메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 8, Issue 1, 2012, Pages 187-230

Private enforcementand judicial discretion in the evolution of antitrust in the United States

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84857927528     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhs003     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (16)

References (193)
  • 1
    • 79955881262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congressional Mobilization of Private Litigants: Evidence from the Civil Rights Act of 1991
    • See, e.g., Sean Farhang, Congressional Mobilization of Private Litigants: Evidence from the Civil Rights Act of 1991, 6 J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD. 1 (2009).
    • (2009) J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD , vol.6 , pp. 1
    • Farhang, S.1
  • 2
    • 85021879870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Civil Liability for Violations of International Humanitarian Law
    • Eric Mongelard, Corporate Civil Liability for Violations of International Humanitarian Law, 88 INT'L REV. RED CROSS 665 (2006).
    • (2006) INT'L REV. RED CROSS , vol.88 , pp. 665
    • Mongelard, E.1
  • 3
    • 84857956821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Civil Liability for Sexual Exploitation in Professional Relationships
    • Tom Allen, Civil Liability for Sexual Exploitation in Professional Relationships, 59 MOD. L. REV. 56 (1996).
    • (1996) MOD. L. REV. , vol.59 , pp. 56
    • Allen, T.1
  • 4
    • 33745190975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Changing Regimes of Workplace Governance: Shifting Axes of Social Mobilization and the Challenge to Industrial Relations Theory
    • Michael J. Piore & Sean Safford, Changing Regimes of Workplace Governance: Shifting Axes of Social Mobilization and the Challenge to Industrial Relations Theory, 45 INDUS. RELATIONS 299 (2006).
    • (2006) INDUS. RELATIONS , vol.45 , pp. 299
    • Piore, M.J.1    Safford, S.2
  • 5
    • 3042688725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Optimal Use of Ex Ante Regulation and Ex Post Liability
    • Yolande Hiriart, David Martimort & Jerome Pouyet, On the Optimal Use of Ex Ante Regulation and Ex Post Liability, 84 ECON. LETTERS 231 (2004).
    • (2004) ECON. LETTERS , vol.84 , pp. 231
    • Hiriart, Y.1    Martimort, D.2    Pouyet, J.3
  • 6
    • 0026475451 scopus 로고
    • Private Enforcement of Federal Environmental Law
    • Wendy Naysnerski & Tom Tietenberg, Private Enforcement of Federal Environmental Law, 68 LAND ECON. 28 (1992).
    • (1992) LAND ECON , vol.68 , pp. 28
    • Naysnerski, W.1    Tietenberg, T.2
  • 7
    • 84857971783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Private Antitrust Remedy: Lessons from the American Experience
    • Edward D. Cavanagh, The Private Antitrust Remedy: Lessons from the American Experience, 41LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 629 (2010).
    • (2010) LOY. U. CHI. L. J , vol.41 , pp. 629
    • Cavanagh, E.D.1
  • 8
    • 33749612530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Public versus Private Provision of Corporate Law
    • Gillian Hadfield & Eric Talley, On Public versus Private Provision of Corporate Law, 22 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 414 (2006).
    • (2006) J. L. ECON. & ORG , vol.22 , pp. 414
    • Hadfield, G.1    Talley, E.2
  • 10
    • 79955814172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Enforcement of Corporate Law: An Empirical Comparison of the United Kingdom and the United States
    • John Armour, Bernard Black, Brian Cheffins & Richard Nolan, Private Enforcement of Corporate Law: An Empirical Comparison of the United Kingdom and the United States, 6 J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD. 687 (2009).
    • (2009) J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD , vol.6 , pp. 687
    • Armour, J.1    Black, B.2    Cheffins, B.3    Nolan, R.4
  • 11
    • 77951988434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corruption and Private Law Enforcement: Theory and History
    • Nuno Garoupa & Daniel M. Klerman, Corruption and Private Law Enforcement: Theory and History, 6 REV. L. & ECON. 3 (2010).
    • (2010) REV. L. & ECON. , vol.6 , pp. 3
    • Garoupa, N.1    Klerman, D.M.2
  • 12
    • 84857975883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Private parties that have not been directly injured by an illegal act, but have access to information and relatively strong incentives to enforce public regulations, can also be granted rights of standing in order to enhance the credibility of public laws (for example, environmental, human rights, consumer, or business associations; employees or competing firms with knowledge about unlawful behavior; and so forth).
  • 13
    • 0036881948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Justice
    • For an analysis of different strategies in the design of private legal mechanisms necessary for identifying unlawful behavior in business organizations
    • For an analysis of different strategies in the design of private legal mechanisms necessary for identifying unlawful behavior in business organizations, see Pamela H. Bucy, Private Justice, 76 S. CAL. L. REV. 1 (2002).
    • (2002) S. CAL. L. REV. , vol.76 , pp. 1
    • Bucy, P.H.1
  • 14
    • 0041431949 scopus 로고
    • Public vs. Private Enforcement of the Law in the Early Middle Ages: Fifth to Twelfth Centuries
    • For historical and theoretical perspectives on the tensions between public and private legal institutions
    • For historical and theoretical perspectives on the tensions between public and private legal institutions, see, e.g., Katherine Fischer Drew, Public vs. Private Enforcement of the Law in the Early Middle Ages: Fifth to Twelfth Centuries, 70 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1583 (1995).
    • (1995) CHI.-KENT L. REV. , vol.70 , pp. 1583
    • Fischer Drew, K.1
  • 15
    • 0041035788 scopus 로고
    • The History of the Public/Private Distinction
    • Morton J. Horwitz, The History of the Public/Private Distinction, 130 U. PA. L. REV. 1423 (1982).
    • (1982) U. PA. L. REV. , vol.130 , pp. 1423
    • Horwitz, M.J.1
  • 16
    • 0038630073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Rise of the Regulatory State
    • Edward L. Glaeser & Andrei Shleifer, The Rise of the Regulatory State, 41 J. ECON. LIT. 401 (2003).
    • (2003) J. ECON. LIT. , vol.41 , pp. 401
    • Glaeser, E.L.1    Shleifer, A.2
  • 17
    • 0009126490 scopus 로고
    • Regulation and the Law of Torts
    • Suzan Rose-Ackerman, Regulation and the Law of Torts, 81 AM. ECON. REV. 54 (1991).
    • (1991) AM. ECON. REV. , vol.81 , pp. 54
    • Rose-Ackerman, S.1
  • 18
    • 77952015579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FDA Preemption of State Tort Law in Drug Regulation: Finding the Sweet Spot
    • Peter H. Schuck, FDA Preemption of State Tort Law in Drug Regulation: Finding the Sweet Spot, 13 ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 73 (2008).
    • (2008) ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. , vol.13 , pp. 73
    • Schuck, P.H.1
  • 19
    • 84857984407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward A Unified Theory of Torts
    • Guido Calabresi, Toward A Unified Theory of Torts, 1 J. TORT L. 1 (2007).
    • (2007) J. TORT L. , vol.1 , pp. 1
    • Calabresi, G.1
  • 20
    • 0010950913 scopus 로고
    • Private versus Public Enforcement of Fines
    • For a general review of economic theories of legal procedure
    • For a general review of economic theories of legal procedure, see A. Mitchell Polinsky, Private versus Public Enforcement of Fines, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 105 (1980).
    • (1980) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.9 , pp. 105
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1
  • 21
    • 0012385754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Theory of Optimal Law Enforcement
    • Nuno Garoupa, The Theory of Optimal Law Enforcement, 11 J. ECON. SURVEYS 267 (1997).
