메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 96, Issue 2, 2010, Pages 301-358

Unbundled powers

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77952031039     PISSN: 00426601     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (38)

References (296)
  • 5
    • 33745686547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Separation of parties, not powers
    • Daryl J. Levinson & Richard H. Pildes, Separation of Parties, Not Powers, 119 Harv. L. Rev. 2311 (2006);
    • (2006) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.119 , pp. 2311
    • Levinson, D.J.1    Pildes, R.H.2
  • 6
    • 0346479813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The real separation in separation of powers law
    • M. Elizabeth Magill, The Real Separation in Separation of Powers Law, 86 Va. L. Rev. 1127 (2000).
    • (2000) Va. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 1127
    • Elizabeth Magill, M.1
  • 7
    • 84878359642 scopus 로고
    • Philip B. Kurland & Ralph Lerner eds.
    • For an overview of historical materials, see generally 1 The Founders' Constitution 311-354 (Philip B. Kurland & Ralph Lerner eds., 1987).
    • (1987) The Founders' Constitution , pp. 311-354
  • 9
    • 0004071845 scopus 로고
    • Univ. of Chicago Press 1979 "The total union of them, we have seen, would be productive of tyranny; the total disjunction of them for the present, would in the end produce the same effects, by causing that union, against which it seems to provide"
    • William Blackstone, Commentaries on the Laws of England 149-150 (Univ. of Chicago Press 1979) (1765) ("The total union of them, we have seen, would be productive of tyranny; the total disjunction of them for the present, would in the end produce the same effects, by causing that union, against which it seems to provide.").
    • (1765) Commentaries on the Laws of England , pp. 149-150
    • Blackstone, W.1
  • 10
    • 77952080025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federalist No.51 (James Madison)
    • The Federalist No.51 (James Madison).
  • 11
    • 77952041415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gwyn, supra note 1, at 3-10
    • See, e.g., Gwyn, supra note 1, at 3-10.
  • 13
    • 69249136821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new separation of powers
    • 643-87
    • Bruce Ackerman, The New Separation of Powers, 113 Harv. L. Rev. 633, 643-87 (2000);
    • (2000) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.113 , pp. 633
    • Ackerman, B.1
  • 14
    • 27844587527 scopus 로고
    • The limits of the parliamentary critique of the separation of powers
    • 679-84
    • Thomas O. Sargentich, The Limits of the Parliamentary Critique of the Separation of Powers, 34 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 679, 679-84 (1993);
    • (1993) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.34 , pp. 679
    • Sargentich, T.O.1
  • 15
    • 77952066673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 524 U.S. 417, 450-52 (Kennedy, J., concurring)
    • see also Clinton v. New York, 524 U.S. 417, 450-52 (1998) (Kennedy, J., concurring);
    • (1998) Clinton V. New York
  • 17
    • 76449115544 scopus 로고
    • 487 U.S. 654, 693-96
    • Morrison v. Olson, 487 U.S. 654, 693-96 (1988);
    • (1988) Morrison V. Olson
  • 18
    • 77952057854 scopus 로고
    • 478 U.S. 714, 721-27
    • Bowsher v. Synar, 478 U.S. 714, 721-27 (1986);
    • (1986) Bowsher V. Synar
  • 19
    • 0011629734 scopus 로고
    • 462 U.S. 919, 951-59
    • INS v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919, 951-59 (1983);
    • (1983) INS V. Chadha
  • 20
    • 0038034254 scopus 로고
    • 424 U.S. 1, 120-24
    • Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1, 120-24 (1976).
    • (1976) Buckley V. Valeo
  • 21
    • 77952086820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are exceptions to this default, of course. Certain actions may only be taken by the executive, legislative, or judicial branch alone
    • There are exceptions to this default, of course. Certain actions may only be taken by the executive, legislative, or judicial branch alone.
  • 22
    • 0003424938 scopus 로고
    • Paul Smith ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 2001
    • The same bundling phenomenon is evident in the parliamentary structure. See generally Walter Bagehot, The English Constitution (Paul Smith ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 2001) (1867) ;
    • (1867) The English Constitution
    • Bagehot, W.1
  • 23
    • 77952042641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilson, supra note 6, at 187-89
    • Wilson, supra note 6, at 187-89.
  • 25
    • 77952060150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 653-57
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 653-57.
  • 26
    • 84985817897 scopus 로고
    • A new political system model: Semi-presidential government
    • 165
    • Semi-presidential regimes blend the explicit commitments further, providing for the election of a President and the selection of a Prime Minister by the legislature. See Maurice Duverger, A New Political System Model: Semi-Presidential Government, 8 Eur. J. Pol. Res. 165, 165 (1980).
    • (1980) Eur. J. Pol. Res. , vol.8 , pp. 165
    • Duverger, M.1
  • 27
    • 77952023554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Executive and legislative functions are combined, but parliament or the ruling coalition retains the authority to utilize those powers over the entire set of permitted policies
    • Executive and legislative functions are combined, but parliament or the ruling coalition retains the authority to utilize those powers over the entire set of permitted policies.
  • 28
    • 77952033852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federalist No. 51, at 349 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961) "A dependence on the people is no doubt the primary controul on the government; but experience has taught mankind the necessity of auxiliary precautions
    • The Federalist No. 51, at 349 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961) ("A dependence on the people is no doubt the primary controul on the government; but experience has taught mankind the necessity of auxiliary precautions.").
  • 29
    • 77952033080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clinton, 524 U.S. at 450 (Kennedy, J., concurring) "Liberty is always at stake when one or more of the branches seek to transgress the separation of powers
    • See, e.g., Clinton, 524 U.S. at 450 (Kennedy, J., concurring) ("Liberty is always at stake when one or more of the branches seek to transgress the separation of powers.");
  • 30
    • 77950477830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 517 U.S. 748, 757-758 By allocating specific powers and responsibilities to a branch fitted to the task, the Framers created a National Government that is both effective and accountable.... The clear assignment of power to a branch, furthermore, allows the citizen to know who may be called to answer for making, or not making, those delicate and necessary decisions essential to governance
    • Loving v. United States, 517 U.S. 748, 757-758 (1996) ("By allocating specific powers and responsibilities to a branch fitted to the task, the Framers created a National Government that is both effective and accountable.... The clear assignment of power to a branch, furthermore, allows the citizen to know who may be called to answer for making, or not making, those delicate and necessary decisions essential to governance.").
    • (1996) Loving V. United States
  • 31
    • 77952037315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This Article's main reference point is Madisonian separation, but parliamentary alternatives are mentioned in passing, particularly when the justifications for topical separation dovetail with the justifications for combining powers in the parliamentary scheme
    • This Article's main reference point is Madisonian separation, but parliamentary alternatives are mentioned in passing, particularly when the justifications for topical separation dovetail with the justifications for combining powers in the parliamentary scheme.
  • 32
    • 77952015349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 664-66 contrasting presidentialism with constrained parliamentarianism
    • See Ackerman, supra note 6, at 664-66 (contrasting presidentialism with constrained parliamentarianism);
  • 33
    • 0242720001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Varieties of parliamentarianism in the advanced industrial democracies
    • 446-47 identifying direct election as one of three definitive distinctions between parliamentary and presidential systems
    • Alan Siaroff, Varieties of Parliamentarianism in the Advanced Industrial Democracies, 24 Int'l Pol. Sci. Rev. 445, 446-47 (2003) (identifying direct election as one of three definitive distinctions between parliamentary and presidential systems);
    • (2003) Int'l Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.24 , pp. 445
    • Siaroff, A.1
  • 34
    • 5844383486 scopus 로고
    • Constitutional frameworks and democratic consolidation: Parliamentarianism versus presidentialism
    • 3-4 contrasting "pure parliamentarianism" with "pure presidentialism" and identifying the electoral mandate of the executive power as a critical component of a presidential system
    • Alfred Stepan & Cindy Skach, Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parliamentarianism versus Presidentialism, 46 World Pol. 1, 3-4 (1993) (contrasting "pure parliamentarianism" with "pure presidentialism" and identifying the electoral mandate of the executive power as a critical component of a presidential system).
    • (1993) World Pol. , vol.46 , pp. 1
    • Stepan, A.1    Skach, C.2
  • 35
    • 77952026605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For analytic tractability, this Article avoids comparisons to constrained parliamentary and semi-presidential regimes
    • For analytic tractability, this Article avoids comparisons to constrained parliamentary and semi-presidential regimes.
  • 36
    • 77952075145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 642-88 comparing presidentialism with constrained parliamentarianism
    • For such comparisons, see Ackerman, supra note 6, at 642-88 (comparing presidentialism with constrained parliamentarianism);
  • 37
    • 77952062685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sartori, supra note 8, at 121-140 comparing presidentialism with semipresidentialism
    • Sartori, supra note 8, at 121-140 (comparing presidentialism with semipresidentialism).
  • 39
    • 0040594393 scopus 로고
    • The passing of dual federalism
    • 4
    • Edward S. Corwin, The Passing of Dual Federalism, 36 Va. L. Rev. 1, 4 (1950).
    • (1950) Va. L. Rev. , vol.36 , pp. 1
    • Corwin, E.S.1
  • 41
    • 84937308408 scopus 로고
    • Checks and balances in an era of presidential lawmaking
    • 172
    • See generally Abner S. Greene, Checks and Balances in an Era of Presidential Lawmaking, 61 U. Chi. L. Rev. 123, 172 (1994);
    • (1994) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 123
    • Greene, A.S.1
  • 42
    • 79957865585 scopus 로고
    • The place of agencies in government: Separation of powers and the fourth branch
    • 615-16
    • Peter L. Strauss, The Place of Agencies in Government: Separation of Powers and the Fourth Branch, 84 Colum. L. Rev. 573, 615-16 (1984).
