메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 66, Issue 2, 2014, Pages 217-302

Does the logic of collective action explain federalism doctrine?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84892729538     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (23)

References (529)
  • 1
    • 0039079572 scopus 로고
    • Congress Is a "They, " Not an "It": Legislative Intent as Oxymoron
    • For the locus classicus of this observation with respect to Congress, see Kenneth A. Shepsle, Congress Is a "They, " Not an "It": Legislative Intent as Oxymoron, 12 Int'l. Rev. L. & Econ. 239, 244 (1992).
    • (1992) Int'l. Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.12
    • Shepsle, K.A.1
  • 2
    • 76749152493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The most obvious of these are the Senate and the Electoral College. See U.S. Const. art. I, § 3, cl. 1 (Senate).
    • U.S. Const. art. I
  • 3
    • 76749152493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The most obvious of these are the Senate and the Electoral College. See U.S. Const. art. I, § 3, cl. 1 (Senate).
    • U.S. Const. art. I
  • 5
    • 0003974598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This formulation raises an important normative question about the nature of representation in a federal government: how can elected institutions, including Congress and the President, simultaneously represent both aggregate populations of electors and also respect institutional commitments, such as federalism or a role fidelity to their respective branches? For the purposes of this Article, I bracket the hard normative question of how to conceptualize representation in a compound democratic republic. For an insightful analysis through a comparative and historical lens, see generally Bernard Manin, The Principles of Representative Government (1997).
    • (1997) The Principles of Representative Government
    • Manin, B.1
  • 6
    • 84894640122 scopus 로고
    • 469 U.S. 528, 550-51 (1985).
    • (1985) U.S. , vol.469
  • 7
    • 15744389689 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Lopez
    • note
    • United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549, 578 (1995) (Kennedy, J., concurring).
    • (1995) U.S. , vol.514
  • 8
    • 0007449467 scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is common for judges and scholars to align the term "federalism" with claims and outcomes that favor the states over the national government. In this Article, I try to avoid this imprecise and selective usage, except when I am quoting and discussing sources speaking in such terms. Instead, I use the term "federalism" more abstractly to refer to an arrangement of governmental powers across jurisdictions of different sizes that coexist in the same geographic territory. For a useful history of the term, see generally S. Rufus Davis, The Federal Principle: A Journey Through Time in Quest of a Meaning (1978).
    • (1978) The Federal Principle: A Journey Through Time in Quest of a Meaning
    • Davis, S.R.1
  • 13
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • note
    • Coase famously explained that when transaction costs are zero, an efficient result is reached regardless of the initial assignment of a legal entitlement. R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & Econ. 1, 8 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 14
    • 84894625070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Enduring Power of Coase
    • Elizabeth Hoffman & Matthew L. Spitzer, The Enduring Power of Coase, 54 J.L. & Econ. S63, S64 (2011).
    • (2011) J.L. & Econ. , vol.54
    • Hoffman, E.1    Spitzer, M.L.2
  • 15
    • 84894625070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Enduring Power of Coase
    • Elizabeth Hoffman & Matthew L. Spitzer, The Enduring Power of Coase, 54 J.L. & Econ. S63, S64 (2011).
    • (2011) J.L. & Econ. , vol.54
    • Hoffman, E.1    Spitzer, M.L.2
  • 16
    • 77953080035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L
    • note
    • Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010) (codified as amended in scattered sections of 25, 26, and 42 U.S.C.).
    • (2010) Stat. , vol.124 , pp. 119
  • 17
    • 84861870818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Free Riding on Benevolence: Collective Action and the Minimum Coverage Provision
    • note
    • See, e.g., Neil S. Siegel, Free Riding on Benevolence: Collective Action and the Minimum Coverage Provision, 75 Law & Contemp. Probs. 29, 62-63 (2012) (identifying an "interstate... collective action problem" as the justification for federal intervention in the health care market).
    • (2012) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.75
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 18
    • 84867522727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Fed'n of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius
    • Nat'l Fed'n of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius, 132 S. Ct. 2566, 2612 (2012) (Ginsburg, J., concurring in part, concurring in the judgment in part, and dissenting in part).
    • (2012) S. Ct. , vol.132
  • 19
    • 84883276978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism and Its Discontents
    • Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism and Its Discontents, 91 Tex. L. Rev. 1937, 1939-40 (2013)
    • (2013) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.91
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 20
    • 84894635908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sebelius
    • note
    • See Sebelius, 132 S. Ct. at 2644-50 (Ginsburg, J., concurring in part, concurring in the judgment in part, and dissenting in part) (discussing the constitutionality of I.R.C. § 5000A (2012).
    • S. Ct. , vol.132 , pp. 2644-2650
  • 21
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 22
    • 0011412477 scopus 로고
    • The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government
    • note
    • See Herbert Wechsler, The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government, 54 Colum. L. Rev. 543, 552 (1954) (coining and defining the phrase).
    • (1954) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • Wechsler, H.1
  • 23
    • 0011412477 scopus 로고
    • The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government
    • note
    • See Herbert Wechsler, The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government, 54 Colum. L. Rev. 543, 552 (1954) (coining and defining the phrase).
    • (1954) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • Wechsler, H.1
  • 24
    • 18344365353 scopus 로고
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth., 469 U.S. 528, 550 (1985).
    • (1985) U.S. , vol.469
  • 25
    • 0036000776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "Conservative" Paths of the Rehnquist Court's Federalism Decisions
    • For a succinct history of federalism doctrine in the past three decades, see Richard H. Fallon, Jr., The "Conservative" Paths of the Rehnquist Court's Federalism Decisions, 69 U. Chi. L. Rev. 429, 452-68 (2002).
    • (2002) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.69
    • Fallon Jr., R.H.1
  • 26
    • 15744389689 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Lopez
    • note
    • United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549, 578 (1995) (Kennedy, J., concurring).
    • (1995) U.S. , vol.514
  • 27
    • 84894633242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that unlike Justice Ginsburg's health care-specific argument in Sebelius, Justice Kennedy's argument does operate at a wholesale, and not a retail, level. The argument developed in this Article focuses largely on the wholesale, rather than the tailored, use of collective action arguments as templates for the general development of federalism jurisprudence.
  • 28
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 29
    • 0347981310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Local Government Boundary Problem in Metropolitan Areas
    • Consonant with the body of jurisprudence and literature analyzed here, I bracket the matter of collective action problems among localities within a state. For treatments of spillover effects between local government units, with attention to the problem of defining local boundaries, see, for example, Richard Briffault, The Local Government Boundary Problem in Metropolitan Areas, 48 Stan. L. Rev. 1115, 1132-44 (1996) (analyzing the relationship between boundary definition and spillover problems).
    • (1996) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.48
    • Briffault, R.1
  • 30
    • 85055297123 scopus 로고
    • Decentering Decentralization
    • Jerry Frug, Decentering Decentralization, 60 U. Chi. L. Rev. 253, 286 (1993).
    • (1993) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.60
    • Frug, J.1
  • 31
    • 53149104050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Piling On: Multilevel Government and the Fiscal Common-Pool
    • note
    • Christopher Berry, Piling On: Multilevel Government and the Fiscal Common-Pool, 52 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 802, 805-06 (2008) (identifying the common-pool problem and documenting such effects empirically).
    • (2008) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.52
    • Berry, C.1
  • 32
    • 84879194862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tiers of Scrutiny in Enumerated Powers Jurisprudence
    • note
    • For an introduction to the diverse lines of doctrine at stake, see Aziz Z. Huq, Tiers of Scrutiny in Enumerated Powers Jurisprudence, 80 U. Chi. L. Rev. 575, 586-611 (2013).
    • (2013) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.80
    • Huq, A.Z.1
  • 33
    • 84926202358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Mikhail Filippov et al., Designing Federalism: A Theory of SelfSustainable Federal Institutions 34, 227 (2004) (noting the possibility of multiple potential federalism equilibria). Filippov et al. argue that this premise suggests the necessity of fixed rules that define "the core institutional structure of the federal center and its relationship to federal subjects. "
    • (2004) Designing Federalism: A Theory of SelfSustainable Federal Institutions , vol.34 , pp. 227
    • Filippov, M.1
  • 34
    • 85055310742 scopus 로고
    • Formal Models of Collective Action
    • Pamela E. Oliver, Formal Models of Collective Action, 19 Ann. Rev. Soc. 271, 275 (1993).
    • (1993) Ann. Rev. Soc. , vol.19
    • Oliver, P.E.1
  • 35
    • 0029837509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dynamics and Dilemmas of Collective Action
    • note
    • Douglas D. Heckathorn, The Dynamics and Dilemmas of Collective Action, 61 Am. Soc. Rev. 250, 253-60 (1996) (identifying five distinct formal models within the supposedly unitary category of collective action).
    • (1996) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.61
    • Heckathorn, D.D.1
  • 37
    • 14544277264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This tracks Elinor Ostrom's point that there is no one "specific set of rules" that will solve collective action problems in the management of common-pool resources. Elinor Ostrom, Understanding Institutional Diversity 255 (2005).
    • (2005) Understanding Institutional Diversity , pp. 255
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 38
    • 67650553143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Generality Problem in Constitutional Interpretation
    • note
    • I should be clear about the limits of the claim advanced here: judicial safeguards for federalism might be justified on terms other than the failure of states' political safeguards, such as the Constitution's original meaning. I do not address such arguments here. Rather, my argument is focused on the interaction between one particular strand of political and economic theory (about collective action) and judicial doctrine. Of course, there have been cogent arguments advanced against other potential foundations for federalism doctrine, such as the inference from an original public understanding of the Constitution's diffuse structure. See, e.g., John F. Manning, Federalism and the Generality Problem in Constitutional Interpretation, 122 Harv. L. Rev. 2003, 2008 (2009) [hereinafter Manning, Generality Problem] (rejecting many other originalist justifications for federalism jurisprudence on the ground that "[w]hen judges enforce freestanding 'federalism,' they ignore the resultant bargains and tradeoffs that made their way into the document").
    • (2009) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.122
    • Manning, J.F.1
  • 39
    • 22744451175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Eleventh Amendment and the Reading of Precise Constitutional Texts
    • note
    • John F. Manning, The Eleventh Amendment and the Reading of Precise Constitutional Texts, 113 Yale L.J. 1663, 1672 (2004) (arguing that "the modern insights of statutory textualism also preclude the application of strong purposivism when interpreting a precise constitutional amendment such as the Eleventh Amendment"). Although I find much to commend in Manning's arguments (and others) against other justifications for federalism doctrine, I do not aim here to canvas the whole waterfront of arguments for federalism doctrine. It suffices to say that my choice to focus on collective action justifications for federalism jurisprudence here reflects an implicit judgment that such arguments are among the most sophisticated and compelling available.
    • (2004) Yale L.J. , vol.113
    • Manning, J.F.1
  • 40
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 41
    • 84894611437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By contrast, courts tend to offer only partially theorized accounts of federalism. In consequence, I focus here largely on scholarship and not judicial opinions.
  • 42
    • 37749015685 scopus 로고
    • Federalism: Evaluating the Founders' Design
    • note
    • Important earlier works demonstrating the importance of collective action mechanisms include Michael W. McConnell, Federalism: Evaluating the Founders' Design, 54 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1484, 1494-96 (1987) (book review) (framing interstate interactions in terms of externalities problems).
    • (1987) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • McConnell, M.W.1
  • 43
    • 27944511320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Beautiful Mend: A Game Theoretical Analysis of the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine
    • note
    • Maxwell L. Stearns, A Beautiful Mend: A Game Theoretical Analysis of the Dormant Commerce Clause Doctrine, 45 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 1, 69-82 (2003) (using an insightful game-theoretic model to gloss dormant Commerce Clause doctrine).
    • (2003) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Stearns, M.L.1
  • 44
    • 22744451175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Eleventh Amendment and the Reading of Precise Constitutional Texts
    • note
    • John F. Manning, The Eleventh Amendment and the Reading of Precise Constitutional Texts, 113 Yale L.J. 1663, 1672 (2004) (arguing that "the modern insights of statutory textualism also preclude the application of strong purposivism when interpreting a precise constitutional amendment such as the Eleventh Amendment"). Although I find much to commend in Manning's arguments (and others) against other justifications for federalism doctrine, I do not aim here to canvas the whole waterfront of arguments for federalism doctrine. It suffices to say that my choice to focus on collective action justifications for federalism jurisprudence here reflects an implicit judgment that such arguments are among the most sophisticated and compelling available.
    • (2004) Yale L.J. , vol.113
    • Manning, J.F.1
  • 45
    • 77950490430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Constitutional Legitimacy of Freestanding Federalism
    • note
    • Gillian E. Metzger, The Constitutional Legitimacy of Freestanding Federalism, 122 Harv. L. Rev. F. 98, 99-107 (2009) (defending the propriety of justiciable federalism principles).
    • (2009) Harv. L. Rev. F. , vol.122
    • Metzger, G.E.1
  • 46
    • 34147154702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Second-Order Structure of Immigration Law
    • note
    • Cf. Adam B. Cox & Eric A. Posner, The Second-Order Structure of Immigration Law, 59 Stan. L. Rev. 809, 811 (2007) ("Second-order design issues concern the legal institutions that are used to implement the first-order policy goals. ").
    • (2007) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.59
    • Cox, A.B.1    Posner, E.A.2
  • 47
    • 84883276978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism and Its Discontents
    • Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism and Its Discontents, 91 Tex. L. Rev. 1937, 1939-40 (2013)
    • (2013) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.91
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 48
    • 0011687094 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See 1 The Records of the Federal Convention of 1787, at 20 (Max Farrand ed., rev. ed. 1966) (establishing that the Virginia Plan was introduced on May 29, 1787).
    • (1966) The Records of the Federal Convention of 1787 , pp. 20
  • 52
    • 84867123968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Resolution VI": The Virginia Plan and Authority to Resolve Collective Action Problems Under Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See Kurt T. Lash, "Resolution VI": The Virginia Plan and Authority to Resolve Collective Action Problems Under Article I, Section 8, 87 Notre Dame L. Rev. 2123, 2134-42 (2012) (providing an alternative view of the Convention's trajectory).
    • (2012) Notre Dame L. Rev. , vol.87
    • Lash, K.T.1
  • 53
    • 77957331080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commerce
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, Commerce, 109 Mich. L. Rev. 1, 6 (2010). Structural principles "explain how the Constitution works in practice and how it should work. "
    • (2010) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.109
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 54
    • 84856144888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, Living Originalism 142 (2011). There is much more to Balkin's rich analysis, and I focus here on a single, albeit surely a keystone, feature of that analysis.
    • (2011) Living Originalism , pp. 142
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 55
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 56
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 57
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 58
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 59
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • note
    • Coase famously explained that when transaction costs are zero, an efficient result is reached regardless of the initial assignment of a legal entitlement. R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & Econ. 1, 8 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 60
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • note
    • Coase famously explained that when transaction costs are zero, an efficient result is reached regardless of the initial assignment of a legal entitlement. R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & Econ. 1, 8 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 61
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • note
    • Coase famously explained that when transaction costs are zero, an efficient result is reached regardless of the initial assignment of a legal entitlement. R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & Econ. 1, 8 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 62
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 63
    • 84894625074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Resolution VI as a Principle of Construction
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, Resolution VI as a Principle of Construction, Balkinization (Aug. 12, 2011, 5:55 AM), http://balkin.blogspot.com/2011/08/resolutionvi-as-principle-of.html.
    • (2011) Balkinization
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 64
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 65
    • 84867044896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nine Perspectives on Living Originalism
    • note
    • Balkin is admirably candid about his substantive commitments. See, e.g., Jack M. Balkin, Nine Perspectives on Living Originalism, 2012 U. Ill. L. Rev. 815, 867 ("I am a liberal defending the modern state.... ").
    • (2012) U. Ill. L. Rev.
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 66
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 67
    • 84872241456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action
    • Neil S. Siegel, Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action, 62 Duke L.J. 797, 803-05 (2012).
    • (2012) Duke L.J. , vol.62
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 68
    • 0345867137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and Collective Action
    • note
    • See, e.g., Richard E. Levy, Federalism and Collective Action, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1241, 1268 (1997) (arguing that "the enumerated federal powers encompass areas where collective action problems such as public goods, externalities, and the prisoner's dilemma prevented effective collective decision making").
