메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 92, Issue 3, 2008, Pages 749-802

The behavioral economics of consumer contracts

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 41449095211     PISSN: 00265535     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (88)

References (354)
  • 1
    • 33645788995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Economics: Human Errors and Market Corrections, 73
    • Richard A. Epstein, Behavioral Economics: Human Errors and Market Corrections, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 111, 111 (2006)
    • (2006) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.111 , pp. 111
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 3
    • 33645758674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bundling and Consumer Misperception, 73
    • See
    • See Oren Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 33 (2006)
    • (2006) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.33
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 5
    • 8644277076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Seduction by Plastic, 98
    • Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 NW. U. L. REV. 1373 (2004)
    • (2004) NW. U. L. REV , vol.1373
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 8
    • 77149134046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Richard A. Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, in BEHAVIORAL PUBLIC FINANCE 355-56, 365-67, 384-85 (Edward J. McCaffery & Joel Slemrod eds., 2006)
    • see also Richard A. Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, in BEHAVIORAL PUBLIC FINANCE 355-56, 365-67, 384-85 (Edward J. McCaffery & Joel Slemrod eds., 2006)
  • 9
    • 41449109395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • hereinafter, Some of the challenges and responses discussed below echo elements of the general debate over the role of behavioral economics in legal policymaking
    • [hereinafter Epstein, Second-Order Rationality], Some of the challenges and responses discussed below echo elements of the general debate over the role of behavioral economics in legal policymaking.
    • Second-Order Rationality
    • Epstein1
  • 10
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Christine Jolis, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471, 1476-88 (1998)
    • (1998) STAN. L. REV , vol.1471 , pp. 1476-1488
    • Jolis, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 12
    • 22044438205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theories and Tropes: A Reply to Posner and Kelman, 50
    • Christine Jolis, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, Theories and Tropes: A Reply to Posner and Kelman, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1593 (1998);
    • (1998) STAN. L. REV , vol.1593
    • Jolis, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 13
    • 22044438367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Economics as Part of a Rhetorical Duet: A Response to Jolis, Sunstein, and Thaler, 50
    • Mark G. Kelman, Behavioral Economics as Part of a Rhetorical Duet: A Response to Jolis, Sunstein, and Thaler, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1577, 1586-90 (1998);
    • (1998) STAN. L. REV , vol.1577 , pp. 1586-1590
    • Kelman, M.G.1
  • 14
    • 0347487318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law, 50
    • This Article, and more broadly, this Exchange, between Professor Epstein and myself-is unique in its focus on the application of behavioral law and economics to consumer contracts
    • Richard A. Posner, Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1551 (1998). This Article, and more broadly, this Exchange - between Professor Epstein and myself-is unique in its focus on the application of behavioral law and economics to consumer contracts.
    • (1998) STAN. L. REV , vol.1551
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 15
    • 41449110138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 114-18, 126-27;
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 114-18, 126-27;
  • 16
    • 41449109557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard A. Epstein, Exchange, The Neoclassical Economics of Consumer Contracts, 92 MINN. L. REV. 803, 810-16 (2008)
    • Richard A. Epstein, Exchange, The Neoclassical Economics of Consumer Contracts, 92 MINN. L. REV. 803, 810-16 (2008)
  • 17
    • 41449109954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exchange, Neoclassical
    • hereinafter
    • [hereinafter Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics].
    • Economics
    • Epstein1
  • 19
    • 41449096575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 816-17
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 816-17.
  • 21
    • 41449118654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 120
    • Id. at 120.
  • 22
    • 41449098100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 121-22
    • Id. at 121-22.
  • 23
    • 41449103714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • B]uyers do not have uniform demands
    • See id. ("[B]uyers do not have uniform demands.").
    • See id
  • 24
    • 41449116559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A qualification should be mentioned: If sellers can segment the market and offer one product (and one pricing scheme) to overestimators and another product (and another pricing scheme) to underestimators, then a design response to consumer misperception need not be inconsistent with an average mistake of zero. This qualification, however, is largely theoretical. As Epstein himself argues, segmentation according to the type or level of misperception is unlikely. See id. at 121 ([N]o consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level].);
    • A qualification should be mentioned: If sellers can segment the market and offer one product (and one pricing scheme) to overestimators and another product (and another pricing scheme) to underestimators, then a design response to consumer misperception need not be inconsistent with an average mistake of zero. This qualification, however, is largely theoretical. As Epstein himself argues, segmentation according to the type or level of misperception is unlikely. See id. at 121 ("[N]o consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level].");
  • 25
    • 41449086074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also infra note 78.
    • see also infra note 78.
  • 27
  • 28
    • 41449115902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 127 (Banks know how to live with predictable defaults, but they hardly regard the failure of their borrowers as an advantage to themselves.).
    • Id. at 127 ("Banks know how to live with predictable defaults, but they hardly regard the failure of their borrowers as an advantage to themselves.").
  • 30
    • 41449090172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 131 (Banning [so-called 'teaser' credit card] rates will do no good, and it could easily work some anticompetitive harm, by making it more difficult for new banks to pry customers away from established competitors.).
    • See id. at 131 ("Banning [so-called 'teaser' credit card] rates will do no good, and it could easily work some anticompetitive harm, by making it more difficult for new banks to pry customers away from established competitors.").
  • 32
    • 41449093295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ([A]ny regulation that slows down the profligate borrower will also deter the cautious borrower from entering into the market by raising his costs of transaction.).
    • See id. ("[A]ny regulation that slows down the profligate borrower will also deter the cautious borrower from entering into the market by raising his costs of transaction.").
  • 33
    • 41449088134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 128.
    • See id. at 128.
  • 35
    • 41449098541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 127 (The general disclosure remedies are shown to have a place.).
    • See id. at 127 ("The general disclosure remedies are shown to have a place.").
  • 36
    • 41449107845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I define use broadly to include the payment of different price components, redeeming rebates, etc
    • I define "use" broadly to include the payment of different price components, redeeming rebates, etc.
  • 37
    • 41449093297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This theme is further developed in a companion piece. See Oren Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers About Themselves 53-63 Oct. 4, 2007, unpublished manuscript, on file with author
    • This theme is further developed in a companion piece. See Oren Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers About Themselves 53-63 (Oct. 4, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author)
  • 40
    • 41449100259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 118
    • Id. at 118.
  • 41
    • 41449115121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 120.
    • See id. at 120.
  • 42
    • 41449117439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (arguing that the competitive, open market corrects consumer misperceptions because a seller of a somewhat different product will draw away the customers [of the original, misperceived product] by trumpeting the mistake).
    • See id. (arguing that the competitive, open market corrects consumer misperceptions because a "seller of a somewhat different product will draw away the customers [of the original, misperceived product] by trumpeting the mistake").
  • 43
    • 41449110870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions, 59 J. BUS. (CONFERENCE PROCEEDINGS) S251, S275 (1986),
    • See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions, 59 J. BUS. (CONFERENCE PROCEEDINGS) S251, S275 (1986),
  • 44
    • 41449108262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • reprinted in RATIONAL CHOICE: THE CONTRAST BETWEEN ECONOMICS AND PSYCHOLOGY 67, 91 (Robin M. Hogarth & Melvin W. Reder eds., 1987) (The claim that the market can be trusted to correct the effect of individual irrationalities cannot be made without supporting evidence . . . .).
    • reprinted in RATIONAL CHOICE: THE CONTRAST BETWEEN ECONOMICS AND PSYCHOLOGY 67, 91 (Robin M. Hogarth & Melvin W. Reder eds., 1987) ("The claim that the market can be trusted to correct the effect of individual irrationalities cannot be made without supporting evidence . . . .").
  • 46
    • 41449105357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this Exchange, Epstein cites findings from a recent study by Agarwal et al. showing that consumers do learn. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 811-12
    • In this Exchange, Epstein cites findings from a recent study by Agarwal et al. showing that consumers do learn. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 811-12
  • 47
    • 41449114935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (citing Sumit Agarwal et al., The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Lifecycle 2 (Mass. Inst, of Tech. Dep't of Econ. Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 07-11, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=973790).
    • (citing Sumit Agarwal et al., The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Lifecycle 2 (Mass. Inst, of Tech. Dep't of Econ. Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 07-11, 2007), available at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=973790).
  • 48
    • 41449110142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am not arguing that consumers do not learn. I am only arguing that learning is imperfect. Indeed, the Agarwal study reveals that a significant number of consumers make mistakes. See, e.g., Agarwal et al., supra, at 15 (concluding that, in home equity credit lending, [t]he unconditional average probability of making a ... mistake [affecting interest rate] is 24[%] for loans and 18[%] for lines [of credit] and [y]ounger and older consumers have a greater tendency to misestimate the value of their house . . . which leads them to borrow at an increased APR).
    • I am not arguing that consumers do not learn. I am only arguing that learning is imperfect. Indeed, the Agarwal study reveals that a significant number of consumers make mistakes. See, e.g., Agarwal et al., supra, at 15 (concluding that, in home equity credit lending, "[t]he unconditional average probability of making a ... mistake [affecting interest rate] is 24[%] for loans and 18[%] for lines [of credit]" and "[y]ounger and older consumers have a greater tendency to misestimate the value of their house . . . which leads them to borrow at an increased APR").
  • 49
    • 21344493140 scopus 로고
    • Good Warnings, Bad Products, and Cognitive Limitations, 41
    • T]he capacity for learning is dependent on the specific product-use context, On the conditions for effective learning and on the limits of learning, see
    • On the conditions for effective learning and on the limits of learning, see Howard Latin, "Good" Warnings, Bad Products, and Cognitive Limitations, 41 UCLA L. REV. 1193, 1252-53 (1994) ("[T]he capacity for learning is dependent on the specific product-use context . . . .");
    • (1994) UCLA L. REV , vol.1193 , pp. 1252-1253
    • Latin, H.1
  • 50
    • 41449113347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75 (Effective learning takes place only under certain conditions . . . . [A]ny claim that a particular error will be eliminated by experience must be supported by demonstrating that the conditions for effective learning are satisfied.).
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75 ("Effective learning takes place only under certain conditions . . . . [A]ny claim that a particular error will be eliminated by experience must be supported by demonstrating that the conditions for effective learning are satisfied.").
  • 51
    • 41449091486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 ([M]ost feedback [about the risks of using a product] takes the form of experiences of safe usage.).
    • Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 ("[M]ost feedback [about the risks of using a product] takes the form of experiences of safe usage.").
  • 52
    • 41449096579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75
    • See Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274-75.
  • 54
    • 41449094297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (criticizing the hopeless artificiality of any example that presupposes universal ignorance of the value of any standard commodity and arguing that there is no sustainable equilibrium when the mistake in information is about a standardized product that everyone can test and use).
    • See id. (criticizing "the hopeless artificiality of any example that presupposes universal ignorance of the value of any standard commodity" and arguing that "there is no sustainable equilibrium when the mistake in information is about a standardized product that everyone can test and use").
  • 55
    • 41449108073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the limits of learning, even by sophisticated decision makers in real world [situations] that involve high stakes and serious deliberation [,] see Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274.
    • On the limits of learning, even by sophisticated decision makers in "real world [situations] that involve high stakes and serious deliberation [,]" see Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 27, at S274.
