메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 5, Issue 1, 2009, Pages

Overshot the mark? a simple explanation of the chicago school's influence on antitrust

(1)  Wright, Joshua D a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 70349199464     PISSN: 15540189     EISSN: 15546853     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (18)

References (261)
  • 1
    • 70349211365 scopus 로고
    • Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Nobel Memorial Lecture: The Process and Progress of Economics (Dec. 8, 1982), Karl-Göran, Mäler ed., World Scientific Publishing Co., Singapore at
    • George Stigler, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Nobel Memorial Lecture: The Process and Progress of Economics (Dec. 8, 1982), in NOBEL LECTURES, ECONOMICS 1981-1990 (Karl-Göran, Mäler ed., World Scientific Publishing Co., Singapore 1992) at 67.
    • (1992) Nobel Lectures, Economics 1981-1990 , pp. 67
    • Stigler, G.1
  • 2
    • 70349192487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 67-69
    • Id. at 67-69.
  • 3
    • 70349203493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rhetorical battles over whether economics qualifies as a science aside, there is no serious debate that the antitrust economics literature conforms to the scientific method and that there is universal agreement that economics should inform antitrust analysis
    • Rhetorical battles over whether economics qualifies as a science aside, there is no serious debate that the antitrust economics literature conforms to the scientific method and that there is universal agreement that economics should inform antitrust analysis.
  • 4
    • 77955907787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The antitrust treatment of vertical restraints: Beyond the possibility theorems
    • Note
    • See Daniel P. O'Brien, The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints: Beyond the Possibility Theorems, in REPORT: THE PROS AND CONS OF VERTICAL RESTRAINTS 40, 80 Konkurrensverket, Swedish Competition Authority, 2008), available at http://www.konkurrensverket.se/upload/Filer/Trycksaker/Rapporter/ Pros&Cons/rap pros and cons vertical restraints.pdf. O'Brien refers to this body of literature as the 1984 Synthesis, rather than the Chicago Synthesis, because the latter has mistakenly come to be associated with an unscientific, non'interventionist view toward the antitrust treatment of vertical practices. While OBriens point is well taken, because one purpose of this review is to confront these mistaken associations directly, we elect to use Chicago School without loss of generality.
    • REPORT: The Pros and Cons of Vertical Restraints 40
    • O'Brien Daniel, P.1
  • 6
    • 70349220579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • See id. at 5-6, for the assertions that conservative economic analysis has impacted U.S. antitrust enforcement such that it is characterized by "preferences for economic models over facts [and] outright mistakes in matters of doctrine," and that "extreme interpretations and misinterpretations of conservative economic theory (and constant disregard of facts) have come to dominate antitrust," to the detriment of consumers.
  • 8
    • 70349208278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • President Obama, for instance, has promised to °direct my administration to reinvigorate antitrust enforcement. Posting of Joshua D. Wright to Truth On The Market, http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2008/11/05/ antitrust under president obama i will direct my administration to reinvigorate antitrust enforcement/ (Nov. 5, 2008, 9:53 EST). President Obamas respective nominee to head the Federal Trade Commission, Commissioner Leibowitz, has already cited favorably to OVERSHOT THE MARK in a policy speech. Jon Leibowitz, Commissioner, FTC, Remarks at Section 5 Workshop (Oct. 17, 2008) (available at http://ftc.gov/speeches/leibowitz/081017section5.pdf). Similarly, Christine Varney has publicly applauded the American Antitrust Institute Transition Report, which adopts an explicitly Post Chicago vision of antitrust enforcement, noting that "a great framework that starts it and I do endorse the conclusion. Posting of Joshua D. Wright to Truth On The Market, http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2009/02/22/doj aag designate christine varney on section 2 europe google a puzzling statement about error costs/ (Feb. 22, 2009 21:10 EST).
  • 9
    • 70349216148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 (2007) (for discussion of plausibility standard)
    • See Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 (2007) (for discussion of plausibility standard).
  • 10
    • 70349206844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHAN VAN OVERTVELDT, THE CHICAGO SCHOOL: HOW THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ASSEMBLED THE THINKERS WHO REVOLUTIONIZED ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS (Agate B2 2007)
    • JOHAN VAN OVERTVELDT, THE CHICAGO SCHOOL: HOW THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ASSEMBLED THE THINKERS WHO REVOLUTIONIZED ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS (Agate B2 2007).
  • 12
    • 0002342504 scopus 로고
    • The fire of truth: Remembrance of law and economics at chicago, 1932-1970
    • Edmund W. Kitch, The Fire of Truth: Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago, 1932-1970, 26 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1983);
    • (1983) J.L. & Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 163
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 13
    • 0039027645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust policy: A century of economic and legal thinking
    • William E. Kovacic & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking, 14 J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES 43 (2000);
    • (2000) J. Econ. Perspectives , vol.14 , pp. 43
    • Kovacic, W.E.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 14
    • 0346248849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying meets the new institutional economics: Farewell to the chimera of forcing
    • Alan J. Meese, Tying Meets the New Institutional Economics: Farewell to the Chimera of Forcing, 146 U. PA. L. REV. 1 (1997);
    • (1997) U. PA. L. REV. , vol.146 , pp. 1
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 15
    • 0346883458 scopus 로고
    • The chicago school and the evolution of antitrust: Characterization, antitrust injury, and evidentiary sufficiency
    • William H. Page, The Chicago School and the Evolution of Antitrust: Characterization, Antitrust Injury, and Evidentiary Sufficiency, 75 VA. L. REV. 1221 (1989);
    • (1989) VA. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 1221
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 16
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The Chicago school of antitrust
    • Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925 (1969).
    • (1969) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 925
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 17
    • 70349194191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pitofsky, supra note 5, at 3, 5; Daniel L. Rubinfeld, On the Foundations of Antitrust Law and Economics, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 51, 52; Richard Schmalensee, Thoughts on the Chicago Legacy in U.S. Antitrust, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 11, 22
    • See, e.g., Pitofsky, supra note 5, at 3, 5; Daniel L. Rubinfeld, On the Foundations of Antitrust Law and Economics, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 51, 52; Richard Schmalensee, Thoughts on the Chicago Legacy in U.S. Antitrust, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 11, 22.
  • 18
    • 46049113694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Chicago school and exclusionary conduct
    • For discussions of Bork's efforts, see Frank H. Easterbrook, The Chicago School and Exclusionary Conduct, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 439 (2008);
    • (2008) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.31 , pp. 439
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 19
    • 46149118959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judge bork, consumer welfare, and antitrust law
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg, Judge Bork, Consumer Welfare, and Antitrust Law, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 449 (2008);
    • (2008) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.31 , pp. 449
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1
  • 20
    • 46049113900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The abiding influence of the antitrust paradox
    • George L. Priest, The Abiding Influence of The Antitrust Paradox, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 455 (2008).
    • (2008) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.31 , pp. 455
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 21
    • 47049093858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The roberts court and the chicago school of antitrust: The 2006 term and beyond
    • (arguing that Chicago School economic principles successfully characterize the Roberts Court antitrust jurisprudence)
    • Joshua D. Wright, The Roberts Court and the Chicago School of Antitrust: The 2006 Term and Beyond, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 24 (2007) (arguing that Chicago School economic principles successfully characterize the Roberts Court antitrust jurisprudence).