    • (1997) J. ECON. SURVEYS , vol.11 , pp. 267
    • Garoupa, N.1
  • 24
    • 84857959403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Merger review provides a useful illustration of the potential advantages of centralized public regimes for implementation of public laws. Private rights of legal action by aggrieved consumers or minority investors concerned about the costs of a particular transaction proposed by the management might constrain the prospects for inefficient mergers and acquisitions. However, decentralization of merger review can prevent or delay efficiency enhancing transactions.
  • 25
    • 84928461294 scopus 로고
    • Competitor Standing to Challenge a Merger of Rivals: The Applicability of Strategic Behavior Analysis
    • For further analysis of the problems in the allocation of enforcement authority in mergers cases
    • For further analysis of the problems in the allocation of enforcement authority in mergers cases, see Jonathan L. Diesenhaus, Competitor Standing to Challenge a Merger of Rivals: The Applicability of Strategic Behavior Analysis, 75 CAL. L. REV. 2057 (1987).
    • (1987) CAL. L. REV. , vol.75 , pp. 2057
    • Diesenhaus, J.L.1
  • 26
    • 0042531256 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Standing in Private Merger Cases: Reconciling Private Incentives and Public Enforcement Goals
    • Joseph F. Broadley, Antitrust Standing in Private Merger Cases: Reconciling Private Incentives and Public Enforcement Goals, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1 (1995).
    • (1995) MICH. L. REV. , vol.94 , pp. 1
    • Broadley, J.F.1
  • 27
    • 84857975899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Courage v. Crehan, C-453/99, 2001 E.C.R. I-6297,¶¶ 26 & 27 (EC) (emphasis added).
  • 28
    • 22544441544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modernizing European Competition Law: A Developmental Perspective
    • For discussions of the potential role of private enforcement in the development of EU competition law
    • For discussions of the potential role of private enforcement in the development of EU competition law, see, e.g., David J. Gerber, Modernizing European Competition Law: A Developmental Perspective, 22 EUR. COMPETITION L. REV. 122 (2001).
    • (2001) EUR. COMPETITION L. REV. , vol.22 , pp. 122
    • Gerber, D.J.1
  • 29
    • 33646475930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Enforcement of Antitrust Rules: Modernization of the EU Rules and the Road Ahead
    • Donncadh Woods, Private Enforcement of Antitrust Rules: Modernization of the EU Rules and the Road Ahead, 16 LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. 431 (2004).
    • (2004) LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. , vol.16 , pp. 431
    • Woods, D.1
  • 30
    • 77952701607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Will the New European Union Competition Regulation Increase Private Litigation? An International Comparison
    • Michael Van Hoof, Will the New European Union Competition Regulation Increase Private Litigation? An International Comparison, 19 CONN. J. INT'L L. 659 (2004).
    • (2004) CONN. J. INT'L L , vol.19 , pp. 659
    • Van Hoof, M.1
  • 31
    • 84857926193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Various studies have tried to draw lessons from the U.S. experience for the design of more robust enforcement institutions in other jurisdictions.
  • 32
    • 31144453830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comparing Antitrust Enforcement in the United States and Europe
    • See, e.g., Douglas H. Ginsburg, Comparing Antitrust Enforcement in the United States and Europe, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 427 (2005).
    • (2005) J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.1 , pp. 427
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1
  • 33
    • 37949010845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revisiting History: What Have We Learned About Private Antitrust Enforcement That We Would Recommend to Others?
    • Donald I. Baker, Revisiting History: What Have We Learned About Private Antitrust Enforcement That We Would Recommend to Others?, 16 LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. 379 (2004).
    • (2004) LOY. CONSUMER L. REV. , vol.16 , pp. 379
    • Baker, D.I.1
  • 34
    • 84857945058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eur. Comm'n, Study on the Conditions of Claims for Damages in Case of Infringement of EC Competition Rules (also known as The Ashurst Report)
    • Eur. Comm'n, Study on the Conditions of Claims for Damages in Case of Infringement of EC Competition Rules (also known as The Ashurst Report) (2004), available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/actionsdamages/study.html.
    • (2004)
  • 35
    • 84857931105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic Considerations in the Emergence of Private Action Rights
    • For an analysis of impediments to the development of decentralized mechanisms for the enforcement of national and EU competition laws
    • For an analysis of impediments to the development of decentralized mechanisms for the enforcement of national and EU competition laws, see Reza Rajabiun, Strategic Considerations in the Emergence of Private Action Rights, 32 WORLD COMPETITION 409 (2009).
    • (2009) WORLD COMPETITION , vol.32 , pp. 409
    • Rajabiun, R.1
  • 36
    • 84857959401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Attempts to enhance private rights of action in the past few years have been more successful in some EU countries than others.
  • 37
    • 84857929794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enforcement of Articles 81 and 82 EC under Regulation 1/2003: The Case of Spain and Portugal
    • See Helmut Brokelmann, Enforcement of Articles 81 and 82 EC under Regulation 1/2003: The Case of Spain and Portugal, 29 WORLD COMPETITION 535 (2006)
    • (2006) WORLD COMPETITION , vol.29 , pp. 535
    • Brokelmann, H.1
  • 38
    • 82555197139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ways to Promote Workable Private Antitrust Enforcement in Italy
    • Selene Rosso, Ways to Promote Workable Private Antitrust Enforcement in Italy, 32 WORLD COMPETITION 305 (2009).
    • (2009) WORLD COMPETITION , vol.32 , pp. 305
    • Rosso, S.1
  • 39
    • 69249195015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Breaking the Habits: The German Competition Law After the 7th Amendment to the Act Against Restraints of Competition (GWB)
    • Andreas Klees, Breaking the Habits: The German Competition Law After the 7th Amendment to the Act Against Restraints of Competition (GWB), 7 GERMAN L.J. 399 (2006).
    • (2006) GERMAN L. J. , vol.7 , pp. 399
    • Klees, A.1
  • 40
    • 85175831411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Era for Private Antitrust Litigation in Germany? A Critical Appraisal of the Modernized Law Against Restraints of Competition
    • Wolfgang Wurmnest, A New Era for Private Antitrust Litigation in Germany? A Critical Appraisal of the Modernized Law Against Restraints of Competition, 6 GERMAN L.J. 1173 (2005).
    • (2005) GERMAN L. J. , vol.6 , pp. 1173
    • Wurmnest, W.1
  • 41
    • 77952723740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Rocky Path for Private Directors General: Procedure, Politics, and the Uncertain Future of EU Antitrust Damages Actions
    • Marc A. Sittenreich, The Rocky Path for Private Directors General: Procedure, Politics, and the Uncertain Future of EU Antitrust Damages Actions, 78 FORDHAM L. REV. 2701 (2010).
    • (2010) FORDHAM L. REV. , vol.782 , pp. 701
    • Sittenreich, M.A.1
  • 43
    • 33645908177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Auditing and Competitive Bidding in the Public Sector
    • For a theoretical analysis of the interplay between information and fixed costs in institutions for the production of public goods
    • For a theoretical analysis of the interplay between information and fixed costs in institutions for the production of public goods, see Gerven Fearon & Lutz-Alexander Busch, Auditing and Competitive Bidding in the Public Sector, 90 J. PUB. ECON. 657 (2006).
    • (2006) J. PUB. ECON. , vol.90 , pp. 657
    • Fearon, G.1    Busch, L.-A.2
  • 44
    • 69249192194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Private Attorney General in a Global Age: Public Interests in Private International Antitrust Litigation
    • Hannah L. Buxbaum, The Private Attorney General in a Global Age: Public Interests in Private International Antitrust Litigation, 26 YALE J. INT'L L. 219 (2001).
    • (2001) YALE J. INT'L L , vol.26 , pp. 219
    • Buxbaum, H.L.1
  • 45
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Antitrust
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1 (1984).
