-
1
-
-
33645788995
-
Behavioral Economics: Human Errors and Market Corrections, 73
-
Richard A. Epstein, Behavioral Economics: Human Errors and Market Corrections, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 111, 111 (2006)
-
(2006)
U. CHI. L. REV
, vol.111
, pp. 111
-
-
Epstein, R.A.1
-
3
-
-
33645758674
-
Bundling and Consumer Misperception, 73
-
See
-
See Oren Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 33 (2006)
-
(2006)
U. CHI. L. REV
, vol.33
-
-
Bar-Gill, O.1
-
5
-
-
8644277076
-
Seduction by Plastic, 98
-
Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 NW. U. L. REV. 1373 (2004)
-
(2004)
NW. U. L. REV
, vol.1373
-
-
Bar-Gill, O.1
-
8
-
-
77149134046
-
-
see also Richard A. Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, in BEHAVIORAL PUBLIC FINANCE 355-56, 365-67, 384-85 (Edward J. McCaffery & Joel Slemrod eds., 2006)
-
see also Richard A. Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, in BEHAVIORAL PUBLIC FINANCE 355-56, 365-67, 384-85 (Edward J. McCaffery & Joel Slemrod eds., 2006)
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
41449109395
-
-
hereinafter, Some of the challenges and responses discussed below echo elements of the general debate over the role of behavioral economics in legal policymaking
-
[hereinafter Epstein, Second-Order Rationality], Some of the challenges and responses discussed below echo elements of the general debate over the role of behavioral economics in legal policymaking.
-
Second-Order Rationality
-
-
Epstein1
-
10
-
-
0348246071
-
A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50
-
See, e.g
-
See, e.g., Christine Jolis, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471, 1476-88 (1998)
-
(1998)
STAN. L. REV
, vol.1471
, pp. 1476-1488
-
-
Jolis, C.1
Sunstein, C.R.2
Thaler, R.3
-
12
-
-
22044438205
-
Theories and Tropes: A Reply to Posner and Kelman, 50
-
Christine Jolis, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, Theories and Tropes: A Reply to Posner and Kelman, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1593 (1998);
-
(1998)
STAN. L. REV
, vol.1593
-
-
Jolis, C.1
Sunstein, C.R.2
Thaler, R.3
-
13
-
-
22044438367
-
Behavioral Economics as Part of a Rhetorical Duet: A Response to Jolis, Sunstein, and Thaler, 50
-
Mark G. Kelman, Behavioral Economics as Part of a Rhetorical Duet: A Response to Jolis, Sunstein, and Thaler, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1577, 1586-90 (1998);
-
(1998)
STAN. L. REV
, vol.1577
, pp. 1586-1590
-
-
Kelman, M.G.1
-
14
-
-
0347487318
-
Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law, 50
-
This Article, and more broadly, this Exchange, between Professor Epstein and myself-is unique in its focus on the application of behavioral law and economics to consumer contracts
-
Richard A. Posner, Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1551 (1998). This Article, and more broadly, this Exchange - between Professor Epstein and myself-is unique in its focus on the application of behavioral law and economics to consumer contracts.
-
(1998)
STAN. L. REV
, vol.1551
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
15
-
-
41449110138
-
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 114-18, 126-27;
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 114-18, 126-27;
-
-
-
-
16
-
-
41449109557
-
-
Richard A. Epstein, Exchange, The Neoclassical Economics of Consumer Contracts, 92 MINN. L. REV. 803, 810-16 (2008)
-
Richard A. Epstein, Exchange, The Neoclassical Economics of Consumer Contracts, 92 MINN. L. REV. 803, 810-16 (2008)
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
41449109954
-
Exchange, Neoclassical
-
hereinafter
-
[hereinafter Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics].
-
Economics
-
-
Epstein1
-
19
-
-
41449096575
-
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 816-17
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 816-17.
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
41449118654
-
-
Id. at 120
-
Id. at 120.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
41449098100
-
-
Id. at 121-22
-
Id. at 121-22.
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
41449103714
-
-
B]uyers do not have uniform demands
-
See id. ("[B]uyers do not have uniform demands.").
-
See id
-
-
-
24
-
-
41449116559
-
-
A qualification should be mentioned: If sellers can segment the market and offer one product (and one pricing scheme) to overestimators and another product (and another pricing scheme) to underestimators, then a design response to consumer misperception need not be inconsistent with an average mistake of zero. This qualification, however, is largely theoretical. As Epstein himself argues, segmentation according to the type or level of misperception is unlikely. See id. at 121 ([N]o consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level].);
-
A qualification should be mentioned: If sellers can segment the market and offer one product (and one pricing scheme) to overestimators and another product (and another pricing scheme) to underestimators, then a design response to consumer misperception need not be inconsistent with an average mistake of zero. This qualification, however, is largely theoretical. As Epstein himself argues, segmentation according to the type or level of misperception is unlikely. See id. at 121 ("[N]o consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level].");
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
41449086074
-
-
see also infra note 78.
-
see also infra note 78.
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
41449101674
-
-
at
-
Id. at 125, 128.
-
-
-
Epstein1
-
28
-
-
41449115902
-
-
Id. at 127 (Banks know how to live with predictable defaults, but they hardly regard the failure of their borrowers as an advantage to themselves.).
-
Id. at 127 ("Banks know how to live with predictable defaults, but they hardly regard the failure of their borrowers as an advantage to themselves.").
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
41449090172
-
-
See id. at 131 (Banning [so-called 'teaser' credit card] rates will do no good, and it could easily work some anticompetitive harm, by making it more difficult for new banks to pry customers away from established competitors.).
-
See id. at 131 ("Banning [so-called 'teaser' credit card] rates will do no good, and it could easily work some anticompetitive harm, by making it more difficult for new banks to pry customers away from established competitors.").
-
-
-
-
32
-
-
41449093295
-
-
See id. ([A]ny regulation that slows down the profligate borrower will also deter the cautious borrower from entering into the market by raising his costs of transaction.).
-
See id. ("[A]ny regulation that slows down the profligate borrower will also deter the cautious borrower from entering into the market by raising his costs of transaction.").
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
41449088134
-
-
See id. at 128.
-
See id. at 128.
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
41449098541
-
-
See id. at 127 (The general disclosure remedies are shown to have a place.).
-
See id. at 127 ("The general disclosure remedies are shown to have a place.").
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
41449107845
-
-
I define use broadly to include the payment of different price components, redeeming rebates, etc
-
I define "use" broadly to include the payment of different price components, redeeming rebates, etc.
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
41449093297
-
-
This theme is further developed in a companion piece. See Oren Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers About Themselves 53-63 Oct. 4, 2007, unpublished manuscript, on file with author
-
This theme is further developed in a companion piece. See Oren Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers About Themselves 53-63 (Oct. 4, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author)
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
41449100259
-
-
Id. at 118
-
Id. at 118.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
41449115121
-
-
See id. at 120.
-
See id. at 120.
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
41449117439
-
-
See id. (arguing that the competitive, open market corrects consumer misperceptions because a seller of a somewhat different product will draw away the customers [of the original, misperceived product] by trumpeting the mistake).
-
See id. (arguing that the competitive, open market corrects consumer misperceptions because a "seller of a somewhat different product will draw away the customers [of the original, misperceived product] by trumpeting the mistake").
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
41449110870
-
-
See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions, 59 J. BUS. (CONFERENCE PROCEEDINGS) S251, S275 (1986),
-
See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions, 59 J. BUS. (CONFERENCE PROCEEDINGS) S251, S275 (1986),
-
-
-
-
44
-
-
41449108262
-
-
reprinted in RATIONAL CHOICE: THE CONTRAST BETWEEN ECONOMICS AND PSYCHOLOGY 67, 91 (Robin M. Hogarth & Melvin W. Reder eds., 1987) (The claim that the market can be trusted to correct the effect of individual irrationalities cannot be made without supporting evidence . . . .).
-
reprinted in RATIONAL CHOICE: THE CONTRAST BETWEEN ECONOMICS AND PSYCHOLOGY 67, 91 (Robin M. Hogarth & Melvin W. Reder eds., 1987) ("The claim that the market can be trusted to correct the effect of individual irrationalities cannot be made without supporting evidence . . . .").
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
41449105357
-
-
In this Exchange, Epstein cites findings from a recent study by Agarwal et al. showing that consumers do learn. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 811-12
-
In this Exchange, Epstein cites findings from a recent study by Agarwal et al. showing that consumers do learn. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 811-12
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
41449114935
-
-
(citing Sumit Agarwal et al., The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Lifecycle 2 (Mass. Inst, of Tech. Dep't of Econ. Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 07-11, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=973790).
-
(citing Sumit Agarwal et al., The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Lifecycle 2 (Mass. Inst, of Tech. Dep't of Econ. Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 07-11, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=973790).
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
41449110142
-
-
I am not arguing that consumers do not learn. I am only arguing that learning is imperfect. Indeed, the Agarwal study reveals that a significant number of consumers make mistakes. See, e.g., Agarwal et al., supra, at 15 (concluding that, in home equity credit lending, [t]he unconditional average probability of making a ... mistake [affecting interest rate] is 24[%] for loans and 18[%] for lines [of credit] and [y]ounger and older consumers have a greater tendency to misestimate the value of their house . . . which leads them to borrow at an increased APR).
-
I am not arguing that consumers do not learn. I am only arguing that learning is imperfect. Indeed, the Agarwal study reveals that a significant number of consumers make mistakes. See, e.g., Agarwal et al., supra, at 15 (concluding that, in home equity credit lending, "[t]he unconditional average probability of making a ... mistake [affecting interest rate] is 24[%] for loans and 18[%] for lines [of credit]" and "[y]ounger and older consumers have a greater tendency to misestimate the value of their house . . . which leads them to borrow at an increased APR").
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
21344493140
-
Good Warnings, Bad Products, and Cognitive Limitations, 41
-
T]he capacity for learning is dependent on the specific product-use context, On the conditions for effective learning and on the limits of learning, see
-
On the conditions for effective learning and on the limits of learning, see Howard Latin, "Good" Warnings, Bad Products, and Cognitive Limitations, 41 UCLA L. REV. 1193, 1252-53 (1994) ("[T]he capacity for learning is dependent on the specific product-use context . . . .");
-
(1994)
UCLA L. REV
, vol.1193
, pp. 1252-1253
-
-
Latin, H.1
-
50
-
-
41449113347
-
-
Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75 (Effective learning takes place only under certain conditions . . . . [A]ny claim that a particular error will be eliminated by experience must be supported by demonstrating that the conditions for effective learning are satisfied.).
-
Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75 ("Effective learning takes place only under certain conditions . . . . [A]ny claim that a particular error will be eliminated by experience must be supported by demonstrating that the conditions for effective learning are satisfied.").
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
41449091486
-
-
Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 ([M]ost feedback [about the risks of using a product] takes the form of experiences of safe usage.).
-
Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 ("[M]ost feedback [about the risks of using a product] takes the form of experiences of safe usage.").
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
41449096579
-
-
See Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75
-
See Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75.
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
41449094297
-
-
See id. (criticizing the hopeless artificiality of any example that presupposes universal ignorance of the value of any standard commodity and arguing that there is no sustainable equilibrium when the mistake in information is about a standardized product that everyone can test and use).
-
See id. (criticizing "the hopeless artificiality of any example that presupposes universal ignorance of the value of any standard commodity" and arguing that "there is no sustainable equilibrium when the mistake in information is about a standardized product that everyone can test and use").
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
41449108073
-
-
On the limits of learning, even by sophisticated decision makers in real world [situations] that involve high stakes and serious deliberation [,] see Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274.
-
On the limits of learning, even by sophisticated decision makers in "real world [situations] that involve high stakes and serious deliberation [,]" see Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
41449106493
-
-
See also Cade Massey & Richard H. Thaler, The Loser's Curse: Overconfidence vs. Market Efficiency in the National Football League Draft 3 (Mar. 15, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract- 697121) (documenting persistent bias in NFL draft picks and overestimation of the decision maker's abilities).
