메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 133, Issue 1-2, 2007, Pages 73-90

The Borda rule is also intended for dishonest men

Author keywords

Borda rule; Simulation; Strategic voting; Welfare

Indexed keywords


EID: 34548553479     PISSN: 00485829     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1007/s11127-007-9178-5     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (13)

References (37)
  • 1
  • 3
    • 0042057704 scopus 로고
    • Partial justification of the Borda count
    • Black, D. (1976). Partial justification of the Borda count. Public Choice, 28 (28), 1-15.
    • (1976) Public Choice , vol.28 , Issue.28 , pp. 1-15
    • Black, D.1
  • 5
    • 0003563997 scopus 로고
    • On elections by ballot
    • I. Mclean, & A. B. Urken Eds, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • de Borda, J.-C. (1995[1784]). On elections by ballot. In I. Mclean, & A. B. Urken (Eds.), Classics in social choice theory (pp. 83-89). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
    • (1784) Classics in social choice theory , pp. 83-89
    • de Borda, J.-C.1
  • 6
    • 0001065439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relative utilitarianism
    • Dhillon, A., & Mertens, J.-F. (1999). Relative utilitarianism. Econométrica, 67(3), 471.
    • (1999) Econométrica , vol.67 , Issue.3 , pp. 471
    • Dhillon, A.1    Mertens, J.-F.2
  • 7
    • 21944448956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Borda count and agenda manipulation
    • Dummett, M. (1998). The Borda count and agenda manipulation. Social Choice and Welfare, 15(2), 289-296.
    • (1998) Social Choice and Welfare , vol.15 , Issue.2 , pp. 289-296
    • Dummett, M.1
  • 8
    • 1542696879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Borda rule, copeland method and strategic manipulation
    • Favardin, P., Lepelley, D., & Serais, J. (2002). Borda rule, copeland method and strategic manipulation. Review of Economic Design, 7(2), 213-228.
    • (2002) Review of Economic Design , vol.7 , Issue.2 , pp. 213-228
    • Favardin, P.1    Lepelley, D.2    Serais, J.3
  • 9
    • 26444495160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Setting the record straight: A note on sophisticated voting under Borda's method
    • Felsenthal, D. S. (1996). Setting the record straight: A note on sophisticated voting under Borda's method. Public Choice, 89(1-2), 17-25.
    • (1996) Public Choice , vol.89 , Issue.1-2 , pp. 17-25
    • Felsenthal, D.S.1
  • 10
    • 29144481265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interpersonally comparable utility
    • S. Barber, P. Hammond, & C. Seidl Eds, Dordrecht: Kluwer
    • Fleurbaey, M., & Hammond, P. (2004). Interpersonally comparable utility. In S. Barber, P. Hammond, & C. Seidl (Eds.), Handbook of utility theory (Vol. 2). Dordrecht: Kluwer.
    • (2004) Handbook of utility theory , vol.2
    • Fleurbaey, M.1    Hammond, P.2
  • 11
    • 0036276643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Borda count versus approval voting: A fuzzy approach
    • García-Lapresta, J. L., & Martínez-Panero, M. (2002). Borda count versus approval voting: A fuzzy approach. Public Choice, 112(1-2), 167-184.
    • (2002) Public Choice , vol.112 , Issue.1-2 , pp. 167-184
    • García-Lapresta, J.L.1    Martínez-Panero, M.2
  • 12
    • 0036520790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: Different perspectives on balanced preferences
    • Gehrlein, W. (2002). Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: Different perspectives on balanced preferences. Theory and Decision, 52(2), 171-199.
    • (2002) Theory and Decision , vol.52 , Issue.2 , pp. 171-199
    • Gehrlein, W.1
  • 13
    • 0040720539 scopus 로고
    • Interpersonal comparisons of utility: Why and how they are and should be made
    • J. Elster, & J. E. Roemer Eds, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Hammond, P. J. (1991). Interpersonal comparisons of utility: Why and how they are and should be made. In J. Elster, & J. E. Roemer (Eds.), Interpersonal comparisons of well-being (pp. 200-254). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    • (1991) Interpersonal comparisons of well-being , pp. 200-254
    • Hammond, P.J.1
  • 14
    • 0242627496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Probabilistic Borda rule voting
    • Heckelman, J. C. (2003). Probabilistic Borda rule voting. Social Choice and Welfare, 21(3), 455-468.
    • (2003) Social Choice and Welfare , vol.21 , Issue.3 , pp. 455-468
    • Heckelman, J.C.1
  • 15
    • 0005187407 scopus 로고
    • Alternative conditions for social orderings
    • Hildreth, C. (1953). Alternative conditions for social orderings. Econometrica, 21, 81-94.
    • (1953) Econometrica , vol.21 , pp. 81-94
    • Hildreth, C.1
  • 16
    • 33644642313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Signal extraction for simulated games with a large number of players
    • Lehtinen, A. (2006a). Signal extraction for simulated games with a large number of players. Computational Statistics and Data Analysis, 50, 2495-2507.
    • (2006) Computational Statistics and Data Analysis , vol.50 , pp. 2495-2507
    • Lehtinen, A.1