  • 56
    • 41449106493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Cade Massey & Richard H. Thaler, The Loser's Curse: Overconfidence vs. Market Efficiency in the National Football League Draft 3 (Mar. 15, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract- 697121) (documenting persistent bias in NFL draft picks and overestimation of the decision maker's abilities).
    • See also Cade Massey & Richard H. Thaler, The Loser's Curse: Overconfidence vs. Market Efficiency in the National Football League Draft 3 (Mar. 15, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract- 697121) (documenting persistent bias in NFL draft picks and overestimation of the decision maker's abilities).
  • 58
    • 41449104952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 59
    • 41449112564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, nonstandardized products may share standardized features, and interpersonal learning about these features can be effective. Cf. id. at 120-21 (arguing that consumers will likewise share information about valuation mistakes even in situations involving nonstandardized products).
    • However, nonstandardized products may share standardized features, and interpersonal learning about these features can be effective. Cf. id. at 120-21 (arguing that consumers will likewise share information about valuation mistakes even in situations involving nonstandardized products).
  • 60
    • 41449093505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For another discussion of this issue, see Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer 15 (Oct. 4, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author).
    • For another discussion of this issue, see Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer 15 (Oct. 4, 2007) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the author).
  • 61
    • 41449093903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 (Product risks and accident scenarios are very diverse; feedback from one mode of use or product application consequently may not be very useful in minimizing other kinds of harms.).
    • Cf. Latin, supra note 29, at 1253 ("Product risks and accident scenarios are very diverse; feedback from one mode of use or product application consequently may not be very useful in minimizing other kinds of harms.").
  • 62
    • 41449089217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a similar discussion, see Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 14
    • For a similar discussion, see Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 14.
  • 63
    • 41449107844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
  • 64
    • 41449109395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also note 3, at, R]ational people take steps that on average reduce, not increase, the frequency and severity of their errors
    • see also Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, supra note 3, at 361 ("[R]ational people take steps that on average reduce, not increase, the frequency and severity of their errors,").
    • Second-Order Rationality, supra , pp. 361
    • Epstein1
  • 65
    • 41449112152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 813;
  • 66
    • 41449098914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • T]hey seek advice from friends, hire experts, attend classes, use MapQuest, and adopt rules of thumb or other tricks of the trade, see also, at
    • see also Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, supra note 3, at 361-62 ("[T]hey seek advice from friends, hire experts, attend classes, use MapQuest, and adopt rules of thumb or other tricks of the trade . . . ."),
    • Second-Order Rationality, supra note , vol.3 , pp. 361-362
    • Epstein1
  • 67
    • 41449117614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many small mistakes can be as harmful as a few large mistakes. Credit card borrowing provides an example. See TERESA A. SULLIVAN ET AL., AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS: BANKRUPTCY AND CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA 178 (1989);
    • Many small mistakes can be as harmful as a few large mistakes. Credit card borrowing provides an example. See TERESA A. SULLIVAN ET AL., AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS: BANKRUPTCY AND CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA 178 (1989);
  • 68
    • 41449086073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • describing how consumers make multiple small mistakes that equal a large mistake they would never make at once, Consumers make mistakes even when the decision is a big one. For example, many consumers take on subprime mortgage loans that they cannot repay, at
    • Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1399 (describing how consumers make multiple small mistakes that equal a large mistake they would never make at once). Consumers make mistakes even when the decision is a big one. For example, many consumers take on subprime mortgage loans that they cannot repay.
    • Seduction by Plastic, supra note , vol.2 , pp. 1399
    • Bar-Gill1
  • 69
    • 41449109037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., James H. Carr & Lopa Kolluri, Predatory Lending: An Overview, in FANNIE MAE FOUNDATION, FINANCIAL SERVICES IN DISTRESSED COMMUNITIES: ISSUES AND ANSWERS 31, 37 (2001) (noting that individuals who would otherwise qualify for prime-rate loans nevertheless signed up for high-interest, subprime loans);
    • See, e.g., James H. Carr & Lopa Kolluri, Predatory Lending: An Overview, in FANNIE MAE FOUNDATION, FINANCIAL SERVICES IN DISTRESSED COMMUNITIES: ISSUES AND ANSWERS 31, 37 (2001) (noting that individuals who would otherwise qualify for prime-rate loans nevertheless signed up for high-interest, subprime loans);
  • 70
    • 55349147804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decisionmaking and the Limits of Disclosure: The Problem of Predatory Lending: Price, 65
    • summarizing studies that show foreclosure rates ranging between 20% and 30, see also
    • see also Lauren E. Willis, Decisionmaking and the Limits of Disclosure: The Problem of Predatory Lending: Price, 65 MD. L. REV. 707, 731-32 (2006) (summarizing studies that show foreclosure rates ranging between 20% and 30%).
    • (2006) MD. L. REV , vol.707 , pp. 731-732
    • Willis, L.E.1
  • 71
    • 41449099092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • arguing that in a situation in which misinformed consumers underestimate the value of a product, the market will cease unless at least one seller attempts to correct the misinformation, See, at
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note I, at 119-20 (arguing that in a situation in which misinformed consumers underestimate the value of a product, the market will cease unless at least one seller attempts to correct the misinformation).
    • Behavioral Economics, supra note , vol.1 , pp. 119-120
    • Epstein1
  • 72
    • 41449102214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Howard Beales et al., The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information, 24 J.L. & ECON. 491, 527 (1981) (describing the lack of an incentive to disclose information if competitors will benefit as free-riders);
    • Cf. Howard Beales et al., The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information, 24 J.L. & ECON. 491, 527 (1981) (describing the lack of an incentive to disclose information if competitors will benefit as free-riders);
  • 73
    • 41449099092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • noting the possibility that no seller will invest in correcting consumers' misperceptions if other sellers will subsequently benefit without expending any resources, at
    • Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 119-20 (noting the possibility that no seller will invest in correcting consumers' misperceptions if other sellers will subsequently benefit without expending any resources).
    • Behavioral Economics, supra note , vol.1 , pp. 119-120
    • Epstein1
  • 74
    • 41449105533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Beales et al, supra note 45, at 527 (explaining why sellers might not disclose both positive and negative information);
    • See Beales et al., supra note 45, at 527 (explaining why sellers might not disclose both positive and negative information);
  • 75
    • 0347305939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also R. Ted Cruz & Jeffrey J. Hinck, Not My Brother's Keeper: The Inability of an Informed Minority to Correct for Imperfect Information, 47 HASTINGS L.J. 635, 659 (1996) (detailing reasons why sellers lack incentive to inform consumers). In some markets, the advantage gained by moving first may be large enough to overcome this collective action problem.
    • see also R. Ted Cruz & Jeffrey J. Hinck, Not My Brother's Keeper: The Inability of an Informed Minority to Correct for Imperfect Information, 47 HASTINGS L.J. 635, 659 (1996) (detailing reasons why sellers lack incentive to inform consumers). In some markets, the advantage gained by moving first may be large enough to overcome this collective action problem.
  • 76
    • 41449096772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a general discussion of information failures in consumer markets, see Beales et al., supra note 45, at 503-09.
    • For a general discussion of information failures in consumer markets, see Beales et al., supra note 45, at 503-09.
  • 77
    • 33646375435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the limits of advertising as a mistake-correction mechanism, see Xavier Gabaix & David Laibson, Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets, 121 Q.J. ECON. 505, 507-10 (2006) (describing how truthful advertising to misinformed consumers does not always increase profitability);
    • On the limits of advertising as a mistake-correction mechanism, see Xavier Gabaix & David Laibson, Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in Competitive Markets, 121 Q.J. ECON. 505, 507-10 (2006) (describing how truthful advertising to misinformed consumers does not always increase profitability);
  • 78
    • 0742271634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70
    • arguing that the costs of changing the way buyers shop will outweigh the small value that marketing is likely to achieve
    • Russell Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1203, 1242-43 (2003) (arguing that the costs of changing the way buyers shop will outweigh the small value that marketing is likely to achieve).
    • (2003) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1203 , pp. 1242-1243
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 79
    • 41449111028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein appears to retract his acknowledgment of the collective action problem, at
    • Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120. In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein appears to retract his acknowledgment of the collective action problem.
    • Behavioral Economics, supra note , vol.1 , pp. 120
    • Epstein1
  • 80
    • 41449095371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 818-19. Using a five-seller example, he argues that [i]f there is only a 50% chance that any one of these [sellers] will deviate from the cooperative mode [i.e., form the low quality equilibrium], then the odds are only 1 in 32 that the collusive equilibrium will stick.
    • See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 818-19. Using a five-seller example, he argues that "[i]f there is only a 50% chance that any one of these [sellers] will deviate from the cooperative mode [i.e., form the low quality equilibrium], then the odds are only 1 in 32 that the collusive equilibrium will stick."
  • 83
    • 77951963656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a New Model of Consumer Protection: The Problem of Inflated Transaction Costs, 47
    • noting reasons why sellers do not advertise terms that consumers would like to know
    • Jeff Sovern, Toward a New Model of Consumer Protection: The Problem of Inflated Transaction Costs, 47 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1635, 1680-81 (2006) (noting reasons why sellers do not advertise terms that consumers would like to know);
    • (2006) WM. & MARY L. REV , vol.1635 , pp. 1680-1681
    • Sovern, J.1
  • 84
    • 41449105141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: A Response to Market Manipulation, 6 ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 259, 336-37 (2000) (describing the possible effects of a manufacturer's effort to educate consumers on product safety, including a reduction in the overall demand for the product).
    • see also Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: A Response to Market Manipulation, 6 ROGER WILLIAMS U. L. REV. 259, 336-37 (2000) (describing the possible effects of a manufacturer's effort to educate consumers on product safety, including a reduction in the overall demand for the product).
  • 86
    • 4043058651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edward L. Glaeser, Psychology and the Market, 94 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 408, 409-11 (2004) (Markets do not eliminate (and often exacerbate) irrationality . . . . The advertising industry is the most important economic example of these systematic attempts to mislead, where suppliers attempt to convince buyers that their products will yield remarkable benefits. . . . It is certainly not true that competition ensures that false beliefs will be dissipated. Indeed, in many cases competition will work to increase the supply of these falsehoods . . . .).
    • See Edward L. Glaeser, Psychology and the Market, 94 AM. ECON. REV. (PAPERS & PROC.) 408, 409-11 (2004) ("Markets do not eliminate (and often exacerbate) irrationality . . . . The advertising industry is the most important economic example of these systematic attempts to mislead, where suppliers attempt to convince buyers that their products will yield remarkable benefits. . . . It is certainly not true that competition ensures that false beliefs will be dissipated. Indeed, in many cases competition will work to increase the supply of these falsehoods . . . .").
  • 87
    • 33645781946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaeser argues, however, that government decision makers have weaker incentives than consumers to overcome errors, and thus intervention in markets might make things worse. See Edward L. Glaeser, Paternalism and Psychology, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 133, 143-44 (2006).
    • Glaeser argues, however, that government decision makers have weaker incentives than consumers to overcome errors, and thus intervention in markets might make things worse. See Edward L. Glaeser, Paternalism and Psychology, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 133, 143-44 (2006).