    • (1984) TEX. L. REV. , vol.63 , pp. 1
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 46
    • 33751515353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imperfect Competition Law Enforcement
    • Maarten Pieter Schinkel & Jan Tuinstra, Imperfect Competition Law Enforcement, 24 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 1267 (2006).
    • (2006) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.24 , pp. 1267
    • Schinkel, M.P.1    Tuinstra, J.2
  • 48
    • 0000787258 scopus 로고
    • Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach
    • Gary S. Becker, Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, 76 J. POL. ECON. 169 (1968).
    • (1968) J. POL. ECON. , vol.76 , pp. 169
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 49
    • 0040497682 scopus 로고
    • The Cost of Antitrust Deterrence: Why Not Hang a Price Fixer Now and Then?
    • Michael K. Block & J. Gregory Sidak, The Cost of Antitrust Deterrence: Why Not Hang a Price Fixer Now and Then? 68 GEO. L.J. 1131 (1980).
    • (1980) GEO. L. J. , vol.68 , pp. 1131
    • Block, M.K.1    Gregory Sidak, J.2
  • 50
    • 0000982594 scopus 로고
    • Noble Prize Lecture: The Economic Way of Looking at Behavior
    • Gary S. Becker, Noble Prize Lecture: The Economic Way of Looking at Behavior, 101 J. POL. ECON. 385 (1993).
    • (1993) J. POL. ECON. , vol.101 , pp. 385
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 51
    • 0033390119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Not Hang Them All? On the Virtues of Inefficient Punishment
    • David D. Friedman, Why Not Hang Them All? On the Virtues of Inefficient Punishment, 107 J. POL. ECON. 259 (1999).
    • (1999) J. POL. ECON. , vol.107 , pp. 259
    • Friedman, D.D.1
  • 52
    • 33846896735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Becker Paradox and Type I versus Type II Errors in the Economics of Crime
    • Mats Persson & Claes-Henric Siven, The Becker Paradox and Type I versus Type II Errors in the Economics of Crime, 48 INT'L ECON. REV. 221 (2007).
    • (2007) INT'L ECON. REV. , vol.48 , pp. 221
    • Persson, M.1    Siven, C.-H.2
  • 53
    • 84857945092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • While Australia has developed a limited system of private access since the 1970s, private actions against anticompetitive practices are rare in legal systems of other English-speaking countries, such as Canada and the United Kingdom.
  • 55
    • 33745695601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Enforcement of Competition Laws
    • Kent Roach & Michael J. Trebilicock, Private Enforcement of Competition Laws, 34 OSGOODE HALL L.J. 461 (1997).
    • (1997) OSGOODE HALL L. J. , vol.34 , pp. 461
    • Roach, K.1    Trebilicock, M.J.2
  • 56
    • 84857975934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional Issues in Competition Litigation
    • Mahmud Jamal, Constitutional Issues in Competition Litigation, 41 CAN. BUS. L.J. 66 (2004).
    • (2004) CAN. BUS. L. J. , vol.41 , pp. 66
    • Jamal, M.1
  • 57
    • 82555168452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Privatizing Competition Regulation
    • Karen Yeung, Privatizing Competition Regulation, 18 OXFORD J. LEGAL STUD. 581 (1998).
    • (1998) OXFORD J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.18 , pp. 581
    • Yeung, K.1
  • 59
    • 84890688256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Albert A. Foer, Jonathan W. Cuneo, Randy Stutz & Bojana Vrcek eds., Edward Elgar Publishing)
    • For a broad and updated review of recent developments in private antitrust law around the world, see THE INTERNATIONAL HANDBOOK ON PRIVATE ENFORCEMENT OF COMPETITION LAW (Albert A. Foer, Jonathan W. Cuneo, Randy Stutz & Bojana Vrcek eds., Edward Elgar Publishing 2010).
    • (2010) THE INTERNATIONAL HANDBOOK ON PRIVATE ENFORCEMENT OF COMPETITION LAW
  • 60
    • 84857959407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This suggests that the damage multiplier under section 4 of the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. § 15) does not fully explain why private enforcement incentives are relatively strong in the United States compared with other countries with statutory or general tort private rights of action. The statutory damage multiplier in the United States remains the source of significant controversy in the application of the Sherman Act.
  • 61
    • 6344268478 scopus 로고
    • Detrebling versus Decoupling Antitrust Damages: Lessons from the Theory of Enforcement
    • See Mitchell A. Polinsky, Detrebling versus Decoupling Antitrust Damages: Lessons from the Theory of Enforcement, 74 GEO. L.J. 1231 (1986).
    • (1986) GEO. L. J. , vol.74 , pp. 1231
    • Polinsky, M.A.1
  • 62
    • 78649683719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does De-Trebling Sacrifice Recoverability of Antitrust Awards?
    • Jaynie L. Randall, Does De-Trebling Sacrifice Recoverability of Antitrust Awards?, 23 YALE J. ON REG. 311 (2006).
    • (2006) YALE J. ON REG. , vol.23 , pp. 311
    • Randall, J.L.1
  • 63
    • 70350445395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Detrebling Antitrust Damages in Monopolization Cases
    • Edward D. Cavanagh, Detrebling Antitrust Damages in Monopolization Cases, 76 ANTITRUST L.J. 100 (2009).
    • (2009) ANTITRUST L. J. , vol.76 , pp. 100
    • Cavanagh, E.D.1
  • 64
    • 18044376117 scopus 로고
    • Private Enforcement of U.S. Antitrust Law
    • John D. Guilfoil, Private Enforcement of U.S. Antitrust Law, 10 ANTITRUST BULL. 747 (1965).
    • (1965) ANTITRUST BULL , vol.10 , pp. 747
    • Guilfoil, J.D.1
  • 65
    • 0039904230 scopus 로고
    • Private Antitrust Enforcement Compensation, Deterrence or Extortion?
    • William F. Shughart II, Private Antitrust Enforcement Compensation, Deterrence or Extortion?, 3 REGULATION 53 (1990).
    • (1990) REGULATION , vol.3 , pp. 53
    • Shughart II, W.F.1
  • 66
    • 84857959406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • There are some inconsistencies between historical accounts of the number of private antitrust cases filed before World War II, potentially because of differences in compiling the data from original courts documents. These inconsistencies do not change the overall picture of judicial resistance to private enforcement of statutory prohibitions against anticompetitive practices.
  • 67
    • 84857959405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Long-term data on private and public enforcement used in this article have been compiled from a number of different sources. The older figures on the federal agencies were part of a project to take an inventory of historical activities and are available from the American Antitrust Institute. More recent data are from the Office of the Superintendent of U.S. Courts and compilations of the sourcebook of legal statistics put together at SUNY Albany Law School. There are discrepancies between these and other data sources, since filings can be counted differently and documentation on original data collection methodology is not available. For this reason, we focus on changing patterns rather than absolute numbers, using consistent sources where possible.
  • 68
    • 84857926227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The erosion of legal constraints against anticompetitive agreements and monopolistic practices in the 1980s and 1990s is usually viewed in terms of a growing aversion to false positive errors by scholars and jurists associated with the Harvard and Chicago schools of antitrust thought.
  • 69
    • 0346883458 scopus 로고
    • The Chicago School and the Evolution of Antitrust: Characterization, Antitrust Injury, and Evidentiary Sufficiency
    • William H. Page, The Chicago School and the Evolution of Antitrust: Characterization, Antitrust Injury, and Evidentiary Sufficiency, 75 VA. L. REV. 1221 (1989).
