
    • See Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 17, and, especially, Christopher Leslie, Trust, Distrust and Antitrust, TEXAS L. REV. 82, 515-680 (2004), for further discussion of these points and illustrations of the role of trust and distrust in cartel stability.
    • (2004) Trust, Distrust and Antitrust, TEXAS L. REV. , vol.82 , pp. 515-680
  • 95
    • 0033476918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social status, entry and predation: The case of british shipping cartels 1879-1929
    • Joel Podolny & Fiona Scott Morton, Social Status, Entry and Predation: The Case of British Shipping Cartels 1879-1929, J. INDUS. ECON. 47, 41-67 (1999).
    • (1999) J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.47 , pp. 41-67
    • Podolny, J.1    Morton, F.S.2
  • 96
    • 77951578953 scopus 로고
    • For instance, Gordon writes: The fear of bankruptcy and the even more widespread fear of temporary financial embarrassment are probably more powerful drives than the desire for the absolute maximum in profits. [-] Given the fog of uncertainty within which [the businessman] must operate, the limited number of variables his mind can juggle at one time, and his desire to play safe, it would not be at all surprising if he adopted a set of yardsticks that promised reasonably satisfactory profits, R. A. Gordon, at 271
    • For instance, Gordon writes: The fear of bankruptcy and the even more widespread fear of temporary financial embarrassment are probably more powerful drives than the desire for the absolute maximum in profits. [-] Given the fog of uncertainty within which [the businessman] must operate, the limited number of variables his mind can juggle at one time, and his desire to play safe, it would not be at all surprising if he adopted a set of yardsticks that promised reasonably satisfactory profits, R. A. Gordon, Short-Period Price Determination in Theory and Practice, AMER. ECON. REV. 3, 265-280 at 271 (1948)
    • (1948) Short-Period Price Determination in Theory and Practice, AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.3 , pp. 265-280
  • 97
    • 77951541992 scopus 로고
    • See also K.W. Rothschild, Price Theory and Oligopoly, ECON. J. 57, 299-320
    • and Herbert Simon
    • See also K.W. Rothschild, Price Theory and Oligopoly, ECON. J. 57, 299-320 1947) and Herbert Simon,A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, Q. J. ECON. 69, 69, 118, 1955.
    • (1947) A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, Q. J. ECON. , vol.69 , Issue.99-118 , pp. 1955
  • 98
    • 84986799029 scopus 로고
    • Simon makes a joke about those economists who believe that departures from the predictions of rational behavior do not matter if the predictions of the standard models are good enough: "economists who are zealous in insisting that economic agents maximize turn around and become satisficers when the evaluation of their own theories is concerned." Herbert Simon
    • at 495
    • Simon makes a joke about those economists who believe that departures from the predictions of rational behavior do not matter if the predictions of the standard models are good enough: "economists who are zealous in insisting that economic agents maximize turn around and become satisficers when the evaluation of their own theories is concerned." Herbert Simon, Rational Decision Making in Business Organizations, AMER. ECON. REV. 69, 493-513, at 495, (1979).
    • (1979) Rational Decision Making in Business Organizations, AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.69 , pp. 493-513
  • 102
    • 77951580260 scopus 로고
    • The prediction is typically reversed when firms have differentiated products and compete in prices. See Raymond Deneckere & Carl Davidson
    • The prediction is typically reversed when firms have differentiated products and compete in prices. See Raymond Deneckere & Carl Davidson, Incentives to Form Coalitions with Bertrand Competition, RAND 16, 474-486 (1985).
    • (1985) Incentives to Form Coalitions with Bertrand Competition, RAND , vol.16 , pp. 474-486
  • 103
    • 77951611133 scopus 로고
    • Levin presents a related theoretical analysis of mergers in Cournot markets, in which he allows that a merged firm changes its behavior from a Cournot-Nash player to a Stackelberg player (among other possible behavioral changes), in which case a merger becomes profitable. Daniel Levin
    • Levin presents a related theoretical analysis of mergers in Cournot markets, in which he allows that a merged firm changes its behavior from a Cournot-Nash player to a Stackelberg player (among other possible behavioral changes), in which case a merger becomes profitable. Daniel Levin, Horizontal Mergers: The 50-Percent Benchmark, AMER. ECON. REV. 80, 1238-1245 (1990).