    • (1984) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 573
    • Strauss, P.L.1
  • 43
    • 0003426427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Council of State Gov'ts, [hereinafter Book of the States]
    • See 38 Council of State Gov'ts, The Book of the States 169 (2006) [hereinafter Book of the States];
    • (2006) The Book of the States , pp. 169
  • 44
    • 59549094645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The unbundled executive
    • 1386
    • see also Christopher R. Berry & Jacob E. Gersen, The Unbundled Executive, 75 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1385, 1386 (2008);
    • (2008) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 1385
    • Berry, C.R.1    Gersen, J.E.2
  • 45
    • 33749170805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Break up the presidency? governors, state attorneys general, and lessons from the divided executive
    • 2453-55 (discussing the interaction between elected Attorneys General and Governors)
    • William P. Marshall, Break Up the Presidency? Governors, State Attorneys General, and Lessons from the Divided Executive, 115 Yale L.J. 2446, 2453-55 (2006) (discussing the interaction between elected Attorneys General and Governors).
    • (2006) Yale L.J. , vol.115 , pp. 2446
    • Marshall, W.P.1
  • 46
    • 77952027015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Book of the States, supra note 14, at 169-174
    • Book of the States, supra note 14, at 169-174
  • 47
    • 77952082624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Census of Governments, at vii (2002) [hereinafter 2002 Census of Governments]
    • See 1 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Census of Governments, at vii (2002) [hereinafter 2002 Census of Governments];
  • 49
    • 77952026181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 2002 Census of Governments, supra note 16, at 14
    • See 2002 Census of Governments, supra note 16, at 14.
  • 50
    • 77952078396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These institutions generate problems as well. For example, overlapping taxing authority may generate incentives to over-tax a local population
    • These institutions generate problems as well. For example, overlapping taxing authority may generate incentives to over-tax a local population.
  • 51
    • 77952050821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Berry, supra note 16, at 84-86
    • See Berry, supra note 16, at 84-86.
  • 52
    • 77952016351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions responsible for a single policy may also be insufficiently attentive to the impact of their decisions on other government units. Finally, as discussed below, an increase in the number of political institutions that citizens must monitor can produce excessive coordination costs and monitoring costs, potentially resulting in minoritarian or ineffective policies
    • Institutions responsible for a single policy may also be insufficiently attentive to the impact of their decisions on other government units. Finally, as discussed below, an increase in the number of political institutions that citizens must monitor can produce excessive coordination costs and monitoring costs, potentially resulting in minoritarian or ineffective policies.
  • 53
    • 77952074114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The five-branch theory is associated with Sun Yat Sen and was first implemented in the late 1920s. It is found in the 1947 Republic of China Constitution that remains in force in Taiwan today. The two extra branches are for examinations and for "control," which is an audit and administrative supervision function. The control branch is itself elected and is tasked with supervising other government officials
    • The five-branch theory is associated with Sun Yat Sen and was first implemented in the late 1920s. It is found in the 1947 Republic of China Constitution that remains in force in Taiwan today. The two extra branches are for examinations and for "control," which is an audit and administrative supervision function. The control branch is itself elected and is tasked with supervising other government officials.
  • 56
    • 77952081277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 137-138 Cicero referred to related functions for minor magistrates as well in his discussion of the ideal republic.
    • See id. at 137-138 Cicero referred to related functions for minor magistrates as well in his discussion of the ideal republic.
  • 57
    • 77952065124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 58
    • 0003261135 scopus 로고
    • Presidentialism and political stability in france
    • Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds
    • See Ezra N. Suleiman, Presidentialism and Political Stability in France, in The Failure of Presidential Democracy 137, 139 (Juan J. Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds., 1994).
    • (1994) The Failure of Presidential Democracy , vol.137 , pp. 139
    • Suleiman, E.N.1
  • 59
    • 4544358532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elected versus appointed regulators: Theory and evidence
    • [hereinafter Besley & Coate, Elected versus Appointed Regulators]
    • See Timothy Besley & Stephen Coate, Elected versus Appointed Regulators: Theory and Evidence, 1 J. Eur. Econ. Ass'n 1176 (2003) [hereinafter Besley & Coate, Elected versus Appointed Regulators];
    • (2003) J. Eur. Econ. Ass'n , vol.1 , pp. 1176
    • Besley, T.1    Coate, S.2
  • 60
    • 67651027843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Issue unbundling via citizens' initiatives
    • (suggesting that issue bundling explains the relevance of direct democracy in a representative system where candidates must already compete for the right to control policy)
    • Timothy Besley & Stephen Coate, Issue Unbundling via Citizens' Initiatives, 3 Q.J. Pol. Sci. 379 (2008) (suggesting that issue bundling explains the relevance of direct democracy in a representative system where candidates must already compete for the right to control policy).
    • (2008) Q.J. Pol. Sci. , vol.3 , pp. 379
    • Besley, T.1    Coate, S.2
  • 61
    • 59549091698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fiscal consequences of electoral institutions
    • 481 [hereinafter Berry & Gersen, Fiscal Consequences]
    • See Christopher R. Berry & Jacob E. Gersen, Fiscal Consequences of Electoral Institutions, 52 J.L. & Econ. 469, 481 (2009) [hereinafter Berry & Gersen, Fiscal Consequences];
    • (2009) J.L. & Econ. , vol.52 , pp. 469
    • Gersen, J.E.1
  • 62
    • 77952027829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berry & Gersen, supra note 14, at 1386-1387
    • Berry & Gersen, supra note 14, at 1386-1387
  • 63
    • 77952021923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are many intricacies ignored for the time being. For example, perhaps voters do not have well-defined preferences or view a large part of government action to be about the quality of the decisionmaking process rather than policy outputs, and so on. I begin, however, with a simplifying assumption that voters have well-specified preferences about policy on all dimensions and that accountability in government is desirable
    • There are many intricacies ignored for the time being. For example, perhaps voters do not have well-defined preferences or view a large part of government action to be about the quality of the decisionmaking process rather than policy outputs, and so on. I begin, however, with a simplifying assumption that voters have well-specified preferences about policy on all dimensions and that accountability in government is desirable.
  • 64
    • 0348223347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking representation
    • 516-25 (developing models of representative democracy).
    • See Jane Mansbridge, Rethinking Representation, 97 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 515, 516-25 (2003) (developing models of representative democracy).
    • (2003) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 515
    • Mansbridge, J.1
  • 66
    • 77952013726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2319; The Federalist No.51 (James Madison), No. 72 (Alexander Hamilton)
    • See Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2319; The Federalist No.51 (James Madison), No. 72 (Alexander Hamilton).
  • 67
    • 0003461439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (providing a survey and synthesis of contemporary literature on democratic policymaking)
    • See, e.g., Torsten Persson & Guido Tabellini, Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy (2000) (providing a survey and synthesis of contemporary literature on democratic policymaking).
    • (2000) Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy
    • Persson, T.1    Tabellini, G.2
  • 68
    • 0004236776 scopus 로고
    • See generally (documenting widespread lack of information and opinions about politics)
    • See generally Angus Campbell et al., The American Voter (1960) (documenting widespread lack of information and opinions about politics);
    • (1960) The American Voter
    • Campbell, A.1
  • 69
    • 0004052835 scopus 로고
    • (explaining that there is "an unresolvable tension between logicality and fairness" that prevents discovery of a true majority preference through electoral voting mechanisms)
    • see also William H. Riker, Liberalism Against Populism: A Confrontation Between the Theory of Democracy and the Theory of Social Choice 136 (1982) (explaining that there is "an unresolvable tension between logicality and fairness" that prevents discovery of a true majority preference through electoral voting mechanisms);
    • (1982) Liberalism Against Populism: A Confrontation between the Theory of Democracy and the Theory of Social Choice , pp. 136
    • Riker, W.H.1
  • 70
    • 84936823866 scopus 로고
    • (finding that public opinion is created by officials and elites rather than preexisting in voters)
    • John R. Zaller, The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion 311-13 (1992) (finding that public opinion is created by officials and elites rather than preexisting in voters).
    • (1992) The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion , pp. 311-313
    • Zaller, J.R.1
  • 71
    • 31344440815 scopus 로고
    • The control of politicians: An economic model
    • Seminal contributions to the literature on agency problems in politics include 22-26 (explaining that, in the absence of electoral consequences, a politician will seek to maximize his own utility)
    • Seminal contributions to the literature on agency problems in politics include Robert J. Barro, The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model, 14 Pub. Choice 19, 22-26 (1973) (explaining that, in the absence of electoral consequences, a politician will seek to maximize his own utility),
    • (1973) Pub. Choice , vol.14 , pp. 19
    • Barro, R.J.1
  • 72
    • 34248428827 scopus 로고
    • Incumbent performance and electoral control
    • 5-9 (arguing that voters should pay more attention to actual performance than to campaign promises and presenting a model in which voters have an incentive to do so)
    • and John Ferejohn, Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control, 50 Pub. Choice 5, 5-9 (1986) (arguing that voters should pay more attention to actual performance than to campaign promises and presenting a model in which voters have an incentive to do so).
    • (1986) Pub. Choice , vol.50 , pp. 5
    • Ferejohn, J.1
  • 73
    • 0010844853 scopus 로고
    • Can inattentive citizens control their elected representatives?
    • Lawrence C. Dodd & Bruce I. Oppenheimer eds., 5th ed. (explaining that many citizens have outcome preferences but not policy preferences, and that it is difficult for legislators to know the preferences of their constituencies on many issues unless the preferences are particularly strong)
    • See R. Douglas Arnold, Can Inattentive Citizens Control Their Elected Representatives?, in Congress Reconsidered 401, 402-06 (Lawrence C. Dodd & Bruce I. Oppenheimer eds., 5th ed. 1993) (explaining that many citizens have outcome preferences but not policy preferences, and that it is difficult for legislators to know the preferences of their constituencies on many issues unless the preferences are particularly strong);
    • (1993) Congress Reconsidered , vol.401 , pp. 402-406
    • Arnold, R.D.1
  • 74
    • 0004157554 scopus 로고
    • (explaining that decision-makers must select only part of the total available information, biasing the information gathered)
    • Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy 219 (1957) (explaining that decision-makers must select only part of the total available information, biasing the information gathered);
    • (1957) An Economic Theory of Democracy , pp. 219
    • Downs, A.1
  • 75
    • 0003651248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (noting that one of the "central dilemmas of delegation" is that agents and principals often do not have common interests)
    • Arthur Lupia & Mathew D. McCubbins, The Democratic Dilemma: Can Citizens Learn What They Need to Know? 79 (1998) (noting that one of the "central dilemmas of delegation" is that agents and principals often do not have common interests).