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Levy, R.E.1
  • 69
    • 81355142285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism, Lochner, and the Individual Mandate
    • See, e.g., Peter J. Smith, Federalism, Lochner, and the Individual Mandate, 91 B.U. L. Rev. 1723, 1737 (2011).
    • (2011) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.91
    • Smith, P.J.1
  • 70
    • 84861846040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Popular Constitutionalism and the Underenforcement Problem: The Case of the National Healthcare Law
    • Ernest A. Young, Popular Constitutionalism and the Underenforcement Problem: The Case of the National Healthcare Law, 75 Law & Contemp. Probs. 157, 171 (2012).
    • (2012) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.75
    • Young, E.A.1
  • 71
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 72
    • 84860163441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Free Rider: A Justification for Mandatory Medical Insurance Under Health Care Reform?
    • note
    • Note that this argument is distinct from the claim that individuals' actions will generate collectively suboptimal outcomes due to free riding, as has been argued in the context of the individual mandate provision. For a critical view of that claim, see Douglas A. Kahn & Jeffrey H. Kahn, Free Rider: A Justification for Mandatory Medical Insurance Under Health Care Reform?, 109 Mich. L. Rev. First Impressions 78 (2011), http://www.michiganlawreview.org/assets/fi/109/kahn.pdf. The argument considered here focuses on states, not natural persons.
    • (2011) Mich. L. Rev. First Impressions , vol.109 , pp. 78
    • Kahn, D.A.1    Kahn, J.H.2
  • 73
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 74
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 75
    • 84872241456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action
    • Neil S. Siegel, Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action, 62 Duke L.J. 797, 803-05 (2012).
    • (2012) Duke L.J. , vol.62
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 76
    • 0003626071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Robert D. Cooter, The Strategic Constitution 106-07 (2000) (discussing spillovers and arguing for the use of "special districts").
    • (2000) The Strategic Constitution , pp. 106-107
    • Cooter, R.D.1
  • 77
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 78
    • 84872241456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action
    • Neil S. Siegel, Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action, 62 Duke L.J. 797, 803-05 (2012).
    • (2012) Duke L.J. , vol.62
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 79
    • 84872241456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action
    • Neil S. Siegel, Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action, 62 Duke L.J. 797, 803-05 (2012).
    • (2012) Duke L.J. , vol.62
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 80
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 81
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 82
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 83
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 84
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 85
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 86
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 87
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 88
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 91
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 92
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 93
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 94
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 95
    • 84872241456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action
    • Neil S. Siegel, Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action, 62 Duke L.J. 797, 803-05 (2012).
    • (2012) Duke L.J. , vol.62
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 96
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 97
    • 18344365353 scopus 로고
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth
    • note
    • See Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth., 469 U.S. 528, 552 (1985) ("State sovereign interests, then, are more properly protected by procedural safeguards inherent in the structure of the federal system than by judicially created limitations on federal power. ").
    • (1985) U.S. , vol.469
  • 98
    • 0011412477 scopus 로고
    • The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government
    • note
    • See Herbert Wechsler, The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government, 54 Colum. L. Rev. 543, 552 (1954) (coining and defining the phrase).
    • (1954) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • Wechsler, H.1
  • 99
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federalist No. 48, at 308-09 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (denying the proposition that it is "sufficient to mark, with precision, the boundaries of these departments in the constitution of the government, and to trust to these parchment barriers against the encroaching spirit of power").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 308-309
  • 100
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federalist No. 48, at 308-09 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (denying the proposition that it is "sufficient to mark, with precision, the boundaries of these departments in the constitution of the government, and to trust to these parchment barriers against the encroaching spirit of power").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 308-309
  • 101
    • 44649088032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Divided Publius: Democracy, Federalism, and the Cultivation of Public Sentiment
    • note
    • See Troy E. Smith, Divided Publius: Democracy, Federalism, and the Cultivation of Public Sentiment, 69 Rev. Pol. 568, 574-78 (2007) (comparing Madison's and Hamilton's views).
    • (2007) Rev. Pol. , vol.69
    • Smith, T.E.1
  • 102
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federalist No. 48, at 308-09 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (denying the proposition that it is "sufficient to mark, with precision, the boundaries of these departments in the constitution of the government, and to trust to these parchment barriers against the encroaching spirit of power").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 308-309
  • 103
    • 77957051942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kleptocracy and Divideand-Rule: A Model of Personal Rule
    • note
    • Contemporary economic analysis suggests that a national entity can dominate through a strategy of "divide-and-rule. " See Daron Acemoglu et al., Kleptocracy and Divideand-Rule: A Model of Personal Rule, 2 J. Eur. Econ. Ass'n 162, 164 (2004) ("The logic of the divide-and-rule strategy is to enable a ruler to bribe politically pivotal groups..., ensuring that he can remain in power against challenges. "). Article I, Section 9 of the Constitution, however, limits Congress's ability to engage in economic preferences.
    • (2004) J. Eur. Econ. Ass'n , vol.2
    • Acemoglu, D.1
  • 104
    • 76749152493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., U.S. Const. art. I, § 9, cl. 6 (barring any "Preference... to the Ports of one State over those of another"). That is, the Framers formulated an effective solution to the most important form of strategic action by the national government.
    • U.S. Const. art. I
  • 105
    • 0011412477 scopus 로고
    • The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government
    • note
    • See Herbert Wechsler, The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government, 54 Colum. L. Rev. 543, 552 (1954) (coining and defining the phrase).
    • (1954) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • Wechsler, H.1
  • 106
    • 0011412477 scopus 로고
    • The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government
    • note
    • See Herbert Wechsler, The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government, 54 Colum. L. Rev. 543, 552 (1954) (coining and defining the phrase).
    • (1954) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • Wechsler, H.1
  • 107
    • 84859819371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Number of States and the Economics of American Federalism
    • note
    • Cf. Steven G. Calabresi & Nicholas Terrell, The Number of States and the Economics of American Federalism, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 1, 18 (2011) (calling the Seventeenth Amendment a "crippling blow to the states"). But it is far from clear that this should be so absent some nonoriginalist commitment to federalism values for their own sake.
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Calabresi, S.G.1    Terrell, N.2
  • 108
    • 79851494832 scopus 로고
    • From Sovereignty to Process: The Jurisprudence of Federalism After Garcia
    • Andrzej Rapacynski, From Sovereignty to Process: The Jurisprudence of Federalism After Garcia, 1985 Sup. Ct. Rev. 341, 373.
    • (1985) Sup. Ct. Rev.
    • Rapacynski, A.1
  • 109
    • 23044520762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putting the Politics Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism
    • Larry D. Kramer, Putting the Politics Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism, 100 Colum. L. Rev. 215, 282 & n.267 (2000).
    • (2000) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.100 , Issue.267
    • Kramer, L.D.1
  • 110
    • 0041384235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Parties, Representation, and Federal Safeguards
    • note
    • But see Paul Frymer & Albert Yoon, Political Parties, Representation, and Federal Safeguards, 96 Nw. U. L. Rev. 977, 985-89 (2002) (disputing this claim).
    • (2002) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.96
    • Frymer, P.1    Yoon, A.2
  • 112
    • 84894611098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 133 S. Ct. 2247, 2257-58 (2013) (emphasizing states' power to define the electorate, and the corresponding limitation on national authority under the Elections Clause).
    • (2013) S. Ct. , vol.133
  • 113
    • 18344365353 scopus 로고
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth., 469 U.S. 528, 550-51 (1985).
    • (1985) U.S. , vol.469
  • 114
    • 18344365353 scopus 로고
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth
    • Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth., 469 U.S. 528, 550-51 (1985).
    • (1985) U.S. , vol.469
  • 115
    • 0347141448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origins of Judicial Review: A Plea for New Contexts
    • Jack N. Rakove, The Origins of Judicial Review: A Plea for New Contexts, 49 Stan. L. Rev. 1031, 1042 (1997).
    • (1997) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.49
    • Rakove, J.N.1
  • 116
    • 0038239556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competing for the People's Affection: Federalism's Forgotten Marketplace
    • note
    • Todd E. Pettys, Competing for the People's Affection: Federalism's Forgotten Marketplace, 56 Vand. L. Rev. 329, 333 (2003) ("With two separate governments vying to win their trust, the Framers reasoned, the people would be free continually to assess the sovereigns' conduct and capabilities, and to confer or withdraw regulatory power as they deemed appropriate. ").
    • (2003) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.56
    • Pettys, T.E.1
  • 117
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federalist No. 48, at 308-09 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (denying the proposition that it is "sufficient to mark, with precision, the boundaries of these departments in the constitution of the government, and to trust to these parchment barriers against the encroaching spirit of power").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 308-309
  • 118
    • 21644448651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Lest this all seem far-fetched, we might recall the role that Madison, along with Thomas Jefferson, played in organizing state resistance to the Alien and Sedition Acts. For a capsule account of the relevant historical context, see Geoffrey R. Stone, Perilous Times: Free Speech in Wartime 29-44 (2004).
    • (2004) Perilous Times: Free Speech in Wartime , pp. 29-44
    • Stone, G.R.1
  • 119
    • 0345775468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Puzzling Persistence of Process-Based Federalism Theories
    • note
    • Saikrishna B. Prakash & John C. Yoo, The Puzzling Persistence of Process-Based Federalism Theories, 79 Tex. L. Rev. 1459, 1479 (2001) ("[T]he federal courts must play backup to Congress, to ensure that any unconstitutional legislation that emerges from the political process... will not survive. ").
    • (2001) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.79
    • Prakash, S.B.1    Yoo, J.C.2
  • 120
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federalist No. 48, at 308-09 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (denying the proposition that it is "sufficient to mark, with precision, the boundaries of these departments in the constitution of the government, and to trust to these parchment barriers against the encroaching spirit of power").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 308-309
  • 122
    • 77249121586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Structural Judicial Review and the Objection from Democracy
    • note
    • The availability of political safeguards for federalism might justify a deflationary recalibration of judicial review's intensity. See, e.g., Jeffrey Goldsworthy, Structural Judicial Review and the Objection from Democracy, 60 U. Toronto L.J. 137, 142 (2010) ("[I]t can be argued that if the national parliament is structured so as to represent both national and state majorities, judges have good reason to adopt a more deferential approach.... ").
    • (2010) U. Toronto L.J. , vol.60
    • Goldsworthy, J.1
  • 123
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 124
    • 79960215164 scopus 로고
    • State Sovereignty and Subordinacy: May Congress Commandeer State Officers to Implement Federal Law?
    • Evan H. Caminker, State Sovereignty and Subordinacy: May Congress Commandeer State Officers to Implement Federal Law?, 95 Colum. L. Rev. 1001, 1065 (1995).
    • (1995) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.95
    • Caminker, E.H.1
  • 125
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 126
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 127
    • 84878534335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commons, Anticommons, Semicommons
    • note
    • For an excellent introduction to the tragedy of the commons problem, see Lee Anne Fennell, Commons, Anticommons, Semicommons, in Research Handbook on the Economics of Property Law 35 (Kenneth Ayotte & Henry E. Smith eds., 2010).
    • (2010) Research Handbook on the Economics of Property Law , pp. 35
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 128
    • 0346406697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Eleventh Amendment as Curb on Bureaucratic Power
    • note
    • Roderick M. Hills, Jr., The Eleventh Amendment as Curb on Bureaucratic Power, 53 Stan. L. Rev. 1225, 1244 (2001) ("State autonomy... is a collective good analogous to balanced budgets. ").
    • (2001) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.53
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 129
    • 15744389689 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Lopez
    • note
    • United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549, 578 (1995) (Kennedy, J., concurring).
    • (1995) U.S. , vol.514
  • 130
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 131
    • 0346941479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congressional Factfinding and the Scope of Judicial Review: A Preliminary Analysis
    • note
    • Neal Devins, Congressional Factfinding and the Scope of Judicial Review: A Preliminary Analysis, 50 Duke L.J. 1169, 1194-200 (2001) [hereinafter Devins, Congressional Factfinding] (doubting whether the political economy of the federal legislative process conduces to serious consideration of federal concerns).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.50
    • Devins, N.1
  • 132
    • 13844256919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism
    • Neal Devins, The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 131, 134 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • Devins, N.1
  • 133
    • 13844256919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism
    • Neal Devins, The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 131, 134 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • Devins, N.1
  • 134
    • 0001447359 scopus 로고
    • The Senate and American Federalism
    • note
    • William H. Riker, The Senate and American Federalism, 49 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 452, 455-69 (1955) (arguing that the Senate has protected states' interests only sporadically, with the Seventeenth Amendment proving the culmination of a long process of centralization).
    • (1955) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.49
    • Riker, W.H.1
  • 135
    • 13844256919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism
    • Neal Devins, The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 131, 134 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • Devins, N.1
  • 136
    • 0010103733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review
    • note
    • Lynn A. Baker & Ernest A. Young, Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review, 51 Duke L.J. 75, 117-24 (2001) (arguing that "some states will harness the federal lawmaking power to impose their policy preferences on other states to the former states' own advantage" (emphases omitted).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.51
    • Baker, L.A.1    Young, E.A.2
  • 137
    • 84937334145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putting the Safeguards Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism
    • note
    • see also Lynn A. Baker, Putting the Safeguards Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism, 46 Vill. L. Rev. 951, 961-72 (2001) (same).
    • (2001) Vill. L. Rev. , vol.46
    • Baker, L.A.1
  • 138
    • 0010103733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review
    • note
    • Lynn A. Baker & Ernest A. Young, Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review, 51 Duke L.J. 75, 117-24 (2001) (arguing that "some states will harness the federal lawmaking power to impose their policy preferences on other states to the former states' own advantage" (emphases omitted).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.51
    • Baker, L.A.1    Young, E.A.2
  • 139
    • 15744389689 scopus 로고
    • Gun-Free School Zones Act at issue in United States v. Lopez
    • Gun-Free School Zones Act at issue in United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549 (1995).
    • (1995) U.S. , vol.514 , pp. 549
  • 140
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 141
    • 34247498788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Against Preemption: How Federalism Can Improve the National Legislative Process
    • note
    • cf. Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Against Preemption: How Federalism Can Improve the National Legislative Process, 82 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1, 33-34 (2007) (analyzing interest group competition in Congress that may be relevant to federalism outcomes).
    • (2007) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.82
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 142
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 143
    • 0010103733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review
    • note
    • Lynn A. Baker & Ernest A. Young, Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review, 51 Duke L.J. 75, 117-24 (2001) (arguing that "some states will harness the federal lawmaking power to impose their policy preferences on other states to the former states' own advantage" (emphases omitted).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.51
    • Baker, L.A.1    Young, E.A.2
  • 144
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 145
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 146
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 147
    • 84894619854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Both sides in the federalism debate are thus focused on a single, specific moment in the political economy of federalism-either the threshold government responses to a policy problem, or the ensuing national legislative and regulatory process that generates federal responses. Each side identifies a specific dynamic at play in that moment, and then draws general conclusions from that observation. Neither side, however, offers an integrated account of the entire policymaking process-from identification to resolution-that accounts for diverse kinds of collective action problems along the way.
  • 148
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 149
    • 84894612001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A negative payoff here can be imagined as a prison term of years; a zero result reflects being set free. The row player's options are represented on the vertical axis while the column player's options are represented on the horizontal axis.
  • 150
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation 9 (1984) ("The Prisoner's Dilemma is simply an abstract formulation of some very common and interesting situations in which what is best for each person individually leads to mutual defection, whereas everyone would have been better off with mutual cooperation. ").
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation , pp. 9
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 151
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 152
    • 0004023766 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Nash equilibrium is [t]he central solution concept in game theory. It is based on the principle that the combination of strategies that players are likely to choose is one in which no player could do better by choosing a different strategy given the ones the others choose. A pair of strategies will form a Nash equilibrium if each strategy is one that cannot be improved upon given the other strategy. We establish whether a particular strategy combination forms a Nash equilibrium by asking if either player has an incentive to deviate from it. Douglas G. Baird et al., Game Theory and the Law 310 (1994) (italics omitted).
    • (1994) Game Theory and the Law , pp. 310
    • Baird, D.G.1
  • 153
    • 62549087027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond the Prisoners' Dilemma: Coordination, Game Theory, and Law
    • Richard H. McAdams, Beyond the Prisoners' Dilemma: Coordination, Game Theory, and Law, 82 S. Cal. L. Rev. 209, 212 (2009).
