메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 6, Issue 1, 2010, Pages 153-202

Innovation and the limits of antitrust

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77955889813     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhp032     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (65)

References (163)
  • 2
    • 77955857538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Google, Zen Master of Market
    • May 17
    • See, e.g., Steve Lohr, Google, Zen Master of Market, N.Y. TIMES, May 17, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2008/07/07/technology/07google.html?pagewanted=pr int; Steve Lohr & Miguel Helft, New Mood in Antitrust May Target Google, N.Y. TIMES, May 17, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/05/18/technology/companies/18antitrust.html
    • (2009) N.Y. Times
    • Lohr, S.1
  • 3
    • 77951754462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Mood in Antitrust May Target Google
    • May 17
    • Steve Lohr & Miguel Helft, New Mood in Antitrust May Target Google, N.Y. TIMES, May 17, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/05/18/technology/companies/18antitrust.html
    • (2009) N.Y. Times
    • Lohr, S.1    Helft, M.2
  • 4
    • 77955869722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They Might Be a Little Evil: Why Google Faces Antitrust Scrutiny
    • May 23
    • Daniel Lyons, They Might Be a Little Evil: Why Google Faces Antitrust Scrutiny, NEWSWEEK, May 23, 2009, available at http://www.newsweek.com/id/198855
    • (2009) Newsweek
    • Lyons, D.1
  • 5
    • 77955720818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case Against the Case Against Google - The Department of Justice Should Take a Hint from the Microsoft Suit: No More Antirust Actions Against Tech Companies
    • July 28
    • Farhad Manjoo, The Case Against the Case Against Google - The Department of Justice Should Take a Hint from the Microsoft Suit: No More Antirust Actions Against Tech Companies, SLATE, July 28, 2009, available at http://www.slate.com/id/2223755
    • (2009) Slate
    • Manjoo, F.1
  • 6
    • 77955878690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • D.C. Antitrust Circles, How Google Became the Hunted
    • Sept. 9
    • Declan McCullagh, In D.C. Antitrust Circles, How Google Became the Hunted, CNET NEWS, Sept. 9, 2008, available at http://news.cnet.com/8301-13578_3-10036948-38.html
    • (2008) Cnet News
    • McCullagh, D.1
  • 7
    • 77955864729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust, Is Google the Next Microsoft
    • July 23
    • Declan McCullagh, On Antitrust, Is Google the Next Microsoft, ZDNET NEWS, July 23, 2007, available at http://news.zdnet.com/2100-9588_22-152610.html
    • (2007) Zdnet News
    • McCullagh, D.1
  • 8
    • 70449342680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Pick Varney Saw Google as New Microsoft
    • Feb. 17
    • James Rowley, Antitrust Pick Varney Saw Google as New Microsoft, BLOOMBERG.COM, Feb. 17, 2009, available at http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aG9B5.J3Bl1w
    • (2009) Bloomberg.Com
    • Rowley, J.1
  • 9
    • 77955868118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posting of Erick Schonfeld to TechCrunch May 11
    • Posting of Erick Schonfeld to TechCrunch, http://www.techcrunch.com/ (May 11, 2009)
    • (2009)
  • 10
    • 79957862477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Is Obama's Top Antitrust Cop Gunning for Google?
    • July 20
    • Fred Vogelstein, Why Is Obama's Top Antitrust Cop Gunning for Google?, WIRED, July 20, 2009, available at http://www.wired.com/techbiz/it/magazine/17-08/mf_googlopoly
    • (2009) Wired
    • Vogelstein, F.1
  • 11
    • 77955878018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May 8, 9:22 EST
    • WSJ Law Blog, http://blogs.wsj.com/law/ (May 8, 2009, 9:22 EST).
    • (2009) WSJ Law Blog
  • 13
    • 77955892502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (May 12, 16:21 EST)
    • See, e.g., Posting of Matthew Karnitschnig to Deal Journal, http://blogs.wsj.com/deals/2009/05/12/putting-the-anti-back-into-antitru st-enforcement/ (May 12, 2009, 16:21 EST)
    • (2009) Posting of Matthew Karnitschnig to Deal Journal
  • 14
    • 77955877378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Giant Step Backward in Antitrust Law
    • May 19
    • Richard Epstein, A Giant Step Backward in Antitrust Law, FORBES, May 19, 2009, available at http://www.forbes.com/2009/05/18/christine-varney-antitrust-opinions-col umnists-law.html.
    • (2009) Forbes
    • Epstein, R.1
  • 15
    • 77955392207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pac. Bel. Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns, Inc., 1113-14 ("Recognizing a price-squeeze claim where the defendant's retail price remains above cost would invite the precise harm we sought to avoid in Brooke Group: Firms might raise their retail prices or refrain from aggressive price competition to avoid potential antitrust liability" and finding it "most troubling [that] firms that seek to avoid price squeeze liability will have no safe harbor for their pricing practices.")
    • Pac. Bel. Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns, Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1109, 1113-14 (2009) ("Recognizing a price-squeeze claim where the defendant's retail price remains above cost would invite the precise harm we sought to avoid in Brooke Group: Firms might raise their retail prices or refrain from aggressive price competition to avoid potential antitrust liability" and finding it "most troubling [that] firms that seek to avoid price squeeze liability will have no safe harbor for their pricing practices.").
    • (2009) S. Ct. , vol.129 , pp. 1109
  • 16
    • 3042777706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the Evidence
    • Robert W. Crandall & Clifford Winston, Does Antitrust Policy Improve Consumer Welfare? Assessing the Evidence, 17 J. ECON. PERSP. 3 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.17 , pp. 3
    • Crandall, R.W.1    Winston, C.2
  • 17
    • 67649218576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring Compliance with Compulsory Licensing Remedies in the American Microsoft Case
    • William H. Page & Seldon J. Childers, Measuring Compliance with Compulsory Licensing Remedies in the American Microsoft Case, 76 ANTITRUST L.J. 239 (2009)
    • (2009) Antitrust L.J. , vol.76 , pp. 239
    • Page, W.H.1    Childers, S.J.2
  • 18
    • 67649185605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mandatory Contracting Remedies in the American and European Microsoft Cases
    • William H. Page, Mandatory Contracting Remedies in the American and European Microsoft Cases, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 787 (2008)
    • (2008) Antitrust L.J. , vol.75 , pp. 787
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 19
    • 67649195316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Software Development as an Antitrust Remedy: Lessons from the Enforcement of the Microsoft Communications Protocol Licensing Requirement
    • William H. Page & Seldon J. Childers, Software Development as an Antitrust Remedy: Lessons from the Enforcement of the Microsoft Communications Protocol Licensing Requirement, 14 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REV. 77 (2008).
