-
1
-
-
84908302104
-
Market street associates limited partnership v frey
-
594, 7th Cir
-
Market Street Associates Limited Partnership v Frey, 941 F2d 588, 594 (7th Cir 1991).
-
(1991)
F2d
, vol.941
, pp. 588
-
-
-
2
-
-
80355148919
-
-
See Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 90 (1979) (providing a remedy for parties who reasonably relied on representations made by parties under an otherwise unenforceable agreement);
-
(1979)
Restatement (Second) of Contracts
, pp. 90
-
-
-
3
-
-
77951952068
-
The many faces of promissory estoppel: An empirical analysis under the restatement (second) of contracts
-
671, 687-98
-
Marco J. Jimenez, The Many Faces of Promissory Estoppel: An Empirical Analysis under the Restatement (Second) of Contracts, 57 UCLA L Rev 669, 671, 687-98 (2010) (examining over three hundred promissory estoppel cases over a twenty-six-year period to determine how judges conceive of equitable claims).
-
(2010)
UCLA L Rev
, vol.57
, pp. 669
-
-
Jimenez, M.J.1
-
4
-
-
84875929451
-
Hoffman v red owl stores, inc
-
275, Wis
-
See, for example, Hoffman v Red Owl Stores, Inc, 133 NW2d 267, 275 (Wis 1965) (allowing damages in equity where the defendant encouraged the plaintiff to rely on its unenforceable promise).
-
(1965)
NW2d
, vol.133
, pp. 267
-
-
-
5
-
-
84875961227
-
Williams v walker-thomas furniture co
-
449, DC Cir
-
See, for example, Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture Co, 350 F2d 445, 449 (DC Cir 1965) (holding that a contract can be invalidated if the terms are unreasonably favorable to one party and the other party's choice to enter the contract was not meaningful).
-
(1965)
F2d
, vol.350
, pp. 445
-
-
-
6
-
-
84875922884
-
Peevyhouse v garland coal & mining co
-
114, Okla
-
See, for example, Peevyhouse v Garland Coal & Mining Co, 382 P2d 109, 114 (Okla 1962) (awarding damages equal to the diminution in market price of land where performance would be more costly than the value of the completed contract).
-
(1962)
P2d
, vol.382
, pp. 109
-
-
-
7
-
-
84908302104
-
-
7th Cir
-
941 F2d 588 (7th Cir 1991).
-
(1991)
F2d
, vol.941
, pp. 588
-
-
-
8
-
-
42149087052
-
Contracts as reference points
-
5-13
-
See Oliver Hart and John Moore, Contracts as Reference Points, 123 Q J Econ 1, 5-13 (2008);
-
(2008)
Q J Econ
, vol.123
, pp. 1
-
-
Hart, O.1
Moore, J.2
-
9
-
-
79955025760
-
Contracts as reference points-experimental evidence
-
518-22
-
Ernst Fehr, Oliver Hart, and Christian Zehnder, Contracts as Reference Points-Experimental Evidence, 101 Am Econ Rev 493, 518-22 (2011);
-
(2011)
Am Econ Rev
, vol.101
, pp. 493
-
-
Fehr, E.1
Hart, O.2
Zehnder, C.3
-
10
-
-
84875946413
-
-
28, working paper, Jan 21, (visited Mar 3, 2013)
-
Yuval Feldman, Amos Schurr, and Doron Teichman, Reference Points and Contractual Choices: An Empirical Examination *25, 28 (working paper, Jan 21, 2012), online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1989556 (visited Mar 3, 2013) (finding that framing payoffs as losses tends to encourage self-serving interpretation of contract language).
-
(2012)
Reference Points and Contractual Choices: An Empirical Examination
, pp. 25
-
-
Feldman, Y.1
Schurr, A.2
Teichman, D.3
-
11
-
-
77951965074
-
The shadow terms: Contract procedure and unilateral amendments
-
630-31
-
David Horton, The Shadow Terms: Contract Procedure and Unilateral Amendments, 57 UCLA L Rev 605, 630-31 (2010);
-
(2010)
UCLA L Rev
, vol.57
, pp. 605
-
-
Horton, D.1
-
12
-
-
79955821352
-
Arbitration as delegation
-
458-59
-
David Horton, Arbitration as Delegation, 86 NYU L Rev 437, 458-59 (2011).
-
(2011)
NYU L Rev
, vol.86
, pp. 437
-
-
Horton, D.1
-
14
-
-
77958606549
-
They can do what!? limitations on the use of change-of-terms clauses
-
1101-06, 1145
-
Peter A. Alces and Michael M. Greenfield, They Can Do What!? Limitations on the Use of Change-of-Terms Clauses, 26 Ga St U L Rev 1099, 1101-06, 1145 (2010).
-
(2010)
Ga St U L Rev
, vol.26
, pp. 1099
-
-
Alces, P.A.1
Greenfield, M.M.2
-
15
-
-
84875946593
-
-
(cited in note 12)
-
See Bar-Gill and Davis, 84 S Cal L Rev at 20 (cited in note 12) ("[M]ost consumers are imperfectly informed or imperfectly rational, and as a result they misperceive the risk of unilateral modifications.");
-
S Cal L Rev
, vol.84
, pp. 20
-
-
Bar-Gill1
Davis2
-
16
-
-
84875926502
-
-
(cited in note 11)
-
Horton, 57 UCLA L Rev at 648 (cited in note 11) ("[T]here is growing acceptance that bounded rationality prevents even informed adherents from making welfare-maximizing choices.").
-
UCLA L Rev
, vol.57
, pp. 648
-
-
Horton1
-
17
-
-
84875918818
-
-
(cited in note 11)
-
See Horton, 57 UCLA L Rev at 646-48 (cited in note 11) (attributing inefficiency in consumers' decisions to the failure to read the terms at issue, unreasonable optimism, and irrationality).
-
UCLA L Rev
, vol.57
, pp. 646-648
-
-
Horton1
-
18
-
-
79952175130
-
The failure of mandated disclosure
-
665
-
See, for example, Omri Ben-Shahar and Carl E. Schneider, The Failure of Mandated Disclosure, 159 U Pa L Rev 647, 665 (2011);
-
(2011)
U Pa L Rev
, vol.159
, pp. 647
-
-
Ben-Shahar, O.1
Schneider, C.E.2
-
19
-
-
84923634012
-
The myth of the 'opportunity to read' in contract law
-
13-21
-
Omri Ben-Shahar, The Myth of the 'Opportunity to Read' in Contract Law, 5 Eur Rev Contemp L 1, 13-21 (2009);
-
(2009)
Eur Rev Contemp L
, vol.5
, pp. 1
-
-
Ben-Shahar, O.1
-
20
-
-
45949086377
-
Just one click: The reality of internet retail contracting
-
998-1001
-
Ronald J. Mann and Travis Siebeneicher, Just One Click: The Reality of Internet Retail Contracting, 108 Colum L Rev 984, 998-1001 (2008).
-
(2008)
Colum L Rev
, vol.108
, pp. 984
-
-
Mann, R.J.1
Siebeneicher, T.2
-
21
-
-
79955953911
-
Defending disclosure in software licensing
-
106-08
-
See, for example, Robert A. Hillman and Maureen O'Rourke, Defending Disclosure in Software Licensing, 78 U Chi L Rev 95, 106-08 (2011).
-
(2011)
U Chi L Rev
, vol.78
, pp. 95
-
-
Hillman, R.A.1
O'rourke, M.2
-
22
-
-
84887031704
-
-
499 US 585 (1991).
-
(1991)
US
, vol.499
, pp. 585
-
-
-
23
-
-
84875930256
-
A relational critique of the third restatement of restitution § 39
-
1112
-
See David Campbell, A Relational Critique of the Third Restatement of Restitution § 39, 68 Wash & Lee L Rev 1063, 1112 (2011) (explaining that a potential plaintiff may wish to minimize the risk of loss from breach by obtaining additional insurance or contracting with multiple suppliers);
-
(2011)
Wash & Lee L Rev
, vol.68
, pp. 1063
-
-
Campbell, D.1
-
24
-
-
0011867939
-
Privately ordered participatory management: An organizational failures analysis
-
1009
-
Stephen M. Bainbridge, Privately Ordered Participatory Management: An Organizational Failures Analysis, 23 Del J Corp L 979, 1009 (1998) ("[M]anagers . . . are tasked with monitoring the organization's members. Management meters the marginal productivity of each member and responds as necessary to prevent shirking.").
-
(1998)
Del J Corp L
, vol.23
, pp. 979
-
-
Bainbridge, S.M.1
-
25
-
-
84917682605
-
Construction insurance: A general perspective
-
45
-
See also Terrance L. Brennan, Construction Insurance: A General Perspective, 15 Construction Law 1, 45 (1995) (emphasizing the importance in construction of insuring against delays).
-
(1995)
Construction Law
, vol.15
, pp. 1
-
-
Brennan, T.L.1
-
26
-
-
0040746598
-
The case for specific performance
-
277
-
But see Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 Yale L J 271, 277 (1979) ("[W]hen the promisor's performance must be rendered over time, as in construction or requirements contracts, it is costly for the promisee to monitor a reluctant promisor's conduct.").
-
(1979)
Yale L J
, vol.89
, pp. 271
-
-
Schwartz, A.1
-
27
-
-
84875917973
-
An experiment in the optimal precision of contract default rules
-
1149-55, 1158
-
See, for example, George S. Geis, An Experiment in the Optimal Precision of Contract Default Rules, 80 Tulane L Rev 1109, 1149-55, 1158 (2006) (arguing that default rules could be mapped onto efficient precautions parties take during negotiations).