  • 18
    • 34250867016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The welfare consequences of strategic voting in two commonly used parliamentary agendas
    • forthcoming
    • Lehtinen, A. (forthcoming). The welfare consequences of strategic voting in two commonly used parliamentary agendas. Theory and Decision.
    • Theory and Decision
    • Lehtinen, A.1
  • 19
    • 0000948966 scopus 로고
    • The vulnerability of four social choice functions to coalitional manipulation of preferences
    • Lepelley, D., & Mbih, B. (1994). The vulnerability of four social choice functions to coalitional manipulation of preferences. Social Choice and Welfare, 11, 256-265.
    • (1994) Social Choice and Welfare , vol.11 , pp. 256-265
    • Lepelley, D.1    Mbih, B.2
  • 20
    • 0038463682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Voting rules, manipulability and social homogeneity
    • Lepelley, D., & Valognes, F. (2003). Voting rules, manipulability and social homogeneity. Public Choice, 116(1-2), 165-184.
    • (2003) Public Choice , vol.116 , Issue.1-2 , pp. 165-184
    • Lepelley, D.1    Valognes, F.2
  • 21
    • 0040390949 scopus 로고
    • Strategic voting and the Borda method
    • Ludwin, W. G. (1978). Strategic voting and the Borda method. Public Choice, 33(1), 85-90.
    • (1978) Public Choice , vol.33 , Issue.1 , pp. 85-90
    • Ludwin, W.G.1
  • 22
    • 0034401455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does the Borda rule provide more than a ranking?
    • Marchant, T. (2000). Does the Borda rule provide more than a ranking? Social Choice, and Welfare, 17(3), 381-391.
    • (2000) Social Choice, and Welfare , vol.17 , Issue.3 , pp. 381-391
    • Marchant, T.1
  • 23
    • 84926282160 scopus 로고
    • A comparison of efficiency of multicandidate electoral systems
    • Merrill III, S. (1984). A comparison of efficiency of multicandidate electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 23-48.
    • (1984) American Journal of Political Science , vol.28 , Issue.1 , pp. 23-48
    • Merrill III, S.1
  • 26
    • 0003252343 scopus 로고
    • Bayesian equilibrium and incentive-compatibility: An introduction
    • L. Hurwicz, D. Schmeidler, & H. Sonnenschein Eds, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Myerson, R. B. (1985). Bayesian equilibrium and incentive-compatibility: An introduction. In L. Hurwicz, D. Schmeidler, & H. Sonnenschein (Eds.), Social goals and social organization: Essays in memory of Elisha Pazner (pp. 229-259). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    • (1985) Social goals and social organization: Essays in memory of Elisha Pazner , pp. 229-259
    • Myerson, R.B.1
  • 27
    • 34547826429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Positional rules of collective decision-making
    • K. J. Arrow, A. K. Sen, & K. Suzumura Eds, Amsterdam: Elsevier
    • Pattanaik, P. K. (2002). Positional rules of collective decision-making. In K. J. Arrow, A. K. Sen, & K. Suzumura (Eds.), Handbook of social choice and welfare (Vol. 1, pp. 361-394). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
    • (2002) Handbook of social choice and welfare , vol.1 , pp. 361-394
    • Pattanaik, P.K.1
  • 28
    • 0001059988 scopus 로고
    • Interpersonal comparisons of utility: A comment
    • Robbins, L. (1938). Interpersonal comparisons of utility: A comment. Economic Journal, 48(192), 635-641.
    • (1938) Economic Journal , vol.48 , Issue.192 , pp. 635-641
    • Robbins, L.1
  • 30
    • 0013019448 scopus 로고
    • Susceptibility to manipulation
    • Saari, D. G. (1990b). Susceptibility to manipulation. Public Choice, 64(1), 21-41.
    • (1990) Public Choice , vol.64 , Issue.1 , pp. 21-41
    • Saari, D.G.1
  • 32
    • 0242641598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unsettling aspects of voting theory
    • Saari, D. G. (2003). Unsettling aspects of voting theory. Economic Theory, 22(3), 529-555.
    • (2003) Economic Theory , vol.22 , Issue.3 , pp. 529-555
    • Saari, D.G.1
  • 33
    • 33745152366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Which is better: The Condorcet or Borda winner?
    • Saari, D. G. (2006). Which is better: the Condorcet or Borda winner? Social Choice and Welfare, 26(1), 107-129.
    • (2006) Social Choice and Welfare , vol.26 , Issue.1 , pp. 107-129
    • Saari, D.G.1
  • 34
    • 0033445753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Manipulability measures of common social choice functions
    • Smith, D. A. (1999). Manipulability measures of common social choice functions. Social Choice and Welfare, 16(4), 639-661.
    • (1999) Social Choice and Welfare , vol.16 , Issue.4 , pp. 639-661
    • Smith, D.A.1
  • 36
    • 0242627507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The impartial culture maximizes the probability of majority cycles
    • Tsetlin, I., Regenwetter, M., & Grofman, B. (2003). The impartial culture maximizes the probability of majority cycles. Social Choice and Welfare, 21(3), 387-398.
    • (2003) Social Choice and Welfare , vol.21 , Issue.3 , pp. 387-398
    • Tsetlin, I.1    Regenwetter, M.2    Grofman, B.3


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.