    • (1990) Horizontal Mergers: The 50-Percent Benchmark, AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.80 , pp. 1238-1245
  • 106
    • 1642527125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An alternative adjustment mechanism which does not require any information about rival actions or profits, or indeed about the demand and cost functions, but which may nevertheless lead again to collusive outcomes, is discussed by Huck, Normann, & Oechssler
    • They consider the rule of thumb: "If your last increase in output [or price] increased your profit, increase your output [or price] again; if your last increase in output [or price] decreased your profit, now decrease your output [or price]." They show that if firms are constrained to change their strategy at a fixed rate over time, then the market moves towards the collusive outcome. Steffen Huck, Hans-Theo Normann, & Jorg Oechssler
    • An alternative adjustment mechanism which does not require any information about rival actions or profits, or indeed about the demand and cost functions, but which may nevertheless lead again to collusive outcomes, is discussed by Huck, Normann, & Oechssler. They consider the rule of thumb: "If your last increase in output [or price] increased your profit, increase your output [or price] again; if your last increase in output [or price] decreased your profit, now decrease your output [or price]." They show that if firms are constrained to change their strategy at a fixed rate over time, then the market moves towards the collusive outcome. Steffen Huck, Hans-Theo Normann, & Jorg Oechssler, Through Trial & Error to Collusion, INT'L ECON. REV. 45, 205-224 (2004).
    • (2004) Through Trial & Error to Collusion, INT'L ECON. REV. , vol.45 , pp. 205-224
  • 107
    • 49149148306 scopus 로고
    • Collusive behavior in non-cooperative Epsilon-Equilibria of oligopolies with long but finite lives
    • See Ellison (supra note 1 at 170-171). Note that if there are n firms instead of just two, the monopoly outcome can be implemented as an ε-equilibrium provided that ε > (n - 1)2/(16n2), and so with more firms it does become harder to sustain the monopoly outcome with satisficing behavior. Relatedly, approximately optimal behavior by firms can sustain tacit collusion when they interact only finitely often, at least for the early periods of the interaction. (In simple models, fully rational firms cannot sustain any collusion when they meet a known, finite number of times.) For further details, see Roy Radnor, Collusive Behavior in Non-Cooperative Epsilon-Equilibria of Oligopolies with Long but Finite Lives, J. ECON. THEORY 22, 136-154 (1980).
    • (1980) J. Econ. Theory , vol.22 , pp. 136-154
  • 108
    • 77951545643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25
    • Baye & Norman, supra note 25.
    • Baye1    Norman2
  • 109
    • 0348166371 scopus 로고
    • For further details of this form of approximately optimal behaviour, see Richard McKelvey & Thomas Palfrey
    • For further details of this form of approximately optimal behaviour, see Richard McKelvey & Thomas Palfrey, Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal Form Games, GAMES AND ECON. BEHAVIOR 10, 6-38 (1995).
    • (1995) Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal Form Games, GAMES AND ECON. BEHAVIOR , vol.10 , pp. 6-38
  • 110
    • 74149083010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Minimax regret and strategic uncertainty
    • Renou & Schlag propose an alternative model for the Bertrand market, which is that firms are unsure about the rationality of their opponents, and a firm aims to minimize the maximum "regret" it experiences when competing with rivals. (A firm feels regret if it sets a price far below the minimum price of its rivals, since it could have made more profit with a higher price, and it feels regret if it sets a price above the minimum of its rivals' prices.) Using this model, they predict that firms set random prices, and expected profits are positive but decreasing with the number of competitors. They argue that the data reported in Baye & Morgan, supra note 25, conform well with their predictions
    • Renou & Schlag propose an alternative model for the Bertrand market, which is that firms are unsure about the rationality of their opponents, and a firm aims to minimize the maximum "regret" it experiences when competing with rivals. (A firm feels regret if it sets a price far below the minimum price of its rivals, since it could have made more profit with a higher price, and it feels regret if it sets a price above the minimum of its rivals' prices.) Using this model, they predict that firms set random prices, and expected profits are positive but decreasing with the number of competitors. They argue that the data reported in Baye & Morgan, supra note 25, conform well with their predictions. See, Ludovic Renou & Karl Schlag, Minimax Regret and Strategic Uncertainty, J. ECON. THEORY 145, 264-286 (2010).
    • (2010) J. ECON. THEORY , vol.145 , pp. 264-286
    • Renou, L.1    Schlag, K.2
  • 111
    • 0013136339 scopus 로고
    • Are we all less risky and more skilful than our fellow drivers?
    • For example, Svenson finds that 93 percent of respondents report that they are above the median in terms of driving ability
    • For example, Svenson finds that 93 percent of respondents report that they are above the median in terms of driving ability. Ola Svenson, Are We All Less risky and More Skilful Than our Fellow Drivers?, ACTA PSYCHOLOGICA 47, 143-148 (1981).