    • (1989) VA. L. REV. , vol.75 , pp. 1221
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 70
    • 70349096585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix
    • William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix, COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1 (2007).
    • (2007) COLUM. BUS. L. REV. , pp. 1
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 72
    • 0347070504 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Damages and Economic Efficiency: An Approach to Antitrust Injury
    • For discussions of basic elements and implications of the rule-of-reason or economic, approach to antitrust liability
    • For discussions of basic elements and implications of the rule-of-reason, or economic, approach to antitrust liability, see William H. Page, Antitrust Damages and Economic Efficiency: An Approach to Antitrust Injury, 47. U. CHI. L. REV. 467 (1980).
    • (1980) U. CHI. L. REV. , vol.47 , pp. 467
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 73
    • 33846795184 scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Antitrust Damages
    • J. Gregory Sidak, Rethinking Antitrust Damages, 33 STAN. L. REV. 329 (1981).
    • (1981) STAN. L. REV. , vol.33 , pp. 329
    • Gregory Sidak, J.1
  • 74
    • 0008215316 scopus 로고
    • Optimal Sanctions for Antitrust Violations
    • William M. Landes, Optimal Sanctions for Antitrust Violations, 50 U. CHI. L. REV. 652 (1983).
    • (1983) U. CHI. L. REV. , vol.50 , pp. 652
    • Landes, W.M.1
  • 75
    • 84928221032 scopus 로고
    • The Scope of Liability for Antitrust Violations
    • William H. Page, The Scope of Liability for Antitrust Violations, 37 STAN. L. REV. 1445 (1985).
    • (1985) STAN. L. REV. , vol.37 , pp. 1445
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 76
    • 84857959404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The erosion of per se rules continues to be an important issue in the United States. For instance, in 2007, the U.S. Supreme Court overruled the long-operative precedent established in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911), prohibiting resale price maintenance on a per se basis. In Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 2705 (2007), the Court declared that minimum price agreements may benefit consumers and hence should be subject to case-by case-analysis. Proponents of the rule-of-reason in the courts tend to emphasize the costs of false positive errors in a system based on per se rules and private rights of action.
  • 77
    • 79952078466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does the Rule of Reason Violate the Rule of Law?
    • See Maurice E. Stucke, Does the Rule of Reason Violate the Rule of Law?, 42 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 1375 (2009).
    • (2009) U. C. DAVIS L. REV. , vol.42 , pp. 1375
    • Stucke, M.E.1
  • 78
    • 84857926201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Although most studies separate the analysis of substantive and procedural elements of the law, the idea that the credibility of public laws depends on their substantive design can be traced to the seminal contribution by CESARE BECCARIA, ON CRIMES AND PUNISHMENTS (1764). He argued that, to prevent crimes, one needed to "make sure that the laws are clear and simple and that the whole strength of the nation is concentrated on defending them." The reason for this conjecture was that, [i]n a nation indolent from the nature of the climate, the uncertainty of the laws confirms and increases men's indolence and stupidity. In a voluptuous but active nation, this uncertainty occasions a multiplicity of cabals and intrigues, which spread distrust and diffidence through the hearts of all, and dissimulation and treachery are the foundation of their prudence. In a brave and powerful nation, this uncertainty of the laws is at last destroyed, after many oscillations from liberty to slavery, and from slavery to liberty again.
  • 79
    • 84977387662 scopus 로고
    • Private Interest Support for Efficiency Enhancing Antitrust Policies
    • See James M. Buchanan & Dwight R. Lee, Private Interest Support for Efficiency Enhancing Antitrust Policies, 30 ECON. INQUIRY 218 (1992).
    • (1992) ECON. INQUIRY , vol.30 , pp. 218
    • Buchanan, J.M.1    Lee, D.R.2
  • 81
    • 84934350397 scopus 로고
    • Use of Antitrust to Subvert Competition
    • William J. Baumol & Janusz A. Ordover, Use of Antitrust to Subvert Competition, 28 J. L. & ECON. 247 (1985).
    • (1985) J. L. & ECON. , vol.28 , pp. 247
    • Baumol, W.J.1    Ordover, J.A.2
  • 82
    • 0348144235 scopus 로고
    • Misuse of the Antitrust Laws: The Competitor Plaintiff
    • Edward A. Snyder & Thomas E. Kauper, Misuse of the Antitrust Laws: The Competitor Plaintiff, 90 MICH. L. REV. 551 (1991).
    • (1991) MICH. L. REV. , vol.90 , pp. 551
    • Snyder, E.A.1    Kauper, T.E.2
  • 83
    • 79955008738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal Antitrust Enforcement: Competitor Suits, Entry, and Post-entry Competition
    • Warren F. Schwartz & Abraham L. Wickelgren, Optimal Antitrust Enforcement: Competitor Suits, Entry, and Post-entry Competition, 95 J. PUB. ECON. 967 (2011).
    • (2011) J. PUB. ECON. , vol.95 , pp. 967
    • Schwartz, W.F.1    Wickelgren, A.L.2
  • 84
    • 57349185911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assessing the Effects of Antitrust Enforcement in the United States
    • For a review of empirical evidence on the economic implications of the U.S. antitrust system
    • For a review of empirical evidence on the economic implications of the U.S. antitrust system, see Gregory J. Werden, Assessing the Effects of Antitrust Enforcement in the United States, 156 DE ECONOMIST 433 (2008).
    • (2008) DE ECONOMIST , vol.1564 , pp. 33
    • Werden, G.J.1
  • 85
    • 34247140575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imports, Entry and Competition Law as Market Disciplines
    • For recent cross-country studies on the links between competition regulations and market outcomes, see Hiau Looi Kee & Bernard Hoekman, Imports, Entry and Competition Law as Market Disciplines, 51 EUR. ECON. REV. 831 (2007).
    • (2007) EUR. ECON. REV. , vol.51 , pp. 831
    • Kee, H.L.1    Hoekman, B.2
  • 86
    • 70449381540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Effects of Competition Policy on Development: Cross-Country Evidence Using Four New Indicators
    • Stefan Voigt, The Effects of Competition Policy on Development: Cross-Country Evidence Using Four New Indicators, 45 J. DEV. STUD. 1225 (2009).
    • (2009) J. DEV. STUD. , vol.45 , pp. 1225
    • Voigt, S.1
  • 87
    • 34548057539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Around the World: An Empirical Analysis of the Scope of Competition Laws and Their Effects
    • Keith N. Hylton & Fei Deng, Antitrust Around the World: An Empirical Analysis of the Scope of Competition Laws and Their Effects, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 271 (2007).
    • (2007) ANTITRUST L. J. , vol.74 , pp. 271
    • Hylton, K.N.1    Deng, F.2
  • 88
    • 84857975904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Although evidence supporting private interest theories of the antitrust may be weak, it is important to note that there is also little systematic evidence on the public benefits of antitrust in terms of consumer welfare in the United States.
  • 89
    • 3042777706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the Evidence
    • See Robert W. Crandall & Clifford Winston, Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the Evidence, 17 J. ECON. LIT. 3 (2003).
    • (2003) J. ECON. LIT. , vol.17 , pp. 3
    • Crandall, R.W.1    Winston, C.2
  • 90
    • 0347070510 scopus 로고
    • Controlling the Competitor Plaintiff in Antitrust Litigation
    • William H. Page & Roger D. Blair, Controlling the Competitor Plaintiff in Antitrust Litigation, 91 MICH. L. REV. 111 (1992).
    • (1992) MICH. L. REV. , vol.91 , pp. 111
    • Page, W.H.1    Blair, R.D.2
  • 91
    • 84857945064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For a given set of institutional arrangements, there is usually a tradeoff between Type I & II errors. Institutional adaptations that mitigate the costs of both types of decision errors tend to be rare and hard to replicate by other jurisdictions. In fact, an efficient adaptation in one jurisdiction may not be optimal for another. Differentiation in existing components of the system is a common process in evolutionary adaptations.