    • (2007) Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.3 , pp. 24
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 22
    • 84881916088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Analysis of Exclusionary Vertical Conduct: Where Chicago Has Overshot the Mark
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 144 (for the claim that "it is important to recognize that [the Post Chicago] approach has its root in the economic analysis of Chicago School commentators," referring to the work of Aaron Director &
    • See Steven C. Salop, Economic Analysis of Exclusionary Vertical Conduct: Where Chicago Has Overshot the Mark, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 141, 144 (for the claim that "it is important to recognize that [the Post Chicago] approach has its root in the economic analysis of Chicago School commentators," referring to the work of Aaron Director &
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 141
    • Salop, S.C.1
  • 23
    • 0001658192 scopus 로고
    • Law and the future: Trade regulation
    • Edward H. Levi, Law and the Future: Trade Regulation, 51 NW. U. L. REV. 281 (1956);
    • (1956) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 281
    • Levi, E.H.1
  • 24
    • 70349211364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Director and levi after 40 years: The anti antitrust agenda revisited
    • Peter C. Carstensen, Director and Levi After 40 Years: The Anti Antitrust Agenda Revisited, 17 MCLR 37, 40 (1996)
    • (1996) MCLR 37 , vol.17 , pp. 40
    • Carstensen, P.C.1
  • 25
    • 70349226473 scopus 로고
    • Comment, vertical forestalling under the antitrust laws
    • (for the proposition that Director and Levi's analysis was a precursor to the raising rivals' costs hypothesis)
    • (for the proposition that Director and Levi's analysis was a precursor to the raising rivals' costs hypothesis); Comment, Vertical Forestalling Under the Antitrust Laws, 19 U. CHI. L. REV. 583 (1952).
    • (1952) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 583
  • 26
    • 0030529224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monopolization by "raising rivals' costs": The standard oil case
    • See, e.g. Elizabeth Granitz & Benjamin Klein, Monopolization by "Raising Rivals' Costs": The Standard Oil Case, 39 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1996);
    • (1996) J.L. & Econ. , vol.39 , pp. 1
    • Granitz, E.1    Klein, B.2
  • 27
    • 0036340592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The strategic use of tying to preserve and create market power in evolving industries
    • Dennis Carlton & Michael Waldman, The Strategic Use of Tying to Preserve and Create Market Power in Evolving Industries, 33 RAND J. ECON. 194 (2002).
    • (2002) Rand J. Econ. , vol.33 , pp. 194
    • Carlton, D.1    Waldman, M.2
  • 28
    • 70349096585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The intellectual dna of modern u.s. competition law for dominant firm conduct: The chicago harvard double helix
    • See William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1 (2007).
    • (2007) Colum. Bus. L. Rev. , vol.2007 , pp. 1
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 29
    • 70349205158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harvard, not chicago: Which antitrust school drives recent u.s. supreme court decisions?
    • Einer Elhauge, Harvard, Not Chicago: Which Antitrust School Drives Recent U.S. Supreme Court Decisions?, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 59 (2007).
    • (2007) Competition Pol'y Int'l , vol.3 , pp. 59
    • Elhauge, E.1
  • 30
    • 70349206843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 20
    • For claims that Chicago School economics caused courts to adopt erroneous economic principles and get specific cases wrong, see e.g. Schmalensee, supra note 12, at 19, 20;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 19
    • Schmalensee1
  • 31
    • 84887985422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Influence of conservative economic analysis on the development of the law of antitrust
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 44
    • Thomas E. Kauper, Influence of Conservative Economic Analysis on the Development of the Law of Antitrust, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 40, 44;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 40
    • Kauper, T.E.1
  • 32
    • 84887890665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The harvard and chicago schools and the dominant firm
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 113
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Harvard and Chicago Schools and the Dominant Firm, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 109, 113;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 109
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 33
    • 70349201841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comment on herbert hovenkamp and the dominant firm: The chicago school has made us too cautious about false positives and the use of section 2 of the sherman act
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 126
    • Harvey J. Goldschmid, Comment on Herbert Hovenkamp and the Dominant Firm: The Chicago School Has Made Us Too Cautious About False Positives and the Use of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 123, 126;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 123
    • Goldschmid, H.J.1
  • 34
    • 84887858933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The sylvania free rider justification for downstream power vertical restraints: Truth or invitation for pretext?
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 191
    • Warren S. Grimes, The Sylvania Free Rider Justification for Downstream Power Vertical Restraints: Truth or Invitation for Pretext?, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 181, 191;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 181
    • Grimes, W.S.1
  • 35
    • 70349192484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Free riding: An overstated, and unconvincing, explanation for resale price maintenance
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 201
    • Marina Lao, Free Riding: An Overstated, and Unconvincing, Explanation for Resale Price Maintenance, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 196, 201.
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 196
    • Lao, M.1
  • 36
    • 70349206842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For claims that the Chicago School caused courts to develop sub optimal legal rules, see e.g. Schmalensee, supra note 12, at 19; Kauper, id. at 42
    • For claims that the Chicago School caused courts to develop sub optimal legal rules, see e.g. Schmalensee, supra note 12, at 19; Kauper, id. at 42;
  • 37
    • 78049319487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The efficiency paradox
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 79-80
    • Eleanor M. Fox, The Efficiency Paradox, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 77, 79-80;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 77
    • Fox, E.M.1
  • 38
    • 84887904966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The chicago school's foundation is flawed: Antitrust protects consumers, not efficiency
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111
    • John B. Kirkwood & Robert H. Lande, The Chicago School's Foundation is Flawed: Antitrust Protects Consumers, Not Efficiency, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 89, 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111.
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 89
    • Kirkwood, J.B.1    Lande, R.H.2
  • 39
    • 84899002470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conservative economics and antitrust: A variety of influences
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 36-37; Rubinfeld, supra note 12, at 52; Fox, id. at 81; Kirkwood & Lande, at 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111
    • For claims that the Chicago School influenced antitrust policy in the wrong direction, see e.g. F.M. Scherer, Conservative Economics and Antitrust: A Variety of Influences, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 30, 36-37; Rubinfeld, supra note 12, at 52; Fox, id. at 81; Kirkwood & Lande, supra, at 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111.
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 30
    • Scherer, F.M.1
  • 40
    • 70349226472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (July 25, 2007, 13:07 EST)
    • Posting of Joshua D. Wright to Truth On The Market, http://www. truthonthemarket.com/2007/07/25/chicago post chicagopost post Chicago on using shorthand labels responsibly/ (July 25, 2007, 13:07 EST).
    • Truth On The Market
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 41
    • 70349203491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This section relies on my earlier work on the influence of the Chicago School on the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence. See Wright, supra note 14
    • This section relies on my earlier work on the influence of the Chicago School on the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence. See Wright, supra note 14.
  • 42
    • 70349209875 scopus 로고
    • (David Wall, ed., Univ. of Chicago Press
    • CHICAGO ESSAYS IN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT vii (David Wall, ed., Univ. of Chicago Press 1972).
    • (1972) Chicago Essays in Economic Development , vol.7
  • 44
    • 70349214507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Chicago School does not deserve all of the credit for this revolution. Kovacic convincingly demonstrates that the intellectual foundations of monopolization doctrine were generated by both Chicago and Harvard, and with substantial convergence between the two. See Kovacic, supra note 17. Additionally, Elhauge argues that the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence represents a shift away from Chicago and toward Harvard. See Elhauge, supra note 18
    • The Chicago School does not deserve all of the credit for this revolution. Kovacic convincingly demonstrates that the intellectual foundations of monopolization doctrine were generated by both Chicago and Harvard, and with substantial convergence between the two. See Kovacic, supra note 17. Additionally, Elhauge argues that the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence represents a shift away from Chicago and toward Harvard. See Elhauge, supra note 18.
  • 47
    • 84925886171 scopus 로고
    • Little Brown and Co.
    • (questioning the causal link between market concentration and price, and providing alternative efficiency based explanations for the correlation); HARVEY J. GOLDSCHMID ET AL., INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION: THE NEW LEARNING (Little Brown and Co. 1974).
