-
1
-
-
70349211365
-
-
Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Nobel Memorial Lecture: The Process and Progress of Economics (Dec. 8, 1982), Karl-Göran, Mäler ed., World Scientific Publishing Co., Singapore at
-
George Stigler, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Nobel Memorial Lecture: The Process and Progress of Economics (Dec. 8, 1982), in NOBEL LECTURES, ECONOMICS 1981-1990 (Karl-Göran, Mäler ed., World Scientific Publishing Co., Singapore 1992) at 67.
-
(1992)
Nobel Lectures, Economics 1981-1990
, pp. 67
-
-
Stigler, G.1
-
2
-
-
70349192487
-
-
Id. at 67-69
-
Id. at 67-69.
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
70349203493
-
-
Rhetorical battles over whether economics qualifies as a science aside, there is no serious debate that the antitrust economics literature conforms to the scientific method and that there is universal agreement that economics should inform antitrust analysis
-
Rhetorical battles over whether economics qualifies as a science aside, there is no serious debate that the antitrust economics literature conforms to the scientific method and that there is universal agreement that economics should inform antitrust analysis.
-
-
-
-
4
-
-
77955907787
-
The antitrust treatment of vertical restraints: Beyond the possibility theorems
-
Note
-
See Daniel P. O'Brien, The Antitrust Treatment of Vertical Restraints: Beyond the Possibility Theorems, in REPORT: THE PROS AND CONS OF VERTICAL RESTRAINTS 40, 80 Konkurrensverket, Swedish Competition Authority, 2008), available at http://www.konkurrensverket.se/upload/Filer/Trycksaker/Rapporter/ Pros&Cons/rap pros and cons vertical restraints.pdf. O'Brien refers to this body of literature as the 1984 Synthesis, rather than the Chicago Synthesis, because the latter has mistakenly come to be associated with an unscientific, non'interventionist view toward the antitrust treatment of vertical practices. While OBriens point is well taken, because one purpose of this review is to confront these mistaken associations directly, we elect to use Chicago School without loss of generality.
-
REPORT: The Pros and Cons of Vertical Restraints 40
-
-
O'Brien Daniel, P.1
-
6
-
-
70349220579
-
-
Note
-
See id. at 5-6, for the assertions that conservative economic analysis has impacted U.S. antitrust enforcement such that it is characterized by "preferences for economic models over facts [and] outright mistakes in matters of doctrine," and that "extreme interpretations and misinterpretations of conservative economic theory (and constant disregard of facts) have come to dominate antitrust," to the detriment of consumers.
-
-
-
-
8
-
-
70349208278
-
-
Note
-
President Obama, for instance, has promised to °direct my administration to reinvigorate antitrust enforcement. Posting of Joshua D. Wright to Truth On The Market, http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2008/11/05/ antitrust under president obama i will direct my administration to reinvigorate antitrust enforcement/ (Nov. 5, 2008, 9:53 EST). President Obamas respective nominee to head the Federal Trade Commission, Commissioner Leibowitz, has already cited favorably to OVERSHOT THE MARK in a policy speech. Jon Leibowitz, Commissioner, FTC, Remarks at Section 5 Workshop (Oct. 17, 2008) (available at http://ftc.gov/speeches/leibowitz/081017section5.pdf). Similarly, Christine Varney has publicly applauded the American Antitrust Institute Transition Report, which adopts an explicitly Post Chicago vision of antitrust enforcement, noting that "a great framework that starts it and I do endorse the conclusion. Posting of Joshua D. Wright to Truth On The Market, http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2009/02/22/doj aag designate christine varney on section 2 europe google a puzzling statement about error costs/ (Feb. 22, 2009 21:10 EST).
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
70349216148
-
-
See Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 (2007) (for discussion of plausibility standard)
-
See Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 (2007) (for discussion of plausibility standard).
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
70349206844
-
-
JOHAN VAN OVERTVELDT, THE CHICAGO SCHOOL: HOW THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ASSEMBLED THE THINKERS WHO REVOLUTIONIZED ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS (Agate B2 2007)
-
JOHAN VAN OVERTVELDT, THE CHICAGO SCHOOL: HOW THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ASSEMBLED THE THINKERS WHO REVOLUTIONIZED ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS (Agate B2 2007).
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
0002342504
-
The fire of truth: Remembrance of law and economics at chicago, 1932-1970
-
Edmund W. Kitch, The Fire of Truth: Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago, 1932-1970, 26 J.L. & ECON. 163 (1983);
-
(1983)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.26
, pp. 163
-
-
Kitch, E.W.1
-
13
-
-
0039027645
-
Antitrust policy: A century of economic and legal thinking
-
William E. Kovacic & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking, 14 J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES 43 (2000);
-
(2000)
J. Econ. Perspectives
, vol.14
, pp. 43
-
-
Kovacic, W.E.1
Shapiro, C.2
-
14
-
-
0346248849
-
Tying meets the new institutional economics: Farewell to the chimera of forcing
-
Alan J. Meese, Tying Meets the New Institutional Economics: Farewell to the Chimera of Forcing, 146 U. PA. L. REV. 1 (1997);
-
(1997)
U. PA. L. REV.
, vol.146
, pp. 1
-
-
Meese, A.J.1
-
15
-
-
0346883458
-
The chicago school and the evolution of antitrust: Characterization, antitrust injury, and evidentiary sufficiency
-
William H. Page, The Chicago School and the Evolution of Antitrust: Characterization, Antitrust Injury, and Evidentiary Sufficiency, 75 VA. L. REV. 1221 (1989);
-
(1989)
VA. L. Rev.
, vol.75
, pp. 1221
-
-
Page, W.H.1
-
16
-
-
0000156633
-
The Chicago school of antitrust
-
Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925 (1969).
-
(1969)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.127
, pp. 925
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
17
-
-
70349194191
-
-
See, e.g., Pitofsky, supra note 5, at 3, 5; Daniel L. Rubinfeld, On the Foundations of Antitrust Law and Economics, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 51, 52; Richard Schmalensee, Thoughts on the Chicago Legacy in U.S. Antitrust, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 11, 22
-
See, e.g., Pitofsky, supra note 5, at 3, 5; Daniel L. Rubinfeld, On the Foundations of Antitrust Law and Economics, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 51, 52; Richard Schmalensee, Thoughts on the Chicago Legacy in U.S. Antitrust, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 11, 22.
-
-
-
-
18
-
-
46049113694
-
The Chicago school and exclusionary conduct
-
For discussions of Bork's efforts, see Frank H. Easterbrook, The Chicago School and Exclusionary Conduct, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 439 (2008);
-
(2008)
Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y
, vol.31
, pp. 439
-
-
Easterbrook, F.H.1
-
19
-
-
46149118959
-
Judge bork, consumer welfare, and antitrust law
-
Douglas H. Ginsburg, Judge Bork, Consumer Welfare, and Antitrust Law, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 449 (2008);
-
(2008)
Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y
, vol.31
, pp. 449
-
-
Ginsburg, D.H.1
-
20
-
-
46049113900
-
The abiding influence of the antitrust paradox
-
George L. Priest, The Abiding Influence of The Antitrust Paradox, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 455 (2008).
-
(2008)
Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y
, vol.31
, pp. 455
-
-
Priest, G.L.1
-
21
-
-
47049093858
-
The roberts court and the chicago school of antitrust: The 2006 term and beyond
-
(arguing that Chicago School economic principles successfully characterize the Roberts Court antitrust jurisprudence)
-
Joshua D. Wright, The Roberts Court and the Chicago School of Antitrust: The 2006 Term and Beyond, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 24 (2007) (arguing that Chicago School economic principles successfully characterize the Roberts Court antitrust jurisprudence).