    • (2009) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.82
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 154
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 156
    • 0004023766 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Nash equilibrium is [t]he central solution concept in game theory. It is based on the principle that the combination of strategies that players are likely to choose is one in which no player could do better by choosing a different strategy given the ones the others choose. A pair of strategies will form a Nash equilibrium if each strategy is one that cannot be improved upon given the other strategy. We establish whether a particular strategy combination forms a Nash equilibrium by asking if either player has an incentive to deviate from it. Douglas G. Baird et al., Game Theory and the Law 310 (1994) (italics omitted).
    • (1994) Game Theory and the Law , pp. 310
    • Baird, D.G.1
  • 157
    • 0004260007 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The literature also contains a highly technical strand, which allows for the creation of highly particularized formal models of collective action. For a technical overview, see generally Drew Fudenberg & Jean Tirole, Game Theory (1991).
    • (1991) Game Theory
    • Fudenberg, D.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 161
    • 84925921036 scopus 로고
    • A Calculus of Group Membership
    • note
    • My analysis, however, remains within a relatively narrow rational choice framework, and does not address the argument that "perceptions of efficacy... ideology, feelings of responsibility, social pressures, and other purposive/solidary dimensions of motivation" also change collective action dynamics. Terry M. Moe, A Calculus of Group Membership, 24 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 593, 629 (1980). In modeling states' (as opposed to individuals') incentives, narrow rationality may well be the better simplification.
    • (1980) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.24
    • Moe, T.M.1
  • 162
    • 0004023766 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Nash equilibrium is [t]he central solution concept in game theory. It is based on the principle that the combination of strategies that players are likely to choose is one in which no player could do better by choosing a different strategy given the ones the others choose. A pair of strategies will form a Nash equilibrium if each strategy is one that cannot be improved upon given the other strategy. We establish whether a particular strategy combination forms a Nash equilibrium by asking if either player has an incentive to deviate from it. Douglas G. Baird et al., Game Theory and the Law 310 (1994) (italics omitted).
    • (1994) Game Theory and the Law , pp. 310
    • Baird, D.G.1
  • 163
    • 14544277264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This tracks Elinor Ostrom's point that there is no one "specific set of rules" that will solve collective action problems in the management of common-pool resources. Elinor Ostrom, Understanding Institutional Diversity 255 (2005).
    • (2005) Understanding Institutional Diversity , pp. 255
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 164
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 165
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 166
    • 84970096253 scopus 로고
    • Acting Together, Contributing Together
    • note
    • See Russell Hardin, Acting Together, Contributing Together, 3 Rationality & Soc'y 365, 366-68, 377 (1991) (identifying and exploring the difference).
    • (1991) Rationality & Soc'y , vol.3
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 167
    • 84894607933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In addition to inequality of benefits and heterogeneity of benefits, which are discussed in the text, there is also the possibility of asymmetries between contributions and benefits. I do not address this possibility because it is not clearly of importance in the context being addressed here.
  • 169
    • 27744455362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Logic of Private and Collective Action
    • note
    • Wendy L. Hansen et al., The Logic of Private and Collective Action, 49 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 150, 151, 163 (2005) (suggesting that firms engaged in lobbying "are motivated as much by private goods as by public goods")
    • (2005) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.49
    • Hansen, W.L.1
  • 170
    • 3543142590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and the Mobilization of Institutions
    • note
    • David Lowery et al., Collective Action and the Mobilization of Institutions, 66 J. Pol. 684, 693 (2004) (identifying free riding effects in large populations of manufacturing firms that inhibit effective lobbying).
    • (2004) J. Pol. , vol.66
    • Lowery, D.1
  • 172
    • 85055295844 scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives
    • note
    • Heterogeneity of participants' interests and heterogeneity of participants' resources are distinct and not necessarily correlated. Nonetheless, they can have the same effect on collective action dynamics. See Douglas D. Heckathorn, Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives, 58 Am. Soc. Rev. 329, 329-30 (1993) (distinguishing heterogeneity of resources and heterogeneity of interest, but noting similar effects).
    • (1993) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 329-330
    • Heckathorn, D.D.1
  • 173
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 174
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 175
    • 84936628848 scopus 로고
    • The Paradox of Group Size in Collective Action: A Theory of the Critical Mass. II
    • note
    • Pamela E. Oliver & Gerald Marwell, The Paradox of Group Size in Collective Action: A Theory of the Critical Mass. II, 53 Am. Soc. Rev. 1, 3 (1988).
    • (1988) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.53
    • Oliver, P.E.1    Marwell, G.2
  • 176
    • 0031520482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Non-Redundant Groups, the Assurance Game and the Origins of Collective Action
    • note
    • Rene Cortazar, Non-Redundant Groups, the Assurance Game and the Origins of Collective Action, 92 Pub. Choice 41, 45-50 (1997) (modeling the incentives of the critical masses' members as an assurance game, which does lead to collective action). Larger groups are also more likely to act than smaller groups even when free riders cannot be excluded from a collective good "if the marginal cost of effort rises sufficiently quickly with respect to resources contributed. "
    • (1997) Pub. Choice , vol.92
    • Cortazar, R.1
  • 177
    • 0035601876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and the Group Size Paradox
    • Joan Esteban & Debraj Ray, Collective Action and the Group Size Paradox, 95 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 663, 664 (2001).
    • (2001) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.95
    • Esteban, J.1    Ray, D.2
  • 178
    • 0035601876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and the Group Size Paradox
    • Joan Esteban & Debraj Ray, Collective Action and the Group Size Paradox, 95 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 663, 664 (2001).
    • (2001) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.95
    • Esteban, J.1    Ray, D.2
  • 179
    • 0016103992 scopus 로고
    • Free Riders and Collective Action: An Appendix to Theories of Economic Regulation
    • See George J. Stigler, Free Riders and Collective Action: An Appendix to Theories of Economic Regulation, 5 Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. 359, 364-65 (1974).
    • (1974) Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. , vol.5
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 181
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 182
    • 84936628584 scopus 로고
    • Social Networks and Collective Action: A Theory of the Critical Mass. III
    • Gerald Marwell et al., Social Networks and Collective Action: A Theory of the Critical Mass. III, 94 Am. J. Soc. 502, 528 (1988).
    • (1988) Am. J. Soc. , vol.94
    • Marwell, G.1
  • 184
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 185
    • 84894615225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I am grateful to Lee Fennell for underscoring this last point to me.
  • 187
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 188
    • 0038964009 scopus 로고
    • Free Riding and Foul Dealing
    • Philip Pettit, Free Riding and Foul Dealing, 83 J. Phil. 361, 373 (1986).
    • (1986) J. Phil. , vol.83
    • Pettit, P.1
  • 189
    • 0040936835 scopus 로고
    • note
    • A Hobbesian state of nature is one in which the absence of centralized authority means "continual fear and danger of violent death, " such that "the life of man [is] solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short. " Thomas Hobbes, Leviathan 76 (Edwin Curley ed., Hackett Publ'g Co. 1994) (1651).
    • (1994) Leviathan , pp. 76
    • Hobbes, T.1
  • 190
    • 0038964009 scopus 로고
    • Free Riding and Foul Dealing
    • Philip Pettit, Free Riding and Foul Dealing, 83 J. Phil. 361, 373 (1986).
    • (1986) J. Phil. , vol.83
    • Pettit, P.1
  • 191
    • 0038964009 scopus 로고
    • Free Riding and Foul Dealing
    • Philip Pettit, Free Riding and Foul Dealing, 83 J. Phil. 361, 373 (1986).
    • (1986) J. Phil. , vol.83
    • Pettit, P.1
  • 192
    • 84894612702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Moving beyond the constraints of a rational actor model, it is also possible to posit that the larger the group, the more free riders there will be, and the greater the resentment felt by members of the operative subgroup.
  • 193
    • 85055310742 scopus 로고
    • Formal Models of Collective Action
    • Pamela E. Oliver, Formal Models of Collective Action, 19 Ann. Rev. Soc. 271, 275 (1993).
    • (1993) Ann. Rev. Soc. , vol.19
    • Oliver, P.E.1
  • 194
    • 84982719869 scopus 로고
    • Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor & Hugh Ward, Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision, 30 Pol. Stud. 350, 352, 363-64 (1982) (associating lumpiness with nonexcludable public goods). I have chosen to characterize the dynamic here in terms of the character of the relevant good. Of course, one might also frame it in terms of payoffs. It seems to me that focusing on the nature of the good is a more useful heuristic for explanatory purposes.
    • (1982) Pol. Stud. , vol.30
    • Taylor, M.1    Ward, H.2
  • 195
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 196
    • 84864029607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lumpy Property
    • Contributions tend to have "strongly complementary elements"-as is the case with parts of a bridge or the walls that make up a house. Lee Anne Fennell, Lumpy Property, 160 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1955, 1957 (2012).
    • (2012) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.160
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 197
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 198
    • 84864029607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lumpy Property
    • Contributions tend to have "strongly complementary elements"-as is the case with parts of a bridge or the walls that make up a house. Lee Anne Fennell, Lumpy Property, 160 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1955, 1957 (2012).
    • (2012) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.160
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 200
    • 84982719869 scopus 로고
    • Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor & Hugh Ward, Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision, 30 Pol. Stud. 350, 352, 363-64 (1982) (associating lumpiness with nonexcludable public goods). I have chosen to characterize the dynamic here in terms of the character of the relevant good. Of course, one might also frame it in terms of payoffs. It seems to me that focusing on the nature of the good is a more useful heuristic for explanatory purposes.
    • (1982) Pol. Stud. , vol.30
    • Taylor, M.1    Ward, H.2
  • 201
    • 0004157554 scopus 로고
    • note
    • This point was first developed in Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy 49-50 (1957), which offers the path-marking account of voting from a rational actor perspective.
    • (1957) An Economic Theory of Democracy , pp. 49-50
    • Downs, A.1
  • 202
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 203
    • 84936628844 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of the Critical Mass. I. Interdependence, Group Heterogeneity, and the Production of Collective Action
    • note
    • See Pamela Oliver et al., A Theory of the Critical Mass. I. Interdependence, Group Heterogeneity, and the Production of Collective Action, 91 Am. J. Soc. 522, 533-34 (1985) (explaining that, depending on the gradient of the relevant slope, a linear production function will induce every player to "contribute either everything possible or nothing"). The point can be illustrated by imagining a multiplying pot. Imagine ten players, each of whom has the chance to contribute, have their contribution tripled, and get back one-tenth of the total. The result is a prisoners' dilemma, in which it is always better not to contribute. If contributions are multiplied by eleven, however, it is always worth contributing. I am again grateful to Lee Fennell for this example.
    • (1985) Am. J. Soc. , vol.91
    • Oliver, P.1
  • 204
    • 85055295844 scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives
    • note
    • Heterogeneity of participants' interests and heterogeneity of participants' resources are distinct and not necessarily correlated. Nonetheless, they can have the same effect on collective action dynamics. See Douglas D. Heckathorn, Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives, 58 Am. Soc. Rev. 329, 329-30 (1993) (distinguishing heterogeneity of resources and heterogeneity of interest, but noting similar effects).
    • (1993) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 329-330
    • Heckathorn, D.D.1
  • 206
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 207
    • 84936824437 scopus 로고
    • Chains of Cooperation: Threshold Effects in Collective Action
    • note
    • For support based on simulations of interdependent action, see Michael W. Macy, Chains of Cooperation: Threshold Effects in Collective Action, 56 Am. Soc. Rev. 730, 734, 745-46 (1991) (using computer simulations to model situations in which "participation may be directly triggered by the actions of others, and... thresholds need not correspond to the point at which an individual investment becomes costeffective" and finding that "interdependence facilitates the coordination of responses needed to escape a noncooperative equilibrium").
    • (1991) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.56
    • Macy, M.W.1
  • 209
    • 0000769811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms
    • Elinor Ostrom, Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms, 14 J. Econ. Persp. 137, 148 (2000); accord Ostrom, supra note 28, at 14.
    • (2000) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.14
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 210
    • 0000769811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms
    • Elinor Ostrom, Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms, 14 J. Econ. Persp. 137, 148 (2000); accord Ostrom, supra note 28, at 14.
    • (2000) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.14
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 211
    • 85055295844 scopus 로고
    • Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives
    • note
    • Heterogeneity of participants' interests and heterogeneity of participants' resources are distinct and not necessarily correlated. Nonetheless, they can have the same effect on collective action dynamics. See Douglas D. Heckathorn, Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives, 58 Am. Soc. Rev. 329, 329-30 (1993) (distinguishing heterogeneity of resources and heterogeneity of interest, but noting similar effects).
    • (1993) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 329-330
    • Heckathorn, D.D.1
  • 212
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 213
    • 0043209923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Expressive Law and Economics
    • Robert Cooter, Expressive Law and Economics, 27 J. Legal Stud. 585, 587 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Legal Stud. , vol.27
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 215
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 216
    • 67649365633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norms and the Law
    • note
    • For applications in the legal scholarship, see Richard H. McAdams & Eric B. Rasmusen, Norms and the Law, in 2 Handbook of Law and Economics 1573, 1573-618 (A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., 2007).
    • (2007) Handbook of Law and Economics , vol.2
    • McAdams, R.H.1    Rasmusen, E.B.2
  • 218
    • 84881912186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Focal Point Theory of Expressive Law
    • note
    • Richard H. McAdams, The Focal Point Theory of Expressive Law, in 7 Encyclopedia of Law and Economics 167, 167 (Francesco Parisi ed., 2d ed. 2011).
    • (2011) Encyclopedia of Law and Economics , vol.7 , pp. 167
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 219
    • 0242426712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norms, Repeated Games, and the Role of Law
    • note
    • This may happen, for example, through third-party enforcement. See Paul G. Mahoney & Chris William Sanchirico, Norms, Repeated Games, and the Role of Law, 91 Calif. L. Rev. 1281, 1295-99 (2003) (modeling a "defect-for-deviate" strategy that can underpin rational community enforcement of norms).
    • (2003) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.91
    • Mahoney, P.G.1    Sanchirico, C.W.2
  • 220
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms
    • Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 Mich. L. Rev. 338, 352 (1997) (emphasis omitted). The same is true for Mancur Olson's theory of "selective incentives" as a way of accounting for the existence of large associations.
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 221
    • 0004124176 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jon Elster, The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order 40 (1989) ("The provision of selective incentives cannot be the general solution to the collective action problem. To assume there is a central authority offering incentives often requires another collective action problem to have been solved already. ").
    • (1989) The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order , pp. 40
    • Elster, J.1
  • 222
    • 14544277264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This tracks Elinor Ostrom's point that there is no one "specific set of rules" that will solve collective action problems in the management of common-pool resources. Elinor Ostrom, Understanding Institutional Diversity 255 (2005).
    • (2005) Understanding Institutional Diversity , pp. 255
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 223
    • 0347873842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symbols, Signals, and Social Norms in Politics and the Law
    • note
    • For a useful model of norm entrepreneurship, see Eric A. Posner, Symbols, Signals, and Social Norms in Politics and the Law, 27 J. Legal Stud. 765, 773 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Legal Stud. , vol.27
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 224
    • 0346403980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recycling Norms
    • note
    • See Ann E. Carlson, Recycling Norms, 89 Calif. L. Rev. 1231, 1239-41 (2001) (canvassing debates about the origins of norms).
    • (2001) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.89
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 225
    • 0346403980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recycling Norms
    • note
    • See Ann E. Carlson, Recycling Norms, 89 Calif. L. Rev. 1231, 1239-41 (2001) (canvassing debates about the origins of norms).
    • (2001) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.89
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 226
    • 0347802256 scopus 로고
    • The Public Choice Case Against the Item Veto
    • See Maxwell L. Stearns, The Public Choice Case Against the Item Veto, 49 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 385, 402-06 (1992).
    • (1992) Wash. & Lee L. Rev. , vol.49
    • Stearns, M.L.1
  • 229
    • 84871031736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gaining Assurances
    • note
    • Beyond norms, recent work shows that some games may be solved by novel mechanisms such as money-back guarantees. See Julia Y. Lee, Gaining Assurances, 2012 Wis. L. Rev. 1137, 1139-40. How such a mechanism might translate to the public law context is an interesting question beyond the scope of my current inquiry.
