메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 89, Issue 5, 2009, Pages 1397-1450

A theory of self-help remedies in contract

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 74849083354     PISSN: 00068047     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (25)

References (445)
  • 1
    • 74849136682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-help remedies have been defined as legally permissible conduct that individuals undertake absent the compulsion of law and without the assistance of a government official in efforts to prevent or remedy a civil wrong. Douglas I. Brandon et al, Self-Help: Extrajudicial Rights, Privileges and Remedies in Contemporary American Society, 37 VAND. L. REV. 845, 850 1984
    • Self-help remedies have been defined as legally permissible conduct that individuals undertake absent the compulsion of law and without the assistance of a government official in efforts to prevent or remedy a civil wrong." Douglas I. Brandon et al., Self-Help: Extrajudicial Rights, Privileges and Remedies in Contemporary American Society, 37 VAND. L. REV. 845, 850 (1984).
  • 2
    • 74849085052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brandon et al. include as instances of self-help remedies in commercial transactions liquidated damage terms, self-help repossession, and arbitration. Id. at 911-13.
    • Brandon et al. include as instances of self-help remedies in commercial transactions liquidated damage terms, self-help repossession, and arbitration. Id. at 911-13.
  • 3
    • 32544460867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This list illustrates some of the difficulties of defining the category. If liquidated damage terms are classified as self-help remedies, then so might any contract term that is designed to simplify litigation or to make the outcome more predictable. This might include, for example, merger provisions that exclude parol evidence. Readers interested in pursuing the topic of designing contracts in anticipation of litigation should look generally at Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design, 115 YALE L. J. 814 2006
    • This list illustrates some of the difficulties of defining the category. If liquidated damage terms are classified as self-help remedies, then so might any contract term that is designed to simplify litigation or to make the outcome more predictable. This might include, for example, merger provisions that exclude parol evidence. Readers interested in pursuing the topic of designing contracts in anticipation of litigation should look generally at Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design, 115 YALE L. J. 814 (2006).
  • 4
    • 74849091536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • My principal focus is on self-help remedies that do not anticipate or require that a parry go to court to make the remedy effective. I will say a fair bit about the power to obtain substitute performance (or cover) and collect the cost and the power to complete performance and collect the contract price. These have been described as forms of self-help specific performance. The power to refuse future dealings with a defaulter has been described as a self-help remedy, as have reputational sanctions more generally. I will not explore these sanctions here. While reputational sanctions are important, they are largely unregulated by courts. The only article I know of that examines the rules on material breach and substantial performance under this heading is Celia R. Taylor, Self-Help in Contract: An Exploration and Proposal, 33 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 839 1998
    • My principal focus is on self-help remedies that do not anticipate or require that a parry go to court to make the remedy effective. I will say a fair bit about the power to obtain substitute performance (or cover) and collect the cost and the power to complete performance and collect the contract price. These have been described as forms of self-help specific performance. The power to refuse future dealings with a defaulter has been described as a self-help remedy, as have reputational sanctions more generally. I will not explore these sanctions here. While reputational sanctions are important, they are largely unregulated by courts. The only article I know of that examines the rules on material breach and substantial performance under this heading is Celia R. Taylor, Self-Help in Contract: An Exploration and Proposal, 33 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 839 (1998).
  • 5
    • 74849115952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is, however, a substantial literature on many of the individual rules. I will refer to this literature when it is relevant, but I will not discuss the law on repossession. For an introduction to, and critical analysis of, this body of law, see Edward L. Rubin, The Code, the Consumer, and the Institutional Structure of the Common Law, 75 WASH. U. L. Q. 11, 36-41 (1997).
    • There is, however, a substantial literature on many of the individual rules. I will refer to this literature when it is relevant, but I will not discuss the law on repossession. For an introduction to, and critical analysis of, this body of law, see Edward L. Rubin, The Code, the Consumer, and the Institutional Structure of the Common Law, 75 WASH. U. L. Q. 11, 36-41 (1997).
  • 6
    • 74849130377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A fair amount has been written on the subject of self-help remedies in the area of property rights. Readers interested in pursuing this topic might start with Symposium, Property Rights on the Frontier: The Economics of Self-Help and Self Defense in Cyberspace, 1 J. L. ECON. & POL'Y 1 (2005).
    • A fair amount has been written on the subject of self-help remedies in the area of property rights. Readers interested in pursuing this topic might start with Symposium, Property Rights on the Frontier: The Economics of Self-Help and Self Defense in Cyberspace, 1 J. L. ECON. & POL'Y 1 (2005).
  • 7
    • 74849135180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The list includes rules on mitigation, material breach, substantial performance, conditions, voluntary payment, waiver, equitable estoppel, election of remedies, restitution as a remedy for breach, restitution to a defaulter, accord and satisfaction, good faith, and duress. To these can be added rules that apply in subfields of contract, such as sales law rules on rejection, revocation, and cure
    • The list includes rules on mitigation, material breach, substantial performance, conditions, voluntary payment, waiver, equitable estoppel, election of remedies, restitution as a remedy for breach, restitution to a defaulter, accord and satisfaction, good faith, and duress. To these can be added rules that apply in subfields of contract, such as sales law rules on rejection, revocation, and cure.
  • 8
    • 26444443440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts I, II. Parts of the argument parallel and support the argument in Melvin A. Eisenberg, Actual and Virtual Specific Performance, the Theory of Efficient Breach, and the Indifference Principle in Contract Law, 93 CAL. L. REV. 975 (2005).
    • See infra Parts I, II. Parts of the argument parallel and support the argument in Melvin A. Eisenberg, Actual and Virtual Specific Performance, the Theory of Efficient Breach, and the Indifference Principle in Contract Law, 93 CAL. L. REV. 975 (2005).
  • 9
    • 74849091819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In particular, Professor Eisenberg argues for a right to cover in good faith - meaning the choice of cover has some basis in reason. Id. at 1043 (quoting Sam Wong & Son v. N. Y. Mercantile Exch., 735 F.2d 653, 655 (2d Cir. 1984) (Friendly, J.)).
    • In particular, Professor Eisenberg argues for a right to cover in "good faith" - meaning the choice of cover has "some basis in reason". Id. at 1043 (quoting Sam Wong & Son v. N. Y. Mercantile Exch., 735 F.2d 653, 655 (2d Cir. 1984) (Friendly, J.)).
  • 10
    • 74849093579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • He lauds cover as a form of self-help specific performance, arguing that the standard for permissible cover should be more generous than the standard for specific performance because of problems posed by the latter, including the nature of the enforcement process and problems of mitigation, opportunism, and jury trial. Id. at 1042.
    • He lauds cover as a form of self-help specific performance, arguing that the standard for permissible cover should be more generous than the standard for specific performance because of problems posed by the latter, "including the nature of the enforcement process and problems of mitigation, opportunism, and jury trial." Id. at 1042.
  • 11
    • 74849097653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The same thing may be said for specific performance when equitable enforcement is a simple and effective way to put the plaintiff in the promised position. Courts routinely specifically enforce contracts to deliver property when the property is in the defendant's possession. See DOUGLAS LAYCOCK, THE DEATH OF THE IRREPARABLE INJURY RULE 100-01 1991
    • The same thing may be said for specific performance when equitable enforcement is a simple and effective way to put the plaintiff in the promised position. Courts routinely specifically enforce contracts to deliver property when the property is in the defendant's possession. See DOUGLAS LAYCOCK, THE DEATH OF THE IRREPARABLE INJURY RULE 100-01 (1991).
  • 12
    • 33646673572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economists have come around to the view that this is the best background rule for such cases. See Steven Shavell, Specific Performance Versus Damages for Breach of Contract: An Economic Analysis, 84 TEX. L. REV. 831, 831-32 (2006).
    • Economists have come around to the view that this is the best background rule for such cases. See Steven Shavell, Specific Performance Versus Damages for Breach of Contract: An Economic Analysis, 84 TEX. L. REV. 831, 831-32 (2006).
