메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 4, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 207-262

Consumer coordination in the small and in the large: Implications for antitrust in markets with networdk effects

(1)  Spulber, Daniel F a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 50549093002     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhm031     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (29)

References (163)
  • 1
    • 50549090330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On monopolization and other antitrust issues in network markets, see, e.g., H. Hovenkamp, The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2005), Chapter 12
    • On monopolization and other antitrust issues in network markets, see, e.g., H. Hovenkamp, The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2005), Chapter 12
  • 2
    • 0006214007 scopus 로고
    • Microsoft Plays Hardball: The Use of Exclusionary Pricing and Technical Incompatibility to Maintain Monopoly Power in Markets for Operating System Software
    • Symposium: Microsoft and the United States Department of Justice, On concerns over exclusionary behavior
    • and K. C. Baseman, F. R. Warren-Boulton and G. A. Woroch, "Microsoft Plays Hardball: The Use of Exclusionary Pricing and Technical Incompatibility to Maintain Monopoly Power in Markets for Operating System Software," Symposium: Microsoft and the United States Department of Justice, 40 Antitrust Bulletin 265-315 (1995). On concerns over exclusionary behavior
    • (1995) Antitrust Bulletin , pp. 265-315
    • Baseman, K.C.1    Warren-Boulton, F.R.2    Woroch, G.A.3
  • 3
    • 0348126262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusivity in Network Industries, 7
    • see, e.g
    • see, e.g., C. Shapiro, "Exclusivity in Network Industries," 7 George Mason Law Review 673-83 (1999)
    • (1999) George Mason Law Review , vol.673 -83
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 4
    • 0347496315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Networks and Exclusivity: Antitrust Analysis to Promote Network Competition, 7
    • D. A. Balto, "Networks and Exclusivity: Antitrust Analysis to Promote Network Competition," 7 George Mason Law Review, 523-76 (1999)
    • (1999) George Mason Law Review , vol.523 -76
    • Balto, D.A.1
  • 5
    • 50549098707 scopus 로고
    • Some Remarks on Monopoly Leveraging
    • Symposium: Microsoft and the United States Department of Justice
    • and R. D. Blair and A. K. Esquibel, "Some Remarks on Monopoly Leveraging, Symposium: Microsoft and the United States Department of Justice, 40 Antitrust Bulletin 371-96 (1995).
    • (1995) Antitrust Bulletin , vol.371 -96 , pp. 40
    • Blair, R.D.1    Esquibel, A.K.2
  • 6
    • 85024536192 scopus 로고
    • Clio and the Economics of QWERTY, 75
    • See
    • See P. David, "Clio and the Economics of QWERTY," 75 American Economic Review 332-7 (1985)
    • (1985) American Economic Review , vol.332 -7
    • David, P.1
  • 7
    • 50549090867 scopus 로고
    • Heros, Herds and Hysteresis in Technological History: The Battle of the Systems=Reconsidered, 1
    • P. David, "Heros, Herds and Hysteresis in Technological History: The Battle of the Systems=Reconsidered," 1 Industrial and Corporate Change 129-80 (1992)
    • (1992) Industrial and Corporate Change , vol.129 -80
    • David, P.1
  • 8
    • 76449114058 scopus 로고
    • Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical Events, 97
    • B. Arthur, "Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical Events," 97 Economic Journal 642-65 (1989)
    • (1989) Economic Journal , vol.642 -65
    • Arthur, B.1
  • 9
    • 0002264274 scopus 로고
    • Positive Feedbacks in the Economy, 262
    • B. Arthur, "Positive Feedbacks in the Economy," 262 Scientific American 92-9 (1990)
    • (1990) Scientific American , vol.92 -9
    • Arthur, B.1
  • 11
    • 85020616309 scopus 로고
    • Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility, 75
    • M. L. Katz and C. Shapiro, "Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility," 75 American Economic Review, 424-40 (1985)
    • (1985) American Economic Review , vol.424 -40
    • Katz, M.L.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 15
    • 0002642594 scopus 로고
    • Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, 16
    • J. Farrell and G. Saloner, "Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation," 16 Rand Journal of Economics 70-83 (1985)
    • (1985) Rand Journal of Economics , pp. 70-83
    • Farrell, J.1    Saloner, G.2
  • 16
    • 0000150059 scopus 로고
    • Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product Preannouncements, and Predation, 76
    • For additional references and an overview of the literature
    • J. Farrell and G. Saloner, "Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product Preannouncements, and Predation," 76 American Economic Review 940-55 (1986). For additional references and an overview of the literature,
    • (1986) American Economic Review , vol.940 -55
    • Farrell, J.1    Saloner, G.2
  • 17
    • 2642563166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects
    • see, Berkeley, CA: University of California, forthcoming, CEPR Discussion Paper Number 5798, August
    • see J. Farrell and P. Klemperer, "Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects," Handbook of Industrial Organization (Berkeley, CA: University of California, 2006), forthcoming, CEPR Discussion Paper Number 5798, August 2006.
