메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 34, Issue 1, 2010, Pages 171-244

Google and the limits of antitrust: The case against the case against Google

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 80052708417     PISSN: 01934872     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (82)

References (230)
  • 1
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., D. C. Cir, en banc per curiam
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D. C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam).
    • (2001) F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 2
    • 80055045655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Complaint, In re Intel Corp., No. 9341, Dec. 16, 2009, The case was eventually settled
    • Complaint, In re Intel Corp., No. 9341, FTC (Dec. 16, 2009), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9341/091216intelcmpt.pdf, The case was eventually settled.
  • 3
    • 80055026870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intel Corp., No. 9341, Oct. 29, 2010
    • See In re Intel Corp., No. 9341, FTC (Oct. 29, 2010), http://www.ftc.gov/os/adjpro/d9341/101102inteldo.pdf.
  • 4
    • 80055049971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust, Christine Varney, has suggested that Google, in particular, is of concern to the government. Christine Varney, U. S. Asst. Att'y Gen for Antitrust, Remarks Before the American Antitrust Institute (Feb. 11, 2008), available at http://www.antitrustinstitute. org/files/20080619-pv-aai061908holemanbreakout-020320091323.mp3.
  • 6
    • 77955392207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Linkline Commc'ns, Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1109, 1113-14 (2009) ("Recognizing a price-squeeze claim where the defendant's retail price remains above cost would invite the precise harm we sought to avoid in Brooke Group: Firms might raise their retail prices or refrain from aggressive price competition to avoid potential antitrust liability" and finding it "most troubling [that] firms that seek to avoid price-squeeze liability will have no safe harbor for their pricing practices.").
    • (2009) S. Ct. , vol.129 , pp. 1109
  • 7
    • 3042777706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does antitrust policy improve consumer welfare? Assessing the evidence
    • Robert W. Crandall & Clifford Winston, Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the Evidence 17 J. ECON. PERSP. 3 (2003). In the Microsoft context
    • (2003) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.17 , pp. 3
    • Crandall, R.W.1    Winston, C.2
  • 8
    • 67649185605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mandatory contracting remedies in the american and european microsoft cases
    • see also William H. Page, Mandatory Contracting Remedies in the American and European Microsoft Cases, 75 ANTITRUST L. J. 787 (2008);
    • (2008) Antitrust L. J. , vol.75 , pp. 787
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 9
    • 67649218576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring compliance with compulsory licensing remedies in the american microsoft case
    • William H. Page & Seldon J. Childers, Measuring Compliance with Compulsory Licensing Remedies in the American Microsoft Case, 76 ANTITRUST L. J. 239 (2009);
    • (2009) Antitrust L. J. , vol.76 , pp. 239
    • Page, W.H.1    Childers, S.J.2
  • 10
    • 67649195316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Software development as an antitrust remedy: Lessons from the enforcement of the microsoft communications protocol licensing requirement
    • William H. Page & Seldon J. Childers, Software Development as an Antitrust Remedy: Lessons from the Enforcement of the Microsoft Communications Protocol Licensing Requirement, 14 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REV. 77 (2008).
    • (2008) Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. , vol.14 , pp. 77
    • Page, W.H.1    Childers, S.J.2
  • 11
    • 57849094991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unlocking technology: Antitrust and innovation
    • Daniel F. Spulber, Unlocking Technology: Antitrust and Innovation, 4 J. COMP. L. & ECON. 915 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Comp. L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 915
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 12
    • 0348126262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusivity in network industries
    • 674-75
    • See, e.g., Carl Shapiro, Exclusivity In Network Industries, 7 GEO. mason l. rev. 673, 674-75 (1999).
    • (1999) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 673
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 14
    • 0033410755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decision theory and antitrust rules
    • C. Frederick Beckner & Steven C. Salop, Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules, 67 Antitrust L. J. 41 (1999);
    • (1999) Antitrust L. J. , vol.67 , pp. 41
    • Beckner, C.F.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 15
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The limits of antitrust
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1 (1984);
    • (1984) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 1
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 16
    • 17244378477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing antitrust rules for assessing unilateral practices: A Neo-Chicago approach
    • David S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A Neo-Chicago Approach, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 73 (2005);
    • (2005) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 73
    • Evans, D.S.1    Padilla, A.J.2
  • 17
    • 24644465518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference
    • Luke Froeb et al., Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 639 (2005);
    • (2005) Int'L J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 639
    • Froeb, L.1
  • 18
    • 0035730228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying law and policy: A decision-theoretic approach
    • Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision-Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L. J. 469 (2001);
    • (2001) Antitrust L. J. , vol.69 , pp. 469
    • Hylton, K.N.1    Salinger, M.2
  • 19
  • 20
    • 80055026487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This conflation of activity level with success has come from a number of sources, including then-presidential candidate Barack Obama. See Barack Obama, Senator, Statement to the American Antitrust Institute (Nov. 5, 2009), available at http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/archives/files/aai- %20Presidential%20campaign%20-%20Obama%209-07-092720071759.pdf (promising to "reinvigorate antitrust enforcement" and asserting that the activity level of enforcement during the Bush administration caused negative consequences for consumers). Officials also have largely repudiated the well-accepted error-cost framework. The FTC Chairman and Commissioner declared that "there is no such thing as a false positive."
  • 22
    • 80055059066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner defined the "New Economy" to denote the rise of three industries: Manufacture of computer software, Internet-based business, and communication services. Richard A. Posner
    • Univ. of Chi. Law Sch., John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper No. 106
    • Judge Richard A. Posner defined the "New Economy" to denote the rise of three industries: manufacture of computer software, Internet-based business, and communication services. Richard A. Posner, Antitrust in the New Economy 2 (Univ. of Chi. Law Sch., John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper No. 106, 2000), available at http://www.law.uchicago.edu/files/files/106.Posner. pdf.
    • (2000) Antitrust in the New Economy , vol.2
    • Richard, A.J.1
  • 24
    • 80055048975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, U. S. Dep't of Justice, Justice Department Withdraws Report on Antitrust Monopoly Law May 11, 2009
    • See Press Release, U. S. Dep't of Justice, Justice Department Withdraws Report on Antitrust Monopoly Law (May 11, 2009), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press-releases/2009/245710.htm.
  • 25
    • 67249125922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust law and regulatory gaming
    • 700-03, discussing the costs of false positives and false negatives
    • See, e.g., Stacey L. Dogan & Mark A. Lemley, Antitrust Law and Regulatory Gaming, 87 TEX. L. REV. 685, 700-03 (2009) (discussing the costs of false positives and false negatives).
    • (2009) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 685
    • Dogan, S.L.1    Lemley, M.A.2
  • 26
    • 0042648955 scopus 로고
    • Workable antitrust policy
    • There are two separate points here. The first is the inevitability of errors with decision by legal rule generally. See Easterbrook, supra note 10, at 14-15 (reiterating that "[o]ne cannot have the savings of decision by rule without accepting the costs of mistakes"). The second point is that the likelihood of antitrust error depends crucially on the development of economic science to produce techniques and methods by which we can successfully identify conduct that harms consumers. See Frank H. Easterbrook, Workable Antitrust Policy, 84 MICH. L. REV. 1696, 1712 (1986).
    • (1986) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1696
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 27
    • 84882337096 scopus 로고
    • This point is most often attributed to then-Judge Breyer's well-known admonition that antitrust rules "must be administratively workable and therefore cannot always take account of every complex economic circumstance or qualification. " Town of Concord v. Bos. Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 22 (1st Cir. 1990). But the Chicago School of antitrust has traditionally shared with Breyer's Harvard School a preference for using economics to generate simple and administrable rules rather than overly sophisticated economic tests.