  • 13
    • 0040172009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Misunderstanding of this point is pervasive. It ties into the widely held view that contract rights are weaker than property rights. So Carol Rose observes: [I]n contract law, liability rules, not property rules, do indeed constitute the background default rule: The parties are supposed to perform, but except in particular circumstances (mostly real estate!) they have the option of defaulting and paying damages instead of performing. Carol M. Rose, The Shadow of The Cathedral, 106 YALE L. J. 2175, 2187 (1997).
    • Misunderstanding of this point is pervasive. It ties into the widely held view that contract rights are weaker than property rights. So Carol Rose observes: "[I]n contract law, liability rules, not property rules, do indeed constitute the background default rule: The parties are supposed to perform, but except in particular circumstances (mostly real estate!) they have the option of defaulting and paying damages instead of performing." Carol M. Rose, The Shadow of The Cathedral, 106 YALE L. J. 2175, 2187 (1997).
  • 14
    • 33845369004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard Brooks pithily summarizes the supposed differences between the two types of rules: Property rules protect entitlements by using the state's police powers to prohibit nonconsensual appropriations, whereas liability rules use court-determined monetary compensation to discourage nonconsensual appropriations. Richard R. W. Brooks, The Efficient Performance Hypothesis, 116 YALE L. J. 568, 575 (2006).
    • Richard Brooks pithily summarizes the supposed differences between the two types of rules: "Property rules protect entitlements by using the state's police powers to prohibit nonconsensual appropriations, whereas liability rules use court-determined monetary compensation to discourage nonconsensual appropriations." Richard R. W. Brooks, The Efficient Performance Hypothesis, 116 YALE L. J. 568, 575 (2006).
  • 15
    • 36348940372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It also ties into the widely held view that contract rights have a lower stature in American contract law than they do in civil law systems and in other common law systems. Ronald J. Scalise, Jr, Why No Efficient Breach in Civil Law? A Comparative Assessment of the Doctrine of Efficient Breach, 55 AM. J. COMP. L. 721, 763 (2007, using the example of efficient breach to show that the difference [in contract law) appears to be one between American common law and the law of the rest of the world
    • It also ties into the widely held view that contract rights have a lower stature in American contract law than they do in civil law systems and in other common law systems. Ronald J. Scalise, Jr., Why No Efficient Breach in Civil Law? A Comparative Assessment of the Doctrine of Efficient Breach, 55 AM. J. COMP. L. 721, 763 (2007) (using the example of efficient breach to show that "the difference [in contract law) appears to be one between American common law and the law of the rest of the world").
  • 16
    • 33846467857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Part III
    • See infra Part III.
    • See infra
  • 17
    • 0038016314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Formalism in Relational Contract, 94
    • Robert E. Scott, The Case for Formalism in Relational Contract, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 847 (2000)
    • (2000) NW. U. L. REV , vol.847
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 18
    • 74849135178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Formalism], makes many of the key points
    • hereinafter, The theoretical argument is that courts are unlikely to do better than sophisticated actors in designing terms when relevant information is unknown or the design of terms involves difficult tradeoffs. Id. at
    • [hereinafter Scott, Formalism], makes many of the key points. The article combines theoretical, empirical, and historical arguments to justify a formalist approach in contract law and criticize what is described as a contextualist approach. The theoretical argument is that courts are unlikely to do better than sophisticated actors in designing terms when relevant information is unknown or the design of terms involves difficult tradeoffs. Id. at 862-66.
    • The article combines theoretical, empirical, and historical arguments to justify a formalist approach in contract law and criticize what is described as a contextualist approach , pp. 862-866
    • Scott1
  • 19
    • 74849090885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The empirical argument is that the world is complex - in Scott's words, it is a thick environment of many heterogeneous parties. Id. at 865.
    • The empirical argument is that the world is complex - in Scott's words, it is "a thick environment of many heterogeneous parties." Id. at 865.
  • 20
    • 74849108734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These points lead to the conclusion that efficient terms are likely to be individualized, meaning they cannot be set by courts on a wholesale basis. The historical argument, which Scott calls the failure of Karl Llewellyn's project, is that courts have not derived individualized rules from trade norms, which might have been a solution to the problem of competence and heterogeneity. Id. at 866-69.
    • These points lead to the conclusion that efficient terms are likely to be individualized, meaning they cannot be set by courts on a wholesale basis. The historical argument, which Scott calls the failure of Karl Llewellyn's project, is that courts have not derived individualized rules from trade norms, which might have been a solution to the problem of competence and heterogeneity. Id. at 866-69.
  • 21
    • 74849111003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The upshot is that Scott touts the old-time virtues of remedial simplicity. He advocates literal interpretation of contracts without regard to context. Id. at 866.
    • The upshot is that Scott touts the old-time virtues of remedial simplicity. He advocates literal interpretation of contracts without regard to context. Id. at 866.
  • 22
    • 74849129477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This presumably means a return to the plain-meaning and four-comers rules and, perhaps, a return to the rule barring enforcement of indefinite terms. See id. at 860, 877 suggesting some indecision on the last point
    • This presumably means a return to the plain-meaning and four-comers rules and, perhaps, a return to the rule barring enforcement of indefinite terms. See id. at 860, 877 (suggesting some indecision on the last point).
  • 23
    • 74849100153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • He nods sympathetically to the doctrines of perfect tender, mistake, and excuse [and] the sharply defined rules regarding expectation damages that assign risks on an all-or-nothing, binary basis. Id. at 852-53.
    • He nods sympathetically to the "doctrines of perfect tender, mistake, and excuse [and] the sharply defined rules regarding expectation damages" that "assign risks on an all-or-nothing, binary basis." Id. at 852-53.
  • 24
    • 74849133960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Robert E. Scott, The Death of Contract Law, 54 U. TORONTO L. J. 369 (2004) [hereinafter Scott, Death], Scott argues that the shift of courts from a formalist to a contextualist approach is partly responsible for the flight from relying on the legal system to enforce contracts to relying on self-enforcement, particularly in contracts that require flexible commitments.
    • In Robert E. Scott, The Death of Contract Law, 54 U. TORONTO L. J. 369 (2004) [hereinafter Scott, Death], Scott argues that the shift of courts from a formalist to a contextualist approach is partly responsible for the flight from relying on the legal system to enforce contracts to relying on self-enforcement, particularly in contracts that require flexible commitments.
  • 25
    • 74849109900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In using the term, I follow Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Theory of Contracts, in THE THEORY OF CONTRACT LAW 206, 223-35 (Peter Benson ed., 2001).
    • In using the term, I follow Melvin A. Eisenberg, The Theory of Contracts, in THE THEORY OF CONTRACT LAW 206, 223-35 (Peter Benson ed., 2001).
  • 26
    • 4344671883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 YALE L. J. 541, 618-19 (2003);
    • (2003) YALE L. J , vol.541 , pp. 618-619
    • Schwartz, A.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 27
    • 4344707144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alan Schwartz & Joel Watson, The Law and Economics of Costly Contracting, 20 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 2, 4-5 (2004);
    • Alan Schwartz & Joel Watson, The Law and Economics of Costly Contracting, 20 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 2, 4-5 (2004);
  • 28
    • 74849084236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alan Schwartz, The Myth that Promisees Prefer Supracompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100 YALE L. J. 369, 406-07 (1990).
    • Alan Schwartz, The Myth that Promisees Prefer Supracompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100 YALE L. J. 369, 406-07 (1990).
  • 29
    • 0347593601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Self-Enforcing Indefinite Agreements, 103
    • Robert E. Scott, A Theory of Self-Enforcing Indefinite Agreements, 103 COLUM. L. REV. 1641, 1692-93 (2003).
    • (2003) COLUM. L. REV , vol.1641 , pp. 1692-1693
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 30
  • 31
    • 74849136368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 474 P.2d 689 (Cal. 1970). As often happens to cases in the canon, Parker has been used to make a variety of points.