    • (2012) Wis. L. Rev.
    • Lee, J.Y.1
  • 230
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 231
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation 9 (1984) ("The Prisoner's Dilemma is simply an abstract formulation of some very common and interesting situations in which what is best for each person individually leads to mutual defection, whereas everyone would have been better off with mutual cooperation. ").
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation , pp. 9
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 232
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 233
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 234
    • 33749683343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Friend or Foe? A Natural Experiment of the Prisoner's Dilemma
    • note
    • John A. List, Friend or Foe? A Natural Experiment of the Prisoner's Dilemma, 88 Rev. Econ. & Stat. 463, 463, 470 (2006). Interestingly, this study finds that the magnitude of the stakes does not change strategic choices.
    • (2006) Rev. Econ. & Stat. , vol.88
    • List, J.A.1
  • 236
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 237
    • 0004124176 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jon Elster, The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order 40 (1989) ("The provision of selective incentives cannot be the general solution to the collective action problem. To assume there is a central authority offering incentives often requires another collective action problem to have been solved already. ").
    • (1989) The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order , pp. 40
    • Elster, J.1
  • 238
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 239
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 240
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 241
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Russell Hardin, Collective Action 17 (1982) ("Public goods are defined by two properties: jointness of supply and impossibility of exclusion. " (emphases omitted)
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 17
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 242
    • 84881963847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional Possibility and Constitutional Evolution
    • note
    • Eric A. Posner, Constitutional Possibility and Constitutional Evolution, in Law, Economics and Evolutionary Theory 131, 134 (Peer Zumbansen & Gralf-Peter Calliess eds., 2011).
    • (2011) Law, Economics and Evolutionary Theory
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 243
    • 0347079900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competing Norms and Social Evolution: Is the Fittest Norm Efficient?
    • Paul G. Mahoney & Chris W. Sanchirico, Competing Norms and Social Evolution: Is the Fittest Norm Efficient?, 149 U. Pa. L. Rev. 2027, 2039-40 (2001).
    • (2001) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.149
    • Mahoney, P.G.1    Sanchirico, C.W.2
  • 244
    • 0004247096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Drew Fudenberg & David K. Levine, The Theory of Learning in Games 138 (1998) ("[I]n general games, risk-dominant equilibria may fail to be Pareto efficient. The conclusion from the study of stochastic adjustment models is that learning procedures tend to select equilibria that are relatively robust to mutations (risk-dominant equilibria), and this is a different criterion than Pareto efficiency. ").
    • (1998) The Theory of Learning in Games , pp. 138
    • Fudenberg, D.1    Levine, D.K.2
  • 245
    • 0004124176 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jon Elster, The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order 40 (1989) ("The provision of selective incentives cannot be the general solution to the collective action problem. To assume there is a central authority offering incentives often requires another collective action problem to have been solved already. ").
    • (1989) The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order , pp. 40
    • Elster, J.1
  • 246
    • 0347079900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competing Norms and Social Evolution: Is the Fittest Norm Efficient?
    • Paul G. Mahoney & Chris W. Sanchirico, Competing Norms and Social Evolution: Is the Fittest Norm Efficient?, 149 U. Pa. L. Rev. 2027, 2039-40 (2001).
    • (2001) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.149
    • Mahoney, P.G.1    Sanchirico, C.W.2
  • 247
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms
    • Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 Mich. L. Rev. 338, 352 (1997) (emphasis omitted). The same is true for Mancur Olson's theory of "selective incentives" as a way of accounting for the existence of large associations.
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 248
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms
    • Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 Mich. L. Rev. 338, 352 (1997) (emphasis omitted). The same is true for Mancur Olson's theory of "selective incentives" as a way of accounting for the existence of large associations.
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 249
    • 84860188715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commerce Games and the Individual Mandate
    • note
    • States' collective action dynamics can be modeled with several other games. See Leslie Meltzer Henry & Maxwell L. Stearns, Commerce Games and the Individual Mandate, 100 Geo. L.J. 1117, 1140-53 (2012) (using plural game-theoretic models to model interstate interactions). The problem of institution creation can also be modeled as an assurance game.
    • (2012) Geo. L.J. , vol.100
    • Henry, L.M.1    Stearns, M.L.2
  • 250
    • 84974399428 scopus 로고
    • Institutions and the Free Rider: The Assurance Problem in Collective Action
    • See Carlisle Ford Runge, Institutions and the Free Rider: The Assurance Problem in Collective Action, 46 J. Pol. 154, 162-63 (1984).
    • (1984) J. Pol. , vol.46
    • Runge, C.F.1
  • 251
    • 0004023766 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Nash equilibrium is [t]he central solution concept in game theory. It is based on the principle that the combination of strategies that players are likely to choose is one in which no player could do better by choosing a different strategy given the ones the others choose. A pair of strategies will form a Nash equilibrium if each strategy is one that cannot be improved upon given the other strategy. We establish whether a particular strategy combination forms a Nash equilibrium by asking if either player has an incentive to deviate from it. Douglas G. Baird et al., Game Theory and the Law 310 (1994) (italics omitted).
    • (1994) Game Theory and the Law , pp. 310
    • Baird, D.G.1
  • 252
    • 3142707241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Common Interest Tragedies
    • note
    • Lee Anne Fennell, Common Interest Tragedies, 98 Nw. U. L. Rev. 907, 946-47 (2004) (explaining and providing a matrix for chicken game). Baird et al. have the two drivers dying; it is not clear how best to represent that outcome numerically.
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.98
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 253
    • 0004051706 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor, Anarchy and Cooperation 6-7 (1976) (exploring the emergence of a single dominant strategy in two-person and multi-person prisoners' dilemmas).
    • (1976) Anarchy and Cooperation , pp. 6-7
    • Taylor, M.1
  • 254
    • 72449156482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Richard Tuck, Free Riding 22 (2008) (explaining why "the causal efficacy of the participants' actions [on each other] is a key feature of a standard prisoners' dilemma").
    • (2008) Free Riding , pp. 22
    • Tuck, R.1
  • 255
    • 84982719869 scopus 로고
    • Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor & Hugh Ward, Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision, 30 Pol. Stud. 350, 352, 363-64 (1982) (associating lumpiness with nonexcludable public goods). I have chosen to characterize the dynamic here in terms of the character of the relevant good. Of course, one might also frame it in terms of payoffs. It seems to me that focusing on the nature of the good is a more useful heuristic for explanatory purposes.
    • (1982) Pol. Stud. , vol.30
    • Taylor, M.1    Ward, H.2
  • 256
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms
    • Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 Mich. L. Rev. 338, 352 (1997) (emphasis omitted). The same is true for Mancur Olson's theory of "selective incentives" as a way of accounting for the existence of large associations.
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 257
    • 0004124176 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jon Elster, The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order 40 (1989) ("The provision of selective incentives cannot be the general solution to the collective action problem. To assume there is a central authority offering incentives often requires another collective action problem to have been solved already. ").
    • (1989) The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order , pp. 40
    • Elster, J.1
  • 258
    • 84864029607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lumpy Property
    • Contributions tend to have "strongly complementary elements"-as is the case with parts of a bridge or the walls that make up a house. Lee Anne Fennell, Lumpy Property, 160 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1955, 1957 (2012).
    • (2012) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.160
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 259
    • 84982719869 scopus 로고
    • Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor & Hugh Ward, Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision, 30 Pol. Stud. 350, 352, 363-64 (1982) (associating lumpiness with nonexcludable public goods). I have chosen to characterize the dynamic here in terms of the character of the relevant good. Of course, one might also frame it in terms of payoffs. It seems to me that focusing on the nature of the good is a more useful heuristic for explanatory purposes.
    • (1982) Pol. Stud. , vol.30
    • Taylor, M.1    Ward, H.2
  • 260
    • 84982719869 scopus 로고
    • Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor & Hugh Ward, Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision, 30 Pol. Stud. 350, 352, 363-64 (1982) (associating lumpiness with nonexcludable public goods). I have chosen to characterize the dynamic here in terms of the character of the relevant good. Of course, one might also frame it in terms of payoffs. It seems to me that focusing on the nature of the good is a more useful heuristic for explanatory purposes.
    • (1982) Pol. Stud. , vol.30
    • Taylor, M.1    Ward, H.2
  • 261
    • 84982719869 scopus 로고
    • Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision
    • note
    • See Michael Taylor & Hugh Ward, Chickens, Whales, and Lumpy Goods: Alternative Models of Public-Goods Provision, 30 Pol. Stud. 350, 352, 363-64 (1982) (associating lumpiness with nonexcludable public goods). I have chosen to characterize the dynamic here in terms of the character of the relevant good. Of course, one might also frame it in terms of payoffs. It seems to me that focusing on the nature of the good is a more useful heuristic for explanatory purposes.
    • (1982) Pol. Stud. , vol.30
    • Taylor, M.1    Ward, H.2
  • 262
    • 56949100272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets
    • note
    • Michael A. Heller, The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets, 111 Harv. L. Rev. 621, 624 (1998) (defining an "anticommons" problem as one in which "multiple owners are each endowed with the right to exclude others from a scarce resource, and no one has an effective privilege of use").
    • (1998) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.111
    • Heller, M.A.1
  • 263
    • 84864029607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lumpy Property
    • Contributions tend to have "strongly complementary elements"-as is the case with parts of a bridge or the walls that make up a house. Lee Anne Fennell, Lumpy Property, 160 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1955, 1957 (2012).
    • (2012) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.160
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 264
    • 0034354977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symmetric Tragedies: Commons and Anticommons
    • note
    • James M. Buchanan & Yong J. Yoon, Symmetric Tragedies: Commons and Anticommons, 43 J.L. & Econ. 1, 3 (2000) (emphasizing both commons and anticommons tragedies as a consequence of partially externalized costs).
    • (2000) J.L. & Econ. , vol.43
    • Buchanan, J.M.1    Yoon, Y.J.2
  • 265
    • 84864029607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lumpy Property
    • Contributions tend to have "strongly complementary elements"-as is the case with parts of a bridge or the walls that make up a house. Lee Anne Fennell, Lumpy Property, 160 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1955, 1957 (2012).
    • (2012) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.160
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 266
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 267
    • 0348068347 scopus 로고
    • Holdouts and Free Riders
    • note
    • See Lloyd Cohen, Holdouts and Free Riders, 20 J. Legal Stud. 351, 354-56 (1991). If the rational anticipation of free riding means no collective action occurs, then the potential free rider gains nothing.
    • (1991) J. Legal Stud. , vol.20
    • Cohen, L.1
  • 268
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 269
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 270
    • 84894611852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Federalism?
    • Donald S. Lutz, Why Federalism?, 61 Wm. & Mary Q. 582, 583 (2004) (book review).
    • (2004) Wm. & Mary Q. , vol.61
    • Lutz, D.S.1
  • 273
    • 84894611852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Federalism?
    • Donald S. Lutz, Why Federalism?, 61 Wm. & Mary Q. 582, 583 (2004) (book review).
    • (2004) Wm. & Mary Q. , vol.61
    • Lutz, D.S.1
  • 274
    • 84937290705 scopus 로고
    • The Northwest Ordinance as a Constitutional Document
    • note
    • Denis P. Duffey, The Northwest Ordinance as a Constitutional Document, 95 Colum. L. Rev. 929, 937 (1995). An earlier version of the Northwest Ordinance, drafted by Thomas Jefferson in 1784, was never implemented because of perceived risks of conflict between the new settler communities and its lack of conformity to geographic realities.
    • (1995) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.95
    • Duffey, D.P.1
  • 276
    • 40849088401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notice of Decision Denying a Waiver of Clean Air Act Preemption for California's 2009 and Subsequent Model Year Greenhouse Gas Emission Standards for New Motor Vehicles
    • note
    • Notice of Decision Denying a Waiver of Clean Air Act Preemption for California's 2009 and Subsequent Model Year Greenhouse Gas Emission Standards for New Motor Vehicles, 73 Fed. Reg. 12,156, 12,156-57 (Mar. 6, 2008) (invoking this reasoning in order to reject a request by the State of California to impose a higher standard on automobile emissions).
    • (2008) Fed. Reg. , vol.73
  • 277
    • 70349234825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iterative Federalism and Climate Change
    • note
    • See, e.g., Ann E. Carlson, Iterative Federalism and Climate Change, 103 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1097, 1097-98 (2009) (discussing history of federal inaction on greenhouse gases).
    • (2009) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.103
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 278
    • 70349234825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iterative Federalism and Climate Change
    • note
    • See, e.g., Ann E. Carlson, Iterative Federalism and Climate Change, 103 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1097, 1097-98 (2009) (discussing history of federal inaction on greenhouse gases).
    • (2009) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.103
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 280
    • 84894614961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See 42 U.S.C. § 7543(b)(1), (e)(2)(A) (2011). The Clean Air Act allows the federal government to step in when the state declines to implement certain provisions. But, as Roderick Hills has explained, when California exercised its right to opt out in the 1970s in the context of a transportation plan, the "EPA immediately backed down because there was no conceivable way it could implement the plan without California's assistance and cooperation. "
    • (2011) U.S.C. , vol.42
  • 281
    • 0042231883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism in Constitutional Context
    • Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Federalism in Constitutional Context, 22 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 181, 185 n.13 (1998).
    • (1998) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.22 , Issue.13
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 282
    • 84870795327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Brussels Effect
    • Anu Bradford, The Brussels Effect, 107 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1, 5 & n.19 (2012) (discussing national emulation of Cal. Health & Safety Code §§ 25249.5-.13).
    • (2012) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.107 , Issue.19
    • Bradford, A.1
  • 283
    • 84875176550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "California Effect" and the Future of American Food: How California's Growing Crackdown on Food and Agriculture Harms the State and the Nation
    • note
    • Baylen J. Linnekin, The "California Effect" and the Future of American Food: How California's Growing Crackdown on Food and Agriculture Harms the State and the Nation, 13 Chap. L. Rev. 357, 377-78 (2010) (noting same effect in the context of Pennsylvania bread regulation).
    • (2010) Chap. L. Rev. , vol.13
    • Linnekin, B.J.1
  • 284
    • 84894640244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Notice also that the CAA's safe harbor from preemption implicitly reflects a comparative judgment: it both reflects California's superior political capacity to identify and enact environmental regulation and at the same time gestures toward the weakness of the national political process in that same regard. It thus suggests a need to make comparative judgments about collective action costs.
  • 285
    • 31544443926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modular Environmental Regulation
    • Jody Freeman & Daniel A. Farber, Modular Environmental Regulation, 54 Duke L.J. 795, 809 (2005).
    • (2005) Duke L.J. , vol.54
    • Freeman, J.1    Farber, D.A.2
  • 286
    • 41549131585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Politics of Coercive Federalism in the Bush Era
    • note
    • Paul Posner, The Politics of Coercive Federalism in the Bush Era, 37 Publius 390, 409 (2007) (criticizing "coercive" federalism tools and advocating "marbleized, networked approaches to governance").
    • (2007) Publius , vol.37
    • Posner, P.1
  • 287
    • 76749152493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See U.S. Const. art. I, § 10, cl. 3 ("No State shall, without the Consent of Congress,... enter into any Agreement or Compact with another State.... ").
    • U.S. Const. art. I
  • 288
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 289
    • 54649083528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion
    • Charles R. Shipan & Craig Volden, The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion, 52 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 840, 853 (2008).
    • (2008) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.52
    • Shipan, C.R.1    Volden, C.2
  • 290
    • 84976184673 scopus 로고
    • Innovation in the States: A Diffusion Study
    • note
    • Virginia Gray, Innovation in the States: A Diffusion Study, 67 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 1174, 1179-80 (1973) (welfare legislation and teachers' qualifications).
    • (1973) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.67
    • Gray, V.1
  • 291
    • 0009923483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Policy Diffusion as a Geographic Expansion of the Scope of Political Conflict: Same-Sex Marriage Bans in the 1990s
    • note
    • Donald P. Haider-Markel, Policy Diffusion as a Geographic Expansion of the Scope of Political Conflict: Same-Sex Marriage Bans in the 1990s, 1 St. Pol. & Pol'y Q. 5, 16-20 (2001) (same-sex marriage laws).
    • (2001) St. Pol. & Pol'y Q. , vol.1
    • Haider-Markel, D.P.1
  • 292
    • 54649083528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion
    • Charles R. Shipan & Craig Volden, The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion, 52 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 840, 853 (2008).