    • (1990) F.2d , vol.915 , pp. 17
  • 28
    • 70349096585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The intellectual DNA of modern U. S. competition law for dominant firm conduct: The Chicago/Harvard double helix
    • 32-35
    • See William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U. S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 32-35;
    • (2007) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , pp. 1
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 29
    • 47049093858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The roberts court and the Chicago school of antitrust: The 2006 term and beyond
    • 37
    • Joshua D. Wright, The Roberts Court and the Chicago School of Antitrust: The 2006 Term and Beyond, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 25, 37 (2007).
    • (2007) Competition Pol'Y Int'L , vol.3 , pp. 25
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 30
    • 80055042452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 10
    • Easterbrook, supra note 10, at 18.
    • Easterbrook , pp. 18
  • 31
    • 70349199464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overshot the mark? A simple explanation of the Chicago school's influence on antitrust
    • Joshua D. Wright, Overshot the Mark? A Simple Explanation of the Chicago School's Influence on Antitrust, 5 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 179 (2009).
    • (2009) Competition Pol'Y Int'L , vol.5 , pp. 179
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 32
    • 24644465518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference
    • See James C. Cooper et al., Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 639 (2005);
    • (2005) Int'L J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 639
    • Cooper, J.C.1
  • 33
    • 80055061119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law and economics of monopolization standards
    • Keith N. Hylton ed., 2d ed
    • see also Keith N. Hylton, The Law and Economics of Monopolization Standards, in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS 82 (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2d ed. 2010).
    • (2010) Antitrust Law and Economics , pp. 82
    • Hylton, K.N.1
  • 34
    • 57049133680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive contracts and vertical restraints: Empirical evidence and public policy
    • Multiple academics review the existing theory and evidence on vertical restraints and single-firm conduct more generally and uniformly conclude that the practices at issue are generally procompetitive and that antitrust rules should "slant" towards requiring plaintiffs to demonstrate clear anticompetitive effect before condemning finding violations. See, e.g., Cooper et al., supra note 24; Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Exclusive Contracts and Vertical Restraints: Empirical Evidence and Public Policy, in HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 391 (Paolo Buccirossi ed., 2008);
    • (2008) Handbook of Antitrust Economics , pp. 391
    • Lafontaine, F.1    Slade, M.2
  • 35
    • 77955907787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The antitrust treatment of vertical restraints: Beyond the possibility of theorems
    • Swedish Competition Auth. ed
    • Daniel P. O'Brien, The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints: Beyond the Possibility of Theorems, in THE PROS AND CONS OF VERTICAL RESTRAINTS 40 (Swedish Competition Auth. ed., 2008), available at http://www.konkurrensverket. se/upload/Filer/Trycksaker/Rapporter/Pros&Cons/rap-pros-and-cons-vertical- restraints.pdf.
    • (2008) The Pros and Cons of Vertical Restraints , pp. 40
    • O'Brien, D.P.1
  • 36
    • 80055039446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is antitrust too complicated for generalist judges? The impact of economic complexity & judicial training on appeals
    • See generally Michael R. Baye & Joshua D. Wright, Is Antitrust Too Complicated for Generalist Judges? The Impact of Economic Complexity & Judicial Training on Appeals, J. L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2010) (finding a statistically significant tendency for economically trained judges to perform better in simple antitrust cases, but not those involving sophisticated economic evidence).
    • (2010) J. L. & Econ.
    • Baye, M.R.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 38
    • 80055035471 scopus 로고
    • Report of the white house task force on antitrust policy
    • 14-15, 65-76
    • Phil C. Neal et al., Report of the White House Task Force on Antitrust Policy, 2 ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. 11, 14-15, 65-76 (1968-1969).
    • (1968) Antitrust L. & Econ. Rev. , vol.2 , pp. 11
    • Neal, P.C.1
  • 39
    • 84878093039 scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co.
    • FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U. S. 568 (1967);
    • (1967) U. S. , vol.386 , pp. 568
  • 40
    • 84873647722 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Pabst Brewing Co.
    • United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U. S. 546 (1966);
    • (1966) U. S. , vol.384 , pp. 546
  • 41
    • 0347414384 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Von's Grocery Co.
    • United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U. S. 270 (1966);
    • (1966) U. S. , vol.384 , pp. 270
  • 42
    • 0039027645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust policy: A century of legal and economic thinking
    • 51-52
    • see also William E. Kovacic & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Policy: A Century of Legal and Economic Thinking, 14 J. ECON. PERSP. 43, 51-52 (2000);
    • (2000) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.14 , pp. 43
    • Kovacic, W.E.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 43
    • 84977355595 scopus 로고
    • The influence of economics on antitrust law
    • 295-96, describing the features of the U. S. competition policy system that give economists a major role in shaping antitrust rules
    • William E. Kovacic, The Influence of Economics on Antitrust Law, 30 J. ECON. INQUIRY 294, 295-96 (1992) (describing the features of the U. S. competition policy system that give economists a major role in shaping antitrust rules).
    • (1992) J. Econ. Inquiry , vol.30 , pp. 294
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 45
    • 0347414384 scopus 로고
    • 384 U. S. 270 (1966).
    • (1966) U. S. , vol.384 , pp. 270
  • 46
    • 80055026676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commissioner rosch, rhetoric, and the relationship between economics and antitrust
    • June 12, 11:55 AM
    • See Joshua Wright, Commissioner Rosch, Rhetoric, and the Relationship Between Economics and Antitrust, TRUTH ON THE MARKET (June 12, 2009, 11:55 AM), http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2009/06/12/commissioner-rosch-rhetoric-andthe- relationship-between-economics-and-antitrust/;
    • (2009) Truth on the Market
    • Wright, J.1
  • 47
    • 0003241064 scopus 로고
    • Industrial organization: A proposal for research
    • 67 Victor R. Fuchs, ed., For more modern critiques of the industrial organization literature in the same vein
    • Ronald H. Coase, Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in POLICY ISSUES AND RESEARCH OPPORTUNITIES IN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 59, 67 (Victor R. Fuchs, ed., 1972). For more modern critiques of the industrial organization literature in the same vein
    • (1972) Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization , pp. 59
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 48
    • 0346746606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Game theory and antitrust: A post mortem
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi, Game Theory and Antitrust: A Post Mortem, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 411 (1997);
    • (1997) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 411
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 49
    • 1442354820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics and antitrust
    • Timothy J. Muris, Economics and Antitrust, 5 GEO. MASON. L. REV. 303 (1997).
    • (1997) Geo. Mason. L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 303
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 50
    • 70350145065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 32 (2007) (recommending that "in industries where innovation, intellectual property, and technological change are central features... antitrust enforcers should carefully consider market dynamics in assessing competitive effects").
    • (2007) Antitrust Modernization Comm'N, Report and Recommendations , pp. 32
  • 51
    • 80055037427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Information, capital markets, and planned development: An essay
    • Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright eds.
    • See, e.g., Robert Cooter, Information, Capital Markets, and Planned Development: An Essay, in REGULATING INNOVATION: COMPETITION POLICY AND PATENT LAW UNDER UNCERTAINTY (Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright eds., forthcoming 2011), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract- id=1462489;
    • (2011) Regulating Innovation: Competition Policy and Patent Law Under Uncertainty
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 52
    • 84924650699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust, multi-dimensional competition, and innovation: Do we have an antitrust relevant theory of competition now?
    • Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright eds.
    • Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust, Multi-Dimensional Competition, and Innovation: Do We Have An Antitrust Relevant Theory of Competition Now?, in REGULATING INNOVATION: COMPETITION POLICY AND PATENT LAW UNDER UNCERTAINTY (Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright eds., forthcoming 2011), available at http://papers/ssrn.com/sol3/papers/cfm?abstract-id=142489.