    • 474 P.2d 689 (Cal. 1970). As often happens to cases in the canon, Parker has been used to make a variety of points.
  • 32
    • 0242619295 scopus 로고
    • Re-Reading Contracts: A Feminist Analysis of a Contracts Casebook, 34
    • discussing feminist issues raised by the case, See
    • See Mary Joe Frug, Re-Reading Contracts: A Feminist Analysis of a Contracts Casebook, 34 AM. U. L. REV. 1065, 1114-25 (1985) (discussing feminist issues raised by the case);
    • (1985) AM. U. L. REV , vol.1065 , pp. 1114-1125
    • Joe Frug, M.1
  • 33
    • 74849108967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Victor P. Goldberg, Bloomer Girl Revisited or How to Frame an Unmade Picture, 1998 WIS. L. REV. 1051, 1052-53 (explaining that the decision should have been rested on the ground that base price in the contract was paid by the studio to have an option on Parker's time);
    • Victor P. Goldberg, Bloomer Girl Revisited or How to Frame an Unmade Picture, 1998 WIS. L. REV. 1051, 1052-53 (explaining that the decision should have been rested on the ground that base price in the contract was paid by the studio to have an option on Parker's time);
  • 34
    • 74849131562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • William J. Woodward, Jr., Clearing the Underbrush for Real-Life Contracting, 24 LAW & Soc. INQUIRY 99, 105 (1999) (explaining that the case is a good vehicle for exploring the difference between book law and real life). I discuss Goldberg's account of the case in Part IV. See infra notes 159-74 and accompanying text.
    • William J. Woodward, Jr., Clearing the Underbrush for Real-Life Contracting, 24 LAW & Soc. INQUIRY 99, 105 (1999) (explaining that the case is a good vehicle for exploring the difference between book law and real life). I discuss Goldberg's account of the case in Part IV. See infra notes 159-74 and accompanying text.
  • 35
    • 74849119595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35F.2d301 (4thCir. 1929).
    • 35F.2d301 (4thCir. 1929).
  • 36
    • 74849120422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 692-93.
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 692-93.
  • 37
    • 74849126719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Luten Bridge, 35 F.2d at 307-08;
    • Luten Bridge, 35 F.2d at 307-08;
  • 38
    • 74849086773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 693-94.
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 693-94.
  • 39
    • 74849111657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 690-91.
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 690-91.
  • 40
    • 74849093576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 41
    • 74849130957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 691
    • Id. at 691.
  • 42
    • 74849127012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 692
    • Id. at 692.
  • 43
    • 74849121300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 693-94
    • Id. at 693-94.
  • 44
    • 74849119325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 45
    • 74849102515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Parker seems to be representative of employment cases more generally. A survey of recent contract and Title VII cases concludes that courts require that two positions be virtually identical before they will require a terminated employee to take another position to mitigate damages. Richard J. Gonzales, Satisfying the Duty to Mitigate in Employment Cases: A Survey and a Guide, 69 Miss. L. J. 749, 760-62 (1999).
    • Id. Parker seems to be representative of employment cases more generally. A survey of recent contract and Title VII cases concludes that courts require that two positions be "virtually identical" before they will require a terminated employee to take another position to mitigate damages. Richard J. Gonzales, Satisfying the Duty to Mitigate in Employment Cases: A Survey and a Guide, 69 Miss. L. J. 749, 760-62 (1999).
  • 46
    • 74849111989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The author adds that courts have been more willing to require an employee to relocate when his line of work and past behavior indicated he was not averse to relocating. Id. at 767-68
    • The author adds that courts have been more willing to require an employee to relocate when his line of work and past behavior indicated he was not averse to relocating. Id. at 767-68.
  • 47
    • 74849096745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Title VII cases (but not breach of contract claims), an employee may be denied full back wages for an extended period of time on the theory that he should have taken less desirable and lower paying work to mitigate damages. Id. at 769-71.
    • In Title VII cases (but not breach of contract claims), an employee may be denied full back wages for an extended period of time on the theory that he should have taken less desirable and lower paying work to mitigate damages. Id. at 769-71.
  • 48
    • 74849131262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldberg, supra note 11, at 1052. I take the facts not found in the opinion from Goldberg's excellent article. Goldberg argues that there was an alternative basis for decision because the contract had a pay-or- play provision that required the studio to pay MacLaine if it cancelled the project. Id. at 1053. Goldberg argues this was an easier basis. I think it was an easy mitigation case as well.
    • Goldberg, supra note 11, at 1052. I take the facts not found in the opinion from Goldberg's excellent article. Goldberg argues that there was an alternative basis for decision because the contract had a "pay-or- play" provision that required the studio to pay MacLaine if it cancelled the project. Id. at 1053. Goldberg argues this was an easier basis. I think it was an easy mitigation case as well.
  • 49
    • 74849087643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This also is true when courts determine whether damages are an adequate remedy to preclude an order of specific performance. Campbell Soup Co. v. Wentz, 172 F.2d 80, 83 3d Cir. 1948, is a classic statement of the principle
    • This also is true when courts determine whether damages are an adequate remedy to preclude an order of specific performance. Campbell Soup Co. v. Wentz, 172 F.2d 80, 83 (3d Cir. 1948), is a classic statement of the principle.
  • 50
    • 74849130376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The caveat about subjective preferences is to acknowledge that courts sometimes apply an objective standard in assessing whether an action taken in response to breach is appropriate. Melvin Eisenberg makes a similar point when he argues that an objective standard should be used to evaluate a buyer's search for cover while a subjective good faith standard should be used to evaluate a buyer's choice of cover. Eisenberg, supra note 3, at 1042-49
    • The caveat about subjective preferences is to acknowledge that courts sometimes apply an objective standard in assessing whether an action taken in response to breach is appropriate. Melvin Eisenberg makes a similar point when he argues that an objective standard should be used to evaluate a buyer's search for cover while a subjective good faith standard should be used to evaluate a buyer's choice of cover. Eisenberg, supra note 3, at 1042-49.
  • 51
    • 74849109585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Eisenberg finds mixed support in the case law on the use of a subjective standard to evaluate choice of cover. Id. at 1046-47
    • Professor Eisenberg finds mixed support in the case law on the use of a subjective standard to evaluate choice of cover. Id. at 1046-47.
  • 52
    • 74849097951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Kellett Aircraft Corp., 186 F.2d 197, 199 (3d Cir. 1950).
    • In re Kellett Aircraft Corp., 186 F.2d 197, 199 (3d Cir. 1950).
  • 53
    • 74849096748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 694.
    • Parker, 474 P.2d at 694.
  • 54
    • 74849101627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DOUGLAS LAYCOCK, MODERN AMERICAN REMEDIES: CASES AND MATERIALS 97 (3d ed. 2002).
    • DOUGLAS LAYCOCK, MODERN AMERICAN REMEDIES: CASES AND MATERIALS 97 (3d ed. 2002).
  • 55
    • 74849140540 scopus 로고
    • Warner Co., 576 F.2d 524
    • & Sons Co. v
    • S. J. Groves & Sons Co. v. Warner Co., 576 F.2d 524, 530 (3d Cir. 1978).
    • (1978) 530 (3d Cir
    • Groves, S.J.1
  • 56
    • 74849106308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 F.2d 301 (4th Cir. 1929).
    • 35 F.2d 301 (4th Cir. 1929).