  • 88
    • 41449095463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The evidence summarized is drawn from the synthesis of existing studies that focus on borrowing behavior in Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 19-33. In addition, experimental evidence suggests that credit cards affect spending behavior.
    • The evidence summarized is drawn from the synthesis of existing studies that focus on borrowing behavior in Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 19-33. In addition, experimental evidence suggests that credit cards affect spending behavior.
  • 89
    • 0005536474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay, 12
    • discussing evidence that the method of payment, credit card or cash, affects people's willingness to pay, See
    • See Drazen Prelec & Duncan Simester, Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay, 12 MARKETING LETTERS 5, 11 (2001) (discussing evidence that the method of payment - credit card or cash - affects people's willingness to pay);
    • (2001) MARKETING LETTERS , vol.5 , pp. 11
    • Prelec, D.1    Simester, D.2
  • 90
    • 41449110516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also GEORGE RITZER, EXPRESSING AMERICA: A CRITIQUE OF THE GLOBAL CREDIT CARD SOCIETY 5-7, 13 (1995);
    • see also GEORGE RITZER, EXPRESSING AMERICA: A CRITIQUE OF THE GLOBAL CREDIT CARD SOCIETY 5-7, 13 (1995);
  • 91
    • 0000415392 scopus 로고
    • Credit Cards as Spending Facilitating Stimuli: A Conditioning Interpretation, 13
    • T]he presence of credit card stimuli enhances the magnitude of spending
    • Richard A. Feinberg, Credit Cards as Spending Facilitating Stimuli: A Conditioning Interpretation, 13 J. CONSUMER RES. 348, 354-55 (1986) ("[T]he presence of credit card stimuli enhances the magnitude of spending.");
    • (1986) J. CONSUMER RES , vol.348 , pp. 354-355
    • Feinberg, R.A.1
  • 92
    • 41449107265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth C Hirschman, Differences in Consumer Purchase Behavior by Credit Card Payment System, 6 J. CONSUMER RES. 58, 64-65 (1979) ([P]ossession of a bank card or store-issued card appears to be positively related to higher levels of in-store expenditures and to a greater incidence of in-store purchasing.);
    • Elizabeth C Hirschman, Differences in Consumer Purchase Behavior by Credit Card Payment System, 6 J. CONSUMER RES. 58, 64-65 (1979) ("[P]ossession of a bank card or store-issued card appears to be positively related to higher levels of in-store expenditures and to a greater incidence of in-store purchasing.");
  • 93
    • 0030494605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael McCall & Heather J. Belmont, Credit Card Insignia and Restaurant Tipping: Evidence for an Associative Link, 81 J. APPLIED PSYCHOL. 609, 612-13 (1996) (showing evidence of increased tipping by consumers using credit cards instead of cash);
    • Michael McCall & Heather J. Belmont, Credit Card Insignia and Restaurant Tipping: Evidence for an Associative Link, 81 J. APPLIED PSYCHOL. 609, 612-13 (1996) (showing evidence of increased tipping by consumers using credit cards instead of cash);
  • 94
    • 0035531896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Effects of Payment Mechanism on Spending Behavior: The Role of Rehearsal and Immediacy of Payments, 27
    • showing that consumers paying by credit cards are more likely to make additional discretionary purchases
    • Dilip Soman, Effects of Payment Mechanism on Spending Behavior: The Role of Rehearsal and Immediacy of Payments, 27 J. CONSUMER RES. 460, 472-74 (2001) (showing that consumers paying by credit cards are more likely to make additional discretionary purchases).
    • (2001) J. CONSUMER RES , vol.460 , pp. 472-474
    • Soman, D.1
  • 95
    • 41449118483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Haiyan Shui & Lawrence M. Ausubel, Time Inconsistency in the Credit Card Market 2-3 (May 3, 2004) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=586622).
    • See Haiyan Shui & Lawrence M. Ausubel, Time Inconsistency in the Credit Card Market 2-3 (May 3, 2004) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=586622).
  • 96
    • 41449097564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 3
    • Id. at 3.
  • 97
    • 41449099888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The evidence shows that most consumers do not jump from one card to another and from one teaser rate to another. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1392;
    • The evidence shows that most consumers do not jump from one card to another and from one teaser rate to another. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1392;
  • 98
    • 41449099091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also infra Part III.B.1. But detailed statistics are not necessary to conclude that consumers do not jump from one teaser rate to another; it is evident from the fact that issuers offer teaser rates. Unless issuers have decided to forgo interest revenues altogether issuers would not offer teaser rates if most consumers did not stay beyond the introductory period. And it is clear that most issuers have not decided to forgo interest revenues altogether. In fact, in 2006 interest revenues represented 65% of issuers' total revenues.
    • see also infra Part III.B.1. But detailed statistics are not necessary to conclude that consumers do not jump from one teaser rate to another; it is evident from the fact that issuers offer teaser rates. Unless issuers have decided to forgo interest revenues altogether issuers would not offer teaser rates if most consumers did not stay beyond the introductory period. And it is clear that most issuers have not decided to forgo interest revenues altogether. In fact, in 2006 interest revenues represented 65% of issuers' total revenues.
  • 99
    • 41449117438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY 11 (Sandra L. Budde ed., 19th ed. 2007) (listing interest revenues as $75.15 billion and issuers' total revenues as $114.99 billion).
    • Cf. CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY 11 (Sandra L. Budde ed., 19th ed. 2007) (listing interest revenues as $75.15 billion and issuers' total revenues as $114.99 billion).
  • 100
    • 41449089603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 3 n.4.
    • Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 3 n.4.
  • 101
    • 41449087157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Shui & Ausubel study, the introductory rates were between 4.9% and 7.9, while the post-introductory rate was 16, Id. at 2, 7
    • In the Shui & Ausubel study, the introductory rates were between 4.9% and 7.9%, while the post-introductory rate was 16%. Id. at 2, 7.
  • 102
    • 41449088338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8
    • Id. at 8.
  • 103
    • 41449114389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2-3
    • Id. at 2-3.
  • 104
    • 41449108669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8
    • Id. at 8.
  • 105
    • 41449101355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 7
    • Id. at 7.
  • 106
    • 41449117898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that all the credit cards had a post-introductory rate of 16%, though the point at which this rate began differed. Id.
    • Note that all the credit cards had a post-introductory rate of 16%, though the point at which this rate began differed. Id.
  • 108
    • 41449095462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 824. But most consumers do not time the acquisition of a new card with large expenditures. Epstein's hypothesis is inconsistent with the data that most borrowing is done at the high post-introductory rates.
    • Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 824. But most consumers do not time the acquisition of a new card with large expenditures. Epstein's hypothesis is inconsistent with the data that most borrowing is done at the high post-introductory rates.
  • 110
    • 41449113887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lawrence M. Ausubel, Credit Card Defaults, Credit Card Profits, and Bankruptcy, 71 AM. BANKR. L.J. 249, 263 (1997) ([A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . .).
    • see also Lawrence M. Ausubel, Credit Card Defaults, Credit Card Profits, and Bankruptcy, 71 AM. BANKR. L.J. 249, 263 (1997) ("[A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . .").
  • 111
    • 41449090761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7
    • See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7.
  • 112
    • 41449100076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 114
    • 0344540194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data, 117
    • See
    • See David B. Gross & Nicholas S. Souleles, Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data, 117 Q.J. ECON. 149 (2002).
    • (2002) Q.J. ECON , vol.149
    • Gross, D.B.1    Souleles, N.S.2
  • 115
    • 41449103904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 180
    • Id. at 180.
  • 116
    • 41449118097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 117
    • 41449118101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 118
    • 41449104096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stephan Meier & Charles Sprenger, Impatience and Credit Behavior: Evidence from a Field Experiment (Fed. Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper No. 07-03, 2007), available at http://www.bos.frb.org/ economic/wp/wp2007/wp0703.pdf.
    • See Stephan Meier & Charles Sprenger, Impatience and Credit Behavior: Evidence from a Field Experiment (Fed. Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper No. 07-03, 2007), available at http://www.bos.frb.org/ economic/wp/wp2007/wp0703.pdf.
  • 119
    • 41449101557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 5
    • Id. at 5.
  • 121
    • 41449110141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 2-3
    • Id. at 2-3.
  • 125
    • 41449108484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also infra note 74. A different critique, not mentioned by Epstein, argues that sellers will not respond to consumer mistakes as long as there are enough consumers that do not make these mistakes.
    • see also infra note 74. A different critique, not mentioned by Epstein, argues that sellers will not respond to consumer mistakes as long as there are enough consumers that do not make these mistakes.
  • 126
    • 41449091312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Alan Schwartz & Louis L. Wilde, Intervening in Markets on the Basis of Imperfect Information: A Legal and Economic Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 630, 638-39 (1979) (providing this informed minority argument for the first time in legal and economic literature). This argument does not apply when sellers can screen for sophisticated consumers. And, of course, it is not at all clear that there is a sufficiently large number of sophisticated, informed buyers in all markets.
    • See Alan Schwartz & Louis L. Wilde, Intervening in Markets on the Basis of Imperfect Information: A Legal and Economic Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 630, 638-39 (1979) (providing this "informed minority" argument for the first time in legal and economic literature). This argument does not apply when sellers can screen for sophisticated consumers. And, of course, it is not at all clear that there is a sufficiently large number of sophisticated, informed buyers in all markets.
  • 127
    • 41449105138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sovern, supra note 49, at 1668-72 and sources cited therein.
    • See Sovern, supra note 49, at 1668-72 and sources cited therein.
  • 128
    • 41449111028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein's critique focuses on my theory of misperception-based bundling. See, at
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120-22. Epstein's critique focuses on my theory of misperception-based bundling.
    • Behavioral Economics, supra note , vol.1 , pp. 120-122
    • Epstein1
  • 129
    • 41449099090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 120-21 & n.28 [B]ecause 'sellers get the same total price under [different] pricing schemes,' they will rationally choose to give the tying product away for free and charge above the marginal cost for the tied product to offset losses.
    • Id. at 120-21 & n.28 ("[B]ecause 'sellers get the same total price under [different] pricing schemes,' they will rationally choose to give the tying product away for free and charge above the marginal cost for the tied product to offset losses."
  • 132
    • 41449103713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein makes another argument that is specific to the bundling response that I study in Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, supra note 2, at 34-35. In that paper I discuss the example of home printing and show that when consumers underestimate the amount of printing that they will do, sellers will bundle together printers and ink, give away printers for free, and set a high price for ink.
    • Epstein makes another argument that is specific to the bundling response that I study in Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, supra note 2, at 34-35. In that paper I discuss the example of home printing and show that when consumers underestimate the amount of printing that they will do, sellers will bundle together printers and ink, give away printers for free, and set a high price for ink.
  • 133
    • 41449118658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 134
    • 41449086597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein argues that this strategy is vulnerable to exploitation by savvy consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121. These savvy consumers will take two free printers from two different suppliers and play each supplier against the other, reducing the price of ink to its unit cost.
    • Epstein argues that this strategy is vulnerable to exploitation by savvy consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121. These savvy consumers will take two free printers from two different suppliers and play each supplier against the other, reducing the price of ink to its unit cost.
