메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 4, Issue 1, 2008, Pages 97-147

Interactions between competition and consumer policy

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 70349469049     PISSN: 15540189     EISSN: 15546853     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Conference Paper
Times cited : (50)

References (138)
  • 1
    • 70350207593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paper presented at Fordham Corporate Law Institute's 29th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, New York (Oct. 31)
    • Timothy Muris, The Interface of Competition and Consumer Protection, Paper presented at Fordham Corporate Law Institute's 29th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, New York (Oct. 31, 2002).
    • (2002) The Interface of Competition and Consumer Protection
    • Muris, T.1
  • 3
    • 70350177798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Muris, supra note 1
    • Muris, supra note 1.
  • 4
    • 61249553749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics for consumer policy
    • 289
    • J. Vickers, Economics for Consumer Policy, 125 PROC. BRIT. ACAD. 287-310, 289 (2004).
    • (2004) Proc. Brit. Acad. , vol.125 , pp. 287-310
    • Vickers, J.1
  • 5
    • 0038548458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for Asymmetric Paternalism
    • C. Camerer, S. Issacharoff, G. Loewenstein, T. O'Donoghue & M. Rabin, Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism", 151(3) U. PENN. L. REV. 1211-54 (2003).
    • (2003) U. Penn. L. Rev. , vol.151 , Issue.3 , pp. 1211-54
    • Camerer, C.1    Issacharoff, S.2    Loewenstein, G.3    O'Donoghue, T.4    Rabin, M.5
  • 6
    • 70350195136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of recent convergence in the area of consumer fraud, see Muris (2002), supra note 1
    • For a discussion of recent convergence in the area of consumer fraud, see Muris (2002), supra note 1.
  • 7
    • 70350174877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The current European Union Unfair Commercial Practices Directive is an important step towards harmonizing consumer policy within Europe. See Directive 2005/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 May 2005 concerning unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices in the internal market, 2005 O.J. (L 149) 22 [hereinafter UCPD]
    • The current European Union Unfair Commercial Practices Directive is an important step towards harmonizing consumer policy within Europe. See Directive 2005/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 May 2005 concerning unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices in the internal market, 2005 O.J. (L 149) 22 [hereinafter UCPD].
  • 8
    • 70350190330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is conventional to divide products into three classes, depending on the extent of the information problem. "Search goods" are products whose attributes are fully observable at the time of purchase; "experience goods" have attributes which are only revealed after purchase; and "credence goods" have attributes which are not fully revealed even after purchase
    • It is conventional to divide products into three classes, depending on the extent of the information problem. "Search goods" are products whose attributes are fully observable at the time of purchase; "experience goods" have attributes which are only revealed after purchase; and "credence goods" have attributes which are not fully revealed even after purchase.
  • 9
    • 70350182562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vickers (2004), supra note 4, at 297
    • See Vickers (2004), supra note 4, at 297.
  • 10
    • 33748566804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effect of word of mouth on sales: Online book reviews
    • On this last point, see
    • On this last point, see J. Chevalier & D. Mayzlin, The Effect of Word of Mouth on Sales: Online Book Reviews, 43(3) J. MARKETING RES. 345-54 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Marketing Res. , vol.43 , Issue.3 , pp. 345-54
    • Chevalier, J.1    Mayzlin, D.2
  • 11
    • 33645766738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On doctors, mechanics, and computer specialists: The economics of credence goods
    • The result referred to is Lemma 7 in that survey. In addition, in situations where consumers commit to get treatment when they get diagnosis from an expert, and where experts post prices for treatment, competition can, under stringent conditions (such as all consumers having the same probability of needing a serious repair), deliver the ideal outcome (see Proposition 1)
    • U. Dulleck & R. Kerschbamer, On Doctors, Mechanics, and Computer Specialists: The Economics of Credence Goods, 44(2) J. ECON. LIT. 5-42 (2006). The result referred to is Lemma 7 in that survey. In addition, in situations where consumers commit to get treatment when they get diagnosis from an expert, and where experts post prices for treatment, competition can, under stringent conditions (such as all consumers having the same probability of needing a serious repair), deliver the ideal outcome (see Proposition 1).
    • (2006) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.44 , Issue.2 , pp. 5-42
    • Dulleck, U.1    Kerschbamer, R.2
  • 12
    • 0031481976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credence goods and fraudulent experts
    • Illustrative anecdotes are provided in, For instance, in a region in Switzerland the general population had significantly more medical operations than medical doctors and their families, consistent with a degree of overtreatment among the uninformed. Likewise, see H. Schneider, Agency Problems and Reputation in Expert Services: Evidence from Auto Repair (2007) (mimeo, Cornell University) reports results from a field experiment where the same faulty car was taken to 40 garages for diagnosis and quotes for repair. He found that 27 percent of garages suggested unnecessary repairs, while real faults were missed in 77 percent of cases
    • Illustrative anecdotes are provided in W. Emons, Credence Goods and Fraudulent Experts, 28(1) RAND J. ECON. 107-19 (1997). For instance, in a region in Switzerland the general population had significantly more medical operations than medical doctors and their families, consistent with a degree of overtreatment among the uninformed. Likewise, see H. Schneider, Agency Problems and Reputation in Expert Services: Evidence from Auto Repair (2007) (mimeo, Cornell University) reports results from a field experiment where the same faulty car was taken to 40 garages for diagnosis and quotes for repair. He found that 27 percent of garages suggested unnecessary repairs, while real faults were missed in 77 percent of cases.
    • (1997) Rand J. Econ. , vol.28 , Issue.1 , pp. 107-19
    • Emons, W.1
  • 13
    • 70350200003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dulleck & Kerschbamer (2006), supra note 11, at Proposition 4
    • See Dulleck & Kerschbamer (2006), supra note 11, at Proposition 4.
  • 14
    • 70350171714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the later discussion of the "Diamond paradox" in Section III.C of this paper
    • See the later discussion of the "Diamond paradox" in Section III.C of this paper.
  • 15
    • 4544275423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic insights from internet auctions
    • §5, surveys the empirical work on the effectiveness of the reputation mechanism in online auctions, which is mixed in its conclusions
    • P. Bajari & A. Hortacsu, Economic Insights from Internet Auctions, 42(2) J. ECON. LIT. 457-86, §5 (2004), surveys the empirical work on the effectiveness of the reputation mechanism in online auctions, which is mixed in its conclusions.
    • (2004) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.42 , Issue.2 , pp. 457-86
    • Bajari, P.1    Hortacsu, A.2
  • 16
    • 85017168631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reputational incentives for restaurant hygiene
    • (forthcoming) provide evidence showing that restaurant hygiene tends to be higher in local markets which have a greater proportion of repeat buyers. Schneider (2007), supra note 12, tests for the impact of reputation by informing some (randomly chosen) garages that he has just moved to the area (thus indicating scope for repeat business) and informing others that he is about to leave the area. He finds that while the potential for repeat business appears to lead to a lower charge for diagnosis, it appears to have no significant affect on the quality of the diagnosis
    • G. Jin & P. Leslie, Reputational Incentives for Restaurant Hygiene, AM. ECON. J.: MICROECONOMICS (forthcoming 2009) provide evidence showing that restaurant hygiene tends to be higher in local markets which have a greater proportion of repeat buyers. Schneider (2007), supra note 12, tests for the impact of reputation by informing some (randomly chosen) garages that he has just moved to the area (thus indicating scope for repeat business) and informing others that he is about to leave the area. He finds that while the potential for repeat business appears to lead to a lower charge for diagnosis, it appears to have no significant affect on the quality of the diagnosis.