  • 57
    • 74849131563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RANDY E. BARNETT, CONTRACTS: CASES AND DOCTRINES 131, 142 (4th ed. 2008);
    • See, e.g., RANDY E. BARNETT, CONTRACTS: CASES AND DOCTRINES 131, 142 (4th ed. 2008);
  • 58
    • 74849130058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN P. DAWSON ET AL., CONTRACTS: CASES AND COMMENTS 60, 66 (9th ed. 2008);
    • JOHN P. DAWSON ET AL., CONTRACTS: CASES AND COMMENTS 60, 66 (9th ed. 2008);
  • 59
    • 74849098759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH ET AL., CONTRACTS: CASES AND MATERIALS 492, 500 (6th ed. 2001);
    • E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH ET AL., CONTRACTS: CASES AND MATERIALS 492, 500 (6th ed. 2001);
  • 60
    • 74849104505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LON L. FULLER & MELVIN A. EISENBERG, BASIC CONTRACT LAW 167, 171 (8th ed. 2006).
    • LON L. FULLER & MELVIN A. EISENBERG, BASIC CONTRACT LAW 167, 171 (8th ed. 2006).
  • 61
    • 74849137365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Luten Bridge, 35 F.2d at 302-03.
    • Luten Bridge, 35 F.2d at 302-03.
  • 62
    • 74849139393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 303
    • Id. at 303.
  • 63
    • 74849128785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 64
    • 74849131875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barak D. Richman, The King of Rockingham County and the Original Bridge to Nowhere, in CONTRACTS STORIES 304-34 (Douglas G. Baird ed., 2007), tells the story behind the case. Professor Richman notes that from the perspective of the parties and the courts, the case only tangentially involved a dispute over contract law. Id. at 305.
    • Barak D. Richman, The King of Rockingham County and the Original Bridge to Nowhere, in CONTRACTS STORIES 304-34 (Douglas G. Baird ed., 2007), tells the story behind the case. Professor Richman notes that from the perspective of the parties and the courts, "the case only tangentially involved a dispute over contract law." Id. at 305.
  • 65
    • 74849129166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Luten Bridge, 35 F.2d at 305-06.
    • Luten Bridge, 35 F.2d at 305-06.
  • 66
    • 74849134557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 307-08
    • Id. at 307-08.
  • 67
    • 74849112609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richman, supra note 33, at 328 ([N]either party proffered an argument challenging the lower court's calculation of damages.). Richman suggests two possible explanations. One is that a supporter of the bridge had promised to indemnify Luten Bridge Company. Id. at 316.
    • Richman, supra note 33, at 328 ("[N]either party proffered an argument challenging the lower court's calculation of damages."). Richman suggests two possible explanations. One is that a supporter of the bridge had promised to indemnify Luten Bridge Company. Id. at 316.
  • 68
    • 74849094289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The other is the company was advised to complete the bridge by its attorneys as the safest course given the uncertainty as to who spoke for the County. Id
    • The other is the company was advised to complete the bridge by its attorneys as the safest course given the uncertainty as to who spoke for the County. Id.
  • 69
    • 74849087051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Denio 317 (N. Y. 1845).
    • Denio 317 (N. Y. 1845).
  • 70
    • 74849134862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id317
    • Id317.
  • 71
    • 74849103169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 72
    • 74849120187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 40Id
    • 40Id.
  • 73
    • 74849083283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Idat 318
    • Idat 318.
  • 74
    • 74849096292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 75
    • 74849125212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, FARNSWORTH ET AL, supra note 29, at 494, presents it as unexceptional that the injured party cannot recover for cost that could have been avoided by simply stopping performance and poses as the difficult case where avoiding loss requires taking affirmative steps. IAN AYRES & RICHARD SPIEDEL, STUDIES IN CONTRACT LAW 953 (7th ed. 2008, preface analysis of damages for breach of a construction contract with the statement any performance by Contractor after the breach is normally out of the question (the work is being done on Owner's land) and, in any event, would probably run afoul of the mitigation principle. It is not clear that an owner's right to exclude trumps a contractor's right to complete work to avoid a loss. In Bomberger v
    • For example, FARNSWORTH ET AL., supra note 29, at 494, presents it as unexceptional "that the injured party cannot recover for cost that could have been avoided by simply stopping performance" and poses as the difficult case where avoiding loss requires "taking affirmative steps." IAN AYRES & RICHARD SPIEDEL, STUDIES IN CONTRACT LAW 953 (7th ed. 2008), preface analysis of damages for breach of a construction contract with the statement "any performance by Contractor after the breach is normally out of the question (the work is being done on Owner's land) and, in any event, would probably run afoul of the mitigation principle." It is not clear that an owner's right to exclude trumps a contractor's right to complete work to avoid a loss. In Bomberger v.
  • 76
    • 74849135943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McKelvey, 220 P.2d 729, 735-37 (Cal. 1950), the trial court permitted a contractor to go on an owner's land to demolish a building the contractor had been hired to demolish though the owner had countermanded the demolition order and asked the trial court to enjoin the entry.
    • McKelvey, 220 P.2d 729, 735-37 (Cal. 1950), the trial court permitted a contractor to go on an owner's land to demolish a building the contractor had been hired to demolish though the owner had countermanded the demolition order and asked the trial court to enjoin the entry.
  • 77
    • 74849106804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rule was not universally embraced even in the United States. John A. Roebling's Sons Co. v. Lock-Stitch Fence Co., 22 N. E. 518, 518 (Ill. 1889),
    • The rule was not universally embraced even in the United States. John A. Roebling's Sons Co. v. Lock-Stitch Fence Co., 22 N. E. 518, 518 (Ill. 1889),
  • 78
    • 74849134261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • holds, to the contrary, that a contractor has a right to complete performance. In many cases that are cited as authority for the rule, the plaintiff did not complete performance and the rule is invoked to deflect the defendant's argument that the plaintiff has no right to damages because of the failure to complete. See, e.g., Davis v. Bronson, 50 N. W. 836, 839 (N. D. 1892) (criticizing a line of cases that would seem to hold that the contract-defaulter would be obliged to pay in full should the other side nonetheless fully perform, and concluding the weight of reason and authority is against it).
    • holds, to the contrary, that a contractor has a right to complete performance. In many cases that are cited as authority for the rule, the plaintiff did not complete performance and the rule is invoked to deflect the defendant's argument that the plaintiff has no right to damages because of the failure to complete. See, e.g., Davis v. Bronson, 50 N. W. 836, 839 (N. D. 1892) (criticizing a line of cases that would seem to hold that the contract-defaulter would be obliged to pay in full should the other side nonetheless fully perform, and concluding "the weight of reason and authority is against it").
  • 79
    • 74849109268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • English law is nominally more protective of the plaintiff in these cases because there is a right to complete performance and recover the contract price unless, perhaps, the plaintiff has no legitimate interest in performing the contract. See White & Carter (Councils) Ltd. v. McGregor, 1962] A. C. 413, 413 H. L. 1961, describing a case where defendants cancelled a contract to have plaintiffs place advertisements on its litterbins on the day the contract was made, plaintiffs went ahead and placed the advertisements for the three-year period of the contract, and plaintiffs were able to recover the contract price
    • English law is nominally more protective of the plaintiff in these cases because there is a right to complete performance and recover the contract price unless, perhaps, the plaintiff has no legitimate interest in performing the contract. See White & Carter (Councils) Ltd. v. McGregor, [1962] A. C. 413, 413 (H. L. 1961) (describing a case where defendants cancelled a contract to have plaintiffs place advertisements on its litterbins on the day the contract was made, plaintiffs went ahead and placed the advertisements for the three-year period of the contract, and plaintiffs were able to recover the contract price).
  • 80
    • 74849085051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew Burrows, REMEDIES FOR TORTS AND BREACH OF CONTRACT 317-22 (2d ed. 1994), surveys the inroads on the rule. Burrows concludes that continued performance is not allowed if it requires the cooperation of the other party or if it runs up damages a great deal and is unnecessary to protect the plaintiff's interests under the contract. This ends up being very close to the American position.
    • Andrew Burrows, REMEDIES FOR TORTS AND BREACH OF CONTRACT 317-22 (2d ed. 1994), surveys the inroads on the rule. Burrows concludes that continued performance is not allowed if it requires the cooperation of the other party or if it runs up damages a great deal and is unnecessary to protect the plaintiff's interests under the contract. This ends up being very close to the American position.