-
(2007)
Competition Pol'y Int'l
, vol.3
, pp. 24
-
-
Wright, J.D.1
-
22
-
-
84881916088
-
Economic Analysis of Exclusionary Vertical Conduct: Where Chicago Has Overshot the Mark
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 144 (for the claim that "it is important to recognize that [the Post Chicago] approach has its root in the economic analysis of Chicago School commentators," referring to the work of Aaron Director &
-
See Steven C. Salop, Economic Analysis of Exclusionary Vertical Conduct: Where Chicago Has Overshot the Mark, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 141, 144 (for the claim that "it is important to recognize that [the Post Chicago] approach has its root in the economic analysis of Chicago School commentators," referring to the work of Aaron Director &
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 141
-
-
Salop, S.C.1
-
23
-
-
0001658192
-
Law and the future: Trade regulation
-
Edward H. Levi, Law and the Future: Trade Regulation, 51 NW. U. L. REV. 281 (1956);
-
(1956)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.51
, pp. 281
-
-
Levi, E.H.1
-
24
-
-
70349211364
-
Director and levi after 40 years: The anti antitrust agenda revisited
-
Peter C. Carstensen, Director and Levi After 40 Years: The Anti Antitrust Agenda Revisited, 17 MCLR 37, 40 (1996)
-
(1996)
MCLR 37
, vol.17
, pp. 40
-
-
Carstensen, P.C.1
-
25
-
-
70349226473
-
Comment, vertical forestalling under the antitrust laws
-
(for the proposition that Director and Levi's analysis was a precursor to the raising rivals' costs hypothesis)
-
(for the proposition that Director and Levi's analysis was a precursor to the raising rivals' costs hypothesis); Comment, Vertical Forestalling Under the Antitrust Laws, 19 U. CHI. L. REV. 583 (1952).
-
(1952)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.19
, pp. 583
-
-
-
26
-
-
0030529224
-
Monopolization by "raising rivals' costs": The standard oil case
-
See, e.g. Elizabeth Granitz & Benjamin Klein, Monopolization by "Raising Rivals' Costs": The Standard Oil Case, 39 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1996);
-
(1996)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.39
, pp. 1
-
-
Granitz, E.1
Klein, B.2
-
27
-
-
0036340592
-
The strategic use of tying to preserve and create market power in evolving industries
-
Dennis Carlton & Michael Waldman, The Strategic Use of Tying to Preserve and Create Market Power in Evolving Industries, 33 RAND J. ECON. 194 (2002).
-
(2002)
Rand J. Econ.
, vol.33
, pp. 194
-
-
Carlton, D.1
Waldman, M.2
-
28
-
-
70349096585
-
The intellectual dna of modern u.s. competition law for dominant firm conduct: The chicago harvard double helix
-
See William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1 (2007).
-
(2007)
Colum. Bus. L. Rev.
, vol.2007
, pp. 1
-
-
Kovacic, W.E.1
-
29
-
-
70349205158
-
Harvard, not chicago: Which antitrust school drives recent u.s. supreme court decisions?
-
Einer Elhauge, Harvard, Not Chicago: Which Antitrust School Drives Recent U.S. Supreme Court Decisions?, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 59 (2007).
-
(2007)
Competition Pol'y Int'l
, vol.3
, pp. 59
-
-
Elhauge, E.1
-
30
-
-
70349206843
-
-
20
-
For claims that Chicago School economics caused courts to adopt erroneous economic principles and get specific cases wrong, see e.g. Schmalensee, supra note 12, at 19, 20;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 19
-
-
Schmalensee1
-
31
-
-
84887985422
-
Influence of conservative economic analysis on the development of the law of antitrust
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 44
-
Thomas E. Kauper, Influence of Conservative Economic Analysis on the Development of the Law of Antitrust, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 40, 44;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 40
-
-
Kauper, T.E.1
-
32
-
-
84887890665
-
The harvard and chicago schools and the dominant firm
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 113
-
Herbert Hovenkamp, The Harvard and Chicago Schools and the Dominant Firm, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 109, 113;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 109
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
33
-
-
70349201841
-
Comment on herbert hovenkamp and the dominant firm: The chicago school has made us too cautious about false positives and the use of section 2 of the sherman act
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 126
-
Harvey J. Goldschmid, Comment on Herbert Hovenkamp and the Dominant Firm: The Chicago School Has Made Us Too Cautious About False Positives and the Use of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 123, 126;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 123
-
-
Goldschmid, H.J.1
-
34
-
-
84887858933
-
The sylvania free rider justification for downstream power vertical restraints: Truth or invitation for pretext?
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 191
-
Warren S. Grimes, The Sylvania Free Rider Justification for Downstream Power Vertical Restraints: Truth or Invitation for Pretext?, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 181, 191;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 181
-
-
Grimes, W.S.1
-
35
-
-
70349192484
-
Free riding: An overstated, and unconvincing, explanation for resale price maintenance
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 201
-
Marina Lao, Free Riding: An Overstated, and Unconvincing, Explanation for Resale Price Maintenance, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 196, 201.
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 196
-
-
Lao, M.1
-
36
-
-
70349206842
-
-
For claims that the Chicago School caused courts to develop sub optimal legal rules, see e.g. Schmalensee, supra note 12, at 19; Kauper, id. at 42
-
For claims that the Chicago School caused courts to develop sub optimal legal rules, see e.g. Schmalensee, supra note 12, at 19; Kauper, id. at 42;
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
78049319487
-
The efficiency paradox
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 79-80
-
Eleanor M. Fox, The Efficiency Paradox, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 77, 79-80;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 77
-
-
Fox, E.M.1
-
38
-
-
84887904966
-
The chicago school's foundation is flawed: Antitrust protects consumers, not efficiency
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111
-
John B. Kirkwood & Robert H. Lande, The Chicago School's Foundation is Flawed: Antitrust Protects Consumers, Not Efficiency, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 89, 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111.
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 89
-
-
Kirkwood, J.B.1
Lande, R.H.2
-
39
-
-
84899002470
-
Conservative economics and antitrust: A variety of influences
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 36-37; Rubinfeld, supra note 12, at 52; Fox, id. at 81; Kirkwood & Lande, at 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111
-
For claims that the Chicago School influenced antitrust policy in the wrong direction, see e.g. F.M. Scherer, Conservative Economics and Antitrust: A Variety of Influences, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 30, 36-37; Rubinfeld, supra note 12, at 52; Fox, id. at 81; Kirkwood & Lande, supra, at 90; Hovenkamp, id. at 111.
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 30
-
-
Scherer, F.M.1
-
40
-
-
70349226472
-
-
(July 25, 2007, 13:07 EST)
-
Posting of Joshua D. Wright to Truth On The Market, http://www. truthonthemarket.com/2007/07/25/chicago post chicagopost post Chicago on using shorthand labels responsibly/ (July 25, 2007, 13:07 EST).
-
Truth On The Market
-
-
Wright, J.D.1
-
41
-
-
70349203491
-
-
This section relies on my earlier work on the influence of the Chicago School on the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence. See Wright, supra note 14
-
This section relies on my earlier work on the influence of the Chicago School on the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence. See Wright, supra note 14.
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
70349209875
-
-
(David Wall, ed., Univ. of Chicago Press
-
CHICAGO ESSAYS IN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT vii (David Wall, ed., Univ. of Chicago Press 1972).
-
(1972)
Chicago Essays in Economic Development
, vol.7
-
-
-
43
-
-
84907685669
-
-
For remarks on how the current financial crisis demonstrates that the Chicago School is "on life support, if it is not dead," see Jan. 29
-
For remarks on how the current financial crisis demonstrates that the Chicago School is "on life support, if it is not dead," see J. Thomas Rosch, Comm'r, Fed. Trade Comm'n, New York Bar Association Annual Dinner: Implications of the Financial Meltdown for the FTC (Jan. 29, 2009), http://ftc.gov/speeches/rosch/090129financialcrisisnybarspeech.pdf.
-
(2009)
Comm'r, Fed. Trade Comm'n, New York Bar Association Annual Dinner: Implications of the Financial Meltdown for the FTC
-
-
Rosch, J.T.1
-
44
-
-
70349214507
-
-
The Chicago School does not deserve all of the credit for this revolution. Kovacic convincingly demonstrates that the intellectual foundations of monopolization doctrine were generated by both Chicago and Harvard, and with substantial convergence between the two. See Kovacic, supra note 17. Additionally, Elhauge argues that the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence represents a shift away from Chicago and toward Harvard. See Elhauge, supra note 18
-
The Chicago School does not deserve all of the credit for this revolution. Kovacic convincingly demonstrates that the intellectual foundations of monopolization doctrine were generated by both Chicago and Harvard, and with substantial convergence between the two. See Kovacic, supra note 17. Additionally, Elhauge argues that the Roberts Court's antitrust jurisprudence represents a shift away from Chicago and toward Harvard. See Elhauge, supra note 18.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
84925886171
-
-
Little Brown and Co.
-
(questioning the causal link between market concentration and price, and providing alternative efficiency based explanations for the correlation); HARVEY J. GOLDSCHMID ET AL., INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION: THE NEW LEARNING (Little Brown and Co. 1974).