    • (2006) Handbook of Industrial Organization
    • Farrell, J.1    Klemperer, P.2
  • 18
    • 50549086559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Farrell and Klemperer, 2006, ibid.
    • See Farrell and Klemperer, 2006, ibid.
  • 19
    • 50549085327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Farrell and Klemperer, 2006, supra note 2, set out this argument and describe several layers of pessimism about markets with network effects: First, both splintering and coordination on the wrong standard are possible, so that adopters collectively may fail to take the best deal offered. Second, because offering better deals is thus unreliable as a way to win the market, sponsors focus more on attracting expectations in other ways and on arranging to extract more rent if they do win-so sponsors offer less good deals. Third, if expectations track history rather than surplus, collective switching costs come to include the value of network effects, cementing us into what can be badly outdated (or just bad) standards. Fourth, the strong competitive advantage conferred on a firm that attracts adopters' expectations opens up new avenues for mischief. Here, splintering refers to consumers failing to adopt a single technology, with different groups ad
    • Farrell and Klemperer, 2006, supra note 2, set out this argument and describe "several layers of pessimism" about markets with network effects: First, both splintering and coordination on the "wrong" standard are possible, so that adopters collectively may fail to take the best deal offered. Second, because offering better deals is thus unreliable as a way to win the market, sponsors focus more on attracting expectations in other ways and on arranging to extract more rent if they do win-so sponsors offer less good deals. Third, if expectations track history rather than surplus, collective switching costs come to include the value of network effects, cementing us into what can be badly outdated (or just bad) standards. Fourth, the strong competitive advantage conferred on a firm that attracts adopters' expectations opens up new avenues for mischief. Here, "splintering" refers to consumers failing to adopt a single technology, with different groups adopting different technologies due to a coordination failure.
  • 21
    • 50549088253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See F. A. Hayek, Spontaneous (Grown) Order and Organized ('Made') Order, in Market, Hierarchies & Networks: The Coordination of Social Life, G. Thompson, J. Francis, R. Levacic, and J. Mitchell, J., eds (London: Sage, 1991), pp. 293-301
    • See F. A. Hayek, "Spontaneous (Grown) Order and Organized ('Made') Order," in Market, Hierarchies & Networks: The Coordination of Social Life, G. Thompson, J. Francis, R. Levacic, and J. Mitchell, J., eds (London: Sage, 1991), pp. 293-301
  • 23
    • 0004161626 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: Chicago University Press
    • and F. A. Hayek, The Constitution of Liberty (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1960), pp. 159-160.
    • (1960) The Constitution of Liberty , pp. 159-160
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 24
    • 50549089968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 49 (D.C. Cir.), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001).
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 49 (D.C. Cir.), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001).
  • 25
    • 50549089003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, 2005, supra note 1, at p. 285
    • Hovenkamp, 2005, supra note 1, at p. 285.
  • 26
    • 50549088012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Microsoft Corporation against Commission of the European Communities Case T-201/04, Ruling on September 17, 2007 by the European Court of First Instance
    • Microsoft Corporation against Commission of the European Communities Case T-201/04, Ruling on September 17, 2007 by the European Court of First Instance.
  • 27
    • 35448991396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Firms and Networks in Two-Sided Markets
    • T. Hendershott, ed, Amsterdam: Elsevier
    • D. F. Spulber, "Firms and Networks in Two-Sided Markets," in T. Hendershott, ed., Handbook in Information Systems, Vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2006), pp. 137-200.
    • (2006) Handbook in Information Systems , vol.1 , pp. 137-200
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 29
    • 0036255050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Microstructure and Incentives to Invest, 110
    • D. F. Spulber, "Market Microstructure and Incentives to Invest," 110 Journal of Political Economy 352-81 (2002)
    • (2002) Journal of Political Economy , vol.352 -81
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 30
    • 0009021411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Making by Price-Setting Firms, 63
    • D. F. Spulber, "Market Making by Price-Setting Firms," 63 Review of Economic Studies 559-80 (1996)
    • (1996) Review of Economic Studies , vol.559 -80
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 31
    • 0000232828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Microstructure and Intermediation, 10
    • D. F. Spulber, "Market Microstructure and Intermediation," 10 Journal of Economic Perspectives 135-52 (1996).