    • (2008) Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. , vol.14 , pp. 77
    • Page, W.H.1    Childers, S.J.2
  • 20
    • 57849094991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unlocking Technology: Antitrust and Innovation
    • Daniel F. Spulber, Unlocking Technology: Antitrust and Innovation, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 915 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 915
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 21
    • 0348126262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusivity in Network Industries
    • 674-75
    • See, e.g., Carl Shapiro, Exclusivity in Network Industries, 7 GEO. MASON L. REV. 673, 674-75 (1999).
    • (1999) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 673
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 22
    • 77955907486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This conflation of activity level with success has come from a number of sources, including President Obama. (Nov. 5), (promising to "reinvigorating antitrust enforcement" and asserting that the activity level of enforcement during the Bush administration caused negative consequences for consumers)
    • This conflation of activity level with success has come from a number of sources, including President Obama. See Barack Obama, Senator, Statement to the American Antitrust Institute (Nov. 5, 2009), available at http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/archives/files/aai-%20Presidential%20c ampaign%20-%20Obama%209-07_092720071759.pdf (promising to "reinvigorating antitrust enforcement" and asserting that the activity level of enforcement during the Bush administration caused negative consequences for consumers).
    • (2009) Senator, Statement to the American Antitrust Institute
    • Obama, B.1
  • 23
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Antitrust
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1 (1984).
    • (1984) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 1
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 25
    • 17244378477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neo-Chicago Approach to Unilateral Practices
    • Table 1 originally appears
    • Table 1 originally appears in David S. Evans & Jorge Padilla, Neo-Chicago Approach to Unilateral Practices, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 73 (2005).
    • (2005) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 73
    • Evans, D.S.1    Padilla, J.2
  • 26
    • 77955908781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • There are really two separate points here. The first is the inevitability of errors with decision by legal rule generally. See Easterbrook, supra note 14, at 14-15 (reiterating that "[O]ne cannot have the savings of decision by rule without accepting the costs of mistakes"). The second point is that the likelihood of antitrust error depends crucially on the development of economic science to produce techniques and methods by which we can successfully identify conduct that harms consumers.
  • 27
    • 0042648955 scopus 로고
    • Workable Antitrust Policy
    • See also Frank H. Easterbrook, Workable Antitrust Policy, 84 MICH. L. REV. 1696 (1986).
    • (1986) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1696
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 28
    • 77955868458 scopus 로고
    • This is a point most often attributed to then Judge Breyer's well-known admonition that antitrust rules "must be administratively workable and therefore cannot always take account of every complex economic circumstance or qualification." Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 22 (1st Cir.). But the Chicago School of antitrust has traditionally shared with Breyer's Harvard School a preference for using economics to generate simple and administrable rules rather than overly sophisticated economic tests
    • This is a point most often attributed to then Judge Breyer's well-known admonition that antitrust rules "must be administratively workable and therefore cannot always take account of every complex economic circumstance or qualification." Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 22 (1st Cir. 1990). But the Chicago School of antitrust has traditionally shared with Breyer's Harvard School a preference for using economics to generate simple and administrable rules rather than overly sophisticated economic tests.
    • (1990)
  • 29
    • 47049093858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Roberts Court and the Chicago School of Antitrust: The 2006 Term and Beyond
    • 27
    • See Joshua D. Wright, The Roberts Court and the Chicago School of Antitrust: The 2006 Term and Beyond, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 25, 27 (2007)
    • (2007) Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.3 , pp. 25
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 30
    • 70349096585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix
    • 32-35
    • William Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 32-35 (2007).
    • (2007) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , vol.2007 , pp. 1
    • Kovacic, W.1
  • 31
    • 70349199464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overshot the Mark? A Simple Explanation of the Chicago School's Influence on Antitrust
    • See generally Joshua D. Wright, Overshot the Mark? A Simple Explanation of the Chicago School's Influence on Antitrust, 5 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 179 (2009)
    • (2009) Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.5 , pp. 179
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 32
    • 0035730228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying Law and Policy: A Decision Theoretic Approach
    • Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 469 (2001)
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.69 , pp. 469
    • Hylton, K.N.1    Salinger, M.2
  • 33
    • 0033410755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules
    • C. Frederick Beckner, III & Steven C. Salop, Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 41 (1999).
    • (1999) Antitrust L.J. , vol.67 , pp. 41
    • Beckner C.F., III.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 34
    • 24644465518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference
    • See generally James C. Cooper, Luke M. Froeb, Dan O'Brien & Michael G. Vita, Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 639 (2005).
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 639
    • Cooper, J.C.1    Froeb, L.M.2    O'Brien, D.3    Vita, M.G.4
  • 35
    • 77955909115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law and Economics of Monopolization Standards
    • See also Keith N. Hylton, The Law and Economics of Monopolization Standards, in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS (2009).
    • (2009) Antitrust Law and Economics
    • Hylton, K.N.1
  • 36
    • 77955875300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Multiple academics review the existing theory and evidence on vertical restraints and single-firm conduct more generally and uniformly conclude that the practices at issue are generally procompetitive and that antitrust rules should "slant" toward requiring plaintiffs to demonstrate clear anticompetitive effect before condemning finding violations.
  • 37
    • 57049133680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive Contracts and Vertical Restraints: Empirical Evidence and Public Policy
    • Paolo Buccirossi ed
    • Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Exclusive Contracts and Vertical Restraints: Empirical Evidence and Public Policy, in HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS (Paolo Buccirossi ed., 2008)
    • (2008) Handbook of Antitrust Economics
    • Lafontaine, F.1    Slade, M.2
  • 38
    • 77955907787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints
    • Daniel P. O'Brien, The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints, in REPORT: THE PROS AND CONS OF VERTICAL RESTRAINTS 40 (2008), available at http://www.konkurrensverket.se/upload/Filer/Trycksaker/Rapporter/Pros &Cons/rap_pros_and_cons_vertical_restraints.pdf.
    • (2008) Report: The Pros and Cons of Vertical Restraints , pp. 40
    • O'brien, D.P.1
  • 39
    • 77955909467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Obviously, this choice of loss function need not be a "mistake" unless compared with a regime where the loss function is measured exclusively by total or consumer welfare. Quite the contrary, the decision to incorporate non-economic arguments is generally deliberate. For example, Cooper et al. explore the possibility that concerns with market integration in the European Union and a higher tolerance for Type 1 error deriving from a less generous system of private rights of action explain divergent treatment of vertical restraints between the EU and the United States.
  • 40
    • 70349217749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements and Exclusive Dealing
    • (Keith N. Hylton ed.) (summarizing the literature and empirical evidence on exclusive dealing contracts)
    • See also Alden F. Abbott & Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements and Exclusive Dealing, in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2009) (summarizing the literature and empirical evidence on exclusive dealing contracts).
    • (2009) Antitrust Law and Economics
    • Abbott, A.F.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 41
    • 79751520696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Too Complicated for Generalist Judges?