  • 92
    • 33745953976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition Policy with Optimally Differentiated Rules Instead of "Per se Rules vs. Rule of Reason"
    • For an analysis of optimal substantive differentiation in the design of competition laws
    • For an analysis of optimal substantive differentiation in the design of competition laws, see Arndt Christiansen & Wolfgang Kerber, Competition Policy with Optimally Differentiated Rules Instead of "Per se Rules vs. Rule of Reason", 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 215 (2006).
    • (2006) J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.2 , pp. 215
    • Christiansen, A.1    Kerber, W.2
  • 93
    • 33544463829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commitments, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange
    • For overviews of economic and legal scholarship on the evolution of institutions, (Claude Ménard & Mary M. Shirley eds., Springer)
    • For overviews of economic and legal scholarship on the evolution of institutions, see Avner Greif, Commitments, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange, in HANDBOOK OF NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS (Claude Ménard & Mary M. Shirley eds., Springer 2005).
    • (2005) HANDBOOK OF NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS
    • Greif, A.1
  • 94
    • 84871687305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Peer Zumbansen & Gralf-Peter Callliess eds., Edward Elgar)
    • LAW, ECONOMICS AND EVOLUTIONARY THEORY (Peer Zumbansen & Gralf-Peter Callliess eds., Edward Elgar 2010).
    • (2010) LAW, ECONOMICS AND EVOLUTIONARY THEORY
  • 96
    • 0043082557 scopus 로고
    • Hanged for a Sheep: The Economics of Marginal Deterrence
    • David D. Friedman & William Sjostrom, Hanged for a Sheep: The Economics of Marginal Deterrence, 22 J. LEGAL STUD. 345 (1993).
    • (1993) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.22 , pp. 345
    • Friedman, D.D.1    Sjostrom, W.2
  • 97
    • 84857959410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • If individuals are risk neutral, it might be desirable to set the probability of punishment as low as possible (to save on enforcement costs) and impose maximal punishments. In the presence of risk aversion, the optimal fine is generally less than the maximal, and the optimal probability will approach one as the costs of enforcement go to zero. The first corner solution is suboptimal, while the second one may not be feasible due to the costs of enforcement.
  • 98
    • 84977413772 scopus 로고
    • The Optimal Tradeoff between the Probability and Magnitude of Fines
    • See A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, The Optimal Tradeoff between the Probability and Magnitude of Fines, 69 AM. ECON. REV. 880 (1979).
    • (1979) AM. ECON. REV. , vol.69 , pp. 880
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 99
    • 0000644567 scopus 로고
    • Optimal Subsidies and Damages in the Presence of Judicial Error
    • I.P.L. Png, Optimal Subsidies and Damages in the Presence of Judicial Error, 6 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 101 (1986).
    • (1986) INT'L REV. L. & ECON. , vol.6 , pp. 101
    • Png, I.P.L.1
  • 100
    • 85050169518 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration
    • For perspectives on the direct costs of errors
    • For perspectives on the direct costs of errors, see Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. LEGAL STUD. 39 (1973).
    • (1973) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.2 , pp. 39
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 102
    • 84857926205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • A growing aversion to the direct and indirect costs of false positive errors helps explain why heavy punishment and low probability strategies have been more or less abandoned by modern democratic societies. Nevertheless, it is important to point out that hang-them-all strategies that do not account for the costs of false positive errors can persist with democratic political support when the costs of the false positives are targeted at particular sub-groups of the population.
  • 103
    • 0039786066 scopus 로고
    • Efficient Institutions for the Private Enforcement of Law
    • David D. Friedman, Efficient Institutions for the Private Enforcement of Law, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 379 (1984).
    • (1984) J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.13 , pp. 379
    • Friedman, D.D.1
  • 104
    • 84857945063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Since enforcement is costly, catching all offenders will not be feasible, and the actual probability of identification and deterrence will be less than one. In this case, the optimal punishment would be the net external harm and enforcement costs, multiplied by the probability that unlawful activities are not detected and punished. This helps explain why a damage multiplier might be necessary for deterring activities that are difficult to identify. Nevertheless, higher punishments can also generate higher false positive errors.
  • 105
    • 0011601647 scopus 로고
    • Contribution and Claim Reduction Among Antitrust Defendants: An Economic Analysis
    • A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, Contribution and Claim Reduction Among Antitrust Defendants: An Economic Analysis, 33 STAN. L. REV. 447 (1981).
    • (1981) STAN. L. REV. , vol.33 , pp. 447
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 106
    • 84857945062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In theory, a strong aversion to the risks of false negative errors or under-enforcement implies that the magnitude of the optimal penalty could approach the maximal (that is, the wealth of the offender in the case of fines) when the costs of false positive errors is small.
  • 107
    • 0003375133 scopus 로고
    • Law Enforcement, Malfeasance and Compensation of Enforces
    • Gary S. Becker & George J. Stigler, Law Enforcement, Malfeasance and Compensation of Enforces, 3 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1974).
    • (1974) J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.3 , pp. 1
    • Becker, G.S.1    Stigler, G.J.2
  • 108
    • 3242703530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal Law Enforcement with a Rent Seeking Government
    • Nuno Garoupa, & Daniel Klerman, Optimal Law Enforcement with a Rent Seeking Government, 4 AM. L. & ECON. REV. 116 (2002).
    • (2002) AM. L. & ECON. REV. , vol.4 , pp. 116
    • Garoupa, N.1    Klerman, D.2
  • 109
    • 49349116816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Note on Optimal Law Enforcement Under Asymmetric Information
    • Nuno Garoupa & Mohamed Jellal, A Note on Optimal Law Enforcement Under Asymmetric Information, 14 EUR. J.L. & ECON. 5 (2002).
    • (2002) EUR. J. L. & ECON. , vol.14 , pp. 5
    • Garoupa, N.1    Jellal, M.2
  • 110
    • 84857975910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The potential for bypassing regulators through the courts can increase the costs of regulatory capture facing potential offenders and explains why private rights of action can function as a tool against corruption..
  • 111
    • 0042581676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transaction Costs, Institutional Design, and the Separation of Powers
    • Jean-Jacques Laffont & David Martimort, Transaction Costs, Institutional Design, and the Separation of Powers, 42 EUR. ECON. REV. 673 (1998).
    • (1998) EUR. ECON. REV. , vol.42 , pp. 673
    • Laffont, J.-J.1    Martimort, D.2
  • 113
    • 67349194270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preemptive Collusion Among Corruptible Law Enforcers
    • For an analysis of the limits of private enforcement against different classes of corrupt behavior
    • For an analysis of the limits of private enforcement against different classes of corrupt behavior, see Andrew Samuel, Preemptive Collusion Among Corruptible Law Enforcers, 71 J. ECON. BEHAV. ORG. 441 (2009).
    • (2009) J. ECON. BEHAV. ORG. , vol.71 , pp. 441
    • Samuel, A.1
  • 114
    • 0002974023 scopus 로고
    • The Deterrent Effect of Antitrust Enforcement
    • See Michael K. Block, Frederick C. Nold & J. Gregory Sidak, The Deterrent Effect of Antitrust Enforcement, 89 J. POL. ECON. 429 (1981).
    • (1981) J. POL. ECON. , vol.89 , pp. 429
    • Block, M.K.1    Nold, F.C.2    Gregory Sidak, J.3
  • 115
    • 49349097628 scopus 로고
    • The Private Enforcement of Law
    • For basic elements of the argument against private enforcement
    • For basic elements of the argument against private enforcement, see William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Private Enforcement of Law, 4 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1975).