-
(1974)
Industrial Concentration: The New Learning
-
-
Goldschmid, H.J.1
-
48
-
-
70350458216
-
Improving the economic foundations of competition policy, 12
-
Professors Demsetz and Armen Alchian are frequently associated with the Chicago School despite the fact that both spent the bulk of their careers at the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA). As any UCLA economist should note, the antitrust community has sometimes allowed the Chicago School to take credit for many of the contributions from UCLA economists such as Alchian, Demsetz, Benjamin Klein, and others. The contributions of the UCLA economists to antitrust analysis are discussed by former FTC Chairman, and UCLA alumnus, Timothy J. Muris. See Timothy J. Muris, Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy, 12 GEO MASON L. REV. 1 (2003).
-
(2003)
Geo Mason L. Rev.
, vol.1
-
-
Muris, T.J.1
-
49
-
-
70349211363
-
Two systems of belief about monopolyindustrial concentration
-
INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION
-
Harold Demsetz, Two Systems of Belief About Monopoly, in INDUSTRIAL CONCENTRATION, supra note 26.
-
Supra Note
, vol.26
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
50
-
-
70349216139
-
Economics and antitrust, 5
-
The contributions of Demsetz and other participants in the famous Airlie House Conference are discussed in Timothy J. Muris, Economics and Antitrust, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 303 (1997).
-
(1997)
Geo. Mason L. Rev.
, vol.303
-
-
Muris, T.J.1
-
52
-
-
30344441222
-
Aaron director's influence on antitrust policy, 48
-
see also Sam Peltzman, Aaron Director's Influence on Antitrust Policy, 48 J.L. & ECON. 313 (2005).
-
(2005)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.48
, pp. 313
-
-
Peltzman, S.1
-
53
-
-
70349217746
-
-
Seminal contributions from the Chicago School literature include, but are not limited to
-
Seminal contributions from the Chicago School literature include, but are not limited to,
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
9944242970
-
Vertical integration and the sherman act: The legal history of an economic misconception, 22
-
Robert H. Bork, Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act: The Legal History of an Economic Misconception, 22 U. CHI. L. REV. 157 (1954);
-
(1954)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.157
-
-
Bork, R.H.1
-
55
-
-
70349216140
-
-
Aaron Director &
-
Aaron Director &
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
0001658192
-
Law and the future of trade regulation, 51
-
Edward H. Levi, Law and the Future of Trade Regulation, 51 NW. U. L. REV. 281 (1956)
-
(1956)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.281
-
-
Levi, E.H.1
-
58
-
-
0002268909
-
Tying arrangements and the leverage problem, 67
-
Ward S. Bowman, Tying Arrangements and the Leverage Problem, 67 YALE L.J. 19 (1957);
-
(1957)
Yale L.J.
, vol.19
-
-
Bowman, W.S.1
-
59
-
-
0001706928
-
Predatory price cutting: The standard oil (nj) case, 1
-
John S. McGee, Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (NJ) Case, 1 J.L. & ECON. 137 (1958);
-
(1958)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.137
-
-
McGee, J.S.1
-
60
-
-
0002917143
-
Why should manufacturers want fair trade?, 3
-
Lester G. Telser, Why Should Manufacturers Want Fair Trade?, 3 J.L. & ECON. 86 (1960).
-
(1960)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.86
-
-
Telser, L.G.1
-
61
-
-
67649382948
-
Antitrust
-
A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., Elsevier B.V. available at
-
See, e.g., Louis Kaplow & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust, in 2 HANDBOOK OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 1073 (A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell eds., Elsevier B.V. 2007) available at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/antitrust2007. pdf.
-
(2007)
2 Handbook of Law and Economics
, vol.1073
-
-
Kaplow, L.1
Shapiro, C.2
-
62
-
-
50349094196
-
Exclusive dealing, 25
-
Howard P. Marvel, Exclusive Dealing, 25 J.L & ECON. 1 (1982);
-
(1982)
J.L & Econ.
, vol.1
-
-
Marvel, H.P.1
-
63
-
-
34548129589
-
The expanded economics of free riding: How exclusive dealing prevents free riding and creates undivided loyalty, 74
-
Benjamin Klein & Andres V. Lerner, The Expanded Economics of Free Riding: How Exclusive Dealing Prevents Free Riding and Creates Undivided Loyalty, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 473 (2007);
-
(2007)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.473
-
-
Klein, B.1
Lerner, A.V.2
-
64
-
-
57049175970
-
Exclusive dealing intensifies competition for distribution, 75
-
Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Exclusive Dealing Intensifies Competition for Distribution, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 433(2008).
-
(2008)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.433
-
-
Klein, B.1
Murphy, K.M.2
-
65
-
-
43949103054
-
The economics of slotting contracts, 50
-
Benjamin Klein & Joshua D. Wright, The Economics of Slotting Contracts, 50 J.L. & ECON. 473 (2007);
-
(2007)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.473
-
-
Klein, B.1
Wright, J.D.2
-
66
-
-
34548142981
-
Slotting contracts and consumer welfare, 74
-
Joshua D. Wright, Slotting Contracts and Consumer Welfare, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 439 (2007);
-
(2007)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.439
-
-
Wright, J.D.1
-
67
-
-
70449367148
-
Antitrust law and competition for distribution, 23
-
Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Law and Competition for Distribution, 23 YALE J. ON REG. 169 (2006).
-
(2006)
Yale J. on Reg.
, vol.169
-
-
Wright, J.D.1
-
68
-
-
84934562707
-
Vertical restraints as contract enforcement mechanisms, 31
-
Benjamin Klein & Kevin M. Murphy, Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms, 31 J.L & ECON. 265 (1988).
-
(1988)
J.L & Econ.
, vol.265
-
-
Klein, B.1
Murphy, K.M.2
-
69
-
-
70349200414
-
-
Cont'l T.V., Inc., v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997); Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993); Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007); Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns., Inc., No. 07 512, 2009 U.S. Lexis 1635 (U.S. Feb. 25, 2009)
-
Cont'l T.V., Inc., v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3 (1997); Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993); Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007); Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns., Inc., No. 07 512, 2009 U.S. Lexis 1635 (U.S. Feb. 25, 2009).
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
70349223523
-
The limits of antitrust, 65
-
See, e.g., Frank Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 65 TEX. L. REV. 1 (1984).
-
(1984)
TEX. L. Rev.
, vol.1
-
-
Easterbrook, F.1
-
71
-
-
0009043973
-
The next step in the antitrust treatment of restricted distribution: Per se legality, 48
-
Richard A. Posner, The Next Step in the Antitrust Treatment of Restricted Distribution: Per Se Legality, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 6 (1981).
-
(1981)
U. CHI. L. Rev.
, vol.6
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
73
-
-
3042797973
-
A preface to post chicago antitrust
-
Antonio Cucinotta et al. eds., Edward Elgar Publishing
-
On the Post Chicago approach to antitrust, see Jonathan B. Baker, A Preface to Post Chicago Antitrust, in POST CHICAGO DEVELOPMENTS IN ANTITRUST LAW 60 (Antonio Cucinotta et al. eds., Edward Elgar Publishing 2003).
-
(2003)
Post Chicago Developments in Antitrust Law
, pp. 60
-
-
Baker, J.B.1
-
74
-
-
0000211369
-
Tying, foreclosure, and exclusion
-
A seminal paper in this literature is Michael D. Whinston, Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion, 80 AM. ECON. REV. 837 (2000).
-
(2000)
AM. Econ. Rev.
, vol.80
, pp. 837
-
-
Whinston, M.D.1
-
75
-
-
84934452640
-
Anticompetitive exclusion: Raising rivals' costs to achieve power over price
-
See Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power over Price, 96 YALE L.J. 209 (1986).
-
(1986)
Yale L.J.
, vol.96
, pp. 209
-
-
Krattenmaker, T.G.1
Salop, S.C.2
-
76
-
-
31944445616
-
Does economics provide a reliable guide to regulating commodity bundling by firms? a survey of the economic literature
-
surveying the bundling literature
-
See, e.g., Whinston, supra note 40; Carlton & Waldman, supra note 16; see also Bruce Kobayashi, Does Economics Provide A Reliable Guide to Regulating Commodity Bundling By Firms? A Survey of the Economic Literature, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 707 (2005) (surveying the bundling literature);
-
(2005)
J. Competition L. & Econ.
, vol.1
, pp. 707
-
-
Kobayashi, B.1
-
79
-
-
35348915494
-
Naked exclusion, efficient breach, and downstream competition
-
John Simpson & Abraham L. Wickelgren, Naked Exclusion, Efficient Breach, and Downstream Competition, 97 AM. ECON. REV. 1305 (2007);
-
(2007)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.97
, pp. 1305
-
-
Simpson, J.1
Wickelgren, A.L.2
-
80
-
-
23044523110
-
Predatory pricing: Strategic theory and legal policy
-
Patrick Bolton, Joseph F. Brodley & Michael H. Riordan, Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy, 88 GEO. L.J. 2239 (2000).