    • (2009) Am. Econ. J.: Microeconomics
    • Jin, G.1    Leslie, P.2
  • 17
    • 0000287635 scopus 로고
    • Information, advertising and health choices: A study of the cereal market
    • In 1984, Kellogg launched an advertising campaign focusing on the health benefits of one of its cereals, All-Bran. This was in direct violation of the U.S. Food and Drug Administration's then-policy which essentially banned health claims on food products. A subsequent relaxation of this ban acted to facilitate information flows to consumers, which led many consumers to change their consumption behavior. Moreover, it seems that government and general information sources before the ban was lifted had little impact on consumer behavior. See
    • In 1984, Kellogg launched an advertising campaign focusing on the health benefits of one of its cereals, All-Bran. This was in direct violation of the U.S. Food and Drug Administration's then-policy which essentially banned health claims on food products. A subsequent relaxation of this ban acted to facilitate information flows to consumers, which led many consumers to change their consumption behavior. Moreover, it seems that government and general information sources before the ban was lifted had little impact on consumer behavior. See P. Ippolito & A. Mathios, Information, Advertising and Health Choices: A Study of the Cereal Market, 21(3) RAND J. ECON. 459-80 (1990).
    • (1990) Rand J. Econ. , vol.21 , Issue.3 , pp. 459-80
    • Ippolito, P.1    Mathios, A.2
  • 18
    • 66049116681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economic analysis of advertising
    • See, (M. Armstrong & R. Porter eds., 2007). Likewise, if users of a search engine tend to click on suggested links in the order in which they appear on the page, then websites which are most likely to fit the user's need will often pay the most to be listed first. (And in this case, consumers indeed should click on the links in the suggested order.)
    • See Kyle Bagwell, The Economic Analysis of Advertising, in 3 THE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 1701-1844 (M. Armstrong & R. Porter eds., 2007). Likewise, if users of a search engine tend to click on suggested links in the order in which they appear on the page, then websites which are most likely to fit the user's need will often pay the most to be listed first. (And in this case, consumers indeed should click on the links in the suggested order.)
    • The Handbook Of Industrial Organization , vol.3 , pp. 1701-1844
    • Bagwell, K.1
  • 20
    • 70350198426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. (United Kingdom), at, (last visited Jan. 17)
    • See, e.g., Money Saving Expert: Consumer Revenge (United Kingdom), at http://www.moneysaving expert.com (last visited Jan. 17, 2008).
    • (2008) Money Saving Expert: Consumer Revenge
  • 21
    • 0002845615 scopus 로고
    • Relying on the information of interested parties
    • In fact, this "unraveling" argument works even with a monopoly seller, provided that consumers think strategically and have accurate information about the market environment (see Section 2 in that paper). When there is competition, consumers do not need to reason in such a sophisticated way for this result to hold (see Sections 3 and 4 in that paper)
    • P. Milgrom & J. Roberts, Relying on the Information of Interested Parties, 17(1) RAND J. ECON. 18-32 (1986). In fact, this "unraveling" argument works even with a monopoly seller, provided that consumers think strategically and have accurate information about the market environment (see Section 2 in that paper). When there is competition, consumers do not need to reason in such a sophisticated way for this result to hold (see Sections 3 and 4 in that paper).
    • (1986) Rand J. Econ. , vol.17 , Issue.1 , pp. 18-32
    • Milgrom, P.1    Roberts, J.2
  • 22
    • 0031476314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paying customers to switch
    • Y. Chen, Paying Customers to Switch, 6(4) J. ECON. MGMT. STRATEGY 877-97 (1997).
    • (1997) J. Econ. Mgmt. Strategy , vol.6 , Issue.4 , pp. 877-97
    • Chen, Y.1
  • 23
    • 33645333256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying odysseus to the mast: Evidence from a commitment savings product in the Philippines
    • For evidence that consumers have demand for commitment devices, see
    • For evidence that consumers have demand for commitment devices, see N. Ashraf, D. Karlan & W. Yin, Tying Odysseus to the Mast: Evidence from a Commitment Savings Product in the Philippines, 121(2) Q.J. ECON. 635-72 (2006).
    • (2006) Q.J. Econ. , vol.121 , Issue.2 , pp. 635-72
    • Ashraf, N.1    Karlan, D.2    Yin, W.3
  • 24
    • 0038969032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting
    • D. Laibson, Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting, 112(2) Q.J. ECON. 443-77 (1997).
    • (1997) Q.J. Econ. , vol.112 , Issue.2 , pp. 443-77
    • Laibson, D.1
  • 25
    • 2542591648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract design and self-control: Theory and evidence
    • S. DellaVigna & U. Malmendier, Contract Design and Self-Control: Theory and Evidence, 119(2) Q.J. ECON. 353-402 (2004)
    • (2004) Q.J. Econ. , vol.119 , Issue.2 , pp. 353-402
    • DellaVigna, S.1    Malmendier, U.2
  • 26
    • 33745813486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contracting with diversely naive agents
    • An alternative and less benign reason why gyms might set low per-visit charges, with respect to exploiting over-optimism on the part of consumers, is discussed in Section III.E of this paper
    • and K. Eliaz & R. Spiegler, Contracting with Diversely Naive Agents, 73(3) REV. ECON. STUD. 689-714 (2006). An alternative and less benign reason why gyms might set low per-visit charges, with respect to exploiting over-optimism on the part of consumers, is discussed in Section III.E of this paper.
    • (2006) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.73 , Issue.3 , pp. 689-714
    • Eliaz, K.1    Spiegler, R.2
  • 27
    • 0000699305 scopus 로고
    • The efficient regulation of consumer information
    • For discussion of this point, see, §1B, The UCPD, supra note 7, at para. 18, takes the view that a commercial practice is unfair if the average consumer in that market is misled (among other hurdles which need to be passed). If a product is marketed at a particular sub-group of consumers (e.g., the elderly), then the average consumer should be taken with reference to that subgroup. Specifically, the UCPD states that "[t]he average consumer test is not a statistical test. National courts and authorities will have to exercise their own faculty of judgment [ . . . ] to determine the typical reaction of the average consumer in a given case."
    • For discussion of this point, see H. Beales, R. Craswell & S. Salop, The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information, 24(3) J.L. & ECON. 491-539, §1B (1981). The UCPD, supra note 7, at para. 18, takes the view that a commercial practice is unfair if the average consumer in that market is misled (among other hurdles which need to be passed). If a product is marketed at a particular sub-group of consumers (e.g., the elderly), then the average consumer should be taken with reference to that subgroup. Specifically, the UCPD states that "[t]he average consumer test is not a statistical test. National courts and authorities will have to exercise their own faculty of judgment [ . . . ] to determine the typical reaction of the average consumer in a given case."
    • (1981) J.L. & Econ. , vol.24 , Issue.3 , pp. 491-539
    • Beales, H.1    Craswell, R.2    Salop, S.3
  • 28
    • 70350174874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a long list of the scams being used in Australia at the time of writing (2008), see ScamNet - Complete Listing of Scams, at (last visited Jan. 25, 2008)
    • For a long list of the scams being used in Australia at the time of writing (2008), see ScamNet - Complete Listing of Scams, at http://www.docep.wa. gov.au/ConsumerProtection/ScamNet/content/ pages/full-list.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
  • 29
    • 70350171709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quot;Claiming that products are able to facilitate winning in games of chance" is one of the 31 practices which are in all circumstances considered unfair in the UCPD, supra note 7
    • quot;Claiming that products are able to facilitate winning in games of chance" is one of the 31 practices which are in all circumstances considered unfair in the UCPD, supra note 7.
  • 30
    • 70350204362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For details of recent intervention against a racing tipster, see Press Release, U.K. Office of Fair Trading, OFT obtains injunction against bogus racing tipster (Jan. 22, 2008), available at. In return for a membership fee of GBP 590, members received tips on likely winners in horse races. Some 3,000 consumers signed up for the service. The marketing materials for the service were judged to be misleading, and falsely claimed for instance that the tipster owned a team of race horses and had ridden regularly for some of the most successful horse trainers. In addition, members were told they would make a "minimum of £47,000 in 30 days."
    • For details of recent intervention against a racing tipster, see Press Release, U.K. Office of Fair Trading, OFT obtains injunction against bogus racing tipster (Jan. 22, 2008), available at http://www.oft.gov.uk/news/press/ 2008/12-08. In return for a membership fee of GBP 590, members received tips on likely winners in horse races. Some 3,000 consumers signed up for the service. The marketing materials for the service were judged to be misleading, and falsely claimed for instance that the tipster owned a team of race horses and had ridden regularly for some of the most successful horse trainers. In addition, members were told they would make a "minimum of £47,000 in 30 days."