-
(2006)
Tulane L Rev
, vol.80
, pp. 1109
-
-
Geis, G.S.1
-
28
-
-
84875919441
-
-
(visited Mar 3, 2013)
-
See, for example, Shipping Insurance Coverage (Shipsurance), online at http://www.shipsurance.com/shipping-insurance.asp (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
Shipping Insurance Coverage (Shipsurance)
-
-
-
29
-
-
84855887823
-
You do have to keep your promises: A disgorgement theory of contract remedies
-
1231
-
See Steve Thel and Peter Siegelman, You Do Have to Keep Your Promises: A Disgorgement Theory of Contract Remedies, 52 Wm & Mary L Rev 1181, 1231 (2011).
-
(2011)
Wm & Mary L Rev
, vol.52
, pp. 1181
-
-
Thel, S.1
Siegelman, P.2
-
30
-
-
0002870467
-
Impossibility and related doctrines in contract law: An economic analysis
-
92
-
Impracticability is often cited as an example of the interplay between the promisee's insurance (or lack of it) and the promisor's discharge. See Richard A. Posner and Andrew M. Rosenfield, Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis, 6 J Legal Stud 83, 92 (1977).
-
(1977)
J Legal Stud
, vol.6
, pp. 83
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
Rosenfield, A.M.2
-
31
-
-
84875914295
-
Overcoming decision biases to reduce losses from natural catastrophes
-
Eldar Shafir, ed, 401-08, 411, Princeton
-
See Howard Kunreuther, Robert Meyer, and Erwann Michel-Kerjan, Overcoming Decision Biases to Reduce Losses from Natural Catastrophes, in Eldar Shafir, ed, Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy 398, 401-08, 411 (Princeton 2013).
-
(2013)
Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy
, pp. 398
-
-
Kunreuther, H.1
Meyer, R.2
Michel-Kerjan, E.3
-
32
-
-
21344493140
-
"Good" warnings, bad products, and cognitive limitations
-
1219
-
See Howard Latin, "Good" Warnings, Bad Products, and Cognitive Limitations, 41 UCLA L Rev 1193, 1219 (1994) (explaining that manufacturers heavily invest in branding in order to create a positive reputation on which consumers will rely);
-
(1994)
UCLA L Rev
, vol.41
, pp. 1193
-
-
Latin, H.1
-
33
-
-
41449095211
-
The behavioral economics of consumer contracts
-
755-56
-
Oren Bar-Gill, The Behavioral Economics of Consumer Contracts, 92 Minn L Rev 749, 755-56 (2008);
-
(2008)
Minn L Rev
, vol.92
, pp. 749
-
-
Bar-Gill, O.1
-
34
-
-
0001450178
-
Contracts, opportunism and trust: Self-interest and social orientation
-
250
-
Bruce Lyons and Judith Mehta, Contracts, Opportunism and Trust: Self-Interest and Social Orientation, 21 Camb J Econ 239, 250 (1997);
-
(1997)
Camb J Econ
, vol.21
, pp. 239
-
-
Lyons, B.1
Mehta, J.2
-
35
-
-
84875942815
-
-
(cited in note 19)
-
Campbell, 68 Wash & Lee L Rev at 1112 (cited in note 19).
-
Wash & Lee L Rev
, vol.68
, pp. 1112
-
-
Campbell1
-
36
-
-
84875942815
-
-
(cited in note 19)
-
But see Campbell, 68 Wash & Lee L Rev at 1112 (cited in note 19) ("Now, if the risk of idiosyncratic loss is high, the potential plaintiff may pay the higher price for [the good for which the party is contracting], because the extra security, and ultimately extra precaution, will be of value to him.").
-
Wash & Lee L Rev
, vol.68
, pp. 1112
-
-
Campbell1
-
37
-
-
0000949337
-
Information and the scope of liability for breach of contract: The rule of hadley v. baxendale
-
286, 296
-
See Lucian Arye Bebchuk and Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J L, Econ, & Org 284, 286, 296 (1991).
-
(1991)
J L, Econ, & Org
, vol.7
, pp. 284
-
-
Arye Bebchuk, L.1
Shavell, S.2
-
38
-
-
84875951921
-
-
FedEx Oct 2, (visited Mar 3, 2013)
-
See also FedEx Express Terms and Conditions: U.S. Shipments 6 (FedEx Oct 2, 2012), online at http://images.fedex.com/us/services/pdf/SG-TermsCond-US- 2012.pdf (visited Mar 3, 2013): The declared value of any package represents our maximum liability in connection with a shipment of that package, including, but not limited to, any loss, damage, delay, misdelivery, nondelivery, misinformation, any failure to provide information, or misdelivery of information relating to the shipment. It is the shipper's responsibility to prove actual damages. Exposure to and risk of any loss in excess of the declared value is assumed by the shipper. You may transfer this risk to an insurance carrier of your choice through the purchase of an insurance policy. Contact an insurance agent or broker if you desire insurance coverage. WE DO NOT PROVIDE INSURANCE COVERAGE OF ANY KIND.
-
(2012)
FedEx Express Terms and Conditions: U.S. Shipments
, pp. 6
-
-
-
39
-
-
79958715405
-
Optimal remedies for bilateral contracts
-
249
-
See Francesco Parisi, Barbara Luppi, and Vincy Fon, Optimal Remedies for Bilateral Contracts, 40 J Legal Stud 245, 249 (2011) (explaining that in some bilateral contracts parties who do not trust that the other contracting party will perform have an incentive to withhold performance rather than invest in the contract);
-
(2011)
J Legal Stud
, vol.40
, pp. 245
-
-
Parisi, F.1
Luppi, B.2
Fon, V.3
-
40
-
-
39049163350
-
Regulation by networks
-
1185
-
Amitai Aviram, Regulation by Networks, 2003 BYU L Rev 1179, 1185.
-
BYU L Rev
, vol.2003
, pp. 1179
-
-
Aviram, A.1
-
41
-
-
77949919958
-
The "incomplete contracts" literature and efficient precautions
-
159-62
-
For a useful summary of the literature on optimal precautions, see Richard Craswell, The "Incomplete Contracts" Literature and Efficient Precautions, 56 Case W Res L Rev 151, 159-62 (2005).
-
(2005)
Case W Res L Rev
, vol.56
, pp. 151
-
-
Craswell, R.1
-
42
-
-
22544435816
-
Economic analysis of contract law after three decades: Success or failure?
-
836-39
-
For a classic statement of the indeterminacy position, see Eric A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure?, 112 Yale L J 829, 836-39 (2003).
-
(2003)
Yale L J
, vol.112
, pp. 829
-
-
Posner, E.A.1
-
43
-
-
21844526836
-
The fault lines in contract damages
-
1234-35
-
Typically in the literature, authors take promisors' precautions to be investments to avoid breach, while the promisees' precautions are the amount that it relies on the bargain. See, for example, George M. Cohen, The Fault Lines in Contract Damages, 80 Va L Rev 1225, 1234-35 (1994).
-
(1994)
Va L Rev
, vol.80
, pp. 1225
-
-
Cohen, G.M.1
-
44
-
-
0000597389
-
Damage measures for breach of contract
-
469-70
-
See, for example, Steven Shavell, Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 11 Bell J Econ 466, 469-70 (1980).
-
(1980)
Bell J Econ
, vol.11
, pp. 466
-
-
Shavell, S.1
-
45
-
-
67649349232
-
Unity in tort, contract and property: The model of precaution
-
12-13
-
See Robert Cooter, Unity in Tort, Contract and Property: The Model of Precaution, 73 Cal L Rev 1, 12-13 (1985) (describing the effect as a result of externalizing the costs of breach).
-
(1985)
Cal L Rev
, vol.73
, pp. 1
-
-
Cooter, R.1
-
46
-
-
84855432734
-
Regulating contract formation: Precontractual reliance, sunk costs, and market structure
-
1985-95
-
For a helpful summary and critique of the literature, see Ofer Grosskopf and Barak Medina, Regulating Contract Formation: Precontractual Reliance, Sunk Costs, and Market Structure, 39 Conn L Rev 1977, 1985-95 (2007).
-
(2007)
Conn L Rev
, vol.39
, pp. 1977
-
-
Grosskopf, O.1
Medina, B.2
-
47
-
-
0008992534
-
Precontractual investigation as an optimal precaution problem
-
402, 420
-
For two classic papers, see Richard Craswell, Precontractual Investigation as an Optimal Precaution Problem, 17 J Legal Stud 401, 402, 420 (1988) (addressing the effect of various damage measures on the parties' incentives to gather information prior to contracting);
-
(1988)
J Legal Stud
, vol.17
, pp. 401
-
-
Craswell, R.1
-
49
-
-
84875956279
-
Anglia television ltd v reed, [1972]
-
64, Ct App
-
But see Anglia Television Ltd v Reed, [1972] 1 QB 60, 64 (Ct App 1971).
-
(1971)
QB
, vol.1
, pp. 60
-
-
-
50
-
-
21144459656
-
Bargaining with uncertainty, moral hazard and sunk costs: A default rule for precontractual negotiations
-
635-41
-
See, for example, Juliet P. Kostritsky, Bargaining with Uncertainty, Moral Hazard and Sunk Costs: A Default Rule for Precontractual Negotiations, 44 Hastings L J 621, 635-41 (1993);
-
(1993)
Hastings L J
, vol.44
, pp. 621
-
-
Kostritsky, J.P.1
-
51
-
-
0009039560
-
Opportunism and trust in the negotiation of commercial contracts: Toward a new cause of action
-
251-64
-
G. Richard Shell, Opportunism and Trust in the Negotiation of Commercial Contracts: Toward a New Cause of Action, 44 Vand L Rev 221, 251-64 (1991).