-
(2000)
Geo. L.J.
, vol.88
, pp. 2239
-
-
Bolton, P.1
Brodley, J.F.2
Riordan, M.H.3
-
81
-
-
27844587041
-
-
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc.
-
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
-
(1992)
U.S.
, vol.504
, pp. 451
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
82
-
-
70349223521
-
The reckoning of Post-Chicago antitrust
-
POST-CHICAGO DEVELOPMENTS IN ANTITRUST
-
In aftermarket "lock-in" cases most closely resembling the Post-Chicago theories in Kodak, lower courts have "bent over backwards to construe Kodak as narrowly as possible." See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Reckoning of Post-Chicago Antitrust, in POST-CHICAGO DEVELOPMENTS IN ANTITRUST, supra note 39, at 8;
-
Supra Note
, vol.39
, pp. 8
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
83
-
-
4944266176
-
The fall of the kodak aftermarket doctrine: Dying a slow death in the lower courts
-
see also David A.J. Goldfine & Kenneth M. Vorrasi, The Fall of the Kodak Aftermarket Doctrine: Dying A Slow Death in the Lower Courts, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 209 (2004);
-
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.72
, pp. 209
-
-
Goldfine, D.A.J.1
Vorassi, K.M.2
-
84
-
-
69549098449
-
Federalism, substantive preemption, and limits on antitrust: An application to patent holdup
-
forthcoming (extending Goldfine and Vorrasi's analysis through 2007 and confirming their results)
-
Bruce H. Kobayashi & Joshua D. Wright, Federalism, Substantive Preemption, and Limits on Antitrust: An Application to Patent Holdup, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2009) (extending Goldfine and Vorrasi's analysis through 2007 and confirming their results).
-
(2009)
J. Competition L. & Econ.
-
-
Kobayashi, B.H.1
Wright, J.D.2
-
85
-
-
0742288973
-
The modern evolution of competition policy enforcement norms
-
William E. Kovacic, The Modern Evolution of Competition Policy Enforcement Norms, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 377 (2003).
-
(2003)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.71
, pp. 377
-
-
Kovacic, W.E.1
-
86
-
-
70349195642
-
-
Kovacic's primary theme is that the Chicago/Post Chicago narrative minimizes the contributions of the Harvard School scholars such as Professors Phillip Areeda and Donald Turner, as well as Justice Stephen Breyer
-
See Kovacic, supra note 17. Kovacic's primary theme is that the Chicago/Post Chicago narrative minimizes the contributions of the Harvard School scholars such as Professors Phillip Areeda and Donald Turner, as well as Justice Stephen Breyer.
-
Supra Note
, vol.17
-
-
Kovacic1
-
87
-
-
70349216141
-
Keynote address: Vertical restrictions and "fragile" monopoly
-
500
-
A view endorsed by one of the Chicago School's more prominent contributors. See Richard A. Posner, Keynote Address: Vertical Restrictions and "Fragile" Monopoly, 50 ANTITRUST BULL. 499, 500 (2005).
-
(2005)
Antitrust Bull
, vol.50
, pp. 499
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
89
-
-
78049265468
-
Some practical thoughts about entry
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 28-29
-
Irwin M. Stelzer, Some Practical Thoughts About Entry, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 24, 28-29;
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 24
-
-
Stelzer, I.M.1
-
90
-
-
70349208265
-
-
86, 88
-
Fox, supra note 19, at 82, 86, 88;
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 82
-
-
Fox1
-
91
-
-
70349197284
-
-
Lao, supra note 19, at 199.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 199
-
-
Lao1
-
94
-
-
0345750054
-
Predation in local cable tv markets
-
Tom Hazlett, Predation in Local Cable TV Markets, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 609 (1995).
-
(1995)
Antitrust Bull
, vol.40
, pp. 609
-
-
Hazlett, T.1
-
95
-
-
0002221161
-
The theory of oligopoly
-
George J. Stigler, The Theory of Oligopoly, 72 J. POL. ECON. 44 (1964).
-
(1964)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.72
, pp. 44
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
97
-
-
70349203490
-
Chicago school of antitrust
-
Posner, Chicago School of Antitrust, supra note 11, at 928;
-
Supra Note
, vol.11
, pp. 928
-
-
Posner1
-
98
-
-
84959708935
-
-
accord BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX
-
accord BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX, supra note 11, at 117.
-
Supra Note
, vol.11
, pp. 117
-
-
-
99
-
-
70349203490
-
Chicago school of antitrust
-
See, e.g., Posner, Chicago School of Antitrust, supra note 5, at 928-29:
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 928-929
-
-
Posner1
-
100
-
-
70349201839
-
-
Note
-
It is still fair to ask why the application of price theory to antitrust should have been a novelty. The answer, I believe, is that in the 1950s and early 1960s, industrial organization, the field of economics that studies monopoly questions, tended to be untheoretical, descriptive, "institutional," and even metaphorical. Casual observations of business behavior, colorful characterizations (such as the term "barrier to entry"), eclectic forays into sociology and psychology, descriptive statistics, and verification by plausibility took the place of the careful definitions and parsimonious logical structure of economic theory. The result was that industrial organization regularly advanced propositions that contradicted economic theory.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
0346746606
-
Game theory and antitrust, a post mortem, 5
-
412 (criticizing the application of game theory in antitrust on the grounds that "game theoretic models of [industrial organization] have not been empirically verified in a meaningful sense")
-
See Bruce H. Kobayashi, Game Theory and Antitrust, A Post Mortem, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 411, 412 (1997) (criticizing the application of game theory in antitrust on the grounds that "game theoretic models of [industrial organization] have not been empirically verified in a meaningful sense").
-
(1997)
Geo. Mason L. Rev.
, vol.5
, pp. 411
-
-
Kobayashi, B.H.1
-
102
-
-
17244378477
-
Designing antitrust rules for assessing unilateral practices: A neo chicago approach
-
98 ("it has yet to demonstrate a capacity to produce what we would call identification theorems-useful descriptions of the circumstances determining whether a practice is procompetitive or anticompetitive")
-
See also David Evans & Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A Neo Chicago Approach, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 73, 98 (2005) ("it has yet to demonstrate a capacity to produce what we would call identification theorems-useful descriptions of the circumstances determining whether a practice is procompetitive or anticompetitive").
-
(2005)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.72
, pp. 73
-
-
Evans, D.1
Padilla, J.2
-
103
-
-
0347509683
-
Price theory and vertical restraints: A misunderstood relation
-
See, e.g., Alan J. Meese, Price Theory and Vertical Restraints: A Misunderstood Relation, 45 UCLA L. REV. 143 (1997);
-
(1997)
Ucla L. Rev.
, vol.45
, pp. 143
-
-
Meese, A.J.1
-
104
-
-
70349220577
-
Exclusive dealing, the theory of the firm, and raising rivals' costs: Toward a new synthesis
-
Alan J. Meese, Exclusive Dealing, The Theory of the Firm, and Raising Rivals' Costs: Toward a New Synthesis, 50 ANTITRUST BULL. 371 (2005);
-
(2005)
Antitrust Bull
, vol.50
, pp. 371
-
-
Meese, A.J.1
-
105
-
-
0041330662
-
Price theory, competition, and the rule of reason
-
Alan J. Meese, Price Theory, Competition, and the Rule of Reason, 2003 U. ILL. L. REV. 77 (2003);
-
(2003)
U. Ill. L. Rev.
, vol.2003
, pp. 77
-
-
Meese, A.J.1
-
106
-
-
27844549838
-
Market failure and non-standard contracting: How the ghost of perfect competition still haunts antitrust
-
Alan J. Meese, Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 21 (2005).
-
(2005)
J. Competition L. & Econ
, vol.1
, pp. 21
-
-
Meese, A.J.1
-
107
-
-
0002734011
-
The economics of information
-
(analyzing the economics of information from a search cost perspective, whereas search costs would not exist under perfect competition)
-
See, e.g., George J. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69 J. POL. ECON. 213 (1964) (analyzing the economics of information from a search cost perspective, whereas search costs would not exist under perfect competition);
-
(1964)
J. Pol. E
, vol.69
, pp. 213
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
108
-
-
70349211362
-
-
analyzing resale price maintenance
-
Telser, supra note 30 (analyzing resale price maintenance);
-
Supra Note
, vol.30
-
-
Telser1
-
110
-
-
0039195660
-
Market power in aftermarkets
-
Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Aftermarkets, 17 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 143 (1996);
-
(1996)
Managerial & Decision Econ
, vol.17
, pp. 143
-
-
Klein, B.1
-
111
-
-
70349226471
-
-
(analyzing the role of exclusive dealing contracts in preventing dealer free riding)
-
Klein & Lerner, supra note 32 (analyzing the role of exclusive dealing contracts in preventing dealer free riding).