-
See also Cade Massey & Richard H. Thaler, The Loser's Curse: Overconfidence vs. Market Efficiency in the National Football League Draft 3 (Mar. 15, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract- 697121) (documenting persistent bias in NFL draft picks and overestimation of the decision maker's abilities).
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
41449104952
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
41449112564
-
-
However, nonstandardized products may share standardized features, and interpersonal learning about these features can be effective. Cf. id. at 120-21 (arguing that consumers will likewise share information about valuation mistakes even in situations involving nonstandardized products).
-
However, nonstandardized products may share standardized features, and interpersonal learning about these features can be effective. Cf. id. at 120-21 (arguing that consumers will likewise share information about valuation mistakes even in situations involving nonstandardized products).
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
41449093505
-
-
For another discussion of this issue, see Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer 15 (Oct. 4, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author).
-
For another discussion of this issue, see Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer 15 (Oct. 4, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author).
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
41449093903
-
-
Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 (Product risks and accident scenarios are very diverse; feedback from one mode of use or product application consequently may not be very useful in minimizing other kinds of harms.).
-
Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 ("Product risks and accident scenarios are very diverse; feedback from one mode of use or product application consequently may not be very useful in minimizing other kinds of harms.").
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
41449089217
-
-
For a similar discussion, see Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 14
-
For a similar discussion, see Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 14.
-
-
-
-
63
-
-
41449107844
-
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
41449109395
-
-
see also note 3, at, R]ational people take steps that on average reduce, not increase, the frequency and severity of their errors
-
see also Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, supra note 3, at 361 ("[R]ational people take steps that on average reduce, not increase, the frequency and severity of their errors,").
-
Second-Order Rationality, supra
, pp. 361
-
-
Epstein1
-
65
-
-
41449112152
-
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
-
-
-
-
66
-
-
41449098914
-
-
T]hey seek advice from friends, hire experts, attend classes, use MapQuest, and adopt rules of thumb or other tricks of the trade, see also, at
-
see also Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, supra note 3, at 361-62 ("[T]hey seek advice from friends, hire experts, attend classes, use MapQuest, and adopt rules of thumb or other tricks of the trade . . . ."),
-
Second-Order Rationality, supra note
, vol.3
, pp. 361-362
-
-
Epstein1
-
67
-
-
41449117614
-
-
Many small mistakes can be as harmful as a few large mistakes. Credit card borrowing provides an example. See TERESA A. SULLIVAN ET AL., AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS: BANKRUPTCY AND CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA 178 (1989);
-
Many small mistakes can be as harmful as a few large mistakes. Credit card borrowing provides an example. See TERESA A. SULLIVAN ET AL., AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS: BANKRUPTCY AND CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA 178 (1989);
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
41449086073
-
-
describing how consumers make multiple small mistakes that equal a large mistake they would never make at once, Consumers make mistakes even when the decision is a big one. For example, many consumers take on subprime mortgage loans that they cannot repay, at
-
Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1399 (describing how consumers make multiple small mistakes that equal a large mistake they would never make at once). Consumers make mistakes even when the decision is a big one. For example, many consumers take on subprime mortgage loans that they cannot repay.
-
Seduction by Plastic, supra note
, vol.2
, pp. 1399
-
-
Bar-Gill1
-
69
-
-
41449109037
-
-
See, e.g., James H. Carr & Lopa Kolluri, Predatory Lending: An Overview, in FANNIE MAE FOUNDATION, FINANCIAL SERVICES IN DISTRESSED COMMUNITIES: ISSUES AND ANSWERS 31, 37 (2001) (noting that individuals who would otherwise qualify for prime-rate loans nevertheless signed up for high-interest, subprime loans);
-
See, e.g., James H. Carr & Lopa Kolluri, Predatory Lending: An Overview, in FANNIE MAE FOUNDATION, FINANCIAL SERVICES IN DISTRESSED COMMUNITIES: ISSUES AND ANSWERS 31, 37 (2001) (noting that individuals who would otherwise qualify for prime-rate loans nevertheless signed up for high-interest, subprime loans);
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
55349147804
-
Decisionmaking and the Limits of Disclosure: The Problem of Predatory Lending: Price, 65
-
summarizing studies that show foreclosure rates ranging between 20% and 30, see also
-
see also Lauren E. Willis, Decisionmaking and the Limits of Disclosure: The Problem of Predatory Lending: Price, 65 MD. L. REV. 707, 731-32 (2006) (summarizing studies that show foreclosure rates ranging between 20% and 30%).
-
(2006)
MD. L. REV
, vol.707
, pp. 731-732
-
-
Willis, L.E.1
-
71
-
-
41449099092
-
-
arguing that in a situation in which misinformed consumers underestimate the value of a product, the market will cease unless at least one seller attempts to correct the misinformation, See, at
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note I, at 119-20 (arguing that in a situation in which misinformed consumers underestimate the value of a product, the market will cease unless at least one seller attempts to correct the misinformation).
-
Behavioral Economics, supra note
, vol.1
, pp. 119-120
-
-
Epstein1
-
72
-
-
41449102214
-
-
Cf. Howard Beales et al., The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information, 24 J.L. & ECON. 491, 527 (1981) (describing the lack of an incentive to disclose information if competitors will benefit as free-riders);
-
Cf. Howard Beales et al., The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information, 24 J.L. & ECON. 491, 527 (1981) (describing the lack of an incentive to disclose information if competitors will benefit as free-riders);
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
41449099092
-
-
noting the possibility that no seller will invest in correcting consumers' misperceptions if other sellers will subsequently benefit without expending any resources, at
-
Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 119-20 (noting the possibility that no seller will invest in correcting consumers' misperceptions if other sellers will subsequently benefit without expending any resources).
-
Behavioral Economics, supra note
, vol.1
, pp. 119-120
-
-
Epstein1
-
74
-
-
41449105533
-
-
See Beales et al, supra note 45, at 527 (explaining why sellers might not disclose both positive and negative information);
-
See Beales et al., supra note 45, at 527 (explaining why sellers might not disclose both positive and negative information);
-
-
-
-
75
-
-
0347305939
-
-
see also R. Ted Cruz & Jeffrey J. Hinck, Not My Brother's Keeper: The Inability of an Informed Minority to Correct for Imperfect Information, 47 HASTINGS L.J. 635, 659 (1996) (detailing reasons why sellers lack incentive to inform consumers). In some markets, the advantage gained by moving first may be large enough to overcome this collective action problem.
-
see also R. Ted Cruz & Jeffrey J. Hinck, Not My Brother's Keeper: The Inability of an Informed Minority to Correct for Imperfect Information, 47 HASTINGS L.J. 635, 659 (1996) (detailing reasons why sellers lack incentive to inform consumers). In some markets, the advantage gained by moving first may be large enough to overcome this collective action problem.
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
41449096772
-
-
For a general discussion of information failures in consumer markets, see Beales et al., supra note 45, at 503-09.
-
For a general discussion of information failures in consumer markets, see Beales et al., supra note 45, at 503-09.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
33646375435
-
-
On the limits of advertising as a mistake-correction mechanism, see Xavier Gabaix & David Laibson, Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets, 121 Q.J. ECON. 505, 507-10 (2006) (describing how truthful advertising to misinformed consumers does not always increase profitability);
-
On the limits of advertising as a mistake-correction mechanism, see Xavier Gabaix & David Laibson, Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets, 121 Q.J. ECON. 505, 507-10 (2006) (describing how truthful advertising to misinformed consumers does not always increase profitability);
-
-
-
-
78
-
-
0742271634
-
Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70
-
arguing that the costs of changing the way buyers shop will outweigh the small value that marketing is likely to achieve
-
Russell Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1203, 1242-43 (2003) (arguing that the costs of changing the way buyers shop will outweigh the small value that marketing is likely to achieve).
-
(2003)
U. CHI. L. REV
, vol.1203
, pp. 1242-1243
-
-
Korobkin, R.1
-
79
-
-
41449111028
-
-
In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein appears to retract his acknowledgment of the collective action problem, at
-
Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120. In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein appears to retract his acknowledgment of the collective action problem.
-
Behavioral Economics, supra note
, vol.1
, pp. 120
-
-
Epstein1
-
80
-
-
41449095371
-
-
See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 818-19. Using a five-seller example, he argues that [i]f there is only a 50% chance that any one of these [sellers] will deviate from the cooperative mode [i.e., form the low quality equilibrium], then the odds are only 1 in 32 that the collusive equilibrium will stick.
-
See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 818-19. Using a five-seller example, he argues that "[i]f there is only a 50% chance that any one of these [sellers] will deviate from the cooperative mode [i.e., form the low quality equilibrium], then the odds are only 1 in 32 that the collusive equilibrium will stick."
-
-
-
-
81
-
-
41449084762
-
But the odds are not 50%. The collective action problem implies a zero probability of deviation, which
-
Id. But the odds are not 50%. The collective action problem implies a zero probability of deviation, which, in turn, implies a 100% chance that the low quality equilibrium will stick. Of course, as described below, a sufficiently strong first-mover advantage, together with branding and product differentiation, can solve the collective action problem. The question - and this is an empirical one - is in what markets are these correcting forces sufficiently strong?
-
turn, implies a 100% chance that the low quality equilibrium will stick. Of course, as described below, a sufficiently strong first-mover advantage, together with branding and product differentiation, can solve the collective action problem. The question - and this is an empirical one - is in what markets are these correcting forces sufficiently strong
-
-
Epstein1
-
83
-
-
77951963656
-
Toward a New Model of Consumer Protection: The Problem of Inflated Transaction Costs, 47
-
noting reasons why sellers do not advertise terms that consumers would like to know
-
Jeff Sovern, Toward a New Model of Consumer Protection: The Problem of Inflated Transaction Costs, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1635, 1680-81 (2006) (noting reasons why sellers do not advertise terms that consumers would like to know);
-
(2006)
WM. & MARY L. REV
, vol.1635
, pp. 1680-1681
-
-
Sovern, J.1
-
84
-
-
41449105141
-
-
see also Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: A Response to Market Manipulation, 6 ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 259, 336-37 (2000) (describing the possible effects of a manufacturer's effort to educate consumers on product safety, including a reduction in the overall demand for the product).
-
see also Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: A Response to Market Manipulation, 6 ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 259, 336-37 (2000) (describing the possible effects of a manufacturer's effort to educate consumers on product safety, including a reduction in the overall demand for the product).
-
-
-
-
86
-
-
4043058651
-
-
See Edward L. Glaeser, Psychology and the Market, 94 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 408, 409-11 (2004) (Markets do not eliminate (and often exacerbate) irrationality . . . . The advertising industry is the most important economic example of these systematic attempts to mislead, where suppliers attempt to convince buyers that their products will yield remarkable benefits. . . . It is certainly not true that competition ensures that false beliefs will be dissipated. Indeed, in many cases competition will work to increase the supply of these falsehoods . . . .).
-
See Edward L. Glaeser, Psychology and the Market, 94 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 408, 409-11 (2004) ("Markets do not eliminate (and often exacerbate) irrationality . . . . The advertising industry is the most important economic example of these systematic attempts to mislead, where suppliers attempt to convince buyers that their products will yield remarkable benefits. . . . It is certainly not true that competition ensures that false beliefs will be dissipated. Indeed, in many cases competition will work to increase the supply of these falsehoods . . . .").
-
-
-
-
87
-
-
33645781946
-
-
Glaeser argues, however, that government decision makers have weaker incentives than consumers to overcome errors, and thus intervention in markets might make things worse. See Edward L. Glaeser, Paternalism and Psychology, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 133, 143-44 (2006).
-
Glaeser argues, however, that government decision makers have weaker incentives than consumers to overcome errors, and thus intervention in markets might make things worse. See Edward L. Glaeser, Paternalism and Psychology, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 133, 143-44 (2006).