    • (1998) The Democratic Dilemma: Can Citizens Learn What They Need to Know? , pp. 79
    • Lupia, A.1    McCubbins, M.D.2
  • 77
    • 0001887423 scopus 로고
    • Political resource allocation
    • 27-28 ("When the setter has monopoly power, voters are forced to choose between the setter's proposal and the status quo or fall-back position."). So long as representatives propose a new policy that is far from voter preferences, but less far than the status quo ante, voters may not be able to obtain desired policy outcomes
    • See Thomas Romer & Howard Rosenthal, Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo, 33 Pub. Choice 27, 27-28 (1978) ("When the setter has monopoly power, voters are forced to choose between the setter's proposal and the status quo or fall-back position."). So long as representatives propose a new policy that is far from voter preferences, but less far than the status quo ante, voters may not be able to obtain desired policy outcomes.
    • (1978) Pub. Choice , vol.33 , pp. 27
    • Romer, T.1    Rosenthal, H.2    Agendas, C.3    Quo, T.S.4
  • 78
    • 0011913013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal retention in agency problems
    • 294 (explaining that "the threat of dismissal... may itself be a powerful tool available to the principal")
    • Jeffrey S. Banks & Rangarajan K. Sundaram, Optimal Retention in Agency Problems, 82 J. Econ. Theory 293, 294 (1998) (explaining that "the threat of dismissal... may itself be a powerful tool available to the principal");
    • (1998) J. Econ. Theory , vol.82 , pp. 293
    • Banks, J.S.1    Sundaram, R.K.2
  • 79
    • 25144458584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reputational dynamics and political careers
    • see also Scott Ashworth, Reputational Dynamics and Political Careers, 21 J.L. Econ. & Org. 441 (2005);
    • (2005) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.21 , pp. 441
    • Ashworth, S.1
  • 80
    • 54549085651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral selection, strategic challenger entry, and the incumbency advantage
    • Scott Ashworth & Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, Electoral Selection, Strategic Challenger Entry, and the Incumbency Advantage, 70 J. Pol. 1006 (2008);
    • (2008) J. Pol. , vol.70 , pp. 1006
    • Ashworth, S.1    De Mesquita, E.B.2
  • 81
    • 0035534478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leadership and pandering: A theory of executive policymaking
    • Brandice Canes-Wrone, Michael C. Herron & Kenneth W. Shotts, Leadership and Pandering: A Theory of Executive Policymaking, 45 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 532 (2001).
    • (2001) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.45 , pp. 532
    • Brandice, C.-W.1    Herron, M.C.2    Shotts, K.W.3
  • 82
    • 0002322389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral accountability and the control of politicians: Selecting good types versus sanctioning poor performance
    • Adam Przeworski, Susan C. Stokes & Bernard Manin eds., (suggesting that, while elections serve both selection and sanctioning purposes, voters may be reasonable to focus more on using elections as a method of selecting good candidates rather than as a sanctioning mechanism)
    • James D. Fearon, Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance, in Democracy, Accountability, and Representation 55, 82 (Adam Przeworski, Susan C. Stokes & Bernard Manin eds., 1999) (suggesting that, while elections serve both selection and sanctioning purposes, voters may be reasonable to focus more on using elections as a method of selecting good candidates rather than as a sanctioning mechanism);
    • (1999) Democracy, Accountability, and Representation , vol.55 , pp. 82
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 83
    • 33645159291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Delivering the goods: Legislative particularism in different electoral and institutional settings
    • 168-69 (explaining that, all else being equal, voters prefer high-ability representatives)
    • Scott Ashworth & Ethan Bueno de Mesquita, Delivering the Goods: Legislative Particularism in Different Electoral and Institutional Settings, 68 J. Pol. 168, 168-69 (2006) (explaining that, all else being equal, voters prefer high-ability representatives);
    • (2006) J. Pol. , vol.68 , pp. 168
    • Ashworth, S.1    De Mesquita, E.B.2
  • 84
    • 35348860948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Challenger entry and voter learning
    • (developing a model to explain how challenger entry can convey valuable information to voters about the relative merits of the candidates)
    • Sanford C. Gordon, Gregory A. Huber & Dimitri Landa, Challenger Entry and Voter Learning, 101 Am. Pol. Sei. Rev. 303 (2007) (developing a model to explain how challenger entry can convey valuable information to voters about the relative merits of the candidates);
    • (2007) Am. Pol. Sei. Rev. , vol.101 , pp. 303
    • Gordon, S.C.1    Huber, G.A.2    Landa, D.3
  • 85
    • 37049034712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral design and voter welfare from the US senate: Evidence from a dynamic selection model
    • (modeling voters as "identical dynamically optimizing agents" and finding that quality differences in candidates is one of two factors contributing to the incumbency advantage)2,15
    • Gautam Gowrisankaran, Matthew F. Mitchell & Andrea Moro, Electoral Design and Voter Welfare from the US Senate: Evidence from a Dynamic Selection Model, 11 Rev. Econ. Dynamics 1, 2,15 (2008) (modeling voters as "identical dynamically optimizing agents" and finding that quality differences in candidates is one of two factors contributing to the incumbency advantage).
    • (2008) Rev. Econ. Dynamics , vol.11 , pp. 1
    • Gowrisankaran, G.1    Mitchell, M.F.2    Moro, A.3
  • 86
  • 87
    • 77952068357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barro, supra note 30, at 26-32
    • Barro, supra note 30, at 26-32;
  • 88
    • 77952078794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ferejohn, supra note 30, at 22-23
    • Ferejohn, supra note 30, at 22-23;
  • 89
    • 0006037416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Separation of powers and political accountability
    • 1165-66
    • Torsten Persson, Gérard Roland & Guido Tabellini, Separation of Powers and Political Accountability, 112 Q.J. Econ. 1163, 1165-66 (1997);
    • (1997) Q.J. Econ. , vol.112 , pp. 1163
    • Persson, T.1    Roland, G.2    Tabellini, G.3
  • 90
    • 0029849418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accountability and decentralisation in government: An incomplete contracts model
    • , 64-65
    • Paul Seabright, Accountability and Decentralisation in Government: An Incomplete Contracts Model, 40 Eur. Econ. Rev. 61, 64-65 (1996).
    • (1996) Eur. Econ. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 61
    • Seabright, P.1
  • 91
    • 77952075144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sartori, supra note 8, at 27-39
    • Sartori, supra note 8, at 27-39;
  • 92
    • 76649132677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Complementary constraints: Separation of powers, rational voting, and constitutional design
    • 5-7
    • Jide O. Nzelibe & Matthew C. Stephenson, Complementary Constraints: Separation of Powers, Rational Voting, and Constitutional Design, 123 Harv. L. Rev. 1, 5-7 (2010);
    • (2010) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.123 , pp. 1
    • Nzelibe, J.O.1    Stephenson, M.C.2
  • 94
    • 77952049694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Fearon, supra note 35, at 83 (noting that "voter's incentives to be interested and well informed about politics are far from strong")
    • See, e.g., Fearon, supra note 35, at 83 (noting that "voter's incentives to be interested and well informed about politics are far from strong").
  • 95
    • 77952026604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 59 (defining a "good type" politician)
    • Id. at 59 (defining a "good type" politician).
  • 96
    • 0003626071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Robert D. Cooter, The Strategic Constitution 158-60 (2000) (comparing the consequences for the agent when the principals exercise oversight unilaterally versus cooperatively). The logic of issue unbundling has been applied sporadically in other settings. This same theme is at play in the scattered assortment of justifications given for single-subject limitations in state constitutions, for instance, in Colorado and Florida.
    • (2000) The Strategic Constitution , pp. 158-160
    • Cooter, R.D.1
  • 97
    • 0041335296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State constitutional restrictions on legislative procedure: Rethinking the analysis of original purpose, single subject, and clear title challenges
    • 114-16
    • Martha J. Dragich, State Constitutional Restrictions on Legislative Procedure: Rethinking the Analysis of Original Purpose, Single Subject, and Clear Title Challenges, 38 Harv. J. on Legis. 103, 114-16 (2001) (explaining'the purpose of single-subject limitations in state constitutions);
    • (2001) Harv. J. on Legis. , vol.38 , pp. 103
    • Dragich, M.J.1
  • 98
    • 33751020843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Single subject rules and the legislative process
    • 813-18
    • Michael D. Gilbert, Single Subject Rules and the Legislative Process, 67 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 803, 813-18 (2006) (setting forth the history of and principal justifications for the single-subject rule);
    • (2006) U. Pitt. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 803
    • Gilbert, M.D.1
  • 99
    • 77952048289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berkeley Program in Law & Econ., Working Paper No. 15
    • Robert D. Cooter & Michael D. Gilbert, Chaos, Direct Democracy, and the Single Subject Rule 5,11 (Berkeley Program in Law & Econ., Working Paper No. 15, 2006), available at http://escholarship.org/uc/item/9xm920bv (explaining that stronger single-subject rules "could improve direct democracy by preventing cycling and riders"). The singlesubject limitation is supposed to preclude logrolls in which policies favored only by a minority of politicians or voters are enacted together. The logic of unbundling, then, is general. In the single-subject context, logrolls could easily be welfare-enhancing so long as the value to the minority receiving benefits along each dimension is high enough. The point is merely that the idea of unbundling has been usefully applied in a handful of other legal and policy contexts.
    • (2006) Chaos, Direct Democracy, and the Single Subject Rule , vol.5 , pp. 11
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Gilbert, M.D.2
  • 101
    • 0029484659 scopus 로고
    • Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: Evidence from the last 30 years
    • 590
    • The unbundling intuition has also been used to explain one of the benefits of citizen initiatives. See John G. Matsusaka, Fiscal Effects of the Voter Initiative: Evidence from the Last 30 Years, 103 J. Pol. Econ. 587, 590 (1995) (explaining that the use of voter initiatives correlates to lower levels of state spending).
    • (1995) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.103 , pp. 587
    • Matsusaka, J.G.1
  • 102
    • 57549112021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Apr. unpublished manuscript
    • For an extension of the implications of the direct democracy argument for the executive branch, see John G. Matsusaka, Direct Democracy and the Executive Branch 23-24 (Apr. 2007) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www-rcf.usc.edu/~matsusak/Papers /Matsusaka -DD-Executive-2007.pdf) (explaining that direct democracy changes the executive branch by allowing policy decisions on some issues to be made by citizens directly and by altering the institutional structure of the executive branch). By unbundling a single issue from a legislative logroll, whether budgetary or policy, voters are thought to be able to better ensure outcomes close to majoritarian preferences for the given policy dimension.