  • 31
    • 70350187433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 26
    • See supra note 26.
  • 32
    • 70350209169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the discussion of "quacks" in Section III.C
    • See the discussion of "quacks" in Section III.C.
  • 33
    • 0004799427 scopus 로고
    • The federal trade commission
    • 62
    • R. Posner, The Federal Trade Commission, 37(1) U. CHI. L. REV. 47-89, 62 (1969).
    • (1969) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.37 , Issue.1 , pp. 47-89
    • Posner, R.1
  • 34
    • 70350193370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner (1969), Id. at 68
    • Posner (1969), Id. at 68.
  • 35
    • 0036309758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does the internet make markets more competitive? Evidence from the life insurance industry
    • provide evidence that the growth of pricecomparison websites for life insurance drove prices down for this product. An interesting study in the pre-Internet era had related findings. In 1974, two districts in Canada were chosen for a market transparency experiment in supermarket pricing. In one district, prices were collected but not publicized; in the other district, average price indices for individual supermarkets in that area were publicized in local newspapers. The result was that price dispersion and price levels fell in the second district relative to the first
    • J. Brown & A. Goolsbee, Does the Internet Make Markets more Competitive? Evidence from the Life Insurance Industry, 110(3) J. POL. ECON. 481-507 (2002) provide evidence that the growth of pricecomparison websites for life insurance drove prices down for this product. An interesting study in the pre-Internet era had related findings. In 1974, two districts in Canada were chosen for a market transparency experiment in supermarket pricing. In one district, prices were collected but not publicized; in the other district, average price indices for individual supermarkets in that area were publicized in local newspapers. The result was that price dispersion and price levels fell in the second district relative to the first.
    • (2002) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.110 , Issue.3 , pp. 481-507
    • Brown, J.1    Goolsbee, A.2
  • 36
    • 0011269850 scopus 로고
    • The influence of consumer price information on retail pricing and consumer behavior
    • See
    • See G. Devine & B. Marion, The Influence of Consumer Price Information on Retail Pricing and Consumer Behavior, 61(2) AM. J. AGRIC. ECON. 228-37 (1979).
    • (1979) Am. J. Agric. Econ. , vol.61 , Issue.2 , pp. 228-37
    • Devine, G.1    Marion, B.2
  • 38
    • 70350204363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ¶ 9.18 (Jun.), reports that only 47 percent of Internet shoppers had used a price comparison website
    • and U.K. OFFICE OF FAIR TRADING (OFT), INTERNET SHOPPING: AN OFT MARKET STUDY ¶ 9.18 (Jun. 2007), reports that only 47 percent of Internet shoppers had used a price comparison website.
    • (2007) U.K. Office of Fair Trading (OFT), Internet Shopping: An OFT Market Study
  • 39
    • 7444262378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price dispersion in the small and the large: Evidence from an internet price comparison site
    • M. Baye, J. Morgan & P. Scholten, Price Dispersion in the Small and the Large: Evidence from an Internet Price Comparison Site, 52(4) J. INDUS. ECON. 463-96 (2004).
    • (2004) J. Indus. Econ. , vol.52 , Issue.4 , pp. 463-96
    • Baye, M.1    Morgan, J.2    Scholten, P.3
  • 40
    • 33745596723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition in two-sided markets
    • The recent literature on two-sided markets is relevant here, one example of which is, §5. Similar issues arise with the (typically non-price) market information found in Yellow Pages directories, where most consumers consult just one directory
    • The recent literature on two-sided markets is relevant here, one example of which is M. Armstrong, Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 37(3) RAND J. ECON. 668-91, §5 (2006). Similar issues arise with the (typically non-price) market information found in Yellow Pages directories, where most consumers consult just one directory.
    • (2006) Rand J. Econ. , vol.37 , Issue.3 , pp. 668-91
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 41
    • 1942501566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition between networks: A study of the market for yellow pages
    • See
    • See M. Rysman, Competition Between Networks: A Study of the Market for Yellow Pages, 71(2) REV. ECON. STUD. 483-512 (2004).
    • (2004) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.71 , Issue.2 , pp. 483-512
    • Rysman, M.1
  • 42
    • 0001463973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Information gatekeepers on the internet and the competitiveness of homogeneous product markets
    • present a model with a monopoly intermediary, and show that the intermediary restricts competition among sellers in order to increase the listing fee it can charge them
    • M. Baye & J. Morgan, Information Gatekeepers on the Internet and the Competitiveness of Homogeneous Product Markets, 91(3) AM. ECON. REV. 454-74 (2001) present a model with a monopoly intermediary, and show that the intermediary restricts competition among sellers in order to increase the listing fee it can charge them.
    • (2001) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.91 , Issue.3 , pp. 454-74
    • Baye, M.1    Morgan, J.2
  • 43
    • 70350184170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is worth noting that consumer-testing organizations often do not permit a good product review to be used in a product's advertising. This is in part because the consumer organization wishes to maintain revenue from consumers buying its magazine or subscribing to its website, but it does act to impede information flows about product quality to the wider consumer population
    • It is worth noting that consumer-testing organizations often do not permit a good product review to be used in a product's advertising. This is in part because the consumer organization wishes to maintain revenue from consumers buying its magazine or subscribing to its website, but it does act to impede information flows about product quality to the wider consumer population.
  • 44
    • 70350188753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Plus shipping and handling: Revenue (Non)equivalence in Field Experiments on eBay
    • Recent papers present evidence that obfuscation strategies, such as presenting a low headline price together with high small-print charges for postage, can confuse consumers and reduce firm-level demand elasticities. See, Search, Obfuscation and Price Elasticities on the Internet (2004) (mimeo, MIT) and OFT (Jun. 2007), supra note 34, at 125-27, documents a survey which revealed that the majority of listed prices do not make clear whether delivery is included, and in a sample of airline ticket bookings the final price was above the original listed price in 47 percent of cases (furthermore, for these cases, the median price increase was 19 percent)
    • Recent papers present evidence that obfuscation strategies, such as presenting a low headline price together with high small-print charges for postage, can confuse consumers and reduce firm-level demand elasticities. See G. Ellison & S. Fisher Ellison, Search, Obfuscation and Price Elasticities on the Internet (2004) (mimeo, MIT) and T. Hossain & J. Morgan, Plus Shipping and Handling: Revenue (Non)equivalence in Field Experiments on eBay, 6(2) ADVANCES IN ECON. ANALYSIS & POL'Y 1429 (2006). OFT (Jun. 2007), supra note 34, at 125-27, documents a survey which revealed that the majority of listed prices do not make clear whether delivery is included, and in a sample of airline ticket bookings the final price was above the original listed price in 47 percent of cases (furthermore, for these cases, the median price increase was 19 percent).
    • (2006) Advances In Econ. Analysis & Pol'Y , vol.6 , Issue.2 , pp. 1429
    • Ellison, G.1    Fisher, E.S.2    Hossain, T.3    Morgan, J.4
  • 45
    • 70350185818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Related issues arise with attempts to measure the life-time cost of a product. Such is the case with printers, which may have different per-page costs, or cars, which may have different running costs, where the lifetime cost depends on the usage made of the durable product. Matters are even worse with multi-product markets such as telecommunications and supermarkets, where consumers must key in their estimated demands for many products to get a valid comparison of suppliers
    • Related issues arise with attempts to measure the life-time cost of a product. Such is the case with printers, which may have different per-page costs, or cars, which may have different running costs, where the lifetime cost depends on the usage made of the durable product. Matters are even worse with multi-product markets such as telecommunications and supermarkets, where consumers must key in their estimated demands for many products to get a valid comparison of suppliers.
  • 46
    • 70350202875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the United Kingdom, several regulators have accredited price-comparison websites listed on their own websites, and one regulator, the Financial Services Authority, has its own comparison website. See FSA: Money made clear, at (last visited Jan. 28, 2008). In addition, the introduction of an approved price-comparison website was one of the remedies to market failure in
    • In the United Kingdom, several regulators have accredited price-comparison websites listed on their own websites, and one regulator, the Financial Services Authority, has its own comparison website. See FSA: Money made clear, at http://www.moneymadeclear.fsa.gov.uk (last visited Jan. 28, 2008). In addition, the introduction of an approved price-comparison website was one of the remedies to market failure in U.K. COMPETITION COMMISSION, HOME CREDIT MARKET INVESTIGATION 10 (2006).