    • (1975) J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.4 , pp. 1
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 116
    • 84934181505 scopus 로고
    • Private Antitrust Enforcement: The New Learning
    • William Breit & Kenneth G. Elzinga, Private Antitrust Enforcement: The New Learning, 28 J.L. & ECON. 405 (1985).
    • (1985) J. L. & ECON. , vol.28 , pp. 405
    • Breit, W.1    Elzinga, K.G.2
  • 117
    • 84857975908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Benefits of coordination (for example, scale economies and reduced duplication in enforcement costs) can be attained in both public and private monopolies.
  • 118
    • 33746097013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coordinating Private Class Action and Public Agency Enforcement of Antitrust Law
    • See, e.g., David Rosenberg & James P. Sullivan, Coordinating Private Class Action and Public Agency Enforcement of Antitrust Law, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 159 (2006).
    • (2006) J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.2 , pp. 159
    • Rosenberg, D.1    Sullivan, J.P.2
  • 119
    • 53549131978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private v. Public Antitrust Enforcement: A Strategic Analysis
    • R. Preston McAfee, Hugo Mialon & Sue Mialon, Private v. Public Antitrust Enforcement: A Strategic Analysis, 92 J. PUB. ECON. 1863 (2008).
    • (2008) J. PUB. ECON. , vol.92 , pp. 1863
    • Preston McAfee, R.1    Mialon, H.2    Mialon, S.3
  • 120
    • 84857938687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Modernization of European Antitrust Enforcement: The Economics of Regulatory Competition
    • Ben Depoorter & Francesco Parisi, Modernization of European Antitrust Enforcement: The Economics of Regulatory Competition, 13 GEO. MASON L. REV. 309 (2005).
    • (2005) GEO. MASON L. REV. , vol.13 , pp. 309
    • Depoorter, B.1    Parisi, F.2
  • 121
    • 0000763749 scopus 로고
    • Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange
    • Oliver E. Williamson, Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange, 73 AM. ECON. REV. 519 (1983).
    • (1983) AM. ECON. REV. , vol.73 , pp. 519
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 122
    • 0041647090 scopus 로고
    • Delimiting Antitrust
    • Oliver E. Williamson, Delimiting Antitrust, 76 GEO. L.J. 271 (1987).
    • (1987) GEO. L. J. , vol.76 , pp. 271
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 124
    • 84985386630 scopus 로고
    • Civil Wrongs: Personal Injury in the Late 19th Century
    • Lawrence M. Friedman, Civil Wrongs: Personal Injury in the Late 19th Century, 12 AM. BAR FOUNDATION RES. J. 351 (1987).
    • (1987) AM. BAR FOUNDATION RES. J. , vol.12 , pp. 351
    • Friedman, L.M.1
  • 128
    • 84857935730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For instance, no specific funds were allocated to antitrust enforcement between 1890 and 1904. The average number of cases in this period was less than two per year.
  • 129
    • 84857945080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For basic information on the evolution of public enforcement, see U.S. Dep't of Justice, Timeline of Antitrust Enforcement Highlights at the Department of Justice
    • For basic information on the evolution of public enforcement, see U.S. Dep't of Justice, Timeline of Antitrust Enforcement Highlights at the Department of Justice, http://www.justice.gov/atr/timeline.htm.
  • 130
    • 33751506357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Monitoring and Antitrust Enforcement: Paying Informants to Reveal Cartels
    • William E. Kovacic, Private Monitoring and Antitrust Enforcement: Paying Informants to Reveal Cartels, 69 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 766 (2000).
    • (2000) GEO. WASH. L. REV. , vol.69 , pp. 766
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 131
    • 33751540593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Impact of Leniency and Whistle-Blowing Programs on Cartels
    • Cecile Aubert, Patrick Rey & William E. Kovacic, The Impact of Leniency and Whistle-Blowing Programs on Cartels, 24 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 1241 (2006).
    • (2006) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. , vol.24 , pp. 1241
    • Aubert, C.1    Rey, P.2    Kovacic, W.E.3
  • 132
    • 0000274841 scopus 로고
    • Ex Post Liability for Harm vs. Ex Ante Safety Regulation: Substitutes or Complements?
    • Charles D. Kolstad, Thomas S. Ulen & Gary V. Johnson, Ex Post Liability for Harm vs. Ex Ante Safety Regulation: Substitutes or Complements?, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 888 (1990).
    • (1990) AM. ECON. REV. , vol.80 , pp. 888
    • Kolstad, C.D.1    Ulen, T.S.2    Johnson, G.V.3
  • 133
    • 0345582468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When Should We Prefer Tort Law to Environmental Regulation?
    • Keith N. Hylton, When Should We Prefer Tort Law to Environmental Regulation?, 41 WASHBURN L.J. 515 (2001).
    • (2001) WASHBURN L. J. , vol.41 , pp. 515
    • Hylton, K.N.1
  • 134
    • 54749112283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public Regulation and Private Lawsuits in the American Separation of Power System
    • Sean Farhang, Public Regulation and Private Lawsuits in the American Separation of Power System, 52 AM. J. POL. SCI. 821 (2008).
    • (2008) AM. J. POL. SCI. , vol.52 , pp. 821
    • Farhang, S.1
  • 135
    • 2942672090 scopus 로고
    • Congress and the Sherman Antitrust Law: 1887-1890
    • William L. Letwin, Congress and the Sherman Antitrust Law: 1887-1890, 23 U. CHI. L. REV. 221 (1956).
    • (1956) U. CHI. L. REV. , vol.23 , pp. 221
    • Letwin, W.L.1
  • 136
    • 0002201724 scopus 로고
    • The Origins of Antitrust: An Interest Group Perspective
    • Thomas J. Dilorenzo, The Origins of Antitrust: An Interest Group Perspective, 5 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 73 (1985).
    • (1985) INT'L REV. L. & ECON. , vol.5 , pp. 73
    • Dilorenzo, T.J.1
  • 137
    • 33748925027 scopus 로고
    • Attitudes Towards Trusts Prior to the Sherman Act
    • Sanford D. Gordon, Attitudes Towards Trusts Prior to the Sherman Act, 30 S. ECON. J. 156 (1963).
    • (1963) S. ECON. J. , vol.30 , pp. 156
    • Gordon, S.D.1
  • 138
    • 84857975923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The Tariff Act of 1890 (the McKinley Tariff) was passed just three months after the Sherman Act and was sponsored by Senator Sherman. In a speech, which was later withdrawn from the Congressional Record for "revision," Senator Sherman confirmed this point and expressed concern about the potential anticompetitive impact of the tariffs.
  • 139
    • 0040639221 scopus 로고
    • The History of Antitrust Market Delineation
    • For discussions of the critical importance of the concept of the relevant market in the application of antitrust law
    • For discussions of the critical importance of the concept of the relevant market in the application of antitrust law, see Gregory J. Werden, The History of Antitrust Market Delineation, 76 MARQ. L. REV. 123 (1992).
    • (1992) MARQ. L. REV. , vol.76 , pp. 123
    • Werden, G.J.1
  • 140
    • 2342562169 scopus 로고
    • New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust
    • Robert Pitofsky, New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust, 90 COLUM. L. REV. 1805 (1990).
    • (1990) COLUM. L. REV. , vol.90 , pp. 1805
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 141
    • 66849101768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Relevant Market: A Concept Still in Search of a Definition
    • Adriaan Ten Kate & Gunnar Niels, The Relevant Market: A Concept Still in Search of a Definition, 5 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 297 (2009).