    • (2008) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.52
    • Shipan, C.R.1    Volden, C.2
  • 293
    • 33645294931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • States as Policy Laboratories: Emulating Success in the Children's Health Insurance Program
    • note
    • See Craig Volden, States as Policy Laboratories: Emulating Success in the Children's Health Insurance Program, 50 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 294, 294-95 (2006) (finding that more successful state children's health insurance programs tended to be emulated). Federal intervention through the imposition of a uniform standard may also have socially undesirable effects in the long term. When a state emulates another state's effective policy, and in turn improves it, it can foster a "virtuous circle... creating new knowledge spillovers. "
    • (2006) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.50 , pp. 294-295
    • Volden, C.1
  • 295
    • 54649083528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion
    • Charles R. Shipan & Craig Volden, The Mechanisms of Policy Diffusion, 52 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 840, 853 (2008).
    • (2008) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.52
    • Shipan, C.R.1    Volden, C.2
  • 296
    • 78149235437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Frequently Asked Questions, Uniform L. Commission, http://www.uniform laws.org/Narrative.aspx?title=Frequently%20Asked%20Questions (last visited Feb. 1, 2014).
    • Frequently Asked Questions
  • 297
    • 84894615775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The ULC is also called the National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws
    • note
    • The ULC is also called the National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws. About the ULC, Uniform L. Commission, http://www.uniformlaws.org/ Narrative.aspx?title=About%20the%20ULC (last visited Feb. 1, 2014).
    • About the ULC
  • 298
    • 0040374393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Uniform Private Laws, National Conference of Commissioners for Uniform State Laws Signaling and Federal Preemption
    • Nim Razook, Uniform Private Laws, National Conference of Commissioners for Uniform State Laws Signaling and Federal Preemption, 38 Am. Bus. L.J. 41, 54 (2000).
    • (2000) Am. Bus. L.J. , vol.38
    • Razook, N.1
  • 300
    • 0347419840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Uniform State Laws
    • Larry E. Ribstein & Bruce H. Kobayashi, An Economic Analysis of Uniform State Laws, 25 J. Legal Stud. 131, 132 (1996).
    • (1996) J. Legal Stud. , vol.25
    • Ribstein, L.E.1    Kobayashi, B.H.2
  • 301
    • 84894635936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See About the Multistate Tax Commission, Multistate Tax Commission, http://www.mtc.gov/About.aspx?id=40 (last visited Feb. 1, 2014).
    • Multistate Tax Commission
  • 302
    • 84889841865 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Steel Corp. v. Multistate Tax Comm'n
    • See U.S. Steel Corp. v. Multistate Tax Comm'n, 434 U.S. 452, 479 (1978).
    • (1978) U.S. , vol.434
  • 303
    • 84894620257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Texas Firms May Collect Millions in Florida Tobacco Suit
    • note
    • One example is tobacco regulation. See Susan Borreson, Texas Firms May Collect Millions in Florida Tobacco Suit, Tex. Law., Dec. 15, 1997, at 4 (describing multistate suit against the tobacco companies).
    • (1997) Tex. Law. , pp. 4
    • Borreson, S.1
  • 304
    • 0347359964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After the Smoke Cleared: The Inside Story of the Big Tobacco $206 Billion Settlement
    • note
    • Alison Frankel, After the Smoke Cleared: The Inside Story of the Big Tobacco $206 Billion Settlement, Am. Law., Jan./Feb. 1999, at 48 (noting settlement reached by the National Association of Attorneys General with tobacco companies).
    • (1999) Am. Law. , pp. 48
    • Frankel, A.1
  • 305
    • 79954507873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When to Befriend the Court? Examining State Amici Curiae Participation Before the U.S. Supreme Court
    • Colin Provost, When to Befriend the Court? Examining State Amici Curiae Participation Before the U.S. Supreme Court, 11 St. Pol. & Pol'y Q. 4, 5-6 (2011).
    • (2011) St. Pol. & Pol'y Q. , vol.11
    • Provost, C.1
  • 306
    • 47849114760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Advocacy Matters Before and Within the Supreme Court: Transforming the Court by Transforming the Bar
    • note
    • It is not the only organization to play this role. The State and Local Legal Center also files amicus briefs on behalf of the major state and local government organizations. See Richard J. Lazarus, Advocacy Matters Before and Within the Supreme Court: Transforming the Court by Transforming the Bar, 96 Geo. L.J. 1487, 1501 & n.68 (2008) (discussing the important role that state solicitors general have recently played in Supreme Court litigation).
    • (2008) Geo. L.J. , vol.96 , Issue.68
    • Lazarus, R.J.1
  • 307
    • 84894619290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Virginia ex rel. Cuccinelli v. Sebelius
    • note
    • See Virginia ex rel. Cuccinelli v. Sebelius, 702 F. Supp. 2d 598 (E.D. Va. 2010), vacated, 656 F.3d 253 (4th Cir. 2011), cert. denied, 133 S. Ct. 59 (2012).
    • (2010) F. Supp. 2d , vol.702 , pp. 598
  • 308
    • 84867522727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Fed'n of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius
    • note
    • See Nat'l Fed'n of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius, 132 S. Ct. 2566, 2576, 2601-09 (2012).
    • (2012) S. Ct. , vol.132
  • 309
    • 84879273344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For States That Opt Out of Medicaid Expansion: 3.6 Million Fewer Insured and $8.6 Billion Less in Federal Payments
    • note
    • See Carter C. Price & Christine Eibner, For States That Opt Out of Medicaid Expansion: 3.6 Million Fewer Insured and $8.6 Billion Less in Federal Payments, 32 Health Aff. 1030, 1030 (2013).
    • (2013) Health Aff. , vol.32 , pp. 1030
    • Price, C.C.1    Eibner, C.2
  • 310
    • 84891094797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shelby Cnty. v. Holder
    • note
    • Shelby Cnty. v. Holder, 133 S. Ct. 2612, 2621, 2631 (2013).
    • (2013) S. Ct. , vol.133
  • 311
    • 0039737179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interstate Compacts in a Democratic Society: The Problem of Permanency
    • Jill Elaine Hasday, Interstate Compacts in a Democratic Society: The Problem of Permanency, 49 Fla. L. Rev. 1, 7 (1997) ("[U]niform standards are a clear means of addressing prisoner's dilemmas in which the perceived threat of interstate competition leaves all states worse off, with policies they otherwise would reject as contrary to the public interest. ").
    • (1997) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.49
    • Hasday, J.E.1
  • 312
    • 0000584741 scopus 로고
    • Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race-to-the-Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation
    • note
    • But see Richard L. Revesz, Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race-to-the-Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation, 67 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1210, 1211-12 (1992) (questioning operation of race-to-the-bottom dynamics in the environmental context).
    • (1992) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.67
    • Revesz, R.L.1
  • 313
    • 84872672981 scopus 로고
    • Virginia v. Tennessee
    • note
    • Not all interstate compacts require congressional approval. See Virginia v. Tennessee, 148 U.S. 503, 519 (1893) (requiring congressional approval only for compacts "tending to the increase of the political power in the States, which may encroach upon or interfere with the just supremacy of the United States").
    • (1893) U.S. , vol.148
  • 314
    • 84889841865 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Steel Corp. v. Multistate Tax Comm'n
    • note
    • see also U.S. Steel Corp. v. Multistate Tax Comm'n, 434 U.S. 452, 473 (1978) (explaining that the legal standard for whether an interstate compact is constitutional rests on whether the compact "enhances state power quoad the National Government").
    • (1978) U.S. , vol.434
  • 315
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 318
    • 84894627301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 10 States to Discuss Curbs on Power-Plant Emissions
    • note
    • Kirk Johnson, 10 States to Discuss Curbs on Power-Plant Emissions, N.Y. Times (July 25, 2003), http://www.nytimes.com/2003/07/25/nyregion /10-states-to-discuss-curbs-on-power-plant-emissions.html.
    • (2003) N.Y. Times
    • Johnson, K.1
  • 319
    • 34249939748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Compact Clause and RGGI
    • note
    • For an argument that no such approval is needed under current precedent, see Note, The Compact Clause and RGGI, 120 Harv. L. Rev. 1958, 1962-67 (2007).
    • (2007) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.120
  • 321
    • 33646430845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State Collective Action
    • note
    • Note, State Collective Action, 119 Harv. L. Rev. 1855, 1863 (2006).
    • (2006) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.119
  • 323
    • 84867009078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Segmentation: The Rise of Nevada as a Liability-Free Jurisdiction
    • note
    • An example of such a foul dealer problem is Nevada's recent creation of "a noliability corporate law" that may shelter "[f]irms that suffer from weak internal controls [and] need regulation the most. " Michal Barzuza, Market Segmentation: The Rise of Nevada as a Liability-Free Jurisdiction, 98 Va. L. Rev. 935, 940, 945 (2012). Nevada, in effect, exploits the compliance of other states with generally accepted norms of corporate government in a way that imposes potentially significant externalities.
    • (2012) Va. L. Rev. , vol.98
    • Barzuza, M.1
  • 324
    • 84867009078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Segmentation: The Rise of Nevada as a Liability-Free Jurisdiction
    • note
    • An example of such a foul dealer problem is Nevada's recent creation of "a noliability corporate law" that may shelter "[f]irms that suffer from weak internal controls [and] need regulation the most. " Michal Barzuza, Market Segmentation: The Rise of Nevada as a Liability-Free Jurisdiction, 98 Va. L. Rev. 935, 940, 945 (2012). Nevada, in effect, exploits the compliance of other states with generally accepted norms of corporate government in a way that imposes potentially significant externalities.
    • (2012) Va. L. Rev. , vol.98
    • Barzuza, M.1
  • 325
    • 84894612506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Charles Stewart III, Analyzing Congress 15-22 (2001) (providing a formal proof of this proposition).
    • (2001) Analyzing Congress , pp. 15-22
    • Stewart III, C.1
  • 326
    • 34250241742 scopus 로고
    • Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice
    • See Kenneth A. Shepsle & Barry R. Weingast, Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice, 37 Pub. Choice 503, 507 (1981) (arguing that "institutional restrictions on the domain of exchange induce stability, not legislative exchange per se" (emphasis omitted).
    • (1981) Pub. Choice , vol.37
    • Shepsle, K.A.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 328
    • 84865325567 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Committees in Agenda Setting in the U.S. Congress
    • See generally Barbara Sinclair, The Role of Committees in Agenda Setting in the U.S. Congress, 11 Legis. Stud. Q. 35 (1986).
    • (1986) Legis. Stud. Q. , vol.11 , pp. 35
    • Sinclair, B.1
  • 330
    • 84892140801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As defined by the Senate itself, a "hold" is "[a]n informal practice by which a senator informs his or her floor leader that he or she does not wish a particular bill or other measure to reach the floor for consideration. " Glossary, U.S. Senate, http:// www.senate.gov/reference/glossary_term/hold.htm (last visited Feb. 1, 2014).
    • Glossary
  • 331
    • 84879406766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A One-Track Senate
    • note
    • Barry Friedman & Andrew D. Martin, Op-Ed., A One-Track Senate, N.Y. Times (Mar. 9, 2010), http://www.nytimes.com/2010/03/10/opinion/10martin.html (discussing examples).
    • (2010) N.Y. Times
    • Friedman, B.1    Martin, A.D.2
  • 334
    • 33947502747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jurisdictional Mismatch in Environmental Federalism
    • note
    • There is also some reason to believe enactment costs of environmental legislation in the states will be lower because of reduced interest group pressure. See Jonathan H. Adler, Jurisdictional Mismatch in Environmental Federalism, 14 N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. 130, 156-57 (2005) ("Empirical studies of state regulatory activity generally fail to support the claim that state governments are more susceptible to interest group pressure than the federal government. ").
    • (2005) N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. , vol.14
    • Adler, J.H.1
  • 335
    • 0039737179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interstate Compacts in a Democratic Society: The Problem of Permanency
    • Jill Elaine Hasday, Interstate Compacts in a Democratic Society: The Problem of Permanency, 49 Fla. L. Rev. 1, 7 (1997) ("[U]niform standards are a clear means of addressing prisoner's dilemmas in which the perceived threat of interstate competition leaves all states worse off, with policies they otherwise would reject as contrary to the public interest. ").
    • (1997) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.49
    • Hasday, J.E.1
  • 336
    • 0030163314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Tax Policy in Federalist Economies: An Overview
    • See Robert P. Inman & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Designing Tax Policy in Federalist Economies: An Overview, 60 J. Pub. Econ. 307, 318 (1996).
    • (1996) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.60
    • Inman, R.P.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 337
    • 0030163314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Tax Policy in Federalist Economies: An Overview
    • See Robert P. Inman & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Designing Tax Policy in Federalist Economies: An Overview, 60 J. Pub. Econ. 307, 318 (1996).
    • (1996) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.60
    • Inman, R.P.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 338
    • 79956223744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Breaking Gridlock: The Determinants of Health Policy Change in Congress
    • note
    • For evidence that legislative gridlock is unusually constrictive in the health care domain, see Craig Volden & Alan E. Wiseman, Breaking Gridlock: The Determinants of Health Policy Change in Congress, 36 J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. 227, 236-43 (2011) (presenting evidence from both the context of committee processes and plenary consideration of bills).
    • (2011) J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. , vol.36
    • Volden, C.1    Wiseman, A.E.2
  • 339
    • 84867522727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 132 S. Ct. 2566, 2642 (2012) (joint dissent).
    • (2012) S. Ct. , vol.132
  • 340
    • 84857951616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National Security Federalism in the Age of Terror
    • note
    • See Matthew C. Waxman, National Security Federalism in the Age of Terror, 64 Stan. L. Rev. 289, 293-94 (2012) (identifying uncertainty).
    • (2012) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.64
    • Waxman, M.C.1
  • 341
    • 84879435349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Social Production of National Security
    • For a critical review and reconsideration of potential causal theories, see generally Aziz Z. Huq, The Social Production of National Security, 98 Cornell L. Rev. 637 (2013).
    • (2013) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 637
    • Huq, A.Z.1
  • 342
    • 84872241456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action
    • Neil S. Siegel, Distinguishing the "Truly National" from the "Truly Local": Customary Allocation, Commercial Activity, and Collective Action, 62 Duke L.J. 797, 803-05 (2012).
    • (2012) Duke L.J. , vol.62
    • Siegel, N.S.1
  • 343
    • 33846306614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • States Flex Prosecutorial Muscle
    • note
    • See, e.g., Brooke A. Masters, States Flex Prosecutorial Muscle, Wash. Post (Jan. 12, 2005), http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A2107-2005Jan11.html ("[S]tate regulators and attorneys general are bringing legal action and launching investigations in... areas where they say federal regulators have fallen down on the job.").
    • (2005) Wash. Post
    • Masters, B.A.1
  • 344
    • 84892585895 scopus 로고
    • State Antitrust Remedies: Lessons from the Laboratories
    • note
    • See Ralph H. Folsom, State Antitrust Remedies: Lessons from the Laboratories, 35 Antitrust Bull. 941, 955 (1991) ("The state attorneys general committed themselves to 'filling the gap' created by Reagan administration antitrust policies by increasing their state antitrust prosecutions. ").
    • (1991) Antitrust Bull. , vol.35
    • Folsom, R.H.1
  • 345
    • 77958410286 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Theory of Statutory Evolution: The Federalization of Environmental Law
    • note
    • See E. Donald Elliott et al., Toward a Theory of Statutory Evolution: The Federalization of Environmental Law, 1 J.L. Econ. & Org. 313, 326 (1985) ("When faced with the threat of inconsistent and increasingly rigorous state laws, [interest groups use] their superior organizational capacities in Washington [to seek federal legislation]. ").
    • (1985) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.1
    • Elliott, E.D.1
  • 346
    • 34548119871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Timing and Form of Federal Regulation: The Case of Climate Change
    • note
    • see also J.R. DeShazo & Jody Freeman, Timing and Form of Federal Regulation: The Case of Climate Change, 155 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1499, 1500 (2007) (predicting a similar dynamic for climate change legislation).
