메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 5, Issue 2, 2009, Pages 297-333

The relevant market: A concept still in search of a definition

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66849101768     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhn029     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (14)

References (45)
  • 1
    • 66849110269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an extensive description of the emergence of the relevant-market concept in antitrust analysis, see Gregory Werden, The History of Antitrust Market Delineation, 76 MARQ. L. REV. 123 (1992 ).
    • For an extensive description of the emergence of the relevant-market concept in antitrust analysis, see Gregory Werden, The History of Antitrust Market Delineation, 76 MARQ. L. REV. 123 (1992 ).
  • 2
    • 66849127277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (1982), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 102 and U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992). There was some guidance provided in the 1968 Guidelines, but that was not considered a proper definition of the relevant-market concept (it was phrased in terms of grouping of sales and area of effective competition among the included sellers). According to the Task Force on Productivity and Competition headed by George Stigler, this guidance was so loose and unprofessional as to be positively embarrassing.
    • U.S. Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (1982), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 102 and U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992). There was some guidance provided in the 1968 Guidelines, but that was not considered a proper definition of the relevant-market concept (it was phrased in terms of "grouping of sales" and "area of effective competition among the included sellers"). According to the Task Force on Productivity and Competition headed by George Stigler, this guidance was "so loose and unprofessional as to be positively embarrassing."
  • 3
    • 66849092697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the Report of the Task Force in 1 J. Reprints for Antitrust Law & Economics (1969), p. 827.
    • See the Report of the Task Force in 1 J. Reprints for Antitrust Law & Economics (1969), p. 827.
  • 4
    • 0141884230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gregory Werden, The 1982 Merger Guidelines and the Ascent of the Hypothetical Monopolist Paradigm, 71 ANTITRUST L. J. 253 (2003).
    • See Gregory Werden, The 1982 Merger Guidelines and the Ascent of the Hypothetical Monopolist Paradigm, 71 ANTITRUST L. J. 253 (2003).
  • 6
    • 66849098660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • European Commission. Commission Notice on the definition of the relevant market for the purpose of Community competition law, 1997 O.J. (C 372), par. 5.
    • European Commission. Commission Notice on the definition of the relevant market for the purpose of Community competition law, 1997 O.J. (C 372), par. 5.
  • 7
    • 66849114413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is much recent literature on how the HMD is applied in practice, ranging from articles dealing with critical loss analysis to operationalize the HMD - see, most recently, Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro, Improving Critical Loss Analysis, ANTITRUST SOURCE (2008)
    • There is much recent literature on how the HMD is applied in practice, ranging from articles dealing with critical loss analysis to operationalize the HMD - see, most recently, Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro, Improving Critical Loss Analysis, ANTITRUST SOURCE (2008)
  • 8
    • 50349090359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Øystein Daljord, Lars Sørgard and Øyvind Thomassen, The SSNIP test and market definition with the aggregate diversion ratio: A reply to Katz and Shapiro, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 4: 263 (2008) - to articles analyzing how competition authorities have applied HMD in real-world cases - for example, Graeme Reynolds and Chris Walters, The use of customer surveys for market definition and the competitive assessment of horizontal mergers, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 4:411 (2008)
    • and Øystein Daljord, Lars Sørgard and Øyvind Thomassen, The SSNIP test and market definition with the aggregate diversion ratio: A reply to Katz and Shapiro, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 4: 263 (2008) - to articles analyzing how competition authorities have applied HMD in real-world cases - for example, Graeme Reynolds and Chris Walters, The use of customer surveys for market definition and the competitive assessment of horizontal mergers, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 4:411 (2008)
  • 9
    • 66849098661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Malcolm B. Coate and Jeffrey H. Fischer, A practical guide to the hypothetical monopolist test for market definition, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON., forthcoming. We do not discuss these here.
    • and Malcolm B. Coate and Jeffrey H. Fischer, A practical guide to the hypothetical monopolist test for market definition, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON., forthcoming. We do not discuss these here.
  • 10
    • 66849088575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that the point on supply characteristics we are making in this article is different from another criticism that is sometimes levelled against the demand-side focus of the Merger Guidelines, which is that even under the Guidelines one sometimes delineates markets based on supply-side substitution, for entirely pragmatic reasons. For example, size 7 and size 9 shoes are not demand substitutes, but making this distinction does not add anything to the competition analysis given that the supply conditions (such as producer market shares) for both sizes will be virtually the same. In fact, note 14 in the 1992 Guidelines explicitly refers to this usage of supply-side substitution as a matter of convenience although the purist would note that even in this case the Guidelines would still speak of markets in the plural rather than of one market
    • Note that the point on supply characteristics we are making in this article is different from another criticism that is sometimes levelled against the demand-side focus of the Merger Guidelines, which is that even under the Guidelines one sometimes delineates markets based on supply-side substitution, for entirely pragmatic reasons. For example, size 7 and size 9 shoes are not demand substitutes, but making this distinction does not add anything to the competition analysis given that the supply conditions (such as producer market shares) for both sizes will be virtually the same. In fact, note 14 in the 1992 Guidelines explicitly refers to this usage of supply-side substitution "as a matter of convenience" (although the purist would note that even in this case the Guidelines would still speak of markets in the plural rather than of one market).