    • (1981) ACTA PSYCHOLOGICA , vol.47 , pp. 143-148
    • Svenson, O.1
  • 112
    • 27744551402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adam smith, behavioral economist
    • For a persuasive account of how Adam Smith anticipated many of the central ideas of behavioral economics
    • For a persuasive account of how Adam Smith anticipated many of the central ideas of behavioral economics, see Nava Ashraf, Colin Camerer & George Loewenstein, Adam Smith, Behavioral Economist, J. ECON. PERSP. 19, 131-145 (2005).
    • (2005) J. ECON. PERSP. , vol.19 , pp. 131-145
    • Ashraf, N.1    Camerer, C.2    Loewenstein, G.3
  • 113
    • 0000745494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The borrower's curse: Optimism, finance and entrepreneurship
    • See De Meza & Southey for empirical evidence and a model which predicts that entrepreneurs are more optimistic than the general population
    • See De Meza & Southey for empirical evidence and a model which predicts that entrepreneurs are more optimistic than the general population, David De Meza & Clive Southey, The Borrower's Curse: Optimism, Finance and Entrepreneurship, ECON. J. 106, 375-386 (1996).
    • (1996) ECON. J. , vol.106 , pp. 375-386
    • De Meza, D.1    Southey, C.2
  • 114
    • 0001372829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach
    • Camerer & Lovallo document in an experimental study that excessive entry can be driven by over-confidence in own ability
    • Camerer & Lovallo document in an experimental study that excessive entry can be driven by over-confidence in own ability, Colin Camerer & Dan Lovallo, Overconfidence and Excess Entry: An Experimental Approach, AMER. ECON. REV. 89, 306-318 (1999).
    • (1999) AMER. ECON. REV. , vol.89 , pp. 306-318
    • Camerer, C.1    Lovallo, D.2
  • 115
    • 33645289278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fable of entry: Bounded rationality, market discipline, and legal policy
    • See Tor for an extended discussion of behavioral economics and entry decisions, and the implications for competition policy
    • See Tor for an extended discussion of behavioral economics and entry decisions, and the implications for competition policy, Avishalom Tor, The Fable of Entry: Bounded Rationality, Market Discipline, and Legal Policy, MICH. L. REV.101, 482-568 (2002).
    • (2002) MICH. L. REV. , vol.101 , pp. 482-568
    • Tor, A.1
  • 116
    • 0000801040 scopus 로고
    • Rank-order tournaments as optimal labor contracts
    • Edward Lazear & Sherwin Rosen, Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimal Labor Contracts, J. POL. ECON. 89, 841-864 (1981).
    • (1981) J. POL. ECON. , vol.89 , pp. 841-864
    • Lazear, E.1    Rosen, S.2
  • 118
    • 34249708976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The dynamic evolution of preferences
    • Aviad Heifetz, Chris Shannon, & Yossi Spiegel, The Dynamic Evolution of Preferences, ECON. THEORY 32, 251-286 (2007).
    • (2007) ECON. THEORY , vol.32 , pp. 251-286
    • Heifetz, A.1    Chris, S.2    Spiegel, Y.3
  • 119
    • 77951598787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 60
    • Vickers, supra note 60.
    • Vickers1
  • 120
    • 77951543684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for such a model. In a Cournot market, hiring a manager who is overoptimistic (say, about the scale of market demand) again confers strategic advantage to the firm, but if all firms do this they will all be worse off relative to the situation with unbiased managers
    • See Florian Englmaier, A Strategic Rationale of Having Overoptimistic Managers, mimeo, (2007) for such a model. In a Cournot market, hiring a manager who is overoptimistic (say, about the scale of market demand) again confers strategic advantage to the firm, but if all firms do this they will all be worse off relative to the situation with unbiased managers.
    • (2007) A Strategic Rationale of Having Overoptimistic Managers
    • Englmaier, F.1
  • 121
    • 0002537125 scopus 로고
    • The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers
    • Richard Roll, The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers, J. BUS. 59, 197-216 (1986).
    • (1986) J. BUS. , vol.59 , pp. 197-216
    • Roll, R.1
  • 122
    • 27544450102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CEO overconfidence and corporate investment
    • Ulrike Malmendier & Geoffrey Tate, CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investment, J. FIN. 60, 2661- 2700 (2005) and
    • J. FIN. , vol.60 , pp. 2661-2700
    • Malmendier, U.1    Tate, G.2
  • 123
    • 48349120485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market's reaction
    • Ulrike Malmendier & Geoffrey Tate, Who Makes Acquisitions? CEO Overconfidence and the Market's Reaction, J. FIN. ECON. 89, 20-43 (2008).