-
-
-
-
88
-
-
41449095463
-
-
The evidence summarized is drawn from the synthesis of existing studies that focus on borrowing behavior in Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 19-33. In addition, experimental evidence suggests that credit cards affect spending behavior.
-
The evidence summarized is drawn from the synthesis of existing studies that focus on borrowing behavior in Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 19-33. In addition, experimental evidence suggests that credit cards affect spending behavior.
-
-
-
-
89
-
-
0005536474
-
Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay, 12
-
discussing evidence that the method of payment, credit card or cash, affects people's willingness to pay, See
-
See Drazen Prelec & Duncan Simester, Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay, 12 MARKETING LETTERS 5, 11 (2001) (discussing evidence that the method of payment - credit card or cash - affects people's willingness to pay);
-
(2001)
MARKETING LETTERS
, vol.5
, pp. 11
-
-
Prelec, D.1
Simester, D.2
-
90
-
-
41449110516
-
-
see also GEORGE RITZER, EXPRESSING AMERICA: A CRITIQUE OF THE GLOBAL CREDIT CARD SOCIETY 5-7, 13 (1995);
-
see also GEORGE RITZER, EXPRESSING AMERICA: A CRITIQUE OF THE GLOBAL CREDIT CARD SOCIETY 5-7, 13 (1995);
-
-
-
-
91
-
-
0000415392
-
Credit Cards as Spending Facilitating Stimuli: A Conditioning Interpretation, 13
-
T]he presence of credit card stimuli enhances the magnitude of spending
-
Richard A. Feinberg, Credit Cards as Spending Facilitating Stimuli: A Conditioning Interpretation, 13 J. CONSUMER RES. 348, 354-55 (1986) ("[T]he presence of credit card stimuli enhances the magnitude of spending.");
-
(1986)
J. CONSUMER RES
, vol.348
, pp. 354-355
-
-
Feinberg, R.A.1
-
92
-
-
41449107265
-
-
Elizabeth C Hirschman, Differences in Consumer Purchase Behavior by Credit Card Payment System, 6 J. CONSUMER RES. 58, 64-65 (1979) ([P]ossession of a bank card or store-issued card appears to be positively related to higher levels of in-store expenditures and to a greater incidence of in-store purchasing.);
-
Elizabeth C Hirschman, Differences in Consumer Purchase Behavior by Credit Card Payment System, 6 J. CONSUMER RES. 58, 64-65 (1979) ("[P]ossession of a bank card or store-issued card appears to be positively related to higher levels of in-store expenditures and to a greater incidence of in-store purchasing.");
-
-
-
-
93
-
-
0030494605
-
-
Michael McCall & Heather J. Belmont, Credit Card Insignia and Restaurant Tipping: Evidence for an Associative Link, 81 J. APPLIED PSYCHOL. 609, 612-13 (1996) (showing evidence of increased tipping by consumers using credit cards instead of cash);
-
Michael McCall & Heather J. Belmont, Credit Card Insignia and Restaurant Tipping: Evidence for an Associative Link, 81 J. APPLIED PSYCHOL. 609, 612-13 (1996) (showing evidence of increased tipping by consumers using credit cards instead of cash);
-
-
-
-
94
-
-
0035531896
-
Effects of Payment Mechanism on Spending Behavior: The Role of Rehearsal and Immediacy of Payments, 27
-
showing that consumers paying by credit cards are more likely to make additional discretionary purchases
-
Dilip Soman, Effects of Payment Mechanism on Spending Behavior: The Role of Rehearsal and Immediacy of Payments, 27 J. CONSUMER RES. 460, 472-74 (2001) (showing that consumers paying by credit cards are more likely to make additional discretionary purchases).
-
(2001)
J. CONSUMER RES
, vol.460
, pp. 472-474
-
-
Soman, D.1
-
95
-
-
41449118483
-
-
See Haiyan Shui & Lawrence M. Ausubel, Time Inconsistency in the Credit Card Market 2-3 (May 3, 2004) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=586622).
-
See Haiyan Shui & Lawrence M. Ausubel, Time Inconsistency in the Credit Card Market 2-3 (May 3, 2004) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=586622).
-
-
-
-
96
-
-
41449097564
-
-
Id. at 3
-
Id. at 3.
-
-
-
-
97
-
-
41449099888
-
-
The evidence shows that most consumers do not jump from one card to another and from one teaser rate to another. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1392;
-
The evidence shows that most consumers do not jump from one card to another and from one teaser rate to another. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1392;
-
-
-
-
98
-
-
41449099091
-
-
see also infra Part III.B.1. But detailed statistics are not necessary to conclude that consumers do not jump from one teaser rate to another; it is evident from the fact that issuers offer teaser rates. Unless issuers have decided to forgo interest revenues altogether issuers would not offer teaser rates if most consumers did not stay beyond the introductory period. And it is clear that most issuers have not decided to forgo interest revenues altogether. In fact, in 2006 interest revenues represented 65% of issuers' total revenues.
-
see also infra Part III.B.1. But detailed statistics are not necessary to conclude that consumers do not jump from one teaser rate to another; it is evident from the fact that issuers offer teaser rates. Unless issuers have decided to forgo interest revenues altogether issuers would not offer teaser rates if most consumers did not stay beyond the introductory period. And it is clear that most issuers have not decided to forgo interest revenues altogether. In fact, in 2006 interest revenues represented 65% of issuers' total revenues.
-
-
-
-
99
-
-
41449117438
-
-
Cf. CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY 11 (Sandra L. Budde ed., 19th ed. 2007) (listing interest revenues as $75.15 billion and issuers' total revenues as $114.99 billion).
-
Cf. CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY 11 (Sandra L. Budde ed., 19th ed. 2007) (listing interest revenues as $75.15 billion and issuers' total revenues as $114.99 billion).
-
-
-
-
100
-
-
41449089603
-
-
Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 3 n.4.
-
Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 3 n.4.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
41449087157
-
-
In the Shui & Ausubel study, the introductory rates were between 4.9% and 7.9, while the post-introductory rate was 16, Id. at 2, 7
-
In the Shui & Ausubel study, the introductory rates were between 4.9% and 7.9%, while the post-introductory rate was 16%. Id. at 2, 7.
-
-
-
-
102
-
-
41449088338
-
-
Id. at 8
-
Id. at 8.
-
-
-
-
103
-
-
41449114389
-
-
Id. at 2-3
-
Id. at 2-3.
-
-
-
-
104
-
-
41449108669
-
-
Id. at 8
-
Id. at 8.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
41449101355
-
-
Id. at 7
-
Id. at 7.
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
41449117898
-
-
Note that all the credit cards had a post-introductory rate of 16%, though the point at which this rate began differed. Id.
-
Note that all the credit cards had a post-introductory rate of 16%, though the point at which this rate began differed. Id.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
41449095462
-
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 824. But most consumers do not time the acquisition of a new card with large expenditures. Epstein's hypothesis is inconsistent with the data that most borrowing is done at the high post-introductory rates.
-
Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 824. But most consumers do not time the acquisition of a new card with large expenditures. Epstein's hypothesis is inconsistent with the data that most borrowing is done at the high post-introductory rates.
-
-
-
-
110
-
-
41449113887
-
-
see also Lawrence M. Ausubel, Credit Card Defaults, Credit Card Profits, and Bankruptcy, 71 AM. BANKR. L.J. 249, 263 (1997) ([A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . .).
-
see also Lawrence M. Ausubel, Credit Card Defaults, Credit Card Profits, and Bankruptcy, 71 AM. BANKR. L.J. 249, 263 (1997) ("[A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . .").
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
41449090761
-
-
See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7
-
See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7.
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
41449100076
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
114
-
-
0344540194
-
Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data, 117
-
See
-
See David B. Gross & Nicholas S. Souleles, Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data, 117 Q.J. ECON. 149 (2002).
-
(2002)
Q.J. ECON
, vol.149
-
-
Gross, D.B.1
Souleles, N.S.2
-
115
-
-
41449103904
-
-
Id. at 180
-
Id. at 180.
-
-
-
-
116
-
-
41449118097
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
117
-
-
41449118101
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
118
-
-
41449104096
-
-
See Stephan Meier & Charles Sprenger, Impatience and Credit Behavior: Evidence from a Field Experiment (Fed. Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper No. 07-03, 2007), available at http://www.bos.frb.org/ economic/wp/wp2007/wp0703.pdf.
-
See Stephan Meier & Charles Sprenger, Impatience and Credit Behavior: Evidence from a Field Experiment (Fed. Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper No. 07-03, 2007), available at http://www.bos.frb.org/ economic/wp/wp2007/wp0703.pdf.
-
-
-
-
119
-
-
41449101557
-
-
Id. at 5
-
Id. at 5.
-
-
-
-
121
-
-
41449110141
-
-
Id. at 2-3
-
Id. at 2-3.
-
-
-
-
125
-
-
41449108484
-
-
see also infra note 74. A different critique, not mentioned by Epstein, argues that sellers will not respond to consumer mistakes as long as there are enough consumers that do not make these mistakes.
-
see also infra note 74. A different critique, not mentioned by Epstein, argues that sellers will not respond to consumer mistakes as long as there are enough consumers that do not make these mistakes.
-
-
-
-
126
-
-
41449091312
-
-
See Alan Schwartz & Louis L. Wilde, Intervening in Markets on the Basis of Imperfect Information: A Legal and Economic Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 630, 638-39 (1979) (providing this informed minority argument for the first time in legal and economic literature). This argument does not apply when sellers can screen for sophisticated consumers. And, of course, it is not at all clear that there is a sufficiently large number of sophisticated, informed buyers in all markets.
-
See Alan Schwartz & Louis L. Wilde, Intervening in Markets on the Basis of Imperfect Information: A Legal and Economic Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 630, 638-39 (1979) (providing this "informed minority" argument for the first time in legal and economic literature). This argument does not apply when sellers can screen for sophisticated consumers. And, of course, it is not at all clear that there is a sufficiently large number of sophisticated, informed buyers in all markets.
-
-
-
-
127
-
-
41449105138
-
-
See Sovern, supra note 49, at 1668-72 and sources cited therein.
-
See Sovern, supra note 49, at 1668-72 and sources cited therein.
-
-
-
-
128
-
-
41449111028
-
-
Epstein's critique focuses on my theory of misperception-based bundling. See, at
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120-22. Epstein's critique focuses on my theory of misperception-based bundling.
-
Behavioral Economics, supra note
, vol.1
, pp. 120-122
-
-
Epstein1
-
129
-
-
41449099090
-
-
Id. at 120-21 & n.28 [B]ecause 'sellers get the same total price under [different] pricing schemes,' they will rationally choose to give the tying product away for free and charge above the marginal cost for the tied product to offset losses.
-
Id. at 120-21 & n.28 ("[B]ecause 'sellers get the same total price under [different] pricing schemes,' they will rationally choose to give the tying product away for free and charge above the marginal cost for the tied product to offset losses."
-
-
-
-
132
-
-
41449103713
-
-
Epstein makes another argument that is specific to the bundling response that I study in Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, supra note 2, at 34-35. In that paper I discuss the example of home printing and show that when consumers underestimate the amount of printing that they will do, sellers will bundle together printers and ink, give away printers for free, and set a high price for ink.
-
Epstein makes another argument that is specific to the bundling response that I study in Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, supra note 2, at 34-35. In that paper I discuss the example of home printing and show that when consumers underestimate the amount of printing that they will do, sellers will bundle together printers and ink, give away printers for free, and set a high price for ink.
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
41449118658
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
134
-
-
41449086597
-
-
Epstein argues that this strategy is vulnerable to exploitation by savvy consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121. These savvy consumers will take two free printers from two different suppliers and play each supplier against the other, reducing the price of ink to its unit cost.
-
Epstein argues that this strategy is vulnerable to exploitation by savvy consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121. These savvy consumers will take two free printers from two different suppliers and play each supplier against the other, reducing the price of ink to its unit cost.