    • (2007) Direct Democracy and the Executive Branch , pp. 23-24
    • Matsusaka, J.G.1
  • 103
    • 77952030352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 24
    • See id. at 24.
  • 104
    • 77952043030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berry & Gersen, supra note 14, at 1401-1421
    • Berry & Gersen, supra note 14, at 1401-1421
  • 105
    • 77952069521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 23
    • For example, one paper provides empirical support for the issue unbundling argument by contrasting elected and appointed utility regulators. See Besley & Coate, Elected versus Appointed Regulators, supra note 23, at 1178-80. Using panel data for forty U.S. states, the authors find that elected regulators systematically enact more consumer-friendly policies than appointed regulators.
    • Elected Versus Appointed Regulators , pp. 1178-1180
    • Besley1    Coate2
  • 106
    • 77952023553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1177-1178
    • See id. at 1177-1178
  • 107
    • 0001197145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Incentives, information, and organizational form
    • 360
    • Eric Maskin, Yingyi Qian & Chenggang Xu, Incentives, Information, and Organizational Form, 67 Rev. Econ. Stud. 359, 360 (2000).
    • (2000) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.67 , pp. 359
    • Maskin, E.1    Qian, Y.2    Xu, C.3
  • 110
    • 77952087223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maskin, Qian & Xu, supra note 45, at 360
    • Maskin, Qian & Xu, supra note 45, at 360.
  • 111
    • 77952078005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id
    • See id.
  • 112
    • 77952033463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 363
    • See id. at 363.
  • 113
    • 77952083029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Williamson, supra note 46, at 117
    • Williamson, supra note 46, at 117.
  • 114
    • 77952032272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maskin, Qian & Xu, supra note 45, at 360
    • See Maskin, Qian & Xu, supra note 45, at 360.
  • 115
    • 77952017942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Williamson, supra note 46, at 113-114
    • Williamson, supra note 46, at 113-114 (expressing the difficulties of the U-form enterprise in terms of "indecomposability, incommensurability, nonoperational goal specification, and the confounding of strategic and operating decisions").
  • 116
    • 33646460265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coordination and experimentation in M-form and U-form organizations
    • See generally Yingyi Qian, Gérard Roland & Chenggang Xu, Coordination and Experimentation in M-Form and U-Form Organizations, 114 J. Pol. Econ. 366 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.114 , pp. 366
    • Qian, Y.1    Roland, G.2    Xu, C.3
  • 117
    • 77952064306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Williamson, supra note 46, at 113-14
    • Williamson, supra note 46, at 113-14.
  • 118
    • 77952035214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 115
    • The conventional account of the M-form is that it removes the burden of operational decisions and the need for coordination from top-level executives by delegating those decisions to more distinct divisions, "[e]ach ... having complete jurisdiction over manufacture, sales, and finance, subject to control from the central authority." Id. at 115
  • 119
    • 0040786687 scopus 로고
    • Pricing policy in relation to financial control
    • (quoting Donaldson Brown, Pricing Policy in Relation to Financial Control, 7 Mgmt. & Admin. 195 (1924)).
    • (1924) Mgmt. & Admin. , vol.7 , pp. 195
    • Brown, D.1
  • 120
    • 77952060151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Qian, Roland & Xu, supra note 53, at 367-368
    • Qian, Roland & Xu, supra note 53, at 367-368
  • 121
    • 77952040112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 367
    • Id. at 367.
  • 122
    • 77952071558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 369
    • Id. at 369.
  • 123
    • 77952054911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 370
    • The M-form also generally outperforms the U-form structure in terms of innovation and experimentation because the M-form can experiment in a distinct division before adopting changes firm-wide. "[S]mall-scale experimentation in the Uform is always dominated by full-scale experimentation because the former creates complications in attribute matching." Id. at 370.
  • 124
    • 77952042234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 369
    • Suppose one wanted to see whether internal separation of functions facilitated government performance. In the current U.S. regime, that is all but impossible. Functions are combined or not, system-wide. In the unbundled structure, several different institutions exercise policy-making authority for one and only one policy domain. One branch could separate executive authority for that domain from legislative authority for that domain. Another branch could continue to operate with such powers combined. Experimentation of this sort would be imperfect because it would be impossible to compare environmental policy established using separation with environmental policy established not using separation. Nevertheless, at least some experimentation is possible without adopting system-wide changes. The U-form must innovate in total or not at all. Id. at 369.
  • 125
    • 77952080682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redish, supra note 12, at 99-134
    • Today this idea is mainly represented by the formalist school in separation of powers scholarship. See, e.g., Redish, supra note 12, at 99-134;
  • 126
    • 84928448935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The distribution of powers after bowsher
    • 40
    • David P. Currie, The Distribution of Powers After Bowsher, 1986 Sup. Ct. Rev. 19, 40;
    • Sup. Ct. Rev. , vol.1986 , pp. 19
    • Currie, D.P.1
  • 127
    • 0042578750 scopus 로고
    • The rise and rise of the administrative state
    • 1248
    • Gary Lawson, The Rise and Rise of the Administrative State, 107 Harv. L. Rev. 1231, 1248 (1994).
    • (1994) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1231
    • Lawson, G.1
  • 128
    • 77952040980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For simplicity's sake, judicial authority is included with executive and legislative authority, but much of the theoretical argument applies with greatest force to legislative and executive authority
    • For simplicity's sake, judicial authority is included with executive and legislative authority, but much of the theoretical argument applies with greatest force to legislative and executive authority.
  • 129
    • 33749182513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Internal separation of Powers: Checking today's most dangerous branch from within
    • explaining how internal separation of powers can check the overall authority of the executive branch
    • See generally Neal Kumar Katyal, Internal Separation of Powers: Checking Today's Most Dangerous Branch from Within, 115 Yale L.J. 2314 (2006) (explaining how internal separation of powers can check the overall authority of the executive branch);
    • (2006) Yale L.J. , vol.115 , pp. 2314
    • Katyal, N.K.1
  • 130
    • 0035528298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond powers and branches in separation of powers law
    • 605-06 arguing that existing diffusion of power within branches sufficiently checks excessive concentrations of authority
    • M. Elizabeth Magill, Beyond Powers and Branches in Separation of Powers Law, 150 U. Pa. L. Rev. 603, 605-06 (2001) (arguing that existing diffusion of power within branches sufficiently checks excessive concentrations of authority).
    • (2001) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.150 , pp. 603
    • Elizabeth Magill, M.1
  • 131
    • 77952028748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Strauss, supra note 13, at 581-583
    • See Strauss, supra note 13, at 581-583
  • 132
    • 77952028363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5 U.S.C. §554(d) 2006
    • -5 U.S.C. §554(d) (2006).
  • 134
    • 84924455634 scopus 로고
    • Separation of functions in administrative agencies
    • 612-14
    • Kenneth Culp Davis, Separation of Functions in Administrative Agencies, 61 Harv. L. Rev. 612, 612-14 (1948).
    • (1948) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 612
    • Davis, K.C.1
  • 136
    • 79956070175 scopus 로고
    • Due process and the administrative state
    • 1109
    • Edward L. Rubin, Due Process and the Administrative State, 72 Cal. L. Rev. 1044, 1109 (1984).
    • (1984) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 1044
    • Rubin, E.L.1
  • 137
    • 77952085992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Section II.F.
    • See infra Section II.F.
  • 138
    • 77952012527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 139
    • 77952033457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If this alternative looks too radical, executive authority for a single policy domain could be parceled off, consistent with a separated and partially unbundled office
    • If this alternative looks too radical, executive authority for a single policy domain could be parceled off, consistent with a separated and partially unbundled office.
  • 140
    • 77952024965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Berry & Gersen, supra note 14, at 1386 arguing that "a partially unbundled executive is likely to perform better than the completely bundled executive structure attendant in the single executive regime
    • See Berry & Gersen, supra note 14, at 1386 (arguing that "a partially unbundled executive is likely to perform better than the completely bundled executive structure attendant in the single executive regime").
  • 142
    • 33845989462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clarity of responsibility and corruption
    • 219-21
    • Margit Tavits, Clarity of Responsibility and Corruption, 51 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 218, 219-21 (2007);
    • (2007) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.51 , pp. 218
    • Tavits, M.1
  • 143
    • 77952058459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sept. 25, unpublished manuscript The idea of institutional clarity has been a core part of the debate between presidentialists and parliamentarists for at least a century. It was at the root of the critiques of presidentialism
    • Ethan Bueno de Mesquita & Dimitri Landa, Transparency and Clarity of Responsibility 1-2 (Sept. 25, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://cas.uchicago.edu/workshops/cpoht/papers/ EBDM-f2007.pdf). The idea of institutional clarity has been a core part of the debate between presidentialists and parliamentarists for at least a century. It was at the root of the critiques of presidentialism.
    • (2007) Transparency and Clarity of Responsibility , pp. 1-2
    • De Mesquita, E.B.1    Landa, D.2
  • 144
    • 77952059240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bagehot, supra note 8, at 200-203
    • See Bagehot, supra note 8, at 200-203
  • 145
    • 77952027414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Powell, supra note 67, at 50-52
    • See Powell, supra note 67, at 50-52.
  • 146
    • 36949038805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Electoral accountability and the variety of democratic regimes
    • More recently, scholars have argued that other sub-institutional conditions affect this calculus as well, such as "majority/minority status of the government, party cohesion, opposition committee chairs and opposition control of upper chambers in systems with strong bicameralism 69
    • More recently, scholars have argued that other sub-institutional conditions affect this calculus as well, such as "majority/minority status of the government, party cohesion, opposition committee chairs and opposition control of upper chambers in systems with strong bicameralism." Timothy Hellwig & David Samuels, Electoral Accountability and the Variety of Democratic Regimes, 38 Brit. J. Pol. Sci. 65, 69 (2008);
    • (2008) Brit. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.38 , pp. 65
    • Hellwig, T.1    Samuels, D.2
  • 147
    • 0011088492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democracy, elections, and accountability for economic outcomes
    • supra note 35, 230
    • see also José Antonio Cheibub & Adam Przeworski, Democracy, Elections, and Accountability for Economic Outcomes, in Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, supra note 35, at 222, 230.