    • (2011) Regulating Innovation: Competition Policy and Patent Law Under Uncertainty
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 54
    • 70349790701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition and innovation
    • Richard J. Gilbert, Competition and Innovation, in 1 ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY 577, 583 (W. Dale Collins ed., 2008) ("Economic theory does not provide unambiguous support either for the view that market power generally threatens innovation by lowering the return to innovative efforts or for the Schumpeterian view that concentrated markets generally promote innovation. ").
    • (2008) Issues in Competition Law and Policy , vol.1 , pp. 577
    • Gilbert, R.J.1
  • 56
    • 31944442162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • July 15
    • see also Timothy J. Muris, Comments on Antitrust Law, Economics, and Bundled Discounts 7 (July 15, 2005), available at http://govinfo.library.unt. edu/amc/commission-hearings/pdf/Muris.pdf ("In the same way that a visitor from Mars who reads only the mathematical IO literature could mistakenly conclude that the U. S. economy is rife with monopoly power, it would be a mistake to infer that the growing volume of theoretical papers examining bundling or bundled rebates as an exclusionary device implies that there is any growing or significant danger from the anticompetitive use of bundling.").
    • (2005) Comments on Antitrust Law, Economics, and Bundled Discounts , pp. 7
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 57
    • 0000145602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring the social return to R&D
    • See, e.g., Charles I. Jones & John C. Williams, Measuring the Social Return to R&D, 113 Q. J. ECON. 1119 (1998) (estimating that the social return to research and development investment far exceeds the private return, meaning existing incentives for innovation are already lower than optimal).
    • (1998) Q. J. Econ. , vol.113 , pp. 1119
    • Jones, C.I.1    Williams, J.C.2
  • 58
    • 0001426594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valuation of new goods under perfect and imperfect competition
    • Timothy F. Bresnahan & Robert J. Gordon eds.
    • See Jerry A. Hausman, Valuation of New Goods under Perfect and Imperfect Competition, in THE ECONOMICS OF NEW GOODS 209 (Timothy F. Bresnahan & Robert J. Gordon eds., 1997);
    • (1997) The Economics of New Goods , pp. 209
    • Hausman, J.A.1
  • 60
    • 0000438997 scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory
    • 212
    • Armen A. Alchian, Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory, 58 J. POL. ECON. 211, 212 (1950).
    • (1950) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.58 , pp. 211
    • Alchian, A.A.1
  • 61
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., D. C. Cir, en banc per curiam
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D. C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam).
    • (2001) F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 62
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 407, 2004
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U. S. 398, 407 (2004).
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
  • 63
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Microsoft
    • See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 50-58.
    • F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 50-58
  • 64
    • 80055053306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. D. Cal. Mar. 16, 2007
    • Google already has defended several private antitrust suits-surely this will not be the last. See, e.g., Kinderstart.com, LLC v. Google, Inc., No. C06-2057JF (RS), 2007 WL 831806 (N. D. Cal. Mar. 16, 2007).
    • (2007) WL 831806
  • 65
    • 32644489299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Managing Google's idea factory
    • Oct. 3
    • See, e.g., Ben Elgin, Managing Google's Idea Factory, BUSINESSWEEK (Oct. 3, 2005), http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/contents/05-40/63953093.htm.
    • (2005) Businessweek
    • Elgin, B.1
  • 66
    • 80055031964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yahoo-google deal doomed? No, they insist
    • Oct. 21
    • See, e.g., Stephen Shankland, Yahoo-Google Deal Doomed? No, They Insist, CNET. COM NEWS, Oct. 21, 2008, http://news.cnet.com/8301-1023-3-10071478-93. html.
    • (2008) Cnet. Com News
    • Shankland, S.1
  • 67
    • 80055040073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FCC on apple, DOJ on Google - The feds are tackling tech
    • Sept. 19
    • Paul Suarez, FCC on Apple, DOJ on Google - the Feds are Tackling Tech, PC WORLD (Sept. 19, 2009), http://www.pcworld.com/article/172295/fcc-on-apple-doj- on-google-the-feds-are-tackling-tech.html.
    • (2009) Pc World
    • Suarez, P.1
  • 68
    • 77953254420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Justice Dept. Opens antitrust inquiry into google books deal
    • Apr. 29
    • Miguel Helft, Justice Dept. Opens Antitrust Inquiry Into Google Books Deal, N. Y. TIMES, Apr. 29, 2010, at B5, available at http://www.nytimes.com/ 2009/04/29/technology/internet/29google.html. Note the DOJ's brief in the case, the court's grant of a delay and ongoing renegotiations.
    • (2010) N. Y. Times
    • Helft, M.1
  • 69
    • 41849100459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Google deal said to bring U. S. Scrutiny
    • May 29
    • Steve Lohr, Google Deal Said to Bring U. S. Scrutiny, N. Y. TIMES, May 29, 2007, at C1, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2007/05/29/technology/ 29antitrust.html;
    • (2007) N. Y. Times
    • Lohr, S.1
  • 70
    • 80055056751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Fed. Trade Comm'n Closes Google/DoubleClick Investigation Dec. 20, 2007
    • Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Fed. Trade Comm'n Closes Google/DoubleClick Investigation (Dec. 20, 2007), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2007/12/googledc.shtm.
  • 71
    • 80055029051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, FTC Closes its Investigation of Google AdMob Deal May 21, 2010
    • Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, FTC Closes its Investigation of Google AdMob Deal (May 21, 2010), available at http://ftc.gov/opa/2010/05/ggladmob. shtm.
  • 72
    • 80055033813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kinderstart.com, LLC v. Google, Inc., No. C06-2057JF RS, N. D. Cal. Mar. 16, 2007
    • See Kinderstart.com, LLC v. Google, Inc., No. C06-2057JF (RS), 2007 WL 831806 (N. D. Cal. Mar. 16, 2007).
    • (2007) WL 831806
  • 73
    • 78149444726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The plot to kill google
    • Jan. 19
    • Nicholas Thompson & Fred Vogelstein, The Plot to Kill Google, WIRED (Jan. 19, 2009), http://www.wired.com/techbiz/it/magazine/17-02/ff-killgoogle.
    • (2009) Wired
    • Thompson, N.1    Vogelstein, F.2
  • 74
    • 0002734011 scopus 로고
    • The economics of information
    • On the economics of information, economists have progressed little since Professor George Stigler's important account of the economics of information and the importance of search-of obvious salience here. See George J. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69 J. POL. ECON. 213 (1961). Although much of the economics of networks and information technology has made important advances, Professor Stigler's (and Freidrich von Hayek's) fundamental point that information is a good like any other, subject to the economics of scarcity, still undergirds our understanding today.
    • (1961) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.69 , pp. 213
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 75
    • 27844557556 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Grinnel Corp., 571
    • United States v. Grinnel Corp., 384 U. S. 563, 571 (1966).
    • (1966) U. S. , vol.384 , pp. 563
  • 78
    • 80055061342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • last visited Nov. 6, 2010
    • Results Page, GOOGLEGUIDE, http://www.googleguide.com/results-page.html (last visited Nov. 6, 2010).
    • Results Page
  • 79
    • 80055039445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • last visited Nov. 6, 2010
    • Ads, GOOGLEGUIDE, http://googleguide.com/ads.html (last visited Nov. 6, 2010).
    • Ads
  • 80
    • 80055049592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 73
    • Results, supra note 73.
    • Results
  • 81
    • 80055044233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 74
    • Ads, supra note 74.
    • Ads
  • 84
    • 80055044079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introduction to google search quality
    • May 20, 2008, 6:20 PM
    • Udi Manber, Introduction to Google Search Quality, THE OFFICIAL GOOGLE BLOG (May 20, 2008, 6:20 PM), http://googleblog.blogspot.com/2008/05/ introduction-togoogle-search-quality.html.