  • 11
    • 0039226600 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep, CCH 103
    • U.S. Department of Justice, Merger Guidelines (1984), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 103.
    • (1984) Merger Guidelines
  • 12
    • 0342746440 scopus 로고
    • Economic Aspects of the Bethlehem Opinion, 45
    • Morris A. Adelman, Economic Aspects of the Bethlehem Opinion, 45 VA. LAW REV. 684 (1959).
    • (1959) VA. LAW REV , vol.684
    • Adelman, M.A.1
  • 13
    • 66849116533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A similar idea that preceded the notion of hypothetical monopolization was that of hypothetical cartelization of the market, that is, which firms would need to be included in the cartel to make the price increase sustainable? For reasons that we do not expand upon here, the notion of hypothetical cartelization suffers from a number of conceptual problems and was soon abandoned in favour of hypothetical monopolization
    • A similar idea that preceded the notion of hypothetical monopolization was that of hypothetical cartelization of the market, that is, which firms would need to be included in the cartel to make the price increase sustainable? For reasons that we do not expand upon here, the notion of hypothetical cartelization suffers from a number of conceptual problems and was soon abandoned in favour of hypothetical monopolization.
  • 14
    • 66849090723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Already before the 1984 Guidelines were issued, Werden argued that the 1982 Guidelines should be interpreted in terms of profit maximization. Gregory J. Werden, Market Delineation and the Justice Department's Merger Guidelines, 1983 DUKE L. J. 514, 542 (1983).
    • Already before the 1984 Guidelines were issued, Werden argued that the 1982 Guidelines should be interpreted in terms of profit maximization. Gregory J. Werden, Market Delineation and the Justice Department's Merger Guidelines, 1983 DUKE L. J. 514, 542 (1983).
  • 15
    • 0032363160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rather than citing examples of unawareness of the difference between the break-even and the profit-maximizing versions, we refer to Gregory Werden who has frequently drawn attention to the distinction. See, for example, Gregory J. Werden, Demand Elasticities in Antitrust Analysis, 66 ANTITRUST L. J. 363 1998
    • Rather than citing examples of unawareness of the difference between the break-even and the profit-maximizing versions, we refer to Gregory Werden who has frequently drawn attention to the distinction. See, for example, Gregory J. Werden, Demand Elasticities in Antitrust Analysis, 66 ANTITRUST L. J. 363 (1998).
  • 16
    • 66849090725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An example of such a situation is given in Werden
    • For that to happen, there must be multiple local optima for the monopolist, note 10, at p
    • For that to happen, there must be multiple local optima for the monopolist. An example of such a situation is given in Werden (1983), supra note 10, at p. 543.
    • supra , pp. 543
  • 17
    • 66849086492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gregory J. Werden, Market Delineation under the Merger Guidelines: A Tenth Anniversary Retrospective, 38 ANTITRUST BULL. 517, 538 (1993).
    • See Gregory J. Werden, Market Delineation under the Merger Guidelines: A Tenth Anniversary Retrospective, 38 ANTITRUST BULL. 517, 538 (1993).
  • 18
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. 104
    • U.S. Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. 104.
    • (1992) Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 19
    • 66849133539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As we explain below, this assumption generally exaggerates the price discipline other products exercise over the products within the group
    • As we explain below, this assumption generally exaggerates the price discipline other products exercise over the products within the group.
  • 20
    • 66849137393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A less important addition is in the words at least. The authors probably realized that a large and significant increase in price would also be sufficient. Technically, they could have achieved the same goal by suppressing the words small but. According to Werden, The word 'small' must have been intended to indicate that a price increase can be significant even though it is small. See Werden, Market Delineation, supra note 10, at 544.
    • A less important addition is in the words "at least." The authors probably realized that a "large and significant increase in price" would also be sufficient. Technically, they could have achieved the same goal by suppressing the words "small but." According to Werden, "The word 'small' must have been intended to indicate that a price increase can be significant even though it is small." See Werden, Market Delineation, supra note 10, at 544.
  • 21
    • 66849118053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One practical area where the difference is important is when the HMD is operationalized through critical loss analysis in real-world cases. There it can lead to approaches that are inconsistent with the HMD, as also noted by Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro, Improving Critical Loss Analysis, ANTITRUST SOURCE, Feb. 2008, at p. 3
    • One practical area where the difference is important is when the HMD is operationalized through critical loss analysis in real-world cases. There it can lead to approaches that are inconsistent with the HMD, as also noted by Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro, Improving Critical Loss Analysis, ANTITRUST SOURCE, Feb. 2008, at p. 3, http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/at-source/08/02/02-08.html.