    • (1996) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.135 -52
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 32
  • 33
    • 0038687398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Access to Networks: Economic and Constitution Connections, 88
    • D. F. Spulber and C. S. Yoo, "Access to Networks: Economic and Constitution Connections", 88 Cornell Law Review 885-1024 (2003)
    • (2003) Cornell Law Review , pp. 885-1024
    • Spulber, D.F.1    Yoo, C.S.2
  • 35
    • 28344447466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Regulation of Networks as Complex Systems: A Graph Theory Approach, 99
    • D. F. Spulber and C. S. Yoo, "On the Regulation of Networks as Complex Systems: A Graph Theory Approach," 99 Northwestern University Law Review 1687-722 (2005b)
    • (2005) Northwestern University Law Review , vol.1687 -722
    • Spulber, D.F.1    Yoo, C.S.2
  • 36
    • 38149057536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mandating Access to Telecom and the Internet: The Hidden Side of Trinko
    • D. F. Spulber and C. S. Yoo, "Mandating Access to Telecom and the Internet: The Hidden Side of Trinko," 107 Columbia Law Review (2007a)
    • (2007) Columbia Law Review , vol.107
    • Spulber, D.F.1    Yoo, C.S.2
  • 38
    • 0346089931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 97
    • J. G. Sidak and D. F. Spulber, "The Tragedy of the Telecommons: Government Pricing of Unbundled Network Elements Under the Telecommunications Act of 1996," 97 Columbia University Law Review 1201-81 (1997)
    • (1997) Columbia University Law Review , vol.1201 -81
    • Sidak, J.G.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 41
    • 84899602138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deregulation and Managed Competition in Network Industries, 15
    • J. G. Sidak and D. F. Spulber, "Deregulation and Managed Competition in Network Industries," 15 Yale Journal on Regulation 117-48 (1998)
    • (1998) Yale Journal on Regulation , vol.117 -48
    • Sidak, J.G.1    Spulber, D.F.2
  • 46
  • 51
    • 50549100496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Liebowitz and Margolis (1994, 2002) point out that the argument that indirect network effects represents an externality repeats conceptual errors in Pigou's pecuniary externality concept.
    • Liebowitz and Margolis (1994, 2002) point out that the argument that indirect network effects represents an "externality" repeats conceptual errors in Pigou's "pecuniary externality" concept.
  • 53
    • 0015604304 scopus 로고
    • The Telephone System as a Public Good: Static and Dynamic Aspects, 4
    • examine interdependent demand in communications based on the number of subscribers
    • R. Artle and C. Averous, "The Telephone System as a Public Good: Static and Dynamic Aspects," 4 Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 89-100 (1973) examine interdependent demand in communications based on the number of subscribers.
    • (1973) Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , pp. 89-100
    • Artle, R.1    Averous, C.2
  • 54
    • 50549102899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • i di
    • i di
  • 55
    • 50549085889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is important to emphasize that the model based on the number of subscribers is a simplification for purposes of illustration. It is more accurate to allow each individual's consumption level to vary and to allow each individual's consumption to have differential effects on the benefits of others. Economic analysis using the simplified model should be checked by careful consideration of the more general model
    • It is important to emphasize that the model based on the number of subscribers is a simplification for purposes of illustration. It is more accurate to allow each individual's consumption level to vary and to allow each individual's consumption to have differential effects on the benefits of others. Economic analysis using the simplified model should be checked by careful consideration of the more general model.
  • 56
    • 50549095304 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spulber and Yoo, 2005, supra note 13.
    • Spulber and Yoo, 2005, supra note 13.
  • 57
    • 50549084295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the discussion of Spulber and Yoo, 2005b, supra note 13.
    • See the discussion of Spulber and Yoo, 2005b, supra note 13.
  • 58
    • 50549096271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Farrell and Saloner, 1986, supra note 2.
    • See, e.g., Farrell and Saloner, 1986, supra note 2.
  • 59
    • 50549084959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 60
    • 84936824352 scopus 로고
    • Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness, 91
    • M. Granovetter, "Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness," 91 The American Journal of Sociology 481-510 (1985).
    • (1985) The American Journal of Sociology , pp. 481-510
    • Granovetter, M.1
  • 62
    • 50549091963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the subject of mass collaboration, see D. Tapscott and A. D. Williams, Wikinomics: How Mass Collaboration Changes Everything (New York: Portfolio, Penguin, 2006). On the related subject of peer production,
    • On the subject of "mass collaboration," see D. Tapscott and A. D. Williams, Wikinomics: How Mass Collaboration Changes Everything (New York: Portfolio, Penguin, 2006). On the related subject of "peer production,"
  • 63
    • 0242685828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase's Penguin, or, Linux and The Nature of the Firm, 112
    • see
    • see Y. Benkler, "Coase's Penguin, or, Linux and The Nature of the Firm," 112 Yale Law Journal 369-446 (2002).
    • (2002) Yale Law Journal , pp. 369-446
    • Benkler, Y.1
  • 64
    • 50549103707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Benkler, 2002, ibid.
    • See Benkler, 2002, ibid.
  • 65
    • 50549098409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Janet Kornblum, Teens Hang Out At MySpace, USA Today, www.USATODAY.com, January 9, 2006, Murdoch Marvels at MySpace Acquisition, October 18, 2007 http://www.ctv.ca/servlet/ ArticleNews/story/CTVNews/20071018/myspace_071018/20071018?hub=SciTech
    • Janet Kornblum, "Teens Hang Out At MySpace," USA Today, www.USATODAY.com, January 9, 2006, "Murdoch Marvels at MySpace Acquisition," October 18, 2007 http://www.ctv.ca/servlet/ ArticleNews/story/CTVNews/20071018/myspace_071018/20071018?hub=SciTech
  • 66
    • 50549098037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Benkler (2002, supra note 27, p. 436) suggests that Contributions may vary widely in their hedonic taste for creation, their social-psychological attitude toward participation, or in opportunities for indirect monetary appropriation.