    • The Official Google Blog
    • Manber, U.1
  • 86
    • 80055054360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 74
    • Ads, supra note 74.
    • Ads
  • 87
    • 80055060505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 84
    • JACOBSON, supra note 84.
    • Jacobson
  • 89
    • 80055028240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Search engine statistics for 2006-2007
    • Feb. 28
    • Search Engine Statistics for 2006-2007, ACCURACAST (Feb. 28, 2007), http://www.accuracast.com/seo-weekly/se-statistics.php.
    • (2007) Accuracast
  • 92
    • 80055043674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper No. 07-24, 2008
    • Robert W. Hahn & Hal J. Singer, An Antitrust Analysis of Google's Proposed Acquisition of DoubleClick 5, 24-32 (AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper No. 07-24, 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1016189.
    • An Antitrust Analysis of Google's Proposed Acquisition of Doubleclick , vol.5 , pp. 24-32
    • Hahn, R.W.1    Singer, H.J.2
  • 93
    • 80055033813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KinderStart.com LLC v. Google, Inc., No. C06-2057JF RS, N. D. Cal. Mar. 16, 2007
    • *6 (N. D. Cal. Mar. 16, 2007) (noting that "there is no logical basis for distinguishing the Search Ad Market from the larger market for Internet advertising");
    • (2007) WL 831806 , pp. 6
  • 94
    • 80055061753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Person v. Google Inc., S. D. N. Y
    • Person v. Google Inc., 456 F. Supp. 2d. 488 (S. D. N. Y. 2006).
    • (2006) F. Supp. 2D. , vol.456 , pp. 488
  • 96
    • 80055051202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pepsi's big gamble: Ditching super bowl for social media
    • Dec. 23
    • Larry D. Woodard, Pepsi's Big Gamble: Ditching Super Bowl for Social Media, ABC NEWS, Dec. 23, 2009, http://abcnews.go.com/print?id=9402514.
    • (2009) Abc News
    • Woodard, L.D.1
  • 97
    • 80055034664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Search engine advertising: Pricing ads to context
    • Avi Goldfarb & Catherine Tucker, Search Engine Advertising: Pricing Ads to Context 96 (NET Institute Working Paper No. 07-23, 2007), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1021451&rec=1&srcabs= 10084 (determining the price of "ambulance chaser" lawyer ads was significantly more expensive in states prohibiting direct mail solicitation by attorneys).
    • (2007) Net Institute Working Paper No. 07-23 , vol.96
    • Goldfarb, A.1    Tucker, C.2
  • 98
    • 80055059666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 72
    • AULETTA, supra note 72, at 16.
    • Auletta , pp. 16
  • 99
    • 12944289524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Local advertising decision makers' perceptions of media effectiveness and substitutability
    • Leonard N. Reid et al., Local Advertising Decision Makers' Perceptions of Media Effectiveness and Substitutability, 18 J. MEDIA ECON. 35 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Media Econ. , vol.18 , pp. 35
    • Reid, L.N.1
  • 100
    • 80055026302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Biggest online Ad spenders with adwords - Top PPC advertisers
    • And, not surprisingly, large national advertisers are among AdWords' top customers. During one thirty-day period in September 2009, the top five Ad-Words spenders included Progressive, Target, and Geico (the other two were Expedia and AOL, both of which have online-only presences). See Biggest Online Ad Spenders with Adwords - Top PPC Advertisers, FRUITION INTERNET MARKETING BLOG (Sept. 24, 2009), http://fruition.net/ppc-management/biggest-online-adspenders- with-adwords-top-ppc-advertisers/.
    • (2009) Fruition Internet Marketing Blog
  • 101
    • 75749148113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economics of the online advertising industry
    • 359-60
    • David S. Evans, The Economics of the Online Advertising Industry, 7 REV. OF NETWORK ECON. 359, 359-60 (2008).
    • (2008) Rev. of Network Econ. , vol.7 , pp. 359
    • Evans, D.S.1
  • 102
    • 80055064058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 99
    • See Woodard, supra note 99.
    • Woodard
  • 103
    • 80055040072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 72
    • AULETTA, supra note 72, at 172-73.
    • Auletta , pp. 172-173
  • 104
    • 80055039209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 74
    • Ads, supra note 74.
    • Ads
  • 105
    • 77958519098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Analyzing the relationship between organic and sponsored search advertising: Positive, negative or zero interdependence?
    • 603
    • Sha Yang & Anindya Ghose, Analyzing the Relationship Between Organic and Sponsored Search Advertising: Positive, Negative or Zero Interdependence?, 29 MARKETING SCI., 602, 603 (2010).
    • (2010) Marketing Sci. , vol.29 , pp. 602
    • Yang, S.1    Ghose, A.2
  • 107
    • 80055048780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Too organic for organic listing? Interplay between organic and sponsored listing in search advertising
    • Lizhen Xu et al., Too Organic for Organic Listing? Interplay Between Organic and Sponsored Listing in Search Advertising 1, 2-3 (McCombs Research Paper Series No. IROM-13-09, 2009), available at http://www.mccombs.utexas.edu/ news/research-calendar/IROM-Xu-10-16-09.pdf.
    • (2009) Mccombs Research Paper Series No. Irom-13-09 , vol.1 , pp. 2-3
    • Xu, L.1
  • 109
    • 80055050390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EBay.com site info
    • For example, in the thirty days ending on February 23, 2010, less than ten percent of visits to eBay.com originated from a search engine. See eBay.com Site Info, ALEXA, http://www.alexa.com/siteinfo/ebay.com (last visited Nov. 6, 2010).
    • Alexa
  • 110
    • 0034188463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How to acquire customers on the web
    • May-June, 5, 7
    • See Donna L. Hoffman & Thomas P. Novak, How to Acquire Customers on the Web, HARV. BUS. REV., May-June 2000, at 3, 5, 7.
    • (2000) Harv. Bus. Rev. , pp. 3
    • Hoffman, D.L.1    Novak, T.P.2
  • 112
    • 77955874600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hot docs vs. cold economics: The use and misuse of business documents in antitrust enforcement and adjudication
    • 610
    • See Geoffrey A. Manne & E. Marcellus Williamson, Hot Docs vs. Cold Economics: The Use and Misuse of Business Documents in Antitrust Enforcement and Adjudication, 47 ARIZ. L. REV. 609, 610 (2005).
    • (2005) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 609
    • Manne, G.A.1    Williamson, E.M.2
  • 113
    • 80055060505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 84
    • JACOBSON, supra note 84.
    • Jacobson
  • 115
    • 80055044079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introduction to google search quality
    • May 20, 6:20 PM
    • Udi Manber, Introduction to Google Search Quality, THE OFFICIAL GOOGLE BLOG (May 20, 2008, 6:20 PM), http://googleblog.blogspot.com/2008/05/ introductionto-google-search-quality.html.
    • (2008) The Official Google Blog
    • Manber, U.1
  • 116
    • 54949090093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal search commission? Access, fairness and accountability in the law of search
    • See, e.g., Oren Bracha & Frank Pasquale, Federal Search Commission? Access, Fairness and Accountability in the Law of Search, 93 CORNELL L. REV. 1149, 1181 (2008) ("Network Effects in Improving Search Responsiveness. The more searches an engine gets, the better able it is to sharpen and perfect its algorithm. The result is that each additional user decreases the cost of a better quality service for all users. Thus, incumbents with large numbers of users enjoy substantial advantages over smaller entrants.")
    • (2008) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 1149
    • Bracha, O.1    Pasquale, F.2
  • 118
    • 79957508900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preserving competition in multi-sided innovative markets: How do you solve a problem like google?