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
41449089417
-
First, it is not clear that there are enough savvy consumers to "break" the free printer/expensive ink equilibrium. Second, the savvy consumers will not affect the identified equilibrium, if sellers can screen for them
-
it is not an argument that printers are priced at cost. The main goal of my analysis was to show that printers will be sold below cost while ink will be sold above cost
-
Id. First, it is not clear that there are enough savvy consumers to "break" the free printer/expensive ink equilibrium. Second, the savvy consumers will not affect the identified equilibrium, if sellers can screen for them. Third, Epstein's argument explains why printers are not free; it is not an argument that printers are priced at cost. The main goal of my analysis was to show that printers will be sold below cost while ink will be sold above cost.
-
Third, Epstein's argument explains why printers are not free
-
-
-
138
-
-
41449083056
-
-
See id. (stating that since some consumers are optimistic while others are pessimistic it may well be that the best strategy is to ignore these biases altogether).
-
See id. (stating that since some consumers are optimistic while others are pessimistic "it may well be that the best strategy is to ignore these biases altogether").
-
-
-
-
139
-
-
41449111595
-
-
If market segmentation based on the level or type of misperception is possible, then sellers will design their products and pricing schemes in response to consumer misperception even when the average bias is zero. In particular, sellers will offer one product design to the overestimators and another product design to the underestimators. Epstein does not consider the segmentation option. Id. He implicitly dismisses it by arguing that no consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level].
-
If market segmentation based on the level or type of misperception is possible, then sellers will design their products and pricing schemes in response to consumer misperception even when the average bias is zero. In particular, sellers will offer one product design to the overestimators and another product design to the underestimators. Epstein does not consider the segmentation option. Id. He implicitly dismisses it by arguing that "no consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level]."
-
-
-
-
141
-
-
41449106880
-
-
Id. at 130
-
Id. at 130.
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
41449106296
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
143
-
-
41449092548
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
144
-
-
41449117434
-
-
Id. at n.58 (citing evidence of fifteen- and thirty-year fixed-rate prime mortgage loans).
-
Id. at n.58 (citing evidence of fifteen- and thirty-year fixed-rate prime mortgage loans).
-
-
-
-
145
-
-
41449088139
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
146
-
-
41449104095
-
-
See Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 29-30
-
See Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 29-30.
-
-
-
-
148
-
-
41449116943
-
-
This is not an easy task. Most design features that appear to respond to consumer misperception can also be rationalized using alternative theories which cannot be rejected in the abstract. Only a market-specific inquiry can determine the source of the identified product and price design. I conducted such an inquiry in the credit card market. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2
-
This is not an easy task. Most design features that appear to respond to consumer misperception can also be rationalized using alternative theories which cannot be rejected in the abstract. Only a market-specific inquiry can determine the source of the identified product and price design. I conducted such an inquiry in the credit card market. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2.
-
-
-
-
149
-
-
41449084231
-
-
The evidence suggests that rational choice theories cannot explain the observed pricing scheme in that market. I therefore concluded that the observed pricing scheme was designed in response to systematic consumer misperception. See id. at 1408-11
-
The evidence suggests that rational choice theories cannot explain the observed pricing scheme in that market. I therefore concluded that the observed pricing scheme was designed in response to systematic consumer misperception. See id. at 1408-11.
-
-
-
-
150
-
-
41449117229
-
-
The assumption, of course, is that the misperceived value is higher than the cost. Epstein analyzes an example of a one-dimensional product and a one-dimensional price and reaches the same conclusion. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120
-
The assumption, of course, is that the misperceived value is higher than the cost. Epstein analyzes an example of a one-dimensional product and a one-dimensional price and reaches the same conclusion. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120.
-
-
-
-
151
-
-
41449099483
-
-
See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 2-3
-
See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 2-3.
-
-
-
-
152
-
-
41449090166
-
-
Id. at 13
-
Id. at 13.
-
-
-
-
153
-
-
44949249561
-
-
See note 49, at, O]nly a handful of consumers obtain rebates
-
See Sovern, supra note 49, at 1638 ("[O]nly a handful of consumers obtain rebates . . . .").
-
supra
, pp. 1638
-
-
Sovern1
-
154
-
-
41449117897
-
-
See id. at 1639 (Manufacturers apparently employ rebates chiefly because they increase sales by creating an illusion of a lower price, while the transaction costs generated by rebate offers permit manufacturers effectively to charge the unrebated price to most consumers.).
-
See id. at 1639 ("Manufacturers apparently employ rebates chiefly because they increase sales by creating an illusion of a lower price, while the transaction costs generated by rebate offers permit manufacturers effectively to charge the unrebated price to most consumers.").
-
-
-
-
155
-
-
41449090565
-
-
An alternative explanation for rebates, which does not rely on consumer misperception, views rebates as a mechanism for price discrimination. See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 40 noting that rebates can be used to charge some customers more than others because, for instance, wealthier consumers may be less likely to turn in the rebate
-
An alternative explanation for rebates, which does not rely on consumer misperception, views rebates as a mechanism for price discrimination. See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 40 (noting that rebates can be used to charge some customers more than others because, for instance, wealthier consumers may be less likely to turn in the rebate
-
-
-
-
156
-
-
25144435947
-
Price Discrimination After the Purchase: Rebates as State-Dependent Discounts, 51
-
This alternative explanation is plausible in some markets and less plausible in others, citing
-
(citing Yuxin Chen et al., Price Discrimination After the Purchase: Rebates as State-Dependent Discounts, 51 MGMT. SCI. 1131, 1131 (2005))). This alternative explanation is plausible in some markets and less plausible in others.
-
(2005)
MGMT. SCI
, vol.1131
, pp. 1131
-
-
Chen, Y.1
-
157
-
-
41449099287
-
-
Late payment may impose an extra cost on the issuer, but this cost surely does not amount to $40 or more for a two-day delay in making a minimum payment of $40
-
Late payment may impose an extra cost on the issuer, but this cost surely does not amount to $40 or more for a two-day delay in making a minimum payment of $40.
-
-
-
-
158
-
-
41449083443
-
-
See infra Part II.C. As with rebates, there is an alternative, rational choice explanation for late fees: if consumers with higher default risk are more likely to pay late (before defaulting), then late fees provide a screening mechanism that can prevent a lemons problem. While theoretically valid, the practical explanatory power of this rational choice account is limited. First, it relies on the assumption that borrowers have superior information about their default risk. This assumption is questionable given issuers' sophisticated risk assessment methods.
-
See infra Part II.C. As with rebates, there is an alternative, rational choice explanation for late fees: if consumers with higher default risk are more likely to pay late (before defaulting), then late fees provide a screening mechanism that can prevent a "lemons" problem. While theoretically valid, the practical explanatory power of this rational choice account is limited. First, it relies on the assumption that borrowers have superior information about their default risk. This assumption is questionable given issuers' sophisticated risk assessment methods.
-
-
-
-
159
-
-
41449107648
-
-
See, e.g., DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC 105-07 (2d ed. 2005). Second, the rational choice/asymmetric information theory assumes that late payment provides valuable, new information to the uninformed issuers - again a questionable assumption.
-
See, e.g., DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC 105-07 (2d ed. 2005). Second, the rational choice/asymmetric information theory assumes that late payment provides valuable, new information to the uninformed issuers - again a questionable assumption.
-
-
-
-
160
-
-
41449106297
-
-
See, e.g., RONALD J. MANN, CHARGING AHEAD 161-63 (2006) (stating that late fees are often incurred because of mistakes, but that these late payments provide no new information on the consumer's default risk). Finally, the data do not support this rational choice account. If issuers wish to screen for high risk borrowers, they have other means at their disposal.
-
See, e.g., RONALD J. MANN, CHARGING AHEAD 161-63 (2006) (stating that late fees are often incurred because of mistakes, but that these late payments provide no new information on the consumer's default risk). Finally, the data do not support this rational choice account. If issuers wish to screen for high risk borrowers, they have other means at their disposal.
-
-
-
-
161
-
-
41449110869
-
-
For example, they can use default interest rates triggered by late payment. Indeed, since such default rates are commonly used, why are late fees needed? Specifically, why did late fees rise substantially after they were exempt from state-level regulation by the Supreme Court's Smiley v. Citibank decision in 1996? 517 U.S. 735 (1996) (finding that credit card fees could be defined as interest for regulatory purposes);
-
For example, they can use default interest rates triggered by late payment. Indeed, since such default rates are commonly used, why are late fees needed? Specifically, why did late fees rise substantially after they were exempt from state-level regulation by the Supreme Court's Smiley v. Citibank decision in 1996? 517 U.S. 735 (1996) (finding that credit card fees could be defined as "interest" for regulatory purposes);
-
-
-
-
162
-
-
41449094996
-
-
see also TAMARA DRAUT & JAVIER SILVA, BORROWING TO MAKE ENDS MEET: THE GROWTH OF CREDIT CARD DEBT IN THE '90S, at 35 (2003), available at http://www.demos.org/pubs/ borrowing_to_make_ends_meet.pdf (discussing the increase in fee usage after Smiley).
-
see also TAMARA DRAUT & JAVIER SILVA, BORROWING TO MAKE ENDS MEET: THE GROWTH OF CREDIT CARD DEBT IN THE '90S, at 35 (2003), available at http://www.demos.org/pubs/ borrowing_to_make_ends_meet.pdf (discussing the increase in fee usage after Smiley).
-
-
-
-
163
-
-
41449096386
-
-
The rise of late fees after Smiley would make sense under the rational choice model if default interest rates triggered by late payment where reduced, but they were not. See Mark Furletti, Credit Card Pricing Developments and Their Disclosure 8 (Fed. Reserve Bank of Phila., Discussion Paper 03-02, 2003), available at http://www.philadelphiafed.org/pcc/ papers/2003/CreditCardPricing_012003.pdf (stating that issuers only started using default interest rates in the late 1990s).
-
The rise of late fees after Smiley would make sense under the rational choice model if default interest rates triggered by late payment where reduced, but they were not. See Mark Furletti, Credit Card Pricing Developments and Their Disclosure 8 (Fed. Reserve Bank of Phila., Discussion Paper 03-02, 2003), available at http://www.philadelphiafed.org/pcc/ papers/2003/CreditCardPricing_012003.pdf (stating that issuers only started using default interest rates in the late 1990s).
-
-
-
-
164
-
-
0001881029
-
The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 81
-
See
-
See Lawrence M. Ausubel, The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 81 AM. ECON. REV. 50, 72 (1991).
-
(1991)
AM. ECON. REV
, vol.50
, pp. 72
-
-
Ausubel, L.M.1
-
165
-
-
41449096958
-
-
Part ILC
-
See infra Part ILC.
-
See infra
-
-
-
166
-
-
41449113171
-
-
See infra Part II.C.
-
See infra Part II.C.
-
-
-
-
168
-
-
41449087771
-
-
The following example is taken from id. at 38-39.
-
The following example is taken from id. at 38-39.
-
-
-
-
169
-
-
41449106491
-
-
Id. at 45;
-
Id. at 45;
-
-
-
-
170
-
-
41449104764
-
-
see also Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 21
-
see also Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 21.