    • (2006) U.K. Competition Commission, Home Credit Market Investigation , pp. 10
  • 47
    • 0000878787 scopus 로고
    • A model of sales
    • H. Varian, A Model of Sales, 70(4) AM. ECON. REV. 651-59 (1980).
    • (1980) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.70 , Issue.4 , pp. 651-59
    • Varian, H.1
  • 48
    • 84959809412 scopus 로고
    • Bargains and ripoffs: A model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion
    • A closely related model is
    • A closely related model is S. Salop & J. Stiglitz, Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of Monopolistically Competitive Price Dispersion, 44(3) REV. ECON. STUD. 493-510 (1977).
    • (1977) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.44 , Issue.3 , pp. 493-510
    • Salop, S.1    Stiglitz, J.2
  • 49
    • 70350200004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For instance, as emphasized by Brown & Goolsbee (2002), supra note 33, the well-informed consumers could be those who use price-comparison websites on the Internet, while the remainder are those who must painstakingly search supplier by supplier. The discussion in the text assumes that suppliers cannot set different prices for online and offline consumers, as was the case in Brown & Goolsbee's data. If suppliers could set different prices to informed and uninformed consumers (e.g., by making the price depend on whether the sale was online or offline), the model would have a very different prediction: informed consumers would pay competitive prices and uninformed consumers would pay monopoly prices, and the prices in each case would not depend on the number of suppliers or the fraction of informed consumers. Thus, informed consumers would not protect the uninformed at all. Here, a policy which boosts the fraction of informed consumers is good for aggregate consumer welfare, but it has no impact on those consumers who remain uninformed.
  • 50
    • 70350187437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brown & Goolsbee (2002), supra note 33, find support for this effect in the early part of their data where the fraction of consumers who used price-comparison websites was small
    • Brown & Goolsbee (2002), supra note 33, find support for this effect in the early part of their data where the fraction of consumers who used price-comparison websites was small.
  • 51
    • 84867938913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The role of consumers in competition and competition policy
    • Markets differ greatly in their consumer search costs. For instance, petrol has a rather low search cost since many consumers are already in their car when buying the product. As a result, prices are reasonably competitive and exhibit little dispersion within a local area. Funerals and condoms, by contrast, are often purchased by consumers with little appetite for market research. Car tires are frequently purchased by consumers who are not very mobile. In one study, 71 percent of consumers wanting to buy tires contact no other outlet apart from the one at which they buy. For details and further discussion, see M.Waterson, The Role of Consumers in Competition and Competition Policy, 21(2) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 129-50 (2003). However, the case of petrol presents an interesting danger: given that the market is understood by consumers to be reasonably competitive, consumers may not even bother checking the prices when they fill up, and this leaves a profit opportunity for unscrupulous (but legal) suppliers. For instance, in 1996, a Mr. Mole in Lancashire (United Kingdom) operated a number of petrol stations where petrol was nearly twice as expensive as his competitors.
    • (2003) Int'L J. Indus. Org. , vol.21 , Issue.2 , pp. 129-50
    • Waterson, M.1
  • 52
    • 70350196801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Garage fuels price protest
    • See, Jan. 19
    • See Garage fuels price protest, LANCASHIRE TELEGRAPH, Jan. 19, 1996.
    • (1996) Lancashire Telegraph
  • 53
    • 0000272277 scopus 로고
    • Equilibrium price dispersion
    • See Salop & Stiglitz (1977), supra note 41 and
    • See Salop & Stiglitz (1977), supra note 41 and K. Burdett & K. Judd, Equilibrium Price Dispersion, 51(4) ECONOMETRICA 955-69 (1983).
    • (1983) Econometrica , vol.51 , Issue.4 , pp. 955-69
    • Burdett, K.1    Judd, K.2
  • 54
    • 0033260379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pricing, product diversity, and search costs: A bertrand-chamberlin- diamond model
    • Related insights are obtained in the model with sequential search in, In that model, there is no price dispersion and the market price is an increasing function of the search cost
    • Related insights are obtained in the model with sequential search in S. Anderson & R. Renault, Pricing, Product Diversity, and Search Costs: a Bertrand-Chamberlin-Diamond Model, 30(4) RAND J. ECON. 719-35 (1999). In that model, there is no price dispersion and the market price is an increasing function of the search cost.
    • (1999) Rand J. Econ. , vol.30 , Issue.4 , pp. 719-35
    • Anderson, S.1    Renault, R.2
  • 55
    • 0000627340 scopus 로고
    • A model of price adjustment
    • P. Diamond, A Model of Price Adjustment, 3(2) J. ECON. THEORY 156-58 (1971).
    • (1971) J. Econ. Theory , vol.3 , Issue.2 , pp. 156-58
    • Diamond, P.1
  • 56
    • 84959835849 scopus 로고
    • Equilibrium distributions of sales and advertising prices
    • G. Butters, Equilibrium Distributions of Sales and Advertising Prices, 44(3) REV. ECON. STUD. 465-91 (1977).
    • (1977) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.44 , Issue.3 , pp. 465-91
    • Butters, G.1
  • 57
    • 0001078944 scopus 로고
    • The effect of advertising on the price of eyeglasses
    • For instance, empirical studies of opticians and legal services in the United States have investigated how relaxing a state ban on price advertising typically led to lower prices. See
    • For instance, empirical studies of opticians and legal services in the United States have investigated how relaxing a state ban on price advertising typically led to lower prices. See L. Benham, The Effect of Advertising on the Price of Eyeglasses, 15(2) J.L. & ECON. 337-52 (1972);
    • (1972) J.L. & Econ. , vol.15 , Issue.2 , pp. 337-52
    • Benham, L.1
  • 58
    • 0001252376 scopus 로고
    • Regulating through the professions: A perspective on information control
    • L. Benham & A. Benham, Regulating Through the Professions: A Perspective on Information Control, 18(2) J.L. & ECON. 421-47 (1975);
    • (1975) J.L. & Econ. , vol.18 , Issue.2 , pp. 421-47
    • Benham, L.1    Benham, A.2
  • 59
    • 0022634103 scopus 로고
    • The effect of commercial practice restrictions: The case of optometry
    • See also the review of related studies on the impact of advertising on prices in Bagwell (2007), supra note 18, at 1745-46
    • and D. Haas-Wilson, The Effect of Commercial Practice Restrictions: The Case of Optometry, 29(1) J.L. & ECON. 165-86 (1986). See also the review of related studies on the impact of advertising on prices in Bagwell (2007), supra note 18, at 1745-46.
    • (1986) J.L. & Econ. , vol.29 , Issue.1 , pp. 165-86
    • Haas-Wilson, D.1
  • 60
    • 24344489887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public service broadcasting
    • More generally, while new technologies often facilitate information flows to consumers, they can sometimes also help consumers avoid adverts. For instance, personal video recorders in broadcasting and "pop-up blockers" on the Internet allow consumer to avoid adverts. Since many consumers dislike viewing adverts, but there is a competitive benefit to consumers as a whole when more consumers receive adverts, it is possible that the increased use of ad-avoidance devices may harm aggregate consumer welfare. A simple model of broadcasting in which the ability to opt out of advertising harms viewers can be found in, 295
    • More generally, while new technologies often facilitate information flows to consumers, they can sometimes also help consumers avoid adverts. For instance, personal video recorders in broadcasting and "pop-up blockers" on the Internet allow consumer to avoid adverts. Since many consumers dislike viewing adverts, but there is a competitive benefit to consumers as a whole when more consumers receive adverts, it is possible that the increased use of ad-avoidance devices may harm aggregate consumer welfare. A simple model of broadcasting in which the ability to opt out of advertising harms viewers can be found in M. Armstrong, Public Service Broadcasting, 26(3) FISCAL STUD. 281-99, 295 (2005).