  • 135
    • 41449089417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • First, it is not clear that there are enough savvy consumers to "break" the free printer/expensive ink equilibrium. Second, the savvy consumers will not affect the identified equilibrium, if sellers can screen for them
    • it is not an argument that printers are priced at cost. The main goal of my analysis was to show that printers will be sold below cost while ink will be sold above cost
    • Id. First, it is not clear that there are enough savvy consumers to "break" the free printer/expensive ink equilibrium. Second, the savvy consumers will not affect the identified equilibrium, if sellers can screen for them. Third, Epstein's argument explains why printers are not free; it is not an argument that printers are priced at cost. The main goal of my analysis was to show that printers will be sold below cost while ink will be sold above cost.
    • Third, Epstein's argument explains why printers are not free
  • 138
    • 41449083056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (stating that since some consumers are optimistic while others are pessimistic it may well be that the best strategy is to ignore these biases altogether).
    • See id. (stating that since some consumers are optimistic while others are pessimistic "it may well be that the best strategy is to ignore these biases altogether").
  • 139
    • 41449111595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If market segmentation based on the level or type of misperception is possible, then sellers will design their products and pricing schemes in response to consumer misperception even when the average bias is zero. In particular, sellers will offer one product design to the overestimators and another product design to the underestimators. Epstein does not consider the segmentation option. Id. He implicitly dismisses it by arguing that no consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level].
    • If market segmentation based on the level or type of misperception is possible, then sellers will design their products and pricing schemes in response to consumer misperception even when the average bias is zero. In particular, sellers will offer one product design to the overestimators and another product design to the underestimators. Epstein does not consider the segmentation option. Id. He implicitly dismisses it by arguing that "no consumer wears a black or white hat that indicates his or her class [i.e., bias type or bias level]."
  • 141
    • 41449106880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 130
    • Id. at 130.
  • 142
    • 41449106296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 143
    • 41449092548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 144
    • 41449117434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at n.58 (citing evidence of fifteen- and thirty-year fixed-rate prime mortgage loans).
    • Id. at n.58 (citing evidence of fifteen- and thirty-year fixed-rate prime mortgage loans).
  • 145
    • 41449088139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 146
    • 41449104095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 29-30
    • See Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 29-30.
  • 148
    • 41449116943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is not an easy task. Most design features that appear to respond to consumer misperception can also be rationalized using alternative theories which cannot be rejected in the abstract. Only a market-specific inquiry can determine the source of the identified product and price design. I conducted such an inquiry in the credit card market. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2
    • This is not an easy task. Most design features that appear to respond to consumer misperception can also be rationalized using alternative theories which cannot be rejected in the abstract. Only a market-specific inquiry can determine the source of the identified product and price design. I conducted such an inquiry in the credit card market. See Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2.
  • 149
    • 41449084231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The evidence suggests that rational choice theories cannot explain the observed pricing scheme in that market. I therefore concluded that the observed pricing scheme was designed in response to systematic consumer misperception. See id. at 1408-11
    • The evidence suggests that rational choice theories cannot explain the observed pricing scheme in that market. I therefore concluded that the observed pricing scheme was designed in response to systematic consumer misperception. See id. at 1408-11.
  • 150
    • 41449117229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The assumption, of course, is that the misperceived value is higher than the cost. Epstein analyzes an example of a one-dimensional product and a one-dimensional price and reaches the same conclusion. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120
    • The assumption, of course, is that the misperceived value is higher than the cost. Epstein analyzes an example of a one-dimensional product and a one-dimensional price and reaches the same conclusion. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 120.
  • 151
    • 41449099483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 2-3
    • See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 2-3.
  • 152
    • 41449090166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 13
    • Id. at 13.
  • 153
    • 44949249561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 49, at, O]nly a handful of consumers obtain rebates
    • See Sovern, supra note 49, at 1638 ("[O]nly a handful of consumers obtain rebates . . . .").
    • supra , pp. 1638
    • Sovern1
  • 154
    • 41449117897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1639 (Manufacturers apparently employ rebates chiefly because they increase sales by creating an illusion of a lower price, while the transaction costs generated by rebate offers permit manufacturers effectively to charge the unrebated price to most consumers.).
    • See id. at 1639 ("Manufacturers apparently employ rebates chiefly because they increase sales by creating an illusion of a lower price, while the transaction costs generated by rebate offers permit manufacturers effectively to charge the unrebated price to most consumers.").
  • 155
    • 41449090565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An alternative explanation for rebates, which does not rely on consumer misperception, views rebates as a mechanism for price discrimination. See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 40 noting that rebates can be used to charge some customers more than others because, for instance, wealthier consumers may be less likely to turn in the rebate
    • An alternative explanation for rebates, which does not rely on consumer misperception, views rebates as a mechanism for price discrimination. See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 40 (noting that rebates can be used to charge some customers more than others because, for instance, wealthier consumers may be less likely to turn in the rebate
  • 156
    • 25144435947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price Discrimination After the Purchase: Rebates as State-Dependent Discounts, 51
    • This alternative explanation is plausible in some markets and less plausible in others, citing
    • (citing Yuxin Chen et al., Price Discrimination After the Purchase: Rebates as State-Dependent Discounts, 51 MGMT. SCI. 1131, 1131 (2005))). This alternative explanation is plausible in some markets and less plausible in others.
    • (2005) MGMT. SCI , vol.1131 , pp. 1131
    • Chen, Y.1
  • 157
    • 41449099287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Late payment may impose an extra cost on the issuer, but this cost surely does not amount to $40 or more for a two-day delay in making a minimum payment of $40
    • Late payment may impose an extra cost on the issuer, but this cost surely does not amount to $40 or more for a two-day delay in making a minimum payment of $40.
  • 158
    • 41449083443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C. As with rebates, there is an alternative, rational choice explanation for late fees: if consumers with higher default risk are more likely to pay late (before defaulting), then late fees provide a screening mechanism that can prevent a lemons problem. While theoretically valid, the practical explanatory power of this rational choice account is limited. First, it relies on the assumption that borrowers have superior information about their default risk. This assumption is questionable given issuers' sophisticated risk assessment methods.
    • See infra Part II.C. As with rebates, there is an alternative, rational choice explanation for late fees: if consumers with higher default risk are more likely to pay late (before defaulting), then late fees provide a screening mechanism that can prevent a "lemons" problem. While theoretically valid, the practical explanatory power of this rational choice account is limited. First, it relies on the assumption that borrowers have superior information about their default risk. This assumption is questionable given issuers' sophisticated risk assessment methods.
  • 159
    • 41449107648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC 105-07 (2d ed. 2005). Second, the rational choice/asymmetric information theory assumes that late payment provides valuable, new information to the uninformed issuers - again a questionable assumption.
    • See, e.g., DAVID S. EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC 105-07 (2d ed. 2005). Second, the rational choice/asymmetric information theory assumes that late payment provides valuable, new information to the uninformed issuers - again a questionable assumption.
  • 160
    • 41449106297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RONALD J. MANN, CHARGING AHEAD 161-63 (2006) (stating that late fees are often incurred because of mistakes, but that these late payments provide no new information on the consumer's default risk). Finally, the data do not support this rational choice account. If issuers wish to screen for high risk borrowers, they have other means at their disposal.
    • See, e.g., RONALD J. MANN, CHARGING AHEAD 161-63 (2006) (stating that late fees are often incurred because of mistakes, but that these late payments provide no new information on the consumer's default risk). Finally, the data do not support this rational choice account. If issuers wish to screen for high risk borrowers, they have other means at their disposal.
  • 161
    • 41449110869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, they can use default interest rates triggered by late payment. Indeed, since such default rates are commonly used, why are late fees needed? Specifically, why did late fees rise substantially after they were exempt from state-level regulation by the Supreme Court's Smiley v. Citibank decision in 1996? 517 U.S. 735 (1996) (finding that credit card fees could be defined as interest for regulatory purposes);
    • For example, they can use default interest rates triggered by late payment. Indeed, since such default rates are commonly used, why are late fees needed? Specifically, why did late fees rise substantially after they were exempt from state-level regulation by the Supreme Court's Smiley v. Citibank decision in 1996? 517 U.S. 735 (1996) (finding that credit card fees could be defined as "interest" for regulatory purposes);
  • 162
    • 41449094996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also TAMARA DRAUT & JAVIER SILVA, BORROWING TO MAKE ENDS MEET: THE GROWTH OF CREDIT CARD DEBT IN THE '90S, at 35 (2003), available at http://www.demos.org/pubs/ borrowing_to_make_ends_meet.pdf (discussing the increase in fee usage after Smiley).
    • see also TAMARA DRAUT & JAVIER SILVA, BORROWING TO MAKE ENDS MEET: THE GROWTH OF CREDIT CARD DEBT IN THE '90S, at 35 (2003), available at http://www.demos.org/pubs/ borrowing_to_make_ends_meet.pdf (discussing the increase in fee usage after Smiley).
  • 163
    • 41449096386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise of late fees after Smiley would make sense under the rational choice model if default interest rates triggered by late payment where reduced, but they were not. See Mark Furletti, Credit Card Pricing Developments and Their Disclosure 8 (Fed. Reserve Bank of Phila., Discussion Paper 03-02, 2003), available at http://www.philadelphiafed.org/pcc/ papers/2003/CreditCardPricing_012003.pdf (stating that issuers only started using default interest rates in the late 1990s).
    • The rise of late fees after Smiley would make sense under the rational choice model if default interest rates triggered by late payment where reduced, but they were not. See Mark Furletti, Credit Card Pricing Developments and Their Disclosure 8 (Fed. Reserve Bank of Phila., Discussion Paper 03-02, 2003), available at http://www.philadelphiafed.org/pcc/ papers/2003/CreditCardPricing_012003.pdf (stating that issuers only started using default interest rates in the late 1990s).
  • 164
    • 0001881029 scopus 로고
    • The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 81
    • See
    • See Lawrence M. Ausubel, The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 81 AM. ECON. REV. 50, 72 (1991).
    • (1991) AM. ECON. REV , vol.50 , pp. 72
    • Ausubel, L.M.1
  • 165
    • 41449096958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part ILC
    • See infra Part ILC.
    • See infra
  • 166
    • 41449113171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C.
    • See infra Part II.C.
  • 168
    • 41449087771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following example is taken from id. at 38-39.
    • The following example is taken from id. at 38-39.
  • 169
    • 41449106491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 45;
    • Id. at 45;
  • 170
    • 41449104764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 21
    • see also Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 21.