    • (2007) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.155
    • DeShazo, J.R.1    Freeman, J.2
  • 347
    • 79851501072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Negotiating Federalism
    • note
    • Erin Ryan, Negotiating Federalism, 52 B.C. L. Rev. 1, 8 (2011) ("[F]ederalism bargaining helps bridge pockets of uncertainty that remain after exhausting the more conventionally understood forms of federalism interpretation, to help allocate contested authority and shepherd interjurisdictional collaboration. ").
    • (2011) B.C. L. Rev. , vol.52
    • Ryan, E.1
  • 348
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 349
    • 79551518212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Reconstruction Power
    • note
    • Jack M. Balkin, The Reconstruction Power, 85 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1801, 1809 (2010) ("The enumerated powers of Article I, Section 8 allowed Congress to establish national standards to solve collective action problems.... ").
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.85
    • Balkin, J.M.1
  • 350
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 351
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 352
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 353
    • 0347539370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vices of the Political System of the United States (1787)
    • note
    • See, e.g., James Madison, Vices of the Political System of the United States (1787), in Writings 69, 71 (Jack N. Rakove ed., 1999) (framing flaws in the Articles of Confederation by identifying among the several newly independent states an undesirable "want of concert in matters where common interest requires it").
    • (1999) Writings
    • Madison, J.1
  • 354
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 355
    • 0004211669 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Garry Wills, Explaining America: The Federalist 13-23 (1981) (describing Madison's education in Hume's works and tracing their influence in The Federalist Papers).
    • (1981) Explaining America: The Federalist , pp. 13-23
    • Wills, G.1
  • 356
    • 0011546520 scopus 로고
    • "That Politics May Be Reduced to a Science": David Hume, James Madison, and the Tenth
    • note
    • Douglass Adair, "That Politics May Be Reduced to a Science": David Hume, James Madison, and the Tenth Federalist, 20 Huntington Libr. Q. 343, 345 (1957) (noting that the work of David Hume and other "prominent... Scottish philosophers... had become the standard textbooks of the colleges of the late colonial period").
    • (1957) Federalist, 20 Huntington Libr. Q.
    • Adair, D.1
  • 357
    • 79957887500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Article III and the Scottish Judiciary
    • James E. Pfander & Daniel D. Birk, Article III and the Scottish Judiciary, 124 Harv. L. Rev. 1613, 1634-35 (2011).
    • (2011) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.124
    • Pfander, J.E.1    Birk, D.D.2
  • 359
    • 84861979919 scopus 로고
    • Hume's example involved a common interest in draining a meadow: Two neighbours may agree to drain a meadow, which they possess in common; because 'tis easy for them to know each others mind; and each must perceive, that the immediate consequence of his failing in his part, is, the abandoning the whole project. But 'tis very difficult, and indeed impossible, that a thousand persons shou'd agree in any such action; it being difficult for them to concert so complicated a design, and still more difficult for them to execute it; while each seeks a pretext to free himself of the trouble and expence, and wou'd lay the whole burden on others. David Hume, A Treatise of Human Nature 590 (Ernest C. Mossner ed., 1969) (1739-1740). Even before Hume, Aristotle had en passant conjured the tragedy of the commons.
    • (1969) A Treatise of Human Nature , pp. 590
    • Hume, D.1
  • 360
    • 84894618984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Aristotle, Politics bk. II, at 77 (H. Rackham trans., Harvard Univ. Press rev. ed. 1944) (c. 350 B.C.E.) ("Property that is common to the greatest number of owners receives the least attention.... ").
    • Aristotle, Politics bk. II , pp. 77
  • 361
    • 20744435411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Stag Hunt
    • note
    • See Brian Skyms, The Stag Hunt, 75 Proc. & Addresses of Am. Phil. Ass'n 31, 31 (2001) (noting that Rousseau identified the assurance game in the Discourse on Inequality).
    • (2001) Proc. & Addresses of Am. Phil. Ass'n , vol.75 , pp. 31
    • Skyms, B.1
  • 362
    • 84894635070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Lawyer's Library in the Early American Republic
    • note
    • Alison L. LaCroix, The Lawyer's Library in the Early American Republic, in Subversion and Sympathy: Gender, Law, and the British Novel 251, 256 (Martha C. Nussbaum & Alison L. LaCroix eds., 2013) (noting that early American lawyers were "avid consumers" of Rousseau's ideas). I do not focus on Rousseau, since Balkin's argument does not depend on the Founders' identification of the assurance game.
    • (2013) Subversion and Sympathy: Gender, Law, and the British Novel
    • LaCroix, A.L.1
  • 363
    • 29144440763 scopus 로고
    • Did Jefferson or Madison Understand Condorcet's Theory of Social Choice?
    • note
    • This cannot be taken for granted. Cf. Iain McLean & Arnold B. Urkin, Did Jefferson or Madison Understand Condorcet's Theory of Social Choice?, 73 Pub. Choice 445, 455 (1992) (noting that while Jefferson and Madison might have read the relevant passages in Condorcet about the voting paradox, there is no evidence they understood his theory of social choice).
    • (1992) Pub. Choice , vol.73
    • McLean, I.1    Urkin, A.B.2
  • 364
    • 84861979919 scopus 로고
    • Hume's example involved a common interest in draining a meadow: Two neighbours may agree to drain a meadow, which they possess in common; because 'tis easy for them to know each others mind; and each must perceive, that the immediate consequence of his failing in his part, is, the abandoning the whole project. But 'tis very difficult, and indeed impossible, that a thousand persons shou'd agree in any such action; it being difficult for them to concert so complicated a design, and still more difficult for them to execute it; while each seeks a pretext to free himself of the trouble and expence, and wou'd lay the whole burden on others. David Hume, A Treatise of Human Nature 590 (Ernest C. Mossner ed., 1969) (1739-1740). Even before Hume, Aristotle had en passant conjured the tragedy of the commons.
    • (1969) A Treatise of Human Nature , pp. 590
    • Hume, D.1
  • 365
    • 0003709313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • John Rawls, Lectures on the History of Moral Philosophy 59-61 (Barbara Herman ed., 2000) (explaining Hume's idea of a convention, and identifying it as a solution to collection action problems).
    • (2000) Lectures on the History of Moral Philosophy , pp. 59-61
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 367
    • 79960519971 scopus 로고
    • Of the Original Contract
    • note
    • David Hume, Of the Original Contract (1748), in Selected Essays 274, 288 (Stephen Copley & Andrew Edgar eds., 1996) (deriving an "obligation of allegiance" to obey the law, and in effect to refrain from free riding on society, from the fact "that men could not live at all in society... without laws, and magistrates, and judges, to prevent the encroachments of the strong upon the weak, of the violent upon the just and equitable"). Hume's work, in short, is not the place to root a Founding-era belief in a general warrant for external government action to resolve collective action problems.
    • (1748) Selected Essays
    • Hume, D.1
  • 368
    • 72449156482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Richard Tuck, Free Riding 22 (2008) (explaining why "the causal efficacy of the participants' actions [on each other] is a key feature of a standard prisoners' dilemma").
    • (2008) Free Riding , pp. 22
    • Tuck, R.1
  • 369
    • 0003624191 scopus 로고
    • note
    • In more contemporary terms, we might understand Hume to be talking about Rawlsian reasonableness, rather than Rawlsian rationality. See John Rawls, Political Liberalism 50-51 (1993) (distinguishing in the course of a larger account of political liberalism the concept of rationality, which is understood in terms of maximizing self-interest, from reasonableness, which is framed as "fair social cooperation").
    • (1993) Political Liberalism , pp. 50-51
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 370
    • 72449156482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Richard Tuck, Free Riding 22 (2008) (explaining why "the causal efficacy of the participants' actions [on each other] is a key feature of a standard prisoners' dilemma").
    • (2008) Free Riding , pp. 22
    • Tuck, R.1
  • 371
    • 0347539370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vices of the Political System of the United States (1787)
    • note
    • See, e.g., James Madison, Vices of the Political System of the United States (1787), in Writings 69, 71 (Jack N. Rakove ed., 1999) (framing flaws in the Articles of Confederation by identifying among the several newly independent states an undesirable "want of concert in matters where common interest requires it").
    • (1999) Writings
    • Madison, J.1
  • 372
    • 0346333608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison's Audience
    • note
    • To be clear, I do not doubt that Madison saw "too little authority in the center to control the jealousies and animosities of the peripheries" as a problem, or that he believed that "[h]istory and experience... conjoined to produce a new theoretical understanding that a robust and independent central authority was indispensable if the Union (and so the states) were to survive. " Larry D. Kramer, Madison's Audience, 112 Harv. L. Rev. 611, 626-27 (1999).
    • (1999) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.112
    • Kramer, L.D.1
  • 373
    • 76449121052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court, 2008 Term-Foreword: System Effects and the Constitution
    • Adrian Vermeule, The Supreme Court, 2008 Term-Foreword: System Effects and the Constitution, 123 Harv. L. Rev. 4, 26 (2009).
    • (2009) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.123
    • Vermeule, A.1
  • 374
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Federalist No. 48, at 308-09 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (denying the proposition that it is "sufficient to mark, with precision, the boundaries of these departments in the constitution of the government, and to trust to these parchment barriers against the encroaching spirit of power").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 308-309
  • 375
    • 85044809540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Conceptual Explanation for Legislative Failure
    • note
    • see also Edward Rubin, The Conceptual Explanation for Legislative Failure, 30 Law & Soc. Inquiry 583, 586 (2005) ("Legislative failure, in Madison's view, occurs when one faction, which may even be a majority of voting citizens, dominates the political process and takes control of government[.]").
    • (2005) Law & Soc. Inquiry , vol.30
    • Rubin, E.1
  • 376
    • 45949113367 scopus 로고
    • Assistance to the Poor in a Federal System
    • note
    • See Charles C. Brown & Wallace E. Oates, Assistance to the Poor in a Federal System, 32 J. Pub. Econ. 307, 308-09 (1987) (showing that "the potential migration of poor households seriously undermines the case for a decentralized system of poor relief").
    • (1987) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.32
    • Brown, C.C.1    Oates, W.E.2
  • 377
    • 84894636634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The conventional modern view-which I do not mean to dispute-is that the General Welfare Clause allows federal action with an economic redistribution effect. Although there is no Supreme Court precedent precisely on point, it suffices here to say that large parts of the federal tax code would be unconstitutional otherwise.
  • 381
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 382
    • 85045162074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Sorting Office
    • note
    • James Meek, In the Sorting Office, 33 London Rev. Books 3, 3 (2011). Meek here is talking centrally about European post offices, but his quite perceptive piece can be understood in more general terms.
    • (2011) London Rev. Books , vol.33 , pp. 3
    • Meek, J.1
  • 383
    • 78650413779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert D. Cooter & Neil S. Siegel, Collective Action Federalism: A General Theory of Article I, Section 8, 63 Stan. L. Rev. 115, 123 (2010). I discuss such theories at greater length in Part I. A below.
    • (2010) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Siegel, N.S.2
  • 384
    • 10844286739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This brackets the question whether the epistemic gains from assignment of enumerated powers questions to the elected branches are overwhelmed by the costs of assigning those decisions to actors with shorter time horizons and the potential distortion of electoral incentives. In this regard, I should note that it is hardly self-evident that matters of constitutional law should always and inevitably be free of short-term, populist influence. See generally Larry D. Kramer, The People Themselves: Popular Constitutionalism and Judicial Review (2004).
    • (2004) The People Themselves: Popular Constitutionalism and Judicial Review
    • Kramer, L.D.1
  • 385
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 386
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 387
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 388
    • 84933492009 scopus 로고
    • Relative Preferences
    • For an account of how the collective nature of a good can lead to underproduction in this fashion, see Richard H. McAdams, Relative Preferences, 102 Yale L.J. 1, 60 (1992).
    • (1992) Yale L.J. , vol.102
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 389
    • 0040146716 scopus 로고
    • Federal Deference to Local Regulators and the Economic Theory of Regulation: Toward a Public-Choice Explanation of Federalism
    • note
    • This is separate from, but complements, Jonathan Macey's insight that at times "Congress will delegate to local regulators" in cases when "the political support it obtains from deferring to the states is greater than the political support it obtains from [federal legislators doing the] regulating [themselves]." Jonathan R. Macey, Federal Deference to Local Regulators and the Economic Theory of Regulation: Toward a Public-Choice Explanation of Federalism, 76 Va. L. Rev. 265, 267 (1990).
    • (1990) Va. L. Rev. , vol.76
    • Macey, J.R.1
  • 390
    • 25844472455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-Enforcing Federalism
    • See Rui J.P. de Figueiredo, Jr. & Barry R. Weingast, Self-Enforcing Federalism, 21 J.L. Econ. & Org. 103, 104, 123-24 (2005) (describing the "twin dilemmas" of federalism).
    • (2005) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.21
    • de Figueiredo Jr., R.J.P.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 391
    • 44849095179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constructing Self-Enforcing Federalism in the Early United States and Modern Russia
    • note
    • Rui J.P. de Figueiredo, Jr. et al., Constructing Self-Enforcing Federalism in the Early United States and Modern Russia, 37 Publius 160, 161 (2007) (same).
    • (2007) Publius , vol.37
    • de Figueiredo Jr., R.J.P.1
  • 393
    • 25844472455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-Enforcing Federalism
    • See Rui J.P. de Figueiredo, Jr. & Barry R. Weingast, Self-Enforcing Federalism, 21 J.L. Econ. & Org. 103, 104, 123-24 (2005) (describing the "twin dilemmas" of federalism).
    • (2005) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.21
    • de Figueiredo Jr., R.J.P.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 394
    • 44849095179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constructing Self-Enforcing Federalism in the Early United States and Modern Russia
    • note
    • Rui J.P. de Figueiredo, Jr. et al., Constructing Self-Enforcing Federalism in the Early United States and Modern Russia, 37 Publius 160, 161 (2007) (same).
    • (2007) Publius , vol.37
    • de Figueiredo Jr., R.J.P.1
  • 395
    • 84894624875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I am grateful to Eric Posner for helpful discussion on this point.
  • 396
    • 0348190012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Framing Transactions in Constitutional Law
    • note
    • Cf. Daryl J. Levinson, Framing Transactions in Constitutional Law, 111 Yale L.J. 1311, 1313 (2002) (pointing out that "constitutional law has no criteria for isolating transactions from the background relationship between government and citizens"). Levinson's argument concerns government-individual interactions, but his basic insight into the importance of framing can be easily transposed into the intergovernmental relations context.
    • (2002) Yale L.J. , vol.111
    • Levinson, D.J.1
  • 397
    • 80052428189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Taxing Power
    • note
    • See Ruth Mason, Federalism and the Taxing Power, 99 Calif. L. Rev. 975, 977 & nn.3-6 (2011) (presenting several of the perspectives on this debate). For a useful recent empirical perspective, see generally Brian Galle, The Politics of Federalism: Self-Interest or Safeguards? Evidence from Congressional Control of State Taxation (Bos. Coll. Law Sch. Legal Studies, Research Paper No. 220, 2011), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1759510.
    • (2011) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.99 , Issue.3-6
    • Mason, R.1
  • 399
    • 13244256992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empire-Building Government in Constitutional Law
    • note
    • What of the argument that legislators will act systematically to advance the institutional interests of Congress at the cost of states' regulatory domains? As a threshold matter, arguments based on the claim that officials have an incentive of this kind have been comprehensively criticized as wanting in support. See Daryl J. Levinson, Empire-Building Government in Constitutional Law, 118 Harv. L. Rev. 915, 920 (2005) (arguing that officials often act based on personal and political incentives that do not entail defending institutional powers and prerogatives of the branch that employs them).
    • (2005) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.118
    • Levinson, D.J.1
  • 400
    • 84866997195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enforcing (But Not Defending) "Unconstitutional" Laws
    • note
    • But see Aziz Z. Huq, Enforcing (But Not Defending) "Unconstitutional" Laws, 98 Va. L. Rev. 1001, 1075-76 (2012) (collecting evidence that Levinson's claim does not hold in respect to executive action).
    • (2012) Va. L. Rev. , vol.98
    • Huq, A.Z.1
  • 401
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 402
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 403
    • 0042231883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism in Constitutional Context
    • Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Federalism in Constitutional Context, 22 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 181, 185 n.13 (1998).