    • (2005) Fiscal Stud. , vol.26 , Issue.3 , pp. 281-99
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 61
    • 33749054115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The market for quacks
    • R. Spiegler, The Market for Quacks, 73(4) REV. ECON. STUD. 1113-31 (2006a).
    • (2006) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.73 , Issue.4 , pp. 1113-31
    • Spiegler, R.1
  • 62
    • 33845979262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition over agents with boundedly rational expectations
    • Spiegler interprets his model in terms of a product with many pricing attributes, where a consumer's inability to process many pieces of information implies that she just looks at a small number of price attributes for the product, while the expected price eventually paid depends on all pricing attributes
    • R. Spiegler, Competition Over Agents with Boundedly Rational Expectations, 1(2) THEORETICAL ECON. 207-31 (2006b). Spiegler interprets his model in terms of a product with many pricing attributes, where a consumer's inability to process many pieces of information implies that she just looks at a small number of price attributes for the product, while the expected price eventually paid depends on all pricing attributes.
    • (2006) Theoretical Econ. , vol.1 , Issue.2 , pp. 207-31
    • Spiegler, R.1
  • 63
    • 70350188758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Suppose the unit production cost is c. If all firms offer transparent prices, there is Bertrand competition and price is equal to c. Suppose instead that one firm sets a noisy price, where its true price is 2c and its (unbiased) signal is either zero or 4c with equal probability. This seller will have the lowest signal in the market half the time, and in these cases it will make the sale and make a positive profit while doing so
    • Suppose the unit production cost is c. If all firms offer transparent prices, there is Bertrand competition and price is equal to c. Suppose instead that one firm sets a noisy price, where its true price is 2c and its (unbiased) signal is either zero or 4c with equal probability. This seller will have the lowest signal in the market half the time, and in these cases it will make the sale and make a positive profit while doing so.
  • 64
    • 0034353982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The impact of mandatory disclosure laws on product choices: An analysis of the salad dressing market
    • discusses how a change to a mandatory policy for food labeling affected disclosure of fat content in salad dressing.With a voluntary labeling regime there was substantial disclosure by low-fat suppliers, but the dressings with no disclosure had a wide range of fat content. Mandatory labeling thus improved the information available to consumers
    • A. Mathios, The Impact of Mandatory Disclosure Laws on Product Choices: An Analysis of the Salad Dressing Market, 43(2) J.L. & ECON. 651-77 (2000) discusses how a change to a mandatory policy for food labeling affected disclosure of fat content in salad dressing.With a voluntary labeling regime there was substantial disclosure by low-fat suppliers, but the dressings with no disclosure had a wide range of fat content. Mandatory labeling thus improved the information available to consumers.
    • (2000) J.L. & Econ. , vol.43 , Issue.2 , pp. 651-77
    • Mathios, A.1
  • 65
    • 21644452154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition and disclosure incentives: An empirical study of HMOs
    • shows that only some health suppliers chose to make use of a (costly) accreditation service
    • Likewise, G. Jin, Competition and Disclosure Incentives: An Empirical Study of HMOs, 36(1) RAND J. ECON. 93-112 (2005) shows that only some health suppliers chose to make use of a (costly) accreditation service.
    • (2005) Rand J. Econ. , vol.36 , Issue.1 , pp. 93-112
    • Jin, L.G.1
  • 66
    • 84925910121 scopus 로고
    • Beyond nader: Consumer protection and the regulation of advertising
    • 664, In fact, Posner (1969), supra note 31, at 69, claims that the FTC acted in the early 1960s to prevent the disclosure of tar and nicotine content in cigarette advertising
    • R. Pitofsky, Beyond Nader: Consumer Protection and the Regulation of Advertising, 90(4) HARV. L. REV. 661-701, 664 (1977). In fact, Posner (1969), supra note 31, at 69, claims that the FTC acted in the early 1960s to prevent the disclosure of tar and nicotine content in cigarette advertising.
    • (1977) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.90 , Issue.4 , pp. 661-701
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 67
    • 0037677802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effect of information on product quality: Evidence from restaurant hygiene grade cards
    • G. Jin & P. Leslie, The Effect of Information on Product Quality: Evidence From Restaurant Hygiene Grade Cards, 118(2) Q.J. ECON. 409-51 (2003).
    • (2003) Q.J. Econ. , vol.118 , Issue.2 , pp. 409-51
    • Jin, G.1    Leslie, P.2
  • 68
    • 70350182561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • G. Jin & P. Leslie (2009), supra note 16, at 1. The authors conclude that "even when there is merit to the argument that reputational incentives operate as a market-based mechanism for mitigating information problems, they may be a poor substitute for full information."
    • G. Jin & P. Leslie (2009), supra note 16, at 1. The authors conclude that "even when there is merit to the argument that reputational incentives operate as a market-based mechanism for mitigating information problems, they may be a poor substitute for full information."
  • 69
    • 21344495199 scopus 로고
    • Retail pricing and advertising strategies
    • R. Lal & C. Matutes, Retail Pricing and Advertising Strategies, 67(3) J. BUS. 345-70 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Bus. , vol.67 , Issue.3 , pp. 345-70
    • Lal, R.1    Matutes, C.2
  • 70
    • 66049101414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects
    • For a survey, see, (M. Armstrong & R. Porter eds.)
    • For a survey, see Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects, in 3 THE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 1967-2072 (M. Armstrong & R. Porter eds., 2007).
    • (2007) The Handbook Of Industrial Organization , vol.3 , pp. 1967-2072
    • Farrell, J.1    Klemperer, P.2
  • 71
    • 84937295025 scopus 로고
    • The limits of cognition and the limits of contract
    • See
    • See M. Eisenberg, The Limits of Cognition and the Limits of Contract, 47(2) STANFORD L. REV. 211-59 (1995)
    • (1995) Stanford L. Rev. , vol.47 , Issue.2 , pp. 211-59
    • Eisenberg, M.1
  • 72
    • 62749123577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract law
    • as well as the discussion of that paper and related literature in, §2.3.4 (M. Polinsky & S. Shavell eds.)
    • as well as the discussion of that paper and related literature in B. Hermalin, A. Katz & R. Craswell, Contract Law, in 1 THE HANDBOOK OF LAW & ECONOMICS §2.3.4 (M. Polinsky & S. Shavell eds., 2007).
    • (2007) The Handbook Of Law & Economics , vol.1
    • Hermalin, B.1    Katz, A.2    Craswell, R.3
  • 73
    • 70350201275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This effect is akin to the so-called "waterbed effect" seen in markets such as mobile telephony. There, if one charge is reduced by policy, it does not necessarily have an impact on equilibrium industry profits, but it will cause another price to rise correspondingly
    • This effect is akin to the so-called "waterbed effect" seen in markets such as mobile telephony. There, if one charge is reduced by policy, it does not necessarily have an impact on equilibrium industry profits, but it will cause another price to rise correspondingly.
  • 74
    • 20444383206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A model of add-on pricing
    • G. Ellison, A Model of Add-on Pricing, 120(2) Q.J. ECON. 585-637 (2005).
    • (2005) Q.J. Econ. , vol.120 , Issue.2 , pp. 585-637
    • Ellison, G.1
  • 75
    • 21844516933 scopus 로고
    • Aftermarkets and consumer welfare: Making sense of kodak
    • See Ellison (2005), Id. at Proposition 4 and
    • See Ellison (2005), Id. at Proposition 4 and C. Shapiro, Aftermarkets and Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak, 63(2) ANTITRUST L.J. 496 (1995).
    • (1995) Antitrust L.J. , vol.63 , Issue.2 , pp. 496
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 76
    • 33646375435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets
    • The numerical example which follows is essentially taken from section 1 of their paper. In a very different model Spiegler (2006a), supra note 50, also shows that firms do not wish to "de-bias" consumers. These recent results go against the claim in Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 502, and many other authors, that "if information dissemination were costless to sellers, theory suggests that disclosure would be complete."