    • Benkler (2002, supra note 27, p. 436) suggests that "Contributions may vary widely in their hedonic taste for creation, their social-psychological attitude toward participation, or in opportunities for indirect monetary appropriation."
  • 67
    • 50549102657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economists have studied two-sided markets for well over a century. Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk's (1891) famous market for horses originates the important idea of a two-sided market. Böhm-Bawerk introduces the term two-sided competition, stating that The case of two-sided competition is the most common in economic life, as it is the most important in the development of the Law of Price. It demands, therefore, our most careful attention. Rather than characterizing supply and demand as aggregates, he begins with individual buyers and sellers and their subjective valuations. E. von Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, translated from the German by W. E. Smart (London: Macmillan, 1891).
    • Economists have studied two-sided markets for well over a century. Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk's (1891) famous market for horses originates the important idea of a two-sided market. Böhm-Bawerk introduces the term "two-sided competition," stating that "The case of two-sided competition is the most common in economic life, as it is the most important in the development of the Law of Price. It demands, therefore, our most careful attention." Rather than characterizing supply and demand as aggregates, he begins with individual buyers and sellers and their subjective valuations. E. von Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, translated from the German by W. E. Smart (London: Macmillan, 1891).
  • 68
    • 50549085202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The term two-sided market has a long history. Shapley and Shubik employ the term two-sided market and observe that Two-sided market models are important, as Cournot, Edgeworth, Böhm-Bawerk, and others have observed, not only for the insights they may give into more general economic situations with many types of traders, consumers, and producers, but also for the simple reason that in real life many markets and most actual transactions are in fact bilateral - i.e., bring together a buyer and a seller of a single commodity.
    • The term "two-sided market" has a long history. Shapley and Shubik employ the term "two-sided market" and observe that "Two-sided market models are important, as Cournot, Edgeworth, Böhm-Bawerk, and others have observed, not only for the insights they may give into more general economic situations with many types of traders, consumers, and producers, but also for the simple reason that in real life many markets and most actual transactions are in fact bilateral - i.e., bring together a buyer and a seller of a single commodity."
  • 70
    • 50549098277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Spulber, 2006, supra note 4
    • See Spulber, 2006, supra note 4.
  • 71
    • 50549094597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 72
    • 50549096035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spulber examines the effects of network structures when firms act as market makers. See Spulber (2006) supra note 4
    • Spulber examines the effects of network structures when firms act as market makers. See Spulber (2006) supra note 4.
  • 74
    • 50549100030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These exchanges are subject to regulation by such agencies as the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission CFTC
    • These exchanges are subject to regulation by such agencies as the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC).
  • 75
    • 50549083107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coordination in electric power transmission networks to manage loads is achieved through industry associations and regulations
    • Coordination in electric power transmission networks to manage loads is achieved through industry associations and regulations
  • 77
    • 31044451865 scopus 로고
    • Reflections on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects, 31
    • E. J. Mishan, "Reflections on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects," 31 Canadian Journal of Political Economy 3-34 (1965)
    • (1965) Canadian Journal of Political Economy , pp. 3-34
    • Mishan, E.J.1
  • 78
    • 0002731033 scopus 로고
    • The Postwar Literature on Externalities: An Interpretive Essay, 9
    • and E. J. Mishan "The Postwar Literature on Externalities: An Interpretive Essay, 9 Journal of Economic Literature 1-28 (1971).
    • (1971) Journal of Economic Literature , pp. 1-28
    • Mishan, E.J.1
  • 79
    • 50549097574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1) = c.
    • 1) = c.
  • 80
    • 50549087297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Formally, equating the sum of marginal benefits to marginal cost for each amount of the network good is represented as follows. For consumer 1's consumption, the efficiency condition is u11 (q1, q2, u22 (q2, q1, c. For consumer 2's consumption, the efficiency condition is u21 (q1, q2, u12 q2, q1, c
    • 2, q1) = c.
  • 82
    • 50549088011 scopus 로고
    • See, Cambridge, MA, Cambridge University Press, Chapters and, for further discussion
    • See Daniel F. Spulber, 1989, Regulation and Markets, Cambridge, MA, Cambridge University Press, Chapters 12 and 13, for further discussion.
    • (1989) Regulation and Markets , pp. 12-13
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 83
    • 0002455414 scopus 로고
    • The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation, 16
    • On pollination in agriculture See
    • See S. N. S. Cheung, "The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation," 16 Journal of Law & Economics 11-33 (1973). On pollination in agriculture
    • (1973) Journal of Law & Economics , pp. 11-33
    • Cheung, S.N.S.1
  • 84
    • 0002243862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Value of Honey Bees As Pollinators of U.S. Crops in 2000
    • see, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
    • see Roger A. Morse and Nicholas W. Calderone, The Value of Honey Bees As Pollinators of U.S. Crops in 2000, Research Report (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, 2000).