    • (1974) Industrial Concentration: The New Learning
    • Goldschmid, H.J.1
  • 48
    • 70350458216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Improving the economic foundations of competition policy, 12
    • Professors Demsetz and Armen Alchian are frequently associated with the Chicago School despite the fact that both spent the bulk of their careers at the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA). As any UCLA economist should note, the antitrust community has sometimes allowed the Chicago School to take credit for many of the contributions from UCLA economists such as Alchian, Demsetz, Benjamin Klein, and others. The contributions of the UCLA economists to antitrust analysis are discussed by former FTC Chairman, and UCLA alumnus, Timothy J. Muris. See Timothy J. Muris, Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy, 12 GEO MASON L. REV. 1 (2003).
    • (2003) Geo Mason L. Rev. , vol.1
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 49
    • 70349211363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two systems of belief about monopolyindustrial concentration
    • INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION
    • Harold Demsetz, Two Systems of Belief About Monopoly, in INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION, supra note 26.
    • Supra Note , vol.26
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 50
    • 70349216139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics and antitrust, 5
    • The contributions of Demsetz and other participants in the famous Airlie House Conference are discussed in Timothy J. Muris, Economics and Antitrust, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 303 (1997).
    • (1997) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.303
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 52
    • 30344441222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aaron director's influence on antitrust policy, 48
    • see also Sam Peltzman, Aaron Director's Influence on Antitrust Policy, 48 J.L. & ECON. 313 (2005).
    • (2005) J.L. & Econ. , vol.48 , pp. 313
    • Peltzman, S.1
  • 53
    • 70349217746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Seminal contributions from the Chicago School literature include, but are not limited to
    • Seminal contributions from the Chicago School literature include, but are not limited to,
  • 54
    • 9944242970 scopus 로고
    • Vertical integration and the sherman act: The legal history of an economic misconception, 22
    • Robert H. Bork, Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act: The Legal History of an Economic Misconception, 22 U. CHI. L. REV. 157 (1954);
    • (1954) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 55
    • 70349216140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aaron Director &
    • Aaron Director &
  • 56
    • 0001658192 scopus 로고
    • Law and the future of trade regulation, 51
    • Edward H. Levi, Law and the Future of Trade Regulation, 51 NW. U. L. REV. 281 (1956)
    • (1956) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.281
    • Levi, E.H.1
  • 58
    • 0002268909 scopus 로고
    • Tying arrangements and the leverage problem, 67
    • Ward S. Bowman, Tying Arrangements and the Leverage Problem, 67 YALE L.J. 19 (1957);
    • (1957) Yale L.J. , vol.19
    • Bowman, W.S.1
  • 59
    • 0001706928 scopus 로고
    • Predatory price cutting: The standard oil (nj) case, 1
    • John S. McGee, Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (NJ) Case, 1 J.L. & ECON. 137 (1958);
    • (1958) J.L. & Econ. , vol.137
    • McGee, J.S.1
  • 60
    • 0002917143 scopus 로고
    • Why should manufacturers want fair trade?, 3
    • Lester G. Telser, Why Should Manufacturers Want Fair Trade?, 3 J.L. & ECON. 86 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.86
    • Telser, L.G.1
  • 61
    • 67649382948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust
    • A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., Elsevier B.V. available at
    • See, e.g., Louis Kaplow & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust, in 2 HANDBOOK OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 1073 (A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., Elsevier B.V. 2007) available at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/antitrust2007. pdf.
    • (2007) 2 Handbook of Law and Economics , vol.1073
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 62
    • 50349094196 scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing, 25
    • Howard P. Marvel, Exclusive Dealing, 25 J.L & ECON. 1 (1982);
    • (1982) J.L & Econ. , vol.1
    • Marvel, H.P.1
  • 63
    • 34548129589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The expanded economics of free riding: How exclusive dealing prevents free riding and creates undivided loyalty, 74
    • Benjamin Klein & Andres V. Lerner, The Expanded Economics of Free Riding: How Exclusive Dealing Prevents Free Riding and Creates Undivided Loyalty, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 473 (2007);
    • (2007) Antitrust L.J. , vol.473
    • Klein, B.1    Lerner, A.V.2
  • 64
    • 57049175970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing intensifies competition for distribution, 75
    • Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Exclusive Dealing Intensifies Competition for Distribution, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 433(2008).
    • (2008) Antitrust L.J. , vol.433
    • Klein, B.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 65
    • 43949103054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economics of slotting contracts, 50
    • Benjamin Klein & Joshua D. Wright, The Economics of Slotting Contracts, 50 J.L. & ECON. 473 (2007);
    • (2007) J.L. & Econ. , vol.473
    • Klein, B.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 66
    • 34548142981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Slotting contracts and consumer welfare, 74
    • Joshua D. Wright, Slotting Contracts and Consumer Welfare, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 439 (2007);
    • (2007) Antitrust L.J. , vol.439
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 67
    • 70449367148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust law and competition for distribution, 23
    • Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Law and Competition for Distribution, 23 YALE J. ON REG. 169 (2006).
    • (2006) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.169
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 68
    • 84934562707 scopus 로고
    • Vertical restraints as contract enforcement mechanisms, 31
    • Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms, 31 J.L & ECON. 265 (1988).
    • (1988) J.L & Econ. , vol.265
    • Klein, B.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 69
    • 70349200414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc., v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997); Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993); Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007); Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns., Inc., No. 07 512, 2009 U.S. Lexis 1635 (U.S. Feb. 25, 2009)
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc., v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997); Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993); Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007); Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns., Inc., No. 07 512, 2009 U.S. Lexis 1635 (U.S. Feb. 25, 2009).
  • 70
    • 70349223523 scopus 로고
    • The limits of antitrust, 65
    • See, e.g., Frank Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 65 TEX. L. REV. 1 (1984).
    • (1984) TEX. L. Rev. , vol.1
    • Easterbrook, F.1
  • 71
    • 0009043973 scopus 로고
    • The next step in the antitrust treatment of restricted distribution: Per se legality, 48
    • Richard A. Posner, The Next Step in the Antitrust Treatment of Restricted Distribution: Per Se Legality, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 6 (1981).
    • (1981) U. CHI. L. Rev. , vol.6
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 73
    • 3042797973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A preface to post chicago antitrust
    • Antonio Cucinotta et al. eds., Edward Elgar Publishing
    • On the Post Chicago approach to antitrust, see Jonathan B. Baker, A Preface to Post Chicago Antitrust, in POST CHICAGO DEVELOPMENTS IN ANTITRUST LAW 60 (Antonio Cucinotta et al. eds., Edward Elgar Publishing 2003).
    • (2003) Post Chicago Developments in Antitrust Law , pp. 60
    • Baker, J.B.1
  • 74
    • 0000211369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying, foreclosure, and exclusion
    • A seminal paper in this literature is Michael D. Whinston, Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 837 (2000).
    • (2000) AM. Econ. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 837
    • Whinston, M.D.1
  • 75
    • 84934452640 scopus 로고
    • Anticompetitive exclusion: Raising rivals' costs to achieve power over price
    • See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power over Price, 96 YALE L.J. 209 (1986).
    • (1986) Yale L.J. , vol.96 , pp. 209
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 76
    • 31944445616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does economics provide a reliable guide to regulating commodity bundling by firms? a survey of the economic literature
    • surveying the bundling literature
    • See, e.g., Whinston, supra note 40; Carlton & Waldman, supra note 16; see also Bruce Kobayashi, Does Economics Provide A Reliable Guide to Regulating Commodity Bundling By Firms? A Survey of the Economic Literature, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 707 (2005) (surveying the bundling literature);
    • (2005) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 707
    • Kobayashi, B.1
  • 79
    • 35348915494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Naked exclusion, efficient breach, and downstream competition
    • John Simpson & Abraham L. Wickelgren, Naked Exclusion, Efficient Breach, and Downstream Competition, 97 AM. ECON. REV. 1305 (2007);
    • (2007) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1305
    • Simpson, J.1    Wickelgren, A.L.2
  • 80
    • 23044523110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predatory pricing: Strategic theory and legal policy
    • Patrick Bolton, Joseph F. Brodley & Michael H. Riordan, Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy, 88 GEO. L.J. 2239 (2000).