    • (2008) J. FIN. ECON. , vol.89 , pp. 20-43
    • Malmendier, U.1    Tate, G.2
  • 124
    • 77951548619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This correlation between holding onto stock options and corporate behavior could also be due to the CEO's inside information. However, Malmendier & Tate argue that this is unlikely to be the explanation since the CEOs who hold onto their stock options do not gain money from doing so, Id
    • This correlation between holding onto stock options and corporate behavior could also be due to the CEO's inside information. However, Malmendier & Tate argue that this is unlikely to be the explanation since the CEOs who hold onto their stock options do not gain money from doing so, Id.
  • 125
    • 77951553141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stucke M.
    • For further discuss of this point, mimeo, University of Tennessee College of Law
    • For further discuss of this point, see Maurice Stucke, Am I a Price-Fixer? A Behavioral Economics Analysis of Cartels, mimeo, University of Tennessee College of Law (2010).
    • Am I a Price-Fixer? A Behavioral Economics Analysis of Cartels , vol.2010
  • 126
    • 0002678030 scopus 로고
    • The survival of noise traders in financial markets
    • For more details, see Bradford De Long, Andrei Shleifer, Laurence Summers, & Robert Waldmann, The Survival of Noise Traders in Financial Markets, J. POL. ECON. 64, 703-738 (1991).
    • (1991) J. POL. ECON. , vol.64 , pp. 703-738
    • De Long, B.1    Shleifer, A.2    Summers, L.3    Waldmann, R.4
  • 127
    • 0007935790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the survival of overconfident traders in a competitive securities market
    • See Luo Hirshleifer & Guo Ying Luo, On the Survival of Overconfident Traders in a Competitive Securities Market, J. FIN. MARKETS 4, 73-84 (2001).
    • (2001) J. FIN. MARKETS , vol.4 , pp. 73-84
    • Hirshleifer, L.1    Luo, G.Y.2
  • 128
    • 0039647005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Speculation duopoly with agreement to disagree: Can overconfidence survive the market test?
    • Albert Kyle & Albert Wang, Speculation Duopoly with Agreement to Disagree: Can Overconfidence Survive the Market Test?, J. FIN. 52, 2073-2090 (1997).
    • (1997) J. FIN. , vol.52 , pp. 2073-2090
    • Kyle, A.1    Wang, A.2
  • 130
    • 44249124523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market forces meet behavioral biases: Cost misallocation and irrational pricing
    • Nabil Al-Najjar, Sandeep Baliga, & David Besanko, Market Forces Meet Behavioral Biases: Cost Misallocation and Irrational Pricing, RAND 39, 214-237 (2008).
    • (2008) RAND , vol.39 , pp. 214-237
    • Al-Najjar, N.1    Baliga Sandeep2    Besanko, D.3
  • 131
    • 33745856916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does auctioning of entry licences induce collusion? An experimental study
    • Theo Offerman & Jan Potters, Does Auctioning of Entry Licences Induce Collusion? An Experimental Study, R. ECON. STUDIES 73, 769-792 (2006).
    • (2006) R. ECON. STUDIES , vol.73 , pp. 769-792
    • Offerman, T.1    Potters, J.2
  • 132
    • 77951618295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 = 1/11, and costs are artificially boosted so as to raise equilibrium prices. In this example, prices rise by approximately 10 percent relative to the situation in which managers base their prices on the true marginal costs
    • 2 = 1/11, and costs are artificially boosted so as to raise equilibrium prices. In this example, prices rise by approximately 10 percent relative to the situation in which managers base their prices on the true marginal costs.
  • 133
    • 77951560719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 106, suppose that the oligopolists reach equilibrium prices via a myopic adjustment process, and this means that rivals do not need to observe the "bias" of the manager. In addition, they assume that each firm observes only its own profits and not the profits of its rivals, and are more likely to choose cost methodologies that are performed well for it in the past
    • Al-Najjar et al., supra note 106, suppose that the oligopolists reach equilibrium prices via a myopic adjustment process, and this means that rivals do not need to observe the "bias" of the manager. In addition, they assume that each firm observes only its own profits and not the profits of its rivals, and are more likely to choose cost methodologies that are performed well for it in the past.
    • Al-Najjar1
  • 134
    • 84958119841 scopus 로고
    • Optimal trade and industrial policy under oligopoly
    • Jonathan Eaton & Gene Grossman, Optimal Trade and Industrial Policy Under Oligopoly, Q. J. ECON. 101, 383-406 (1986).
    • (1986) Q. J. ECON. , vol.101 , pp. 383-406
    • Eaton, J.1    Grossman, G.2
  • 135
    • 84934452509 scopus 로고
    • Vertical separation
    • See Giacomo Bonanno & John Vickers, Vertical Separation, J. INDUS. ECON. 36, 257-265 (1988) for this model.