    • (2000) Research Report
    • Morse, R.A.1    Calderone, N.W.2
  • 85
    • 0002102617 scopus 로고
    • External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive Situation, 62
    • See
    • See J. E. Meade, "External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive Situation," 62 Economic Journal 54-67 (1952).
    • (1952) Economic Journal , pp. 54-67
    • Meade, J.E.1
  • 86
    • 84963037127 scopus 로고
    • The Anatomy of Market Failure, 72
    • The fable was used to illustrate market failure by
    • The fable was used to illustrate market failure by F. M. Bator, "The Anatomy of Market Failure," 72 Quarterly Journal of Economics 351-79 (1958)
    • (1958) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.351 -79
    • Bator, F.M.1
  • 87
    • 31044451865 scopus 로고
    • Reflections on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects, 31
    • see also
    • see also E. J. Mishan, "Reflections on Recent Developments in the Concept of External Effects," 31 Canadian Journal of Political Economy 3-34 (1965).
    • (1965) Canadian Journal of Political Economy , vol.34 , pp. 3-34
    • Mishan, E.J.1
  • 88
    • 50549085548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Let p be the price of the network good. For consumer 1, equating the sum of marginal benefits to the price the network good yields the efficiency condition u11 (q1, q2, u22 (q2, q1, p. For consumer 2, the efficiency condition is u21 (q1, q2, u12 q2, q1, p
    • 1) = p.
  • 89
    • 50549092571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1*) = p.
    • 1*) = p.
  • 90
    • 0001119009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the optimal outcome and Nash equilibria with network effects, see P. H. Dybvig and C. S. Spatt, Adoption Externalities as Public Goods, 20 Journal of Public Economics 231-47 (1983).
    • On the optimal outcome and Nash equilibria with network effects, see P. H. Dybvig and C. S. Spatt, "Adoption Externalities as Public Goods," 20 Journal of Public Economics 231-47 (1983).
  • 91
    • 50549093862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 92
    • 0000221289 scopus 로고
    • Rational Learning Leads to Nash Equilibrium, 61
    • and the references therein. See, e.g
    • See, e.g., E. Kalai and E. Lehrer, "Rational Learning Leads to Nash Equilibrium," 61 Econometrica, 1019-45 (1993) and the references therein.
    • (1993) Econometrica , vol.1019 -45
    • Kalai, E.1    Lehrer, E.2
  • 93
    • 0039001814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Evolution of Pareto-Optimal Behavior in Repeated Coordination Problems 41
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., R. Lagunoff, "On the Evolution of Pareto-Optimal Behavior in Repeated Coordination Problems" 41 International Economic Review 273-93 (2000).
    • (2000) International Economic Review , vol.273 -93
    • Lagunoff, R.1
  • 94
    • 0000257192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Origin of Convention: Evidence from Coordination Games, 107
    • J. B. Van Huyck, R. C. Battalio, and F. W. Rankin, "On the Origin of Convention: Evidence from Coordination Games," 107 Economic Journal 576-96 (1997).
    • (1997) Economic Journal , vol.576 -96
    • Van Huyck, J.B.1    Battalio, R.C.2    Rankin, F.W.3
  • 95
    • 0004161626 scopus 로고
    • Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press
    • F. A. Hayek, The Constitution of Liberty (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1960), p. 160.
    • (1960) The Constitution of Liberty , pp. 160
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 96
    • 50549084171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Spulber, 1999, supra note 5
    • See Spulber, 1999, supra note 5.
  • 97
    • 0001073135 scopus 로고
    • The Use of Knowledge in Society, 35
    • See
    • See F. A. Hayek, "The Use of Knowledge in Society," 35 The American Economic Review 519-30 (1945)
    • (1945) The American Economic Review , vol.519 -30
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 98
    • 50549104183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at pp. 521-522. See also Friedrich Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty, v. 1 Rules and Order (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1973), Chapter 2.
    • at pp. 521-522. See also Friedrich Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty, v. 1 Rules and Order (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1973), Chapter 2.
  • 99
    • 50549090972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hayek, 1945, p. 521
    • Hayek, 1945, p. 521.
  • 100
    • 50549091092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid, pp. 521-2.
  • 101
    • 50549088715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid, p. 524.
  • 102
    • 50549097575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid, p. 527.
  • 103
    • 50549098040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid, p. 528
  • 105
    • 50549098039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the marketing mix and the four Ps of marketing (product, price, place, and promotion), see P. Kotler, Marketing Management, 9th edn (New York: The Free Press, 1999).
    • On the "marketing mix" and the four Ps of marketing (product, price, place, and promotion), see P. Kotler, Marketing Management, 9th edn (New York: The Free Press, 1999).
  • 106
    • 50549089335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T e-mail commercial advertisement, March 29, 2007.
    • AT&T e-mail commercial advertisement, March 29, 2007.
  • 107
    • 50549083812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T website: Attreferrals.com.
    • AT&T website: Attreferrals.com.