    • (George Mason Univ. Sch. of Law, Working Paper, Aug. 21)(finding a statistically significant tendency for economically trained judges to perform better in simple antitrust cases, but not those involving sophisticated economic evidence)
    • See generally Michael R. Baye & Joshua D. Wright, Is Antitrust Too Complicated for Generalist Judges? The Impact of Economic Complexity and Judicial Training on Appeals (George Mason Univ. Sch. of Law, Working Paper, Aug. 21, 2009), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1319888 (finding a statistically significant tendency for economically trained judges to perform better in simple antitrust cases, but not those involving sophisticated economic evidence).
    • (2009) The Impact of Economic Complexity and Judicial Training on Appeals
    • Baye, M.R.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 42
    • 80055026676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commissioner Rosch, Rhetoric, and the Relationship Between Economics and Antitrust
    • (June 12, 11:55 AM)
    • Joshua Wright, Commissioner Rosch, Rhetoric, and the Relationship Between Economics and Antitrust, TRUTH ON THE MARKET (June 12, 2009, 11:55 AM), http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2009/06/12/commissioner-rosch-rhetoric-a nd-the-relationship-between-economics-and-antitrust/
    • (2009) Truth On The Market
    • Wright, J.1
  • 43
    • 77955886624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Indeed, one of the most powerful implications of the error-cost framework is one that creates some tension for economically minded antitrust scholars. The implication is that a movement toward sophisticated rule-of-reason standards that attempt to determine fully the competitive effects of a given practice on a case-by-case basis with modern economic tools, a movement many antitrust economists support, is likely to increase error costs if sufficient attention is not paid to the administrability of the tests.
  • 45
    • 67249125922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Law and Regulatory Gaming
    • See, e.g., Stacey L. Dogan & Mark A. Lemley, Antitrust Law and Regulatory Gaming, 87 TEX. L. REV. 685 (2009).
    • (2009) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 685
    • Dogan, S.L.1    Lemley, M.A.2
  • 46
    • 0003241064 scopus 로고
    • Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research
    • (Victor R. Fuchs ed.). For more modern critiques of the industrial organization literature in the same vein
    • Ronald Coase, Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in POLICY ISSUES AND RESEARCH OPPORTUNITIES IN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (Victor R. Fuchs ed., 1972). For more modern critiques of the industrial organization literature in the same vein
    • (1972) Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization
    • Coase, R.1
  • 47
    • 1442354820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics and Antitrust
    • see Timothy J. Muris, Economics and Antitrust, 5 GEO. MASON. L. REV. 303 (1997)
    • (1997) Geo. Mason. L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 303
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 48
    • 0346746606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Game Theory and Antitrust: A Post Mortem
    • (reviewing critiques of the IO literature)
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi, Game Theory and Antitrust: A Post Mortem, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 411 (1997) (reviewing critiques of the IO literature)
    • (1997) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 411
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 49
    • 27844549838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust
    • See Alan Meese, Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 21 (2005)
    • (2005) J. Competition L. & Econ , vol.1 , pp. 21
    • Meese, A.1
  • 50
    • 84977424533 scopus 로고
    • How Many Cheers for Antitrust's 100 Years?
    • Harold Demsetz, How Many Cheers for Antitrust's 100 Years? 30 ECON. INQ. 207 (1992).
    • (1992) Econ. Inq. , vol.30 , pp. 207
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 51
    • 70350145065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (recommending that "in industries where innovation, intellectual property, and technological change are central features... antitrust enforcers should carefully consider market dynamics in assessing competitive effects....")
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMMISSION, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 32 (2007) (recommending that "in industries where innovation, intellectual property, and technological change are central features... antitrust enforcers should carefully consider market dynamics in assessing competitive effects....").
    • (2007) Antitrust Modernization Commission, Report and Recommendations , pp. 32
  • 52
    • 77955855921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust, Multi-Dimensional Competition, and Innovation: Do We Have An Antitrust Relevant Theory of Competition Now?
    • (Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright eds., Cambridge Univ. Press, forthcoming 2010)
    • See, e.g., Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust, Multi-Dimensional Competition, and Innovation: Do We Have An Antitrust Relevant Theory of Competition Now?, in REGULATING INNOVATION: COMPETITION POLICY AND PATENT LAW UNDER UNCERTAINTY (Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright eds., Cambridge Univ. Press, forthcoming 2010)
    • (2010) Regulating Innovation: Competition Policy and Patent Law Under Uncertainty
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 53
    • 77955872731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see generally Geoffrey A. Manne & Joshua D. Wright in id. ch. 1, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1462489.
    • Manne, G.A.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 55
    • 70349790701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition and Innovation
    • 583 (W. Dale Collins ed., 2008) ("economic theory does not provide unambiguous support either for the view that market power generally threatens innovation by lowering the return to innovative efforts nor the Schumpeterian view that concentrated markets generally promote innovation.")
    • accord Richard J. Gilbert, Competition and Innovation, in 1 ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY 577, 583 (W. Dale Collins ed., 2008) ("economic theory does not provide unambiguous support either for the view that market power generally threatens innovation by lowering the return to innovative efforts nor the Schumpeterian view that concentrated markets generally promote innovation.").
    • (2008) Issues in Competition Law and Policy , vol.1 , pp. 577
    • Gilbert, R.J.1
  • 56
    • 77955872061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • It should be noted that Gilbert takes from this mixed record the implication that presumptions that product market competition increases innovation should be applied under certain conditions and that generally, case-by-case fact-specific analysis is appropriate. This is in line with the general view of economists that rule-of-reason analysis is best suited for situations where competing theories render predictions on consumer welfare indeterminate. We do not agree for reasons discussed in Parts III and IV. The primary point is that where economic science generates indeterminate predictions, asking judges to resolve the debate requires an unrealistic degree of economic literacy. An alternative approach, and the one advocated in The Limits of Antitrust, is to harness existing economic knowledge into simple presumptions that can reduce error rates. We note in passing, moreover, that to the extent that we are correct about the relationship between antitrust enforcement and error costs, the empirical failure of the Schumpeterian hypothesis may be a consequence of a long history of antitrust enforcement decisions that account insufficiently for the benefits of monopoly to innovation.
  • 57
    • 0001426594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valuation of New Goods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition
    • (Bresnahan & Gordon eds.) (discussing the consumer welfare gains from new product introductions and product line extensions)
    • See, e.g., Jerry Hausman, Valuation of New Goods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition, in THE ECONOMICS OF NEW GOODS 209-67 (Bresnahan & Gordon eds., 1997) (discussing the consumer welfare gains from new product introductions and product line extensions).
    • (1997) The Economics of New Goods , pp. 209-267
    • Hausman, J.1
  • 60
    • 31944442162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (July 15). ("In the same way that a visitor from Mars who reads only the mathematical 10 literature could mistakenly conclude that the U.S. economy is rife with monopoly power, it would be a mistake to infer that the growing volume of theoretical papers examining bundling or bundled rebates as an exclusionary device implies that there is any growing or significant danger from the anticompetitive use of bundling.")