    • Democracy, Accountability, and Representation , pp. 222
    • Cheibub, J.A.1    Przeworski, A.2
  • 148
    • 0142168530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who's responsible for the economy? the formation and consequences of responsibility attributions
    • See Hellwig & Samuels, supra note 68, at 68 (distinguishing "voters' ability to assign responsibility from their ability to use the vote to act on the basis of that assignment") emphasis omitted examining voters' attribution of responsibility for the economy between the President and Congress
    • See Hellwig & Samuels, supra note 68, at 68 (distinguishing "voters' ability to assign responsibility from their ability to use the vote to act on the basis of that assignment") (emphasis omitted); Thomas J. Rudolph, Who's Responsible for the Economy? The Formation and Consequences of Responsibility Attributions, 47 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 698 (2003) (examining voters' attribution of responsibility for the economy between the President and Congress).
    • (2003) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.47 , pp. 698
    • Rudolph, T.J.1
  • 149
    • 77952073265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Compare Persson, Roland & Tabellini, supra note 36, at 1166 (arguing that separation of powers between the legislature and executive improves accountability, but only when neither body can act unilaterally), with Stephenson & Nzelibe, supra note 37, at 3 (finding that, under certain circumstances, voters are better off if the executive retains the option of acting unilaterally because they can implement a more refined set of political incentives). Relevant institutional variables might include "separate executive and legislative elections, variation in the electoral cycle for executive and legislative elections, and the possibility of cohabitation in semi-presidential systems." Hellwig & Samuels, supra note 68, at 68. In pure presidential regimes, voters directly elect the executive and the legislature separately for fixed terms. Id. at 69;
  • 150
    • 77952029544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Powell, supra note 67, at 57-58 observing that, despite having a separate base of election, the chief executive cannot pass new legislation without negotiating with the opposition party in the legislature
    • see also Powell, supra note 67, at 57-58 (observing that, despite having a separate base of election, the chief executive cannot pass new legislation without negotiating with the opposition party in the legislature);
  • 151
    • 69249129841 scopus 로고
    • The perils of presidentialism
    • 52 (comparing parliamentary and presidential regimes and concluding that parliamentarianism is more conducive to stable democracy). In semipresidential systems, the President is elected for a fixed term, but the legislature is not
    • Juan J. Linz, The Perils of Presidentialism, 1 J. Democracy 51, 52 (1990) (comparing parliamentary and presidential regimes and concluding that parliamentarianism is more conducive to stable democracy). In semipresidential systems, the President is elected for a fixed term, but the legislature is not.
    • (1990) J. Democracy , vol.1 , pp. 51
    • Linz, J.J.1
  • 153
    • 0012269113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The politics of semi-presidentialism
    • Robert Elgie ed., (establishing a framework for studying the politics of semi-presidential regimes). Concurrent legislative and executive elections may also enhance incentive effects because both branches may be held accountable in any given election. Hellwig & Samuels, supra note 68, at 70;
    • See generally Robert Elgie, The Politics of Semi-Presidentialism, inSemiPresidentialism in Europe 1 (Robert Elgie ed., 1999) (establishing a framework for studying the politics of semi-presidential regimes). Concurrent legislative and executive elections may also enhance incentive effects because both branches may be held accountable in any given election. Hellwig & Samuels, supra note 68, at 70;
    • (1999) SemiPresidentialism in Europe , vol.1
    • Elgie, R.1
  • 154
    • 4644254607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidentialism and accountability for the economy in comparative perspective
    • 427
    • David Samuels, Presidentialism and Accountability for the Economy in Comparative Perspective, 98 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 425, 427 (2004);
    • (2004) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 425
    • Samuels, D.1
  • 155
    • 84974284436 scopus 로고
    • The electoral cycle and institutional sources of divided presidential government
    • 328 (finding that concurrent elections rarely result in divided government).
    • cf. Matthew Soberg Shugart, The Electoral Cycle and Institutional Sources of Divided Presidential Government, 89 Am. Pol. Sei. Rev. 327, 328 (1995) (finding that concurrent elections rarely result in divided government).
    • (1995) Am. Pol. Sei. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 327
    • Shugart, M.S.1
  • 156
    • 77952059772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Powell, supra note 67, at 51. In fact, studies on economic voting normally assume that voters are rational, have complete information, use all of this information when voting, and vote retrospectively.
    • See Powell, supra note 67, at 51. In fact, studies on economic voting normally assume that voters are rational, have complete information, use all of this information when voting, and vote retrospectively.
  • 158
    • 84926201963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poland, Hungary, Slovakia, and the Czech Republic 1990-99
    • Joshua A. Tucker, Regional Economic Voting: Russia, Poland, Hungary, Slovakia, and the Czech Republic, 1990-99, at 338-42 (2006);
    • (2006) Regional Economic Voting: Russia , pp. 338-342
    • Tucker, J.A.1
  • 159
    • 0031428925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From argentina to zambia: A worldwide test of economic voting
    • 302-03
    • Sam Wilkin, Brandon Haller & Helmut Norpoth, From Argentina to Zambia: a WorldWide Test of Economic Voting, 16 Electoral Stud. 301, 302-03 (1997).
    • (1997) Electoral Stud. , vol.16 , pp. 301
    • Wilkin, S.1    Haller, B.2    Norpoth, H.3
  • 161
    • 0000139690 scopus 로고
    • Moral hazard in teams
    • See generally Bengt Holmstrom, Moral Hazard in Teams, 13 Bell J. Econ. 324 (1982).
    • (1982) Bell J. Econ. , vol.13 , pp. 324
    • Holmstrom, B.1
  • 162
    • 77952018925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The study of team production occupies an enormous body of literature, and conclusions about moral hazard and adverse selection depend critically on settings and assumptions. The idea in the text, and alluded to throughout, is one of the possible problems associated with such a structure. For a general, albeit technical, overview
    • The study of team production occupies an enormous body of literature, and conclusions about moral hazard and adverse selection depend critically on settings and assumptions. The idea in the text, and alluded to throughout, is one of the possible problems associated with such a structure. For a general, albeit technical, overview,
  • 164
    • 77952019306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Vile, supra note 1
    • See generally Vile, supra note 1;
  • 165
    • 77952080866 scopus 로고
    • Essay, separation of powers and federalism: Their impact on individual liberty and the functioning of our government
    • 640
    • Candace H. Beckett, Essay, Separation of Powers and Federalism: Their Impact on Individual Liberty and the Functioning of Our Government, 29 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 635, 640 (1988);
    • (1988) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.29 , pp. 635
    • Beckett, C.H.1
  • 166
    • 0348195773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accountability, liberty, and the constitution
    • 535 (discussing the link between separation of powers and protection of liberty).
    • Rebecca L. Brown, Accountability, Liberty, and the Constitution, 98 Colum. L. Rev. 531, 535 (1998) (discussing the link between separation of powers and protection of liberty).
    • (1998) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 531
    • Brown, R.L.1
  • 167
    • 77952072852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federalist No. 47, at 326 (James Madison) Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961
    • The Federalist No. 47, at 326 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961).
  • 168
    • 77952085718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. quoting Montesquieu, supra note 2
    • Id. (quoting Montesquieu, supra note 2).
  • 169
    • 77952067081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Casper, supra note 1, at 9-10
    • See generally Casper, supra note 1, at 9-10.
  • 170
    • 77952079596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Magill, supra note 1, at 1191-94
    • See Magill, supra note 1, at 1191-94;
  • 171
    • 27844598991 scopus 로고
    • The contemporary debate about legislative-executive separation of powers
    • 449-454
    • Thomas O. Sargentich, The Contemporary Debate About Legislative-Executive Separation of Powers, 72 Cornell L. Rev. 430, 449-454 (1987).
    • (1987) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 430
    • Sargentich, T.O.1
  • 173
    • 77952074112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Magill, supra note 60, at 603-606
    • See, e.g., Magill, supra note 60, at 603-606
  • 174
    • 77952071130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rakové, supra note 1, at 282 ("Federalist 51 does not so much explain how these ambitions will work as assume that differences in election and tenure among the branches will foster the desired attachment...."); Magill, supra note 1, at 1128-1132
    • See Rakové, supra note 1, at 282 ("Federalist 51 does not so much explain how these ambitions will work as assume that differences in election and tenure among the branches will foster the desired attachment...."); Magill, supra note 1, at 1128-1132
  • 175
    • 77952080680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rakove, supra note 1, at 282; see also Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2317
    • See Rakove, supra note 1, at 282; see also Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2317.
  • 176
    • 77952021232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This line of attack was explicitly addressed by Madison in The Federalist No. 47, and these ideas have been replicated many times over in the commentary
    • This line of attack was explicitly addressed by Madison in The Federalist No. 47, and these ideas have been replicated many times over in the commentary.
  • 177
    • 77952089130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See The Federalist No. 47, at 323 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961) "One of the principal objections inculcated by the more respectable adversaries to the constitution, is its supposed violation of the political maxim, that the legislative, executive and judiciary departments ought to be separate and distinct. In the structure of the federal government, no regard, it is said, seems to have been paid to this essential precaution in favor of liberty
    • See The Federalist No. 47, at 323 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961) ("One of the principal objections inculcated by the more respectable adversaries to the constitution, is its supposed violation of the political maxim, that the legislative, executive and judiciary departments ought to be separate and distinct. In the structure of the federal government, no regard, it is said, seems to have been paid to this essential precaution in favor of liberty.").
  • 178
    • 77952026601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2317-2319
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2317-2319
  • 179
    • 77952019307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2319
    • Id. at 2319.
  • 180
    • 77952071560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another gloss on the same underlying ideas would be that there are agency problems between branch interests and the officials that administer policy within a branch. Sometimes these problems will be slight; other times, severe.
    • Another gloss on the same underlying ideas would be that there are agency problems between branch interests and the officials that administer policy within a branch. Sometimes these problems will be slight; other times, severe.
  • 181
    • 77952056098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 689
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 689.
  • 182
    • 77952037313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 531 U.S. 457 2001
    • -531 U.S. 457 (2001).