-
(1991)
Vand L Rev
, vol.44
, pp. 221
-
-
Richard Shell, G.1
-
52
-
-
0009037768
-
Contract remedies, renegotiation, and the theory of efficient breach
-
652
-
Richard Craswell, Contract Remedies, Renegotiation, and the Theory of Efficient Breach, 61 S Cal L Rev 629, 652 (1988).
-
(1988)
S Cal L Rev
, vol.61
, pp. 629
-
-
Craswell, R.1
-
53
-
-
70849098655
-
Instrumental theories of compensation: A survey
-
1163-65
-
Richard Craswell, Instrumental Theories of Compensation: A Survey, 40 San Diego L Rev 1135, 1163-65 (2003) (discussing both selection and risk investigation as a form of precaution).
-
(2003)
San Diego L Rev
, vol.40
, pp. 1135
-
-
Craswell, R.1
-
54
-
-
3142780149
-
Contracts without consent: Exploring a new basis for contractual liability
-
1851-52
-
See, for example, Omri Ben-Shahar, Contracts without Consent: Exploring a New Basis for Contractual Liability, 152 U Pa L Rev 1829, 1851-52 (2004) ("[T]he noretraction regime improves the parties' incentives to make precontractual investments.");
-
(2004)
U Pa L Rev
, vol.152
, pp. 1829
-
-
Ben-Shahar, O.1
-
55
-
-
84875935492
-
-
(cited in note 30)
-
Cohen, 80 Va L Rev at 1251-55 (cited in note 30) (discussing how courts might infuse promisee's fault into doctrine as a way of setting optimal precautions).
-
Va L Rev
, vol.80
, pp. 1251-1255
-
-
Cohen1
-
56
-
-
0742323938
-
Disclosure in contract law
-
1649-56
-
See Melvin A. Eisenberg, Disclosure in Contract Law, 91 Cal L Rev 1645, 1649- 56 (2003).
-
(2003)
Cal L Rev
, vol.91
, pp. 1645
-
-
Eisenberg, M.A.1
-
57
-
-
77949991240
-
Do liquidated damages encourage breach? a psychological experiment
-
637, 655, 663-64
-
See Tess Wilkinson-Ryan, Do Liquidated Damages Encourage Breach? A Psychological Experiment, 108 Mich L Rev 633, 637, 655, 663-64 (2010).
-
(2010)
Mich L Rev
, vol.108
, pp. 633
-
-
Wilkinson-Ryan, T.1
-
58
-
-
84977378511
-
Does monitoring increase work effort? the rivalry with trust and loyalty
-
664-66
-
See Bruno S. Frey, Does Monitoring Increase Work Effort? The Rivalry with Trust and Loyalty, 31 Econ Inq 663, 664-66 (1993).
-
(1993)
Econ Inq
, vol.31
, pp. 663
-
-
Frey, B.S.1
-
59
-
-
33847627576
-
The hidden costs of control
-
1611, 1617-22
-
See Armin Falk and Michael Kosfeld, The Hidden Costs of Control, 96 Am Econ Rev 1611, 1611, 1617-22 (2006).
-
(2006)
Am Econ Rev
, vol.96
, pp. 1611
-
-
Falk, A.1
Kosfeld, M.2
-
60
-
-
17444416442
-
The dirt on coming clean: Perverse effects of disclosing conflicts of interest
-
5-7, 12-14, 17
-
Daylian M. Cain, George Loewenstein, and Don A. Moore, The Dirt on Coming Clean: Perverse Effects of Disclosing Conflicts of Interest, 34 J Leg Stud 1, 5-7, 12-14, 17 (2005);
-
(2005)
J Leg Stud
, vol.34
, pp. 1
-
-
Cain, D.M.1
Loewenstein, G.2
Moore, D.A.3
-
61
-
-
78751549455
-
When sunlight fails to disinfect: Understanding the perverse effects of disclosing conflicts of interest
-
849-51
-
Daylian M. Cain, George Loewenstein, and Don A. Moore, When Sunlight Fails to Disinfect: Understanding the Perverse Effects of Disclosing Conflicts of Interest, 37 J Consumer Rsrch 836, 849-51 (2011).
-
(2011)
J Consumer Rsrch
, vol.37
, pp. 836
-
-
Cain, D.M.1
Loewenstein, G.2
Moore, D.A.3
-
62
-
-
84875952397
-
-
(cited in note 45)
-
See Cain, Loewenstein, and Moore, 34 J Leg Stud at 5-6 (cited in note 45) ("Indeed, it is even possible that disclosure could sometimes increase rather than decrease trust, especially if the person with the conflict of interest is the one who issues the disclosure.").
-
J Leg Stud
, vol.34
, pp. 5-6
-
-
Cain1
Loewenstein2
Moore3
-
63
-
-
82955191962
-
-
working paper, Dec 7, (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
Sunita Sah, George Loewenstein, and Daylian M. Cain, The Burden of Disclosure: Increased Compliance with Distrusted Advice *6 (working paper, Dec 7, 2011), online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id= 1615025 (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
(2011)
The Burden of Disclosure: Increased Compliance with Distrusted Advice
, pp. 6
-
-
Sah, S.1
Loewenstein, G.2
Cain, D.M.3
-
64
-
-
0000744908
-
Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market
-
729
-
Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard Thaler, Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market, 76 Am Econ Rev 728, 729 (1986).
-
(1986)
Am Econ Rev
, vol.76
, pp. 728
-
-
Kahneman, D.1
Knetsch, J.L.2
Thaler, R.3
-
65
-
-
84875913018
-
-
10-11 (cited in note 8)
-
Hart and Moore, 123 Q J Econ at 2, 10-11 (cited in note 8).
-
Q J Econ
, vol.123
, pp. 2
-
-
Hart1
Moore2
-
66
-
-
84875933320
-
-
(cited in note 8)
-
Fehr, Hart, and Zehnder, 101 Am Econ Rev at 494 (cited in note 8) ("A flexible contract is good in that parties can adjust to the state of nature, but bad in that there can be a lot of aggrievement and shading.").
-
Am Econ Rev
, vol.101
, pp. 494
-
-
Fehr1
Hart2
Zehnder3
-
67
-
-
84875937268
-
-
(cited in note 8)
-
See also Hart and Moore, 123 Q J Econ at 4 (cited in note 8) ("A flexible contract has the advantage that parties can adjust the outcome to the state of the world, but the disadvantage that any outcome selected will typically cause at least one party to feel aggrieved and shortchanged, which leads to a loss of surplus from shading.").
-
Q J Econ
, vol.123
, pp. 4
-
-
Hart1
Moore2
-
68
-
-
84875954706
-
-
(cited in note 8)
-
Fehr, Hart, and Zehnder, 101 Am Econ Rev at 498 (cited in note 8) (giving experimental buyers the ability to choose either a rigid contract, under which the price is fixed at the time of contracting, or a flexible contract, under which the buyer can, at the time of exchange, choose from a range of prices).
-
Am Econ Rev
, vol.101
, pp. 498
-
-
Fehr1
Hart2
Zehnder3
-
69
-
-
84875922258
-
-
(cited in note 8)
-
Fehr, Hart, and Zehnder, 101 Am Econ Rev at 499 (cited in note 8).
-
Am Econ Rev
, vol.101
, pp. 499
-
-
Fehr1
Hart2
Zehnder3
-
70
-
-
84875946413
-
-
(cited in note 8)
-
See also Feldman, Schurr, and Teichman, Reference Points and Contractual Choices at *28 (cited in note 8) (finding similar results in experiments focusing on the parties' interpretation of their contractual commitment).
-
Reference Points and Contractual Choices
, pp. 28
-
-
Feldman1
Schurr2
Teichman3
-
71
-
-
84870436666
-
-
(visited Mar 3, 2013)
-
For more details regarding Amazon's Mechanical Turk, see Amazon Mechanical Turk (Amazon Web Services), online at http://aws.amazon.com/mturk (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
Amazon Mechanical Turk (Amazon Web Services)
-
-
-
72
-
-
0003529429
-
-
McGraw-Hill 3d ed
-
Nonparametric tests of statistical significance like the one used here (the Wilcoxon test) are common when sample sizes are small and when the distribution is nonnormal. The tests are typically less powerful but more robust than parametric tests like the t- or F-statistics. One study reported here uses a small sample. For consistency, we report the p-values generated by the nonparametric test in all three studies. See Robert Rosenthal and Ralph L. Rosnow, Essentials of Behavioral Research: Method and Data Analysis 403-04 (McGraw-Hill 3d ed 2008).
-
(2008)
Essentials of Behavioral Research: Method and Data Analysis
, pp. 403-404
-
-
Rosenthal, R.1
Rosnow, R.L.2
-
73
-
-
84924710673
-
-
Cambridge
-
Subjects may even think that adding a rider is impermissible. Professor Larry Cunningham has noted that one of the most prevalent misconceptions about contracts is that they cannot be modified. See Lawrence A. Cunningham, Contracts in the Real World: Stories of Popular Contracts and Why They Matter 170-71 (Cambridge 2012) (correcting the misconception that "contracts cannot be changed once they are made").