    • Kristine Laudadio Devine, Preserving Competition in Multi-Sided Innovative Markets: How Do You Solve a Problem Like Google?, 10 N. C. J. L. & TECH. 59 (2008) (describing Google's network effects by analogy and conjecture, although going into far more detail than any of the other articles cited);
    • (2008) N. C. J. L. & Tech. , vol.10 , pp. 59
    • Devine, K.L.1
  • 119
    • 84900291818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How to fix the google book search settlement
    • James Grimmelmann, How to Fix the Google Book Search Settlement, J. INTERNET L., Apr. 2009, at 1, 14 ("Thus, Google's first-past-the-post status here could easily turn into a durable monopoly. That might be the inevitable result anyway; this is a market with substantial economies of scale and positive network effects.");
    • (2009) J. Internet L. , pp. 1
    • Grimmelmann, J.1
  • 120
    • 74949088358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Knowledge accessibility and preservation policy for the digital age
    • 1052, listing "concentration due to network effects " on a table describing competitive effects in Google Book Search
    • Peter S. Menell, Knowledge Accessibility and Preservation Policy for the Digital Age, 44 HOUS. L. REV. 1013, 1052 (2007) (listing "concentration (due to network effects) " on a table describing competitive effects in Google Book Search);
    • (2007) Hous. L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 1013
    • Menell, P.S.1
  • 121
    • 77955494723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulating search
    • Viva R. Moffat, Regulating Search, 22 HARV. J. L. & TECH 475, 489 (2009) ("Additionally, while Google may not be a monopoly, it certainly has a great deal of market power and network effects also exist in the search world. These factors, together with the arguably substantial barriers to entry in the search engine market, permit the analogy to common carriers." (citing a New York Times article referring to "network advantages"));
    • (2009) Harv. J. L. & Tech , vol.22 , pp. 475
    • Moffat, V.R.1
  • 122
    • 80055054359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Watching over the web: A substantive equality regime for broadband applications
    • William D. Rahm, Watching over the Web: A Substantive Equality Regime for Broadband Applications, 24 YALE J. ON REG. 1, 16 (2007) ("Broadband technology exhibits two network effects.... Companies like Google, Vonage and Amazon will develop more services when they are confident that there are more users whom they can reach.");
    • (2007) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.24 , pp. 1
    • Rahm, W.D.1
  • 123
    • 33846828281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A consumer-welfare approach to network neutrality regulation of the internet
    • J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Network Neutrality Regulation of the Internet, 2 J. COMPETITIVE L. & ECON. 349, 454 (2006) ("Network effects make the market for Internet portals highly concentrated. Entry is difficult because a critical mass of users has chosen a particular portal (Yahoo! or Google) to begin their Internet experience. A critical mass of advertisers has followed.");
    • (2006) J. Competitive L. & Econ. , vol.2 , pp. 349
    • Sidak, J.G.1
  • 124
    • 70350460625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Only connect
    • Kevin Werbach, Only Connect, 22 BERKELEY TECH. L. J. 1233, 1292 (2007) ("Nonetheless, it is possible for applications to become exclusive platforms with anticompetitive effects similar to those of exclusive physical broadband networks. Google's dominant search engine and MySpace's massive social networking site might be candidates for such scrutiny at some point in the future. Because these are network-centric applications, whatever ability they have to distort competition and innovation arises from their ability to capture network effects.").
    • (2007) Berkeley Tech. L. J. , vol.22 , pp. 1233
    • Werbach, K.1
  • 125
    • 80055050597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defining markets that involve multi-sided platform businesses: An empirical framework with an application google's purchase of doubleclick
    • "[Multisided platforms] have business models that are not yet well understood and engage in highly complex business strategies; unusual practices are suspect practices in our experience." David S. Evans & Michael D. Noel, Defining Markets That Involve Multi-Sided Platform Businesses: An Empirical Framework With an Application Google's Purchase of DoubleClick 4 (AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 07-18, 2007), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1089073.
    • Aei-brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 07-18, 2007 , vol.4
    • Evans, D.S.1    Noel, M.D.2
  • 126
    • 0001606417 scopus 로고
    • Network externality: An uncommon tragedy
    • 135
    • Stan J. Liebowitz & Stephen E. Margolis, Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. 133, 135 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.8 , pp. 133
    • Liebowitz, S.J.1    Margolis, S.E.2
  • 127
    • 84897529763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Complaint ¶ 91, TradeComet. Com LLC v. Google, Inc., S. D. N. Y, No. 09Civ. 1400 SHS
    • Complaint ¶ 91, TradeComet. Com LLC v. Google, Inc., 693 F. Supp. 2d 370 (S. D. N. Y. 2009) (No. 09Civ. 1400 (SHS)).
    • (2009) F. Supp. 2d , vol.693 , pp. 370
  • 128
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This argument is analogized to a claim that received traction in the Microsoft litigation. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 54-55 (D. C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam) (finding monopoly power as a result of a "'chickenand-egg' situation [that] ensures that [software] applications will continue to be written for the already dominant Windows, which in turn ensures that consumers will continue to prefer it over other operating systems"). But the comparison is inapposite. In Microsoft, the incentives of platform users external to the platform itself were being driven by the feedback effect between sides of the network. Here the argument has the platform itself (Google) driving the incentives through investment. In the present case the network effect is endogenous and under Google's (or a competitor's) control. Conversely, in Microsoft the effect was exogenous and therefore difficult for competitors to disrupt.
    • (2001) F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 129
    • 80055033617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bing shopping
    • And of course "difficult" does not mean "impossible." Entrants could pay for new users, and they do so in a variety of creative ways. Microsoft, for example, introduced its "cashback" program on its Live Search (now Bing) search engine, offering end users who searched for and purchased products using Microsoft's search platform a discount on the purchased product. Bing Shopping, WIKIPEDIA, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bing- Shoppingashback-program (last visited Nov. 6, 2010);
    • Wikipedia
  • 130
    • 50549093002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer coordination in the small and in the large: Implications for antitrust in markets with network effects
    • 257-58
    • see Daniel F. Spulber, Consumer Coordination in the Small and in the Large: Implications for Antitrust in Markets with Network Effects, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 207, 257-58 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 207
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 131
    • 80055039015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • List of search engines
    • This makes especially troubling the unfounded and undocumented claims found in Bracha and Pasquale's Federal Search Commission paper. In explaining why they think "robust and dynamic competition [is] unlikely", and why the search engine market is subject to "high barriers to entry", the authors report that "[s]earch algorithms may be analogous to the high-cost infrastructure required for entry into the utility or railroad markets." Bracha & Pasquale, supra note 126, at 1180-81. At the same time, the authors argue that "[t]he more searches an engine gets, the better able it is to sharpen and perfect its algorithm." Id. The last point is not true, or at least not true beyond a minimum scale. And consequently, the claim that an algorithm is, in essence, a "natural monopoly" or essential facility (thus requiring regulatory or antitrust intervention to pry open access to competitors) is equally fallacious. While Google's specific algorithm is not accessible by competitors, it is not the case that another viable algorithm is inaccessible, nor the data sufficient to manage it. And, of course, in addition to Google's major competitors there are dozens of other search engines competing with Google's specific algorithm. See List of search engines, WIKIPEDIA, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List-of-search-engines (last visited Nov. 6, 2010).
    • Wikipedia
  • 132
    • 66049101414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects
    • Evidence demonstrates that thicker auctions result in higher prices, irrespective of the characteristics of additional bidders-a presumably undesirable consequence (to the bidders) of a broader network. See, e.g., Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-in: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects in 3 THE HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 2018 (M. Armstrong and R. Porter eds., 2007) ("Second, there may be no intra-group network effects; there may even be intra-group congestion. Thus, given the number of photographers, a developer prefers fewer other developers for competitive reasons, just as with merchants accepting credit cards.");
    • (2007) The Handbook of Industrial Organization , vol.3 , pp. 2018
    • Farrell, J.1    Klemperer, P.2
  • 133
    • 0002654730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What really matters in auction design
    • 172
    • Paul Klemperer, What Really Matters in Auction Design, 16 J. ECON. PERSP. 169, 172 (2002).