  • 183
    • 11244336654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking article i, section 1: from nondelegation to exclusive delegation
    • (arguing that exclusive delegation is superior to the nondelegation doctrine)
    • See, e.g., Thomas W. Merrill, Rethinking Article I, Section 1: From Nondelegation to Exclusive Delegation, 104 Colum. L. Rev. 2097 (2004) (arguing that exclusive delegation is superior to the nondelegation doctrine);
    • (2004) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.104 , pp. 2097
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 184
    • 0036766708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interring the nondelegation doctrine
    • 1723 (arguing that there is no constitutional delegation rule because "[a] statutory grant of authority to the executive isn't a transfer of legislative power, but an exercise of legislative power") emphasis omitted
    • Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Interring the Nondelegation Doctrine, 69 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1721, 1723 (2002) (arguing that there is no constitutional delegation rule because "[a] statutory grant of authority to the executive isn't a transfer of legislative power, but an exercise of legislative power") (emphasis omitted).
    • (2002) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 1721
    • Posner, E.A.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 185
    • 77952087910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 531 U.S
    • American Trucking, 531 U.S. at 473-474
    • American Trucking , pp. 473-474
  • 186
    • 77952014923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 475 (internal citations omitted)
    • Id. at 475 (internal citations omitted);
  • 187
    • 77950477830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 517 U.S. 748, 772-73 (upholding the delegation to the President of authority to define aggravating factors for murder cases tried in military court)
    • see also Loving v. United States, 517 U.S. 748, 772-73 (1996) (upholding the delegation to the President of authority to define aggravating factors for murder cases tried in military court);
    • (1996) Loving V. United States
  • 188
    • 0038421546 scopus 로고
    • 419 U.S. 544, 556-57 (upholding the delegation to tribal authorities of power to regulate alcohol sales on reservations)
    • United States v. Mazurie, 419 U.S. 544, 556-57 (1975) (upholding the delegation to tribal authorities of power to regulate alcohol sales on reservations).
    • (1975) United States V. Mazurie
  • 189
    • 77952068356 scopus 로고
    • 272 U.S. 52, 293 (Brandeis, J., dissenting) ("The doctrine of the separation of powers was adopted by the Convention of 1787, not to promote efficiency but to preclude the exercise of arbitrary power.")
    • See, e.g., Myers v. United States, 272 U.S. 52, 293 (1926) (Brandeis, J., dissenting) ("The doctrine of the separation of powers was adopted by the Convention of 1787, not to promote efficiency but to preclude the exercise of arbitrary power.").
    • (1926) Myers V. United States
  • 190
    • 77952038961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Const, art. I, §7
    • See U.S. Const, art. I, §7;
  • 192
    • 59349094667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The price of public action: Constitutional doctrine and the judicial manipulation of legislative enactment costs
    • For a general discussion of legislative enactment costs, see Matthew C. Stephenson, The Price of Public Action: Constitutional Doctrine and the Judicial Manipulation of Legislative Enactment Costs, 118 Yale L.J. 2 (2008).
    • (2008) Yale L.J. , vol.118 , pp. 2
    • Stephenson, M.C.1
  • 193
    • 77952077226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Const, art. I, §7
    • See U.S. Const, art. I, §7;
  • 194
    • 0039540523 scopus 로고
    • The article i, section 7 game
    • (providing a positive model of bicameralism and presentment)
    • See, e.g., William N. Eskridge & John Ferejohn, The Article I, Section 7 Game, 80 Geo. L.J. 523 (1992) (providing a positive model of bicameralism and presentment);
    • (1992) Geo. L.J. , vol.80 , pp. 523
    • Eskridge, W.N.1    Ferejohn, J.2
  • 195
    • 0000388293 scopus 로고
    • Bicameralism: When are two decisions better than one?
    • (providing a positive account of bicameralism)
    • Saul Levmore, Bicameralism: When Are Two Decisions Better than One?, 12 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 145 (1992) (providing a positive account of bicameralism).
    • (1992) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 145
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 196
    • 77952061751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2338
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2338;
  • 197
    • 77952084943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • , supra note 75, at 570
    • see, e.g., Brown, supra note 75, at 570;
  • 198
    • 33846378591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The virtues of presidential government: Why professor ackerman is wrong to prefer the german to the U.S. constitution
    • 56
    • Steven G. Calabresi, The Virtues of Presidential Government: Why Professor Ackerman is Wrong to Prefer the German to the U.S. Constitution, 18 Const. Comment. 51, 56 (2001);
    • (2001) Const. Comment. , vol.18 , pp. 51
    • Calabresi, S.G.1
  • 199
    • 2342616834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reexamining marbury in the administrative state: A structural and institutional defense of judicial power over statutory interpretation
    • 1246
    • Jonathan T. Molot, Reexamining Marbury in the Administrative State: A Structural and Institutional Defense of Judicial Power over Statutory Interpretation, 96 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1239, 1246 (2002).
    • (2002) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1239
    • Molot, J.T.1
  • 200
    • 2942520961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The constitutional law of congressional procedure
    • 402-410 (discussing justifications for supermajority and submajority voting rules for the legislature that are specified throughout the Constitution)
    • See Adrian Vermeule, The Constitutional Law of Congressional Procedure, 71 U. Chi. L. Rev. 361, 402-410 (2004) (discussing justifications for supermajority and submajority voting rules for the legislature that are specified throughout the Constitution).
    • (2004) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 361
    • Vermeule, A.1
  • 201
    • 33846442002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chevron as a Voting Rule
    • 684-88 (discussing tradeoffs between voting rules and other mecha- nisms). See generally Adrian Vermeule, Mechanisms of Democracy: Institutional Design Writ Small (2007)
    • See Jacob E. Gersen & Adrian Vermeule, Chevron as a Voting Rule, 116 Yale L.J. 676, 684-88 (2007) (discussing tradeoffs between voting rules and other mecha- nisms). See generally Adrian Vermeule, Mechanisms of Democracy: Institutional Design Writ Small (2007).
    • (2007) Yale L.J. , vol.116 , pp. 676
    • Gersen, J.E.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 202
    • 38049132739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Timing rules and legal institutions
    • 574-577 (presenting a framework for analyzing timing rules and contrasting with supermajority voting rules)
    • See Jacob E. Gersen & Eric A. Posner, Timing Rules and Legal Institutions, 121 Harv. L. Rev. 543, 574-577 (2007) (presenting a framework for analyzing timing rules and contrasting with supermajority voting rules).
    • (2007) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.121 , pp. 543
    • Gersen, J.E.1    Posner, E.A.2
  • 203
    • 77952085356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 577
    • Id. at 577.
  • 204
    • 34248355616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Temporary legislation
    • 250 n.7 The idea of temporary factions is featured prominently in The Federalist Papers
    • See generally Jacob E. Gersen, Temporary Legislation, 74 U. Chi. L. Rev. 247, 250 n.7 (2007). The idea of temporary factions is featured prominently in The Federalist Papers.
    • (2007) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 247
    • Gersen, J.E.1
  • 205
    • 77952021645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison argues in The Federalist No.10 that the republican form of government is a partial shield against the willingness of citizens to sacrifice justice on the basis of temporary or partial views. The Federalist No. 10, at 56-57 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961)
    • For example, Madison argues in The Federalist No.10 that the republican form of government is a partial shield against the willingness of citizens to sacrifice justice on the basis of temporary or partial views. The Federalist No. 10, at 56-57 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961).
  • 206
    • 77952054910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Similarly, in The Federalist No. 27, Hamilton draws a parallel between factions and "temporary views." Speaking of representatives, Hamilton notes that they will be less apt to be tainted by the spirit of faction, and more out of the reach of those occasional ill humors or temporary prejudices and propensities, which in smaller societies frequently contaminate the public councils, beget injustice and oppression of a part of the community, and engender schemes, which though they gratify a momentary inclination or desire, terminate in general distress, dissatisfaction and disgust. The Federalist No. 27, at 172 (Alexander Hamilton) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961). Hamilton's concluding remarks in The Federalist No. 85 echo the negative vision of temporary views and temporary factions: "No partial motive, no particular interest, no pride of opinion, no temporary passion or prejudice, will justify to himself, to his country or to his posterity, an improper election of the part he is to act." The Federalist No. 85, at 590 (Alexander Hamilton) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961).
  • 207
    • 77952069921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redish, supra note 12, at 102-105 (discussing the transition from theories of mixed government to separation of powers)
    • See generally Redish, supra note 12, at 102-105 (discussing the transition from theories of mixed government to separation of powers);
  • 209
    • 77952056515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vile, supra note 1, at 23
    • Vile, supra note 1, at 23.
  • 210
    • 77952050085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redish, supra note 12, at 103
    • See Redish, supra note 12, at 103.
  • 211
    • 77952078395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Const., art. I, §7
    • See U.S. Const., art. I, §7.
  • 212
    • 77952050818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 213
    • 33747076145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fable of the nationalist president and the parochial congress
    • 1218
    • See Jide Nzelibe, The Fable of the Nationalist President and the Parochial Congress, 53 UCLA L. Rev. 1217, 1218 (2006).
    • (2006) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 1217
    • Nzelibe, J.1
  • 214
    • 77952036813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1221
    • See id. at 1221.
  • 215
    • 77952024739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2324-2325
    • See Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2324-2325
  • 216
    • 77952080021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vermeule, supra note 98
    • Vermeule, supra note 98.
  • 217
    • 0004242170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2d ed. (noting that the U.S. government has been divided for roughly forty percent of the time between 1832 and 1992)
    • See Morris Fiorina, Divided Government 6-7 (2d ed. 1996) (noting that the U.S. government has been divided for roughly forty percent of the time between 1832 and 1992);
    • (1996) Divided Government , pp. 6-7
    • Fiorina, M.1
  • 218
    • 77952022725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2330-2347 (discussing the implications of unified and divided government)
    • see also Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2330-2347 (discussing the implications of unified and divided government).
  • 219
    • 77952027012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gersen & Vermeule, supra note 98 (discussing parallel dynamics in the context of voting rules and doctrinal norms)
    • Cf. Gersen & Vermeule, supra note 98 (discussing parallel dynamics in the context of voting rules and doctrinal norms).