-
(2012)
Contracts in the Real World: Stories of Popular Contracts and Why They Matter
, pp. 170-171
-
-
Cunningham, L.A.1
-
74
-
-
33745259012
-
The demand for immutable contracts: Another look at the law and economics of contract modifications
-
496
-
See Kevin E. Davis, The Demand for Immutable Contracts: Another Look at the Law and Economics of Contract Modifications, 81 NYU L Rev 487, 496 (2006) (suggesting that one problem with creating incentives for renegotiation is that renegotiating incurs additional costs while "redistribut[ing], rather than creat[ing], value").
-
(2006)
NYU L Rev
, vol.81
, pp. 487
-
-
Davis, K.E.1
-
75
-
-
84875922063
-
-
(cited in note 8)
-
See Hart and Moore, 123 Q J Econ at 12 (cited in note 8).
-
Q J Econ
, vol.123
, pp. 12
-
-
Hart1
Moore2
-
76
-
-
3042718957
-
Prospect theory, risk preference, and the law
-
1118
-
See Chris Guthrie, Prospect Theory, Risk Preference, and the Law, 97 Nw U L Rev 1115, 1118 (2003).
-
(2003)
Nw U L Rev
, vol.97
, pp. 1115
-
-
Guthrie, C.1
-
77
-
-
0037786760
-
Terrorism and probability neglect
-
123
-
Cass R. Sunstein, Terrorism and Probability Neglect, 26 J Risk & Uncertainty 121, 123 (2003).
-
(2003)
J Risk & Uncertainty
, vol.26
, pp. 121
-
-
Sunstein, C.R.1
-
78
-
-
70349932303
-
Prospect theory, reference points, and health decisions
-
176 figure 1
-
See Alan Schwartz, Julie Goldberg, and Gordon Hazen, Prospect Theory, Reference Points, and Health Decisions, 3 Judgment & Dec Making 174, 176 figure 1 (2008) (depicting the prospect theory value function).
-
(2008)
Judgment & Dec Making
, vol.3
, pp. 174
-
-
Schwartz, A.1
Goldberg, J.2
Hazen, G.3
-
79
-
-
0000538440
-
Mental accounting and consumer choice
-
201-02
-
See Richard Thaler, Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice, 4 Mtkg Sci 199, 201-02 (1985).
-
(1985)
Mtkg Sci
, vol.4
, pp. 199
-
-
Thaler, R.1
-
80
-
-
0013324794
-
-
Princeton
-
In terms of utility, contracts are almost certainly mixed gains because people are typically getting something that they want more than they want the money. See David D. Friedman, Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters 18- 19 (Princeton 2000) (explaining that based on rational-choice theory, economic legal analysis understands the way a contracting party values a given exchange based on her willingness to enter into the transaction).
-
(2000)
Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters
, pp. 18-19
-
-
Friedman, D.D.1
-
82
-
-
10044298804
-
The endowment effect and legal analysis
-
1228-29
-
See Russell Korobkin, The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis, 97 Nw U L Rev 1227, 1228-29 (2003) (defining the "status quo bias").
-
(2003)
Nw U L Rev
, vol.97
, pp. 1227
-
-
Korobkin, R.1
-
83
-
-
0347873744
-
Inertia and preference in contract negotiation: The psychological power of default rules and form terms
-
1605-07
-
For classic demonstrations of how the status quo bias may in general motivate contracting parties to prefer preexisting form terms, see Russell Korobkin, Inertia and Preference in Contract Negotiation: The Psychological Power of Default Rules and Form Terms, 51 Vand L Rev 1583, 1605-07 (1998);
-
(1998)
Vand L Rev
, vol.51
, pp. 1583
-
-
Korobkin, R.1
-
84
-
-
0346837978
-
The status quo bias and contract default rules
-
633-66
-
Russell Korobkin, The Status Quo Bias and Contract Default Rules, 83 Cornell L Rev 608, 633-66 (1998).
-
(1998)
Cornell L Rev
, vol.83
, pp. 608
-
-
Korobkin, R.1
-
85
-
-
84875938458
-
-
(cited in note 78)
-
See Korobkin, 97 Nw U L Rev at 1280 (cited in note 78) ("[T]he endowment effect is not obviously 'irrational' behavior: a preference for what one has over what one does not have, or for what one is accustomed to compared to the unknown, is no more troublesome than a preference for chocolate ice cream over vanilla.");
-
Nw U L Rev
, vol.97
, pp. 1280
-
-
Korobkin1
-
86
-
-
0002025043
-
Status quo bias in decision making
-
33-35
-
William Samuelson and Richard Zeckhauser, Status Quo Bias in Decision Making, 1 J Risk & Uncertainty 7, 33- 35 (1988).
-
(1988)
J Risk & Uncertainty
, vol.1
, pp. 7
-
-
Samuelson, W.1
Zeckhauser, R.2
-
87
-
-
84875953668
-
-
(cited in note 80)
-
See Korobkin, 83 Cornell L Rev at 624 (cited in note 80) (explaining that rational choice theory cannot account for the status quo bias).
-
Cornell L Rev
, vol.83
, pp. 624
-
-
Korobkin1
-
88
-
-
73349129390
-
Why do consumers buy extended service contracts?
-
611
-
See, for example, Tao Chen, Ajay Kalra, and Baohong Sun, Why Do Consumers Buy Extended Service Contracts?, 36 J Consumer Rsrch 611, 611 (2009) ("Although most consumer magazines and experts advocate consumers not buy [extended service contracts] because they provide little value, it is intriguing that the demand for [extended service contracts] remains high.").
-
(2009)
J Consumer Rsrch
, vol.36
, pp. 611
-
-
Chen, T.1
Kalra, A.2
Sun, B.3
-
89
-
-
0001875669
-
Non-contractual relations in business: A preliminary study
-
58-60
-
Stewart Macaulay, Non-contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 Am Soc Rev 55, 58-60 (1963).
-
(1963)
Am Soc Rev
, vol.28
, pp. 55
-
-
MacAulay, S.1
-
90
-
-
0039548966
-
Nonlegal sanctions in commercial relationships
-
391-425
-
David Charny, Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships, 104 Harv L Rev 373, 391-425 (1990).
-
(1990)
Harv L Rev
, vol.104
, pp. 373
-
-
Charny, D.1
-
91
-
-
74249087349
-
A cognitive theory of trust
-
1755-56
-
For a more in-depth look at promissory morality, see Claire A. Hill and Erin Ann O'Hara, A Cognitive Theory of Trust, 84 Wash U L Rev 1717, 1755-56 (2006) (discussing contract law's role in promoting optimal trust).
-
(2006)
Wash U L Rev
, vol.84
, pp. 1717
-
-
Hill, C.A.1
Ann O'hara, E.2
-
92
-
-
70849134262
-
The correspondence of contract and promise
-
1635
-
See Jody S. Kraus, The Correspondence of Contract and Promise, 109 Colum L Rev 1603, 1635 (2009).
-
(2009)
Colum L Rev
, vol.109
, pp. 1603
-
-
Kraus, J.S.1
-
93
-
-
84875914469
-
Origins and scope of the american moral obligation principle
-
See generally Kevin M. Teeven, Origins and Scope of the American Moral Obligation Principle, 46 Cleve St L Rev 585 (1998).
-
(1998)
Cleve St L Rev
, vol.46
, pp. 585
-
-
Teeven, K.M.1
-
94
-
-
66749166121
-
Moral judgment and moral heuristics in breach of contract
-
420-23
-
See Tess Wilkinson-Ryan and Jonathan Baron, Moral Judgment and Moral Heuristics in Breach of Contract, 6 J Empirical Legal Stud 405, 420-23 (2009).
-
(2009)
J Empirical Legal Stud
, vol.6
, pp. 405
-
-
Wilkinson-Ryan, T.1
Baron, J.2
-
96
-
-
83655182264
-
Are all contractual obligations created equal?
-
26-27
-
See Yuval Feldman and Doron Teichman, Are All Contractual Obligations Created Equal?, 100 Georgetown L J 5, 26-27 (2011) (hypothesizing that "the process of contracting, so long as it is the outcome of free choice, could lead to a deeper commitment to the contracts' terms");
-
(2011)
Georgetown L J
, vol.100
, pp. 5
-
-
Feldman, Y.1
Teichman, D.2
-
97
-
-
84875917088
-
Temporal dynamics of disclosure: The example of residential real estate conveyancing
-
86
-
Stephanie Stern, Temporal Dynamics of Disclosure: The Example of Residential Real Estate Conveyancing, 2005 Utah L Rev 57, 86 (arguing that late disclosures in real estate contracts will be ignored because buyers are invested in the deal going forward);
-
Utah L Rev
, vol.2005
, pp. 57
-
-
Stern, S.1
-
98
-
-
37149037607
-
Behavioral science and consumer standard form contracts
-
131-32
-
Shmuel I. Becher, Behavioral Science and Consumer Standard Form Contracts, 68 La L Rev 117, 131-32 (2007) (arguing that individuals are less likely to take care with terms after they have decided to enter a contract).
-
(2007)
La L Rev
, vol.68
, pp. 117
-
-
Becher, S.I.1
-
99
-
-
0038840680
-
Postdecision exposure to relevant information
-
101
-
See Danuta Ehrlich, et al, Postdecision Exposure to Relevant Information, 54 J Abnormal & Soc Psych 98, 101 (1957).