    • (2000) Geo. L.J. , vol.88 , pp. 2239
    • Bolton, P.1    Brodley, J.F.2    Riordan, M.H.3
  • 81
    • 27844587041 scopus 로고
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc.
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
    • (1992) U.S. , vol.504 , pp. 451
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 82
    • 70349223521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The reckoning of Post-Chicago antitrust
    • POST-CHICAGO DEVELOPMENTS IN ANTITRUST
    • In aftermarket "lock-in" cases most closely resembling the Post-Chicago theories in Kodak, lower courts have "bent over backwards to construe Kodak as narrowly as possible." See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Reckoning of Post-Chicago Antitrust, in POST-CHICAGO DEVELOPMENTS IN ANTITRUST, supra note 39, at 8;
    • Supra Note , vol.39 , pp. 8
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 83
    • 4944266176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fall of the kodak aftermarket doctrine: Dying a slow death in the lower courts
    • see also David A.J. Goldfine & Kenneth M. Vorrasi, The Fall of the Kodak Aftermarket Doctrine: Dying A Slow Death in the Lower Courts, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 209 (2004);
    • Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 209
    • Goldfine, D.A.J.1    Vorassi, K.M.2
  • 84
    • 69549098449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism, substantive preemption, and limits on antitrust: An application to patent holdup
    • forthcoming (extending Goldfine and Vorrasi's analysis through 2007 and confirming their results)
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi & Joshua D. Wright, Federalism, Substantive Preemption, and Limits on Antitrust: An Application to Patent Holdup, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2009) (extending Goldfine and Vorrasi's analysis through 2007 and confirming their results).
    • (2009) J. Competition L. & Econ.
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 85
    • 0742288973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The modern evolution of competition policy enforcement norms
    • William E. Kovacic, The Modern Evolution of Competition Policy Enforcement Norms, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 377 (2003).
    • (2003) Antitrust L.J. , vol.71 , pp. 377
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 86
    • 70349195642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kovacic's primary theme is that the Chicago/Post Chicago narrative minimizes the contributions of the Harvard School scholars such as Professors Phillip Areeda and Donald Turner, as well as Justice Stephen Breyer
    • See Kovacic, supra note 17. Kovacic's primary theme is that the Chicago/Post Chicago narrative minimizes the contributions of the Harvard School scholars such as Professors Phillip Areeda and Donald Turner, as well as Justice Stephen Breyer.
    • Supra Note , vol.17
    • Kovacic1
  • 87
    • 70349216141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keynote address: Vertical restrictions and "fragile" monopoly
    • 500
    • A view endorsed by one of the Chicago School's more prominent contributors. See Richard A. Posner, Keynote Address: Vertical Restrictions and "Fragile" Monopoly, 50 ANTITRUST BULL. 499, 500 (2005).
    • (2005) Antitrust Bull , vol.50 , pp. 499
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 89
    • 78049265468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some practical thoughts about entry
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 28-29
    • Irwin M. Stelzer, Some Practical Thoughts About Entry, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 24, 28-29;
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 24
    • Stelzer, I.M.1
  • 90
    • 70349208265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 86, 88
    • Fox, supra note 19, at 82, 86, 88;
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 82
    • Fox1
  • 91
    • 70349197284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lao, supra note 19, at 199.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 199
    • Lao1
  • 94
    • 0345750054 scopus 로고
    • Predation in local cable tv markets
    • Tom Hazlett, Predation in Local Cable TV Markets, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 609 (1995).
    • (1995) Antitrust Bull , vol.40 , pp. 609
    • Hazlett, T.1
  • 95
    • 0002221161 scopus 로고
    • The theory of oligopoly
    • George J. Stigler, The Theory of Oligopoly, 72 J. POL. ECON. 44 (1964).
    • (1964) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.72 , pp. 44
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 97
    • 70349203490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago school of antitrust
    • Posner, Chicago School of Antitrust, supra note 11, at 928;
    • Supra Note , vol.11 , pp. 928
    • Posner1
  • 98
    • 84959708935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • accord BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX
    • accord BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX, supra note 11, at 117.
    • Supra Note , vol.11 , pp. 117
  • 99
    • 70349203490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago school of antitrust
    • See, e.g., Posner, Chicago School of Antitrust, supra note 5, at 928-29:
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 928-929
    • Posner1
  • 100
    • 70349201839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • It is still fair to ask why the application of price theory to antitrust should have been a novelty. The answer, I believe, is that in the 1950s and early 1960s, industrial organization, the field of economics that studies monopoly questions, tended to be untheoretical, descriptive, "institutional," and even metaphorical. Casual observations of business behavior, colorful characterizations (such as the term "barrier to entry"), eclectic forays into sociology and psychology, descriptive statistics, and verification by plausibility took the place of the careful definitions and parsimonious logical structure of economic theory. The result was that industrial organization regularly advanced propositions that contradicted economic theory.
  • 101
    • 0346746606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Game theory and antitrust, a post mortem, 5
    • 412 (criticizing the application of game theory in antitrust on the grounds that "game theoretic models of [industrial organization] have not been empirically verified in a meaningful sense")
    • See Bruce H. Kobayashi, Game Theory and Antitrust, A Post Mortem, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 411, 412 (1997) (criticizing the application of game theory in antitrust on the grounds that "game theoretic models of [industrial organization] have not been empirically verified in a meaningful sense").
    • (1997) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 411
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 102
    • 17244378477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing antitrust rules for assessing unilateral practices: A neo chicago approach
    • 98 ("it has yet to demonstrate a capacity to produce what we would call identification theorems-useful descriptions of the circumstances determining whether a practice is procompetitive or anticompetitive")
    • See also David Evans & Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A Neo Chicago Approach, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 73, 98 (2005) ("it has yet to demonstrate a capacity to produce what we would call identification theorems-useful descriptions of the circumstances determining whether a practice is procompetitive or anticompetitive").
    • (2005) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 73
    • Evans, D.1    Padilla, J.2
  • 103
    • 0347509683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price theory and vertical restraints: A misunderstood relation
    • See, e.g., Alan J. Meese, Price Theory and Vertical Restraints: A Misunderstood Relation, 45 UCLA L. REV. 143 (1997);
    • (1997) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.45 , pp. 143
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 104
    • 70349220577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing, the theory of the firm, and raising rivals' costs: Toward a new synthesis
    • Alan J. Meese, Exclusive Dealing, The Theory of the Firm, and Raising Rivals' Costs: Toward a New Synthesis, 50 ANTITRUST BULL. 371 (2005);
    • (2005) Antitrust Bull , vol.50 , pp. 371
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 105
    • 0041330662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price theory, competition, and the rule of reason
    • Alan J. Meese, Price Theory, Competition, and the Rule of Reason, 2003 U. ILL. L. REV. 77 (2003);
    • (2003) U. Ill. L. Rev. , vol.2003 , pp. 77
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 106
    • 27844549838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market failure and non-standard contracting: How the ghost of perfect competition still haunts antitrust
    • Alan J. Meese, Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 21 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Competition L. & Econ , vol.1 , pp. 21
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 107
    • 0002734011 scopus 로고
    • The economics of information
    • (analyzing the economics of information from a search cost perspective, whereas search costs would not exist under perfect competition)
    • See, e.g., George J. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69 J. POL. ECON. 213 (1964) (analyzing the economics of information from a search cost perspective, whereas search costs would not exist under perfect competition);
    • (1964) J. Pol. E , vol.69 , pp. 213
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 108
    • 70349211362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • analyzing resale price maintenance
    • Telser, supra note 30 (analyzing resale price maintenance);
    • Supra Note , vol.30
    • Telser1
  • 110
    • 0039195660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market power in aftermarkets
    • Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Aftermarkets, 17 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 143 (1996);
    • (1996) Managerial & Decision Econ , vol.17 , pp. 143
    • Klein, B.1
  • 111
    • 70349226471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (analyzing the role of exclusive dealing contracts in preventing dealer free riding)
    • Klein & Lerner, supra note 32 (analyzing the role of exclusive dealing contracts in preventing dealer free riding).