    • (2002) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.16 , pp. 169
    • Klemperer, P.1
  • 134
    • 70649103630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U. S. C. § 2 (2006).
    • (2006) U. S. C. , vol.15 , pp. 2
  • 135
    • 80055025875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 31, "The bare language of the Sherman Act conveys little...."
    • BORK, supra note 31, at 57 ("The bare language of the Sherman Act conveys little....");
    • Bork , pp. 57
  • 136
    • 0039031297 scopus 로고
    • Vertical arrangements and the rule of reason
    • 136, "The language of the Sherman Act governs no real cases."
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, Vertical Arrangements and the Rule of Reason, 53 ANTITRUST L. J. 135, 136 (1984) ("The language of the Sherman Act governs no real cases.");
    • (1984) Antitrust L. J. , vol.53 , pp. 135
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 137
    • 29144513634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Section two of the sherman act: The search for standards
    • Thomas E. Kauper, Section Two of the Sherman Act: The Search for Standards, 93 GEO. L. J. 1623, 1623 (2005) ("Section Two of the Sherman Act has been a source of puzzlement to lawyers, judges and scholars, a puzzlement derived in large part from the statute's extraordinary brevity.").
    • (2005) Geo. L. J. , vol.93 , pp. 1623
    • Kauper, T.E.1
  • 138
    • 27844557556 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U. S. 563, 570-571 (1965).
    • (1965) U. S. , vol.384 , pp. 563
  • 140
    • 70349213021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing as competition "on the merits"
    • See Benjamin Klein, Exclusive Dealing as Competition "On the Merits", 12 GEO. MASON L. REV. 119 (2003).
    • (2003) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12 , pp. 119
    • Klein, B.1
  • 141
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., D. C. Cir, en banc per curiam
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D. C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam).
    • (2001) F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 142
    • 70349209871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust decisions of the U. S. supreme court, 1967 to 2007
    • Leah Brannon & Douglas H. Ginsburg, Antitrust Decisions of the U. S. Supreme Court, 1967 to 2007, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 3 (2007). Brannon and Ginsburg, for example, find that from 1997 to 2006, eighty-five percent of all antitrust decisions were decided by a supermajority margin (and each in favor of the defendant, although this is fairly predictable given the proplaintiff nature of 1960s antitrust jurisprudence). Id. at 20. When one considers the Supreme Court decisions during the Bush administration, for example, the aggregate vote count is 86-9 with seven of eleven opinions generating unanimous agreement.
    • (2007) Competition Pol'Y Int'L , vol.3 , pp. 3
    • Brannon, L.1    Ginsburg, D.H.2
  • 143
    • 84883097786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 525 U. S. 128 (1998).
    • (1998) U. S. , vol.525 , pp. 128
  • 144
    • 77955392207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Linkline Cmmc'ns, Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1109 (2009);
    • (2009) S. Ct. , vol.129 , pp. 1109
  • 145
    • 84875104859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U. S. 312 (2007);
    • (2007) U. S. , vol.549 , pp. 312
  • 146
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U. S. 398 (2004);
    • (2004) U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
  • 147
    • 84883097786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NYNEX
    • NYNEX, 525 U. S. 128. For an analysis of the Roberts Court antitrust decisions
    • U. S. , vol.525 , pp. 128
  • 148
    • 47049093858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Roberts court and the Chicago school of antitrust: The 2006 term and beyond
    • see Joshua D. Wright, The Roberts Court and the Chicago School of Antitrust: The 2006 Term and Beyond, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 25 (2007) (arguing that Chicago School economic principles characterize the Roberts Court antitrust jurisprudence).
    • (2007) Competition Pol'Y Int'L , vol.3 , pp. 25
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 149
    • 33846837924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U. S. at 407.
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 407
    • Trinko1
  • 150
    • 77749326358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The lawful acquisition and exercise of monopoly power and its implications for the objectives of antitrust
    • 203
    • See David S. Evans & Keith N. Hylton, The Lawful Acquisition and Exercise of Monopoly Power and its Implications for the Objectives of Antitrust, 4 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 203, 203 (2008).
    • (2008) Competition Pol'Y Int'L , vol.4 , pp. 203
    • Evans, D.S.1    Hylton, K.N.2
  • 151
    • 80055063655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Linkline, 129 S. Ct. at 1118;
    • S. Ct. , vol.129 , pp. 1118
    • Linkline1
  • 152
    • 33846837924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U. S. at 407-08;
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 407-408
    • Trinko1
  • 153
    • 80055059469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NYNEX
    • NYNEX, 525 U. S. at 136-37.
    • U. S. , vol.525 , pp. 136-137
  • 154
    • 70350155199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When is it worthwhile to use courts to search for exclusionary conduct?
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, When Is It Worthwhile to Use Courts to Search for Exclusionary Conduct?, 2003 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 345, 345 ("Aggressive, competitive conduct by any firm, even one with market power, is beneficial to consumers. Courts should prize and encourage it. Aggressive, exclusionary conduct is deleterious to consumers, and courts should condemn it. The big problem lies in this: competitive and exclusionary conduct look alike.").
    • (2003) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , pp. 345
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 155
    • 79955909658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Linkline, 129 S. Ct. at 1120;
    • S. Ct. , vol.129 , pp. 1120
    • Linkline1
  • 156
    • 33846795175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U. S. at 414 ("The cost of false positives counsels against an undue expansion of § 2 liability.");
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 414
    • Trinko1
  • 157
    • 80055059469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NYNEX
    • NYNEX, 525 U. S. at 136-37;
    • U. S. , vol.525 , pp. 136-137
  • 158
    • 0346195823 scopus 로고
    • Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U. S. 447, 456, 458 (1993) ("[T]his Court and other courts have been careful to avoid constructions of § 2 which might chill competition, rather than foster it.");
    • (1993) U. S. , vol.506 , pp. 447
  • 159
    • 84870608407 scopus 로고
    • Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 728
    • Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U. S. 717, 728 (1988);
    • (1988) U. S. , vol.485 , pp. 717
  • 160
    • 27844479319 scopus 로고
    • Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U. S. 574, 594 (1986) (stating that mistaken inferences in predatorypricing cases "are especially costly because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect");
    • (1986) U. S. , vol.475 , pp. 574
  • 161
    • 84870620449 scopus 로고
    • Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U. S. 752, 767-68 (1984) (noting that scrutiny of single firms under the Sherman Act is appropriate only when they pose a danger of monopolization, an approach that "reduces the risk that the antitrust laws will dampen the competitive zeal of a single aggressive [competitor]").
    • (1984) U. S. , vol.467 , pp. 752
  • 162
    • 80055047386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 525 U. S. at 133 (1998) ("[C]ertain kinds of agreements will so often prove so harmful to competition and so rarely prove justified that the antitrust laws do not require proof that an agreement of that kind is, in fact, anticompetitive in the particular circumstances.").
    • (1998) U. S. , vol.525 , pp. 133
  • 163
    • 27844612205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 522 U. S. 3, 10 (1997) (Certain "types of restraints... have such predictable and pernicious anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive benefit, that they are deemed unlawful per se.").
    • (1997) U. S. , vol.522 , pp. 3
  • 164
    • 27844532782 scopus 로고
    • 223-24
    • 509 U. S. 209, 223-24 (1993).
    • (1993) U. S. , vol.509 , pp. 209
  • 165
    • 84870591535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 886
    • Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U. S. 877, 886 (2007).
    • (2007) U. S. , vol.551 , pp. 877
  • 166
    • 84875104859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 319-20
    • Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U. S. 312, 319-20 (2007).