    • see also Comments from Timothy J. Muris, Antitrust Law, Economics, and Bundled Discounts (July 15, 2005), available at http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/amc/commission_hearings/pdf/Muris.pdf ("In the same way that a visitor from Mars who reads only the mathematical 10 literature could mistakenly conclude that the U.S. economy is rife with monopoly power, it would be a mistake to infer that the growing volume of theoretical papers examining bundling or bundled rebates as an exclusionary device implies that there is any growing or significant danger from the anticompetitive use of bundling.").
    • (2005) Antitrust Law, Economics, and Bundled Discounts
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 61
    • 0000438997 scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory
    • 212
    • Armen Alchian, Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory, 58 J. POL. ECON. 211, 212 (1950).
    • (1950) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.58 , pp. 211
    • Alchian, A.1
  • 62
    • 0000145602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring the Social Return to R&D
    • (estimating that the social return to R&D investment far exceeds the private return, meaning existing incentives for innovation are already lower than optimal)
    • Charles I. Jones & John C. Williams, Measuring the Social Return to R&D, 113 Q.J. ECON. 1119 (1998) (estimating that the social return to R&D investment far exceeds the private return, meaning existing incentives for innovation are already lower than optimal).
    • (1998) Q.J. Econ. , vol.113 , pp. 1119
    • Jones, C.I.1    Williams, J.C.2
  • 63
    • 0035579072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust in the New Economy
    • 927
    • Richard A. Posner, Antitrust in the New Economy, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925, 927 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.68 , pp. 925
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 65
    • 77955890875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • In addition to a general insensitivity to the facts and market conditions of the particular cases in which these theorems are to be applied, as noted above, the literature is particularly insensitive to the institutional and political economy limitations of enforcers and courts.
  • 66
    • 77955862055 scopus 로고
    • Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 273 (2d., Cir.) (citations omitted)
    • Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 273 (2d., Cir. 1979) (citations omitted).
    • (1979)
  • 67
    • 77955898154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Including language evidencing a concern for the substantial risk and cost of false positives created by uncertain or overly complex application of the antitrust laws. Id. at 282. ("But it is difficult to comprehend how a major corporation, accustomed though it is to making business decisions with antitrust considerations in mind, could possess the omniscience to anticipate all the instances in which a jury might one day in the future retrospectively conclude that predisclosure was warranted.").
  • 69
    • 77955875628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • It is worth noting that Kodak's share of the camera market was less consistently under pressure during this period, with a significant bump attributable to its introduction of the Pocket 110 camera at issue in the case. Also notable, however, is that its most significant decline (seven percentage points) in camera market share came from competitors in this very market, only about one year after the introduction of the Pocket 110.
  • 70
    • 77955876383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The lower court's decision is made only more troubling by the fact that Kodak did offer advance disclosure of its innovation (for a fee)-but apparently the two months of advance notice given to Berkey were insufficient.
  • 71
    • 49649089333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition Policy: Toward a New Approach
    • 30-31
    • Federico Etro, Competition Policy: Toward a New Approach, 2 EUR. COMPETITION J 29, 30-31 (2006).
    • (2006) Eur. Competition J. , vol.2 , pp. 29
    • Etro, F.1
  • 72
    • 0001849038 scopus 로고
    • Why Regulate Utilities?
    • Harold Demsetz, Why Regulate Utilities?, 11 J.L. & ECON. 55 (1968).
    • (1968) J.L. & Econ. , vol.11 , pp. 55
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 73
    • 0040419158 scopus 로고
    • Predation, Monopolization and Antitrust
    • Such theories abound. (Schmalensee & Willig eds.)
    • Such theories abound. See, e.g., Janusz Ordover & Garth Saloner, Predation, Monopolization and Antitrust, in HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 538 (Schmalensee & Willig eds., 1989).
    • (1989) Handbook of Industrial Organization , pp. 538
    • Ordover, J.1    Saloner, G.2
  • 74
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mandatory dealing Verizon Comm'ns., Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 408 ("Requires antitrust courts to act as central planners, identifying the proper price, quantity, and other terms of dealing-a role for which they are ill-suited.")
    • Mandatory dealing Verizon Comm'ns., Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 408 (2005) ("Requires antitrust courts to act as central planners, identifying the proper price, quantity, and other terms of dealing-a role for which they are ill-suited.").
    • (2005) U.S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
  • 75
    • 0346617007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essential Facilities
    • For a comprehensive assessment of the problem of mandatory access and the essential facilities doctrine as an antitrust remedy and theory
    • For a comprehensive assessment of the problem of mandatory access and the essential facilities doctrine as an antitrust remedy and theory, see Abbott B. Lipsky, Jr. & J. Gregory Sidak, Essential Facilities, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1187 (1999).
    • (1999) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 1187
    • Lipsky A.B., Jr.1    Sidak, J.G.2
  • 76
    • 77955881813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 603 F.2d at 281
    • Berkey Photo, 603 F.2d at 281.
    • Photo, B.1
  • 77
    • 77950589811 scopus 로고
    • U.S. 422, 436 n.13 and citing Sargent-Welch Scientific Co., 567 F.2d at 712
    • United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. 422, 436 n.13 (1978) and citing Sargent-Welch Scientific Co., 567 F.2d at 712.
    • (1978) United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co. , pp. 422
  • 78
    • 77955874600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hot Docs vs. Cold Economics: The Use and Misuse of Business Documents in Antitrust Enforcement and Adjudication
    • 647-48. Harold Demsetz makes a related point in the context of predatory pricing: "A price cut to obtain new customers imposes as much harm on rivals as a price cut whose objective is to harm them."
    • Geoffrey A. Manne & E. Marcellus Williamson, Hot Docs vs. Cold Economics: The Use and Misuse of Business Documents in Antitrust Enforcement and Adjudication, 47 ARIZ. L. REV. 609, 647-48 (2005). Harold Demsetz makes a related point in the context of predatory pricing: "A price cut to obtain new customers imposes as much harm on rivals as a price cut whose objective is to harm them."
    • (2005) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 609
    • Manne, G.A.1    Williamson, E.M.2
  • 79
    • 84912874627 scopus 로고
    • Barriers to Entry
    • 54. It is hard to know what value evidence of intent could have where a claim depends on proof of injury and injury is as likely a result of anticompetitive as procompetitive intent
    • Harold Demsetz, Barriers to Entry, 72 AM. ECON. REV. 47, 54 (1982). It is hard to know what value evidence of intent could have where a claim depends on proof of injury and injury is as likely a result of anticompetitive as procompetitive intent.
    • (1982) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 47
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 80
    • 77955916489 scopus 로고
    • A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881 F.2d 1396, 1402 (7th Cir. 1989) (emphasis in original)
    • A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc., 881 F.2d 1396, 1402 (7th Cir. 1989) (emphasis in original).