    • Supra Note , vol.32
    • Klein1    Lerner2
  • 112
    • 84881821535 scopus 로고
    • Brent T. Upson Memorial Lecture, George Mason University School of Law, Law and Economics Center Sept. 21
    • See Harold Demsetz, 100 Years of Antitrust: Should We Celebrate?, Brent T. Upson Memorial Lecture, George Mason University School of Law, Law and Economics Center (Sept. 21, 1989).
    • (1989) 100 Years of Antitrust: Should We Celebrate?
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 118
    • 0008634564 scopus 로고
    • Midcentury neoclassicalist with a passion to quantify
    • Harold Demsetz, George J. Stigler: Midcentury Neoclassicalist with a Passion to Quantify, 101 J. POL. ECON. 793 (1993).
    • (1993) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.101 , pp. 793
    • Demsetz, H.1    Stigler, G.J.2
  • 119
    • 70349205157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1982 (Oct. 20, 1982)
    • Press Release, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1982 (Oct. 20, 1982), http://nobelprize.org/nobel prizes/economics/laureates/1982/press.html.
  • 120
    • 0008658488 scopus 로고
    • The economist and the state
    • 17
    • See, e.g., George J. Stigler, The Economist and the State, 55 AM. ECON. REV. 1, 17 (1965):
    • (1965) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 1
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 121
    • 70349200413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note
    • It will become inconceivable that the margin requirements on securities markets will be altered once a year without knowing whether they have even a modest effect. It will become impossible for an import-quota system to evade calculus of gains and costs . . . . Studies will inevitably and irresistibly enter into the subject of public policy, and we shall develop a body of knowledge essential to intelligent policy formation.
  • 122
    • 0009041001 scopus 로고
    • The economic effects of the antitrust laws
    • George J. Stigler, The Economic Effects of the Antitrust Laws, 9 J.L. & ECON. 225 (1966).
    • (1966) J.L. & Econ. , vol.9 , pp. 225
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 123
    • 0000383136 scopus 로고
    • United states v. loew's: A note on block booking
    • George J. Stigler, United States v. Loew's: A Note on Block Booking, 1963 SUP. CT. REV. 152 (1963).
    • (1963) Sup. Ct. Rev. , vol.1963 , pp. 152
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 124
    • 0001946637 scopus 로고
    • The economies of scale
    • George J. Stigler, The Economies of & Scale, 1 J.L. & ECON. 54 (1958).
    • (1958) J.L. & Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 54
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 126
  • 127
    • 70349208273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • includes a detailed discussion of Coors' use of vertical restraints to solve dealer free riding problems
    • The seminal article from Klein & Murphy, supra note 34, includes a detailed discussion of Coors' use of vertical restraints to solve dealer free riding problems.
    • Supra Note , vol.34
    • Klein1    Murphy2
  • 129
    • 0033410755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decision theory and antitrust rules
    • See, e.g., Evans & Padilla, supra note 55; C. Frederick Beckner III & Steven C. Salop, Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 41 (1999);
    • (1999) Antitrust L.J. , vol.67 , pp. 41
    • Beckner III, C.F.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 130
    • 0035730228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying law and policy: A decision theoretic approach
    • Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 469 (2001);
    • (2001) Antitrust L.J. , vol.69 , pp. 469
    • Hylton, K.N.1    Salinger, M.2
  • 131
    • 24644465518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference
    • Luke Froeb et al., Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 639 (2005).
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 639
    • Froeb, L.1
  • 133
    • 70349208274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Others have applied the error-cost framework in a similar manner. See supra note 71.
    • Supra Note , vol.71
  • 134
    • 70349209870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 88
    • See id. at 88.
  • 135
    • 70349220566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 75
    • See id. at 75.
  • 138
    • 84878095876 scopus 로고
    • Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 234 (1st Cir.)
    • Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 724 F.2d 227, 234 (1st Cir. 1983).
    • (1983) F.2d , vol.724 , pp. 227
  • 139
    • 70349213031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 82,86,88
    • See Fox, supra note 19, at 79-80, 82, 86, 88;
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 79-80
    • Fox1
  • 140
    • 70349197284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 208
    • Lao, supra note 19, at 199, 208.
    • Supra NOte , vol.19 , pp. 199
    • Lao1
  • 141
    • 70349223513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wrong turns in exclusive dealing law
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK,165-67
    • See also Stephen Calkins, Wrong Turns in Exclusive Dealing Law, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 156, 165-67.
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 156
    • Calkins, S.1
  • 142
    • 66849112799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reinvigorating horizontal merger enforcement
    • OVERSHOT THE MARK, 246-7
    • We exclude mergers from our analysis here for a number of reasons. The first is that OVERSHOT THE MARK largely ignores mergers with the exception of Baker & Shapiro, Reinvigorating Horizontal Merger Enforcement. One of the primary points made in that article is that, during the George W. Bush administration, the Department of Justice did not vigorously enforce the Clayton Act. Jonathan B. Baker & Carl Shapiro, Reinvigorating Horizontal Merger Enforcement, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 235, 246-7.
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 235
    • Baker, J.B.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 143
    • 70349216142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Facts trump politics: The complexities of comparing merger enforcement over time and between agencies
    • Summer
    • Baker & Shapiro offer some evidence that the percentage of merger challenges relative to transactions identified by the Hart Scott Rodino filing requirements fell. Id. at 246. The second is that others have defended against, discussed, and picked apart these claims in great detail. See, e.g., Timothy J. Muris, Facts Trump Politics: The Complexities of Comparing Merger Enforcement over Time and Between Agencies, ANTITRUST, Summer 2008, at 37;
    • (2008) Antitrust , pp. 37
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 144
    • 70349220575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust enforcement during the bush administration-an econometric estimation
    • Summer
    • John D. Harkrider, Antitrust Enforcement During the Bush Administration-An Econometric Estimation, ANTITRUST, Summer 2008, at 43.
    • (2008) Antitrust , pp. 43
    • Harkrider, J.D.1
  • 145
    • 50349091080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The price effects of horizontal mergers
    • The third reason is that, even if one accepts the questionable statistical foundation of Baker and Shapiro's claims that the Bush II Department of Justice (and to a lesser extent the FTC) gave a pass to anticompetitive mergers, there is little evidence to support that such a result (including the split between the DOJ and FTC on merger enforcement) is attributable to Chicago School economics. Finally, there is growing convergence on the relevant antitrust economics of mergers. This literature focuses on empirical methods designed to improve post merger pricing predictions and is not inherently ideological. For a survey of the state of empirical evidence on the competitive effects of mergers, see Matthew Weinberg, The Price Effects of Horizontal Mergers, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 433 (2008);
    • (2008) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 433
    • Weinberg, M.1
  • 147
    • 11244249297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evidence on mergers and acquisitions
    • Paul Paulter, Evidence on Mergers and Acquisitions, 48 ANTITRUST BULL. 119 (2003);
    • (2003) Antitrust Bull. , vol.48 , pp. 119
    • Paulter, P.1
  • 150
    • 70349213030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger retrospective studies: A review
    • Fall
    • Graeme Hunter, Gregory K. Leonard & G. Steven Olley, Merger Retrospective Studies: A Review, ANTITRUST, Fall 2008, at 34.