-
-
-
-
171
-
-
41449116743
-
-
This pricing flexibility requires that ink for a seller's printer be purchased only from the same seller. This is in fact the meaning of bundling. Such bundling can be achieved through patent protection of the printer-ink cartridge interface. A recent threat to the printer and ink bundle comes from sellers offering to refill consumers' ink cartridges. But the refill option is still limited. Questions about the quality, reliability, and ease of operation of the refill option remain. See, e.g, ConsumerReports.org, Do-It-Yourself Refills Are Cheap, But Be Prepared for a Mess, July 2006
-
This pricing flexibility requires that ink for a seller's printer be purchased only from the same seller. This is in fact the meaning of bundling. Such bundling can be achieved through patent protection of the printer-ink cartridge interface. A recent threat to the printer and ink bundle comes from sellers offering to refill consumers' ink cartridges. But the refill option is still limited. Questions about the quality, reliability, and ease of operation of the refill option remain. See, e.g., ConsumerReports.org, Do-It-Yourself Refills Are Cheap, But Be Prepared for a Mess, July 2006, http://www.consumerreports .org/cro/electronics-computers/computers/computer/ printers/printer-inks-7-06/do-it-yourself-refills/0607_printer-inks_do-it- yourself-refills.htm;
-
-
-
-
172
-
-
41449111420
-
-
ConsumerReports.org, Printer Inks: More Choice & Value, July 2006, http://www.consumerreports.org/cro/electronics-computers/computers/ computer/printers/printer-inks-7-06/overview/0607_printer-inks_ov.htm. But more sophisticated and effective ink refill options are emerging.
-
ConsumerReports.org, Printer Inks: More Choice & Value, July 2006, http://www.consumerreports.org/cro/electronics-computers/computers/ computer/printers/printer-inks-7-06/overview/0607_printer-inks_ov.htm. But more sophisticated and effective ink refill options are emerging.
-
-
-
-
173
-
-
41449102589
-
-
See, e.g., Tom Mainelli, Inke Unveils Clean, Cheap Ink Jet Refills, PC WORLD, Jan. 8, 2006, http://www.pcworld.com/article/id,114170- page,1/article.html. Printer manufacturers, in an effort to sustain using the bundle, are trying to convince consumers that the refill option is inferior.
-
See, e.g., Tom Mainelli, Inke Unveils Clean, Cheap Ink Jet Refills, PC WORLD, Jan. 8, 2006, http://www.pcworld.com/article/id,114170- page,1/article.html. Printer manufacturers, in an effort to sustain using the bundle, are trying to convince consumers that the refill option is inferior.
-
-
-
-
174
-
-
41449110868
-
-
For example, the HP website refers to a commissioned study finding that ink cartridges score lower on both quality and reliability. See HP, The Truth About Ink Refills and Remanufactured Ink, http://h71036.www7.hp.com/hho/ cache/546038-0-0-225-121.html?jumpid-reg_ R1002_USEN (last visited Nov. 30, 2007)
-
For example, the HP website refers to a commissioned study finding that ink cartridges score lower on both quality and reliability. See HP, The Truth About Ink Refills and Remanufactured Ink, http://h71036.www7.hp.com/hho/ cache/546038-0-0-225-121.html?jumpid-reg_ R1002_USEN (last visited Nov. 30, 2007)
-
-
-
-
175
-
-
41449089074
-
-
(directing users to QUALITYLOGIC, RELIABILITY COMPARISON STUDY: HP INKJET PRINT CARTRIDGES VS. REFILLED BRANDS: CARTRIDGE RELIABILITY, PRINT QUALITY (2005), http://www.hp.com/united-states/consumer/inkjet/qualitylogic_study.pdf).
-
(directing users to QUALITYLOGIC, RELIABILITY COMPARISON STUDY: HP INKJET PRINT CARTRIDGES VS. REFILLED BRANDS: CARTRIDGE RELIABILITY, PRINT QUALITY (2005), http://www.hp.com/united-states/consumer/inkjet/qualitylogic_study.pdf).
-
-
-
-
176
-
-
41449098730
-
-
These efforts are at least partially successful, ink cartridge sales are a multibillion dollar business for HP, See John Lui, HP Holds Patent for Ink-Refill Device, ZDNET.CO.UK, Oct. 20, 2003, 1000000183,39117220,00.htm
-
These efforts are at least partially successful - ink cartridge sales are a multibillion dollar business for HP, See John Lui, HP Holds Patent for Ink-Refill Device, ZDNET.CO.UK, Oct. 20, 2003, http://news.zdnet.co.uk/emergingtech/0,1000000183,39117220,00.htm.
-
-
-
-
177
-
-
41449100629
-
-
In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein argues that there are sophisticated, business buyers of printers and ink and that less-sophisticated consumers free-ride off the expertise of these more-sophisticated buyers. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 830. Such free-riding is possible, however, only if sellers cannot segment the market and differentiate between the sophisticated business buyers and the less-sophisticated consumers. While further empirical investigation is necessary, casual observation suggests that the printers market is at least partially segmented.
-
In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein argues that there are sophisticated, business buyers of printers and ink and that less-sophisticated consumers free-ride off the expertise of these more-sophisticated buyers. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 830. Such free-riding is possible, however, only if sellers cannot segment the market and differentiate between the sophisticated business buyers and the less-sophisticated consumers. While further empirical investigation is necessary, casual observation suggests that the printers market is at least partially segmented.
-
-
-
-
178
-
-
33744548714
-
-
See Stefano Della Vigna & Ulrike Malmendier, Paying Not to Go to the Gym, 96 AM. ECON. REV. 694, 714 (2006) ([F]lat-rate contracts are on average more profitable for the health clubs than pay-per-visit contracts. Health club employees, therefore, have incentive to persuade consumers to sign flat-rate contracts.).
-
See Stefano Della Vigna & Ulrike Malmendier, Paying Not to Go to the Gym, 96 AM. ECON. REV. 694, 714 (2006) ("[F]lat-rate contracts are on average more profitable for the health clubs than pay-per-visit contracts. Health club employees, therefore, have incentive to persuade consumers to sign flat-rate contracts.").
-
-
-
-
179
-
-
41449097561
-
-
For evidence of the large disparity between the expected and the actual number of health club visits, see id
-
For evidence of the large disparity between the expected and the actual number of health club visits, see id.
-
-
-
-
180
-
-
41449102395
-
-
Cf. Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects § 2.3.1 (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 917785) ([F]irms are willing to price below cost in period 1 to acquire the customer who will become a valuable follow-on purchaser in period 2 . . . .).
-
Cf. Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects § 2.3.1 (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 917785) ("[F]irms are willing to price below cost in period 1 to acquire the customer who will become a valuable follow-on purchaser in period 2 . . . .").
-
-
-
-
181
-
-
41449096576
-
-
See, e.g, Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7-8
-
See, e.g., Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7-8.
-
-
-
-
182
-
-
41449113884
-
-
Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.4.5.
-
Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.4.5.
-
-
-
-
183
-
-
41449088336
-
-
See id. § 2.8.3.
-
See id. § 2.8.3.
-
-
-
-
184
-
-
41449099694
-
-
See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2
-
See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2.
-
-
-
-
185
-
-
41449114602
-
-
See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at xii, 164-67 ([Credit card issuers] have chosen to collect a larger portion of their revenues from finance charges. This pattern may arise in part because of their view that the overall demand for credit is relatively insensitive to interest rates, a view supported by at least one empirical study and considerable folklore within the industry.).
-
See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at xii, 164-67 ("[Credit card issuers] have chosen to collect a larger portion of their revenues from finance charges. This pattern may arise in part because of their view that the overall demand for credit is relatively insensitive to interest rates, a view supported by at least one empirical study and considerable folklore within the industry.").
-
-
-
-
186
-
-
41449117612
-
-
See Ausubel, supra note 95, at 72 ([T]he experience of credit card marketers is that consumers are much more sensitive to increases in the annual fee than to commensurate increases in the interest rate . . . .).
-
See Ausubel, supra note 95, at 72 ("[T]he experience
-
-
-
-
187
-
-
41449109394
-
-
See Bar-Gill, supra note 2, at 1401-02.
-
See Bar-Gill, supra note 2, at 1401-02.
-
-
-
-
188
-
-
41449104950
-
-
See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2-3
-
See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2-3.
-
-
-
-
189
-
-
41449086242
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
190
-
-
41449089981
-
-
See id. at 10-14.
-
See id. at 10-14.
-
-
-
-
191
-
-
41449108257
-
-
In Beasley v. Wells Fargo Bank, 1 Cal. Rptr. 2d 446 (Ct. App. 1991), the bank's Credit Card Task Force proposed increasing late and overlimit fees as a good source of revenue.
-
In Beasley v. Wells Fargo Bank, 1 Cal. Rptr. 2d 446 (Ct. App. 1991), the bank's "Credit Card Task Force" proposed increasing "late" and "overlimit" fees as a "good source of revenue."
-
-
-
-
192
-
-
41449101175
-
-
Id. at 448
-
Id. at 448.
-
-
-
-
193
-
-
41449104949
-
-
Penalty fees are perceived as a good source of revenue, because the industry perceives that there (are) very few cardholders that switch cards because the late fee is too high. Credit Card Fees Soar Again, CNNMONEY.COM, Aug. 18, 1998, http://money.cnn.com/1998/08/18/banking/ q_bankrate (quoting Peter Davidson, Executive Vice President, Speer & Associates) (internal quotation marks omitted).
-
Penalty fees are perceived as a good source of revenue, because the industry perceives that "there (are) very few cardholders that switch cards because the late fee is too high." Credit Card Fees Soar Again, CNNMONEY.COM, Aug. 18, 1998, http://money.cnn.com/1998/08/18/banking/ q_bankrate (quoting Peter Davidson, Executive Vice President, Speer & Associates) (internal quotation marks omitted).
-
-
-
-
194
-
-
41449091862
-
-
See Fee Income, CARDFLASH, Jan. 10, 2007 (subscription-restricted Internet source, on file with the author).
-
See Fee Income, CARDFLASH, Jan. 10, 2007 (subscription-restricted Internet source, on file with the author).
-
-
-
-
195
-
-
41449086955
-
-
Penalty fees began their rapid growth in 1996 when the Supreme Court, in Smiley v. Citibank, 517 U.S. 735, 735 (1996), exempted late and over-limit fees from state-level regulation.
-
Penalty fees began their rapid growth in 1996 when the Supreme Court, in Smiley v. Citibank, 517 U.S. 735, 735 (1996), exempted late and over-limit fees from state-level regulation.
-
-
-
-
196
-
-
41449103551
-
-
See also DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35
-
See also DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35.
-
-
-
-
197
-
-
41449083244
-
-
See CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY, supra note 54, at 11
-
See CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY, supra note 54, at 11.
-
-
-
-
198
-
-
41449112563
-
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, CREDIT CARDS: INCREASED COMPLEXITY IN RATES AND FEES HEIGHTENS NEED FOR MORE EFFECTIVE DISCLOSURES TO CONSUMERS 49 (2006).
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, CREDIT CARDS: INCREASED COMPLEXITY IN RATES AND FEES HEIGHTENS NEED FOR MORE EFFECTIVE DISCLOSURES TO CONSUMERS 49 (2006).
-
-
-
-
199
-
-
41449111967
-
-
See 2005 Credit Card Survey, CONSUMER ACTION NEWS (Consumer Action, San Francisco, Cal.) Summer 2005, at 1, available at http://www.consumer-action.org/downloads/english/ CC_Issue_2005.pdf (detailing the most prevalent triggers of universal default rate hikes).
-
See 2005 Credit Card Survey, CONSUMER ACTION NEWS (Consumer Action, San Francisco, Cal.) Summer 2005, at 1, available at http://www.consumer-action.org/downloads/english/ CC_Issue_2005.pdf (detailing the most prevalent triggers of universal default rate hikes).
-
-
-
-
200
-
-
41449097751
-
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 49-50
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 49-50.
-
-
-
-
201
-
-
41449098913
-
-
Compare Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1407 (describing how consumers underestimate the probability of paying late or exceeding their credit limit),
-
Compare Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1407 (describing how consumers underestimate "the probability of paying late or exceeding their credit limit"),
-
-
-
-
202
-
-
41449101839
-
-
with 2005 Credit Card Survey, supra note 121, at 1 (stating that paying late and going over the credit limit are important factors contributing to a universal default rate hike). Another recent innovation also magnifies the cost of penalty fees. Some issuers are dividing up credit extensions between multiple cards so that a customer with a $2500 credit limit will be issued five cards with five $500 limits (instead of a single card with a $2500 limit).