    • (1989)
  • 82
    • 77955879854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although this section focuses on the U.S. Microsoft case, the relevant cites for the relevant decisions from both the U.S. and the EU are: United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir.)
    • Although this section focuses on the U.S. Microsoft case, the relevant cites for the relevant decisions from both the U.S. and the EU are: United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001)
    • (2001)
  • 83
    • 77955881119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case COMP/C-3/37.792 Microsoft, Commission Decision of 24 March 2004, [hereinafter EC Decision]
    • Case COMP/C-3/37.792 Microsoft, Commission Decision of 24 March 2004, available at http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/antitrust/cases/decisions/37792/en .pdf [hereinafter EC Decision]
    • (2004)
  • 84
    • 77955893996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • European Commission v. Microsoft Corp., Judgment of the Court of First Instance (Grand Chamber), Case T-201/04. Sept. 17 [hereinafter CFI Decision]
    • European Commission v. Microsoft Corp., Judgment of the Court of First Instance (Grand Chamber), Case T-201/04. Sept. 17, 2007, available at http://curia.europa.eu/jurisp/cgibin/form.pl?lang=EN&Submit=Recherch er$docrequire=alldocs&numaff=T-201/04&datefs=&datefe= &nomusuel=&domaine=&mots=&resmax=100 [hereinafter CFI Decision].
    • (2007)
  • 85
    • 77955902948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • have done yeomen's work in discussing the Microsoft cases
    • William Page and John Lopatka have done yeomen's work in discussing the Microsoft cases.
    • Page, W.1    Lopatka, J.2
  • 86
    • 78049297508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition Policy and the Incentive to Innovate: The Dynamic Effects of Microsoft v. Commission
    • See also Daniel F. Spulber, Competition Policy and the Incentive to Innovate: The Dynamic Effects of Microsoft v. Commission, 25 YALE J. ON REG. 101 (2008).
    • (2008) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.25 , pp. 101
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 87
    • 0001606417 scopus 로고
    • Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy
    • Compare Stan J. Liebowitz & Stephen E. Margolis, Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. 133 (1994)
    • (1994) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.8 , pp. 133
    • Stan, C.J.1    Liebowitz2    Margolis, S.E.3
  • 88
    • 0348126262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusivity in Network Industries
    • Carl Shapiro, Exclusivity in Network Industries, 7 GEO. MASON L. REV. 673 (1999).
    • (1999) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 673
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 90
    • 0002981164 scopus 로고
    • Systems Competition and Network Effects
    • Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Systems Competition and Network Effects, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. 93 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.8 , pp. 93
    • Katz, M.L.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 91
    • 77955904927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 55 (D.C. Cir. 2001)
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 55 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
    • (2001)
  • 92
    • 77955894352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • The district court was not quite so circumspect.
  • 93
    • 77955915799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Jan.)
    • Wired Magazine, Posts (Jan. 2007), available at http://www.wired.com/wired/archive/15.01/posts.html?pg=6.
    • (2007) Wired Magazine, Posts
  • 94
    • 77955881448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • This diminution is especially ironic given that it is based at least in part on the court's assessment that Microsoft's long-term, dynamic concerns about entry were too remote, even though the applicable structural literature is entirely concerned with long-term, dynamic efficiency effects.
  • 96
    • 77955866041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Timothy F. Bresnahan & Robert J. Gordon eds.)
    • See generally THE ECONOMICS OF NEW GOODS 209 (Timothy F. Bresnahan & Robert J. Gordon eds., 1997)
    • (1997) The Economics of New Goods , pp. 209
  • 97
    • 50549093002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer Coordination in the Small and in the Large: Implications for Antitrust in Markets with Network Effects
    • 209
    • Daniel F. Spulber, Consumer Coordination in the Small and in the Large: Implications for Antitrust in Markets with Network Effects, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 207, 209 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 207
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 98
    • 77955860202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Even Judge Posner falls into this trap in his discussion of the Standard Fashion case (Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston Co., 258 U.S. 346 (1922)) in Antitrust in the New Economy. There, Judge Posner suggests that Standard Fashion's exclusive dealing contracts may have been problematic because of economies of scale in distribution-the desire on the part of consumers (and thus retailers) to have a complete line of clothing available to choose from at a single store. Judge Posner makes the analogy to network effects explicit, arguing that "the network corresponds to the full-line retail store" and that Standard Fashion could use exclusive dealing with the local dry-goods monopolist retailer to deter the entry of rivals. However, the Standard Fashion as New Economy exclusion story does not hold up to scrutiny.
  • 99
    • 70349213021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive Dealing as Competition on the Merits
    • 146-52 First, Standard Fashion's product line did not appear, in fact, to be essential to retailers. Second, the contracts were only two years in duration and thus unlikely to deter entry for a period of time significant enough to prevent substitution. Third, as Klein explains, Standard Fashion's exclusive dealing contract was likely an attempt to align promotional incentives between Standard Fashion and its retailers
    • See Benjamin Klein, Exclusive Dealing as Competition on the Merits, 12 J. GEO. MASON L. REV. 119, 146-52 (2003). First, Standard Fashion's product line did not appear, in fact, to be essential to retailers. Second, the contracts were only two years in duration and thus unlikely to deter entry for a period of time significant enough to prevent substitution. Third, as Klein explains, Standard Fashion's exclusive dealing contract was likely an attempt to align promotional incentives between Standard Fashion and its retailers.
    • (2003) J. Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12 , pp. 119
    • Klein, B.1
  • 100
    • 84934562707 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms
    • (explaining vertical restraints as mechanisms to solve this pervasive incentive conflict over promotional services and induce retailer performance)
    • See Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms, 31 J.L. & ECON. 265 (1988) (explaining vertical restraints as mechanisms to solve this pervasive incentive conflict over promotional services and induce retailer performance)
    • (1988) J.L. & Econ. , vol.31 , pp. 265
    • Klein, B.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 101
    • 43949103054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Slotting Contracts
    • (applying this framework to explain supermarket slotting contracts for premium shelf space as a form of promotion). But even absent procompetitive justification, the claim of foreclosure is a tenuous one. First, at some price, consumers would willingly visit multiple stores to collect their wardrobes if the cost of doing so were less than the monopoly overcharge they would have to pay to buy from Standard Fashion's complete line at its exclusive retailers; network effects have their limits. Second and more important, for how long would Standard Fashion's clothing remain in fashion? Fashion is, in fact, notoriously fleeting and even dominant brands and designs find themselves quickly displaced as tastes change. The appropriate trade-off in this, as in all cases, is whether the cost of monopoly over its duration without intervention outweighs the cost of enforcement plus the savings from (potentially) curtailing anticompetitive conduct more quickly than it would end without intervention.