    • (2008) Antitrust , pp. 34
    • Hunter, G.1    Leonard, G.K.2    Olley, G.S.3
  • 151
    • 70349195639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin, 127 S. Ct. 2705. On Leegin and its antitrust implications, see Wright, supra note 14.
    • Supra Note , vol.14
    • Wright1
  • 152
    • 70349194189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dr. miles is dead. now what?: Structuring a rule of reason for evaluating minimum resale price maintenance
    • forthcoming
    • See Thomas A. Lambert, Dr. Miles is Dead. Now What?: Structuring a Rule of Reason for Evaluating Minimum Resale Price Maintenance, WM. & MARY L. REV. (forthcoming 2009).
    • (2009) Wm. & Mary L. Rev.
    • Lambert, T.A.1
  • 153
    • 0002201036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distribution restrictions operate by creating dealer profits: Explaining the use of maximum resale price maintenance in state oil v. kahn
    • Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2709. The Supreme Court overruled the per se rule against maximum RPM ten years earlier in State Oil v. Khan, 522 U.S. at 3. See Benjamin Klein, Distribution Restrictions Operate by Creating Dealer Profits: Explaining the Use of Maximum Resale Price Maintenance in State Oil v. Kahn, 7 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 1 (1999).
    • (1999) Sup. Ct. Econ. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 1
    • Klein, B.1
  • 154
    • 84934563329 scopus 로고
    • Resale price maintenance: Empirical evidence from litigation
    • 270
    • See Brief of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Petitioner at 16, Leegin Creative Leather Prods. V. PSKS, Inc, 127 S. Ct. 2705 (No. 06-480), 2007 WL 173681 (stating that "[i]n the theoretical literature, it is essentially undisputed that minimum RPM can have procompetitive effects and that under a variety of market conditions it is unlikely to have anticompetitive effects"). The best estimate of the prevalence of collusion allegations in RPM cases is no greater than 15 percent. See Pauline Ippolito, Resale Price Maintenance: Empirical Evidence from Litigation, 34 J.L. & ECON. 263, 270 (1991).
    • (1991) J.L. & Econ. , vol.34 , pp. 263
    • Ippolito, P.1
  • 155
    • 57049122321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The path forward after leegin: Seeking consensus reform of the antitrust laws of vertical restraints
    • Warren S. Grimes, The Path Forward After Leegin: Seeking Consensus Reform of the Antitrust Laws of Vertical Restraints, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 467 (2008).
    • (2008) Antitrust L.J. , vol.75 , pp. 467
    • Grimes, W.S.1
  • 156
    • 70349213026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 189, 191, 195
    • See, e.g., Grimes, supra note 19, at 182, 189, 191, 195;
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 182
    • Grimes1
  • 157
    • 70349197284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 203, 209
    • Lao, supra note 19, at 199, 203, 209.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 199
    • Lao1
  • 158
    • 70349213022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Discount Pricing Consumer Protection Act, S. 148
    • Discount Pricing Consumer Protection Act, S. 148, 111th Cong. (2009).
    • (2009) 111th Cong.
  • 159
    • 70349192470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sylvania
    • Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 55.
    • U.S. , vol.433 , pp. 55
  • 160
    • 70349192472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This economic rationale for RPM is typically associated with Telser
    • This economic rationale for RPM is typically associated with Telser, supra note 30.
    • Supra Note , vol.30
  • 161
    • 2342484759 scopus 로고
    • Why 'Dr. Miles' was right
    • 29
    • Robert Pitofsky, Why 'Dr. Miles' Was Right, 8 REGULATION 27, 29 (1984).
    • (1984) Regulation , vol.8 , pp. 27
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 162
    • 43949132089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are retailers who offer discounts really "knaves"?: The coming challenge to the Dr. Miles rule
    • Spring, 63
    • Robert Pitofsky, Are Retailers Who Offer Discounts Really "Knaves"?: The Coming Challenge to the Dr. Miles Rule, ANTITRUST, Spring 2007, at 61, 63;
    • (2007) Antitrust , pp. 61
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 164
    • 70350388578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Feb. 10, (draft for FTC Hearings on Resale Price Maintenance, Feb. 17, 2009), available at
    • Benjamin Klein, Competitive Resale Price Maintenance in the Absence of Free Riding (Feb. 10, 2009) (draft for FTC Hearings on Resale Price Maintenance, Feb. 17, 2009), available at http://ftc.gov/opp/workshops/rpm/docs/bklein0217. pdf.
    • (2009) Competitive Resale Price Maintenance in the Absence of Free Riding
    • Klein, B.1
  • 165
    • 70349217747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Protecting consumers post leegin
    • Fall
    • See, e.g. Robert L. Hubbard, Protecting Consumers Post Leegin, ANTITRUST, Fall 2007, at 41.
    • (2007) Antitrust , pp. 41
    • Hubbard, R.L.1
  • 166
    • 76649105370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin Creative Leather Products., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 2733
    • Leegin Creative Leather Products., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 2705, 2733 (2007).
    • (2007) S. Ct. , vol.127 , pp. 2705
  • 168
    • 70349195637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lao, supra note 19, at 203.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 203
    • Lao1
  • 169
    • 70349205155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 15.
  • 170
    • 70349194188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A second critical economic question is why the compensation for the desired promotional services takes its particular form, e.g. RPM, a lump sum per unit time payment such as a slotting fee, or a wholesale price discount. For a discussion of the relative merits of volume based payment schemes such as RPM and wholesale price discounts in comparison to slotting fees, see Klein and Wright, supra note 33.
    • Supra Note , vol.33
    • Klein1    Wright2
  • 171
    • 70349208272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2716 (citing Klein & Murphy, supra note 34, at 295. Klein has recently revisited the economics of resale price maintenance as first articulated by Klein and Murphy
    • Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2716 (citing Klein & Murphy, supra note 34, at 295. Klein has recently revisited the economics of resale price maintenance as first articulated by Klein and Murphy, in Klein, supra note 900.
    • Supra Note , vol.900
    • Klein1
  • 172
    • 80052356265 scopus 로고
    • Vertical control and price versus nonprice competition
    • This is not the case where the services desired have significant inter-retailer demand effects and consumers shift their purchases from one retailer to another in response to the retailer's supply of the service. However, these large inter retailer demand effects are not likely to be present for many desired services, such as the provision of premium shelf space. A more complete economic analysis of the incentive conflict based inter-retailer demand effects is presented in Ralph Winter, Vertical Control and Price Versus Nonprice Competition, 108 Q. J. ECON. 61 (1993),
    • (1993) Q. J. Econ. , vol.108 , pp. 61
    • Winter, R.1
  • 175
    • 0001457802 scopus 로고
    • The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance
    • See Benjamin Klein & Keith B. Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. POL. ECON. 615 (1981).
    • (1981) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.89 , pp. 615
    • Klein, B.1    Leffler, K.B.2
  • 176
    • 70349213029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • describing how RPM facilitates self-enforcement
    • See Klein, supra note 90 (describing how RPM facilitates self-enforcement).
    • Supra Note , vol.90
    • Klein1
  • 177
    • 70349192473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Grimes, supra note 84, at 477-78.
    • Supra Note , vol.84 , pp. 477-478
    • Grimes1
  • 178
    • 70349197283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lao, supra note 19, at 209.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 209
    • Lao1
  • 179
    • 70349220568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 210
    • Id. at 210.
  • 180
    • 70349201833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 211
    • Id. at 211.
  • 181
  • 182
    • 70349205153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for an excellent and extensive discussion of the relevant theoretical and empirical literature on RPM and vertical restraints generally
    • See Dan O'Brien, supra note 4, for an excellent and extensive discussion of the relevant theoretical and empirical literature on RPM and vertical restraints generally.