-
(1957)
J Abnormal & Soc Psych
, vol.54
, pp. 98
-
-
Ehrlich, D.1
-
100
-
-
85040398057
-
Cognitive dissonance and mutual fund investors
-
152-53
-
See William N. Goetzmann and Nadav Peles, Cognitive Dissonance and Mutual Fund Investors, 20 J Fin Rsrch 145, 152-53 (1997).
-
(1997)
J Fin Rsrch
, vol.20
, pp. 145
-
-
Goetzmann, W.N.1
Peles, N.2
-
101
-
-
0000541009
-
-
150-52 (cited in note 94)
-
Goetzmann and Peles, 20 J Fin Rsrch at 145, 150-52 (cited in note 94).
-
J Fin Rsrch
, vol.20
, pp. 145
-
-
Goetzmann1
Peles2
-
102
-
-
0000245521
-
Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises
-
177-78
-
See Raymond S. Nickerson, Confirmation Bias: A Ubiquitous Phenomenon in Many Guises, 2 Rev Gen Psych 175, 177-78 (1998).
-
(1998)
Rev Gen Psych
, vol.2
, pp. 175
-
-
Nickerson, R.S.1
-
103
-
-
84875957625
-
-
unpublished manuscript, (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
See, for example, Uriel Haran, A Person-Organization Discontinuity in Contract Perception: Why Organizations Can Get Away with Breaking Contracts but Individuals Cannot *23 (unpublished manuscript, 2012), online at http://law.huji.ac.il/upload/ HaranContractBreach.pdf (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
(2012)
A Person-Organization Discontinuity in Contract Perception: Why Organizations Can Get Away with Breaking Contracts but Individuals Cannot
, pp. 23
-
-
Haran, U.1
-
104
-
-
79251605439
-
The devil in the details: The interrelationship among citizenship, rule of law, and form-adhesive contracts
-
18-19
-
See, for example, Zev J. Eigen, The Devil in the Details: The Interrelationship among Citizenship, Rule of Law, and Form-Adhesive Contracts, 41 Conn L Rev 1, 18-19 (2008).
-
(2008)
Conn L Rev
, vol.41
, pp. 1
-
-
Eigen, Z.J.1
-
105
-
-
0036327974
-
Standard-form contracting in the electronic age
-
480-82
-
Consider Robert A. Hillman and Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age, 77 NYU L Rev 429, 480-82 (2002) (discussing ways in which firms could encourage consumers to fail to read their contracts online).
-
(2002)
NYU L Rev
, vol.77
, pp. 429
-
-
Hillman, R.A.1
Rachlinski, J.J.2
-
106
-
-
79960800790
-
From wax seals to hypertext: Electronic signatures, contract formation, and a new model for consumer protection in internet transactions
-
934
-
See Anthony M. Balloon, From Wax Seals to Hypertext: Electronic Signatures, Contract Formation, and a New Model for Consumer Protection in Internet Transactions, 50 Emory L J 905, 934 (2001) ("That a signature is the central formality in contract formation- particularly in a consumer transaction-cannot be overstated. Most consumers equate their signature with being bound to the terms of an agreement.").
-
(2001)
Emory L J
, vol.50
, pp. 905
-
-
Balloon, A.M.1
-
107
-
-
34247528699
-
Turning a blind eye: Wall street finance of predatory lending
-
2043-45, 2080
-
See Kathleen C. Engel and Patricia A. McCoy, Turning a Blind Eye: Wall Street Finance of Predatory Lending, 75 Fordham L Rev 2039, 2043-45, 2080 (2007) (including in its definition of predatory lending nonfraudulent forms of nontransparency between brokers or lenders and consumers).
-
(2007)
Fordham L Rev
, vol.75
, pp. 2039
-
-
Engel, K.C.1
McCoy, P.A.2
-
108
-
-
22544443064
-
Choice of law for internet transactions: The uneasy case for online consumer protection
-
1925
-
This is not, of course, a new insight. See, for example, Erin Ann O'Hara, Choice of Law for Internet Transactions: The Uneasy Case for Online Consumer Protection, 153 U Pa L Rev 1883, 1925 (2005) (exploring social and psychological forces that reduce the likelihood that consumers will protect themselves by reading their agreements).
-
(2005)
U Pa L Rev
, vol.153
, pp. 1883
-
-
Ann O'hara, E.1
-
109
-
-
0347095200
-
Odd man out: Preliminary findings concerning the diminishing role of lawyers in the home-buying process
-
471
-
See Michael Braunstein and Hazel Genn, Odd Man Out: Preliminary Findings Concerning the Diminishing Role of Lawyers in the Home-Buying Process, 52 Ohio St L J 469, 471 (1991) (citing a survey in which the most commonly articulated reason for home buyers hiring a lawyer was for the lawyer to "protect" the buyer).
-
(1991)
Ohio St L J
, vol.52
, pp. 469
-
-
Braunstein, M.1
Genn, H.2
-
110
-
-
70349515951
-
Competition and the quality of standard form contracts: The case of software license agreements
-
473-74
-
But see Florencia Marotta-Wurgler, Competition and the Quality of Standard Form Contracts: The Case of Software License Agreements, 5 J Empirical Legal Stud 447, 473-74 (2008).
-
(2008)
J Empirical Legal Stud
, vol.5
, pp. 447
-
-
Marotta-Wurgler, F.1
-
111
-
-
84883997067
-
Trustworthiness and contract
-
Paul J. Zak, ed, 187, Princeton
-
Erin Ann O'Hara, Trustworthiness and Contract, in Paul J. Zak, ed, Moral Markets: The Critical Role of Values in the Economy 173, 187 (Princeton 2008).
-
(2008)
Moral Markets: The Critical Role of Values in the Economy
, pp. 173
-
-
Ann O'hara, E.1
-
113
-
-
84868680785
-
Wood v lucy, lady duff-gordon
-
214-15, NY
-
That said, there are of course strands of good faith doctrine written into the negotiation process. For example, courts will routinely "fix" illusory contracts by implying some reasonable set of reciprocal obligations into the parties' terms. See, for example, Wood v Lucy, Lady Duff-Gordon, 118 NE 214, 214-15 (NY 1917);
-
(1917)
NE
, vol.118
, pp. 214
-
-
-
114
-
-
84875957397
-
Palisades properties, inc v brunetti
-
531, NJ
-
Palisades Properties, Inc v Brunetti, 207 A2d 522, 531 (NJ 1965).
-
(1965)
A2d
, vol.207
, pp. 522
-
-
-
116
-
-
33750562783
-
The best puffery article ever
-
1420-27
-
See David A. Hoffman, The Best Puffery Article Ever, 91 Iowa L Rev 1395, 1420- 27 (2006).
-
(2006)
Iowa L Rev
, vol.91
, pp. 1395
-
-
Hoffman, D.A.1
-
118
-
-
17544376308
-
The situational character: A critical realist perspective on the human animal
-
14
-
Jon Hanson and David Yosifon, The Situational Character: A Critical Realist Perspective on the Human Animal, 93 Georgetown L J 1, 14 (2004) (describing undue influence and duress as "very narrow doctrines").
-
(2004)
Georgetown L J
, vol.93
, pp. 1
-
-
Hanson, J.1
Yosifon, D.2
-
119
-
-
84875939812
-
-
9.7 (cited in note 111)
-
Perillo, Contracts § 9.7 at 284 (cited in note 111) (discussing business compulsion).
-
Contracts
, pp. 284
-
-
Perillo1
-
120
-
-
84875920977
-
United states v stump home specialties manufacturing, inc
-
1122, 7th Cir
-
See, for example, United States v Stump Home Specialties Manufacturing, Inc, 905 F2d 1117, 1122 (7th Cir 1990) (arguing that modifications ought not be policed by good faith or consideration doctrines but rather unconscionability or duress);
-
(1990)
F2d
, vol.905
, pp. 1117
-
-
-
121
-
-
84875949797
-
Levine v blumenthal
-
458, NJ
-
Levine v Blumenthal, 186 A 457, 458 (NJ 1936).
-
(1936)
A
, vol.186
, pp. 457
-
-
-
122
-
-
84875939812
-
-
§ 4.9 at 164 (cited in note 111)
-
See Perillo, Contracts § 4.9 at 164 (cited in note 111);
-
Contracts
-
-
Perillo1
-
124
-
-
84875926426
-
Brian construction and development co v brighenti
-
76, Conn
-
See Brian Construction and Development Co v Brighenti, 405 A2d 72, 76 (Conn 1978) (holding a contract modification binding where one party would have been forced to incur unforeseen expenses under the initial contract).
-
(1978)
A2d
, vol.405
, pp. 72
-
-
-
125
-
-
84055216988
-
Managing moral risk: The case of contract
-
1924
-
See Aditi Bagchi, Managing Moral Risk: The Case of Contract, 111 Colum L Rev 1878, 1924 n 148 (2011).
-
(2011)
Colum L Rev
, vol.111
, Issue.148
, pp. 1878
-
-
Bagchi, A.1
-
127
-
-
84875951108
-
-
(cited in note 11)
-
See Horton, 57 UCLA L Rev at 623-36 (cited in note 11);
-
UCLA L Rev
, vol.57
, pp. 623-36
-
-
Horton1
-
128
-
-
84875926911
-
-
(cited in note 12)
-
Bar-Gill and Davis, 84 S Cal L Rev at 8-16 (cited in note 12) (providing evidence of the scope of the unilateral modification problem).