    • (1998) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.22 , Issue.13
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 404
    • 0010103733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review
    • note
    • Lynn A. Baker & Ernest A. Young, Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review, 51 Duke L.J. 75, 117-24 (2001) (arguing that "some states will harness the federal lawmaking power to impose their policy preferences on other states to the former states' own advantage" (emphases omitted).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.51
    • Baker, L.A.1    Young, E.A.2
  • 405
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 406
    • 0346096850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dissecting the State: The Use of Federal Law to Free State and Local Officials from State Legislatures' Control
    • note
    • The baseline problem is exacerbated by the tendency of scholars to use the term "federalism" imprecisely to encompass a plural set of normative values-including sovereignty, democracy, and efficiency-related concepts-that lack any clear metric and are associated with a range of institutional actors. See Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Dissecting the State: The Use of Federal Law to Free State and Local Officials from State Legislatures' Control, 97 Mich. L. Rev. 1201, 1201 (1999) (commenting that it is common, yet misleading, to think of a "state" as speaking with a single voice when a state government encompasses a multitude of subdivisions, branches, and agencies controlled by various individual politicians). Claims about federalism thus risk having an imprecise and mercurial quality.
    • (1999) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1201
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 407
    • 0010103733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review
    • note
    • Lynn A. Baker & Ernest A. Young, Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review, 51 Duke L.J. 75, 117-24 (2001) (arguing that "some states will harness the federal lawmaking power to impose their policy preferences on other states to the former states' own advantage" (emphases omitted).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.51
    • Baker, L.A.1    Young, E.A.2
  • 408
    • 84937334145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putting the Safeguards Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism
    • note
    • see also Lynn A. Baker, Putting the Safeguards Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism, 46 Vill. L. Rev. 951, 961-72 (2001) (same).
    • (2001) Vill. L. Rev. , vol.46
    • Baker, L.A.1
  • 409
    • 0010103733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review
    • note
    • Lynn A. Baker & Ernest A. Young, Federalism and the Double Standard of Judicial Review, 51 Duke L.J. 75, 117-24 (2001) (arguing that "some states will harness the federal lawmaking power to impose their policy preferences on other states to the former states' own advantage" (emphases omitted).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.51
    • Baker, L.A.1    Young, E.A.2
  • 410
    • 84887288287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Windsor
    • note
    • To be clear, I do not mean here to express a view on the Equal Protection Clause questions at stake in respect to debates on same-sex marriage. Cf. United States v. Windsor, 133 S. Ct. 2675, 2692-93 (2013) (relying on not merely arguments of federalism but also liberty and equality arguments to require recognition of same-sex marriages by the federal government).
    • (2013) S. Ct. , vol.133
  • 411
    • 84925214670 scopus 로고
    • The Puzzling Persistence of Process-Based Constitutional Theories
    • note
    • This parallels the problem in the individual rights context of figuring out "how we are supposed to distinguish... 'prejudice' from principled, if 'wrong,' disapproval. Which groups are to count as 'discrete and insular minorities'? Which are instead to be deemed appropriate losers...?" Laurence H. Tribe, The Puzzling Persistence of Process-Based Constitutional Theories, 89 Yale L.J. 1063, 1073 (1980).
    • (1980) Yale L.J. , vol.89
    • Tribe, L.H.1
  • 412
    • 84866676451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Michael Greve offers a similar horizontal aggrandizement claim, but uses a libertarian baseline of maximal economic competition to resolve it. See, e.g., Michael S. Greve, The Upside-Down Constitution 7, 11 (2012). Of course, the claim that all forms of economic competition are desirable, even if they produce negative externalities such as atmospheric pollution, wage deflation, or predatory firm behavior, is (to say the least) a controversial one.
    • (2012) The Upside-Down Constitution
    • Greve, M.S.1
  • 414
    • 0346179806 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Ratification of Human Rights Conventions: The Ghost of Senator Bricker
    • note
    • For useful discussions of this practice, see Louis Henkin, Commentary, U.S. Ratification of Human Rights Conventions: The Ghost of Senator Bricker, 89 Am. J. Int'l L. 341, 341, 345-46 (1995).
    • (1995) Am. J. Int'l L. , vol.89
    • Henkin, L.1
  • 415
    • 0043245912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Agreements and the Political Safeguards of Federalism
    • David Sloss, International Agreements and the Political Safeguards of Federalism, 55 Stan. L. Rev. 1963, 1984-87 (2003).
    • (2003) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.55
    • Sloss, D.1
  • 416
    • 0346179806 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Ratification of Human Rights Conventions: The Ghost of Senator Bricker
    • note
    • For useful discussions of this practice, see Louis Henkin, Commentary, U.S. Ratification of Human Rights Conventions: The Ghost of Senator Bricker, 89 Am. J. Int'l L. 341, 341, 345-46 (1995).
    • (1995) Am. J. Int'l L. , vol.89
    • Henkin, L.1
  • 418
    • 33751210609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Executive Federalism: Forging New Federalist Constraints on the Treaty Power
    • note
    • Duncan B. Hollis, Executive Federalism: Forging New Federalist Constraints on the Treaty Power, 79 S. Cal. L. Rev. 1327, 1361-62 (2006) (discussing the United States' ratification of the U.N. Convention).
    • (2006) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.79
    • Hollis, D.B.1
  • 419
    • 78751503683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AEDPA's Wrecks: Comity, Finality, and Federalism
    • note
    • Lee Kovarsky, AEDPA's Wrecks: Comity, Finality, and Federalism, 82 Tul. L. Rev. 443, 459-68 (2007) (discussing 1996 federal habeas statute's legislative history and the Oklahoma City bombing).
    • (2007) Tul. L. Rev. , vol.82
    • Kovarsky, L.1
  • 420
    • 84894624774 scopus 로고
    • Prison Litigation Reform Act of 1995, H.R. 2076
    • Prison Litigation Reform Act of 1995, H.R. 2076, 104th Cong. tit. VIII (1995).
    • (1995) 104th Cong. tit. VIII
  • 421
    • 0037621815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inmate Litigation
    • note
    • Margo Schlanger, Inmate Litigation, 116 Harv. L. Rev. 1555, 1566-67 (2003) (discussing role of state attorneys general in lobbying for the Prison Litigation Reform Act, which restricted the powers of federal courts to interfere with the administration of state prison systems).
    • (2003) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.116
    • Schlanger, M.1
  • 422
    • 84959671823 scopus 로고
    • Law, Politics and the New Federalism: State Attorneys General as National Policymakers
    • See Cornell W. Clayton, Law, Politics and the New Federalism: State Attorneys General as National Policymakers, 56 Rev. Pol. 525, 540 (1994).
    • (1994) Rev. Pol. , vol.56
    • Clayton, C.W.1
  • 423
    • 0002857636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Federalism
    • note
    • It bears noting that 1996 also saw enactment of the welfare reform legislation that increased states' policy control over social welfare policies dramatically. See Robert P. Inman & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Rethinking Federalism, 11 J. Econ. Persp. 43, 56-59 (1997) (describing the law's federalism effects).
    • (1997) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.11
    • Inman, R.P.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 424
    • 84894609253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 U.S.C. §§ 1501-1571 (2012).
    • (2012) U.S.C. , vol.2
  • 425
    • 18444393076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Unfulfilled Promise of the Constitution in Executive Hands
    • note
    • Article II values, though, may be vindicated by the Office of Legal Counsel's (OLC) bill comment process. See Cornelia T.L. Pillard, The Unfulfilled Promise of the Constitution in Executive Hands, 103 Mich. L. Rev. 676, 711-12 (2005) (explaining ex ante review of bills by the OLC).
    • (2005) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.103
    • Pillard, C.T.L.1
  • 426
    • 0347507805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reconceptualizing Unfunded Mandates and Other Regulations
    • Julie A. Roin, Reconceptualizing Unfunded Mandates and Other Regulations, 93 Nw. U. L. Rev. 351, 380 n.109 (1999).
    • (1999) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.93 , Issue.109
    • Roin, J.A.1
  • 427
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 428
    • 36348992079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Federal Policymakers Account for the Concerns of State and Local Governments in the Formulation of Federal Tax Policy
    • note
    • See Jane G. Gravelle & Jennifer Gravelle, How Federal Policymakers Account for the Concerns of State and Local Governments in the Formulation of Federal Tax Policy, 60 Nat'l Tax J. 631, 631 (2007).
    • (2007) Nat'l Tax J. , vol.60 , pp. 631
    • Gravelle, J.G.1    Gravelle, J.2
  • 431
    • 33745246512 scopus 로고
    • PUD No. 1 v. Wash. Dep't of Ecology
    • See, e.g., PUD No. 1 v. Wash. Dep't of Ecology, 511 U.S. 700, 711-12 (1994).
    • (1994) U.S. , vol.511
  • 432
    • 84894630537 scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 79-15
    • note
    • Pub. L. No. 79-15, 59 Stat. 33 (1945) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011-1015 (2012).
    • (1945) Stat. , vol.59 , pp. 33
  • 433
    • 15144356681 scopus 로고
    • The McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945: Reconceiving the Federal Role in Insurance Regulation
    • note
    • See, e.g., Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, The McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945: Reconceiving the Federal Role in Insurance Regulation, 68 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 13, 17-20 (1993) (suggesting "modifications" to the statute).
    • (1993) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.68
    • Macey, J.R.1    Miller, G.P.2
  • 434
    • 84894617284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National Flood Insurance Act of 1968, Pub. L. 90-448
    • note
    • National Flood Insurance Act of 1968, Pub. L. 90-448, 82 Stat. 572 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 42 U.S.C.).
    • Stat. , vol.82 , pp. 572
  • 435
    • 84894622536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The examples I give might also be explained in terms of the heterogeneous preferences of federal legislators over policy domains where states have an interest. Even if that explanation were compelling-and I am skeptical-it would still mean that states' interests were in fact protected in the federal legislative process, even if not as a result of states' political actions.
  • 437
    • 84894634892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consider, for example, carve-outs for state actors from generally applicable regulatory regimes. These tend to benefit all states, not just those who participated in the lobbying effort. See, e.g., 29 U.S.C. § 630(f) (2012) (exempting "policymaking" officials from the Age Discrimination in Employment Act of 1967).
    • (2012) U.S.C. , vol.29
  • 438
    • 84894628540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consider, for example, carve-outs for state actors from generally applicable regulatory regimes. These tend to benefit all states, not just those who participated in the lobbying effort. See, e.g., 29 U.S.C. § 630(f) (2012) (exempting "policymaking" officials from the Age Discrimination in Employment Act of 1967).
    • (2012) U.S.C. , vol.29
  • 439
    • 13844256919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism
    • Neal Devins, The Judicial Safeguards of Federalism, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 131, 134 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • Devins, N.1
  • 440
    • 0042231883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism in Constitutional Context
    • Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Federalism in Constitutional Context, 22 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 181, 185 n.13 (1998).
    • (1998) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.22 , Issue.13
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 441
    • 0042231883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism in Constitutional Context
    • Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Federalism in Constitutional Context, 22 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 181, 185 n.13 (1998).
    • (1998) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.22 , Issue.13
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 442
    • 77958410286 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Theory of Statutory Evolution: The Federalization of Environmental Law
    • note
    • See E. Donald Elliott et al., Toward a Theory of Statutory Evolution: The Federalization of Environmental Law, 1 J.L. Econ. & Org. 313, 326 (1985) ("When faced with the threat of inconsistent and increasingly rigorous state laws, [interest groups use] their superior organizational capacities in Washington [to seek federal legislation]. ").
    • (1985) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.1
    • Elliott, E.D.1
  • 445
    • 84894625550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consider a simplified two-state version of the dynamic: Both states are within a federal welfare system, and both want to enjoy federal benefits while not investing in a domestic safety net. If both shirk, the net effect is a collapse of the safety net, raising mortality and morbidity without either state gaining. But if one state ties its hands by committing to underinvest, the other state gains little by underinvesting, even as it is committed to the safety net.
  • 447
    • 0347664782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norm Theory and the Future of the Federal Appointments Process
    • note
    • Michael J. Gerhardt, Norm Theory and the Future of the Federal Appointments Process, 50 Duke L.J. 1687, 1687 (2001).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.50 , pp. 1687
    • Gerhardt, M.J.1
  • 449
    • 0040433168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Picking Federal Judges: A Note on Policy and Partisan Selection Agendas
    • Michael W. Giles et al., Picking Federal Judges: A Note on Policy and Partisan Selection Agendas, 54 Pol. Res. Q. 623, 624 (2001).
    • (2001) Pol. Res. Q. , vol.54
    • Giles, M.W.1
  • 450
    • 62649148804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Soft Law: Lessons from Congressional Practice
    • Jacob E. Gersen & Eric A. Posner, Soft Law: Lessons from Congressional Practice, 61 Stan. L. Rev. 573, 578 (2008).
    • (2008) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.61
    • Gersen, J.E.1    Posner, E.A.2
  • 451
    • 84894624580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. Con. Res
    • note
    • See, e.g., H.R. Con. Res. 299, 105th Cong. (1998) (specifying criteria for executive departments to follow when preempting state law consistent with the Constitution).
    • (1998) 105th Cong. , vol.299
  • 452
    • 84894622259 scopus 로고
    • H.R. Con. Res
    • note
    • H.R. Con. Res. 161, 101st Cong. (1989) (expressing the "sense of the Congress that it is in the interest of a viable Federal system of Government that primary regulatory authority over alcohol beverages within their borders shall remain with the States").
    • (1989) 101st Cong. , vol.161
  • 453
    • 84894620073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • At least on the assumption that legislators have a preference for being seen as having consistent preferences over time. That is, I presume (reasonably, I think) that there is some credibility-related cost to politicians to taking mutually inconsistent positions at different points in time.
  • 459
    • 84892735983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standing for the Structural Constitution
    • note
    • I develop the point that the relationship between federalism and individual liberty is an unstable one elsewhere. See Aziz Z. Huq, Standing for the Structural Constitution, 99 Va. L. Rev. 1435, 1484-89 (2013).
    • (2013) Va. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • Huq, A.Z.1
  • 460
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms
    • Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 Mich. L. Rev. 338, 352 (1997) (emphasis omitted). The same is true for Mancur Olson's theory of "selective incentives" as a way of accounting for the existence of large associations.
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 461
    • 84898188600 scopus 로고
    • Political Overload & Federalism
    • Samuel H. Beer, Political Overload & Federalism, 10 Polity 5, 11 (1977).
    • (1977) Polity , vol.10
    • Beer, S.H.1
  • 463
    • 68049093467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Internationalization of American Federalism, Missouri and Holland
    • note
    • Judith Resnik, The Internationalization of American Federalism, Missouri and Holland, 73 Mo. L. Rev. 1105, 1128-30 (2008) (listing organizations with founding dates).
    • (2008) Mo. L. Rev. , vol.73
    • Resnik, J.1
  • 464
    • 84928460272 scopus 로고
    • State and Local Governments' Washington "Reps"-Lobbying Strategies and President Reagan's New Federalism
    • note
    • John P. Pelissero & Robert E. England, State and Local Governments' Washington "Reps"-Lobbying Strategies and President Reagan's New Federalism, 19 St. & Loc. Gov't Rev. 68, 68 (1987).
    • (1987) St. & Loc. Gov't Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 68
    • Pelissero, J.P.1    England, R.E.2
  • 466
    • 79960121643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shaping Health Reform: State Government Influence in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act
    • John Dinan, Shaping Health Reform: State Government Influence in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, 41 Publius 395, 407 (2011).
    • (2011) Publius , vol.41
    • Dinan, J.1
  • 467
    • 79960121643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shaping Health Reform: State Government Influence in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act
    • John Dinan, Shaping Health Reform: State Government Influence in the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, 41 Publius 395, 407 (2011).
    • (2011) Publius , vol.41
    • Dinan, J.1
  • 468
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 469
    • 0038992127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redesigning the Architecture of Federalism-An American Tradition: Modern Devolution Policies in Perspective
    • Harry N. Scheiber, Redesigning the Architecture of Federalism-An American Tradition: Modern Devolution Policies in Perspective, 14 Yale L. & Pol'y Rev. 227, 254 (1996).
    • (1996) Yale L. & Pol'y Rev. , vol.14
    • Scheiber, H.N.1
  • 470
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 471
    • 84894628865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Permanent Policy Principles for State-Federal Relations, Nat'l Governors Ass'n, http://www.nga.org/cms/home/federal-relations/nga-policy-positions/ page-ec-policies/col2-content/main-content-list/principles-for-state-federal-rel.html (last visited Feb. 1, 2014) (delineating proposals for reform on structural federalism issues).