-
with 2005 Credit Card Survey, supra note 121, at 1 (stating that paying late and going over the credit limit are important factors contributing to a universal default rate hike). Another recent innovation also magnifies the cost of penalty fees. Some issuers are dividing up credit extensions between multiple cards so that a customer with a $2500 credit limit will be issued five cards with five $500 limits (instead of a single card with a $2500 limit).
-
-
-
-
203
-
-
33750852808
-
Five cards mean five opportunities to pay late fees, overlimit fees, etc. See Robert Berner, Cap One's Credit Trap
-
Nov. 6, at
-
Five cards mean five opportunities to pay late fees, overlimit fees, etc. See Robert Berner, Cap One's Credit Trap, BUS. WK., Nov. 6, 2006, at 35, 35.
-
(2006)
BUS. WK
-
-
-
204
-
-
41449084232
-
-
Epstein argues that introductory periods with low introductory rates are a reasonable mechanism for providing valuable information to rational consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129-31. In making this argument, Epstein relies on the free samples in a bakery analogy: So what is wrong with teaser rates anyhow? Go into any bakery and there are free samples that are intended to entice customers into purchases.
-
Epstein argues that introductory periods with low introductory rates are a reasonable mechanism for providing valuable information to rational consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129-31. In making this argument, Epstein relies on the free samples in a bakery analogy: "So what is wrong with teaser rates anyhow? Go into any bakery and there are free samples that are intended to entice customers into purchases."
-
-
-
-
205
-
-
41449106295
-
-
There is significant uncertainty about the quality of the baker's product. But money is money. Epstein himself argues that issuers are offering a standardized good
-
Id. at 131. This analogy is inapt. There is significant uncertainty about the quality of the baker's product. But money is money. Epstein himself argues that issuers are offering a standardized good.
-
at 131. This analogy is inapt
-
-
-
207
-
-
41449092066
-
-
See id. at 129-131. This is unconvincing, however, as survey evidence suggests that customer service is not among the product attributes that attract most consumers.
-
See id. at 129-131. This is unconvincing, however, as survey evidence suggests that customer service is not among the product attributes that attract most consumers.
-
-
-
-
208
-
-
41449093503
-
-
See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225
-
See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225.
-
-
-
-
210
-
-
41449103339
-
-
See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 263 ([A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . . Thus finance charges paid to credit card issuers have not dropped as much as the introductory offers might suggest.);
-
See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 263 ("[A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . . Thus finance charges paid to credit card issuers have not dropped as much as the introductory offers might suggest.");
-
-
-
-
211
-
-
41449085507
-
-
David I. Laibson et al., A Debt Puzzle, in KNOWLEDGE, INFORMATION, AND EXPECTATIONS IN MODERN MACRO-ECONOMICS: IN HONOR OF EDMUND S. PHELPS 228, 228-29 (Philippe Aghion et al. eds., 2003) (finding that consumers pay high effective interest rates [d]espite the rise of teaser interest rates).
-
David I. Laibson et al., A Debt Puzzle, in KNOWLEDGE, INFORMATION, AND EXPECTATIONS IN MODERN MACRO-ECONOMICS: IN HONOR OF EDMUND S. PHELPS 228, 228-29 (Philippe Aghion et al. eds., 2003) (finding that consumers pay high effective interest rates "[d]espite the rise of teaser interest rates").
-
-
-
-
212
-
-
41449117436
-
-
Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26
-
Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26.
-
-
-
-
213
-
-
41449096020
-
-
Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.8.3.
-
Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.8.3.
-
-
-
-
214
-
-
41449094653
-
-
Cf. Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1406 (describing how rational consumers would anticipate the lock-in effect, but that most consumers are not rational in this respect).
-
Cf. Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1406 (describing how rational consumers would anticipate the lock-in effect, but that most consumers are not rational in this respect).
-
-
-
-
215
-
-
41449110140
-
-
Id. at 1407
-
Id. at 1407.
-
-
-
-
216
-
-
41449116361
-
-
Id. at 1405-07.
-
Id. at 1405-07.
-
-
-
-
217
-
-
41449107457
-
-
Lawrence M. Ausubel, Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market 21 (June 17, 1999) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.ausubel .com/ere ditcard-papers/adverse.pdf).
-
Lawrence M. Ausubel, Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market 21 (June 17, 1999) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.ausubel .com/ere ditcard-papers/adverse.pdf).
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
41449087944
-
-
See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225
-
See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225.
-
-
-
-
219
-
-
41449104760
-
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 27 (noting how in most cases cardholder payments [are] allocated first to the balance that is assessed the lowest rate of interest).
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 27 (noting how in most cases "cardholder payments [are] allocated first to the balance that is assessed the lowest rate of interest").
-
-
-
-
222
-
-
41449105727
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
224
-
-
41449103342
-
-
See note 94, at, arguing that a causal link exists between credit card debt and bankruptcy filings
-
See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68 (arguing that a causal link exists between credit card debt and bankruptcy filings).
-
supra
, pp. 66-68
-
-
MANN1
-
225
-
-
41449109034
-
-
But see Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, 3 CHAP. L. REV. 79, 82, 166-70 (2000) (arguing that such a causal link does not exist).
-
But see Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, 3 CHAP. L. REV. 79, 82, 166-70 (2000) (arguing that such a causal link does not exist).
-
-
-
-
227
-
-
41449099883
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
228
-
-
41449110698
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
229
-
-
41449089414
-
-
Consumers who are perfectly informed and perfectly rational will take advantage of the available credit only when the benefit of credit exceeds the expected cost of credit, specifically, the costs of financial distress that might lead to bankruptcy
-
Consumers who are perfectly informed and perfectly rational will take advantage of the available credit only when the benefit of credit exceeds the expected cost of credit, specifically, the costs of financial distress that might lead to bankruptcy.
-
-
-
-
231
-
-
41449089215
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
232
-
-
41449089980
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
233
-
-
41449091864
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
234
-
-
41449100434
-
-
See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68
-
See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
-
-
-
-
235
-
-
41449092549
-
-
Cf. id. at 67 contrasting credit card debt with other types of consumer
-
Cf. id. at 67 (contrasting credit card debt with other types of consumer
-
-
-
-
236
-
-
41449084233
-
-
debt such as mortgages and loans
-
debt such as mortgages and loans).
-
-
-
-
238
-
-
41449116942
-
-
280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
-
280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
-
-
-
-
240
-
-
41449108072
-
-
Rossman, 280 F.3d at 387-89.
-
Rossman, 280 F.3d at 387-89.
-
-
-
-
241
-
-
41449113170
-
-
Id. at 394-95
-
Id. at 394-95.
-
-
-
-
243
-
-
41449111968
-
-
Id. at 127
-
Id. at 127.
-
-
-
-
244
-
-
41449114934
-
-
See id. at 126-27
-
See id. at 126-27
-
-
-
-
245
-
-
41449107071
-
-
(quoting Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388) (internal quotation marks omitted).
-
(quoting Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388) (internal quotation marks omitted).
-
-
-
-
246
-
-
41449087546
-
-
See id. at 127.
-
See id. at 127.
-
-
-
-
247
-
-
41449110515
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
248
-
-
41449086245
-
-
See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26
-
See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26.
-
-
-
-
249
-
-
41449104951
-
-
See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 171
-
See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 171.
-
-
-
-
251
-
-
41449111219
-
-
See id. (noting that most borrowing is done at high post-promotion rates rather than at low teaser rates).
-
See id. (noting that most borrowing is done at high post-promotion rates rather than at low teaser rates).
-
-
-
-
252
-
-
41449090760
-
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 127 (noting that because most people have multiple credit cards, an increase in rates on one card will likely generate a migration of business elsewhere).
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 127 (noting that because most people have multiple credit cards, an increase in rates on one card will likely generate a migration of business elsewhere).
-
-
-
-
253
-
-
41449117433
-
-
Banks, self-interest is a powerful market constraint against excessive borrowing
-
See id. ("[Banks'] self-interest is a powerful market constraint against excessive borrowing.").
-
See id
-
-
-
255
-
-
41449088136
-
-
See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57 analyzing bankruptcy data alongside credit card delinquency and credit card chargeoff data
-
See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57 (analyzing bankruptcy data alongside credit card delinquency and credit card chargeoff data).
-
-
-
-
256
-
-
41449111220
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
257
-
-
33947201787
-
-
See Ronald J. Mann, Bankruptcy Reform and the Sweat Box of Credit Card Debt, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 375, 386-90.
-
See Ronald J. Mann, Bankruptcy Reform and the "Sweat Box" of Credit Card Debt, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 375, 386-90.
-
-
-
-
259
-
-
41449089076
-
-
See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57
-
See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57.
-
-
-
-
260
-
-
41449103341
-
-
See Mann, supra note 94, at 385-86 (For the credit card lender, the first hint of sustained profitability comes when the cardholder (now borrower) stops regularly paying her balance in full each month.).
-
See Mann, supra note 94, at 385-86 ("For the credit card lender, the first hint of sustained profitability comes when the cardholder (now borrower) stops regularly paying her balance in full each month.").
-
-
-
-
262
-
-
41449096384
-
-
See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 8. The $250 cost of failing to switch cards post-introductory period was calculated by multiplying the average balance on credit cards ($2500) by the common margin between introductory and post-introductory interest rates (10%).
-
See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 8. The $250 cost of failing to switch cards post-introductory period was calculated by multiplying the average balance on credit cards ($2500) by the common margin between introductory and post-introductory interest rates (10%).
-
-
-
-
263
-
-
41449097934
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
264
-
-
41449090563
-
-
See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 178-80. More than 90% of consumers with credit card debts have some liquid assets in checking and savings accounts, and one-third of credit card borrowers hold more than one month's income in these liquid assets.
-
See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 178-80. More than 90% of consumers with credit card debts have some liquid assets in checking and savings accounts, and one-third of credit card borrowers hold more than one month's income in these liquid assets.
-
-
-
-
265
-
-
41449104093
-
-
Id. With a median balance of more than $2000 (conditional on having a balance, i.e., the median balance among consumers who have a positive balance) and a spread of 10% between credit card interest rates and interest rates on checking and savings accounts, a typical consumer is losing more than $200 a year in interest payments.
-
Id. With a median balance of more than $2000 (conditional on having a balance, i.e., the median balance among consumers who have a positive balance) and a spread of 10% between credit card interest rates and interest rates on checking and savings accounts, a typical consumer is losing more than $200 a year in interest payments.
-
-
-
-
266
-
-
41449111786
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
267
-
-
41449097385
-
-
Recent evidence shows a causal link between unsafe financial products and financial distress, including bankruptcy. See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
-
Recent evidence shows a causal link between unsafe financial products and financial distress, including bankruptcy. See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
-
-
-
-
268
-
-
41449108258
-
-
This number is based on the following data: about seventeen million households open a new general purpose credit card account each year and about 50% of new accounts include introductory rates. Fixed Rate vs. Intro Rate, CARDFLASH, July 29, 1999 subscription required Internet source, on file with the author, reporting findings from a 1999 study of account acquisition and attrition conducted by PSI Global, Additionally, at least 50% of cardholders carry a balance
-
This number is based on the following data: about seventeen million households open a new general purpose credit card account each year and about 50% of new accounts include introductory rates. Fixed Rate vs. Intro Rate, CARDFLASH, July 29, 1999 (subscription required Internet source, on file with the author) (reporting findings from a 1999 study of account acquisition and attrition conducted by PSI Global). Additionally, at least 50% of cardholders carry a balance.
-
-
-
-
269
-
-
41449108668
-
-
See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 151 (discussing the number of households that carry a balance on their cards). I recognize that cards with introductory offers might be issued at different rates to borrowing and nonborrowing consumers/households. Nevertheless, the preceding calculation probably yields a conservative estimate, if issuers are more likely to target introductory offers to borrowers and/or if borrowers are more likely to be attracted by introductory offers.