-
S Cal L Rev
, vol.84
, pp. 8-16
-
-
Bar-Gill1
Davis2
-
129
-
-
73049102468
-
Disclosure, deception, and deep- packet inspection: The role of the federal trade commission act's deceptive conduct prohibitions in the net neutrality debate
-
692-93
-
See, for example, Catherine J.K. Sandoval, Disclosure, Deception, and Deep- Packet Inspection: The Role of the Federal Trade Commission Act's Deceptive Conduct Prohibitions in the Net Neutrality Debate, 78 Fordham L Rev 641, 692-93 (2009) (explaining that many jurisdictions do not permit unilateral contract modification in the absence of additional consideration);
-
(2009)
Fordham L Rev
, vol.78
, pp. 641
-
-
Catherine, J.K.1
Sandoval2
-
130
-
-
84875940214
-
-
(cited in note 12)
-
Bar-Gill and Davis, 84 S Cal L Rev at 19-26 (cited in note 12).
-
S Cal L Rev
, vol.84
, pp. 19-26
-
-
Bar-Gill1
Davis2
-
131
-
-
84875951424
-
After outcry, verizon abandons $2 fee
-
Dec 31
-
Ron Lieber, After Outcry, Verizon Abandons $2 Fee, NY Times B1 (Dec 31, 2011).
-
(2011)
NY Times
-
-
Lieber, R.1
-
132
-
-
84875941821
-
Bank of america drops plan for debit card fee
-
Nov 2
-
Tara Siegel Bernard, Bank of America Drops Plan for Debit Card Fee, NY Times A1 (Nov 2, 2011).
-
(2011)
NY Times
-
-
Siegel Bernard, T.1
-
133
-
-
84875939592
-
Verizon abandons $2 fee
-
(cited in note 123)
-
See Lieber, Verizon Abandons $2 Fee, NY Times at B1 (cited in note 123) (describing the online petition that caused Verizon to revoke the proposed policy);
-
NY Times
-
-
Lieber1
-
134
-
-
84875941821
-
Bank of america drops plan for debit card fee
-
(cited in note 124)
-
Bernard, Bank of America Drops Plan for Debit Card Fee, NY Times at A1 (cited in note 124) (noting dissatisfied customers' responses to the proposal).
-
NY Times
-
-
Bernard1
-
135
-
-
78049276288
-
Unstacking the deck? contract manipulation and credit card accountability
-
1475
-
See, for example, Eric A. Zacks, Unstacking the Deck? Contract Manipulation and Credit Card Accountability, 78 U Cin L Rev 1471, 1475 (2010);
-
(2010)
U Cin L Rev
, vol.78
, pp. 1471
-
-
Zacks, E.A.1
-
136
-
-
11844286037
-
Behavioral economics, contract formation, and contract law
-
Cass R. Sunstein, ed, 117-20, Cambridge
-
Russell Korobkin, Behavioral Economics, Contract Formation, and Contract Law, in Cass R. Sunstein, ed, Behavioral Law and Economics 116, 117-20 (Cambridge 2000).
-
(2000)
Behavioral Law and Economics
, pp. 116
-
-
Korobkin, R.1
-
137
-
-
84875927322
-
-
(cited in note 92)
-
Of course, these are not actually competing explanations. See, for example, Becher, 68 La L Rev at 138-40 (cited in note 92).
-
La L Rev
, vol.68
, pp. 138-40
-
-
Becher1
-
138
-
-
84875916707
-
-
(cited in note 13)
-
Alces and Greenfield, 26 Ga St U L Rev at 1100 (cited in note 13).
-
Ga St U L Rev
, vol.26
, pp. 1100
-
-
Alces1
Greenfield2
-
139
-
-
84875924101
-
Opting out or copping out? an argument for strict scrutiny of individual contracts
-
126-35
-
See, for example, Charles L. Knapp, Opting Out or Copping Out? An Argument for Strict Scrutiny of Individual Contracts, 40 Loyola LA L Rev 95, 126-35 (2006) (arguing for more rigorous judicial standards in evaluating "rolling contracts").
-
(2006)
Loyola la L Rev
, vol.40
, pp. 95
-
-
Knapp, C.L.1
-
140
-
-
84875952068
-
-
2-209(1) ALI
-
See UCC § 2-209(1) (ALI 1962).
-
(1962)
UCC
-
-
-
141
-
-
33847402188
-
-
7th Cir
-
105 F3d 1147 (7th Cir 1997).
-
(1997)
F3d
, vol.105
, pp. 1147
-
-
-
142
-
-
33645542763
-
ProCD, inc v zeidenberg
-
1451-53, 7th Cir
-
See also ProCD, Inc v Zeidenberg, 86 F3d 1447, 1451-53 (7th Cir 1996).
-
(1996)
F3d
, vol.86
, pp. 1447
-
-
-
143
-
-
84871531551
-
-
In reality, the Hills agreed to a sale on the phone. See Hill, 105 F3d at 1148.
-
F3d
, vol.105
, pp. 1148
-
-
Hill1
-
144
-
-
33847357305
-
Klocek v gateway, inc
-
1339, D Kan
-
See Klocek v Gateway, Inc, 104 F Supp 2d 1332, 1339 (D Kan 2000)
-
(2000)
F Supp 2d
, vol.104
, pp. 1332
-
-
-
145
-
-
84875922304
-
-
stating that UCC § 2-207, which governs the inclusion of additional terms in acceptance or confirmation of a contract, applies even when there is only one written form;
-
UCC
, pp. 2-207
-
-
-
146
-
-
84875939812
-
-
2.12 64 (cited in note 111)
-
Perillo, Contracts § 2.12 at 64 (cited in note 111) (describing the reasoning in Hill as flawed because according to the UCC the terms in the box constituted additional terms that do not become part of a contract).
-
Contracts
-
-
Perillo1
-
147
-
-
0036971381
-
Rolling contracts
-
For a summary of this debate, see generally Robert A. Hillman, Rolling Contracts, 71 Fordham L Rev 743 (2002).
-
(2002)
Fordham L Rev
, vol.71
, pp. 743
-
-
Hillman, R.A.1
-
149
-
-
84875926830
-
-
(cited in note 17)
-
Hillman and O'Rourke, 78 U Chi L Rev at 106-08 (cited in note 17).
-
U Chi L Rev
, vol.78
, pp. 106-108
-
-
Hillman1
O'rourke2
-
150
-
-
84875926830
-
-
(cited in note 17)
-
Hillman and O'Rourke, 78 U Chi L Rev at 106 (cited in note 17).
-
U Chi L Rev
, vol.78
, pp. 106
-
-
Hillman1
O'rourke2
-
151
-
-
84859015072
-
Against notice skepticism in privacy (and elsewhere)
-
1062
-
See, for example, M. Ryan Calo, Against Notice Skepticism in Privacy (and Elsewhere), 87 Notre Dame L Rev 1027, 1062 (2012) (arguing that changes in website design can make reading terms more likely).
-
(2012)
Notre Dame L Rev
, vol.87
, pp. 1027
-
-
Ryan Calo, M.1
-
152
-
-
84875934553
-
-
(cited in note 16)
-
See, for example, Ben-Shahar and Schneider, 159 U Pa L Rev at 651 (cited in note 16);
-
U Pa L Rev
, vol.159
, pp. 651
-
-
Ben-Shahar1
Schneider2
-
153
-
-
79952222063
-
-
(cited in note 16)
-
Ben-Shahar, 5 Eur Rev Contemp L at 13-21 (cited in note 16);
-
Eur Rev Contemp L
, vol.5
, pp. 13-21
-
-
Ben-Shahar1
-
154
-
-
84875958627
-
-
(cited in note 16)
-
Mann and Siebeneicher, 108 Colum L Rev at 998-1001 (cited in note 16).
-
Colum L Rev
, vol.108
, pp. 998-1001
-
-
Mann1
Siebeneicher2
-
155
-
-
84875942168
-
-
(cited in note 104)
-
See Hillman and Rachlinski, 77 NYU L Rev at 436 (cited in note 104) ("The consumer, engaging in a rough but reasonable cost-benefit analysis of these factors, understands that the costs of reading, interpreting, and comparing standard terms outweigh any benefits of doing so and therefore chooses not to read the form carefully or even at all.");
-
NYU L Rev
, vol.77
, pp. 436
-
-
Hillman1
Rachlinski2
-
156
-
-
79952130559
-
Will increased disclosure help? evaluating the recommendations of the ali's "principles of the law of software contracts,"
-
173-82
-
Florencia Marotta-Wurgler. Will Increased Disclosure Help? Evaluating the Recommendations of the ALI's "Principles of the Law of Software Contracts," 78 U Chi L Rev 165, 173-82 (2011);
-
(2011)
U Chi L Rev
, vol.78
, pp. 165
-
-
Marotta-Wurgler, F.1
-
157
-
-
84857510160
-
Does contract disclosure matter?