    • (2009) J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. , vol.5 , pp. 297
    • Ten Kate, A.1    Niels, G.2
  • 142
    • 85050707366 scopus 로고
    • The Stock Market and Early Antitrust Enforcement
    • For an analysis of the volatility of antitrust enforcement and its impact of particular firms before the adoption of the Clayton Act
    • For an analysis of the volatility of antitrust enforcement and its impact of particular firms before the adoption of the Clayton Act, see George Bittlingmayer, The Stock Market and Early Antitrust Enforcement, 36 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1993).
    • (1993) J.L. & ECON , vol.36 , pp. 1
    • Bittlingmayer, G.1
  • 143
    • 84857935740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Standard Oil of New Jersey v. U.S., 221 U.S. 1 (1911).
  • 144
    • 0003484886 scopus 로고
    • For historical studies of the role of public antitrust in the regulation of the energy industry,.(McClure, Phillips)
    • For historical studies of the role of public antitrust in the regulation of the energy industry, see IDA M. TARBELL, THE HISTORY OF THE STANDARD OIL COMPANY (McClure, Phillips 1904).
    • (1904) The History of the Standard Oil Company
    • Tarbell, I.M.1
  • 145
    • 0004011824 scopus 로고
    • THE PRIZE: THE EPIC QUEST FOR OIL, MONEY
    • (Simon & Schuster)
    • DANIEL H. YERGIN, THE PRIZE: THE EPIC QUEST FOR OIL, MONEY, AND POWER (Simon & Schuster 1991).
    • (1991) AND POWER
    • Yergin, D.H.1
  • 146
    • 84857975922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Standard Oil and a number of other high-profile cases from the late 19th century to the early 20th century often obscure the fact that the federal governments of that period had limited incentives to enforce the Sherman Act in a systematic manner, as is documented by historical measures of public cases.
  • 148
    • 84857926220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The sudden rise in the level of criminal case filings in the late 1930s can be attributed to the growing utilization of antitrust law against cartels based in other industrialized countries after the appointment of Thurman Arnold to the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice.
  • 150
    • 84971922795 scopus 로고
    • Thurman Arnold Goes to Washington: A Look at Antitrust Policy in the Later New Deal
    • Consequently, despite the apparently larger number of criminal filings, the federal government continued to lack commitment to domestic enforcement
    • Consequently, despite the apparently larger number of criminal filings, the federal government continued to lack commitment to domestic enforcement. Wilson D. Miscamble, Thurman Arnold Goes to Washington: A Look at Antitrust Policy in the Later New Deal, 56 BUS. HIST. REV. 1 (1982).
    • (1982) BUS. HIST. REV. , vol.56 , pp. 1
    • Miscamble, W.D.1
  • 151
    • 85050412901 scopus 로고
    • The Antimonopoly Ideal and the Liberal State: The Case of Thurman Arnold
    • Alan Brinkley, The Antimonopoly Ideal and the Liberal State: The Case of Thurman Arnold, 80 J. AM. HIST. 557 (1993).
    • (1993) J. AM. HIST. , vol.80 , pp. 557
    • Brinkley, A.1
  • 152
    • 4544279195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Deal Policies and the Persistence of the Great Depression: A General Equilibrium Analysis
    • Harold Cole & Lee Ohanian, New Deal Policies and the Persistence of the Great Depression: A General Equilibrium Analysis, 112 J. POL. ECON. 779 (2004).
    • (2004) J. POL. ECON. , vol.112 , pp. 779
    • Cole, H.1    Ohanian, L.2
  • 153
    • 84857926219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • However, others have found that the impact of these policies on the production of cartelized industries was negative during the depression. Evidence from the 1930s in the United States contradict the "efficient cartel" hypothesis.
  • 154
    • 0036001888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Output Effects of Government Sponsored Cartel During the New Deal
    • See Jason E. Taylor, The Output Effects of Government Sponsored Cartel During the New Deal, 50 J. INDUS. ECON. 1 (2002).
    • (2002) J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.50 , pp. 1
    • Taylor, J.E.1
  • 155
    • 85055764121 scopus 로고
    • The Eisenhower Antitrust Policy: Progressivism or Conservatism?
    • Richard B. Wilson, The Eisenhower Antitrust Policy: Progressivism or Conservatism?, 12 POL. RES. Q. 559 (1959).
    • (1959) POL. RES. Q. , vol.12 , pp. 559
    • Wilson, R.B.1
  • 156
    • 84857983216 scopus 로고
    • The Antitrust Record of the Eisenhower Administration
    • Theodore P. Kovaleff, The Antitrust Record of the Eisenhower Administration, 21 ANTITRUST BULL. 589 (1976).
    • (1976) ANTITRUST BULL , vol.21 , pp. 589
    • Kovaleff, T.P.1
  • 157
    • 84857926218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The growing reliance on economic analysis of effects in merger review increased demands on the public enforcers starting in the late 1960s. The legal basis for the need to shift resources from civil case filings to merger analysis can be found in the Supreme Court decision in United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270 (1966), argued by Richard Posner for the United States. While the majority of the Court upheld the administrative decision against the merger, Justice Stewart dissented: "The sole consistency that I can find is that in litigation under [section] 7, the Government always wins."
  • 158
    • 84857975926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18a (as amended 1976).
  • 159
    • 21744450555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Twenty Years of Hart-Scott-Rodino on Merger Practice: A Case Study in the Law of Unintended Consequences Applied to Antitrust Legislation
    • See also Joe Sims & Deborah P. Herman, The Effect of Twenty Years of Hart-Scott-Rodino on Merger Practice: A Case Study in the Law of Unintended Consequences Applied to Antitrust Legislation, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 865 (1996).
    • (1996) ANTITRUST L. J. , vol.65 , pp. 865
    • Sims, J.1    Herman, D.P.2
  • 160
    • 84857945082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Relatively active merger policies during the 1990s in the United States appear to have had a positive economic impact by promoting specialization and export performance in the manufacturing industry.
  • 161
    • 21944446775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Export Orientation and Domestic Merger Policy: Theory and Some Empirical Evidence
    • See Josef A. Clougherty & Anming Zhang, Export Orientation and Domestic Merger Policy: Theory and Some Empirical Evidence, 38 CAN. J. ECON. 778 (2005).
    • (2005) CAN. J. ECON. , vol.38 , pp. 778
    • Clougherty, J.A.1    Zhang, A.2
  • 162
    • 84857975925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Some observers of antitrust history point out that mandatory trebling of damages may have in fact made the courts more reluctant to award damages to plaintiffs in the pre-World War II period. Changes in the manner in which the courts calculated damages may have been a factor in increasing private antitrust incentives in the initial stages of the transition to a mixed regime in the 1950s.
  • 163
    • 84857954648 scopus 로고
    • The Treble Damage Bonanza: New Doctrines of Damages in Private Antitrust Suits
    • See Homer Clark, The Treble Damage Bonanza: New Doctrines of Damages in Private Antitrust Suits, 52 MICH. L. REV. 363 (1954).
    • (1954) MICH. L. REV. , vol.52 , pp. 363
    • Clark, H.1
  • 164
    • 0040611857 scopus 로고
    • Economic Analysis of Private Antitrust Litigation
    • Steven C. Salop & Lawrence J. White, Economic Analysis of Private Antitrust Litigation, 74 GEO. L.J. 1001 (1986).