    • (2007) U. S. , vol.549 , pp. 312
  • 167
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 414
    • 540 U. S. 398, 414 (2004).
    • (2004) U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
  • 168
    • 84877720550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit Suisse Sec. USA LLC v. Billing, 283
    • Credit Suisse Sec. (USA) LLC v. Billing, 551 U. S. 264, 283 (2007).
    • (2007) U. S. , vol.551 , pp. 264
  • 169
    • 77955392207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1122
    • 129 S. Ct. 1109, 1122 (2009).
    • (2009) S. Ct. , vol.129 , pp. 1109
  • 170
    • 70350440813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 at 414 (citation omitted)
    • Trinko , vol.540 , pp. 414
  • 171
    • 27844479319 scopus 로고
    • quoting Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 594
    • (quoting Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U. S. 574, 594 (1986)).
    • (1986) U. S. , vol.475 , pp. 574
  • 172
    • 33044495298 scopus 로고
    • United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co, 391
    • United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co, 351 U. S. 377, 391 (1956).
    • (1956) U. S. , vol.351 , pp. 377
  • 173
    • 80055052479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Google's U. S. search share nears 70 percent
    • July 15
    • Stephen Shankland, Google's U. S. Search Share Nears 70 Percent, CNET NEWS, July 15, 2008, http://news.cnet.com/8301-1023-3-9991866-93.html.
    • (2008) Cnet News
    • Shankland, S.1
  • 176
    • 27844587041 scopus 로고
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 481, finding eighty to ninety-five percent predominant
    • See, e.g., Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U. S. 451, 481 (1992) (finding eighty to ninety-five percent predominant);
    • (1992) U. S. , vol.504 , pp. 451
  • 177
    • 27844557556 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Grinnell Corp, 571
    • United States v. Grinnell Corp, 384 U. S. 563, 571 (1966)
    • (1966) U. S. , vol.384 , pp. 563
  • 178
    • 33044495298 scopus 로고
    • finding eighty-seven percent predominant; United States v. E. I. du Pont Numours & Co., 379
    • (finding eighty-seven percent predominant); United States v. E. I. du Pont Numours & Co., 351 U. S. 377, 379 (1956)
    • (1956) U. S. , vol.351 , pp. 377
  • 179
    • 84871736910 scopus 로고
    • finding seventy-five percent predominant; American Tobacco Co. v. United States.
    • (finding seventy-five percent predominant); American Tobacco Co. v. United States., 328 U. S. 781 (1946)
    • (1946) U. S. , vol.328 , pp. 781
  • 180
    • 33745470556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Dentsply Int'l Inc., 188 3d Cir, finding seventy-five to eighty percent predominant
    • United States v. Dentsply Int'l Inc., 399 F.3d 181, 188 (3d Cir. 2005) (finding seventy-five to eighty percent predominant).
    • (2005) F.3d , vol.399 , pp. 181
  • 181
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 49-50 D. C. Cir, en banc per curiam
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 49-50 (D. C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam).
    • (2001) F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 182
    • 0002981164 scopus 로고
    • Systems competition and network effects
    • 95-96
    • Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Systems Competition and Network Effects, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. 93, 95-96 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.8 , pp. 93
    • Katz, M.L.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 183
    • 80055061118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Microsoft
    • Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 55-56.
    • F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 55-56
  • 184
    • 27844608082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Note that the court does not even assess the extent that mere discouragement operates as an effective entry barrier. The district court, we note, however, was not quite so circumspect. See United States v. Microsoft, 87 F. Supp. 2d 30, 42 (D. D. C. 2000)
    • (2000) F. Supp. 2d , vol.87 , pp. 30
  • 185
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • aff'd in part, rev'd in part, 253 F.3d 34 (D. C. Cir. 2001).
    • (2001) F.3D , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 187
    • 24644462122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Network effects
    • The general economic consequences of indirect and direct network effects are substantially different, and indirect network effects are not a source of inefficient technology lock-in-and they thus do not pose a barrier to entry. See Stanley J. Liebowitz & Stephen E. Margolis, Network Effects, in 1 HANDBOOK OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS ECONOMICS: STRUCTURE, REGULATION AND COMPETITION 79, 85-86 (Martin E. Cave et al. eds., 2002). See generally Spulber, supra note 8 (explaining why technology lock-in rarely occurs).
    • (2002) Handbook of Telecommunications Economics: Structure, Regulation and Competition , vol.1 , pp. 79
    • Liebowitz, S.J.1    Margolis, S.E.2
  • 188
    • 0346168864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Paddock Publ'ns, Inc. v. Chi. Tribune Co., 103 F.3d 42, 45 (7th Cir. 1996) ("Competition-for-the-contract is a form of competition that antitrust laws protect rather than proscribe, and it is common. ").
    • (1996) F.3d , vol.103 , pp. 42
  • 189
    • 80055038638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Menasha Corp. v. News Am. Mktg. In-Store, Inc., 354 F.3d 661, 663 (7th Cir. 2004).
    • F.3d , vol.354 , pp. 661
  • 190
    • 70449367148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust law and competition for distribution
    • 170, 191
    • Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Law and Competition for Distribution, 23 YALE J. ON REG. 169, 170, 191 (2006); see also Klein, supra note 149 (explaining that, contrary to the "unfortunate tendency" of viewing exclusive distribution contracts as uncompetitive, such contracts often involve "competition on the merits").
    • (2006) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.23 , pp. 169
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 191
    • 34548129589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The expanded economics of free-riding: How exclusive dealing prevents free-riding and creates undivided loyalty
    • 483-84, 498
    • See Benjamin Klein & Andres V. Lerner, The Expanded Economics of Free-Riding: How Exclusive Dealing Prevents Free-Riding and Creates Undivided Loyalty, 74 ANTITRUST L. J. 473, 483-84, 498 (2007).
    • (2007) Antitrust L. J. , vol.74 , pp. 473
    • Klein, B.1    Lerner, A.V.2
  • 192
    • 57049175970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing intensifies competition for distribution
    • 437
    • Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Exclusive Dealing Intensifies Competition for Distribution, 75 ANTITRUST L. J. 433, 437 (2008). This explanation is related to, and provides the economic basis for, the argument that exclusives "instigated" by customers should enjoy a presumption of legality.
    • (2008) Antitrust L. J. , vol.75 , pp. 433
    • Klein, B.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 193
    • 0034414761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Customer-instigated exclusive dealing
    • 240-42
    • See Richard M. Steuer, Customer-Instigated Exclusive Dealing, 68 ANTITRUST L. J. 239, 240-42 (2000).
    • (2000) Antitrust L. J. , vol.68 , pp. 239
    • Steuer, R.M.1
  • 194
    • 80055036680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2nd ed, citation omitted
    • 11 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1821 (2nd ed. 2005) (citation omitted).
    • (2005) Antitrust Law , vol.11 , pp. 1821
    • Areeda, P.E.1    Hovenkamp, H.2
  • 195
    • 31344469627 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U. S. 2, 7 (1984) (holding that a hospital with thirty percent of the relevant market did not possess significant market power).
    • (1984) U. S. , vol.466 , pp. 2
  • 196
    • 0036926346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing, "foreclosure", and consumer harm
    • 324 n. 85, listing exemplary decisions illustrating use of the forty percent threshold
    • Jonathan M. Jacobson, Exclusive Dealing, "Foreclosure", and Consumer Harm, 70 ANTITRUST L. J. 311, 324 n. 85 (2002) (listing exemplary decisions illustrating use of the forty percent threshold).