  • 220
    • 77952039726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The costs of voting rule chevron: A comment on gersen and vermeule's proposal
    • Pocket Part 238
    • But see Matthew C. Stephenson, The Costs of Voting Rule Chevron: A Comment on Gersen and Vermeule's Proposal, 116 Yale L.J. Pocket Part 238 (2007), available at http://thepocketpart.org/2007/01/25/ stephenson.html.
    • (2007) Yale L.J. , vol.116
    • Stephenson, M.C.1
  • 221
    • 77952068765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federalist No. 37, at 233 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961)
    • The Federalist No. 37, at 233 (James Madison) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961).
  • 222
    • 77952055300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federalist No. 70, at 471 (Alexander Hamilton) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961)
    • The Federalist No. 70, at 471 (Alexander Hamilton) (Jacob E. Cooke ed., 1961).
  • 223
    • 77952038959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2325-2326
    • See Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2325-2326
  • 224
    • 77952088334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilson, supra note 6, at 186-187
    • See generally Wilson, supra note 6, at 186-187
  • 225
    • 77952080280 scopus 로고
    • Remarks at the pennsylvania ratifying convention
    • Philip B. Kurland & Ralph Lerner eds.
    • (Dec. 4,1787), James Wilson, Remarks at the Pennsylvania Ratifying Convention (Dec. 4,1787), in 3 The Founders' Constitution 501 (Philip B. Kurland & Ralph Lerner eds., 1987).
    • (1987) The Founders' Constitution , vol.3 , pp. 501
    • Wilson, J.1
  • 226
    • 77952050086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fearon, supra note 35, at 82-83
    • Fearon, supra note 35, at 82-83.
  • 227
    • 77952070358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2343 ("But of course it is a different type of accountability that they have in mind. The existence of checks and balances between rivalrous branches, each with an incentive to monitor and prevent the other's misbehavior, might be regarded as a systemic form of accountability in its own right.")
    • Levinson & Pildes, supra note 1, at 2343 ("But of course it is a different type of accountability that they have in mind. The existence of checks and balances between rivalrous branches, each with an incentive to monitor and prevent the other's misbehavior, might be regarded as a systemic form of accountability in its own right.");
  • 229
    • 77952084558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gwyn, supra note 1, at 16
    • Gwyn, supra note 1, at 16;
  • 230
    • 77952058282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sargentich, supra note 6, at 718
    • Sargentich, supra note 6, at 718.
  • 233
    • 0000508965 scopus 로고
    • Structure and process, politics and policy: Administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies
    • 439 (discussing how agencies can "shift... policy outcome[s] away from the legislative intent")
    • Mathew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll & Barry R. Weingast, Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies, 75 Va. L. Rev. 431, 439 (1989) (discussing how agencies can "shift... policy outcome[s] away from the legislative intent").
    • (1989) Va. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 431
    • McCubbins, M.D.1    Noll, R.G.2    Weingast, B.R.3
  • 234
    • 0002893643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Formal and real authority in organizations
    • 17-18 (analyzing authority delegated to agencies as a function of information distribution)
    • See Philippe Aghion & Jean Tirole, Formal and Real Authority in Organizations, 105 J. Pol. Econ. 1, 17-18 (1997) (analyzing authority delegated to agencies as a function of information distribution);
    • (1997) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.105 , pp. 1
    • Aghion, P.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 235
    • 84974355898 scopus 로고
    • Political control versus expertise: Congressional choices about administrative procedures
    • 62-63 (analyzing the tradeoff between political control and agency expertise)
    • Kathleen Bawn, Political Control Versus Expertise: Congressional Choices About Administrative Procedures, 89 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 62, 62-63 (1995) (analyzing the tradeoff between political control and agency expertise);
    • (1995) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 62
    • Bawn, K.1
  • 236
    • 3042728591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spatial models of delegation
    • 301 (extending delegation models to consider costs of information gathering)
    • Jonathan Bendor & Adam Meirowitz, Spatial Models of Delegation, 98 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 293, 301 (2004) (extending delegation models to consider costs of information gathering).
    • (2004) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 293
    • Bendor, J.1    Meirowitz, A.2
  • 237
    • 62549133585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Discretion rather than rules: Choice of instruments to control bureaucratic policy making
    • (comparing "menu laws" (rules) with "action restrictions" (discretion) as tools of control in delegation)
    • See generally Sean Gailmard, Discretion Rather than Rules: Choice of Instruments to Control Bureaucratic Policy Making, 17 Pol. Analysis 25 (2009) (comparing "menu laws" (rules) with "action restrictions" (discretion) as tools of control in delegation);
    • (2009) Pol. Analysis , vol.17 , pp. 25
    • Gailmard, S.1
  • 238
    • 34547431787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bureaucratic decision costs and endogenous agency expertise
    • (analyzing the impact of decision costs on the development of agency expertise)
    • Matthew C. Stephenson, Bureaucratic Decision Costs and Endogenous Agency Expertise, 23 J.L. Econ. & Org. 469 (2007) (analyzing the impact of decision costs on the development of agency expertise).
    • (2007) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.23 , pp. 469
    • Stephenson, M.C.1
  • 240
    • 77952053333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Miller, supra note 72, at 235-238
    • Miller, supra note 72, at 235-238
  • 241
    • 32644440759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political control and the power of the agent
    • 22
    • Members of teachers unions are up to seven times more likely to participate in school board elections than the average registered voter. See Terry M. Moe, Political Control and the Power of the Agent, 22 J.L. Econ. & Org. 1, 22 (2006).
    • (2006) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.22 , pp. 1
    • Moe, T.M.1
  • 242
    • 0041513829 scopus 로고
    • The president's power to execute the laws
    • 638-39
    • See Steven G. Calabresi & Saikrishna B. Prakash, The President's Power to Execute the Laws, 104 Yale L.J. 541, 638-39 (1994);
    • (1994) Yale L.J. , vol.104 , pp. 541
    • Calabresi, S.G.1    Prakash, S.B.2
  • 243
    • 0011527688 scopus 로고
    • The president and the administration
    • 101
    • Lawrence Lessig & Cass R. Sunstein, The President and the Administration, 94 Colum. L. Rev. 1, 101 (1994).
    • (1994) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 1
    • Lessig, L.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 244
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential administration
    • 2339-2340
    • See Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 Harv. L. Rev. 2245, 2339-2340 (2001).
    • (2001) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.114 , pp. 2245
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 245
    • 41849100758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When does coordination require centralization?
    • 145-148 (surveying contexts in which coordination of agents can be achieved without centralized control)
    • See, e.g., Ricardo Alonso, Wouter Dessein & Niko Matouschek, When Does Coordination Require Centralization?, 98 Am. Econ. Rev. 145, 145-148 (2008) (surveying contexts in which coordination of agents can be achieved without centralized control).
    • (2008) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 145
    • Alonso, R.1    Dessein, W.2    Matouschek, N.3
  • 246
    • 77952057457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 147
    • Id. at 147;
  • 247
    • 0000178003 scopus 로고
    • Horizontal vs. Vertical information structure of the firm
    • 973
    • see also Masahiko Aoki, Horizontal vs. Vertical Information Structure of the Firm, 76 Am. Econ. Rev. 971, 973 (1986);
    • (1986) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 971
    • Aoki, M.1
  • 248
    • 84934563046 scopus 로고
    • Decentralization, duplication, and delay
    • 820-22
    • Patrick Bolton & Joseph Farrell, Decentralization, Duplication, and Delay, 98 J. Pol. Econ. 803, 820-22 (1990);
    • (1990) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.98 , pp. 803
    • Bolton, P.1    Farrell, J.2
  • 249
    • 0033661553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hierarchies and the organization of knowledge in production
    • 897-98
    • Luis Garicano, Hierarchies and the Organization of Knowledge in Production, 108 J. Pol. Econ. 874, 897-98 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.108 , pp. 874
    • Garicano, L.1
  • 250
    • 33747631037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decentralization, hierarchies, and incentives: A mechanism design perspective
    • 379-81
    • See generally Dilip Mookherjee, Decentralization, Hierarchies, and Incentives: A Mechanism Design Perspective, 44 J. Econ. Literature 367, 379-81 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Econ. Literature , vol.44 , pp. 367
    • Mookherjee, D.1
  • 251
    • 77952079179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deliberative Democracy (John Elster ed., 1998) (discussing the strengths and weaknesses of deliberative democracy)
    • See generally Deliberative Democracy (John Elster ed., 1998) (discussing the strengths and weaknesses of deliberative democracy);
  • 252
    • 84935178662 scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, interest groups in american public law
    • 45-46 (explaining the belief that deliberation achieves better outcomes)
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Interest Groups in American Public Law, 38 Stan. L. Rev. 29, 45-46 (1985) (explaining the belief that deliberation achieves better outcomes).
    • (1985) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.38 , pp. 29
    • Cass, R.1
  • 253
    • 22744437692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essay, the emergency constitution
    • 1041-42 (discussing emergencies and constitutionalism)
    • Cf. Bruce Ackerman, Essay, The Emergency Constitution, 113 Yale L.J. 1029, 1041-42 (2004) (discussing emergencies and constitutionalism);
    • (2004) Yale L.J. , vol.113 , pp. 1029
    • Ackerman, B.1
  • 254
    • 1042291360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Accommodating emergencies
    • 635-42 (discussing same)
    • Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Accommodating Emergencies, 56 Stan. L. Rev. 605, 635-42 (2003) (discussing same);
    • (2003) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 605
    • Posner, E.A.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 255
    • 33750528353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emergencies and democratic failure
    • 1145-46
    • Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Emergencies and Democratic Failure, 92 Va. L. Rev. 1091, 1145-46 (2006) (discussing same).
    • (2006) Va. L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1091
    • Posner, E.A.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 256
    • 77952071561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 697, 728
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 697, 728.
  • 257
    • 77952081275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alonso, Dessein & Matouschek, supra note 126, at 146-147
    • See Alonso, Dessein & Matouschek, supra note 126, at 146-147
  • 258
    • 77952057055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Failure of Presidential Democracy, supra note 22
    • See generally The Failure of Presidential Democracy, supra note 22;
  • 259
    • 0348198424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The tyranny of madison
    • 810-812
    • Jonathan Zasloff, The Tyranny of Madison, 44 UCLA L. Rev. 795, 810-812 (1997).