  • 81
    • 74849105412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. Cotton-Oil Co. v. Heflin, 99 F. 339, 347-48 (5th Cir. 1900) (holding that manufacturer of cotton seed who contracted to sell manufacturing by-products to defendant could continue production after stop order and recover difference between contract price and market price);
    • S. Cotton-Oil Co. v. Heflin, 99 F. 339, 347-48 (5th Cir. 1900) (holding that manufacturer of cotton seed who contracted to sell manufacturing by-products to defendant could continue production after stop order and recover difference between contract price and market price);
  • 82
    • 74849092137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Helix Co. v. United States, 524 F.2d 707, 726 (Ct. Cl. 1975) (holding that manufacturer could continue to produce and deliver helium under long-term contract where production was interrelated with other operations, manufacturer had no storage facilities, and there were no other buyers);
    • N. Helix Co. v. United States, 524 F.2d 707, 726 (Ct. Cl. 1975) (holding that manufacturer could continue to produce and deliver helium under long-term contract where production was interrelated with other operations, manufacturer had no storage facilities, and there were no other buyers);
  • 83
    • 74849120427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O'Hare v. Peacock Dairies, Inc., 79 P.2d 433, 442 (Cal. 1938) (holding that a farmer could continue to produce and deliver milk to buyer under long-term contract on the reasoning that the farmer is not obliged to sell his herd to stop production);
    • O'Hare v. Peacock Dairies, Inc., 79 P.2d 433, 442 (Cal. 1938) (holding that a farmer could continue to produce and deliver milk to buyer under long-term contract on the reasoning that the farmer is not obliged to sell his herd to stop production);
  • 84
    • 74849088442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dougan Co. v. Klamath County, 193 P. 645, 657 (Or. 1920, holding a contractor had a right to complete construction of courthouse after a stop order where work had to be completed for the contractor to collect from a special fund established for that purpose and the contractor otherwise would have had a claim only against general revenues of the county, Chief Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr. wrote in a case refusing to apply the rule: We assume that these decisions [citing Clark v. Marsiglia] are right in cases where the continuance of work by the plaintiff would be merely a useless enhancement of damages, But a clear repudiation] would not have ended the right of the plaintiffs to go on under the contract in a case like the present, where there was a common interest in the performance, and where what had been done and what remained to do probably were to a large extent interdependent. Martin v. Meles, 60 N. E. 397, 399 Mass. 1901, Common interest appears to
    • Dougan Co. v. Klamath County, 193 P. 645, 657 (Or. 1920) (holding a contractor had a right to complete construction of courthouse after a stop order where work had to be completed for the contractor to collect from a special fund established for that purpose and the contractor otherwise would have had a claim only against general revenues of the county). Chief Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr. wrote in a case refusing to apply the rule: We assume that these decisions [citing Clark v. Marsiglia] are right in cases where the continuance of work by the plaintiff would be merely a useless enhancement of damages.... [But a clear repudiation] would not have ended the right of the plaintiffs to go on under the contract in a case like the present, where there was a common interest in the performance, and where what had been done and what remained to do probably were to a large extent interdependent. Martin v. Meles, 60 N. E. 397, 399 (Mass. 1901). "Common interest" appears to mean that the plaintiff has an interest in completing performance other than receiving the contract profit.
  • 85
    • 74849107444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 220 P.2d 729 (Cal. 1950).
    • 220 P.2d 729 (Cal. 1950).
  • 86
    • 74849140539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The relevant passage follows. I quote it at length because it is a good statement of the exceptions to the rule and the rationale for both the rule and the exceptions. The reason for this rule is twofold: Ordinarily a plaintiff is interested only in the profit he will make from his contract, and if he receives this he obtains the full benefit of his bargain; on the other hand, performance by the plaintiff might be useless to the defendant, although he would have to pay the entire contract price if the plaintiff were permitted to perform, and this would inflict damage on the defendant without benefit to the plaintiff, If these reasons are not present, the rule is not applied. For example, where the plaintiff is not interested solely in profit from the agreement but must proceed with the work in order to fulfill contract obligations to others, or where refraining from performance might involve closing a factory, damages may be inadequate and the plaintiff may have a right to continue
    • The relevant passage follows. I quote it at length because it is a good statement of the exceptions to the rule and the rationale for both the rule and the exceptions. The reason for this rule is twofold: Ordinarily a plaintiff is interested only in the profit he will make from his contract, and if he receives this he obtains the full benefit of his bargain; on the other hand, performance by the plaintiff might be useless to the defendant, although he would have to pay the entire contract price if the plaintiff were permitted to perform, and this would inflict damage on the defendant without benefit to the plaintiff.... If these reasons are not present, the rule is not applied. For example, where the plaintiff is not interested solely in profit from the agreement but must proceed with the work in order to fulfill contract obligations to others, or where refraining from performance might involve closing a factory, damages may be inadequate and the plaintiff may have a right to continue performance.... It has likewise been held that where a contractor has started work and has reached a point where it would be impracticable to attempt to make a reasonable estimate of damages, or where to complete the work will diminish damages or at least not enhance them, the contractor may go forward and complete performance.... The general rule is also subject to the jurisdiction of equity to order specific performance of the contract, and, apparently in recognition of this principle, it has been held that in cases where damages will not afford adequate compensation and where specific performance will lie, the plaintiff may continue to perform, in spite of a notice to stop, and thereafter recover on the basis of his continued performance.... Id. at 733-34.
  • 87
    • 74849134556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 731
    • Id. at 731.
  • 88
    • 74849084547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 89
    • 74849131265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 90
    • 74849089788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 732
    • Id. at 732.
  • 91
    • 74849140536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In an interesting twist, McKelvey went to court and tried to get a preliminary injunction prohibiting Bomberger from demolishing the building, asserting its right as owner to exclude Bomberger from the property. The trial court denied the request. Id. at 729
    • In an interesting twist, McKelvey went to court and tried to get a preliminary injunction prohibiting Bomberger from demolishing the building, asserting its right as owner to exclude Bomberger from the property. The trial court denied the request. Id. at 729.
  • 92
    • 74849111941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 732
    • Id. at 732.
  • 93
    • 74849105118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 736-37
    • Id. at 736-37.
  • 94
    • 74849102863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 732-33
    • Id. at 732-33.
  • 95
    • 74849097032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clea Shipping Corp. v. Bulk Oil Int'l Ltd., [1984] 1 All E. R. 129, 136-37 (Q. B. 1983).
    • Clea Shipping Corp. v. Bulk Oil Int'l Ltd., [1984] 1 All E. R. 129, 136-37 (Q. B. 1983).
  • 96
    • 84868052511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The occurrence of a material breach or a total breach triggers several possible legal responses. These include the power to suspend performance, the power to abandon a contract and make substitute arrangements (e.g., cover or resale), and the power to recover in restitution for the reasonable value of any performance rendered. The Restatement (Second) of Contracts distinguishes between material and total breach on the basis of whether the harm from the breach is curable. Under the Restatement, a material breach that is curable justifies suspending performance. See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 242 cmt. a (1981).
    • The occurrence of a material breach or a total breach triggers several possible legal responses. These include the power to suspend performance, the power to abandon a contract and make substitute arrangements (e.g., cover or resale), and the power to recover in restitution for the reasonable value of any performance rendered. The Restatement (Second) of Contracts distinguishes between material and total breach on the basis of whether the harm from the breach is curable. Under the Restatement, a material breach that is curable justifies suspending performance. See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 242 cmt. a (1981).
  • 97
    • 84868052510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A total breach - meaning an incurable material breach - discharges the non-defaulting party, justifying his withdrawal from the contract. Id. §§ 236, 243 (1) - (2). It also justifies the optional restitution remedy.