-
Supra Note
, vol.32
-
-
Klein1
Lerner2
-
112
-
-
84881821535
-
-
Brent T. Upson Memorial Lecture, George Mason University School of Law, Law and Economics Center Sept. 21
-
See Harold Demsetz, 100 Years of Antitrust: Should We Celebrate?, Brent T. Upson Memorial Lecture, George Mason University School of Law, Law and Economics Center (Sept. 21, 1989).
-
(1989)
100 Years of Antitrust: Should We Celebrate?
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
113
-
-
24644465518
-
Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference
-
See James C. Cooper, Luke M. Froeb, Dan O'Brien & Michael G. Vita, Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 639 (2005);
-
(2005)
Int'l J. Indus. Org.
, vol.23
, pp. 639
-
-
Cooper, J.C.1
Froeb, L.M.2
O'Brien, D.3
Vita, M.G.4
-
118
-
-
0008634564
-
Midcentury neoclassicalist with a passion to quantify
-
Harold Demsetz, George J. Stigler: Midcentury Neoclassicalist with a Passion to Quantify, 101 J. POL. ECON. 793 (1993).
-
(1993)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.101
, pp. 793
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
Stigler, G.J.2
-
119
-
-
70349205157
-
-
Press Release, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1982 (Oct. 20, 1982)
-
Press Release, The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1982 (Oct. 20, 1982), http://nobelprize.org/nobel prizes/economics/laureates/1982/press.html.
-
-
-
-
120
-
-
0008658488
-
The economist and the state
-
17
-
See, e.g., George J. Stigler, The Economist and the State, 55 AM. ECON. REV. 1, 17 (1965):
-
(1965)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.55
, pp. 1
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
121
-
-
70349200413
-
-
Note
-
It will become inconceivable that the margin requirements on securities markets will be altered once a year without knowing whether they have even a modest effect. It will become impossible for an import-quota system to evade calculus of gains and costs . . . . Studies will inevitably and irresistibly enter into the subject of public policy, and we shall develop a body of knowledge essential to intelligent policy formation.
-
-
-
-
122
-
-
0009041001
-
The economic effects of the antitrust laws
-
George J. Stigler, The Economic Effects of the Antitrust Laws, 9 J.L. & ECON. 225 (1966).
-
(1966)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.9
, pp. 225
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
123
-
-
0000383136
-
United states v. loew's: A note on block booking
-
George J. Stigler, United States v. Loew's: A Note on Block Booking, 1963 SUP. CT. REV. 152 (1963).
-
(1963)
Sup. Ct. Rev.
, vol.1963
, pp. 152
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
124
-
-
0001946637
-
The economies of scale
-
George J. Stigler, The Economies of & Scale, 1 J.L. & ECON. 54 (1958).
-
(1958)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.1
, pp. 54
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
126
-
-
70349216147
-
-
See Muris, supra note 27, at 17.
-
Supra Note
, vol.27
, pp. 17
-
-
Muris1
-
127
-
-
70349208273
-
-
includes a detailed discussion of Coors' use of vertical restraints to solve dealer free riding problems
-
The seminal article from Klein & Murphy, supra note 34, includes a detailed discussion of Coors' use of vertical restraints to solve dealer free riding problems.
-
Supra Note
, vol.34
-
-
Klein1
Murphy2
-
129
-
-
0033410755
-
Decision theory and antitrust rules
-
See, e.g., Evans & Padilla, supra note 55; C. Frederick Beckner III & Steven C. Salop, Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 41 (1999);
-
(1999)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.67
, pp. 41
-
-
Beckner III, C.F.1
Salop, S.C.2
-
130
-
-
0035730228
-
Tying law and policy: A decision theoretic approach
-
Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 469 (2001);
-
(2001)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.69
, pp. 469
-
-
Hylton, K.N.1
Salinger, M.2
-
131
-
-
24644465518
-
Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference
-
Luke Froeb et al., Vertical Antitrust Policy as a Problem of Inference, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 639 (2005).
-
(2005)
Int'l J. Indus. Org.
, vol.23
, pp. 639
-
-
Froeb, L.1
-
133
-
-
70349208274
-
-
Others have applied the error-cost framework in a similar manner. See supra note 71.
-
Supra Note
, vol.71
-
-
-
134
-
-
70349209870
-
-
See id. at 88
-
See id. at 88.
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
70349220566
-
-
See id. at 75
-
See id. at 75.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
84878095876
-
-
Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 234 (1st Cir.)
-
Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 724 F.2d 227, 234 (1st Cir. 1983).
-
(1983)
F.2d
, vol.724
, pp. 227
-
-
-
139
-
-
70349213031
-
-
82,86,88
-
See Fox, supra note 19, at 79-80, 82, 86, 88;
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 79-80
-
-
Fox1
-
140
-
-
70349197284
-
-
208
-
Lao, supra note 19, at 199, 208.
-
Supra NOte
, vol.19
, pp. 199
-
-
Lao1
-
141
-
-
70349223513
-
Wrong turns in exclusive dealing law
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK,165-67
-
See also Stephen Calkins, Wrong Turns in Exclusive Dealing Law, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 156, 165-67.
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 156
-
-
Calkins, S.1
-
142
-
-
66849112799
-
Reinvigorating horizontal merger enforcement
-
OVERSHOT THE MARK, 246-7
-
We exclude mergers from our analysis here for a number of reasons. The first is that OVERSHOT THE MARK largely ignores mergers with the exception of Baker & Shapiro, Reinvigorating Horizontal Merger Enforcement. One of the primary points made in that article is that, during the George W. Bush administration, the Department of Justice did not vigorously enforce the Clayton Act. Jonathan B. Baker & Carl Shapiro, Reinvigorating Horizontal Merger Enforcement, in OVERSHOT THE MARK, supra note 5, at 235, 246-7.
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 235
-
-
Baker, J.B.1
Shapiro, C.2
-
143
-
-
70349216142
-
Facts trump politics: The complexities of comparing merger enforcement over time and between agencies
-
Summer
-
Baker & Shapiro offer some evidence that the percentage of merger challenges relative to transactions identified by the Hart Scott Rodino filing requirements fell. Id. at 246. The second is that others have defended against, discussed, and picked apart these claims in great detail. See, e.g., Timothy J. Muris, Facts Trump Politics: The Complexities of Comparing Merger Enforcement over Time and Between Agencies, ANTITRUST, Summer 2008, at 37;
-
(2008)
Antitrust
, pp. 37
-
-
Muris, T.J.1
-
144
-
-
70349220575
-
Antitrust enforcement during the bush administration-an econometric estimation
-
Summer
-
John D. Harkrider, Antitrust Enforcement During the Bush Administration-An Econometric Estimation, ANTITRUST, Summer 2008, at 43.
-
(2008)
Antitrust
, pp. 43
-
-
Harkrider, J.D.1
-
145
-
-
50349091080
-
The price effects of horizontal mergers
-
The third reason is that, even if one accepts the questionable statistical foundation of Baker and Shapiro's claims that the Bush II Department of Justice (and to a lesser extent the FTC) gave a pass to anticompetitive mergers, there is little evidence to support that such a result (including the split between the DOJ and FTC on merger enforcement) is attributable to Chicago School economics. Finally, there is growing convergence on the relevant antitrust economics of mergers. This literature focuses on empirical methods designed to improve post merger pricing predictions and is not inherently ideological. For a survey of the state of empirical evidence on the competitive effects of mergers, see Matthew Weinberg, The Price Effects of Horizontal Mergers, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 433 (2008);
-
(2008)
J. Competition L. & Econ.
, vol.4
, pp. 433
-
-
Weinberg, M.1
-
147
-
-
11244249297
-
Evidence on mergers and acquisitions
-
Paul Paulter, Evidence on Mergers and Acquisitions, 48 ANTITRUST BULL. 119 (2003);
-
(2003)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.48
, pp. 119
-
-
Paulter, P.1
-
150
-
-
70349213030
-
Merger retrospective studies: A review
-
Fall
-
Graeme Hunter, Gregory K. Leonard & G. Steven Olley, Merger Retrospective Studies: A Review, ANTITRUST, Fall 2008, at 34.