-
See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 151 (discussing the number of households that carry a balance on their cards). I recognize that cards with introductory offers might be issued at different rates to borrowing and nonborrowing consumers/households. Nevertheless, the preceding calculation probably yields a conservative estimate, if issuers are more likely to target introductory offers to borrowers and/or if borrowers are more likely to be attracted by introductory offers.
-
-
-
-
270
-
-
41449102397
-
-
In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein correctly points out that the $350 million figure is not a direct social cost. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 825. Rather, it is a transfer from consumers to issuers or, in a competitive market, from one group of consumers-those who make mistakes - to another group of consumers - those who do not make mistakes. Still, such a transfer from a weaker group to a stronger group constitutes a social cost.
-
In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein correctly points out that the $350 million figure is not a direct social cost. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 825. Rather, it is a transfer from consumers to issuers or, in a competitive market, from one group of consumers-those who make mistakes - to another group of consumers - those who do not make mistakes. Still, such a transfer from a weaker group to a stronger group constitutes a social cost.
-
-
-
-
271
-
-
41449088530
-
-
MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68
-
MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
-
-
-
-
272
-
-
41449093697
-
-
See, e.g., Adam Feibelman, Defining the Social Insurance Function of Consumer Bankruptcy, 13 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 129, 162-63 (2005);
-
See, e.g., Adam Feibelman, Defining the Social Insurance Function of Consumer Bankruptcy, 13 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 129, 162-63 (2005);
-
-
-
-
273
-
-
33947270990
-
-
Melissa B. Jacoby, Bankruptcy Reform and Homeownership Risk, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 323, 330-31;
-
Melissa B. Jacoby, Bankruptcy Reform and Homeownership Risk, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 323, 330-31;
-
-
-
-
274
-
-
41449114760
-
-
Robert M. Lawless & Stephen P. Ferris, Economics and the Rhetoric of Valuation, 5 J. BANKR. L. & PRAC. 3, 8 n.22 (1995).
-
Robert M. Lawless & Stephen P. Ferris, Economics and the Rhetoric of Valuation, 5 J. BANKR. L. & PRAC. 3, 8 n.22 (1995).
-
-
-
-
275
-
-
0001475698
-
Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom to Contract, 24
-
See
-
See Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom to Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283, 307-08 (1995).
-
(1995)
J. LEGAL STUD
, vol.283
, pp. 307-308
-
-
Posner, E.A.1
-
276
-
-
41449093104
-
-
U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, REPORT ON PREDATORY LENDING PRACTICES DIRECTED AT MEMBERS OF THE ARMED FORCES AND THEIR DEPENDENTS 35-36, 45, 86-87 (2006), http://www.usa4militaryfamilies. dod.mil/dav/lsn/LSN/BINARY_RESOURCE/BINARY_CONTENT/2141721.pdf.
-
U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, REPORT ON PREDATORY LENDING PRACTICES DIRECTED AT MEMBERS OF THE ARMED FORCES AND THEIR DEPENDENTS 35-36, 45, 86-87 (2006), http://www.usa4militaryfamilies. dod.mil/dav/lsn/LSN/BINARY_RESOURCE/BINARY_CONTENT/2141721.pdf.
-
-
-
-
277
-
-
41449090167
-
-
The DOD report also describes how military personnel in financial distress become more vulnerable to extortion and, consequently, can lose their security clearance. Id. at 35-36, 45
-
The DOD report also describes how military personnel in financial distress become more vulnerable to extortion and, consequently, can lose their security clearance. Id. at 35-36, 45.
-
-
-
-
278
-
-
74049118413
-
-
For a similar discussion, see, note 38, at, arguing that unsafe credit products skew the distribution of resources within society, resulting in regressive redistribution
-
For a similar discussion, see Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 36-37 (arguing that unsafe credit products skew the distribution of resources within society, resulting in regressive redistribution).
-
supra
, pp. 36-37
-
-
Gill, B.1
Warren2
-
279
-
-
41449087543
-
-
See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, supra note 183, at 10-22 (describing predatory lending to enlisted military personnel who often lack the experience and education to avoid such pitfalls).
-
See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, supra note 183, at 10-22 (describing predatory lending to enlisted military personnel who often lack the experience and education to avoid such pitfalls).
-
-
-
-
280
-
-
41449086958
-
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 116-18, 128
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 116-18, 128.
-
-
-
-
281
-
-
41449118864
-
-
See id. at 125, 128.
-
See id. at 125, 128.
-
-
-
-
282
-
-
41449086071
-
-
Cf. Jolis et al., Behavioral Approach, supra note 3, at 1541 (engaging in a normative analysis of anti-anti-paternalism).
-
Cf. Jolis et al., Behavioral Approach, supra note 3, at 1541 (engaging in a normative analysis of anti-anti-paternalism).
-
-
-
-
284
-
-
41449083242
-
-
See id. at 116.
-
See id. at 116.
-
-
-
-
285
-
-
41449117435
-
-
See id. at 116-17.
-
See id. at 116-17.
-
-
-
-
286
-
-
41449087545
-
-
See, e.g., Anthony T. Kronman, Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 4-5 (1978).
-
See, e.g., Anthony T. Kronman, Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 4-5 (1978).
-
-
-
-
287
-
-
41449105139
-
-
See supra Part U.C.
-
See supra Part U.C.
-
-
-
-
288
-
-
41449105724
-
-
See Kronman, supra note 193, at 4-5
-
See Kronman, supra note 193, at 4-5.
-
-
-
-
289
-
-
41449091689
-
-
One of the exceptions to the contract law rule refusing to recognize an excuse for unilateral mistake is the case of an accounting or a clerical error, where the nonmistaken party is in a better position to detect the mistake and prevent the potential allocative inefficiency that might follow from it. See, e.g, Boise Junior Coll. Dist. v. Matters Constr. Co, 450 P.2d 604, 609 Idaho 1969
-
One of the exceptions to the contract law rule refusing to recognize an excuse for unilateral mistake is the case of an accounting or a clerical error, where the nonmistaken party is in a better position to detect the mistake and prevent the potential allocative inefficiency that might follow from it. See, e.g., Boise Junior Coll. Dist. v. Matters Constr. Co., 450 P.2d 604, 609 (Idaho 1969).
-
-
-
-
291
-
-
41449103340
-
-
The facts in Rossman provide an example of such misleading statements. Rossman v. Fleet Bank (R.I.) Natl Ass'n, 280 F.3d 384, 387-89 (3d Cir. 2002).
-
The facts in Rossman provide an example of such misleading statements. Rossman v. Fleet Bank (R.I.) Natl Ass'n, 280 F.3d 384, 387-89 (3d Cir. 2002).
-
-
-
-
292
-
-
41449086956
-
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121-22 (But at this point the behavioral critique loses much of its bite, because it can no longer predict any systematic direction to the market errors . ... [I]t is hard to make policy recommendations in the absence of information as to which effect is likely to be most profound in any given setting. The behavioral critique lacks real bite.);
-
See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121-22 ("But at this point the behavioral critique loses much of its bite, because it can no longer predict any systematic direction to the market errors . ... [I]t is hard to make policy recommendations in the absence of information as to which effect is likely to be most profound in any given setting. The behavioral critique lacks real bite.");
-
-
-
-
293
-
-
41449088532
-
-
Dwelling on imperfections of ordinary individuals carries no clear implication as to the appropriate policy choice because there is no directionality to these cognitive errors, see also, at
-
see also Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, supra note 3, at 364 ("Dwelling on imperfections of ordinary individuals carries no clear implication as to the appropriate policy choice because there is no directionality to these cognitive errors.").
-
Second-Order Rationality, supra note
, vol.3
, pp. 364
-
-
Epstein1
-
295
-
-
41449111598
-
-
See supra Parts ILB-C.
-
See supra Parts ILB-C.
-
-
-
-
296
-
-
41449116362
-
-
See, e.g., HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 13-20 (2005).
-
See, e.g., HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 13-20 (2005).
-
-
-
-
299
-
-
41449086244
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
300
-
-
41449112561
-
-
See id. (One key difficulty with all prophylactic legislation is that it tends to ignore striking differences by treating persons, even within narrow socioeconomic groupings, as part of some homogeneous mass.).
-
See id. ("One key difficulty with all prophylactic legislation is that it tends to ignore striking differences by treating persons, even within narrow socioeconomic groupings, as part of some homogeneous mass.").
-
-
-
-
301
-
-
0742306363
-
Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron, 70
-
If feasible, a comparison of possible rules should be done using a form of cost-benefit analysis, one that pays serious attention to welfare effects. In many cases, however, such analyses will be both difficult and expensive
-
Cass R. Sunstein & Richard H. Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1159, 1190 (2003) ("If feasible, a comparison of possible rules should be done using a form of cost-benefit analysis, one that pays serious attention to welfare effects. In many cases, however, such analyses will be both difficult and expensive.").
-
(2003)
U. CHI. L. REV
, vol.1159
, pp. 1190
-
-
Sunstein, C.R.1
Thaler, R.H.2
-
302
-
-
41449104762
-
-
Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129 (Who is confident enough to decide which error counts for more, and to spend public money on the strength of their speculations?).
-
Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129 ("Who is confident enough to decide which error counts for more, and to spend public money on the strength of their speculations?").
-
-
-
-
303
-
-
0038548458
-
Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism," 151
-
See generally
-
See generally Colin Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism," 151 U. PA. L. REV. 1211 (2003);
-
(2003)
U. PA. L. REV
, vol.1211
-
-
Camerer, C.1
-
304
-
-
41449095823
-
-
Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205
-
Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205.
-
-
-
-
306
-
-
41449086070
-
-
A regulatory mechanism, which is somewhat similar to mandatory disclosure, uses public information campaigns to undo consumer misperception. Epstein argues that public information campaigns are unnecessary, since [ajnyone can enter the market on information, And by putting the government into the fray, there is always the risk that debiasing will take the form of rebiasing, by overstating credit card risks to individuals who would do well to have them. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 131. While Epstein is right that anyone can enter the market for information, non-government entities might not have sufficient incentives or sufficient funding to mount effective information campaigns. The risk of rebiasing is also a valid concern-one that needs to be weighed against the benefits of debiasing
-
A regulatory mechanism, which is somewhat similar to mandatory disclosure, uses public information campaigns to undo consumer misperception. Epstein argues that public information campaigns are unnecessary, since "[ajnyone can enter the market on information. . . . And by putting the government into the fray, there is always the risk that debiasing will take the form of rebiasing, by overstating credit card risks to individuals who would do well to have them." See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 131. While Epstein is right that anyone can enter the market for information, non-government entities might not have sufficient incentives or sufficient funding to mount effective information campaigns. The risk of rebiasing is also a valid concern-one that needs to be weighed against the benefits of debiasing.
-
-
-
-
307
-
-
41449099484
-
-
See generally Christine Jolis & Cass R. Sunstein, Debiasing Through Law (U. Chi. Law Sch. John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper Series, Paper No. 225 (2d series), 2005), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-590929.
-
See generally Christine Jolis & Cass R. Sunstein, Debiasing Through Law (U. Chi. Law Sch. John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper Series, Paper No. 225 (2d series), 2005), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-590929.
-
-
-
-
308
-
-
41449098102
-
-
See Camerer et al, supra note 207, at 1224-30;
-
See Camerer et al., supra note 207, at 1224-30;
-
-
-
-
309
-
-
41449107070
-
-
Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205, at 1162-67
-
Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205, at 1162-67.
-
-
-
-
311
-
-
41449111218
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
312
-
-
41449083058
-
-
See supra Parts II-III.
-
See supra Parts II-III.