    • A total breach - meaning an incurable material breach - discharges the non-defaulting party, justifying his withdrawal from the contract. Id. §§ 236, 243 (1) - (2). It also justifies the optional restitution remedy.
  • 99
    • 74849090886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Reynolds v. Armstead, 443 P.2d 990, 992 (Colo. 1968) (holding that a contractor in material breach nonetheless could recover the value his work had added to the house);
    • See, e.g., Reynolds v. Armstead, 443 P.2d 990, 992 (Colo. 1968) (holding that a contractor in material breach nonetheless could recover the value his work had added to the house);
  • 100
    • 74849084765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levan v. Richter, 504 N. E.2d 1373, 1381 (Ill. 1987) (ruling that a contractor who constructed an in-ground swimming pool so shoddily that it could not hold water was entitled to nothing as it had no value at all);
    • Levan v. Richter, 504 N. E.2d 1373, 1381 (Ill. 1987) (ruling that a contractor who constructed an in-ground swimming pool so shoddily that it could not hold water was entitled to nothing as it had no value at all);
  • 101
    • 74849139995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Plante v. Jacobs, 103 N. W.2d 296, 298-99 (Wis. 1960)
    • Plante v. Jacobs, 103 N. W.2d 296, 298-99 (Wis. 1960)
  • 102
    • 74849097652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (holding that a builder who did not entirely complete construction of a house was entitled to contract price minus damages). In a few states, a party who substantially performs has a right to recover in restitution, while a party whose work falls short of this forfeits compensation. J. A. Sullivan Corp. v. Commonwealth, 494 N. E.2d 374, 378-79 (Mass. 1986)
    • (holding that a builder who did not entirely complete construction of a house was entitled to contract price minus damages). In a few states, a party who substantially performs has a right to recover in restitution, while a party whose work falls short of this forfeits compensation. J. A. Sullivan Corp. v. Commonwealth, 494 N. E.2d 374, 378-79 (Mass. 1986)
  • 103
    • 74849092134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (finding that a contractor who built a college gym was entitled to payment for the work he had completed, despite contract allowing payment only if every item finished). The New York rule on construction contracts is a variant. A contractor who substantially performs is paid on the contract (less damages) but there is no claim in restitution if the work falls short of this. Steel Storage & Elevator Constr. Co. v. Stock, 121 N. E. 786, 787 (N. Y. 1919)
    • (finding that a contractor who built a college gym was entitled to payment for the work he had completed, despite contract allowing payment only if every item finished). The New York rule on construction contracts is a variant. A contractor who substantially performs is paid on the contract (less damages) but there is no claim in restitution if the work falls short of this. Steel Storage & Elevator Constr. Co. v. Stock, 121 N. E. 786, 787 (N. Y. 1919)
  • 104
    • 74849103866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (holding that an elevator fabricator failed to show cause for any award because the elevator had not met every essential requirement). New York law has softened outside the construction context. Hadden v. Consolidated Edison Co. of New York, 312 N. E.2d 445, 449 (N. Y. 1974),
    • (holding that an elevator fabricator failed to show cause for any award because the elevator had not met every essential requirement). New York law has softened outside the construction context. Hadden v. Consolidated Edison Co. of New York, 312 N. E.2d 445, 449 (N. Y. 1974),
  • 105
    • 74849083587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • states that willfulness of default is only one factor to consider in deciding if an employee substantially performed his job and holds that an employee who had taken bribes from contractors might not forfeit his pension. The New York Court of Appeals ultimately concluded forfeiture of the pension was appropriate on a technical ground. Hadden v. Consol. Edison Co. of N. Y, Inc. 382 N. E.2d 1136, 1139 N. Y. 1978
    • states that willfulness of default is only one factor to consider in deciding if an employee substantially performed his job and holds that an employee who had taken bribes from contractors might not forfeit his pension. The New York Court of Appeals ultimately concluded forfeiture of the pension was appropriate on a technical ground. Hadden v. Consol. Edison Co. of N. Y., Inc. 382 N. E.2d 1136, 1139 (N. Y. 1978).
  • 106
    • 74849100150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert A. Hillman, Keeping the Deal Together After Material Breach - Common Law Mitigation Rules, the UCC, and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts, 47 COLO. L. REV. 553 (1976), remains a good treatment of the topic.
    • Robert A. Hillman, Keeping the Deal Together After Material Breach - Common Law Mitigation Rules, the UCC, and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts, 47 COLO. L. REV. 553 (1976), remains a good treatment of the topic.
  • 107
    • 74849087642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hillman challenges the many cases that state in categorical terms that there is no obligation to do further business with a defaulter. Id. The most famous of these cases is Canadian Industrial Alcohol Co. v. Dunabar Molasses Co, 179 N. E. 383 N. Y. 1932
    • Hillman challenges the many cases that state in categorical terms that there is no obligation to do further business with a defaulter. Id. The most famous of these cases is Canadian Industrial Alcohol Co. v. Dunabar Molasses Co., 179 N. E. 383 (N. Y. 1932).
  • 108
    • 74849083282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It held that the plaintiff replied in substance that it had no longer any faith in the defendant's readiness or ability to live up to its engagements, and did not wish to add another contract to the one already broken. The law did not charge it with a duty to make such an experiment again. Id. at 385;
    • It held that the plaintiff replied in substance that it had no longer any faith in the defendant's readiness or ability to live up to its engagements, and did not wish to add another contract to the one already broken. The law did not charge it with a duty to make such an experiment again. Id. at 385;
  • 109
    • 74849083590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also W-V Enters., Inc. v. Fed. Sav. & Loan Ins. Corp. 673 P.2d 1112, 1122 (Kan. 1983) ([T]here is no obligation to mitigate damages if the mitigation involves dealing with the breaching party.).
    • see also W-V Enters., Inc. v. Fed. Sav. & Loan Ins. Corp. 673 P.2d 1112, 1122 (Kan. 1983) ("[T]here is no obligation to mitigate damages if the mitigation involves dealing with the breaching party.").
  • 110
    • 74849086488 scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of excuse to avoid forfeiture, see, 2d ed
    • For a discussion of excuse to avoid forfeiture, see E. ALLAN FARNS wORTH, CONTRACTS 595-600 (2d ed. 1990).
    • (1990) FARNS wORTH, CONTRACTS , pp. 595-600
    • ALLAN, E.1
  • 111
    • 84868052509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (1981).
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (1981).
  • 112
    • 74849119877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The factors are: (a) the extent to which the injured party will be deprived of the benefit which he reasonably expected; (b) the extent to which the injured party can be adequately compensated for the part of the benefit of which he will be deprived; (c) the extent to which the party failing to perform or to offer to perform will suffer forfeiture; (d) the likelihood that the party failing to perform or to offer to perform will cure his failure, taking account of all the circumstances including any reasonable assurances; (e) the extent to which the behavior of the party failing to perform or to offer to perform comports with standards of good faith and fair dealing.
    • The factors are: (a) the extent to which the injured party will be deprived of the benefit which he reasonably expected; (b) the extent to which the injured party can be adequately compensated for the part of the benefit of which he will be deprived; (c) the extent to which the party failing to perform or to offer to perform will suffer forfeiture; (d) the likelihood that the party failing to perform or to offer to perform will cure his failure, taking account of all the circumstances including any reasonable assurances; (e) the extent to which the behavior of the party failing to perform or to offer to perform comports with standards of good faith and fair dealing.