-
(2008)
Antitrust
, pp. 34
-
-
Hunter, G.1
Leonard, G.K.2
Olley, G.S.3
-
151
-
-
70349195639
-
-
Leegin, 127 S. Ct. 2705. On Leegin and its antitrust implications, see Wright, supra note 14.
-
Supra Note
, vol.14
-
-
Wright1
-
152
-
-
70349194189
-
Dr. miles is dead. now what?: Structuring a rule of reason for evaluating minimum resale price maintenance
-
forthcoming
-
See Thomas A. Lambert, Dr. Miles is Dead. Now What?: Structuring a Rule of Reason for Evaluating Minimum Resale Price Maintenance, WM. & MARY L. REV. (forthcoming 2009).
-
(2009)
Wm. & Mary L. Rev.
-
-
Lambert, T.A.1
-
153
-
-
0002201036
-
Distribution restrictions operate by creating dealer profits: Explaining the use of maximum resale price maintenance in state oil v. kahn
-
Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2709. The Supreme Court overruled the per se rule against maximum RPM ten years earlier in State Oil v. Khan, 522 U.S. at 3. See Benjamin Klein, Distribution Restrictions Operate by Creating Dealer Profits: Explaining the Use of Maximum Resale Price Maintenance in State Oil v. Kahn, 7 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 1 (1999).
-
(1999)
Sup. Ct. Econ. Rev.
, vol.7
, pp. 1
-
-
Klein, B.1
-
154
-
-
84934563329
-
Resale price maintenance: Empirical evidence from litigation
-
270
-
See Brief of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Petitioner at 16, Leegin Creative Leather Prods. V. PSKS, Inc, 127 S. Ct. 2705 (No. 06-480), 2007 WL 173681 (stating that "[i]n the theoretical literature, it is essentially undisputed that minimum RPM can have procompetitive effects and that under a variety of market conditions it is unlikely to have anticompetitive effects"). The best estimate of the prevalence of collusion allegations in RPM cases is no greater than 15 percent. See Pauline Ippolito, Resale Price Maintenance: Empirical Evidence from Litigation, 34 J.L. & ECON. 263, 270 (1991).
-
(1991)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.34
, pp. 263
-
-
Ippolito, P.1
-
155
-
-
57049122321
-
The path forward after leegin: Seeking consensus reform of the antitrust laws of vertical restraints
-
Warren S. Grimes, The Path Forward After Leegin: Seeking Consensus Reform of the Antitrust Laws of Vertical Restraints, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. 467 (2008).
-
(2008)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.75
, pp. 467
-
-
Grimes, W.S.1
-
156
-
-
70349213026
-
-
189, 191, 195
-
See, e.g., Grimes, supra note 19, at 182, 189, 191, 195;
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 182
-
-
Grimes1
-
157
-
-
70349197284
-
-
203, 209
-
Lao, supra note 19, at 199, 203, 209.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 199
-
-
Lao1
-
158
-
-
70349213022
-
-
Discount Pricing Consumer Protection Act, S. 148
-
Discount Pricing Consumer Protection Act, S. 148, 111th Cong. (2009).
-
(2009)
111th Cong.
-
-
-
159
-
-
70349192470
-
-
Sylvania
-
Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 55.
-
U.S.
, vol.433
, pp. 55
-
-
-
160
-
-
70349192472
-
This economic rationale for RPM is typically associated with Telser
-
This economic rationale for RPM is typically associated with Telser, supra note 30.
-
Supra Note
, vol.30
-
-
-
161
-
-
2342484759
-
Why 'Dr. Miles' was right
-
29
-
Robert Pitofsky, Why 'Dr. Miles' Was Right, 8 REGULATION 27, 29 (1984).
-
(1984)
Regulation
, vol.8
, pp. 27
-
-
Pitofsky, R.1
-
162
-
-
43949132089
-
Are retailers who offer discounts really "knaves"?: The coming challenge to the Dr. Miles rule
-
Spring, 63
-
Robert Pitofsky, Are Retailers Who Offer Discounts Really "Knaves"?: The Coming Challenge to the Dr. Miles Rule, ANTITRUST, Spring 2007, at 61, 63;
-
(2007)
Antitrust
, pp. 61
-
-
Pitofsky, R.1
-
164
-
-
70350388578
-
-
Feb. 10, (draft for FTC Hearings on Resale Price Maintenance, Feb. 17, 2009), available at
-
Benjamin Klein, Competitive Resale Price Maintenance in the Absence of Free Riding (Feb. 10, 2009) (draft for FTC Hearings on Resale Price Maintenance, Feb. 17, 2009), available at http://ftc.gov/opp/workshops/rpm/docs/bklein0217. pdf.
-
(2009)
Competitive Resale Price Maintenance in the Absence of Free Riding
-
-
Klein, B.1
-
165
-
-
70349217747
-
Protecting consumers post leegin
-
Fall
-
See, e.g. Robert L. Hubbard, Protecting Consumers Post Leegin, ANTITRUST, Fall 2007, at 41.
-
(2007)
Antitrust
, pp. 41
-
-
Hubbard, R.L.1
-
166
-
-
76649105370
-
-
Leegin Creative Leather Products., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 2733
-
Leegin Creative Leather Products., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 2705, 2733 (2007).
-
(2007)
S. Ct.
, vol.127
, pp. 2705
-
-
-
168
-
-
70349195637
-
-
Lao, supra note 19, at 203.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 203
-
-
Lao1
-
169
-
-
70349205155
-
-
Id
-
Id. at 15.
-
-
-
-
170
-
-
70349194188
-
-
A second critical economic question is why the compensation for the desired promotional services takes its particular form, e.g. RPM, a lump sum per unit time payment such as a slotting fee, or a wholesale price discount. For a discussion of the relative merits of volume based payment schemes such as RPM and wholesale price discounts in comparison to slotting fees, see Klein and Wright, supra note 33.
-
Supra Note
, vol.33
-
-
Klein1
Wright2
-
171
-
-
70349208272
-
-
Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2716 (citing Klein & Murphy, supra note 34, at 295. Klein has recently revisited the economics of resale price maintenance as first articulated by Klein and Murphy
-
Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2716 (citing Klein & Murphy, supra note 34, at 295. Klein has recently revisited the economics of resale price maintenance as first articulated by Klein and Murphy, in Klein, supra note 900.
-
Supra Note
, vol.900
-
-
Klein1
-
172
-
-
80052356265
-
Vertical control and price versus nonprice competition
-
This is not the case where the services desired have significant inter-retailer demand effects and consumers shift their purchases from one retailer to another in response to the retailer's supply of the service. However, these large inter retailer demand effects are not likely to be present for many desired services, such as the provision of premium shelf space. A more complete economic analysis of the incentive conflict based inter-retailer demand effects is presented in Ralph Winter, Vertical Control and Price Versus Nonprice Competition, 108 Q. J. ECON. 61 (1993),
-
(1993)
Q. J. Econ.
, vol.108
, pp. 61
-
-
Winter, R.1
-
175
-
-
0001457802
-
The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance
-
See Benjamin Klein & Keith B. Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. POL. ECON. 615 (1981).
-
(1981)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.89
, pp. 615
-
-
Klein, B.1
Leffler, K.B.2
-
176
-
-
70349213029
-
-
describing how RPM facilitates self-enforcement
-
See Klein, supra note 90 (describing how RPM facilitates self-enforcement).
-
Supra Note
, vol.90
-
-
Klein1
-
177
-
-
70349192473
-
-
See, e.g., Grimes, supra note 84, at 477-78.
-
Supra Note
, vol.84
, pp. 477-478
-
-
Grimes1
-
178
-
-
70349197283
-
-
Lao, supra note 19, at 209.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 209
-
-
Lao1
-
179
-
-
70349220568
-
-
Id. at 210
-
Id. at 210.
-
-
-
-
180
-
-
70349201833
-
-
Id. at 211
-
Id. at 211.
-
-
-
-
181
-
-
70349195641
-
-
See Klein, supra note 90, at 42.
-
Supra Note
, vol.90
, pp. 42
-
-
Klein1
-
182
-
-
70349205153
-
-
for an excellent and extensive discussion of the relevant theoretical and empirical literature on RPM and vertical restraints generally
-
See Dan O'Brien, supra note 4, for an excellent and extensive discussion of the relevant theoretical and empirical literature on RPM and vertical restraints generally.
-
Supra Note
, vol.4
-
-
Dan O'Brien1
-
183
-
-
70349220576
-
-
Cooper et al., supra note 59
-
Cooper et al., supra note 59.