    • (1997) UCLA L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 795
    • Zasloff, J.1
  • 260
    • 77952040592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 650-652
    • Ackerman, supra note 6, at 650-652
  • 261
    • 77952043028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The parliamentary alternative is said to produce more desirable intermediate level legislation for two reasons. First, coalitions do not inevitably face a quick second election, with the accompanying risks of losing control of one branch. Because the timing of elections is not pre-set in the Westminster system, there is less pressure to underreach with symbolic legislation that appeals to voters but is not in the long-term interest of the country. Second, there is no incentive to create de facto entrenchment because the executive cannot veto changes by a future coalition. In the presidential regime, when the legislature is lost to the opposing party, the President can block efforts to undo the old united government policy. This might produce too much quick legislation that can be changed subsequently only by a supermajority of the legislature.
  • 262
    • 77952024741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 651-653
    • Id. at 651-653
  • 263
    • 77952033461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 652-653
    • Id. at 652-653
  • 264
    • 77952042235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some of these statements should be taken with a grain of salt, as the implications differ depending on electoral rules like proportional representation or first-past-thepost.
    • Some of these statements should be taken with a grain of salt, as the implications differ depending on electoral rules like proportional representation or first-past-thepost.
  • 265
    • 0040741746 scopus 로고
    • The institutional foundations of democratic government: A comparison of presidential and parliamentary systems
    • 172 (arguing that the professionalization of a bureaucracy is endogenously determined as a function of presidential and parliamentary regime features)
    • See Terry M. Moe & Michael Caldwell, The Institutional Foundations of Democratic Government: A Comparison of Presidential and Parliamentary Systems, 150 J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. 171, 172 (1994) (arguing that the professionalization of a bureaucracy is endogenously determined as a function of presidential and parliamentary regime features).
    • (1994) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.150 , pp. 171
    • Moe, T.M.1    Caldwell, M.2
  • 267
    • 77952015620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Book review
    • (reviewing The Courts of International Trade: Judicial Specialization, Expertise, and Bureaucratic Policy-Making (1998) and discussing tradeoffs)
    • Christopher Zorn, Book Review, 9 L. & Pol. Book Rev. 127 (1999) (reviewing The Courts of International Trade: Judicial Specialization, Expertise, and Bureaucratic Policy-Making (1998) and discussing tradeoffs).
    • (1999) L. & Pol. Book Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 127
    • Zorn, C.1
  • 268
    • 84928437701 scopus 로고
    • Separated powers and ordered liberty
    • 1517 (Unanimity among constitutional scholars is all but unheard of. Perhaps when achieved it should be celebrated. But one point on which the literature has spoken virtually in unison is no cause for celebration: The Supreme Court's treatment of the constitutional separation of powers is an incoherent muddle.)
    • See Rebecca L. Brown, Separated Powers and Ordered Liberty, 139 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1513, 1517 (1991) ("Unanimity among constitutional scholars is all but unheard of. Perhaps when achieved it should be celebrated. But one point on which the literature has spoken virtually in unison is no cause for celebration: The Supreme Court's treatment of the constitutional separation of powers is an incoherent muddle.");
    • (1991) U. Pa.. L. Rev. , vol.139 , pp. 1513
    • Brown, R.L.1
  • 269
    • 33750903233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cadenced power: The kinetic constitution
    • 689 (The separation of powers puzzle appears to have stumped the Supreme Court. In a series of decisions over the last half-century, and particularly in the last twenty-five years, the Court has veered between two separation of powers doctrines that cannot easily be reconciled.)
    • Laura S. Fitzgerald, Cadenced Power: The Kinetic Constitution, 46 Duke L.J. 679, 689 (1997) ("The separation of powers puzzle appears to have stumped the Supreme Court. In a series of decisions over the last half-century, and particularly in the last twenty-five years, the Court has veered between two separation of powers doctrines that cannot easily be reconciled.");
    • (1997) Duke L.J. , vol.46 , pp. 679
    • Fitzgerald, L.S.1
  • 270
    • 0346685501 scopus 로고
    • The indeterminacy of the separation of powers and the federal courts
    • (explaining that judicial confidence in the precision of the Constitution regarding separation of powers is unjustified).
    • William B. Gwyn, The Indeterminacy of the Separation of Powers and the Federal Courts, 57 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 474 (1989) (explaining that judicial confidence in the precision of the Constitution regarding separation of powers is unjustified).
    • (1989) Geo. Wash. L. Rev. , vol.57 , pp. 474
    • Gwyn, W.B.1
  • 271
    • 77952048288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Magill, supra note 1, at 1129 ("The debate is well-developed: It includes two competing schools of thought, formalism and functionalism, and the predictable bickering back and forth between adherents to each school").
    • See generally Magill, supra note 1, at 1129 ("The debate is well-developed: It includes two competing schools of thought, formalism and functionalism, and the predictable bickering back and forth between adherents to each school").
  • 272
    • 77952088729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss, supra note 13, at 577-578
    • See, e.g., Strauss, supra note 13, at 577-578
  • 273
    • 84930556481 scopus 로고
    • Territorial governments and the limits of formalism
    • 858 (The separation of powers principle is violated whenever the categorizations of the exercised power and the exercising institution do not match and the Constitution does not specifically permit such blending.).
    • Gary Lawson, Territorial Governments and the Limits of Formalism, 78 Cal. L. Rev. 853, 858 (1990) ("The separation of powers principle is violated whenever the categorizations of the exercised power and the exercising institution do not match and the Constitution does not specifically permit such blending.").
    • (1990) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 853
    • Lawson, G.1
  • 274
    • 77952045766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Magill, supra note 1, at 1142-43
    • Magill, supra note 1, at 1142-43;
  • 275
    • 0346345177 scopus 로고
    • Farina, statutory interpretation and the balance of power in the administrative state
    • 477-78
    • see also Cynthia R. Farina, Statutory Interpretation and the Balance of Power in the Administrative State, 89 Colum. L. Rev. 452, 477-78 (1989);
    • (1989) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 452
    • Cynthia, R.1
  • 276
    • 9144269749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The constitutional principle of separation of powers
    • 231
    • Thomas W. Merrill, The Constitutional Principle of Separation of Powers, 1991 Sup. Ct. Rev. 225, 231;
    • Sup. Ct. Rev. , vol.1991 , pp. 225
    • Merrill, T.W.1
  • 277
    • 0042529211 scopus 로고
    • Formal and functional approaches to separation-of-powers questions-a foolish inconsistency?
    • 492
    • Peter L. Strauss, Formal and Functional Approaches to Separation-of-Powers Questions-A Foolish Inconsistency?, 72 Cornell L. Rev. 488, 492 (1987);
    • (1987) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 488
    • Strauss, P.L.1
  • 278
    • 77952014551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss, supra note 13, at 578.
    • Strauss, supra note 13, at 578.
  • 279
    • 77952088335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Redish, supra note 12, at 125.
    • Redish, supra note 12, at 125.
  • 280
    • 76449115544 scopus 로고
    • 487 U.S. 654, 693-696
    • See, e.g., Morrison v. Olson, 487 U.S. 654, 693-696 (1988).
    • (1988) Morrison v. Olson
  • 281
    • 77952018926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Casper, supra note 1, at 8-12.
    • See Casper, supra note 1, at 8-12.
  • 282
    • 77952057854 scopus 로고
    • 478 U.S. 714
    • Many of the most prominent recent separation of powers cases, like Bowsher v. Synar, 478 U.S. 714 (1986), and
    • (1986) Bowsher V. Synar
  • 283
    • 0011629734 scopus 로고
    • 462 U.S. 919 involve issues of exactly this sort. Violations of separation of powers principles tend to occur with the consent of two branches rather than unilateral incursion by one.
    • INS v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919 (1983), involve issues of exactly this sort. Violations of separation of powers principles tend to occur with the consent of two branches rather than unilateral incursion by one.
    • (1983) Ins V. Chadha
  • 284
    • 77952085357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Magill, supra note 1, at 1139-1140
    • Magill, supra note 1, at 1139-1140
  • 285
    • 0041557883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most dangerous branch
    • 1740-1741
    • See Martin S. Flaherty, The Most Dangerous Branch, 105 Yale L.J. 1725,1740-1741 (1996).
    • (1996) Yale L.J. , vol.105 , pp. 1725
    • Flaherty, M.S.1
  • 286
    • 77952057855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lawson, supra note 58, at 1238 n.45
    • Lawson, supra note 58, at 1238 n.45;
  • 287
    • 0042461214 scopus 로고
    • The vesting clauses as power grants
    • 1390 & n.47
    • see also Steven G. Calabresi, The Vesting Clauses as Power Grants, 88 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1377, 1390 & n.47 (1994).
    • (1994) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 1377
    • Calabresi, S.G.1
  • 288
    • 77952013725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Magill, supra note 1, at 1142 & n.50 (discussing the views of Lawson and Calabresi).
    • See generally Magill, supra note 1, at 1142 & n.50 (discussing the views of Lawson and Calabresi).
  • 292
    • 58149110064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 415 F.3d 50, 67 D.C. Cir. rev'd and remanded, 549 U.S. 497 (2007)
    • Massachusetts v. EPA, 415 F.3d 50, 67 (D.C. Cir. 2005), rev'd and remanded, 549 U.S. 497 (2007);
    • (2005) Massachusetts V. EPA
  • 294
    • 77952072446 scopus 로고
    • 72 F.3d 698, 700 9th Cir.
    • Alaska v. Babbitt, 72 F.3d 698, 700 (9th Cir. 1995).
    • (1995) Alaska V. Babbitt
  • 295
    • 84858736953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overlapping and underlapping jurisdiction in administrative law
    • 211-216 (discussing justifications for giving deference to agency determinations of their own jurisdiction).
    • See generally Jacob E. Gersen, Overlapping and Underlapping Jurisdiction in Administrative Law, 2006 Sup. Ct. Rev. 201, 211-216 (discussing justifications for giving deference to agency determinations of their own jurisdiction).
    • Sup. Ct. Rev. , vol.2006 , pp. 201
    • Gersen, J.E.1
  • 296
    • 77952065564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 223-224
    • Id. at 223-224


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.