  • 108
    • 50549093861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dybvig and Spatt, 1983, discuss government provision of insurance contracts to induce consumers to adopt a network good. The insurance is never paid in equilibrium because consumers adopt the good. They do not consider provision of network goods by private firms. Private firms are better able to create such mechanisms than the public sector. Private firms have far better market information than the government. Governments have cumbersome bureaucracies and are subject to corruption; an agency for the subsidization of consumer adoptions of goods in network industry seems far afield from the standard functions of government. Moreover, the government would need to select technology winners to provide the subsidy. Governments do promote universal service in network industries through common carrier regulations and regulated rates with cross subsidies. Such promotion of universal service is a subject of considerable controversy, however
    • Dybvig and Spatt, 1983, discuss government provision of insurance contracts to induce consumers to adopt a network good. The insurance is never paid in equilibrium because consumers adopt the good. They do not consider provision of network goods by private firms. Private firms are better able to create such mechanisms than the public sector. Private firms have far better market information than the government. Governments have cumbersome bureaucracies and are subject to corruption; an agency for the subsidization of consumer adoptions of goods in network industry seems far afield from the standard functions of government. Moreover, the government would need to select technology winners to provide the subsidy. Governments do promote universal service in network industries through common carrier regulations and regulated rates with cross subsidies. Such promotion of universal service is a subject of considerable controversy, however.
  • 109
    • 50549104059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reuters, April, 10, washingtonpost.com, Apple Press release
    • "Apple Sells More Than 100 Million iPods," Reuters, April, 10, 2007, washingtonpost.com, Apple Press release, http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2007/04/09ipod.html
    • (2007) Apple Sells More Than 100 Million iPods
  • 110
    • 50549092211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 111
    • 50549089967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 112
    • 50549083572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 113
    • 50549086338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
  • 114
    • 50549102787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CIA Factbook, https://www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook/geos/xx.html
  • 115
  • 116
    • 50549083000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Websites are measured in terms of web servers, although one host may have multiple sites by using different domains or port numbers, see Hobbes' Internet Timeline Copyright 1993-2006 by Robert H Zakon, Version: 8.2, ArcHive-location: http://www.zakon.org/robert/internet/timeline/
    • Websites are measured in terms of web servers, although "one host may have multiple sites by using different domains or port numbers," see Hobbes' Internet Timeline Copyright 1993-2006 by Robert H Zakon, Version: 8.2, ArcHive-location: http://www.zakon.org/robert/internet/timeline/
  • 118
    • 50549102656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On measuring the diameter of the Web, see Albert László, Linked: The New Science of Networks (Cambridge, MA: Perseus Publishing, 2002).
    • On measuring the diameter of the Web, see Albert László, Linked: The New Science of Networks (Cambridge, MA: Perseus Publishing, 2002).
  • 121
    • 0001138987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the literature, see A. Devenow and I. Welch, Rational Herding in Financial Economics, 40 European Economic Review 603-15 (1996)
    • For an overview of the literature, see A. Devenow and I. Welch, "Rational Herding in Financial Economics," 40 European Economic Review 603-15 (1996)
  • 123
    • 0001015501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades
    • With herding, inefficiencies can occur if individuals rely on the behavior of other agents rather than on their own private information
    • S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch, "Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades," 12 Journal of Economic Perspectives 151-70 (1998). With herding, inefficiencies can occur if individuals rely on the behavior of other agents rather than on their own private information.
    • (1998) Journal of Economic Perspectives , vol.12 , pp. 151-170
    • Bikhchandani, S.1    Hirshleifer, D.2    Welch, I.3
  • 124
    • 84977727359 scopus 로고
    • Sequential Sales, Learning, and Cascades, 47
    • See
    • See I. Welch, "Sequential Sales, Learning, and Cascades," 47 The Journal of Finance 695-732 (1992)
    • (1992) The Journal of Finance , pp. 695-732
    • Welch, I.1
  • 125
    • 27744568768 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades
    • S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch, "A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades," 100 Journal of Political Economy 992-1026 (1992)
    • (1992) Journal of Political Economy , vol.100 , pp. 992-1026
    • Bikhchandani, S.1    Hirshleifer, D.2    Welch, I.3
  • 126
    • 84960565609 scopus 로고
    • A Simple Model of Herd Behavior
    • Choi connects herd behavior with network effects in the adoption of new technologies
    • A. V. Banerjee, "A Simple Model of Herd Behavior," 107 Quarterly Journal of Economics 797-817 (1992). Choi connects herd behavior with network effects in the adoption of new technologies
    • (1992) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.107 , pp. 797-817
    • Banerjee, A.V.1
  • 127
    • 0040007877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Herd Behavior, the 'Penguin Effect,' and the Suppression of Informational Diffusion: An Analysis of Informational Externalities and Payoff Interdependency, 28
    • see
    • see J. P. Choi, "Herd Behavior, the 'Penguin Effect,' and the Suppression of Informational Diffusion: An Analysis of Informational Externalities and Payoff Interdependency," 28 Rand Journal of Economics 407-25 (1997).