  • 171
    • 41449116743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This pricing flexibility requires that ink for a seller's printer be purchased only from the same seller. This is in fact the meaning of bundling. Such bundling can be achieved through patent protection of the printer-ink cartridge interface. A recent threat to the printer and ink bundle comes from sellers offering to refill consumers' ink cartridges. But the refill option is still limited. Questions about the quality, reliability, and ease of operation of the refill option remain. See, e.g, ConsumerReports.org, Do-It-Yourself Refills Are Cheap, But Be Prepared for a Mess, July 2006
    • This pricing flexibility requires that ink for a seller's printer be purchased only from the same seller. This is in fact the meaning of bundling. Such bundling can be achieved through patent protection of the printer-ink cartridge interface. A recent threat to the printer and ink bundle comes from sellers offering to refill consumers' ink cartridges. But the refill option is still limited. Questions about the quality, reliability, and ease of operation of the refill option remain. See, e.g., ConsumerReports.org, Do-It-Yourself Refills Are Cheap, But Be Prepared for a Mess, July 2006, http://www.consumerreports .org/cro/electronics-computers/computers/computer/ printers/printer-inks-7-06/do-it-yourself-refills/0607_printer-inks_do-it- yourself-refills.htm;
  • 172
    • 41449111420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ConsumerReports.org, Printer Inks: More Choice & Value, July 2006, http://www.consumerreports.org/cro/electronics-computers/computers/ computer/printers/printer-inks-7-06/overview/0607_printer-inks_ov.htm. But more sophisticated and effective ink refill options are emerging.
    • ConsumerReports.org, Printer Inks: More Choice & Value, July 2006, http://www.consumerreports.org/cro/electronics-computers/computers/ computer/printers/printer-inks-7-06/overview/0607_printer-inks_ov.htm. But more sophisticated and effective ink refill options are emerging.
  • 173
    • 41449102589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Tom Mainelli, Inke Unveils Clean, Cheap Ink Jet Refills, PC WORLD, Jan. 8, 2006, http://www.pcworld.com/article/id,114170- page,1/article.html. Printer manufacturers, in an effort to sustain using the bundle, are trying to convince consumers that the refill option is inferior.
    • See, e.g., Tom Mainelli, Inke Unveils Clean, Cheap Ink Jet Refills, PC WORLD, Jan. 8, 2006, http://www.pcworld.com/article/id,114170- page,1/article.html. Printer manufacturers, in an effort to sustain using the bundle, are trying to convince consumers that the refill option is inferior.
  • 174
    • 41449110868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, the HP website refers to a commissioned study finding that ink cartridges score lower on both quality and reliability. See HP, The Truth About Ink Refills and Remanufactured Ink, http://h71036.www7.hp.com/hho/ cache/546038-0-0-225-121.html?jumpid-reg_ R1002_USEN (last visited Nov. 30, 2007)
    • For example, the HP website refers to a commissioned study finding that ink cartridges score lower on both quality and reliability. See HP, The Truth About Ink Refills and Remanufactured Ink, http://h71036.www7.hp.com/hho/ cache/546038-0-0-225-121.html?jumpid-reg_ R1002_USEN (last visited Nov. 30, 2007)
  • 175
    • 41449089074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (directing users to QUALITYLOGIC, RELIABILITY COMPARISON STUDY: HP INKJET PRINT CARTRIDGES VS. REFILLED BRANDS: CARTRIDGE RELIABILITY, PRINT QUALITY (2005), http://www.hp.com/united-states/consumer/inkjet/qualitylogic_study.pdf).
    • (directing users to QUALITYLOGIC, RELIABILITY COMPARISON STUDY: HP INKJET PRINT CARTRIDGES VS. REFILLED BRANDS: CARTRIDGE RELIABILITY, PRINT QUALITY (2005), http://www.hp.com/united-states/consumer/inkjet/qualitylogic_study.pdf).
  • 176
    • 41449098730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These efforts are at least partially successful, ink cartridge sales are a multibillion dollar business for HP, See John Lui, HP Holds Patent for Ink-Refill Device, ZDNET.CO.UK, Oct. 20, 2003, 1000000183,39117220,00.htm
    • These efforts are at least partially successful - ink cartridge sales are a multibillion dollar business for HP, See John Lui, HP Holds Patent for Ink-Refill Device, ZDNET.CO.UK, Oct. 20, 2003, http://news.zdnet.co.uk/emergingtech/0,1000000183,39117220,00.htm.
  • 177
    • 41449100629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein argues that there are sophisticated, business buyers of printers and ink and that less-sophisticated consumers free-ride off the expertise of these more-sophisticated buyers. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 830. Such free-riding is possible, however, only if sellers cannot segment the market and differentiate between the sophisticated business buyers and the less-sophisticated consumers. While further empirical investigation is necessary, casual observation suggests that the printers market is at least partially segmented.
    • In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein argues that there are sophisticated, business buyers of printers and ink and that less-sophisticated consumers free-ride off the expertise of these more-sophisticated buyers. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 830. Such free-riding is possible, however, only if sellers cannot segment the market and differentiate between the sophisticated business buyers and the less-sophisticated consumers. While further empirical investigation is necessary, casual observation suggests that the printers market is at least partially segmented.
  • 178
    • 33744548714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stefano Della Vigna & Ulrike Malmendier, Paying Not to Go to the Gym, 96 AM. ECON. REV. 694, 714 (2006) ([F]lat-rate contracts are on average more profitable for the health clubs than pay-per-visit contracts. Health club employees, therefore, have incentive to persuade consumers to sign flat-rate contracts.).
    • See Stefano Della Vigna & Ulrike Malmendier, Paying Not to Go to the Gym, 96 AM. ECON. REV. 694, 714 (2006) ("[F]lat-rate contracts are on average more profitable for the health clubs than pay-per-visit contracts. Health club employees, therefore, have incentive to persuade consumers to sign flat-rate contracts.").
  • 179
    • 41449097561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For evidence of the large disparity between the expected and the actual number of health club visits, see id
    • For evidence of the large disparity between the expected and the actual number of health club visits, see id.
  • 180
    • 41449102395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects § 2.3.1 (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 917785) ([F]irms are willing to price below cost in period 1 to acquire the customer who will become a valuable follow-on purchaser in period 2 . . . .).
    • Cf. Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and Network Effects § 2.3.1 (unpublished manuscript, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 917785) ("[F]irms are willing to price below cost in period 1 to acquire the customer who will become a valuable follow-on purchaser in period 2 . . . .").
  • 181
    • 41449096576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7-8
    • See, e.g., Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 7-8.
  • 182
    • 41449113884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.4.5.
    • Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.4.5.
  • 183
    • 41449088336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 2.8.3.
    • See id. § 2.8.3.
  • 184
    • 41449099694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2
    • See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2.
  • 185
    • 41449114602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at xii, 164-67 ([Credit card issuers] have chosen to collect a larger portion of their revenues from finance charges. This pattern may arise in part because of their view that the overall demand for credit is relatively insensitive to interest rates, a view supported by at least one empirical study and considerable folklore within the industry.).
    • See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at xii, 164-67 ("[Credit card issuers] have chosen to collect a larger portion of their revenues from finance charges. This pattern may arise in part because of their view that the overall demand for credit is relatively insensitive to interest rates, a view supported by at least one empirical study and considerable folklore within the industry.").
  • 186
    • 41449117612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ausubel, supra note 95, at 72 ([T]he experience of credit card marketers is that consumers are much more sensitive to increases in the annual fee than to commensurate increases in the interest rate . . . .).
    • See Ausubel, supra note 95, at 72 ("[T]he experience
  • 187
    • 41449109394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bar-Gill, supra note 2, at 1401-02.
    • See Bar-Gill, supra note 2, at 1401-02.
  • 188
    • 41449104950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2-3
    • See Furletti, supra note 94, at 2-3.
  • 189
    • 41449086242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 190
    • 41449089981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 10-14.
    • See id. at 10-14.
  • 191
    • 41449108257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Beasley v. Wells Fargo Bank, 1 Cal. Rptr. 2d 446 (Ct. App. 1991), the bank's Credit Card Task Force proposed increasing late and overlimit fees as a good source of revenue.
    • In Beasley v. Wells Fargo Bank, 1 Cal. Rptr. 2d 446 (Ct. App. 1991), the bank's "Credit Card Task Force" proposed increasing "late" and "overlimit" fees as a "good source of revenue."
  • 192
    • 41449101175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 448
    • Id. at 448.
  • 193
    • 41449104949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penalty fees are perceived as a good source of revenue, because the industry perceives that there (are) very few cardholders that switch cards because the late fee is too high. Credit Card Fees Soar Again, CNNMONEY.COM, Aug. 18, 1998, http://money.cnn.com/1998/08/18/banking/ q_bankrate (quoting Peter Davidson, Executive Vice President, Speer & Associates) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • Penalty fees are perceived as a good source of revenue, because the industry perceives that "there (are) very few cardholders that switch cards because the late fee is too high." Credit Card Fees Soar Again, CNNMONEY.COM, Aug. 18, 1998, http://money.cnn.com/1998/08/18/banking/ q_bankrate (quoting Peter Davidson, Executive Vice President, Speer & Associates) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 194
    • 41449091862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fee Income, CARDFLASH, Jan. 10, 2007 (subscription-restricted Internet source, on file with the author).
    • See Fee Income, CARDFLASH, Jan. 10, 2007 (subscription-restricted Internet source, on file with the author).
  • 195
    • 41449086955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penalty fees began their rapid growth in 1996 when the Supreme Court, in Smiley v. Citibank, 517 U.S. 735, 735 (1996), exempted late and over-limit fees from state-level regulation.
    • Penalty fees began their rapid growth in 1996 when the Supreme Court, in Smiley v. Citibank, 517 U.S. 735, 735 (1996), exempted late and over-limit fees from state-level regulation.
  • 196
    • 41449103551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35
    • See also DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35.
  • 197
    • 41449083244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY, supra note 54, at 11
    • See CARD INDUSTRY DIRECTORY, supra note 54, at 11.
  • 198
    • 41449112563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, CREDIT CARDS: INCREASED COMPLEXITY IN RATES AND FEES HEIGHTENS NEED FOR MORE EFFECTIVE DISCLOSURES TO CONSUMERS 49 (2006).
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, CREDIT CARDS: INCREASED COMPLEXITY IN RATES AND FEES HEIGHTENS NEED FOR MORE EFFECTIVE DISCLOSURES TO CONSUMERS 49 (2006).
  • 199
    • 41449111967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 2005 Credit Card Survey, CONSUMER ACTION NEWS (Consumer Action, San Francisco, Cal.) Summer 2005, at 1, available at http://www.consumer-action.org/downloads/english/ CC_Issue_2005.pdf (detailing the most prevalent triggers of universal default rate hikes).
    • See 2005 Credit Card Survey, CONSUMER ACTION NEWS (Consumer Action, San Francisco, Cal.) Summer 2005, at 1, available at http://www.consumer-action.org/downloads/english/ CC_Issue_2005.pdf (detailing the most prevalent triggers of universal default rate hikes).
  • 200
    • 41449097751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 49-50
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 49-50.
  • 201
    • 41449098913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1407 (describing how consumers underestimate the probability of paying late or exceeding their credit limit),
    • Compare Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1407 (describing how consumers underestimate "the probability of paying late or exceeding their credit limit"),
  • 202
    • 41449101839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • with 2005 Credit Card Survey, supra note 121, at 1 (stating that paying late and going over the credit limit are important factors contributing to a universal default rate hike). Another recent innovation also magnifies the cost of penalty fees. Some issuers are dividing up credit extensions between multiple cards so that a customer with a $2500 credit limit will be issued five cards with five $500 limits (instead of a single card with a $2500 limit).