  • 22
    • 66849105514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gregory J. Werden, MARKET DELINEATION ALGORITHMS BASED ON THE HYPOTHETICAL MONOPOLIST PARADIGM, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, EAG Discussion Paper 02-8, August 2002.
    • Gregory J. Werden, MARKET DELINEATION ALGORITHMS BASED ON THE HYPOTHETICAL MONOPOLIST PARADIGM, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, EAG Discussion Paper 02-8, August 2002.
  • 23
    • 66849130400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In principle, it is possible that insiders produce some outside products at the same time, which would raise specific problems for the profit maximization by the hypothetical monopolist who is supposed to keep the prices of those outside products constant. We abstract from this possibility here
    • In principle, it is possible that insiders produce some outside products at the same time, which would raise specific problems for the profit maximization by the hypothetical monopolist who is supposed to keep the prices of those outside products constant. We abstract from this possibility here.
  • 25
    • 66849092695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The power set of a set is the set of all its subsets. Thus, groups of products are elements of the power set
    • The power set of a set is the set of all its subsets. Thus, groups of products are elements of the power set.
  • 26
    • 66849140043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A partition of a set is a collectively exhaustive and mutually exclusive division of that set into subsets
    • A partition of a set is a collectively exhaustive and mutually exclusive division of that set into subsets.
  • 27
    • 66849118052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An example of this partitioning of the universe in the geographical dimension can be found in the investigation by the Mexican Federal Competition Commission of the distribution of liquid petroleum gas, in which the national territory was split up into thirty-seven regions considered to be the relevant markets. Comisión Federal de Competencia, Declaración de inexistencia de condiciones de competencia efectiva en el mercado de distribución del gas licuado de petróleo, Gaceta de Competencia Económica, Año 6, núm. 16, mayo-agosto 2003, pp. 275-342
    • An example of this partitioning of the universe in the geographical dimension can be found in the investigation by the Mexican Federal Competition Commission of the distribution of liquid petroleum gas, in which the national territory was split up into thirty-seven regions considered to be the relevant markets. Comisión Federal de Competencia, Declaración de inexistencia de condiciones de competencia efectiva en el mercado de distribución del gas licuado de petróleo, Gaceta de Competencia Económica, Año 6, núm. 16, mayo-agosto 2003, pp. 275-342.
  • 28
    • 66849110263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This point was also made in Gunnar Niels, The SSNIP Test: Some Common Misperceptions, 3:4 COMP. L. J. 267 2004
    • This point was also made in Gunnar Niels, The SSNIP Test: Some Common Misperceptions, 3:4 COMP. L. J. 267 (2004).
  • 29
    • 66849110266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A minor addition is that our version of the HMD not only assumes that the terms of sale of all outside products are held constant (as in the original version) but also that the terms of sale of inside products outside the area are kept at the pre-merger level, an assumption that is absent from the official version of the HMD
    • A minor addition is that our version of the HMD not only assumes that the terms of sale of all outside products are held constant (as in the original version) but also that the terms of sale of inside products outside the area are kept at the pre-merger level, an assumption that is absent from the official version of the HMD.
  • 30
    • 2342562169 scopus 로고
    • New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust, 90
    • See
    • See Robert Pitofsky, New Definitions of Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust, 90 COLUM. L. REV. 1805 (1991).
    • (1991) COLUM. L. REV. 1805
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 31
    • 66849112803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is important to note that these three factors are interrelated. In the theory of consumer demand, demand reduction is expressed in terms of own-elasticities and substitution between products in terms of cross-elasticities. In a Marshallian demand system, the own-elasticity of a product (taken as a positive number) equals one plus the relative-share-weighted sum of its cross elasticities.
    • It is important to note that these three factors are interrelated. In the theory of consumer demand, demand reduction is expressed in terms of own-elasticities and substitution between products in terms of cross-elasticities. In a Marshallian demand system, the own-elasticity of a product (taken as a positive number) equals one plus the relative-share-weighted sum of its cross elasticities.
  • 32
    • 66849116532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the so-called adding-up restriction derived from the budget constraint. See, e.g, ANGUS DEATON & JOHN MUELLBAUER, ECONOMICS AND CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Cambridge University Press, 1980
    • This is the so-called adding-up restriction derived from the budget constraint. See, e.g., ANGUS DEATON & JOHN MUELLBAUER, ECONOMICS AND CONSUMER BEHAVIOR (Cambridge University Press, 1980).
  • 33
    • 66849120823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Par. 1.0 of the Guidelines.