    • (1997) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.407 -25
    • Choi, J.P.1
  • 131
    • 50549083106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Northwestern University Working Paper, 2007, examines a strengthening of the Nash equilibrium requirements to allow blocking by incremental groups. The incremental Nash equilibrium selects the Pareto-dominant Nash equilibrium. This shows that the formation of incremental groups is sufficient for equilibrium adoption decisions to achieve an efficient outcome
    • D. F. Spulber, "The Interplay Between Social Networks and Market Networks," Northwestern University Working Paper, 2007, examines a strengthening of the Nash equilibrium requirements to allow blocking by incremental groups. The incremental Nash equilibrium selects the Pareto-dominant Nash equilibrium. This shows that the formation of incremental groups is sufficient for equilibrium adoption decisions to achieve an efficient outcome.
    • The Interplay Between Social Networks and Market Networks
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 132
    • 50549099332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Liebowitz and Margolis, 1994, supra note 15.
    • Liebowitz and Margolis, 1994, supra note 15.
  • 134
    • 0000917844 scopus 로고
    • The Strength of Weak Ties: A Network Theory Revisited, 1
    • and M. S. Granovetter, "The Strength of Weak Ties: A Network Theory Revisited," 1 Sociological Theory 201-33 (1983).
    • (1983) Sociological Theory , vol.201 -33
    • Granovetter, M.S.1
  • 136
    • 3042771207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For additional discussion, see B. G. Malkiel, The Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its Critics, 17 Journal of Economic Perspectives 59-82 (2003).
    • For additional discussion, see B. G. Malkiel, "The Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its Critics," 17 Journal of Economic Perspectives 59-82 (2003).
  • 137
    • 50549098038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is sometimes referred to as a fulfilled-expectations demand curve. Rohlfs (1974, supra note 18, Economides (1996, and Economides and Himmelberg (1995, supra note 2) conclude that the fulfilled expectations demand is nonmonotonic, that is, it is an inverted u-shaped curve because the willingness-to-pay curve has that slope. However, only the downward-sloping portion of the willingness-to-pay curve is the demand function because the other portion of the curve does not correspond to a stable equilibrium
    • This is sometimes referred to as a fulfilled-expectations demand curve. Rohlfs (1974, supra note 18), Economides (1996), and Economides and Himmelberg (1995, supra note 2) conclude that the fulfilled expectations demand is nonmonotonic, that is, it is an inverted u-shaped curve because the willingness-to-pay curve has that slope. However, only the downward-sloping portion of the willingness-to-pay curve is the demand function because the other portion of the curve does not correspond to a stable equilibrium.
  • 138
    • 50549084170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For corrections of the fable, see John E. Davies, Giffen Goods, the Survival Imperative, and the Irish Potato Culture, 102.3 Journal of Political Economy 547-65 (1994)
    • For corrections of the fable, see John E. Davies, "Giffen Goods, the Survival Imperative, and the Irish Potato Culture," 102.3 Journal of Political Economy 547-65 (1994)
  • 139
    • 21844519744 scopus 로고
    • Sir Robert Giffen and the Great Potato Famine: A Discussion of the Role of a Legend in Neoclassical Economics, XXIX
    • Terrence McDonough and Joseph Eisenhauer, "Sir Robert Giffen and the Great Potato Famine: A Discussion of the Role of a Legend in Neoclassical Economics," XXIX Journal of Economic Issues 747-59 (1995)
    • (1995) Journal of Economic Issues , pp. 747-759
    • McDonough, T.1    Eisenhauer, J.2
  • 140
    • 0033368747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Potato Paradoxes, 107.6 (pt 2)
    • McDonough and Eisenhauer state that the Giffen legend concerning the great potato famine appears at best to be a misinterpretation of some observed but misunderstood phenomenon, and at worst a kind of hoax. For a model with storage, S
    • and Sherwin Rosen, "Potato Paradoxes," 107.6 (pt 2) Journal of Political Economy S294-313 (1999). McDonough and Eisenhauer state that "the Giffen legend concerning the great potato famine appears at best to be a misinterpretation of some observed but misunderstood phenomenon, and at worst a kind of hoax." For a model with storage
    • (1999) Journal of Political Economy , pp. 294-313
    • Rosen, S.1
  • 141
    • 0000064359 scopus 로고
    • The Demand Curves for Giffen Goods are Downward Sloping, 102
    • Claims that demands for luxury or superior goods are upward sloping typically are justified by assumption or by anecdotal speculation see
    • see Yoram Barzel and Wing Suen, "The Demand Curves for Giffen Goods are Downward Sloping," 102 The Economic Journal 896-905 (1992). Claims that demands for luxury or superior goods are upward sloping typically are justified by assumption or by anecdotal speculation
    • (1992) The Economic Journal , pp. 896-905
    • Barzel, Y.1    Suen, W.2
  • 142
    • 62349107040 scopus 로고
    • A Note on Restaurant Pricing and Other Examples of Social Influences on Price, 99
    • see, e.g
    • see, e.g., Gary S. Becker, "A Note on Restaurant Pricing and Other Examples of Social Influences on Price," 99 The Journal of Political Economy 1109-16 (1991)
    • (1991) The Journal of Political Economy , vol.1109 -16
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 143
    • 33747031687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pricing Superior Goods: Utility Generated By Scarcity, 10
    • The claims that network effects lead to upward-sloping demands for network goods similarly have no empirical foundation, although some anecdotes are offered
    • and S. Yao and Ke Li, "Pricing Superior Goods: Utility Generated By Scarcity," 10 Pacific Economic Review 529-38 (2005). The claims that network effects lead to upward-sloping demands for network goods similarly have no empirical foundation, although some anecdotes are offered
    • (2005) Pacific Economic Review , vol.529 -38
    • Yao, S.1    Li, K.2
  • 144
    • 50549096762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, e.g., Rohlfs (1974, supra note 18, and 2001 supra note 80).