-
-
-
-
313
-
-
41449100256
-
-
Another way to address the heterogeneity concern is by screening for sophistication. For example, under Regulation D, the SEC proscribes all but the very wealthy, who qualify as accredited investors, from investing in hedge funds. See 17 C.F.R. § 230.501 2007, defining the term accredited investor, One reason for this regulation is that the rich have a greater tolerance for risk. Another reason is that wealth can serve as a proxy for sophistication, especially since money can buy expert advice. By the same token perhaps some consumers should be denied access to mortgage loans or credit cards. The financial risk imposed by these products is substantial. Evidence suggests that not all consumers are sufficiently informed and sufficiently rational to understand the risk and protect against it
-
Another way to address the heterogeneity concern is by screening for sophistication. For example, under Regulation D, the SEC proscribes all but the very wealthy, who qualify as "accredited investors," from investing in hedge funds. See 17 C.F.R. § 230.501 (2007) (defining the term "accredited investor"). One reason for this regulation is that the rich have a greater tolerance for risk. Another reason is that wealth can serve as a proxy for sophistication, especially since money can buy expert advice. By the same token perhaps some consumers should be denied access to mortgage loans or credit cards. The financial risk imposed by these products is substantial. Evidence suggests that not all consumers are sufficiently informed and sufficiently rational to understand the risk and protect against it.
-
-
-
-
314
-
-
41449107647
-
-
See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. The problem, of course, is that accurate proxies for screening consumers are hard to come by, and using wealth as a proxy might result in denial of valuable products and services to poor consumers.
-
See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. The problem, of course, is that accurate proxies for screening consumers are hard to come by, and using wealth as a proxy might result in denial of valuable products and services to poor consumers.
-
-
-
-
316
-
-
41449106106
-
-
Id.;
-
Id.;
-
-
-
-
317
-
-
0344497355
-
-
see also Stephen J. Choi & A.C. Pritchard, Behavioral Economics and the SEC, 56 STAN. L. REV. 1, 5-6 (2003) ([I]f everyone suffers from cognitive defects, doesn't that also include [the regulators]?).
-
see also Stephen J. Choi & A.C. Pritchard, Behavioral Economics and the SEC, 56 STAN. L. REV. 1, 5-6 (2003) ("[I]f everyone suffers from cognitive defects, doesn't that also include [the regulators]?").
-
-
-
-
319
-
-
41449089602
-
-
see also Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C. §§1601-1667 2000
-
see also Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C. §§1601-1667 (2000).
-
-
-
-
321
-
-
41449099485
-
-
280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
-
280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
-
-
-
-
322
-
-
41449096191
-
-
See id. at 387-89.
-
See id. at 387-89.
-
-
-
-
323
-
-
41449084415
-
-
Id. at 387-88
-
Id. at 387-88.
-
-
-
-
324
-
-
41449118656
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
325
-
-
41449099089
-
-
Id
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
326
-
-
41449114096
-
-
Id. at 388-89
-
Id. at 388-89.
-
-
-
-
328
-
-
41449092065
-
-
See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 394 ([W]e believe a reasonable consumer would ... be entitled to assume upon reading Fleet's solicitation that the issuer was committed to refraining from imposing an annual fee for at least one year. The statement 'no annual fee,' in other words, is fairly understood to contain an implied term of a year.).
-
See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 394 ("[W]e believe a reasonable consumer would ... be entitled to assume upon reading Fleet's solicitation that the issuer was committed to refraining from imposing an annual fee for at least one year. The statement 'no annual fee,' in other words, is fairly understood to contain an implied term of a year.").
-
-
-
-
330
-
-
41449103712
-
-
Rossman's no annual fee for one year interpretation does not comport with Fleet's expectations either. Fleet did not think that it had to wait a year before imposing an annual fee. See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388-89.
-
Rossman's "no annual fee for one year" interpretation does not comport with Fleet's expectations either. Fleet did not think that it had to wait a year before imposing an annual fee. See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388-89.
-
-
-
-
331
-
-
41449095157
-
-
Epstein acknowledges that the bank had planned from the outset to impose an annual fee before the end of the year. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 126.
-
Epstein acknowledges that "the bank had planned from the outset to impose an annual fee before the end of the year." See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 126.
-
-
-
-
332
-
-
41449085887
-
-
More comprehensive disclosure might not reduce the incidence of consumer mistakes, because of the risk of information overload. Imperfectly rational consumers can process only a limited amount of information. See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. Therefore, more disclosure does not necessarily mean better-informed consumers.
-
More comprehensive disclosure might not reduce the incidence of consumer mistakes, because of the risk of information overload. Imperfectly rational consumers can process only a limited amount of information. See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. Therefore, more disclosure does not necessarily mean better-informed consumers.
-
-
-
-
333
-
-
41449090758
-
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 46 (finding that credit card disclosures contain too much information);
-
See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 46 (finding that credit card disclosures contain too much information);
-
-
-
-
334
-
-
33746338548
-
-
Richard Craswell, Taking Information Seriously: Misrepresentation and Nondisclosure in Contract Law and Elsewhere, 92 VA. L. REV. 565, 578 (2006) (arguing that provision of additional information dilutes the effectiveness of existing disclosures);
-
Richard Craswell, Taking Information Seriously: Misrepresentation and Nondisclosure in Contract Law and Elsewhere, 92 VA. L. REV. 565, 578 (2006) (arguing that provision of additional information dilutes the effectiveness of existing disclosures);
-
-
-
-
335
-
-
41449113503
-
-
note 94, at, concluding that it is not clear that requiring more details in regulatory disclosures would be useful for consumers
-
Furletti, supra note 94, at 19 (concluding that it is not clear that requiring more details in regulatory disclosures would be useful for consumers).
-
supra
, pp. 19
-
-
Furletti1
-
336
-
-
41449117232
-
-
See DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35 (finding that most major issuers consider a payment late if it arrives after 2:00 p.m. on the due date).
-
See DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35 (finding that most major issuers consider a payment late if it arrives after 2:00 p.m. on the due date).
-
-
-
-
337
-
-
84956547845
-
-
§ 1601a, 2000, discussing the purpose of the disclosures
-
See 15 U.S.C. § 1601(a) (2000) (discussing the purpose of the disclosures).
-
15 U.S.C
-
-
-
338
-
-
41449109035
-
-
See note 94, at, describing the current disclosures in credit card agreements
-
See MANN, supra note 94, at 131-32 (describing the current disclosures in credit card agreements).
-
supra
, pp. 131-132
-
-
MANN1
-
339
-
-
41449105140
-
-
There are examples of existing disclosure regulations that mandate use-pattern disclosures. See, e.g., 15 U.S.C. § 2056 (2000) (providing the Consumer Products Safety Commission with authority to promulgate requirements that a consumer product be marked with or accompanied by clear and adequate warnings or instructions in order to ensure products are used correctly). Still, in many consumer markets use-pattern disclosure is missing. And, where use-pattern disclosure is required, the use-pattern information disclosed is often insufficient.
-
There are examples of existing disclosure regulations that mandate use-pattern disclosures. See, e.g., 15 U.S.C. § 2056 (2000) (providing the Consumer Products Safety Commission with authority to promulgate "requirements that a consumer product be marked with or accompanied by clear and adequate warnings or instructions" in order to ensure products are used correctly). Still, in many consumer markets use-pattern disclosure is missing. And, where use-pattern disclosure is required, the use-pattern information disclosed is often insufficient.
-
-
-
-
340
-
-
41449105918
-
Informing Consumers
-
See, note 22, at, providing examples of such inefficiencies
-
See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 46-53 (providing examples of such inefficiencies).
-
supra
, pp. 46-53
-
-
Bar-Gill1
-
341
-
-
41449116940
-
-
Cf. Thomas A. Durkin, Requirements and Prospects for a New Time to Payoff Disclosure for Open End Credit Under Truth in Lending 25 (Fed. Reserve Bd., Fin. and Econ. Discussion Series, Paper No. 2006-34, 2006), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2006/200634/ (Beyond the consumer surveys, specific information on consumers' payment patterns has heretofore been available only to the creditors who issue the cards.).
-
Cf. Thomas A. Durkin, Requirements and Prospects for a New Time to Payoff Disclosure for Open End Credit Under Truth in Lending 25 (Fed. Reserve Bd., Fin. and Econ. Discussion Series, Paper No. 2006-34, 2006), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2006/200634/ ("Beyond the consumer surveys, specific information on consumers' payment patterns has heretofore been available only to the creditors who issue the cards.").
-
-
-
-
342
-
-
41449094465
-
-
See id. at 40-41 (explaining a sample of credit card account information assembled in 2001 from the portfolios of five of the fifteen largest credit card issuers).
-
See id. at 40-41 (explaining a sample of credit card account information "assembled in 2001 from the portfolios of five of the fifteen largest credit card issuers").
-
-
-
-
343
-
-
41449106490
-
-
See id
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
345
-
-
41449112761
-
-
For instance, consumers can easily access their own credit information via credit reports on the Internet. See, e.g., Experian, Free Credit Report and Credit Score, http://www.experian.com/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2007). Additionally, consumers can access reports and statistical data on government and nongovernmental organizations' websites, as well as through the use of free research databases.
-
For instance, consumers can easily access their own credit information via credit reports on the Internet. See, e.g., Experian, Free Credit Report and Credit Score, http://www.experian.com/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2007). Additionally, consumers can access reports and statistical data on government and nongovernmental organizations' websites, as well as through the use of free research databases.
-
-
-
-
346
-
-
39149130217
-
-
Social Science Research Network, last visited Nov. 30
-
See, e.g., Social Science Research Network, http://www .ssrn.com/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2007).
-
(2007)
See, e.g
-
-
-
347
-
-
41449089075
-
-
See note 94, at, discussing card issuers' use of collected information to adjust rates
-
See Furletti, supra note 94, at 6-9 (discussing card issuers' use of collected information to adjust rates).
-
supra
, pp. 6-9
-
-
Furletti1
-
348
-
-
41449116561
-
-
MANN, supra note 94, at 192 ([A] point-of-sale reminder of the account balance might cause a consumer to respond differently. The consumer could switch to another payment device or discontinue the sales transaction entirely.).
-
MANN, supra note 94, at 192 ("[A] point-of-sale reminder of the account balance might cause a consumer to respond differently. The consumer could switch to another payment device or discontinue the sales transaction entirely.").
-
-
-
-
351
-
-
41449090759
-
-
see also MANN, supra note 94, at 160-61 (arguing for individual reports on debt repayment time and cost at the point of borrowing);
-
see also MANN, supra note 94, at 160-61 (arguing for individual reports on debt repayment time and cost at the point of borrowing);
-
-
-
-
352
-
-
41449086418
-
-
Thomas A. Durkin, Credit Cards: Use and Consumer Attitudes, 1970-2000, 86 FED. RES. BULL. 623, 629 (2000) (Many holders of bank-type cards in 2000 said that it would be helpful to include on their billing statement information about the length of time it would take to pay off the balance if only the minimum payment were made each month.).
-
Thomas A. Durkin, Credit Cards: Use and Consumer Attitudes, 1970-2000, 86 FED. RES. BULL. 623, 629 (2000) ("Many holders of bank-type cards in 2000 said that it would be helpful to include on their billing statement information about the length of time it would take to pay off the balance if only the minimum payment were made each month.").
-
-
-
-
353
-
-
41449089416
-
-
Such an individualized warning, tailored to the consumer's actual repayment record, should be more effective than the general warning that Congress recently enacted as part of the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005. See Pub. L. No. 109-8, § 1301, 119 Stat. 23, 204-08 (2005). A more individualized version of § 1301 was soundly defeated by the issuers' lobby in the House of Representatives.
-
Such an individualized warning, tailored to the consumer's actual repayment record, should be more effective than the general warning that Congress recently enacted as part of the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005. See Pub. L. No. 109-8, § 1301, 119 Stat. 23, 204-08 (2005). A more individualized version of § 1301 was soundly defeated by the issuers' lobby in the House of Representatives.
-
-
-
-
354
-
-
41449096577
-
-
See H.R. 1052, 107th Cong. (2001).
-
See H.R. 1052, 107th Cong. (2001).
-
-
-
|