-
108-10
-
Florencia Marotta-Wurgler, Does Contract Disclosure Matter?, 168 J Inst & Theoretical Econ 94, 108-10 (2012);
-
(2012)
J Inst & Theoretical Econ
, vol.168
, pp. 94
-
-
Marotta-Wurgler, F.1
-
158
-
-
84875921034
-
-
(cited in note 16)
-
Ben-Shahar and Schneider, 159 U Pa L Rev at 671-72 (cited in note 16);
-
U Pa L Rev
, vol.159
, pp. 671-672
-
-
Ben-Shahar1
Schneider2
-
159
-
-
79751489738
-
-
NYU Center for Law, Economics and Organization Working Paper No 09-40, Oct 6, (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
Yannis Bakos, Florencia Marotta-Wurgler, and David R. Trossen, Does Anyone Read the Fine Print? Testing a Law and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts *36-37 (NYU Center for Law, Economics and Organization Working Paper No 09-40, Oct 6, 2009), online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ papers.cfm ?abstract-id=1443256 (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
(2009)
Does Anyone Read the Fine Print? Testing A Law and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts
, pp. 36-37
-
-
Bakos, Y.1
Marotta-Wurgler, F.2
Trossen, D.R.3
-
160
-
-
0842334737
-
Literacy and contract
-
237-38
-
See, for example, Alan M. White and Cathy Lesser Mansfield, Literacy and Contract, 13 Stan L & Pol Rev 233, 237-38 (2002) (explaining that 96 percent of Americans do not have the requisite literacy skills to extract and compute credit cost information from contract and disclosure documents).
-
(2002)
Stan L & Pol Rev
, vol.13
, pp. 233
-
-
White, A.M.1
Lesser Mansfield, C.2
-
161
-
-
84875933647
-
-
(cited in note 16)
-
See Ben-Shahar and Schneider, 159 U Pa L Rev at 738-40 (cited in note 16).
-
U Pa L Rev
, vol.159
, pp. 738-740
-
-
Ben-Shahar1
Schneider2
-
162
-
-
84875950074
-
-
1066-67 (cited in note 139);
-
See also Calo, 87 Notre Dame L Rev at 1035-44, 1066-67 (cited in note 139);
-
Notre Dame L Rev
, vol.87
, pp. 1035-1044
-
-
Calo1
-
163
-
-
84875952971
-
-
(cited in note 16)
-
Ben-Shahar and Schneider, 159 U Pa L Rev at 696-702 (cited in note 16).
-
U Pa L Rev
, vol.159
, pp. 696-702
-
-
Ben-Shahar1
Schneider2
-
164
-
-
84871596574
-
-
Hill, 105 F3d at 1149.
-
F3d
, vol.105
, pp. 1149
-
-
Hill1
-
165
-
-
33847357305
-
-
D Kan
-
104 F Supp 2d 1332 (D Kan 2000).
-
(2000)
F Supp 2d
, vol.104
, pp. 1332
-
-
-
166
-
-
84875939812
-
-
2.18 71 (cited in note 111)
-
See Perillo, Contracts § 2.18 at 71 (cited in note 111).
-
Contracts
-
-
Perillo1
-
167
-
-
84875954900
-
-
See Klocek, 104 F Supp 2d at 1341.
-
F Supp 2d
, vol.104
, pp. 1341
-
-
Klocek1
-
168
-
-
84875964403
-
Rogers v dell computer corp
-
831, Okla
-
See also Rogers v Dell Computer Corp, 138 P3d 826, 831 (Okla 2005).
-
(2005)
P3d
, vol.138
, pp. 826
-
-
-
169
-
-
84868693171
-
Sun printing & publishing assn v remington paper & power co
-
470, NY
-
For the case on which these facts are loosely based, see Sun Printing & Publishing Assn v Remington Paper & Power Co, 139 NE 470, 470 (NY 1923).
-
(1923)
NE
, vol.139
, pp. 470
-
-
-
170
-
-
84875939812
-
-
2.9(a)(4) 53 (cited in note 111)
-
See Perillo, Contracts § 2.9(a)(4) at 53 (cited in note 111).
-
Contracts
-
-
Perillo1
-
171
-
-
77957711270
-
Clicking and cringing
-
848
-
But see Nancy S. Kim, Clicking and Cringing, 86 Or L Rev 797, 848 (2007);
-
(2007)
Or L Rev
, vol.86
, pp. 797
-
-
Kim, N.S.1
-
173
-
-
84875941097
-
-
(cited in note 152)
-
See Kim, 86 Or L Rev at 836-48 (cited in note 152) (summarizing the difference between browsewrap and clickwrap cases).
-
Or L Rev
, vol.86
, pp. 836-848
-
-
Kim1
-
174
-
-
84875942828
-
Becher
-
(cited in note 92)
-
A more conventional (but related) argument holds that consumers can be induced to enter contracts online without even knowing that they are doing so, as the process lacks the ordinary off-line formalities. Becher, 68 La L Rev at 164-66 (cited in note 92).
-
La L Rev
, vol.68
, pp. 164-166
-
-
-
176
-
-
84928217792
-
Beyond promissory estoppel: Contract law and the "invisible handshake,"
-
929-30
-
See, for example, Daniel A. Farber and John H. Matheson, Beyond Promissory Estoppel: Contract Law and the "Invisible Handshake," 52 U Chi L Rev 903, 929-30 (1985);
-
(1985)
U Chi L Rev
, vol.52
, pp. 903
-
-
Farber, D.A.1
Matheson, J.H.2
-
177
-
-
84928439568
-
The promissory basis of section 90
-
129-30
-
Edward Yorio and Steve Thel, The Promissory Basis of Section 90, 101 Yale L J 111, 129-30 (1991).
-
(1991)
Yale L J
, vol.101
, pp. 111
-
-
Yorio, E.1
Thel, S.2
-
178
-
-
0346935093
-
Questioning the "new consensus" on promissory estoppel: An empirical and theoretical study
-
618
-
Robert A. Hillman, Questioning the "New Consensus" on Promissory Estoppel: An Empirical and Theoretical Study, 98 Colum L Rev 580, 618 (1998).
-
(1998)
Colum L Rev
, vol.98
, pp. 580
-
-
Hillman, R.A.1
-
179
-
-
84875929177
-
-
(cited in note 2)
-
See also Jimenez, 57 UCLA L Rev at 701-02 (cited in note 2) (arguing that courts justify themselves in terms of both promise and reliance).
-
UCLA L Rev
, vol.57
, pp. 701-702
-
-
Jimenez1
-
180
-
-
1542627833
-
Reliance in the revised restatement: The proliferation of promissory estoppel
-
53
-
See Charles L. Knapp, Reliance in the Revised Restatement: The Proliferation of Promissory Estoppel, 81 Colum L Rev 52, 53 (1981) ("[P]romissory estoppel . . . has become perhaps the most radical and expansive development of this century in the law of promissory liability.") (quotation marks omitted);
-
(1981)
Colum L Rev
, vol.81
, pp. 52
-
-
Knapp, C.L.1
-
182
-
-
78650845742
-
Breach is for suckers
-
1039-40
-
Tess Wilkinson-Ryan and David A. Hoffman, Breach Is for Suckers, 63 Vand L Rev 1003, 1039-40 (2010).
-
(2010)
Vand L Rev
, vol.63
, pp. 1003
-
-
Wilkinson-Ryan, T.1
Hoffman, D.A.2
-
183
-
-
84875918814
-
-
See Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 90 (making enforceable a promise that the "promisor should reasonably expect to induce action or forbearance") (emphasis added);
-
Restatement (Second) of Contracts
, pp. 90
-
-
-
184
-
-
84875942692
-
Stewart v cendant mobility services corp
-
742, Conn
-
Stewart v Cendant Mobility Services Corp, 837 A2d 736, 742 (Conn 2003).
-
(2003)
A2d
, vol.837
, pp. 736
-
-
-
185
-
-
78650818283
-
Promissory estoppel and the protection of interpersonal trust
-
50-51
-
See John J. Chung, Promissory Estoppel and the Protection of Interpersonal Trust, 56 Cleve St L Rev 37, 50-51 (2008) (discussing the differences between trust and reliance).
-
(2008)
Cleve St L Rev
, vol.56
, pp. 37
-
-
Chung, J.J.1
-
187
-
-
21944443686
-
The new requirement of enforcement reliance in commercial promissory estoppel: Section 90 as catch-22
-
959
-
See Sidney W. DeLong, The New Requirement of Enforcement Reliance in Commercial Promissory Estoppel: Section 90 as Catch-22, 1997 Wis L Rev 943, 959 (noting that some courts suggest that promisees must demonstrate that they believed a promise legally enforceable to obtain relief under § 90).
-
Wis L Rev
, vol.1997
, pp. 943
-
-
Sidney, W.1
Delong2
-
188
-
-
84875929451
-
-
Wis
-
133 NW2d 267 (Wis 1965).
-
(1965)
NW2d
, vol.133
, pp. 267
-
-
-
189
-
-
84875931468
-
Hoffman v. red owl stores and the myth of precontractual reliance
-
Douglas G. Baird, ed, 82, Foundation
-
For an extended argument against the Hoffman holding and against treating it as a typical promissory estoppel case, see Robert E. Scott, Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores and the Myth of Precontractual Reliance, in Douglas G. Baird, ed, Contracts Stories 62, 82 (Foundation 2007).
-
(2007)
Contracts Stories
, pp. 62
-
-
Scott, R.E.1
-
190
-
-
84875939687
-
-
Hoffman, 133 NW2d at 269.
-
NW2d
, vol.133
, pp. 269
-
-
Hoffman1
-
191
-
-
84875959320
-
-
(cited in note 71)
-
For a discussion of why survey responses might not track actual behavior, see Guthrie, 97 Nw U L Rev at 1156-59 (cited in note 71) (discussing external validity concerns typical of prospect theory research);
-
Nw U L Rev
, vol.97
, pp. 1156-1159
-
-
Guthrie1
-
192
-
-
83655185005
-
Attitudes and behavior
-
David S. Clark, ed, 102-04, Sage
-
Yuval Feldman, Attitudes and Behavior, in David S. Clark, ed, Encyclopedia of Law & Society: American and Global Perspectives 102, 102-04 (Sage 2007) (discussing concerns with survey experiments).