    • (1988) J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.36 , pp. 257-265
    • Bonanno, G.1    Vickers, J.2
  • 136
    • 33847069350 scopus 로고
    • Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners' dilemma
    • See David Kreps, Paul Milgrom, John Roberts, & Robert Wilson, Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners' Dilemma, J. ECON. THEORY 27, 245-252 (1982).
    • (1982) J. ECON. THEORY , vol.27 , pp. 245-252
    • Kreps, D.1    Milgrom, P.2    Roberts, J.3    Wilson, R.4
  • 137
    • 77951586822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, if the potential irrationality took a different form then collusion might not be sustained. For instance, if the irrational player has a strategy of always colluding, then a rational player's best response to this is always to defect (just as if she were playing against a rational agent
    • However, if the potential irrationality took a different form then collusion might not be sustained. For instance, if the irrational player has a strategy of always colluding, then a rational player's best response to this is always to defect (just as if she were playing against a rational agent).
  • 138
    • 44149093434 scopus 로고
    • Reputation and Imperfect Information
    • See David Kreps & Robert Wilson, Reputation and Imperfect Information, J. ECON THEORY 27, 253-279 (1982).
    • (1982) J. ECON THEORY , vol.27 , pp. 253-279
    • Kreps, D.1    Wilson, R.2
  • 139
    • 21344496503 scopus 로고
    • On the existence of predatory pricing: An experimental study of reputation and entry deterrence in the chain-store game
    • Yun Joo Jung, John Kagel, & Dan Levin, On the Existence of Predatory pricing: An Experimental Study of Reputation and Entry Deterrence in the Chain-Store Game, RAND 25, 72-93 (1994).
    • (1994) RAND , vol.25 , pp. 72-93
    • Jung, Y.J.1    Kagel, J.2    Levin, D.3
  • 140
    • 84947586303 scopus 로고
    • The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target
    • Kenneth Rogoff, The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target, Q. J. ECON. 100, 1169-1189 (1985).
    • (1985) Q. J. ECON. , vol.100 , pp. 1169-1189
    • Rogoff, K.1
  • 142
    • 77649251552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rationality analysis in antitrust
    • For more analysis of this and related points, see Christopher Leslie, Rationality Analysis in Antitrust, U. PA. L. REV. 158, 262-353 (2010).
    • (2010) U. PA. L. REV. , vol.158 , pp. 262-353
    • Leslie, C.1
  • 143
    • 77951618296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, as discussed in section III, the effect may be limited if rivals react punitively when one firm puts in place an aggressive manager or an incentive scheme which induces aggressive behavior by its manager
    • However, as discussed in section III, the effect may be limited if rivals react punitively when one firm puts in place an aggressive manager or an incentive scheme which induces aggressive behavior by its manager.
  • 144
    • 0037332222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does market experience eliminate market anomalies?
    • John List, Does Market Experience Eliminate Market Anomalies? Q. J. ECON. 118, 41-71 (2003)
    • (2003) Q. J. ECON. , vol.118 , pp. 41-71
    • List, J.1
  • 145
    • 1642346858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: Evidence from the marketplace
    • and John List, Neoclassical Theory Versus Prospect Theory: Evidence From the Marketplace, ECONOMETRICA 72, 615-625 (2004).
    • (2004) ECONOMETRICA , vol.72 , pp. 615-625
    • List, J.1
  • 146
    • 77951530800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 80
    • Huck et al., supra note 80.
    • Huck1
  • 148
    • 77951547733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 118 at 269
    • Leslie, supra note 118 at 269.
    • Leslie
  • 149
    • 77951609454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 118 at § III.F
    • See also Leslie, supra note 118 at § III.F.
    • Leslie
  • 150
    • 76549106279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A model of delegated project choice
    • Armstrong & Vickers show how it can be optimal for a competition authority to permit only those mergers which do not harm consumers, even if society places equal weight on profit and consumer surplus. The reason is that a "consumer standard" affects the merger opportunities considered by firms, in a way which enhances total welfare
    • For instance, Armstrong & Vickers show how it can be optimal for a competition authority to permit only those mergers which do not harm consumers, even if society places equal weight on profit and consumer surplus. The reason is that a "consumer standard" affects the merger opportunities considered by firms, in a way which enhances total welfare. Mark Armstrong & John Vickers, A Model of Delegated Project Choice, ECONOMETRICA 78, 213-244 (2010).
    • (2010) ECONOMETRICA , vol.78 , pp. 213-244
    • Armstrong, M.1    Vickers, J.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.