    • Supra Note , vol.4
    • Dan O'Brien1
  • 183
    • 70349220576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cooper et al., supra note 59
    • Cooper et al., supra note 59.
  • 184
    • 57049133680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical assessment of exclusive contracts
    • Paolo Buccirossi ed., The MIT Press
    • Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Empirical Assessment of Exclusive Contracts, in HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS (Paolo Buccirossi ed., The MIT Press 2008).
    • (2008) Handbook of Antitrust Economics
    • Lafontaine, F.1    Slade, M.2
  • 185
    • 70349198685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • emphasis added
    • Cooper et al., supra note 59, at 18 (emphasis added).
    • Supra Note , vol.59 , pp. 18
    • Cooper1
  • 188
    • 33947684796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical relationships between manufacturers and retailers: Inference with limited data
    • (citing Sofia Berto Villas-Boas, Vertical Relationships between Manufacturers and Retailers: Inference with Limited Data, 74 REV. ECON. STUD. 625 (2007);
    • (2007) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.74 , pp. 625
    • Villas-Boas, S.B.1
  • 189
    • 36949030703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical contracts in the video rental industry
    • Julie H. Mortimer, Vertical Contracts in the Video Rental Industry, 75 REV. ECON. STUD. 165 (2008);
    • (2008) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.75 , pp. 165
    • Mortimer, J.H.1
  • 190
    • 70349197286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical restraints and the law: Evidence from automobile franchising
    • forthcoming
    • Giorgio Zanarone, Vertical Restraints and the Law: Evidence from Automobile Franchising, 52 J.L. & CON. (forthcoming 2009)).
    • (2009) J.L. & Con. , vol.52
    • Zanarone, G.1
  • 191
    • 70349226469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 15.
  • 193
    • 70349217749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust analysis of tying arrangements and xclusive dealing
    • (George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 08-37) forthcoming Keith N. Hylton, ed., Edward Elgar Publishing
    • This section relies on the discussion in Alden F. Abbott & Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements and xclusive Dealing (George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 08-37) (forthcoming in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS, Keith N. Hylton, ed., Edward Elgar Publishing, 2009).
    • (2009) Antitrust Law and Economics
    • Abbott, A.F.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 194
    • 70349223516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Salop also acknowledges that the RRC concept has its roots in the work of earlier Chicago commentators such as Aaron Director and Edward Levi, who recognized the potential for anticompetitive effects arising from exclusive dealing contracts. Id. at 144
    • Salop, supra note 15, at 142-44. Salop also acknowledges that the RRC concept has its roots in the work of earlier Chicago commentators such as Aaron Director and Edward Levi, who recognized the potential for anticompetitive effects arising from exclusive dealing contracts. Id. at 144.
    • Supra Note , vol.15 , pp. 142-144
    • Salop1
  • 195
    • 0001145690 scopus 로고
    • Raising rivals' costs
    • This anticompetitive strategy using exclusive contracts belongs to the more general class of strategies analyzed in the raising rivals' costs literature. See Krattenmaker & Salop, supra note 41; Stephen C. Salop & David T. Scheffman, Raising Rivals' Costs, 73 AM. ECON. REV. 267 (1983).
    • (1983) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 267
    • Salop, S.C.1    Scheffman, D.T.2
  • 196
    • 70349216144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BORK
    • This line of reasoning is conventionally associated with Robert Bork. See, e.g., BORK, supra note 11, at 309 ("A seller who wants exclusivity must give the buyer something for it. If he gives a lower price, the reason must be that the seller expects the arrangement to create efficiencies that justify the lower price. If he were to give a lower price simply to harm his rivals, he would be engaging in deliberate predation by price cutting, and that, as we have seen in Chapter 7, would be foolish and self defeating behavior on his part").
    • Supra Note , vol.11 , pp. 309
  • 197
    • 70349213021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing as competition for distribution on the merits
    • 122-128
    • This analogy is explored and used to derive the economic conditions necessary for exclusive contracts to cause anticompetitive effects in Benjamin Klein, Exclusive Dealing as Competition for Distribution on the Merits, 12 GEO. MASON L. REV. 119, 122-28 (2003).
    • (2003) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12 , pp. 119
    • Klein, B.1
  • 199
    • 70349209874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • formally derive this result
    • Bernheim & Whinston, supra note 42, formally derive this result.
    • Supra Note , vol.42
    • Bernheim1    Whinston2
  • 201
    • 70349208267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An alternative, but related, theory of exclusion operates by driving out competing retailers and allowing S to monopolize distribution and also collect its monopoly price on the distribution of rival products. See Whinston, supra note 40. This alternative theory also requires substantial economies of scope or scale in the supply of distribution services. Economies of scope in distribution may be present if, for example, S's product is essential to the economic viability of R.
    • Supra Note , vol.40
    • Whinston1
  • 203
  • 204
    • 33747338146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MIT Press, for arguments that the ability to make discriminatory or sequential offers to buyers increases the support for exclusion
    • But see id., and MICHAEL D. WHINSTON, LECTURES ON ANTITRUST ECONOMICS (MIT Press, 2008), for arguments that the ability to make discriminatory or sequential offers to buyers increases the support for exclusion.
    • (2008) Lectures on Antitrust Economics
    • Whinston, M.D.1
  • 205
    • 33747737990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing and entry when buyers compete
    • (exclusion is not likely with downstream retail competition where potential entrant can achieve scale through distribution with a small number of retailers);
    • See, e.g., Chiara Fumagalli & Massimo Motta, Exclusive Dealing and Entry When Buyers Compete, 96 AM. ECON. REV. 785 (2006) (exclusion is not likely with downstream retail competition where potential entrant can achieve scale through distribution with a small number of retailers);
    • (2006) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 785
    • Fumagalli, C.1    Motta, M.2
  • 206
    • 70349211355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (exclusion is possible with downstream retail competition because each individual retailer has little to gain from holding out from the exclusive and the increased benefits of upstream competition are largely passed on to final consumers)
    • Simpson & Wickelgren, supra note 42 (exclusion is possible with downstream retail competition because each individual retailer has little to gain from holding out from the exclusive and the increased benefits of upstream competition are largely passed on to final consumers);
    • Supra Note , vol.42
    • Simpson1    Wickelgren2
  • 210
    • 0036926346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing, "foreclosure," and consumer harm
    • 357-60
    • A description of other commonly accepted justifications for exclusive dealing is presented in Jonathan M. Jacobson, Exclusive Dealing, "Foreclosure," and Consumer Harm, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 311, 357-60 (2002).
    • (2002) Antitrust L.J. , vol.70 , pp. 311
    • Jacobson, J.M.1
  • 211
    • 70349206838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing
    • Marvel, Exclusive Dealing, supra note 32.
    • Supra Note , vol.32
    • Marvel1
  • 212
    • 70349214505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 823 F.2d 1215 (8th Cir. 1987). See also Klein & Lerner, supra note 32, at 481-83 (discussing Ryko as an example of this type of free-riding).
    • Supra Note , vol.32 , pp. 481-83
    • Klein1    Lerner2
  • 215
    • 70349208268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • which extends the original analysis of inadequate dealer incentives to promote and the use of vertical restraints in solving this dealer incentive problem in Klein & Murphy, supra note 34.
    • Supra Note , vol.34
    • Klein1    Murphy2
  • 217
    • 70349209872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 502-04
    • Id. at 502-04.
  • 218
    • 0346826027 scopus 로고
    • Joyce Beverages of N.Y., Inc. v. Royal Crown Cola Co., 276-77 (S.D.N.Y.)
    • Joyce Beverages of N.Y., Inc. v. Royal Crown Cola Co., 555 F. Supp. 271, 276-77 (S.D.N.Y. 1983).
    • (1983) F. Supp. , vol.555 , pp. 271
  • 219
    • 70349200411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Hendricks Music Co. v. Steinway, Inc., (N.D. Ill.)