  • 113
    • 74849090065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Some cases offer a somewhat higher standard to justify termination, requiring a material breach which destroys the entire purpose of entering into the contract. Ervin Constr. Co. v. Van Orden, 874 P.2d 506, 511 (Idaho 1993);
    • Id. Some cases offer a somewhat higher standard to justify termination, requiring "a material breach which destroys the entire purpose of entering into the contract." Ervin Constr. Co. v. Van Orden, 874 P.2d 506, 511 (Idaho 1993);
  • 114
    • 74849137364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, e.g., Peters v. Blagden Homes Inc., 151 A.2d 183, 184 (D. C. 1959) (finding for a homebuilder whose guaranteed damp-proof basement flooded before it could be finished, prompting purchaser to breach before allowing the builder to finish all necessary work). Another version of the standard asks if the contract would not have been made if default in that particular had been expected or contemplated. Huffman v. Saul Holdings Ltd. P'ship, 194 F.3d 1072, 1081 (8th Cir. 1999) (quoting Berland's, Inc. of Tulsa v. Northside Vill. Shopping Ctr., Inc., 378 P.2d 860, 865 (Okla. 1963)).
    • see also, e.g., Peters v. Blagden Homes Inc., 151 A.2d 183, 184 (D. C. 1959) (finding for a homebuilder whose guaranteed damp-proof basement flooded before it could be finished, prompting purchaser to breach before allowing the builder to finish all necessary work). Another version of the standard asks if "the contract would not have been made if default in that particular had been expected or contemplated." Huffman v. Saul Holdings Ltd. P'ship, 194 F.3d 1072, 1081 (8th Cir. 1999) (quoting Berland's, Inc. of Tulsa v. Northside Vill. Shopping Ctr., Inc., 378 P.2d 860, 865 (Okla. 1963)).
  • 115
    • 74849096003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (2004) : In determining whether a failure to perform an obligation amounts to a fundamental non-performance regard shall be had, in particular, to whether: (a) the nonperformance substantially deprives the aggrieved party of what it was entitled to expect under the contract unless the other party did not foresee and could not reasonably have foreseen such result; (b) strict compliance with the obligation which has not been performed is of essence under the contract; (c) the non-performance is intentional or reckless; (d) the non-performance gives the aggrieved party reason to believe that it cannot rely on the other party's future performance; (e) the non-performing party will suffer disproportionate loss as a result of the preparation or performance if the contract is terminated. The UNIDROIT Principles are a product of an effort to state global principles of commercial law incorporating both common law and civil law.
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (2004) : In determining whether a failure to perform an obligation amounts to a fundamental non-performance regard shall be had, in particular, to whether: (a) the nonperformance substantially deprives the aggrieved party of what it was entitled to expect under the contract unless the other party did not foresee and could not reasonably have foreseen such result; (b) strict compliance with the obligation which has not been performed is of essence under the contract; (c) the non-performance is intentional or reckless; (d) the non-performance gives the aggrieved party reason to believe that it cannot rely on the other party's future performance; (e) the non-performing party will suffer disproportionate loss as a result of the preparation or performance if the contract is terminated. The UNIDROIT Principles are a product of an effort to state global principles of commercial law incorporating both common law and civil law.
  • 116
    • 84868057819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (a) - (b), (d) (1981);
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (a) - (b), (d) (1981);
  • 117
    • 74849126720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (a) - (b), (d) (2004).
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (a) - (b), (d) (2004).
  • 118
    • 84868057820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (c) (1981)
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (c) (1981)
  • 119
    • 84868057821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • states the principle against forfeiture. UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (e) (2004) speaks of avoiding a disproportionate loss to the defaulter. These are much the same thing. The Restatement (Second) of Contracts defines forfeiture as the denial of compensation that results when the obligee loses his right to the agreed exchange after he has relied substantially. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 227 cmt. b (1981).
    • states the principle against forfeiture. UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (e) (2004) speaks of avoiding a "disproportionate loss" to the defaulter. These are much the same thing. The Restatement (Second) of Contracts defines forfeiture as "the denial of compensation that results when the obligee loses his right to the agreed exchange after he has relied substantially." RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 227 cmt. b (1981).
  • 120
    • 74849121900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Restatement's definition of forfeiture suggests two baselines for measuring forfeiture. The references to reliance and the denial of compensation suggest a baseline of the defaulter's pre-contractual position. The reference to the defaulter's right to the agreed exchange suggests a baseline of the defaulter's position if the contract was fully performed by both sides. I think the latter view is more in accord with the law. Countless insurance cases invoke the principle opposing forfeiture to protect the right of an insured to collect on what is in effect a winning bet notwithstanding his default on a technical term of the bet using tools such as construction to protect reasonable expectation, interpretation, waiver, estoppel, and impracticability. See Clark v. West, 86 N. E. 1, 5 N. Y. 1908
    • The Restatement's definition of forfeiture suggests two baselines for measuring forfeiture. The references to "reliance" and "the denial of compensation" suggest a baseline of the defaulter's pre-contractual position. The reference to the defaulter's "right to the agreed exchange" suggests a baseline of the defaulter's position if the contract was fully performed by both sides. I think the latter view is more in accord with the law. Countless insurance cases invoke the principle opposing forfeiture to protect the right of an insured to collect on what is in effect a winning bet notwithstanding his default on a technical term of the bet using tools such as construction to protect reasonable expectation, interpretation, waiver, estoppel, and impracticability. See Clark v. West, 86 N. E. 1, 5 (N. Y. 1908)
  • 121
    • 74849133964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (The cases which present the most familiar phases of the doctrine of waiver are those which have arisen out of litigation over insurance policies where the defendants have claimed a forfeiture because of the breach of some condition in the contract....). Aetna Casualty & Surety Co. v. Murphy, 538 A.2d 219, 221-22 (Conn. 1988),
    • ("The cases which present the most familiar phases of the doctrine of waiver are those which have arisen out of litigation over insurance policies where the defendants have claimed a forfeiture because of the breach of some condition in the contract...."). Aetna Casualty & Surety Co. v. Murphy, 538 A.2d 219, 221-22 (Conn. 1988),
  • 122
    • 84868057818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • is striking because the court dispensed with these tools and applied a rule requiring an insurer to show actual prejudice from an insured's failure to give timely notice of a claim, relying on RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 229 1981, Sales cases that prevent a buyer from rejecting goods because of a minor defect to get out of a losing bargain are similar
    • is striking because the court dispensed with these tools and applied a rule requiring an insurer to show actual prejudice from an insured's failure to give timely notice of a claim, relying on RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 229 (1981). Sales cases that prevent a buyer from rejecting goods because of a minor defect to get out of a losing bargain are similar.
  • 123
    • 74849086179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JAMES J. WHITE & ROBERT S. SUMMERS, UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE 355-57 (3d ed. 1988)
    • See JAMES J. WHITE & ROBERT S. SUMMERS, UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE 355-57 (3d ed. 1988)
  • 124
    • 84868052505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (concluding that relatively little is left of the UCC perfect tender rule, U. C. C. §2-601, because courts have used a variety of devices to prevent sellers from rejecting goods in bad faith to escape a disadvantageous bargain).
    • (concluding that "relatively little is left" of the UCC perfect tender rule, U. C. C. §2-601, because courts have used a variety of devices to prevent sellers from rejecting goods in bad faith to escape a disadvantageous bargain).