    • X. Gabaix & D. Laibson, Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets, 121(2) Q.J. ECON. 505-40 (2006). The numerical example which follows is essentially taken from section 1 of their paper. In a very different model Spiegler (2006a), supra note 50, also shows that firms do not wish to "de-bias" consumers. These recent results go against the claim in Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 502, and many other authors, that "if information dissemination were costless to sellers, theory suggests that disclosure would be complete."
    • (2006) Q.J. Econ. , vol.121 , Issue.2 , pp. 505-40
    • Gabaix, X.1    Laibson, D.2
  • 77
    • 70350205921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a competitive market, the excess profits made on the add-on will be passed back to consumers in the form of inducements to buy the main item, and industry profits will not be excessive overall. In this case, the consumer harm consists just of the deadweight loss "triangles" rather than the monopoly profit "rectangles" which result from excessive pricing of add-ons. As such, the consumer welfare loss may be relatively small. See Shapiro (1995), supra note 62, at 497-98
    • In a competitive market, the excess profits made on the add-on will be passed back to consumers in the form of inducements to buy the main item, and industry profits will not be excessive overall. In this case, the consumer harm consists just of the deadweight loss "triangles" rather than the monopoly profit "rectangles" which result from excessive pricing of add-ons. As such, the consumer welfare loss may be relatively small. See Shapiro (1995), supra note 62, at 497-98.
  • 78
    • 70350188755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As an example of the latter policy, Gabaix & Laibson (2006), supra note 63, report that policy in Singapore required that hotels price their international phone calls at marginal cost plus a maximum of 30 Singaporean cents
    • As an example of the latter policy, Gabaix & Laibson (2006), supra note 63, report that policy in Singapore required that hotels price their international phone calls at marginal cost plus a maximum of 30 Singaporean cents.
  • 80
    • 70350195133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OFT (Jun. 2007), supra note 34, at 127
    • OFT (Jun. 2007), supra note 34, at 127.
  • 81
    • 70350190329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This assumes the printer controls the retail price of its cartridges, and would also require a standardized "page" to facilitate comparisons. The general issue of establishing standardized scoring systems, and how a public body might act as a useful coordination device for this, is discussed in Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 523-27
    • This assumes the printer controls the retail price of its cartridges, and would also require a standardized "page" to facilitate comparisons. The general issue of establishing standardized scoring systems, and how a public body might act as a useful coordination device for this, is discussed in Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 523-27.
  • 82
    • 33846642123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.K. Financial Services Authority, reports that when buying a financial product, about half of survey respondents read the terms and conditions "in detail", while 10 percent did not read them at all
    • U.K. FINANCIAL SERVICES AUTHORITY, LEVELS OF FINANCIAL CAPABILITY IN THE UK: RESULTS OF A BASELINE SURVEY (2006) reports that when buying a financial product, about half of survey respondents read the terms and conditions "in detail", while 10 percent did not read them at all.
    • (2006) Levels of Financial Capability in the Uk: Results of a Baseline Survey
  • 83
    • 0742271634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded rationality, standard form contracts, and unconscionability
    • See also the references in, and the references listed in note 38 supra
    • See also the references in R. Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1203-95, n. 45 (2003) and the references listed in note 38 supra.
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , Issue.45 , pp. 1203-95
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 84
    • 33744548714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paying not to go to the gym
    • DellaVigna & Malmendier (2004), supra note 24, Their 2006 paper provides evidence showing that many consumers choose a gym membership, even though they end up going so rarely they would be better off with pay-per-visit arrangement
    • DellaVigna & Malmendier (2004), supra note 24, and S. DellaVigna & U. Malmendier, Paying Not to Go to the Gym, 96(3) AM. ECON. REV. 694-719 (2006). Their 2006 paper provides evidence showing that many consumers choose a gym membership, even though they end up going so rarely they would be better off with pay-per-visit arrangement.
    • (2006) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.96 , Issue.3 , pp. 694-719
    • DellaVigna, S.1    Malmendier, U.2
  • 85
    • 70350184167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A related feature is observed in a monopoly context in Milgrom & Roberts (1986), supra note 20, at Proposition 3
    • A related feature is observed in a monopoly context in Milgrom & Roberts (1986), supra note 20, at Proposition 3.
  • 86
    • 84945701095 scopus 로고
    • Unrealistic optimism about future life events
    • See, respectively
    • See, respectively, N.Weinstein, Unrealistic Optimism About Future Life Events, 39(5) J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 806-20 (1980);
    • (1980) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.39 , Issue.5 , pp. 806-20
    • Weinstein, N.1
  • 87
    • 0013136339 scopus 로고
    • Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers?
    • and O. Svenson, Are We All Less Risky and More Skillful than our Fellow Drivers?, 47(2) ACTA PSYCHOLOGICA 143-48 (1981).
    • (1981) Acta Psychologica , vol.47 , Issue.2 , pp. 143-48
    • Svenson, O.1
  • 88
    • 0001881029 scopus 로고
    • The failure of competition in the credit card market
    • L. Ausubel, The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 81(1) AM. ECON. REV. 50-81 (1991).
    • (1991) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.81 , Issue.1 , pp. 50-81
    • Ausubel, L.1
  • 89
    • 70350207591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M. Grubb, Selling to Overconfident Consumers (2007) (mimeo, MIT). As well as providing the theoretical analysis outlined here, Grubb presents empirical data in support of the hypothesis that consumers are overconfident in their predictions of future usage. See Eliaz & Spiegler (2006), supra note 24, for closely related theoretical work in the context of time-inconsistent consumers
    • M. Grubb, Selling to Overconfident Consumers (2007) (mimeo, MIT). As well as providing the theoretical analysis outlined here, Grubb presents empirical data in support of the hypothesis that consumers are overconfident in their predictions of future usage. See Eliaz & Spiegler (2006), supra note 24, for closely related theoretical work in the context of time-inconsistent consumers.
  • 90
    • 70350200001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DellaVigna & Malmendier (2004), supra note 24, at §II.G, discuss possible regulatory intervention in the contracts offered by, say, gyms. They come to the pessimistic conclusion that "it requires extensive information which the government is unlikely to have [ . . . ]. A better policy for the government, in general, is to educate partially naive users and make them aware of their naiveté." No specific guidelines for how to do this are given, however
    • DellaVigna & Malmendier (2004), supra note 24, at §II.G, discuss possible regulatory intervention in the contracts offered by, say, gyms. They come to the pessimistic conclusion that "it requires extensive information which the government is unlikely to have [ . . . ]. A better policy for the government, in general, is to educate partially naive users and make them aware of their naiveté." No specific guidelines for how to do this are given, however.
  • 91
    • 33645299546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Debiasing through law
    • Here, the form of the warning is likely to be very important. See
    • Here, the form of the warning is likely to be very important. See C. Jolls & C. Sunstein, Debiasing Through Law, 35(1) J. LEGAL STUD. 199-241 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Legal Stud. , vol.35 , Issue.1 , pp. 199-241
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.2
  • 92
    • 38049123120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overconfidence, insurance, and paternalism
    • A. Sandroni & F. Squintani, Overconfidence, Insurance, and Paternalism, 97(5) AM. ECON. REV. 1994-2004 (2007).
    • (2007) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.97 , Issue.5 , pp. 1994-2004
    • Sandroni, A.1    Squintani, F.2
  • 93
    • 70350188757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taken from Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5, at 1231
    • Taken from Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5, at 1231.
  • 94
    • 0344944817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Projection bias in predicting future utility
    • G. Loewenstein, T. O'Donoghue & M. Rabin, Projection Bias in Predicting Future Utility, 118(4) Q.J. ECON. 1209-48 (2003).
    • (2003) Q.J. Econ. , vol.118 , Issue.4 , pp. 1209-48
    • Loewenstein, G.1    O'Donoghue, T.2    Rabin, M.3
  • 95
    • 70350193366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5. Of course, another reason for cooling-off periods is when there is a danger that the contract may have been signed under duress. In this case, the cooling-off period will both protect the consumer from being locked into a contract she did not freely sign, and lessen the incentive to engage in aggressive selling practices in the first place
    • Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5. Of course, another reason for cooling-off periods is when there is a danger that the contract may have been signed under duress. In this case, the cooling-off period will both protect the consumer from being locked into a contract she did not freely sign, and lessen the incentive to engage in aggressive selling practices in the first place.