    • with 2005 Credit Card Survey, supra note 121, at 1 (stating that paying late and going over the credit limit are important factors contributing to a universal default rate hike). Another recent innovation also magnifies the cost of penalty fees. Some issuers are dividing up credit extensions between multiple cards so that a customer with a $2500 credit limit will be issued five cards with five $500 limits (instead of a single card with a $2500 limit).
  • 203
    • 33750852808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Five cards mean five opportunities to pay late fees, overlimit fees, etc. See Robert Berner, Cap One's Credit Trap
    • Nov. 6, at
    • Five cards mean five opportunities to pay late fees, overlimit fees, etc. See Robert Berner, Cap One's Credit Trap, BUS. WK., Nov. 6, 2006, at 35, 35.
    • (2006) BUS. WK
  • 204
    • 41449084232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein argues that introductory periods with low introductory rates are a reasonable mechanism for providing valuable information to rational consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129-31. In making this argument, Epstein relies on the free samples in a bakery analogy: So what is wrong with teaser rates anyhow? Go into any bakery and there are free samples that are intended to entice customers into purchases.
    • Epstein argues that introductory periods with low introductory rates are a reasonable mechanism for providing valuable information to rational consumers. Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129-31. In making this argument, Epstein relies on the free samples in a bakery analogy: "So what is wrong with teaser rates anyhow? Go into any bakery and there are free samples that are intended to entice customers into purchases."
  • 205
    • 41449106295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is significant uncertainty about the quality of the baker's product. But money is money. Epstein himself argues that issuers are offering a standardized good
    • Id. at 131. This analogy is inapt. There is significant uncertainty about the quality of the baker's product. But money is money. Epstein himself argues that issuers are offering a standardized good.
    • at 131. This analogy is inapt
  • 207
    • 41449092066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 129-131. This is unconvincing, however, as survey evidence suggests that customer service is not among the product attributes that attract most consumers.
    • See id. at 129-131. This is unconvincing, however, as survey evidence suggests that customer service is not among the product attributes that attract most consumers.
  • 208
    • 41449093503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225
    • See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225.
  • 210
    • 41449103339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 263 ([A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . . Thus finance charges paid to credit card issuers have not dropped as much as the introductory offers might suggest.);
    • See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 263 ("[A] substantial portion of credit card borrowing still occurs at post-introductory interest rates . . . . Thus finance charges paid to credit card issuers have not dropped as much as the introductory offers might suggest.");
  • 211
    • 41449085507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David I. Laibson et al., A Debt Puzzle, in KNOWLEDGE, INFORMATION, AND EXPECTATIONS IN MODERN MACRO-ECONOMICS: IN HONOR OF EDMUND S. PHELPS 228, 228-29 (Philippe Aghion et al. eds., 2003) (finding that consumers pay high effective interest rates [d]espite the rise of teaser interest rates).
    • David I. Laibson et al., A Debt Puzzle, in KNOWLEDGE, INFORMATION, AND EXPECTATIONS IN MODERN MACRO-ECONOMICS: IN HONOR OF EDMUND S. PHELPS 228, 228-29 (Philippe Aghion et al. eds., 2003) (finding that consumers pay high effective interest rates "[d]espite the rise of teaser interest rates").
  • 212
    • 41449117436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26
    • Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26.
  • 213
    • 41449096020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.8.3.
    • Cf. Farrel & Klemperer, supra note 105, § 2.8.3.
  • 214
    • 41449094653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1406 (describing how rational consumers would anticipate the lock-in effect, but that most consumers are not rational in this respect).
    • Cf. Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, supra note 2, at 1406 (describing how rational consumers would anticipate the lock-in effect, but that most consumers are not rational in this respect).
  • 215
    • 41449110140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1407
    • Id. at 1407.
  • 216
    • 41449116361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1405-07.
    • Id. at 1405-07.
  • 217
    • 41449107457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lawrence M. Ausubel, Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market 21 (June 17, 1999) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.ausubel .com/ere ditcard-papers/adverse.pdf).
    • Lawrence M. Ausubel, Adverse Selection in the Credit Card Market 21 (June 17, 1999) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://www.ausubel .com/ere ditcard-papers/adverse.pdf).
  • 218
    • 41449087944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225
    • See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 94, at 225.
  • 219
    • 41449104760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 27 (noting how in most cases cardholder payments [are] allocated first to the balance that is assessed the lowest rate of interest).
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 27 (noting how in most cases "cardholder payments [are] allocated first to the balance that is assessed the lowest rate of interest").
  • 222
    • 41449105727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 224
    • 41449103342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 94, at, arguing that a causal link exists between credit card debt and bankruptcy filings
    • See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68 (arguing that a causal link exists between credit card debt and bankruptcy filings).
    • supra , pp. 66-68
    • MANN1
  • 225
    • 41449109034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, 3 CHAP. L. REV. 79, 82, 166-70 (2000) (arguing that such a causal link does not exist).
    • But see Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, 3 CHAP. L. REV. 79, 82, 166-70 (2000) (arguing that such a causal link does not exist).
  • 227
    • 41449099883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 228
    • 41449110698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 229
    • 41449089414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumers who are perfectly informed and perfectly rational will take advantage of the available credit only when the benefit of credit exceeds the expected cost of credit, specifically, the costs of financial distress that might lead to bankruptcy
    • Consumers who are perfectly informed and perfectly rational will take advantage of the available credit only when the benefit of credit exceeds the expected cost of credit, specifically, the costs of financial distress that might lead to bankruptcy.
  • 231
    • 41449089215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 232
    • 41449089980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 233
    • 41449091864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 234
    • 41449100434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68
    • See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
  • 235
    • 41449092549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. id. at 67 contrasting credit card debt with other types of consumer
    • Cf. id. at 67 (contrasting credit card debt with other types of consumer
  • 236
    • 41449084233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • debt such as mortgages and loans
    • debt such as mortgages and loans).
  • 238
    • 41449116942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
    • 280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
  • 240
    • 41449108072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rossman, 280 F.3d at 387-89.
    • Rossman, 280 F.3d at 387-89.
  • 241
    • 41449113170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 394-95
    • Id. at 394-95.
  • 243
    • 41449111968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 127
    • Id. at 127.
  • 244
    • 41449114934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 126-27
    • See id. at 126-27
  • 245
    • 41449107071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • (quoting Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 246
    • 41449087546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 127.
    • See id. at 127.
  • 247
    • 41449110515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 248
    • 41449086245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26
    • See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 25-26.
  • 249
    • 41449104951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 171
    • See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 171.
  • 251
    • 41449111219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (noting that most borrowing is done at high post-promotion rates rather than at low teaser rates).
    • See id. (noting that most borrowing is done at high post-promotion rates rather than at low teaser rates).
  • 252
    • 41449090760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 127 (noting that because most people have multiple credit cards, an increase in rates on one card will likely generate a migration of business elsewhere).
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 127 (noting that because most people have multiple credit cards, an increase in rates on one card will likely generate a migration of business elsewhere).
  • 253
    • 41449117433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Banks, self-interest is a powerful market constraint against excessive borrowing
    • See id. ("[Banks'] self-interest is a powerful market constraint against excessive borrowing.").
    • See id
  • 255
    • 41449088136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57 analyzing bankruptcy data alongside credit card delinquency and credit card chargeoff data
    • See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57 (analyzing bankruptcy data alongside credit card delinquency and credit card chargeoff data).
  • 256
    • 41449111220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 257
    • 33947201787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ronald J. Mann, Bankruptcy Reform and the Sweat Box of Credit Card Debt, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 375, 386-90.
    • See Ronald J. Mann, Bankruptcy Reform and the "Sweat Box" of Credit Card Debt, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 375, 386-90.
  • 259
    • 41449089076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57
    • See Ausubel, supra note 61, at 251-57.
  • 260
    • 41449103341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mann, supra note 94, at 385-86 (For the credit card lender, the first hint of sustained profitability comes when the cardholder (now borrower) stops regularly paying her balance in full each month.).
    • See Mann, supra note 94, at 385-86 ("For the credit card lender, the first hint of sustained profitability comes when the cardholder (now borrower) stops regularly paying her balance in full each month.").
  • 262
    • 41449096384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 8. The $250 cost of failing to switch cards post-introductory period was calculated by multiplying the average balance on credit cards ($2500) by the common margin between introductory and post-introductory interest rates (10%).
    • See Shui & Ausubel, supra note 53, at 8. The $250 cost of failing to switch cards post-introductory period was calculated by multiplying the average balance on credit cards ($2500) by the common margin between introductory and post-introductory interest rates (10%).
  • 263
    • 41449097934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 264
    • 41449090563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 178-80. More than 90% of consumers with credit card debts have some liquid assets in checking and savings accounts, and one-third of credit card borrowers hold more than one month's income in these liquid assets.
    • See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 178-80. More than 90% of consumers with credit card debts have some liquid assets in checking and savings accounts, and one-third of credit card borrowers hold more than one month's income in these liquid assets.
  • 265
    • 41449104093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. With a median balance of more than $2000 (conditional on having a balance, i.e., the median balance among consumers who have a positive balance) and a spread of 10% between credit card interest rates and interest rates on checking and savings accounts, a typical consumer is losing more than $200 a year in interest payments.
    • Id. With a median balance of more than $2000 (conditional on having a balance, i.e., the median balance among consumers who have a positive balance) and a spread of 10% between credit card interest rates and interest rates on checking and savings accounts, a typical consumer is losing more than $200 a year in interest payments.
  • 266
    • 41449111786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 267
    • 41449097385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent evidence shows a causal link between unsafe financial products and financial distress, including bankruptcy. See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
    • Recent evidence shows a causal link between unsafe financial products and financial distress, including bankruptcy. See MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
  • 268
    • 41449108258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This number is based on the following data: about seventeen million households open a new general purpose credit card account each year and about 50% of new accounts include introductory rates. Fixed Rate vs. Intro Rate, CARDFLASH, July 29, 1999 subscription required Internet source, on file with the author, reporting findings from a 1999 study of account acquisition and attrition conducted by PSI Global, Additionally, at least 50% of cardholders carry a balance
    • This number is based on the following data: about seventeen million households open a new general purpose credit card account each year and about 50% of new accounts include introductory rates. Fixed Rate vs. Intro Rate, CARDFLASH, July 29, 1999 (subscription required Internet source, on file with the author) (reporting findings from a 1999 study of account acquisition and attrition conducted by PSI Global). Additionally, at least 50% of cardholders carry a balance.
  • 269
    • 41449108668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 151 (discussing the number of households that carry a balance on their cards). I recognize that cards with introductory offers might be issued at different rates to borrowing and nonborrowing consumers/households. Nevertheless, the preceding calculation probably yields a conservative estimate, if issuers are more likely to target introductory offers to borrowers and/or if borrowers are more likely to be attracted by introductory offers.
    • See Gross & Souleles, supra note 65, at 151 (discussing the number of households that carry a balance on their cards). I recognize that cards with introductory offers might be issued at different rates to borrowing and nonborrowing consumers/households. Nevertheless, the preceding calculation probably yields a conservative estimate, if issuers are more likely to target introductory offers to borrowers and/or if borrowers are more likely to be attracted by introductory offers.