    • Benjamin Klein & Joshua D. Wright, The Economics of Slotting Contracts, 50 J.L. & ECON 473 (2007) (applying this framework to explain supermarket slotting contracts for premium shelf space as a form of promotion). But even absent procompetitive justification, the claim of foreclosure is a tenuous one. First, at some price, consumers would willingly visit multiple stores to collect their wardrobes if the cost of doing so were less than the monopoly overcharge they would have to pay to buy from Standard Fashion's complete line at its exclusive retailers; network effects have their limits. Second and more important, for how long would Standard Fashion's clothing remain in fashion? Fashion is, in fact, notoriously fleeting and even dominant brands and designs find themselves quickly displaced as tastes change. The appropriate trade-off in this, as in all cases, is whether the cost of monopoly over its duration without intervention outweighs the cost of enforcement plus the savings from (potentially) curtailing anticompetitive conduct more quickly than it would end without intervention. The fact that the conduct had clear procompetitive justification (having nothing to do with network effects) makes this minimal calculation all the more essential.
    • (2007) J.L. & Econ , vol.50 , pp. 473
    • Klein, B.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 102
    • 77955862054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • At the same time, the list could be even more inclusive (and is not meant to be exhaustive). For example, Intel has encountered antitrust problems arising from its pricing practices-practices which are sophisticated and interesting, but not particularly innovative; we declined to treat Intel as a business innovation case. But, of course, Intel is in a dramatically innovative industry. It is, in fact, the New Economy character of its business-particularly the problem of recouping the extraordinarily high fixed costs of product innovation given low marginal costs-that leads Intel to engage in its controversial contracting practices. In this way, Intel presents a typical product innovation case.
  • 103
    • 77955870759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Product innovations, of course, are not themselves limited to the New Economy; however, it is only New Economy products, characterized by network effects or employing far-reaching restrictions on the use of intellectual property, that seem to draw antitrust scrutiny.
  • 104
    • 77955862371 scopus 로고
    • From Von's to Schwinn to the Chicago School: Interview with Judge Richard Posner
    • Seventh Circuit Court of Appeals, (Spring)
    • From Von's to Schwinn to the Chicago School: Interview with Judge Richard Posner, Seventh Circuit Court of Appeals, ANTITRUST 4-5 (Spring 1992).
    • (1992) Antitrust , pp. 4-5
  • 105
    • 0007101958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2d ed. ("the fatal flaw in the government's case was to ignore the easy and rapidity of entry into the retail grocery industry")
    • See also Richard A. Posner, ANTITRUST LAW 127 (2d ed. 2001) ("the fatal flaw in the government's case was to ignore the easy and rapidity of entry into the retail grocery industry").
    • (2001) Antitrust Law , pp. 127
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 106
    • 0035586774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Von's Grocery and the Concentration-Price Relationship in Grocery Retail
    • (providing empirical evidence that the retail grocery industry examined in Vons was highly competitive and that, even at modern concentration levels, there was no positive correlation between market concentration and price)
    • See also Joshua D. Wright, Von's Grocery and the Concentration-Price Relationship in Grocery Retail, 48 UCLA L. REV. 743 (2001) (providing empirical evidence that the retail grocery industry examined in Vons was highly competitive and that, even at modern concentration levels, there was no positive correlation between market concentration and price).
    • (2001) UCLA L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 743
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 108
    • 77955865730 scopus 로고
    • White House Task Force Report on Antitrust Policy
    • 14-15, 65-76
    • White House Task Force Report on Antitrust Policy, 2 ANTITRUST L. & ECON. REV. 11, 14-15, 65-76 (1968-69).
    • (1968) Antitrust L. & Econ. Rev. , vol.2 , pp. 11
  • 109
    • 84878093039 scopus 로고
    • 386 U.S. 568 (1967).
    • (1967) U.S. , vol.386 , pp. 568
  • 110
    • 84873647722 scopus 로고
    • 384 U.S. 546 (1966).
    • (1966) U.S. , vol.384 , pp. 546
  • 111
    • 79851469389 scopus 로고
    • 370 U.S. 294 (1962).
    • (1962) U.S. , vol.370 , pp. 294
  • 112
    • 0039027645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Policy: A Century of Legal and Economic Thinking
    • 52
    • William E. Kovacic & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Policy: A Century of Legal and Economic Thinking, 14 J. ECON. PERSP. 43, 52 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.14 , pp. 43
    • Kovacic, W.E.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 113
    • 84977355595 scopus 로고
    • The Influence of Economics on Antitrust Law
    • 295-96 describing features of U.S. competition policy system that give economists major role in shaping antitrust rules)
    • See also William E. Kovacic, The Influence of Economics on Antitrust Law, 30 J. ECON. INQ. 294, 295-96 (1992) (describing features of U.S. competition policy system that give economists major role in shaping antitrust rules).
    • (1992) J. Econ. Inq. , vol.30 , pp. 294
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 114
    • 0347414384 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 281 (Stewart, J., dissenting)
    • United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. 270, 281 (1966) (Stewart, J., dissenting).
    • (1966) U.S. , vol.384 , pp. 270
  • 115
    • 70350458216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy
    • Timothy J. Muris, Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy, 12 GEO. MASON L. REV. 1 (2003).
    • (2003) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12 , pp. 1
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 116
    • 0002589676 scopus 로고
    • Two Systems of Belief About Monopoly
    • (Harvey J. Goldschmid et al. eds.)
    • Harold Demsetz, Two Systems of Belief About Monopoly, in INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION: THE NEW LEARNING 164 (Harvey J. Goldschmid et al. eds., 1974).
    • (1974) Industrial Concentration: The New Learning , pp. 164
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 118
    • 79851490238 scopus 로고
    • 220 U.S. 373 (1911).
    • (1911) U.S. , vol.220 , pp. 373
  • 119
    • 0040901346 scopus 로고
    • Resale Price Maintenance: What Do Economists Know and When Did They Know It?
    • (claiming that Alfred Marshall's Principles of Economics was the first product distributed under an RPM scheme in the United States)
    • See William Breit, Resale Price Maintenance: What Do Economists Know and When Did They Know It?, J. INST. & THEOR. ECON. 147 (1991) (claiming that Alfred Marshall's Principles of Economics was the first product distributed under an RPM scheme in the United States).
    • (1991) J. Inst. & Theor. Econ. , pp. 147
    • Breit, W.1
  • 120
    • 77955889737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 220 U.S. at 400.
    • U.S. , vol.220 , pp. 400
  • 121
    • 84870591535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 551 U.S. 877 (2007).
    • (2007) U.S. , vol.551 , pp. 877
  • 122
    • 70349194189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dr. Miles is Dead. Now What? Structuring a Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance
    • For a proposed structural rule-of-reason approach consistent with an error cost approach
    • For a proposed structural rule-of-reason approach consistent with an error cost approach, see Thomas A. Lambert, Dr. Miles is Dead. Now What? Structuring a Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance, 50 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1937 (2009).
    • (2009) Wm. & Mary L. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 1937
    • Lambert, T.A.1
  • 124
    • 57049133680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical Assessment of Exclusive Contracts
    • (Paolo Buccirossi ed.)
    • Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Empirical Assessment of Exclusive Contracts, in HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS (Paolo Buccirossi ed., 2008).
    • (2008) Handbook of Antitrust Economics
    • Lafontaine, F.1    Slade, M.2
  • 125
    • 77955907787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints: Beyond the Possibility Theorems
    • 80 (Konkurrensverket, Swedish Competition Authority)
    • Daniel P. O'Brien, The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints: Beyond the Possibility Theorems, in REPORT: THE PROS AND CONS OF VERTICAL RESTRAINTS 40, 80 (Konkurrensverket, Swedish Competition Authority, 2008), available at http://www.konkurrensverket.se/upload/Filer/Trycksaker/Rapporter/Pros &Cons/rap_pros_and_cons_vertical_restraints.pdf.
    • (2008) Report: The Pros and Cons of Vertical Restraints , pp. 40
    • O'Brien, D.P.1
  • 126
    • 76649105370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Petitioner at 16, Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc (No. 06-480) WL 173681
    • See Brief of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Petitioner at 16, Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc, 127 S. Ct. 2705 (No. 06-480), 2007 WL 173681.
    • (2007) S. Ct. , vol.127 , pp. 2705
  • 127
    • 76649105370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc
    • Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 2705 (2007).
    • (2007) S. Ct. , vol.127 , pp. 2705
  • 128
    • 84934562707 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms
    • Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms, 31 J.L. & ECON. 265 (1988).
    • (1988) J.L. & Econ. , vol.31 , pp. 265
    • Klein, B.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 129
    • 43949103054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Slotting Contracts
    • See also Benjamin Klein & Joshua D. Wright, The Economics of Slotting Contracts, 50 J.L. & ECON 473 (2007).
    • (2007) J.L. & Econ , vol.50 , pp. 473
    • Klein, B.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 130
    • 84878083365 scopus 로고
    • White Motor Co. v. United States, 261 ("This is the first case involving a territorial restriction in a vertical arrangement; and we know too little of the actual impact of both that restriction and the one respecting customers to reach a conclusion on the bare bones of the documentary evidence before us.")
    • White Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U.S. 253, 261 (1963) ("This is the first case involving a territorial restriction in a vertical arrangement; and we know too little of the actual impact of both that restriction and the one respecting customers to reach a conclusion on the bare bones of the documentary evidence before us.").
    • (1963) U.S. , vol.372 , pp. 253
  • 131
    • 27844533222 scopus 로고
    • Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc. 351 (citing White and referring to the "the established position that a new per se rule is not justified until the judiciary obtains considerable rule-of-reason experience with the particular type of restraint challenged")
    • Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc., 457 U.S. 332, 351 n.19 (1982) (citing White and referring to the "the established position that a new per se rule is not justified until the judiciary obtains considerable rule-of-reason experience with the particular type of restraint challenged")
    • (1982) U.S. , vol.457 , Issue.19 , pp. 332
  • 132
    • 84870626592 scopus 로고
    • Broad. Music, Inc. v. CBS, 9 ("it is only after considerable experience with certain business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations" and going on to say that "We have never examined a practice like this one before; indeed, the Court of Appeals recognized that "[i]n dealing with performing rights in the music industry we confront conditions both in copyright law and in antitrust law which are sui generis. And though there has been rather intensive antitrust scrutiny of ASCAP and its blanket licenses, that experience hardly counsels that we should outlaw the blanket license as a per se restraint of trade.")
    • Broad. Music, Inc. v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 9 (1979) ("it is only after considerable experience with certain business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations" and going on to say that "We have never examined a practice like this one before; indeed, the Court of Appeals recognized that "[i]n dealing with performing rights in the music industry we confront conditions both in copyright law and in antitrust law which are sui generis. And though there has been rather intensive antitrust scrutiny of ASCAP and its blanket licenses, that experience hardly counsels that we should outlaw the blanket license as a per se restraint of trade.").
    • (1979) U.S. , vol.441 , pp. 1
  • 133
    • 27844513106 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 607-08, 92 S.Ct. 1126, 1133-34, 31 L.Ed.2d 515 ("It is only after considerable experience with certain business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations of the Sherman Act.")
    • United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 607-08, 92 S.Ct. 1126, 1133-34, 31 L.Ed.2d 515 (1972) ("It is only after considerable experience with certain business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations of the Sherman Act.").
    • (1972) U.S. , vol.405 , pp. 596
  • 134
    • 77955905270 scopus 로고
    • Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla. v. NCAA, 707 F.2d 1147, 1166
    • Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla. v. NCAA, 707 F.2d 1147, 1166 (1984).
    • (1984)
  • 135
    • 77955914016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • "While every 'business relationship' will in some sense have unique features, some represent entire, novel categories of dealings. As we shall explain, the arrangement before us is an example of the latter, offering the first up-close look at the technological integration of added functionality into software that serves as a platform for third-party applications. There being no close parallel in prior antitrust cases, simplistic application of per se tying rules carries a serious risk of harm. Accordingly, we vacate the District Court's finding of a per se tying violation and remand the case. Plaintiffs may on remand pursue their tying claim under the rule of reason." United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 87 (2001).
  • 136
    • 77955906860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, Janis and Lemley have proposed the use of intent evidence in this context, as a way of identifying problematic product introductions. (Supp.) § 12.4. We note, however, that a weaker form of our proposal might require proof of anticompetitive intent before assigning liability in product introduction cases
    • Hovenkamp, Janis and Lemley have proposed the use of intent evidence in this context, as a way of identifying problematic product introductions. See HERBERT HOVENKAMP, MARK D. JANIS & MARK A. LEMLEY, 1 IP AND ANTITRUST (2005 Supp.) § 12.4. We note, however, that a weaker form of our proposal might require proof of anticompetitive intent before assigning liability in product introduction cases.
    • (2005) Ip and Antitrust , vol.1
    • Hovenkamp, H.1    Janis, M.D.2    Lemley, M.A.3
  • 137
    • 0042191796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Intent
    • Far more problematic is the approach taken in the U.S. Microsoft case, which shifted the burden of demonstrating procompetitive justification for product design decisions to the defendants. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 203 F.3d at 64-67
    • See Ronald A. Cass & Keith N. Hylton, Antitrust Intent, 74 S. CAL. L. REV. 657 (2001). Far more problematic is the approach taken in the U.S. Microsoft case, which shifted the burden of demonstrating procompetitive justification for product design decisions to the defendants. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 203 F.3d at 64-67.
    • (2001) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 657
    • Cass, R.A.1    Hylton, K.N.2
  • 138
    • 77955854907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • Note that this was one of the issues in the interminable IBM case, but, of course, distinguishing between "predatory" product innovations and real innovations is an intractable problem, and the case was, after 13 years, dropped.