    • Permanent Policy Principles for State-Federal Relations
  • 474
    • 0039198787 scopus 로고
    • The Paradox of Voting and Congressional Rules for Voting on Amendments
    • note
    • One reason that agenda control is overlooked is identified by Riker, who argues that the existence of "elaborate" legislative choices involving the simultaneous consideration of multiple amendments can obscure the existence of decisional intransitivities. See William H. Riker, The Paradox of Voting and Congressional Rules for Voting on Amendments, 52 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 349, 354 (1958). This opportunity for both creating and hiding intransitivities in turn might be exploited by a legislative agenda setter in order to steer outcomes toward his or her preferred policy ends.
    • (1958) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.52
    • Riker, W.H.1
  • 477
    • 68049092963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism Accountability: "Agency-Forcing" Measures
    • note
    • See Catherine M. Sharkey, Federalism Accountability: "Agency-Forcing" Measures, 58 Duke L.J. 2125, 2150-52 (2009) (documenting how agencies were more responsive to state regulatory concerns about the REAL ID Act of 2005 than Congress).
    • (2009) Duke L.J. , vol.58
    • Sharkey, C.M.1
  • 478
    • 8744306085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chevron and Preemption
    • Nina A. Mendelson, Chevron and Preemption, 102 Mich. L. Rev. 737, 741 (2004).
    • (2004) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.102
    • Mendelson, N.A.1
  • 479
    • 79851501072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Negotiating Federalism
    • note
    • Erin Ryan, Negotiating Federalism, 52 B.C. L. Rev. 1, 8 (2011) ("[F]ederalism bargaining helps bridge pockets of uncertainty that remain after exhausting the more conventionally understood forms of federalism interpretation, to help allocate contested authority and shepherd interjurisdictional collaboration. ").
    • (2011) B.C. L. Rev. , vol.52
    • Ryan, E.1
  • 480
    • 84926271532 scopus 로고
    • Competition in Interregional Taxation: The Case of Western Coal
    • note
    • For inferential evidence of socially undesirable rent-seeking through state taxation, see Charles D. Kolstad & Frank A. Wolak, Jr., Competition in Interregional Taxation: The Case of Western Coal, 91 J. Pol. Econ. 443, 449, 454-55 (1983).
    • (1983) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.91
    • Kolstad, C.D.1    Wolak Jr., F.A.2
  • 481
    • 21844509872 scopus 로고
    • Strategizing in Small Group Decision-Making: Host State Identification for Radioactive Waste Disposal Among Eight Southern States
    • See Dennis Coates & Michael C. Munger, Strategizing in Small Group Decision-Making: Host State Identification for Radioactive Waste Disposal Among Eight Southern States, 82 Pub. Choice 1, 2 (1995).
    • (1995) Pub. Choice , vol.82
    • Coates, D.1    Munger, M.C.2
  • 482
    • 0347507805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reconceptualizing Unfunded Mandates and Other Regulations
    • Julie A. Roin, Reconceptualizing Unfunded Mandates and Other Regulations, 93 Nw. U. L. Rev. 351, 380 n.109 (1999).
    • (1999) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.93 , Issue.109
    • Roin, J.A.1
  • 483
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 484
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 488
    • 0040283227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995
    • note
    • The most eloquent version of this argument is offered by Elizabeth Garrett, Enhancing the Political Safeguards of Federalism? The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, 45 U. Kan. L. Rev. 1113, 1118 (1997), as part of a larger package of otherwise powerful arguments.
    • (1997) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Garrett, E.1
  • 489
    • 0346941479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congressional Factfinding and the Scope of Judicial Review: A Preliminary Analysis
    • note
    • Neal Devins, Congressional Factfinding and the Scope of Judicial Review: A Preliminary Analysis, 50 Duke L.J. 1169, 1194-200 (2001) [hereinafter Devins, Congressional Factfinding] (doubting whether the political economy of the federal legislative process conduces to serious consideration of federal concerns).
    • (2001) Duke L.J. , vol.50
    • Devins, N.1
  • 490
    • 33644911174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy
    • States' comparative advantage may also be deepened by an epistemic edge they have on private interest groups (although the empirical evidence for this effect is sparse). Recent studies of lobbying suggest that lobbying operates "as a form of legislative subsidy-a matching grant of costly policy information, political intelligence, and legislative labor. " Richard L. Hall & Alan V. Deardorff, Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy, 100 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 69, 69 (2006).
    • (2006) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 69
    • Hall, R.L.1    Deardorff, A.V.2
  • 491
    • 58049176678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does the Federal Government Learn from the States? Medicaid and the Limits of Expertise in the Intergovernmental Lobby
    • Kevin M. Esterling, Does the Federal Government Learn from the States? Medicaid and the Limits of Expertise in the Intergovernmental Lobby, 39 Publius 1, 18 (2008).
    • (2008) Publius , vol.39
    • Esterling, K.M.1
  • 492
    • 84974040577 scopus 로고
    • Campaign Contributions and Access
    • note
    • There is evidence that interest group contributions foster access. See David Austen-Smith, Campaign Contributions and Access, 89 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 566, 566 (1995).
    • (1995) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 566
    • Austen-Smith, D.1
  • 493
    • 84879093245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under the Influence
    • note
    • Martin Gilens, Under the Influence, Boston Rev., July/Aug. 2012, at 15, 31 (doubting that differential interest group access explains why federal lawmaking is more responsive to some slices of the population than others).
    • (2012) Boston Rev.
    • Gilens, M.1
  • 494
    • 36549087944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shakedown at Gucci Gulch: The New Logic of Collective Action
    • Edward J. McCaffery & Linda R. Cohen, Shakedown at Gucci Gulch: The New Logic of Collective Action, 84 N.C. L. Rev. 1159, 1164 (2006).
    • (2006) N.C. L. Rev. , vol.84
    • McCaffery, E.J.1    Cohen, L.R.2
  • 496
    • 62649145065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative Threats
    • Guy Halfteck, Legislative Threats, 61 Stan. L. Rev. 629, 664 n.145 (2008) (documenting the pervasiveness of rent extraction). Even the threat of adverse government action can have a negative effect on firms.
    • (2008) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.61 , Issue.145
    • Halfteck, G.1
  • 497
    • 0042615732 scopus 로고
    • Rent Extraction Through Political Extortion: An Empirical Examination
    • note
    • R. Beck et al., Rent Extraction Through Political Extortion: An Empirical Examination, 21 J. Legal Stud. 217, 223 (1992) (demonstrating that Canadian firms suffered negative stock returns following the announcement of potential adverse government action).
    • (1992) J. Legal Stud. , vol.21
    • Beck, R.1
  • 498
    • 0000456233 scopus 로고
    • The Theory of Economic Regulation
    • note
    • In addition, it is possible that intraindustry competition will conduce to "races to the Hill" in order to secure exclusionary regulation that enables a lobbying firm to capture monopoly rents. See George J. Stigler, The Theory of Economic Regulation, 2 Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. 3, 5 (1971). Although states are said to engage in horizontal competition, it would be surprising if it was as intense as interfirm competition.
    • (1971) Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. , vol.2
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 499
    • 15744379092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Seminole Tribe v. Florida
    • See Seminole Tribe v. Florida, 517 U.S. 44, 54 (1996) (not allowing abrogation of state sovereign immunity under Article I).
    • (1996) U.S. , vol.517
  • 500
    • 15744380047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alden v. Maine
    • note
    • Alden v. Maine, 527 U.S. 706, 754 (1999) (holding that Congress could not abrogate state sovereign immunity in state court under Article I).
    • (1999) U.S. , vol.527
  • 501
    • 18344368345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Printz v. United States
    • See Printz v. United States, 521 U.S. 898, 929-30 (1997).
    • (1997) U.S. , vol.521
  • 502
    • 33044493019 scopus 로고
    • New York v. United States
    • New York v. United States, 505 U.S. 144, 168-69 (1992).
    • (1992) U.S. , vol.505
  • 503
    • 84863954064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sossamon v. Texas
    • note
    • See, e.g., Sossamon v. Texas, 131 S. Ct. 1651, 1658 (2011) (concluding that absent an "unequivocal expression of state consent, " the phrase "[a]ppropriate relief" in the Religious Land Use and Institutionalized Persons Act of 2000 could not be construed to permit money damages).
    • (2011) S. Ct. , vol.131
  • 504
    • 84875198650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barnes v. Gorman
    • note
    • Barnes v. Gorman, 536 U.S. 181, 185-88 (2002) (same for punitive damages).
    • (2002) U.S. , vol.536
  • 505
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 506
    • 13844281742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System
    • John O. McGinnis & Ilya Somin, Federalism vs. States' Rights: A Defense of Judicial Review in a Federal System, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 89, 99 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99
    • McGinnis, J.O.1    Somin, I.2
  • 508
    • 84858857589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding Supreme Court Confirmations
    • note
    • For studies of rates of senatorial disapproval, see Geoffrey R. Stone, Understanding Supreme Court Confirmations, 2010 Sup. Ct. Rev. 381, 382-84 (showing legislative influence over time).
    • (2010) Sup. Ct. Rev.
    • Stone, G.R.1
  • 509
    • 34547980613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidents, Senates, and Failed Supreme Court Nominations
    • Keith E. Whittington, Presidents, Senates, and Failed Supreme Court Nominations, 2006 Sup. Ct. Rev. 401, 408.
    • (2006) Sup. Ct. Rev.
    • Whittington, K.E.1
  • 510
    • 64949134484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Role of Qualifications in the Confirmation of Nominees to the U.S. Supreme Court
    • note
    • There is a large body of empirical work to this effect. See Lee Epstein et al., The Role of Qualifications in the Confirmation of Nominees to the U.S. Supreme Court, 32 Fla. St. U. L. Rev. 1145, 1168-70 (2005) (finding that a candidate's ideology as well as her qualifications influences senators' decisions).
    • (2005) Fla. St. U. L. Rev. , vol.32
    • Epstein, L.1
  • 511
    • 84971722490 scopus 로고
    • Senate Voting on Supreme Court Nominees: A Neoinstitutional Model
    • Charles M. Cameron et al., Senate Voting on Supreme Court Nominees: A Neoinstitutional Model, 84 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 525, 530-31 (1990).
    • (1990) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.84
    • Cameron, C.M.1
  • 512
    • 84934563594 scopus 로고
    • A Spatial Model of Roll Call Voting: Senators, Constituents, Presidents, and Interest Groups in Supreme Court Confirmations
    • Jeffrey A. Segal et al., A Spatial Model of Roll Call Voting: Senators, Constituents, Presidents, and Interest Groups in Supreme Court Confirmations, 36 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 96, 113-14 (1992). In addition, legislators have long exercised influence on judicial behavior through court funding and jurisdictional legislation.
    • (1992) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.36
    • Segal, J.A.1
  • 513
    • 0036735373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Political Parties Can Use the Courts to Advance Their Agendas: Federal Courts in the United States, 1875-1891
    • Howard Gillman, How Political Parties Can Use the Courts to Advance Their Agendas: Federal Courts in the United States, 1875-1891, 96 Am. Po. Sci. Rev. 511, 512, 515-16, 520 (2002).
    • (2002) Am. Po. Sci. Rev. , vol.96
    • Gillman, H.1
  • 514
    • 22144496650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Rehnquist Court and the Political Dynamics of Federalism
    • See J. Mitchell Pickerill & Cornell W. Clayton, The Rehnquist Court and the Political Dynamics of Federalism, 2 Persp. on Pol. 233, 240-43 (2004).
    • (2004) Persp. on Pol. , vol.2
    • Pickerill, J.M.1    Clayton, C.W.2
  • 515
    • 22644435762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Guess What Happened on the Way to the Revolution? Precursors to the Supreme Court's Federalism Revolution
    • Cornell W. Clayton & J. Mitchell Pickerill, Guess What Happened on the Way to the Revolution? Precursors to the Supreme Court's Federalism Revolution, 34 Publius 85 (2004).
    • (2004) Publius , vol.34 , pp. 85
    • Clayton, C.W.1    Pickerill, J.M.2
  • 517
    • 22644435762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Guess What Happened on the Way to the Revolution? Precursors to the Supreme Court's Federalism Revolution
    • Cornell W. Clayton & J. Mitchell Pickerill, Guess What Happened on the Way to the Revolution? Precursors to the Supreme Court's Federalism Revolution, 34 Publius 85 (2004).
    • (2004) Publius , vol.34 , pp. 85
    • Clayton, C.W.1    Pickerill, J.M.2
  • 518
    • 0039584992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dismantling the Modern State? The Changing Structural Foundations of Federalism
    • Keith E. Whittington, Dismantling the Modern State? The Changing Structural Foundations of Federalism, 25 Hastings Const. L.Q. 483, 527 (1998).
    • (1998) Hastings Const. L.Q. , vol.25
    • Whittington, K.E.1
  • 519
    • 84894627488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I do not wish to overstate the case here. As noted, judges' attention to politics surely declines in the period after their appointment, and the judiciary's agenda may imperfectly overlap with that of the elected branches.
  • 520
    • 84894630474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Is it possible that the time lag between congressional and judicial preferences will have a smoothing effect on outcomes? It is certainly possible that the preference divergence necessarily created by the lag has a stabilizing effect at some moments. But it might also be that federal judges are appointed to satisfy more ideologically committed factions of a party, such that they run a little ahead of legislators. This possibility would help explain why states may go to federal courts even though they have already sought and failed to obtain a result in Congress (although the frictional effect of vetogates in Congress means that even a court with similar preferences to Congress has a freedom to act that legislators lack).
  • 521
    • 84937334145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putting the Safeguards Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism
    • note
    • see also Lynn A. Baker, Putting the Safeguards Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism, 46 Vill. L. Rev. 951, 961-72 (2001) (same).
    • (2001) Vill. L. Rev. , vol.46
    • Baker, L.A.1
  • 522
    • 34548299197 scopus 로고
    • Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?
    • Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 Yale L.J. 31, 82-83 (1991).
    • (1991) Yale L.J. , vol.101
    • Elhauge, E.R.1
  • 523
    • 84866558937 scopus 로고
    • Bailey v. Drexel Furniture Co
    • note
    • Decisions that fit this profile might include Bailey v. Drexel Furniture Co., 259 U.S. 20, 44 (1922), which struck down the Child Labor Tax Law. States maintain robust federal court litigation capacity consistent with either a positive story of judicial safeguards or a negative one about rent-seeking through the courts.
    • (1922) U.S. , vol.259
  • 526
    • 33044493019 scopus 로고
    • 505 U.S. 144, 187 (1992).
    • (1992) U.S. , vol.505
  • 527
    • 84937304127 scopus 로고
    • The Case of the Prisoners and the Origins of Judicial Review
    • note
    • See William Michael Treanor, The Case of the Prisoners and the Origins of Judicial Review, 143 U. Pa. L. Rev. 491, 527 (1994) (describing preratification proceedings in which participants believed a statute had to be "dramatically at odds with the constitution" for it to be unconstitutional).
    • (1994) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.143
    • Treanor, W.M.1
  • 528
    • 84963082747 scopus 로고
    • The General Theory of Second Best
    • note
    • For a general statement of the theory, see R.G. Lipsey & R.K. Lancaster, The General Theory of Second Best, 24 Rev. Econ. Stud. 11, 11 (1956) ("[I]f there is introduced into a general equilibrium system a constraint which prevents the attainment of one of the Paretian conditions [i.e., the circumstances that generate Pareto-optimal outcomes], the other Paretian conditions, although still attainable, are, in general, no longer desirable. ").
    • (1956) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.24 , pp. 11
    • Lipsey, R.G.1    Lancaster, R.K.2
  • 529
    • 84874562895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Removal as a Political Question
    • note
    • Writing in these pages last year, I offered an analogous institutional capacity argument respecting certain separation-of-powers questions. See Aziz Z. Huq, Removal as a Political Question, 65 Stan. L. Rev. 1, 70-76 (2013) (arguing that Article II challenges to administrative positions based on a deficit of presidential control should not be justiciable). Obviously, the federalism-related argument here resonates with the skepticism about separation-of-powers jurisprudence offered there.
    • (2013) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.65
    • Huq, A.Z.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.