  • 270
    • 41449102397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein correctly points out that the $350 million figure is not a direct social cost. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 825. Rather, it is a transfer from consumers to issuers or, in a competitive market, from one group of consumers-those who make mistakes - to another group of consumers - those who do not make mistakes. Still, such a transfer from a weaker group to a stronger group constitutes a social cost.
    • In his contribution to this Exchange, Epstein correctly points out that the $350 million figure is not a direct social cost. See Epstein, Exchange, Neoclassical Economics, supra note 4, at 825. Rather, it is a transfer from consumers to issuers or, in a competitive market, from one group of consumers-those who make mistakes - to another group of consumers - those who do not make mistakes. Still, such a transfer from a weaker group to a stronger group constitutes a social cost.
  • 271
    • 41449088530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68
    • MANN, supra note 94, at 66-68.
  • 272
    • 41449093697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Adam Feibelman, Defining the Social Insurance Function of Consumer Bankruptcy, 13 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 129, 162-63 (2005);
    • See, e.g., Adam Feibelman, Defining the Social Insurance Function of Consumer Bankruptcy, 13 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 129, 162-63 (2005);
  • 273
    • 33947270990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Melissa B. Jacoby, Bankruptcy Reform and Homeownership Risk, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 323, 330-31;
    • Melissa B. Jacoby, Bankruptcy Reform and Homeownership Risk, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 323, 330-31;
  • 274
    • 41449114760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert M. Lawless & Stephen P. Ferris, Economics and the Rhetoric of Valuation, 5 J. BANKR. L. & PRAC. 3, 8 n.22 (1995).
    • Robert M. Lawless & Stephen P. Ferris, Economics and the Rhetoric of Valuation, 5 J. BANKR. L. & PRAC. 3, 8 n.22 (1995).
  • 275
    • 0001475698 scopus 로고
    • Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom to Contract, 24
    • See
    • See Eric A. Posner, Contract Law in the Welfare State: A Defense of the Unconscionability Doctrine, Usury Laws, and Related Limitations on the Freedom to Contract, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 283, 307-08 (1995).
    • (1995) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.283 , pp. 307-308
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 276
    • 41449093104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, REPORT ON PREDATORY LENDING PRACTICES DIRECTED AT MEMBERS OF THE ARMED FORCES AND THEIR DEPENDENTS 35-36, 45, 86-87 (2006), http://www.usa4militaryfamilies. dod.mil/dav/lsn/LSN/BINARY_RESOURCE/BINARY_CONTENT/2141721.pdf.
    • U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, REPORT ON PREDATORY LENDING PRACTICES DIRECTED AT MEMBERS OF THE ARMED FORCES AND THEIR DEPENDENTS 35-36, 45, 86-87 (2006), http://www.usa4militaryfamilies. dod.mil/dav/lsn/LSN/BINARY_RESOURCE/BINARY_CONTENT/2141721.pdf.
  • 277
    • 41449090167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The DOD report also describes how military personnel in financial distress become more vulnerable to extortion and, consequently, can lose their security clearance. Id. at 35-36, 45
    • The DOD report also describes how military personnel in financial distress become more vulnerable to extortion and, consequently, can lose their security clearance. Id. at 35-36, 45.
  • 278
    • 74049118413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a similar discussion, see, note 38, at, arguing that unsafe credit products skew the distribution of resources within society, resulting in regressive redistribution
    • For a similar discussion, see Bar-Gill & Warren, supra note 38, at 36-37 (arguing that unsafe credit products skew the distribution of resources within society, resulting in regressive redistribution).
    • supra , pp. 36-37
    • Gill, B.1    Warren2
  • 279
    • 41449087543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, supra note 183, at 10-22 (describing predatory lending to enlisted military personnel who often lack the experience and education to avoid such pitfalls).
    • See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF DEFENSE, supra note 183, at 10-22 (describing predatory lending to enlisted military personnel who often lack the experience and education to avoid such pitfalls).
  • 280
    • 41449086958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 116-18, 128
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 116-18, 128.
  • 281
    • 41449118864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 125, 128.
    • See id. at 125, 128.
  • 282
    • 41449086071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Jolis et al., Behavioral Approach, supra note 3, at 1541 (engaging in a normative analysis of anti-anti-paternalism).
    • Cf. Jolis et al., Behavioral Approach, supra note 3, at 1541 (engaging in a normative analysis of anti-anti-paternalism).
  • 284
    • 41449083242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 116.
    • See id. at 116.
  • 285
    • 41449117435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 116-17.
    • See id. at 116-17.
  • 286
    • 41449087545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Anthony T. Kronman, Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 4-5 (1978).
    • See, e.g., Anthony T. Kronman, Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 4-5 (1978).
  • 287
    • 41449105139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part U.C.
    • See supra Part U.C.
  • 288
    • 41449105724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kronman, supra note 193, at 4-5
    • See Kronman, supra note 193, at 4-5.
  • 289
    • 41449091689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One of the exceptions to the contract law rule refusing to recognize an excuse for unilateral mistake is the case of an accounting or a clerical error, where the nonmistaken party is in a better position to detect the mistake and prevent the potential allocative inefficiency that might follow from it. See, e.g, Boise Junior Coll. Dist. v. Matters Constr. Co, 450 P.2d 604, 609 Idaho 1969
    • One of the exceptions to the contract law rule refusing to recognize an excuse for unilateral mistake is the case of an accounting or a clerical error, where the nonmistaken party is in a better position to detect the mistake and prevent the potential allocative inefficiency that might follow from it. See, e.g., Boise Junior Coll. Dist. v. Matters Constr. Co., 450 P.2d 604, 609 (Idaho 1969).
  • 291
    • 41449103340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The facts in Rossman provide an example of such misleading statements. Rossman v. Fleet Bank (R.I.) Natl Ass'n, 280 F.3d 384, 387-89 (3d Cir. 2002).
    • The facts in Rossman provide an example of such misleading statements. Rossman v. Fleet Bank (R.I.) Natl Ass'n, 280 F.3d 384, 387-89 (3d Cir. 2002).
  • 292
    • 41449086956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121-22 (But at this point the behavioral critique loses much of its bite, because it can no longer predict any systematic direction to the market errors . ... [I]t is hard to make policy recommendations in the absence of information as to which effect is likely to be most profound in any given setting. The behavioral critique lacks real bite.);
    • See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 121-22 ("But at this point the behavioral critique loses much of its bite, because it can no longer predict any systematic direction to the market errors . ... [I]t is hard to make policy recommendations in the absence of information as to which effect is likely to be most profound in any given setting. The behavioral critique lacks real bite.");
  • 293
    • 41449088532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dwelling on imperfections of ordinary individuals carries no clear implication as to the appropriate policy choice because there is no directionality to these cognitive errors, see also, at
    • see also Epstein, Second-Order Rationality, supra note 3, at 364 ("Dwelling on imperfections of ordinary individuals carries no clear implication as to the appropriate policy choice because there is no directionality to these cognitive errors.").
    • Second-Order Rationality, supra note , vol.3 , pp. 364
    • Epstein1
  • 295
    • 41449111598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts ILB-C.
    • See supra Parts ILB-C.
  • 296
    • 41449116362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 13-20 (2005).
    • See, e.g., HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 13-20 (2005).
  • 299
    • 41449086244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 300
    • 41449112561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (One key difficulty with all prophylactic legislation is that it tends to ignore striking differences by treating persons, even within narrow socioeconomic groupings, as part of some homogeneous mass.).
    • See id. ("One key difficulty with all prophylactic legislation is that it tends to ignore striking differences by treating persons, even within narrow socioeconomic groupings, as part of some homogeneous mass.").
  • 301
    • 0742306363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron, 70
    • If feasible, a comparison of possible rules should be done using a form of cost-benefit analysis, one that pays serious attention to welfare effects. In many cases, however, such analyses will be both difficult and expensive
    • Cass R. Sunstein & Richard H. Thaler, Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 1159, 1190 (2003) ("If feasible, a comparison of possible rules should be done using a form of cost-benefit analysis, one that pays serious attention to welfare effects. In many cases, however, such analyses will be both difficult and expensive.").
    • (2003) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1159 , pp. 1190
    • Sunstein, C.R.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 302
    • 41449104762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129 (Who is confident enough to decide which error counts for more, and to spend public money on the strength of their speculations?).
    • Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 129 ("Who is confident enough to decide which error counts for more, and to spend public money on the strength of their speculations?").
  • 303
    • 0038548458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism," 151
    • See generally
    • See generally Colin Camerer et al., Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for "Asymmetric Paternalism," 151 U. PA. L. REV. 1211 (2003);
    • (2003) U. PA. L. REV , vol.1211
    • Camerer, C.1
  • 304
    • 41449095823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205
    • Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205.
  • 306
    • 41449086070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A regulatory mechanism, which is somewhat similar to mandatory disclosure, uses public information campaigns to undo consumer misperception. Epstein argues that public information campaigns are unnecessary, since [ajnyone can enter the market on information, And by putting the government into the fray, there is always the risk that debiasing will take the form of rebiasing, by overstating credit card risks to individuals who would do well to have them. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 131. While Epstein is right that anyone can enter the market for information, non-government entities might not have sufficient incentives or sufficient funding to mount effective information campaigns. The risk of rebiasing is also a valid concern-one that needs to be weighed against the benefits of debiasing
    • A regulatory mechanism, which is somewhat similar to mandatory disclosure, uses public information campaigns to undo consumer misperception. Epstein argues that public information campaigns are unnecessary, since "[ajnyone can enter the market on information. . . . And by putting the government into the fray, there is always the risk that debiasing will take the form of rebiasing, by overstating credit card risks to individuals who would do well to have them." See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 131. While Epstein is right that anyone can enter the market for information, non-government entities might not have sufficient incentives or sufficient funding to mount effective information campaigns. The risk of rebiasing is also a valid concern-one that needs to be weighed against the benefits of debiasing.
  • 307
    • 41449099484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Christine Jolis & Cass R. Sunstein, Debiasing Through Law (U. Chi. Law Sch. John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper Series, Paper No. 225 (2d series), 2005), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-590929.
    • See generally Christine Jolis & Cass R. Sunstein, Debiasing Through Law (U. Chi. Law Sch. John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper Series, Paper No. 225 (2d series), 2005), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract-590929.
  • 308
    • 41449098102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Camerer et al, supra note 207, at 1224-30;
    • See Camerer et al., supra note 207, at 1224-30;
  • 309
    • 41449107070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205, at 1162-67
    • Sunstein & Thaler, supra note 205, at 1162-67.
  • 311
    • 41449111218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 312
    • 41449083058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts II-III.
    • See supra Parts II-III.