  • 139
    • 77955889067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • We exclude naked horizontal restraints because, as discussed, the per se rule is appropriate in instances where economic and empirical learning suggests that a business practice has a high likelihood of producing anticompetitive effects. The prophylactic language of the Clayton Act requires that we exclude non-consummated horizontal mergers.
  • 140
    • 0035583308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided
    • 675 ("efficiencies are hard to measure, and the benefit of the doubt should go to defendants, not to plaintiffs; otherwise, the continued generation of the large efficiency benefits responsible for raising our standard of living will be jeopardized")
    • See Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 659, 675 (2001) ("efficiencies are hard to measure, and the benefit of the doubt should go to defendants, not to plaintiffs; otherwise, the continued generation of the large efficiency benefits responsible for raising our standard of living will be jeopardized").
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.68 , pp. 659
    • Carlton, D.W.1
  • 141
    • 0345809009 scopus 로고
    • Price Fixing: The Probability of Detection of Getting Caught
    • See, e.g., Peter G. Bryant & E. Woodrow Eckard, Jr., Price Fixing: The Probability of Detection of Getting Caught, 73 REV. OF ECON. & STAT. 531 (1991)
    • (1991) Rev. Of Econ. & Stat. , vol.73 , pp. 531
    • Bryant, P.G.1    Eckard E.W., Jr.2
  • 142
    • 70350595433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic Leniency and Cartel Enforcement
    • see also Nathan H. Miller, Strategic Leniency and Cartel Enforcement, 99 AM. ECON. REV. 750 (2009).
    • (2009) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 750
    • Miller, N.H.1
  • 143
    • 77955875943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Separate statement of Dennis Carlton, ("I favor a reduction in the multiple to single damages when the actions are overt (e.g., exclusive dealing)")
    • Separate statement of Dennis Carlton, Antitrust Modernization Committee Report and Recommendations 399-400 ("I favor a reduction in the multiple to single damages when the actions are overt (e.g., exclusive dealing)").
    • Antitrust Modernization Committee Report and Recommendations , pp. 399-400
  • 144
    • 0001367604 scopus 로고
    • Predatory Pricing and Practices Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act
    • See Phillip Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Predatory Pricing and Practices Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 88 HARV. L. REV. 697 (1975)
    • (1975) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 697
    • Areeda, P.1    Turner, D.F.2
  • 145
    • 77955907166 scopus 로고
    • Predatory Pricing
    • 899-90 (proposing that courts "refuse to consider intent, unless the party relying upon it gives the tribunal reason to believe that his evidence is unusually probative"). Areeda himself saw the problem outside of the predatory pricing context
    • Phillip Areeda, Predatory Pricing, 49 ANTITRUST L.J. 897, 899-90 (1981) (proposing that courts "refuse to consider intent, unless the party relying upon it gives the tribunal reason to believe that his evidence is unusually probative"). Areeda himself saw the problem outside of the predatory pricing context.
    • (1981) Antitrust L.J. , vol.49 , pp. 897
    • Areeda, P.1
  • 146
    • 84928461119 scopus 로고
    • Monopolization, Mergers, and Markets: A Century Past and Future
    • 963-65 (discussing problems with the use of intent evidence in monopolization cases). Many others, including Frank Easterbrook, have also noted the problem and suggested limitations like the one we propose here
    • See Phillip Areeda, Monopolization, Mergers, and Markets: A Century Past and Future, 75 CAL. L. REV. 959, 963-65 (1987) (discussing problems with the use of intent evidence in monopolization cases). Many others, including Frank Easterbrook, have also noted the problem and suggested limitations like the one we propose here.
    • (1987) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 959
    • Areeda, P.1
  • 147
    • 77955910279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LePage's Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 159-63 (3d Cir. 2003)
    • LePage's Inc. v. 3M, 324 F.3d 141, 159-63 (3d Cir. 2003).
  • 148
    • 0039671701 scopus 로고
    • On Identifying Exclusionary Conduct
    • 973
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, On Identifying Exclusionary Conduct, 61 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 972, 973 (1986).
    • (1986) Notre Dame L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 972
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 149
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Comm. Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP
    • Verizon Comm. Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004).
    • (2004) U.S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
  • 151
    • 48049085957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, (concluding that "liability for mere unilateral refusals to license will not play a meaningful part in the interface between patent rights and antitrust protections")
    • See also U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND PROTECTING COMPETITION 23-24 (2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf (concluding that "liability for mere unilateral refusals to license will not play a meaningful part in the interface between patent rights and antitrust protections")
    • (2007) Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Protecting Competition , pp. 23-24
  • 152
    • 77955912086 scopus 로고
    • (Univ. of Chicago Press) (noting that "it cannot be sound antitrust law that, when Congress refuses or omits to regulate some aspect of a natural monopolist's behavior, the antitrust court will step in and, by decree, supply the missing regulatory regime")
    • Richard A. Posner, ANTITRUST LAW 243-44 (Univ. of Chicago Press 1976) (noting that "it cannot be sound antitrust law that, when Congress refuses or omits to regulate some aspect of a natural monopolist's behavior, the antitrust court will step in and, by decree, supply the missing regulatory regime").
    • (1976) Antitrust Law , pp. 43-44
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 153
    • 0006608377 scopus 로고
    • Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles
    • P. E. Areeda, Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles, 58 ANTITRUST L. J. 841 (1989).
    • (1989) Antitrust L. J. , vol.58 , pp. 841
    • Areeda, P.E.1
  • 154
    • 0035583308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided
    • D. W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen and Kodak Are Misguided, 68 ANTITRUST L. J. 659 (2001).
    • (2001) Antitrust L. J. , vol.68 , pp. 659
    • Carlton, D.W.1
  • 155
    • 77955911094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holding Innovation to an Antitrust Standard
    • R. J. Gilbert, Holding Innovation to an Antitrust Standard, 3 COMP. POL'Y. INT'L. 3 (2007).
    • (2007) Comp. Pol'y. Int'l. , vol.3 , pp. 3
    • Gilbert, R.J.1
  • 158
    • 0001606417 scopus 로고
    • Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy
    • S. J. Liebowitz & Stephen E. Margolis, Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy, 8 J. ECON. PERSP. 133 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.8 , pp. 133
    • Liebowitz, S.J.1    Margolis, S.E.2
  • 162
    • 78049297508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition Policy and the Incentive to Innovate: The Dynamic Effects of Microsoft v. Commission
    • D. F. Spulber, Competition Policy and the Incentive to Innovate: The Dynamic Effects of Microsoft v. Commission, 25 YALE J. ON REG. 101 (2008).
    • (2008) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.25 , pp. 101
    • Spulber, D.F.1
  • 163
    • 50549093002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer Coordination in the Small and in the Large: Implications for Antitrust in Markets with Network Effects
    • D. F. Spulber, Consumer Coordination in the Small and in the Large: Implications for Antitrust in Markets with Network Effects, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 207 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 207
    • Spulber, D.F.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.