-
-
-
-
184
-
-
57049133680
-
Empirical assessment of exclusive contracts
-
Paolo Buccirossi ed., The MIT Press
-
Francine Lafontaine & Margaret Slade, Empirical Assessment of Exclusive Contracts, in HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS (Paolo Buccirossi ed., The MIT Press 2008).
-
(2008)
Handbook of Antitrust Economics
-
-
Lafontaine, F.1
Slade, M.2
-
185
-
-
70349198685
-
-
emphasis added
-
Cooper et al., supra note 59, at 18 (emphasis added).
-
Supra Note
, vol.59
, pp. 18
-
-
Cooper1
-
188
-
-
33947684796
-
Vertical relationships between manufacturers and retailers: Inference with limited data
-
(citing Sofia Berto Villas-Boas, Vertical Relationships between Manufacturers and Retailers: Inference with Limited Data, 74 REV. ECON. STUD. 625 (2007);
-
(2007)
Rev. Econ. Stud.
, vol.74
, pp. 625
-
-
Villas-Boas, S.B.1
-
189
-
-
36949030703
-
Vertical contracts in the video rental industry
-
Julie H. Mortimer, Vertical Contracts in the Video Rental Industry, 75 REV. ECON. STUD. 165 (2008);
-
(2008)
Rev. Econ. Stud.
, vol.75
, pp. 165
-
-
Mortimer, J.H.1
-
190
-
-
70349197286
-
Vertical restraints and the law: Evidence from automobile franchising
-
forthcoming
-
Giorgio Zanarone, Vertical Restraints and the Law: Evidence from Automobile Franchising, 52 J.L. & CON. (forthcoming 2009)).
-
(2009)
J.L. & Con.
, vol.52
-
-
Zanarone, G.1
-
191
-
-
70349226469
-
-
Id
-
Id. at 15.
-
-
-
-
193
-
-
70349217749
-
Antitrust analysis of tying arrangements and xclusive dealing
-
(George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 08-37) forthcoming Keith N. Hylton, ed., Edward Elgar Publishing
-
This section relies on the discussion in Alden F. Abbott & Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements and xclusive Dealing (George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 08-37) (forthcoming in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS, Keith N. Hylton, ed., Edward Elgar Publishing, 2009).
-
(2009)
Antitrust Law and Economics
-
-
Abbott, A.F.1
Wright, J.D.2
-
194
-
-
70349223516
-
-
Salop also acknowledges that the RRC concept has its roots in the work of earlier Chicago commentators such as Aaron Director and Edward Levi, who recognized the potential for anticompetitive effects arising from exclusive dealing contracts. Id. at 144
-
Salop, supra note 15, at 142-44. Salop also acknowledges that the RRC concept has its roots in the work of earlier Chicago commentators such as Aaron Director and Edward Levi, who recognized the potential for anticompetitive effects arising from exclusive dealing contracts. Id. at 144.
-
Supra Note
, vol.15
, pp. 142-144
-
-
Salop1
-
195
-
-
0001145690
-
Raising rivals' costs
-
This anticompetitive strategy using exclusive contracts belongs to the more general class of strategies analyzed in the raising rivals' costs literature. See Krattenmaker & Salop, supra note 41; Stephen C. Salop & David T. Scheffman, Raising Rivals' Costs, 73 AM. ECON. REV. 267 (1983).
-
(1983)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.73
, pp. 267
-
-
Salop, S.C.1
Scheffman, D.T.2
-
196
-
-
70349216144
-
-
BORK
-
This line of reasoning is conventionally associated with Robert Bork. See, e.g., BORK, supra note 11, at 309 ("A seller who wants exclusivity must give the buyer something for it. If he gives a lower price, the reason must be that the seller expects the arrangement to create efficiencies that justify the lower price. If he were to give a lower price simply to harm his rivals, he would be engaging in deliberate predation by price cutting, and that, as we have seen in Chapter 7, would be foolish and self defeating behavior on his part").
-
Supra Note
, vol.11
, pp. 309
-
-
-
197
-
-
70349213021
-
Exclusive dealing as competition for distribution on the merits
-
122-128
-
This analogy is explored and used to derive the economic conditions necessary for exclusive contracts to cause anticompetitive effects in Benjamin Klein, Exclusive Dealing as Competition for Distribution on the Merits, 12 GEO. MASON L. REV. 119, 122-28 (2003).
-
(2003)
Geo. Mason L. Rev.
, vol.12
, pp. 119
-
-
Klein, B.1
-
199
-
-
70349209874
-
-
formally derive this result
-
Bernheim & Whinston, supra note 42, formally derive this result.
-
Supra Note
, vol.42
-
-
Bernheim1
Whinston2
-
201
-
-
70349208267
-
-
An alternative, but related, theory of exclusion operates by driving out competing retailers and allowing S to monopolize distribution and also collect its monopoly price on the distribution of rival products. See Whinston, supra note 40. This alternative theory also requires substantial economies of scope or scale in the supply of distribution services. Economies of scope in distribution may be present if, for example, S's product is essential to the economic viability of R.
-
Supra Note
, vol.40
-
-
Whinston1
-
204
-
-
33747338146
-
-
MIT Press, for arguments that the ability to make discriminatory or sequential offers to buyers increases the support for exclusion
-
But see id., and MICHAEL D. WHINSTON, LECTURES ON ANTITRUST ECONOMICS (MIT Press, 2008), for arguments that the ability to make discriminatory or sequential offers to buyers increases the support for exclusion.
-
(2008)
Lectures on Antitrust Economics
-
-
Whinston, M.D.1
-
205
-
-
33747737990
-
Exclusive dealing and entry when buyers compete
-
(exclusion is not likely with downstream retail competition where potential entrant can achieve scale through distribution with a small number of retailers);
-
See, e.g., Chiara Fumagalli & Massimo Motta, Exclusive Dealing and Entry When Buyers Compete, 96 AM. ECON. REV. 785 (2006) (exclusion is not likely with downstream retail competition where potential entrant can achieve scale through distribution with a small number of retailers);
-
(2006)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.96
, pp. 785
-
-
Fumagalli, C.1
Motta, M.2
-
206
-
-
70349211355
-
-
(exclusion is possible with downstream retail competition because each individual retailer has little to gain from holding out from the exclusive and the increased benefits of upstream competition are largely passed on to final consumers)
-
Simpson & Wickelgren, supra note 42 (exclusion is possible with downstream retail competition because each individual retailer has little to gain from holding out from the exclusive and the increased benefits of upstream competition are largely passed on to final consumers);
-
Supra Note
, vol.42
-
-
Simpson1
Wickelgren2
-
210
-
-
0036926346
-
Exclusive dealing, "foreclosure," and consumer harm
-
357-60
-
A description of other commonly accepted justifications for exclusive dealing is presented in Jonathan M. Jacobson, Exclusive Dealing, "Foreclosure," and Consumer Harm, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 311, 357-60 (2002).
-
(2002)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.70
, pp. 311
-
-
Jacobson, J.M.1
-
211
-
-
70349206838
-
Exclusive dealing
-
Marvel, Exclusive Dealing, supra note 32.
-
Supra Note
, vol.32
-
-
Marvel1
-
212
-
-
70349214505
-
-
823 F.2d 1215 (8th Cir. 1987). See also Klein & Lerner, supra note 32, at 481-83 (discussing Ryko as an example of this type of free-riding).
-
Supra Note
, vol.32
, pp. 481-83
-
-
Klein1
Lerner2
-
215
-
-
70349208268
-
-
which extends the original analysis of inadequate dealer incentives to promote and the use of vertical restraints in solving this dealer incentive problem in Klein & Murphy, supra note 34.
-
Supra Note
, vol.34
-
-
Klein1
Murphy2
-
217
-
-
70349209872
-
-
Id. at 502-04
-
Id. at 502-04.
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
0346826027
-
-
Joyce Beverages of N.Y., Inc. v. Royal Crown Cola Co., 276-77 (S.D.N.Y.)
-
Joyce Beverages of N.Y., Inc. v. Royal Crown Cola Co., 555 F. Supp. 271, 276-77 (S.D.N.Y. 1983).
-
(1983)
F. Supp.
, vol.555
, pp. 271
-
-
-
219
-
-
70349200411
-
-
See also Hendricks Music Co. v. Steinway, Inc., (N.D. Ill.)