  • 313
    • 41449100256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another way to address the heterogeneity concern is by screening for sophistication. For example, under Regulation D, the SEC proscribes all but the very wealthy, who qualify as accredited investors, from investing in hedge funds. See 17 C.F.R. § 230.501 2007, defining the term accredited investor, One reason for this regulation is that the rich have a greater tolerance for risk. Another reason is that wealth can serve as a proxy for sophistication, especially since money can buy expert advice. By the same token perhaps some consumers should be denied access to mortgage loans or credit cards. The financial risk imposed by these products is substantial. Evidence suggests that not all consumers are sufficiently informed and sufficiently rational to understand the risk and protect against it
    • Another way to address the heterogeneity concern is by screening for sophistication. For example, under Regulation D, the SEC proscribes all but the very wealthy, who qualify as "accredited investors," from investing in hedge funds. See 17 C.F.R. § 230.501 (2007) (defining the term "accredited investor"). One reason for this regulation is that the rich have a greater tolerance for risk. Another reason is that wealth can serve as a proxy for sophistication, especially since money can buy expert advice. By the same token perhaps some consumers should be denied access to mortgage loans or credit cards. The financial risk imposed by these products is substantial. Evidence suggests that not all consumers are sufficiently informed and sufficiently rational to understand the risk and protect against it.
  • 314
    • 41449107647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. The problem, of course, is that accurate proxies for screening consumers are hard to come by, and using wealth as a proxy might result in denial of valuable products and services to poor consumers.
    • See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. The problem, of course, is that accurate proxies for screening consumers are hard to come by, and using wealth as a proxy might result in denial of valuable products and services to poor consumers.
  • 316
    • 41449106106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.;
    • Id.;
  • 317
    • 0344497355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Stephen J. Choi & A.C. Pritchard, Behavioral Economics and the SEC, 56 STAN. L. REV. 1, 5-6 (2003) ([I]f everyone suffers from cognitive defects, doesn't that also include [the regulators]?).
    • see also Stephen J. Choi & A.C. Pritchard, Behavioral Economics and the SEC, 56 STAN. L. REV. 1, 5-6 (2003) ("[I]f everyone suffers from cognitive defects, doesn't that also include [the regulators]?").
  • 319
    • 41449089602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C. §§1601-1667 2000
    • see also Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C. §§1601-1667 (2000).
  • 321
    • 41449099485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
    • 280 F.3d 384 (3d Cir. 2002).
  • 322
    • 41449096191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 387-89.
    • See id. at 387-89.
  • 323
    • 41449084415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 387-88
    • Id. at 387-88.
  • 324
    • 41449118656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 325
    • 41449099089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 326
    • 41449114096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 388-89
    • Id. at 388-89.
  • 328
    • 41449092065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 394 ([W]e believe a reasonable consumer would ... be entitled to assume upon reading Fleet's solicitation that the issuer was committed to refraining from imposing an annual fee for at least one year. The statement 'no annual fee,' in other words, is fairly understood to contain an implied term of a year.).
    • See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 394 ("[W]e believe a reasonable consumer would ... be entitled to assume upon reading Fleet's solicitation that the issuer was committed to refraining from imposing an annual fee for at least one year. The statement 'no annual fee,' in other words, is fairly understood to contain an implied term of a year.").
  • 330
    • 41449103712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rossman's no annual fee for one year interpretation does not comport with Fleet's expectations either. Fleet did not think that it had to wait a year before imposing an annual fee. See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388-89.
    • Rossman's "no annual fee for one year" interpretation does not comport with Fleet's expectations either. Fleet did not think that it had to wait a year before imposing an annual fee. See Rossman, 280 F.3d at 388-89.
  • 331
    • 41449095157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Epstein acknowledges that the bank had planned from the outset to impose an annual fee before the end of the year. See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 126.
    • Epstein acknowledges that "the bank had planned from the outset to impose an annual fee before the end of the year." See Epstein, Behavioral Economics, supra note 1, at 126.
  • 332
    • 41449085887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More comprehensive disclosure might not reduce the incidence of consumer mistakes, because of the risk of information overload. Imperfectly rational consumers can process only a limited amount of information. See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. Therefore, more disclosure does not necessarily mean better-informed consumers.
    • More comprehensive disclosure might not reduce the incidence of consumer mistakes, because of the risk of information overload. Imperfectly rational consumers can process only a limited amount of information. See, e.g., Korobkin, supra note 46, at 1209-44. Therefore, more disclosure does not necessarily mean better-informed consumers.
  • 333
    • 41449090758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 46 (finding that credit card disclosures contain too much information);
    • See U.S. GOV'T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 120, at 46 (finding that credit card disclosures contain too much information);
  • 334
    • 33746338548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard Craswell, Taking Information Seriously: Misrepresentation and Nondisclosure in Contract Law and Elsewhere, 92 VA. L. REV. 565, 578 (2006) (arguing that provision of additional information dilutes the effectiveness of existing disclosures);
    • Richard Craswell, Taking Information Seriously: Misrepresentation and Nondisclosure in Contract Law and Elsewhere, 92 VA. L. REV. 565, 578 (2006) (arguing that provision of additional information dilutes the effectiveness of existing disclosures);
  • 335
    • 41449113503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 94, at, concluding that it is not clear that requiring more details in regulatory disclosures would be useful for consumers
    • Furletti, supra note 94, at 19 (concluding that it is not clear that requiring more details in regulatory disclosures would be useful for consumers).
    • supra , pp. 19
    • Furletti1
  • 336
    • 41449117232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35 (finding that most major issuers consider a payment late if it arrives after 2:00 p.m. on the due date).
    • See DRAUT & SILVA, supra note 94, at 35 (finding that most major issuers consider a payment late if it arrives after 2:00 p.m. on the due date).
  • 337
    • 84956547845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1601a, 2000, discussing the purpose of the disclosures
    • See 15 U.S.C. § 1601(a) (2000) (discussing the purpose of the disclosures).
    • 15 U.S.C
  • 338
    • 41449109035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 94, at, describing the current disclosures in credit card agreements
    • See MANN, supra note 94, at 131-32 (describing the current disclosures in credit card agreements).
    • supra , pp. 131-132
    • MANN1
  • 339
    • 41449105140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are examples of existing disclosure regulations that mandate use-pattern disclosures. See, e.g., 15 U.S.C. § 2056 (2000) (providing the Consumer Products Safety Commission with authority to promulgate requirements that a consumer product be marked with or accompanied by clear and adequate warnings or instructions in order to ensure products are used correctly). Still, in many consumer markets use-pattern disclosure is missing. And, where use-pattern disclosure is required, the use-pattern information disclosed is often insufficient.
    • There are examples of existing disclosure regulations that mandate use-pattern disclosures. See, e.g., 15 U.S.C. § 2056 (2000) (providing the Consumer Products Safety Commission with authority to promulgate "requirements that a consumer product be marked with or accompanied by clear and adequate warnings or instructions" in order to ensure products are used correctly). Still, in many consumer markets use-pattern disclosure is missing. And, where use-pattern disclosure is required, the use-pattern information disclosed is often insufficient.
  • 340
    • 41449105918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Informing Consumers
    • See, note 22, at, providing examples of such inefficiencies
    • See Bar-Gill, Informing Consumers, supra note 22, at 46-53 (providing examples of such inefficiencies).
    • supra , pp. 46-53
    • Bar-Gill1
  • 341
    • 41449116940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Thomas A. Durkin, Requirements and Prospects for a New Time to Payoff Disclosure for Open End Credit Under Truth in Lending 25 (Fed. Reserve Bd., Fin. and Econ. Discussion Series, Paper No. 2006-34, 2006), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2006/200634/ (Beyond the consumer surveys, specific information on consumers' payment patterns has heretofore been available only to the creditors who issue the cards.).
    • Cf. Thomas A. Durkin, Requirements and Prospects for a New Time to Payoff Disclosure for Open End Credit Under Truth in Lending 25 (Fed. Reserve Bd., Fin. and Econ. Discussion Series, Paper No. 2006-34, 2006), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2006/200634/ ("Beyond the consumer surveys, specific information on consumers' payment patterns has heretofore been available only to the creditors who issue the cards.").
  • 342
    • 41449094465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 40-41 (explaining a sample of credit card account information assembled in 2001 from the portfolios of five of the fifteen largest credit card issuers).
    • See id. at 40-41 (explaining a sample of credit card account information "assembled in 2001 from the portfolios of five of the fifteen largest credit card issuers").
  • 343
    • 41449106490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 345
    • 41449112761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For instance, consumers can easily access their own credit information via credit reports on the Internet. See, e.g., Experian, Free Credit Report and Credit Score, http://www.experian.com/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2007). Additionally, consumers can access reports and statistical data on government and nongovernmental organizations' websites, as well as through the use of free research databases.
    • For instance, consumers can easily access their own credit information via credit reports on the Internet. See, e.g., Experian, Free Credit Report and Credit Score, http://www.experian.com/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2007). Additionally, consumers can access reports and statistical data on government and nongovernmental organizations' websites, as well as through the use of free research databases.
  • 346
    • 39149130217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social Science Research Network, last visited Nov. 30
    • See, e.g., Social Science Research Network, http://www .ssrn.com/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2007).
    • (2007) See, e.g
  • 347
    • 41449089075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 94, at, discussing card issuers' use of collected information to adjust rates
    • See Furletti, supra note 94, at 6-9 (discussing card issuers' use of collected information to adjust rates).
    • supra , pp. 6-9
    • Furletti1
  • 348
    • 41449116561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MANN, supra note 94, at 192 ([A] point-of-sale reminder of the account balance might cause a consumer to respond differently. The consumer could switch to another payment device or discontinue the sales transaction entirely.).
    • MANN, supra note 94, at 192 ("[A] point-of-sale reminder of the account balance might cause a consumer to respond differently. The consumer could switch to another payment device or discontinue the sales transaction entirely.").
  • 351
    • 41449090759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also MANN, supra note 94, at 160-61 (arguing for individual reports on debt repayment time and cost at the point of borrowing);
    • see also MANN, supra note 94, at 160-61 (arguing for individual reports on debt repayment time and cost at the point of borrowing);
  • 352
    • 41449086418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas A. Durkin, Credit Cards: Use and Consumer Attitudes, 1970-2000, 86 FED. RES. BULL. 623, 629 (2000) (Many holders of bank-type cards in 2000 said that it would be helpful to include on their billing statement information about the length of time it would take to pay off the balance if only the minimum payment were made each month.).
    • Thomas A. Durkin, Credit Cards: Use and Consumer Attitudes, 1970-2000, 86 FED. RES. BULL. 623, 629 (2000) ("Many holders of bank-type cards in 2000 said that it would be helpful to include on their billing statement information about the length of time it would take to pay off the balance if only the minimum payment were made each month.").
  • 353
    • 41449089416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such an individualized warning, tailored to the consumer's actual repayment record, should be more effective than the general warning that Congress recently enacted as part of the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005. See Pub. L. No. 109-8, § 1301, 119 Stat. 23, 204-08 (2005). A more individualized version of § 1301 was soundly defeated by the issuers' lobby in the House of Representatives.
    • Such an individualized warning, tailored to the consumer's actual repayment record, should be more effective than the general warning that Congress recently enacted as part of the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005. See Pub. L. No. 109-8, § 1301, 119 Stat. 23, 204-08 (2005). A more individualized version of § 1301 was soundly defeated by the issuers' lobby in the House of Representatives.
  • 354
    • 41449096577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See H.R. 1052, 107th Cong. (2001).
    • See H.R. 1052, 107th Cong. (2001).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.