    • see, e.g., Rohlfs (1974, supra note 18, and 2001 supra note 80).
  • 145
    • 50549103595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2(n, i) < 0 for all n in [0, N].
    • 2(n, i) < 0 for all n in [0, N].
  • 146
    • 50549101071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The marginal consumer equals the ttal number of consumers N if u(N, N) ≥ p. The marginal consumer also can equal 0 if no one joins the network.
    • The marginal consumer equals the ttal number of consumers N if u(N, N) ≥ p. The marginal consumer also can equal 0 if no one joins the network.
  • 147
    • 50549096511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, 2005, p. 281
    • Hovenkamp, 2005, p. 281.
  • 148
    • 50549096983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., p. 282.
  • 150
    • 50549083455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, 2005, p. 278
    • Hovenkamp, 2005, p. 278.
  • 151
    • 50549091589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If output Q is the sum of Q′ and Q″, the natural monopoly property is defined formally as C(Q) ≤ C(Q′) + C(Q″).
    • If output Q is the sum of Q′ and Q″, the natural monopoly property is defined formally as C(Q) ≤ C(Q′) + C(Q″).
  • 154
    • 50549096635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • n u(n/2, i)di - C(n/2)
    • n u(n/2, i)di - C(n/2)
  • 155
    • 50549099686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • n u(n/2, i)di - 2C(n/2)
    • n u(n/2, i)di - 2C(n/2)
  • 156
    • 50549086924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • n u(n/2, i)di. This condition is simply a restatement of the assumption that consumers prefer more members in a network.
    • n u(n/2, i)di. This condition is simply a restatement of the assumption that consumers prefer more members in a network.
  • 157
    • 0001237271 scopus 로고
    • Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network Externalities, 94
    • See
    • See M. L. Katz and C. Shapiro, "Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network Externalities," 94 The Journal of Political Economy 822-41 (1986).
    • (1986) The Journal of Political Economy , vol.822 -41
    • Katz, M.L.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 158
    • 50549097335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the costs of interconnection, see Katz and Shapiro, 1985, supra note 2.
    • On the costs of interconnection, see Katz and Shapiro, 1985, supra note 2.
  • 159
    • 50549088251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Spulber and Yoo, note 13, for additional discussion related to this point
    • See Spulber and Yoo, 2003, supra note 13, for additional discussion related to this point.
    • (2003) supra
  • 160
    • 0001849038 scopus 로고
    • Why Regulate Utilities?, 11
    • Firms compete for a franchise in a regulated market, see
    • Firms compete for a franchise in a regulated market, see H. Demsetz, "Why Regulate Utilities?," 11 Journal of Law and Economics 55-65 (1968).
    • (1968) Journal of Law and Economics , pp. 55-65
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 161
    • 50549083571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Spulber, 1989 supra note 42 on competition for regulatory franchises. With low entry costs, market is contestable and firms compete to serve the market as in Baumol, Panzer, and Willig, 1982, supra note 96.
    • See also Spulber, 1989 supra note 42 on competition for regulatory franchises. With low entry costs, market is "contestable" and firms compete to serve the market as in Baumol, Panzer, and Willig, 1982, supra note 96.
  • 162
    • 50549091201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The presence of switching costs potentially creates an advantage for an incumbent because the price difference between the incumbent and the entrant must compensate for switching costs. The presence of network effects may interact with switching costs and presumably increase their input, see Farrell and Klemperer (2006, supra note 2). However, an incumbent advantage due to switching costs is not unique to an industry with network effects; any industry in which customers have switching costs can encounter this advantage.
    • The presence of switching costs potentially creates an advantage for an incumbent because the price difference between the incumbent and the entrant must compensate for switching costs. The presence of network effects may interact with switching costs and presumably increase their input, see Farrell and Klemperer (2006, supra note 2). However, an incumbent advantage due to switching costs is not unique to an industry with network effects; any industry in which customers have switching costs can encounter this advantage.
  • 163
    • 50549103239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Katz and Shapiro, 1985, supra note 2.
    • Katz and Shapiro, 1985, supra note 2.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.