-
See also Hendricks Music Co. v. Steinway, Inc., 689 F. Supp. 1501 (N.D. Ill. 1988) ("it is perfectly legitimate and, in fact, procompetitive, for manufacturers to insist that their dealers devote undivided loyalty to their products and not to those of their competitors").
-
F. Supp.
, vol.689
, pp. 1501
-
-
-
220
-
-
0346195443
-
-
Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus., Inc., (7th Cir.)
-
Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus., Inc., 749 F.2d 380 (7th Cir. 1984).
-
(1984)
F.2d
, vol.749
, pp. 380
-
-
-
222
-
-
70349217748
-
-
See generally United States v. Dentsply Int'l, Inc., (D. Del. 2003), rev'd, 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 2005), cert. denied, 126 S. Ct. 1023
-
See generally United States v. Dentsply Int'l, Inc., 277 F. Supp. 2d 387 (D. Del. 2003), rev'd, 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 2005), cert. denied, 126 S. Ct. 1023 (2006).
-
(2006)
F. Supp.
, vol.277
, pp. 387
-
-
-
223
-
-
70349201835
-
-
Klein and Lerner conclude that creating "undivided dealer loyalty" was a plausible justification in Dentsply, but that "we do not know if a more complete analysis would have found the net effect of Dentsply's exclusive dealing to be procompetitive or anticompetitive," and "what is clear is that further analysis of the undivided loyalty rationale for exclusive dealing should have been undertaken." Klein & Lerner, supra note 32, at 518.
-
Supra Note
, vol.32
, pp. 518
-
-
Klein1
Lerner2
-
224
-
-
70349220572
-
-
See Klein & Murphy, supra note 32. This explanation is related to, and provides the economic basis for, the argument that exclusives "instigated" by customers should enjoy a presumption of legality.
-
Supra Note
, vol.32
-
-
Klein1
Murphy2
-
225
-
-
0034414761
-
Customer instigated exclusive dealing
-
See also Richard M. Steuer, Customer Instigated Exclusive Dealing, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 239 (2000).
-
(2000)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.68
, pp. 239
-
-
Steuer, R.M.1
-
226
-
-
70349214503
-
-
Antitrust analysis of category management: Conwood co. v. united states tobacco co., forthcoming
-
Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Analysis of Category Management: Conwood Co. v. United States Tobacco Co., 17 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. (forthcoming 2009).
-
(2009)
Sup. CT. Econ. Rev.
, vol.17
-
-
Wright, J.D.1
-
228
-
-
70349206839
-
-
For example, Professor Calkins criticizes the trend in lower courts toward presuming legality for distribution contracts of less than one year. See also Salop, supra note 15.
-
Supra Note
, vol.15
-
-
Salop1
-
229
-
-
70349216145
-
-
But see Wright, supra note 33 (providing a defense of presumptive legality for short term contracts).
-
Supra Note
, vol.33
-
-
Wright1
-
231
-
-
11544291411
-
Exclusive dealing and business efficiency: Evidence from industry practice
-
Jan B. Heide et al., Exclusive Dealing and Business Efficiency: Evidence from Industry Practice, 41 J.L. & ECON. 387 (1988).
-
(1988)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.41
, pp. 387
-
-
Heide, J.B.1
-
232
-
-
34249314286
-
Diagnosing foreclosure due to exclusive dealing
-
See John Asker, Diagnosing Foreclosure Due to Exclusive Dealing (NYU Working Paper No. EC 04-36, 2005);
-
(2005)
NYU Working Paper No. EC 04-36
-
-
Asker, J.1
-
233
-
-
18144420069
-
The competitive effects of exclusive dealing: Evidence from the US beer industry
-
Tim R. Sass, The Competitive Effects of Exclusive Dealing: Evidence from the US Beer Industry, 23 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 203 (2005).
-
(2005)
Int'l J. Indus. Org.
, vol.23
, pp. 203
-
-
Sass, T.R.1
-
236
-
-
70349213027
-
-
Fox, supra note 19, at 83.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 83
-
-
Fox1
-
237
-
-
70349220570
-
-
See also Robert Pitofsky, supra note 5, at 6 ("Because extreme interpretations and misinterpretations of conservative economic theory (and constant disregard of facts) have come to dominate antitrust, there is reason to believe that the United States is headed in a profoundly wrong direction")
-
Supra Note
, vol.5
, pp. 6
-
-
Pitofsky, R.1
-
238
-
-
70349223514
-
-
Fox, supra note 19, at 81.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 81
-
-
Fox1
-
239
-
-
27844532782
-
-
Brooke Group
-
Brooke Group, 509 U.S. 209.
-
U.S.
, vol.509
, pp. 209
-
-
-
240
-
-
84870581687
-
-
California Dental Ass'n v. FTC
-
California Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756 (1999).
-
(1999)
U.S.
, vol.526
, pp. 756
-
-
-
241
-
-
33645576784
-
-
Trinko, 540 U.S. 398.
-
U.S.
, vol.540
, pp. 398
-
-
Trinko1
-
242
-
-
70349208271
-
-
Leegin, 127 S. Ct. 2705.
-
S. Ct.
, vol.127
, pp. 2705
-
-
Leegin1
-
243
-
-
70349208265
-
-
Fox, supra note 19, at 82.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 82
-
-
Fox1
-
244
-
-
70349214504
-
-
Id
-
Id. at 15.
-
-
-
-
245
-
-
70349208265
-
-
Fox, supra note 19, at 82
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 82
-
-
Fox1
-
246
-
-
23044523110
-
Predatory pricing: Strategic theory and legal policy
-
(citing Joseph F. Brodley, Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy, 88 GEO. L.J. 2239 (2000)).
-
(2000)
Geo. L.J.
, vol.88
, pp. 2239
-
-
Brodley, J.F.1
-
247
-
-
0347033946
-
Predatory pricing and strategic theory
-
2475
-
But see Kenneth G. Elzinga & David E. Mills, Predatory Pricing and Strategic Theory, 89 GEO.. L.J. 2475, 2475 (2001)
-
(2001)
Geo.. L.J.
, vol.89
, pp. 2475
-
-
Elzinga, K.G.1
Mills, D.E.2
-
248
-
-
70349211357
-
-
U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT, (collecting studies)
-
("Although strategic theories of predatory pricing are exemplary in their coherence and rigor, their potential to add value to antitrust policy is much more modest than the authors admit."). Indeed, the economic literature does provide some evidence of profitable predation. See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT (2008), at 56, note 85 (collecting studies).
-
(2008)
Note
, vol.85
, pp. 56
-
-
-
249
-
-
70349203488
-
The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing
-
forthcoming in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS
-
See generally Bruce H. Kobayashi, The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing (forthcoming in ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS, supra note 114).
-
Supra Note
, vol.114
-
-
Kobayashi, B.H.1
-
250
-
-
70349211360
-
-
Fox, supra note 19, at 84.
-
Supra Note
, vol.19
, pp. 84
-
-
Fox1
-
251
-
-
70349198683
-
-
Id
-
Id. at 15.
-
-
-
-
252
-
-
70349195640
-
-
Id. at 86
-
Id. at 86.
-
-
-
-
254
-
-
70349209871
-
Antitrust decisions of the u.s. supreme court, 1967-2007
-
Leah Brannon & Douglas H. Ginsburg, Antitrust Decisions of the U.S. Supreme Court, 1967-2007, 3 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 3 (2007).
-
(2007)
Competition Pol'y INT'L
, vol.3
, pp. 3
-
-
Brannon, L.1
Ginsburg, D.H.2
-
255
-
-
70349197285
-
-
Id. at 20
-
Id. at 20.
-
-
-
-
256
-
-
70349198682
-
-
Id. at Table 4
-
Id. at Table 4.
-
-
-
-
257
-
-
70349213028
-
-
See Einer Elhauge, supra note 18, at 64 (speculating that the fact that -Breyer's dissent referred no less than six times to the stare decisis considerations that were cited in an abortion case made it hard to avoid the conclusion that this case had gotten mixed up with abortion politics.
-
Supra Note
, vol.18
, pp. 64
-
-
Elhauge, E.1
-
258
-
-
70349214506
-
-
Linkline, No. 07-512
-
Linkline, No. 07-512, 2009 U.S. Lexis 1635.
-
U.S. Lexis
, vol.2009
, pp. 1635
-
-
-
261
-
-
31344439723
-
Why do firms bundle and tie? evidence from competitive markets and implications for tying law
-
David S. Evans & Michael A. Salinger, Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 YALE J. ON REG. 37 (2005).
-
(2005)
Yale J. on Reg.
, vol.22
, pp. 37
-
-
Evans, D.S.1
Salinger, M.A.2
|