    • Par. 1.0 of the Guidelines.
  • 34
    • 66849090727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The failure of earlier Guidelines to address the issue of price reactions of outside products rendered their market definitions indeterminate. This holds for both the break-even and the profit-maximizing versions of the HMD
    • The failure of earlier Guidelines to address the issue of price reactions of outside products rendered their market definitions indeterminate. This holds for both the break-even and the profit-maximizing versions of the HMD.
  • 35
    • 66849085469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gregory J. Werden, MARKET DELINEATION ALGORITHMS BASED ON THE HYPOTHETICAL MONOPOLIST PARADIGM, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, EAG Discussion Paper 02-8, August 2002.
    • See Gregory J. Werden, MARKET DELINEATION ALGORITHMS BASED ON THE HYPOTHETICAL MONOPOLIST PARADIGM, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, EAG Discussion Paper 02-8, August 2002.
  • 36
    • 66849098659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Additionally, if sufficient data were available to approximate the level of normal profits, one might as well use this data to determine market power directly that is, market power defined as the ability to sustain profits above the competitive level for a significant period, and skip the intermediate stage of market delineation altogether. See Neils, supra note 25
    • Additionally, if sufficient data were available to approximate the level of normal profits, one might as well use this data to determine market power directly (that is, market power defined as the ability to sustain profits above the competitive level for a significant period), and skip the intermediate stage of market delineation altogether. See Neils, supra note 25.
  • 37
    • 66849083051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is so unless outsiders were firms with infinite supply elasticities; keeping their prices fixed would be at odds with profit maximization and they might even incur losses
    • This is so unless outsiders were firms with infinite supply elasticities; keeping their prices fixed would be at odds with profit maximization and they might even incur losses.
  • 38
    • 66849127276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Here we assumed that the prices of outside products are also at marginal cost and are kept at that level post-merger. If one would have assumed that the pre-merger prices of all the outside products are at their Bertrand equilibrium level, the results would have been even more dramatic. In fact, the price increase after the (non)merger would already be significant for values of d below twenty
    • Here we assumed that the prices of outside products are also at marginal cost and are kept at that level post-merger. If one would have assumed that the pre-merger prices of all the outside products are at their Bertrand equilibrium level, the results would have been even more dramatic. In fact, the price increase after the (non)merger would already be significant for values of d below twenty.
  • 39
    • 66849108202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To get an idea of how substitutable the products are at d = 10, consider the case in which all prices are at forty and all quantities at sixty. From that position, an increase in the price for one of the products by one unit - that is, by 2.5 percent - would induce a decline in demand for that product of twenty-one units, of which one unit is demand reduction and twenty units - that is, one-third of the demand before the increase - leak away to the substitutes. In such circumstances, every brand of every product would constitute a relevant market by itself, and a merger between two firms producing different brands of the same product would not even be considered to have horizontal overlaps.
    • To get an idea of how substitutable the products are at d = 10, consider the case in which all prices are at forty and all quantities at sixty. From that position, an increase in the price for one of the products by one unit - that is, by 2.5 percent - would induce a decline in demand for that product of twenty-one units, of which one unit is demand reduction and twenty units - that is, one-third of the demand before the increase - leak away to the substitutes. In such circumstances, every brand of every product would constitute a relevant market by itself, and a merger between two firms producing different brands of the same product would not even be considered to have horizontal overlaps.
  • 40
    • 66849137395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Due to the symmetry assumption, it is not clear which of the two products should join the original product in its relevant market. However, a small tremble in the parameters would be sufficient to break the tie
    • Due to the symmetry assumption, it is not clear which of the two products should join the original product in its relevant market. However, a small tremble in the parameters would be sufficient to break the tie.
  • 41
    • 66849090729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The two-to-one relation between break-even and optimal prices was mentioned in Werden, Market Delineation, supra note 10, at 543, and more recently in Farrell & Shapiro, supra note 17, at 17.
    • The two-to-one relation between break-even and optimal prices was mentioned in Werden, Market Delineation, supra note 10, at 543, and more recently in Farrell & Shapiro, supra note 17, at 17.
  • 42
    • 66849088576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that we are not advocating that the definition of the relevant market for antitrust purposes should only depend on demand substitution factors; see further below
    • Note that we are not advocating that the definition of the relevant market for antitrust purposes should only depend on demand substitution factors; see further below.
  • 43
    • 66849134017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The prices of complements would go down
    • The prices of complements would go down.
  • 44
    • 66849103230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DEATON & MUELLBAUER, supra note 27; at ch. 1.2.
    • See DEATON & MUELLBAUER, supra note 27; at ch. 1.2.
  • 45
    • 66849090728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Occasionally, the second or third next best substitute may be sufficient to reach the cut-off level
    • Occasionally, the second or third next best substitute may be sufficient to reach the cut-off level.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.