    • (2002) Antitrust L. J. , vol.70 , pp. 311
    • Jacobson, J.M.1
  • 197
    • 27844450159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 70-71 D. C. Cir, en banc per curiam finding less than forty percent foreclosure sufficient for antitrust liability
    • See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 70-71 (D. C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam) (finding less than forty percent foreclosure sufficient for antitrust liability);
    • (2001) F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 34
  • 198
    • 0035583308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A general analysis of exclusionary conduct and refusal to deal-why aspen and kodak are misguided
    • 676, 678
    • see also Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided, 68 ANTITRUST L. J. 659, 676, 678 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust L. J. , vol.68 , pp. 659
    • Carlton, D.W.1
  • 199
  • 200
    • 80055047798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Microsoft
    • Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 70-71.
    • F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 70-71
  • 201
    • 80055047798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Microsoft
    • Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 70-71.
    • F.3d , vol.253 , pp. 70-71
  • 202
    • 85027879130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A number of courts have held that exclusive contracts of one year or less are presumptively lawful. See, e.g., Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 207 F.3d 1039, 1059 (8th Cir. 2000);
    • (2000) F.3d , vol.207 , pp. 1039
  • 203
    • 80055040500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CDC Techs., Inc. v. IDEXX Labs, Inc., 81, 2d Cir
    • CDC Techs., Inc. v. IDEXX Labs, Inc., 186 F.3d 74, 81 (2d Cir. 1999);
    • (1999) F.3d , vol.186 , pp. 74
  • 204
    • 0346195409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Omega Envtl. Inc. v. Gilbarco, Inc., 1163-64, 9th Cir
    • Omega Envtl. Inc. v. Gilbarco, Inc., 127 F.3d 1157, 1163-64 (9th Cir. 1997);
    • (1997) F.3d , vol.127 , pp. 1157
  • 205
    • 0346168864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paddock Publ'ns, Inc. v. Chicago Tribune Co., 103 F.3d 42, 47 (7th Cir. 1996) ("[T]he FTC and the Supreme Court concluded that even exclusive dealing contracts are lawful if limited to one year's duration. ");
    • (1996) F.3d , vol.103 , pp. 42
  • 206
    • 0348060315 scopus 로고
    • Thompson Everett, Inc. v. Nat'l Cable Adver. L. P., 57 F.3d 1317, 1324-25 (4th Cir. 1995);
    • (1995) F.3d , vol.57 , pp. 1317
  • 207
    • 27844588166 scopus 로고
    • U. S. Healthcare, Inc. v. Healthsource, Inc., 596, 1st Cir
    • U. S. Healthcare, Inc. v. Healthsource, Inc., 986 F.2d 589, 596 (1st Cir. 1993);
    • (1993) F.2d , vol.986 , pp. 589
  • 208
    • 0346195443 scopus 로고
    • *8 (D. Del. Mar. 31, 2001);
    • (1984) F.2d , vol.749 , pp. 380
  • 209
    • 85018243167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *1-2 (W. D. Ky. Oct. 26, 1983)
    • (1999) F. Supp. 2d , vol.35 , pp. 1138
  • 210
    • 80055027048 scopus 로고
    • (enjoining requirements contracts covering large percentage of the market though only thirty days to one year in duration), aff'd per curiam, 758 F.2d 654 (6th Cir. 1985).
    • (1985) F.2d , vol.758 , pp. 654
  • 211
    • 77955869722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They might be a little evil
    • June 1, at
    • See Daniel Lyons, They Might Be a Little Evil, NEWSWEEK, June 1, 2009, at 24;
    • (2009) Newsweek , pp. 24
    • Lyons, D.1
  • 212
    • 61349171413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stuck in Google's doghouse
    • Sept. 13, at
    • Joe Nocera, Stuck in Google's Doghouse, N. Y. TIMES, Sept. 13, 2008, at C1.
    • (2008) N. Y. Times
    • Nocera, J.1
  • 213
    • 27844609535 scopus 로고
    • Compare Complaint, supra note 134 ¶ 8, with Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U. S. 585, 601 (1985).
    • (1985) U. S. , vol.472 , pp. 585
  • 214
    • 51949093632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U. S. 300, 307 (1919) (noting that antitrust laws typically do not "restrict the long recognized right of [a] trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to parties with whom he will deal"). The right to refuse to deal with rivals is not absolute, however, but it is close.
    • (1919) U. S. , vol.250 , pp. 300
  • 215
    • 84859616356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Aspen Skiing, 472 U. S. at 601 ("[T]he high value... placed on the right to refuse to deal with other firms does not mean that the right is unqualified.").
    • U. S. , vol.472 , pp. 601
  • 216
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Verizon Comm. Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U. S. 398, 407 (2004).
    • (2004) U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
  • 217
    • 85042646563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U. S. at 408.
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 408
    • Trinko1
  • 219
    • 33846837924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U. S. at 407-08
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 407-408
    • Trinko1
  • 220
    • 51949093632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (citing Colgate, 250 U. S. at 307).
    • U. S. , vol.250 , pp. 307
  • 221
    • 0039579668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preserving competition: Economic analysis, legal standards and microsoft
    • 27
    • See, e.g., Ronald A. Cass & Keith N. Hylton, Preserving Competition: Economic Analysis, Legal Standards and Microsoft, 8 GEO. MASON L. REV. 1, 27 (1999);
    • (1999) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.8 , pp. 1
    • Cass, R.A.1    Hylton, K.N.2
  • 222
    • 0039671701 scopus 로고
    • On identifying exclusionary conduct
    • 973
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, On Identifying Exclusionary Conduct, 61 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 972, 973 (1986).
    • (1986) Notre Dame L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 972
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 223
    • 33846811999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We do not separately discuss this claim as an essential facility claim both because the Supreme Court has refused to endorse such a claim, see Trinko, 540 U. S. at 410, and because there is near universal agreement from commentators that it should be abandoned.
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 410
    • Trinko1
  • 224
    • 0004010763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 3A PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 771c, at 196 (3d ed. 2008) (noting that "the essential facility doctrine is both harmful and unnecessary and should be abandoned");
    • (2008) Antitrust Law , pp. 196
    • Areeda, P.E.1    Hovenkamp, H.2
  • 225
    • 57349181665 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust doctrine and the sway of metaphor
    • Michael Boudin, Antitrust Doctrine and the Sway of Metaphor, 75 GEO. L. J. 395, 402 (1986) (noting "embarrassing weakness" of essential facilities doctrine);
    • (1986) Geo. L. J. , vol.75 , pp. 395
    • Boudin, M.1
  • 226
    • 0346617007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essential facilities
    • 1195
    • Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187, 1195 (1999) ("[M]andatory access remedies, such as the essential facilities doctrine, do not fit comfortably within antitrust law.");
    • (1999) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1187
    • Lipsky Jr., A.B.1    Gregory Sidak, J.2
  • 227
    • 0040724486 scopus 로고
    • The law and economics of the essential facility doctrine
    • 480
    • Gregory J. Werden, The Law and Economics of the Essential Facility Doctrine, 32 ST. LOUIS U. L. J. 433, 480 (1987) ("Courts should reject the doctrine").
    • (1987) St. Louis U. L. J. , vol.32 , pp. 433
    • Werden, G.J.1
  • 228
    • 77954653046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at, n. 64
    • U. S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, supra note 16, at 42 n. 64.
    • U. S. Dep'T of Justice , pp. 42
  • 229
    • 85042646563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U. S. at 408.
    • U. S. , vol.540 , pp. 408
    • Trinko1
  • 230
    • 78049319468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 37, at, "Forced sharing requires courts to determine the price at which such sharing must take place, thereby transforming antitrust courts into price regulators, a role for which they are ill suited."
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, supra note 37, at 102 ("[F]orced sharing requires courts to determine the price at which such sharing must take place, thereby transforming antitrust courts into price regulators, a role for which they are ill suited.").
    • Antitrust Modernization Comm'n , pp. 102


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.