    • See also Hendricks Music Co. v. Steinway, Inc., 689 F. Supp. 1501 (N.D. Ill. 1988) ("it is perfectly legitimate and, in fact, procompetitive, for manufacturers to insist that their dealers devote undivided loyalty to their products and not to those of their competitors").
    • F. Supp. , vol.689 , pp. 1501
  • 220
    • 0346195443 scopus 로고
    • Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus., Inc., (7th Cir.)
    • Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus., Inc., 749 F.2d 380 (7th Cir. 1984).
    • (1984) F.2d , vol.749 , pp. 380
  • 222
    • 70349217748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally United States v. Dentsply Int'l, Inc., (D. Del. 2003), rev'd, 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 2005), cert. denied, 126 S. Ct. 1023
    • See generally United States v. Dentsply Int'l, Inc., 277 F. Supp. 2d 387 (D. Del. 2003), rev'd, 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 2005), cert. denied, 126 S. Ct. 1023 (2006).
    • (2006) F. Supp. , vol.277 , pp. 387
  • 223
    • 70349201835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klein and Lerner conclude that creating "undivided dealer loyalty" was a plausible justification in Dentsply, but that "we do not know if a more complete analysis would have found the net effect of Dentsply's exclusive dealing to be procompetitive or anticompetitive," and "what is clear is that further analysis of the undivided loyalty rationale for exclusive dealing should have been undertaken." Klein & Lerner, supra note 32, at 518.
    • Supra Note , vol.32 , pp. 518
    • Klein1    Lerner2
  • 224
    • 70349220572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Klein & Murphy, supra note 32. This explanation is related to, and provides the economic basis for, the argument that exclusives "instigated" by customers should enjoy a presumption of legality.
    • Supra Note , vol.32
    • Klein1    Murphy2
  • 225
    • 0034414761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Customer instigated exclusive dealing
    • See also Richard M. Steuer, Customer Instigated Exclusive Dealing, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 239 (2000).
    • (2000) Antitrust L.J. , vol.68 , pp. 239
    • Steuer, R.M.1
  • 226
    • 70349214503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust analysis of category management: Conwood co. v. united states tobacco co., forthcoming
    • Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Analysis of Category Management: Conwood Co. v. United States Tobacco Co., 17 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. (forthcoming 2009).
    • (2009) Sup. CT. Econ. Rev. , vol.17
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 227
  • 228
    • 70349206839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, Professor Calkins criticizes the trend in lower courts toward presuming legality for distribution contracts of less than one year. See also Salop, supra note 15.
    • Supra Note , vol.15
    • Salop1
  • 229
    • 70349216145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Wright, supra note 33 (providing a defense of presumptive legality for short term contracts).
    • Supra Note , vol.33
    • Wright1
  • 231
    • 11544291411 scopus 로고
    • Exclusive dealing and business efficiency: Evidence from industry practice
    • Jan B. Heide et al., Exclusive Dealing and Business Efficiency: Evidence from Industry Practice, 41 J.L. & ECON. 387 (1988).
    • (1988) J.L. & Econ. , vol.41 , pp. 387
    • Heide, J.B.1
  • 232
    • 34249314286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Diagnosing foreclosure due to exclusive dealing
    • See John Asker, Diagnosing Foreclosure Due to Exclusive Dealing (NYU Working Paper No. EC 04-36, 2005);
    • (2005) NYU Working Paper No. EC 04-36
    • Asker, J.1
  • 233
    • 18144420069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The competitive effects of exclusive dealing: Evidence from the US beer industry
    • Tim R. Sass, The Competitive Effects of Exclusive Dealing: Evidence from the US Beer Industry, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 203 (2005).
    • (2005) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.23 , pp. 203
    • Sass, T.R.1
  • 236
    • 70349213027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fox, supra note 19, at 83.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 83
    • Fox1
  • 237
    • 70349220570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Robert Pitofsky, supra note 5, at 6 ("Because extreme interpretations and misinterpretations of conservative economic theory (and constant disregard of facts) have come to dominate antitrust, there is reason to believe that the United States is headed in a profoundly wrong direction")
    • Supra Note , vol.5 , pp. 6
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 238
    • 70349223514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fox, supra note 19, at 81.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 81
    • Fox1
  • 239
    • 27844532782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brooke Group
    • Brooke Group, 509 U.S. 209.
    • U.S. , vol.509 , pp. 209
  • 240
    • 84870581687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • California Dental Ass'n v. FTC
    • California Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756 (1999).
    • (1999) U.S. , vol.526 , pp. 756
  • 241
    • 33645576784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. 398.
    • U.S. , vol.540 , pp. 398
    • Trinko1
  • 242
    • 70349208271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin, 127 S. Ct. 2705.
    • S. Ct. , vol.127 , pp. 2705
    • Leegin1
  • 243
    • 70349208265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fox, supra note 19, at 82.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 82
    • Fox1
  • 244
    • 70349214504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 15.
  • 245
  • 246
    • 23044523110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predatory pricing: Strategic theory and legal policy
    • (citing Joseph F. Brodley, Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy, 88 GEO. L.J. 2239 (2000)).
    • (2000) Geo. L.J. , vol.88 , pp. 2239
    • Brodley, J.F.1
  • 247
    • 0347033946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predatory pricing and strategic theory
    • 2475
    • But see Kenneth G. Elzinga & David E. Mills, Predatory Pricing and Strategic Theory, 89 GEO.. L.J. 2475, 2475 (2001)
    • (2001) Geo.. L.J. , vol.89 , pp. 2475
    • Elzinga, K.G.1    Mills, D.E.2
  • 248
    • 70349211357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT, (collecting studies)
    • ("Although strategic theories of predatory pricing are exemplary in their coherence and rigor, their potential to add value to antitrust policy is much more modest than the authors admit."). Indeed, the economic literature does provide some evidence of profitable predation. See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT (2008), at 56, note 85 (collecting studies).
    • (2008) Note , vol.85 , pp. 56
  • 249
    • 70349203488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing
    • forthcoming in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS
    • See generally Bruce H. Kobayashi, The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing (forthcoming in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS, supra note 114).
    • Supra Note , vol.114
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 250
    • 70349211360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fox, supra note 19, at 84.
    • Supra Note , vol.19 , pp. 84
    • Fox1
  • 251
    • 70349198683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 15.
  • 252
    • 70349195640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 86
    • Id. at 86.
  • 254
    • 70349209871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust decisions of the u.s. supreme court, 1967-2007
    • Leah Brannon & Douglas H. Ginsburg, Antitrust Decisions of the U.S. Supreme Court, 1967-2007, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 3 (2007).
    • (2007) Competition Pol'y INT'L , vol.3 , pp. 3
    • Brannon, L.1    Ginsburg, D.H.2
  • 255
    • 70349197285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 20
    • Id. at 20.
  • 256
    • 70349198682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at Table 4
    • Id. at Table 4.
  • 257
    • 70349213028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Einer Elhauge, supra note 18, at 64 (speculating that the fact that -Breyer's dissent referred no less than six times to the stare decisis considerations that were cited in an abortion case made it hard to avoid the conclusion that this case had gotten mixed up with abortion politics.
    • Supra Note , vol.18 , pp. 64
    • Elhauge, E.1
  • 258
    • 70349214506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Linkline, No. 07-512
    • Linkline, No. 07-512, 2009 U.S. Lexis 1635.
    • U.S. Lexis , vol.2009 , pp. 1635
  • 261
    • 31344439723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why do firms bundle and tie? evidence from competitive markets and implications for tying law
    • David S. Evans & Michael A. Salinger, Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 YALE J. ON REG. 37 (2005).
    • (2005) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.22 , pp. 37
    • Evans, D.S.1    Salinger, M.A.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.