    • (1986) GEO. L. J. , vol.74 , pp. 1001
    • Salop, S.C.1    White, L.J.2
  • 165
    • 84857926222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The level of private case filings represents the broadest indicator of enforcement activity and can be viewed as a good proxy for the evolution of legal constraints against anticompetitive practices. However, the aggregate level of case filings has an important limitation, since multiple filings can be later consolidated in a single case. Unfortunately, narrower measures of litigation than case filings were not compiled in a systematic manner for the period under analysis in this Part. For the 1980s and 1990s, the last Part of this article provides a more detailed analysis of private enforcement at different stages of the judicial process. 101 As documented in the last Part of this article, public civil actions were on a declining path since the early 1970s, as resources were increasingly focused on merger review and criminal prosecutions. Criminal cases initially increased in the late 1940s, but they remained stable. until the early 1980s, when they became increasingly common.
  • 166
    • 84857926221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See infra Figures 1 & 6.
  • 167
    • 0033939487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The U. S. Antitrust System and Recent Trends in Antitrust Enforcement
    • Ping Lin, Baldev Raj, Michael Sandfort & Daniel Slottje, The U.S. Antitrust System and Recent Trends in Antitrust Enforcement, 14 J. ECON. SURV. 255 (2000).
    • (2000) J. ECON. SURV. , vol.14 , pp. 255
    • Lin, P.1    Raj, B.2    Sandfort, M.3    Slottje, D.4
  • 168
    • 84925971981 scopus 로고
    • The Functions of Courts in the United States, 1950-1980
    • For a discussion of the evolving functions of the judicial system during the growth of private actions
    • For a discussion of the evolving functions of the judicial system during the growth of private actions, see James Willard Hurst, The Functions of Courts in the United States, 1950-1980, 15 L. & SOC'Y REV. 401 (1981).
    • (1981) L. & SOC'Y REV , vol.15 , pp. 401
    • Willard Hurst, J.1
  • 169
    • 84857935735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See infra Figure 1.
  • 170
    • 84857945085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See infra Figures 1 & 6. Part III.C provides further analysis of potential links between public and private enforcement activity.
  • 171
    • 84857974555 scopus 로고
    • Private Action: The Strongest Pillar of Antitrust
    • For a detailed analysis of justifications for private antitrust enforcement and reforms required to enhance its role as a complement to public enforcement
    • For a detailed analysis of justifications for private antitrust enforcement and reforms required to enhance its role as a complement to public enforcement, see Lee Loevinger, Private Action: The Strongest Pillar of Antitrust, 3 ANTITRUST BULL. 167 (1958).
    • (1958) ANTITRUST BULL , vol.3 , pp. 167
    • Loevinger, L.1
  • 172
    • 84857926224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For example, in his testimony to Congress in 1951, Assistant Attorney General H. Graham Morrison argued that, in the absence of private suits, public enforcers would require four times as much funding. Testimony of H. Graham Morrison, Hearings on H.R. 3408, 82d Cong., 1st Sess. 42 (1951).
  • 173
    • 84857975928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Standard Oil of New Jersey v. U.S., 221 U.S. 1 (1911).
  • 174
    • 84857945083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • United States v. Trenton Potteries Co., 273 U.S. 392 (1927). In United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940), the Supreme Court reaffirmed this guidance.
  • 175
    • 84857935733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211 (1951).
  • 176
    • 84857975927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967); Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1968).
  • 177
    • 84857975930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Vertical price fixing represents a possible exemption to this rule, since this class of restrictions had been viewed as per se illegal pursuant to the 1911 Supreme Court decision in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911). One reason for this might be that vertical price fixing can sometimes benefit both parties (that is, it can be Pareto optimal), while horizontal collusion mostly benefits the members of a cartel at the expense of downstream firms and consumers. Consequently, vertical price fixing may appear less pernicious than horizontal collusion from the perspective of firms.
  • 178
    • 69549090107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Antitrust Enforcement in the Presence of Pre-Trial Bargaining
    • See, e.g., Sylvain Bourjade, Patrick Rey & Paul Seabright, Private Antitrust Enforcement in the Presence of Pre-Trial Bargaining, 57 J. INDUS. ECON. 372 (2009).
    • (2009) J. INDUS. ECON. , vol.57 , pp. 372
    • Bourjade, S.1    Rey, P.2    Seabright, P.3
  • 179
    • 84857935734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The authors show that, in the presence of information costs, Bayesian filtering by the courts is not necessarily optimal, and some restrictions on the range of evidence that the courts can consider are necessary to induce private litigation incentives.
  • 180
    • 84857975931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • That is, offenders may be too rich or poor to care about monetary damages. For instance, declaring bankruptcy in an extreme event is a viable strategy for avoiding liability.
  • 181
    • 84857926225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The results of this investigation are not reported here. This analysis also explored the interaction between case filing indicators and the rate of growth in gross national product (GNP), as an indicator of the broader economic environment. Public actions appear less sensitive to the macroeconomic climate than private case filings. Litigation levels appear to be higher when the economy is doing very well or very poorly.
  • 182
    • 84857935736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 (1977).
  • 183
    • 84857975932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In this case, the state of Illinois and 700 local governments had been subject to a pricefixing conspiracy by producers of concrete blocks.
  • 184
    • 84857926226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This possibility essentially captures the fact that, even though they have been separated in legal and economic analysis, horizontal and vertical anticompetitive arrangements can be closely linked in practice.
  • 185
    • 84857935737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • For an interesting illustration of the growing tendency of some judges to ignore restrictions imposed on case-by-case analysis with the adoption of bright-line rules in the 1960s and 1960s, see Hearings on the Nomination of Judge Robert Bork to be Associate Justice of the Supreme Court Before the Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, 100th Cong., 1st Sess. 215 (1987) (testimony of Robert Abrams, Attorney General of New York).
  • 186
    • 84857986388 scopus 로고
    • Bork's Private Agenda in Antitrust: Judicial Refusal to Enforce
    • Robert Abrams, Bork's Private Agenda in Antitrust: Judicial Refusal to Enforce, 19 ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. 19 (1987).
    • (1987) ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. , vol.19 , pp. 19
    • Abrams, R.1
  • 187
    • 84857945088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967).
  • 188
    • 84857945087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979). The concept of antitrust injury increasingly accepted by the courts required that liability for antitrust damages be equated with the anticompetitive harm from an unlawful practice.
  • 189
    • 84857977681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The concept of antitrust injury increasingly accepted by the courts required that liability for antitrust damages be equated with the anticompetitive aspects of the unlawful practice in order to minimize the risk of false positive errors. This approach reflected the assumption that, with risk aversion, the application of treble damages can lead to over-deterrence, requiring the courts to engage in a costly and complex process of case-by-case assessment.
  • 190
    • 84857935741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • If the evidence that the plaintiff has about prohibited behavior by the defendants is sufficiently strong, then the threat of litigation might be sufficient to motivate the parties to reach a private bargain, and filing a case may not be necessary. Nonetheless, filing a case with the courts represents an important point of escalation that is reached only after private bargaining has failed to produce a mutually acceptable private solution.
  • 191
    • 84857935739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Data on judicial outcomes are drawn from The Database on U.S. Judicial Statistics Compiled by Theodore Eisenberg and Kevin M. Clermont (2001), available at Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research or Cornell Law School Library, Federal District-Court Civil Cases, All Cases, http://legal1.cit.cornell.edu:8090/fed_all.htm [hereinafter Database on U.S. Judicial Statistics].
  • 192
    • 22144474006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Vanishing Trial: An Examination of Trials and Related Matters in Federal and State Courts
    • Marc Galanter, The Vanishing Trial: An Examination of Trials and Related Matters in Federal and State Courts, 1 J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD. 459 (2004).
    • (2004) J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD. , vol.1 , pp. 459
    • Galanter, M.1
  • 193
    • 84857975933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Unfortunately, a longer set of historical data on judicial outcomes at this stage of the litigation process is not available.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.