  • 96
    • 70350209171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DellaVigna & Malmendier (2004), supra note 24, at §IV
    • See DellaVigna & Malmendier (2004), supra note 24, at §IV.
  • 97
    • 70350205923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When Korobkin (2003), supra note 69, at 1235-36, discusses this point, he does not analyze a monopolist's incentive to supply the low-quality product
    • When Korobkin (2003), supra note 69, at 1235-36, discusses this point, he does not analyze a monopolist's incentive to supply the low-quality product.
  • 98
    • 70350202873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M. Armstrong & Y. Chen, Inattentive Consumers and Product Quality (2007) (mimeo, University College London and University of Colorado at Boulder)
    • M. Armstrong & Y. Chen, Inattentive Consumers and Product Quality (2007) (mimeo, University College London and University of Colorado at Boulder).
  • 99
    • 70350205924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Y. Chen & M. Riordan, Price-Increasing Competition (2006) (mimeo, University of Colorado at Boulder and Columbia University)
    • Y. Chen & M. Riordan, Price-Increasing Competition (2006) (mimeo, University of Colorado at Boulder and Columbia University).
  • 100
    • 70350193368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is discussed in Armstrong & Chen (2007), supra note 83, rather than in Varian's article itself
    • This is discussed in Armstrong & Chen (2007), supra note 83, rather than in Varian's article itself.
  • 101
    • 0034571771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing?
    • A famous psychology experiment is described in
    • A famous psychology experiment is described in S. Iyengar & M. Lepper, When Choice is Demotivating: Can One Desire Too Much of a Good Thing?, 79(6) J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 995-1006 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.79 , Issue.6 , pp. 995-1006
    • Iyengar, S.1    Lepper, M.2
  • 103
    • 58149105629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For data indicating that many consumers do not choose the best electricity supplier for their needs even when they switch supplier, see, (Centre for Competition Policy,Working Paper No. 07-6)
    • For data indicating that many consumers do not choose the best electricity supplier for their needs even when they switch supplier, see CHRIS WILSON & CATHERINE WADDAMS PRICE, DO CONSUMERS SWITCH TO THE BEST SUPPLIER? (Centre for Competition Policy,Working Paper No. 07-6, 2007).
    • (2007) Do Consumers Switch TO the Best Supplier?
    • Wilson, C.1    Price, C.W.2
  • 104
    • 70350193369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All of this is taken from U.K. National Audit Office, Mar
    • All of this is taken from U.K. NATIONAL AUDIT OFFICE, DIRECTORY ENQUIRIES: FROM 192 TO 118 (Mar. 2005).
    • (2005) Directory Enquiries: From 192 to 118
  • 105
    • 70350195135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Waterson (2003), supra note 44, at Table 7, presents a survey in which one-third of consumers thought it would take at least a day to switch electricity supplier, when in fact it would probably take less than an hour
    • Waterson (2003), supra note 44, at Table 7, presents a survey in which one-third of consumers thought it would take at least a day to switch electricity supplier, when in fact it would probably take less than an hour.
  • 107
    • 70350200002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See COASE (1950), Id. at 177
    • See COASE (1950), Id. at 177.
  • 108
    • 70350205926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 497
    • See Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 497.
  • 109
    • 70350184169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pitofsky (1977), supra note 54, at 674. The report by Professor Posner alluded to was expanded to become Posner (1969), supra note 31. 95
    • Pitofsky (1977), supra note 54, at 674. The report by Professor Posner alluded to was expanded to become Posner (1969), supra note 31. 95
  • 110
    • 70350174876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 17, supra
    • See note 17, supra.
  • 112
    • 70350205922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Muris, supra note 1. Muris quotes the FTC as writing in a court statement that "[r]ather than protect[ ing] consumers by exposing funeral directors to meaningful competition, the [law] protects funeral directors from facing any competition from third-party casket sellers."
    • See Muris, supra note 1. Muris quotes the FTC as writing in a court statement that "[r]ather than protect[ ing] consumers by exposing funeral directors to meaningful competition, the [law] protects funeral directors from facing any competition from third-party casket sellers."
  • 114
    • 70350205925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, information remedies which educate naive consumers can also make sophisticated consumers worse off in the B-type situations described in Section III.D. But there is a difference between correcting an "unfair" cross-subsidy caused by inattentive consumers, and harming sophisticated consumers in order to support inattentive consumers
    • However, information remedies which educate naive consumers can also make sophisticated consumers worse off in the B-type situations described in Section III.D. But there is a difference between correcting an "unfair" cross-subsidy caused by inattentive consumers, and harming sophisticated consumers in order to support inattentive consumers.
  • 115
    • 36248979927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Repugnance as a constraint on markets
    • Also, in democracies majorities may vote to outlaw choices made by minorities. For instance, in 1998 a California referendum voted to outlaw the sale of horsemeat in restaurants. See
    • Also, in democracies majorities may vote to outlaw choices made by minorities. For instance, in 1998 a California referendum voted to outlaw the sale of horsemeat in restaurants. See Alvin Roth, Repugnance as a Constraint on Markets, 21(3) J. ECON. PERSP. 37-58 (2007).
    • (2007) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.21 , Issue.3 , pp. 37-58
    • Roth, A.1
  • 116
    • 33745949507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government regulation of irrationality: Moral and cognitive hazards
    • J. Klick & G. Mitchell, Government Regulation of Irrationality: Moral and Cognitive Hazards, 90 MINNESOTA L. REV. 1620-63 (2006).
    • (2006) Minnesota L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 1620-63
    • Klick, J.1    Mitchell, G.2
  • 117
    • 70350209173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 513
    • Beales et al. (1981), supra note 25, at 513.
  • 118
    • 70350209172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Likewise, in 2005 the European Commission required airlines to compensate consumers for cancelled flights, regardless of the cause, thus bundling together the flight and travel insurance
    • Likewise, in 2005 the European Commission required airlines to compensate consumers for cancelled flights, regardless of the cause, thus bundling together the flight and travel insurance.
  • 119
    • 0000312617 scopus 로고
    • Quacks, lemons and licensing: A theory of minimum quality standards
    • H. Leland, Quacks, Lemons and Licensing: A Theory of Minimum Quality Standards, 87(6) J. POL. ECON. 1328-46 (1979).
    • (1979) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.87 , Issue.6 , pp. 1328-46
    • Leland, H.1
  • 120
    • 70350187436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Korobkin (2003), supra note 69, at 1251-52, puts it: "ex ante mandatory terms are desirable when a simple rule or an only moderately complicated rule can insure that the mandated content will be efficient for a relatively large proportion of contracts."
    • As Korobkin (2003), supra note 69, at 1251-52, puts it: "ex ante mandatory terms are desirable when a simple rule or an only moderately complicated rule can insure that the mandated content will be efficient for a relatively large proportion of contracts."
  • 121
    • 70350171713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Armstrong & Chen (2007), supra note 83
    • See Armstrong & Chen (2007), supra note 83.
  • 122
    • 70350196799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, then such a firm would not put the charge in the small print. Alternatively, a credit card company might require its customers to agree to pay a minimum monthly payment (or even the entire balance) by direct debit each month. The supplier may thus hope to attract credit-worthy customers and also to remove the need to run a large "debt collection" office. However, this point conflicts with the discussion in Section III.D of this paper, where I discussed how a credit card company might make more money from its less solvent customers
    • Of course, then such a firm would not put the charge in the small print. Alternatively, a credit card company might require its customers to agree to pay a minimum monthly payment (or even the entire balance) by direct debit each month. The supplier may thus hope to attract credit-worthy customers and also to remove the need to run a large "debt collection" office. However, this point conflicts with the discussion in Section III.D of this paper, where I discussed how a credit card company might make more money from its less solvent customers.