-
(2007)
Encyclopedia of Law & Society: American and Global Perspectives
, pp. 102
-
-
Feldman, Y.1
-
193
-
-
84875964793
-
-
(cited in note 92)
-
See Feldman and Teichman, 100 Georgetown L J at 46 & n 209 (cited in note 92).
-
Georgetown L J
, vol.100
, Issue.209
, pp. 46
-
-
Feldman1
Teichman2
-
194
-
-
80051530557
-
In praise of pedantic eclecticism: Pitfalls and opportunities in the psychology of judging
-
David Klein and Gregory Mitchell, eds, 143, Oxford
-
See, for example, Dan Simon, In Praise of Pedantic Eclecticism: Pitfalls and Opportunities in the Psychology of Judging, in David Klein and Gregory Mitchell, eds, The Psychology of Judicial Decision Making 131, 143 (Oxford 2010).
-
(2010)
The Psychology of Judicial Decision Making
, pp. 131
-
-
Simon, D.1
-
195
-
-
77957011930
-
Running experiments on amazon mechanical turk
-
415-17
-
See, for example, Gabriele Paolacci, Jesse Chandler, and Panagiotis G. Ipeirotis, Running Experiments on Amazon Mechanical Turk, 5 Judgment & Dec Making 411, 415-17 (2010);
-
(2010)
Judgment & Dec Making
, vol.5
, pp. 411
-
-
Paolacci, G.1
Chandler, J.2
Ipeirotis, P.G.3
-
196
-
-
84857918066
-
The promise of mechanical turk: How online labor markets can help theorists run behavioral experiments
-
175-76
-
David G. Rand, The Promise of Mechanical Turk: How Online Labor Markets Can Help Theorists Run Behavioral Experiments, 299 J Theoretical Bio 172, 175-76 (2012).
-
(2012)
J Theoretical Bio
, vol.299
, pp. 172
-
-
Rand, D.G.1
-
198
-
-
0040884260
-
Boys will be boys: Gender, overconfidence, and common stock investment
-
264-66
-
See Brad M. Barber and Terrance Odean, Boys Will Be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence, and Common Stock Investment, 116 Q J Econ 261, 264-66 (2001) (summarizing studies that find that men are more risk seeking than women).
-
(2001)
Q J Econ
, vol.116
, pp. 261
-
-
Barber, B.M.1
Odean, T.2
-
199
-
-
84875953864
-
-
(cited in note 171)
-
See Paolacci, Chandler, and Ipeirotis, 5 Judgment & Dec Making at 412-13 (cited in note 171) (surveying various motivations that Mechanical Turk users gave for using the service and noting that 32.3 percent said they used it for "killing time").
-
Judgment & Dec Making
, vol.5
, pp. 412-413
-
-
Paolacci1
Chandler2
Ipeirotis3
-
200
-
-
67651014851
-
Instructional manipulation checks: Detecting satisficing to increase statistical power
-
869-70
-
See Daniel M. Oppenheimer, Tom Meyvis, and Nicolas Davidenko, Instructional Manipulation Checks: Detecting Satisficing to Increase Statistical Power, 45 J Exp Soc Psych 867, 869-70 (2009).
-
(2009)
J Exp Soc Psych
, vol.45
, pp. 867
-
-
Oppenheimer, D.M.1
Meyvis, T.2
Davidenko, N.3
-
201
-
-
84875950550
-
-
(cited in note 92)
-
See, for example, Feldman and Teichman, 100 Georgetown L J at 47 (cited in note 92).
-
Georgetown L J
, vol.100
, pp. 47
-
-
Feldman1
Teichman2
-
202
-
-
84855337530
-
-
working paper, July 19, (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
In an interesting experiment, Professors Raymond Fisman, Shachar Kariv, and Daniel Markovits observe that even one semester's worth of law school education may change students' distributional preferences in the Dictator Game, a game in which one player (the dictator) is free to divide a sum of money with another player however she sees fit. See Raymond Fisman, Shachar Kariv, and Daniel Markovits, Exposure to Ideology and Distributional Preferences *3-4 (working paper, July 19, 2009), online at http://emlab.berkeley.edu/~kariv/FKM- II.pdf (visited Mar 3, 2013).
-
(2009)
Exposure to Ideology and Distributional Preferences
, pp. 3-4
-
-
Fisman, R.1
Kariv, S.2
Markovits, D.3
-
203
-
-
0001875669
-
-
(cited in note 85)
-
See, for example, Macaulay, 28 Am Soc Rev at 55 (cited in note 85);
-
Am Soc Rev
, vol.28
, pp. 55
-
-
MacAulay1
-
204
-
-
0345916159
-
Exploring the battle of the forms in action
-
2695-2704
-
Daniel Keating, Exploring the Battle of the Forms in Action, 98 Mich L Rev 2678, 2695-2704 (2000);
-
(2000)
Mich L Rev
, vol.98
, pp. 2678
-
-
Keating, D.1
-
205
-
-
0042237540
-
A survey of contract practice and policy
-
13-30
-
Russell J. Weintraub, A Survey of Contract Practice and Policy, 1992 Wis L Rev 1, 13-30.
-
Wis L Rev
, vol.1992
, pp. 1
-
-
Weintraub, R.J.1
-
206
-
-
84855887848
-
The myth of efficient breach: New defenses of the expectation interest
-
1954
-
Daniel Markovits and Alan Schwartz, The Myth of Efficient Breach: New Defenses of the Expectation Interest, 97 Va L Rev 1939, 1954 n 32 (2011).
-
(2011)
Va L Rev
, vol.97
, Issue.32
, pp. 1939
-
-
Markovits, D.1
Schwartz, A.2
-
207
-
-
0347140588
-
The law of contract and the concept of change: Public and private attempts to regulate modification, waiver, and estoppel
-
654
-
David V. Snyder, The Law of Contract and the Concept of Change: Public and Private Attempts to Regulate Modification, Waiver, and Estoppel, 1999 Wis L Rev 607, 654.
-
Wis L Rev
, vol.1999
, pp. 607
-
-
Snyder, D.V.1
-
208
-
-
33847024553
-
Insurers, illusions of judgment & litigation
-
2047
-
See Chris Guthrie and Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Insurers, Illusions of Judgment & Litigation, 59 Vand L Rev 2017, 2047 (2006) (reporting that decision makers at insurance firms were less prone to anchoring, framing, and self-serving biases).
-
(2006)
Vand L Rev
, vol.59
, pp. 2017
-
-
Guthrie, C.1
Rachlinski, J.J.2
-
209
-
-
4544385672
-
Apologies and legal settlement: An empirical examination
-
482-90
-
As an example, it's well established that certain kinds of apologies will provoke settlements, though such apologies must be perceived to be genuine to be effective. See Jennifer K. Robbennolt, Apologies and Legal Settlement: An Empirical Examination, 102 Mich L Rev 460, 482-90 (2003) (finding that the acceptance rate for settlements increased from 52 percent under no apology to 73 percent under a full apology).
-
(2003)
Mich L Rev
, vol.102
, pp. 460
-
-
Robbennolt, J.K.1
-
210
-
-
74849083354
-
A theory of self-help remedies in contract
-
1397-1401
-
This is not to say that they might not learn about such remedies indirectly through the actions of creditors for example. Consider Mark P. Gergen, A Theory of Self-Help Remedies in Contract, 89 BU L Rev 1397, 1397-1401 (2009) (discussing self-help rules).
-
(2009)
BU L Rev
, vol.89
, pp. 1397
-
-
Gergen, M.P.1
-
211
-
-
60249086873
-
Empirically assessing hadley v. baxendale
-
921-49
-
See, for example, George S. Geis, Empirically Assessing Hadley v. Baxendale, 32 Fla St U L Rev 897, 921-49 (2005).
-
(2005)
Fla St U L Rev
, vol.32
, pp. 897
-
-
Geis, G.S.1
-
212
-
-
38649116624
-
Intuitions of justice: Implications for criminal law and justice policy
-
18-31
-
See, for example, Paul H. Robinson and John M. Darley, Intuitions of Justice: Implications for Criminal Law and Justice Policy, 81 S Cal L Rev 1, 18-31 (2007).
-
(2007)
S Cal L Rev
, vol.81
, pp. 1
-
-
Robinson, P.H.1
Darley, J.M.2
-
213
-
-
84873020450
-
Some hypotheses about empirical desert
-
1193-98
-
See, for example, Christopher Slobogin, Some Hypotheses about Empirical Desert, 42 Ariz St L J 1189, 1193-98 (2011) (arguing that individuals either won't notice a departure from ordinary intuitions about punishment or won't care).
-
(2011)
Ariz St L J
, vol.42
, pp. 1189
-
-
Slobogin, C.1
-
214
-
-
78449239068
-
Some realism about punishment naturalism
-
1566-68
-
See also Donald Braman, Dan M. Kahan, and David A. Hoffman, Some Realism about Punishment Naturalism, 77 U Chi L Rev 1531, 1566-68 (2010) (arguing that individuals' views about the morality of punishment are culturally contingent).
-
(2010)
U Chi L Rev
, vol.77
, pp. 1531
-
-
Braman, D.1
Kahan, D.M.2
Hoffman, D.A.3
|