  • 123
    • 70350187434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In 2006, the OFT announced that it regarded penalty charges (for all kinds of default, including spending beyond the agreed credit limit) higher than GBP 12 as being unfair, and that such charges would lead it to intervene. The legal framework for this decision is provided by the 1999 Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Regulations. A "core term" (e.g., the headline price, or interest rate in the case of credit cards) in a contract can essentially be set at any level, but other items in a standard contract (to which some consumers will not pay attention when they sign) are subject to a "fairness" constraint. In the case of breach of contract (which is what late payment technically is), the fairness constraint broadly allows the supplier to have its additional administrative costs covered by the penalty charge. The OFT estimated these administrative costs at GBP 12, and gave some broad (but unquantified) indications of how it estimated these costs. It states that "on the basis of our analysis we consider that the threshold is robust and there are unlikely to be grounds to consider any higher threshold for our action over the short or medium term." See U.K. OFFICE OF FAIR TRADING, CALCULATING FAIR DEFAULT CHARGES IN CREDIT CARD CONTRACTS: A STATEMENT OF THE OFT'S POSITION (Apr. 2006).
    • (2006) U.K. Office of Fair Trading, Calculating Fair Default Charges in Credit Card Contracts: A Statement of the Oft'S Position
  • 124
    • 70350171711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to this list, one could point out that in the United Kingdom there has been so much recent publicity about credit card penalty charges that the number of consumers who are now unaware of such charges has shrunk substantially, thus mitigating to some extent the need for further intervention in this area
    • In addition to this list, one could point out that in the United Kingdom there has been so much recent publicity about credit card penalty charges that the number of consumers who are now unaware of such charges has shrunk substantially, thus mitigating to some extent the need for further intervention in this area.
  • 125
    • 70350193367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This view is emphasized in Klick & Mitchell (2006), supra note 101. In particular, §1A of that paper surveys the ample, though not unanimous, evidence that subjects in laboratory experiments make better decisions when their stakes are higher
    • This view is emphasized in Klick & Mitchell (2006), supra note 101. In particular, §1A of that paper surveys the ample, though not unanimous, evidence that subjects in laboratory experiments make better decisions when their stakes are higher.
  • 126
    • 70350187435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner (1969), supra note 31, at 67
    • Posner (1969), supra note 31, at 67.
  • 127
    • 70350207592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • However, just because there is moral hazard does not mean insurance should not be offered at all. One might balk at permitting sales to the general public of Japanese pufferfish, which is fatal if prepared even slightly incorrectly. Staying with the food theme, another related issue is the widespread use of "use-by" dates on food. Many consumers never use food beyond its use-by date. Given that the use-by date is chosen so that the foodstuff is almost certain to be edible regardless of local conditions (e.g., how often the consumer's fridge is opened), it is plausible that inefficiency arises from this policy. If use-by dates were less widespread (say, in the days when many consumers purchased meat from a butcher rather than a supermarket), consumers would likely have better skills in detecting whether food is edible (e.g., by smell). This is another instance of how arguably excessive protection leads to consumers possessing too few market skills. Of course, though, one cannot sniff a "ready meal".
  • 128
    • 38949192008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a plausible lifecycle effect here. Younger consumers may not yet have learnt their market skills, whereas some of the elderly may have learnt, but forgotten, their skills. In particular, policy might sometimes exempt the latter group from this caution about over-insulating consumers against market risk. See, (MIT Department of Economics,Working Paper No. 07-11) for some evidence that consumers reach their decision-making peak for financial products at around 53 years of age
    • There is a plausible lifecycle effect here. Younger consumers may not yet have learnt their market skills, whereas some of the elderly may have learnt, but forgotten, their skills. In particular, policy might sometimes exempt the latter group from this caution about over-insulating consumers against market risk. See S. AGARWAL, J. DRISCOLL, X. GABAIX & D. LAIBSON, THE AGE OF REASON: FINANCIAL DECISION-MAKING OVER THE LIFECYCLE (MIT Department of Economics,Working Paper No. 07-11, 2007) for some evidence that consumers reach their decision-making peak for financial products at around 53 years of age.
    • (2007) The Age of Reason: Financial Decision-Making Over the Lifecycle
    • Agarwal, S.1    Driscoll, J.2    Gabaix, X.3    Laibson, D.4
  • 129
    • 85076737870 scopus 로고
    • Monopolistic competition when price and quality are imperfectly observable
    • The first model presented in the appendix is similar to (but simpler than)
    • The first model presented in the appendix is similar to (but simpler than) D. Dranove & M. Satterthwaite, Monopolistic Competition when Price and
    • (1992) Rand J. Econ. , vol.23 , Issue.4 , pp. 518-34
    • Dranove, D.1    Satterthwaite, M.2
  • 130
    • 70350198424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. Huck, G. Lünser & J.-R. Tyran, Pricing and Trust (2008) (mimeo, University of College London), presents experimental evidence which is consistent with this discussion
    • S. Huck, G. Lünser & J.-R. Tyran, Pricing and Trust (2008) (mimeo, University of College London), presents experimental evidence which is consistent with this discussion.
  • 131
    • 0002430504 scopus 로고
    • Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design
    • This insight is similar to that in the principal-agent literature, where when an agent's overall performance depends on several kinds of effort, excessive focus on one kind of effort may lead to poor overall performance. See
    • This insight is similar to that in the principal-agent literature, where when an agent's overall performance depends on several kinds of effort, excessive focus on one kind of effort may lead to poor overall performance. See B. Holmstrom & P. Milgrom, Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design, 7(special issue) J.L. ECON & ORG. 24-52 (1991).
    • (1991) J.L. Econ & Org. , vol.7 , Issue.SPEC. ISSUE , pp. 24-52
    • Holmstrom, B.1    Milgrom, P.2
  • 132
    • 0042626505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is more information better? The effects of "report cards" on health care providers
    • D. Dranove, D. Kessler, M. McClellan & M. Satterthwaite, Is More Information Better? The Effects of "Report Cards" on Health Care Providers, 111(3) J. POL. ECON. 555-88 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.111 , Issue.3 , pp. 555-88
    • Dranove, D.1    Kessler, D.2    McClellan, M.3    Satterthwaite, M.4
  • 133
    • 84928277629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, (Cambridge University Press) for a detailed analysis and evaluation of various transparency policies such as this one
    • See ARCHON FUNG, MARY GRAHAM & DAVID WEIL, FULL DISCLOSURE: THE PERILS & PROMISE OF TRANSPARENCY (Cambridge University Press, 2007) for a detailed analysis and evaluation of various transparency policies such as this one.
    • (2007) Full Disclosure: The Perils & Promise of Transparency
    • Fung, A.1    Graham, M.2    Weil, D.3
  • 134
    • 0031521686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government-assisted oligopoly coordination? A concrete case
    • S. Albæk, P. Møllgaard & P. Overgaard, Government-Assisted Oligopoly Coordination? A Concrete Case, 45(4) J. INDUS. ECON. 429-43 (1997).
    • (1997) J. Indus. Econ. , vol.45 , Issue.4 , pp. 429-43
    • Albæk, S.1    Møllgaard, P.2    Overgaard, P.3
  • 135
    • 34247617016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent developments in the economics of price discrimination §3.3
    • See, e.g, (R. Blundell et al. eds.)
    • See, e.g., Mark Armstrong, Recent Developments in the Economics of Price Discrimination §3.3, in II ADVANCES IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS 97-141 (R. Blundell et al. eds., 2006).
    • (2006) II Advances in Economics & Econometrics , pp. 97-141
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 136
    • 1842863101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Libertarian paternalism
    • The philosophy behind such policies is sometimes termed "asymmetric paternalism" by Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5, or "libertarian paternalism" (or even "anti-anti-paternalism") by
    • The philosophy behind such policies is sometimes termed "asymmetric paternalism" by Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5, or "libertarian paternalism" (or even "anti-anti-paternalism") by R. Thaler & C. Sunstein, Libertarian Paternalism, 93(2) AM. ECON. REV. 175-79 (2003).1
    • (2003) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.93 , Issue.2 , pp. 175-79
    • Thaler, R.1    Sunstein, C.2
  • 137
    • 70350177797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5, at 1226. 122
    • See Camerer et al. (2003), supra note 5, at 1226. 122
  • 138
    • 70350195134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., MOTTA (2004), supra note 2, at §1.3.1
    • See, e.g., MOTTA (2004), supra note 2, at §1.3.1.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.