  • 125
    • 84868052506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (e) (1981);
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 (e) (1981);
  • 126
    • 74849137367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (c) (2004). I will come back to this element in the next Part, for it may be invoked to excuse a refusal to perform when the obligation to perform is uncertain. A related rule in the law of substantial performance and in the law of restitution denies a contractor who knowingly deviates from a contract any recovery for the value of the work done. Many cases state the rule though there seem to be few occasions to apply it. Tolstoy Constr. Co. v. Minter, 143 Cal. Rptr. 570, 573 (Ct. App. 1978);
    • UNIDROIT PRINCIPLES OF INT'L COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS art. 7.3.1 (2) (c) (2004). I will come back to this element in the next Part, for it may be invoked to excuse a refusal to perform when the obligation to perform is uncertain. A related rule in the law of substantial performance and in the law of restitution denies a contractor who knowingly deviates from a contract any recovery for the value of the work done. Many cases state the rule though there seem to be few occasions to apply it. Tolstoy Constr. Co. v. Minter, 143 Cal. Rptr. 570, 573 (Ct. App. 1978);
  • 127
    • 74849139673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moore's Builder & Contractor, Inc. v. Hoffman, 409 N. W.2d 191, 195 (Iowa Ct. App. 1987);
    • Moore's Builder & Contractor, Inc. v. Hoffman, 409 N. W.2d 191, 195 (Iowa Ct. App. 1987);
  • 128
    • 74849108738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peabody N. E., Inc. v. Town of Marshfield, 689 N. E.2d 774, 779-80 (Mass. 1998);
    • Peabody N. E., Inc. v. Town of Marshfield, 689 N. E.2d 774, 779-80 (Mass. 1998);
  • 129
    • 74849107442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sear-Brown Assocs., P. C. v. Blackwatch Dev. Corp., 492 N. Y. S.2d 266, 266 (App. Div. 1985) (applying the rule to deny recovery due to intentional deviation);
    • Sear-Brown Assocs., P. C. v. Blackwatch Dev. Corp., 492 N. Y. S.2d 266, 266 (App. Div. 1985) (applying the rule to deny recovery due to intentional deviation);
  • 130
    • 74849122485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merrill Iron & Steel, Inc. v. Minn-Dak Seeds, Ltd., 334 N. W.2d 652, 656-57 (N. D. 1983);
    • Merrill Iron & Steel, Inc. v. Minn-Dak Seeds, Ltd., 334 N. W.2d 652, 656-57 (N. D. 1983);
  • 131
    • 74849089493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ahlers Bldg. Supply, Inc. v. Larsen, 535 N. W.2d 431, 435 (S. D. 1995);
    • Ahlers Bldg. Supply, Inc. v. Larsen, 535 N. W.2d 431, 435 (S. D. 1995);
  • 132
    • 74849118060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Uhlir v. Golden Triangle Dev. Corp., 763 S. W.2d 512, 514, 516-17 (Tex. Civ. App. 1988) (referencing the rule but not finding it applicable in that case).
    • Uhlir v. Golden Triangle Dev. Corp., 763 S. W.2d 512, 514, 516-17 (Tex. Civ. App. 1988) (referencing the rule but not finding it applicable in that case).
  • 133
    • 74849116952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There have been some inroads on this rule. Hayeck Building & Realty Co. v. Turcotte, 282 N. E.2d 907, 910 (Mass. 1972), requires only that a contractor act in good faith and countenances a switch to less costly method of doing work.
    • There have been some inroads on this rule. Hayeck Building & Realty Co. v. Turcotte, 282 N. E.2d 907, 910 (Mass. 1972), requires only that a contractor act in good faith and countenances a switch to less costly method of doing work.
  • 134
    • 84868084623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mathis v. Thunderbird Village, 389 P.2d 343, 351 (Or. 1964), which is the basis for RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 illus. 7 (1981), excuses a builder's intentional failure to complete work in a minor respect because it was prompted by the owner's failure to pay.
    • Mathis v. Thunderbird Village, 389 P.2d 343, 351 (Or. 1964), which is the basis for RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 illus. 7 (1981), excuses a builder's intentional failure to complete work in a minor respect because it was prompted by the owner's failure to pay.
  • 135
    • 74849114859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vincenzi v. Cerro, 442 A.2d 1352, 1354 (Conn. 1982), excuses allegedly willful failure to complete work in a timely fashion because the failure was minimal. A parallel rule holds that in a case in which a contractor willfully deviates from contract specifications, a plaintiff is entitled to recover remedial cost, no matter how disproportionate this amount may be to the apparent loss.
    • Vincenzi v. Cerro, 442 A.2d 1352, 1354 (Conn. 1982), excuses allegedly willful failure to complete work in a timely fashion because the failure was minimal. A parallel rule holds that in a case in which a contractor willfully deviates from contract specifications, a plaintiff is entitled to recover remedial cost, no matter how disproportionate this amount may be to the apparent loss.
  • 136
    • 74849124835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kangas v. Trust, 441 N. E.2d 1271, 1276 (Ill. 1982);
    • Kangas v. Trust, 441 N. E.2d 1271, 1276 (Ill. 1982);
  • 137
    • 74849100152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roudis v. Hubbard, 574 N. Y. S.2d 95, 96 (App. Div. 1991);
    • Roudis v. Hubbard, 574 N. Y. S.2d 95, 96 (App. Div. 1991);
  • 138
    • 74849106310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fid. & Deposit Co. v. Stool, 607 S. W.2d 17, 20-21 (Tex. Civ. App. 1980).
    • Fid. & Deposit Co. v. Stool, 607 S. W.2d 17, 20-21 (Tex. Civ. App. 1980).
  • 139
    • 74849126128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contra Grossman Holdings, Ltd. v. Hourihan, 414 So. 2d 1037, 1039-40 (Fla. 1982) (denying remedial cost though contractor built house facing in wrong direction over repeated protests of owner). A plausible explanation for the traditional rules is that they discourage a party from unilaterally modifying a contract by denying him compensation for-a knowing deviation.
    • Contra Grossman Holdings, Ltd. v. Hourihan, 414 So. 2d 1037, 1039-40 (Fla. 1982) (denying remedial cost though contractor built house facing in wrong direction over repeated protests of owner). A plausible explanation for the traditional rules is that they discourage a party from unilaterally modifying a contract by denying him compensation for-a knowing deviation.
  • 140
    • 84868084625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Andrew Kull, Restitution's Outlaws, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 17, 18 (2003) (making the general point that restitution punishes wrongdoers by withholding a claim that it would otherwise allow to prevent unjust enrichment). The Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment concurs by stating that restitution to the builder who knowingly deviates from plans should be qualified or denied in order to avoid subjecting the owner to a forced exchange. RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 36 (b) (Council Draft No. 5, Nov. 24, 2003);
    • See Andrew Kull, Restitution's Outlaws, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 17, 18 (2003) (making the general point that restitution punishes wrongdoers by withholding a claim that it would otherwise allow to prevent unjust enrichment). The Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment concurs by stating that restitution to the builder who knowingly deviates from plans should be qualified or denied in order to avoid subjecting the owner to a forced exchange. RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 36 (b) (Council Draft No. 5, Nov. 24, 2003);
  • 141
    • 74849088439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. cmt. b. This analogizes the builder who deviates from plans to the knowing trespasser who builds an improvement.
    • id. cmt. b. This analogizes the builder who deviates from plans to the knowing trespasser who builds an improvement.
  • 142
    • 74849107387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Even property rights can give way if an infringement is minor and enjoining the infringement would inflict an undue hardship on the infringer. Mannillo v. Gorski, 255 A.2d 258, 264 (N. J. 1969) (innocent encroacher is only made to pay the market value of what he has taken). Typically, the doctrine of undue hardship protects only innocent infringers.
    • Id. Even property rights can give way if an infringement is minor and enjoining the infringement would inflict an undue hardship on the infringer. Mannillo v. Gorski, 255 A.2d 258, 264 (N. J. 1969) (innocent encroacher is only made to pay the market value of what he has taken). Typically, the doctrine of undue hardship protects only innocent infringers.
  • 143
    • 74849123378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ariola v. Nigro, 156 N. E.2d 536, 543 (111. 1959) (relying on rule that an intentional encroachment will always be enjoined). There are some situations in which it is well established that intentional breach will not bar recovery for the value of part performance. One is where a defaulter renders part performance and then abandons a contract.
    • Ariola v. Nigro, 156 N. E.2d 536, 543 (111. 1959) (relying on rule that an intentional encroachment will always be enjoined). There are some situations in which it is well established that intentional breach will not bar recovery for the value of part performance. One is where a defaulter renders part performance and then abandons a contract.
  • 144
    • 74849110133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two staples of the Contracts course, Britton v. Turner, 6 N. H. 481 (1834),
    • Two staples of the Contracts course, Britton v. Turner, 6 N. H. 481 (1834),
  • 145
    • 74849103569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Vines v. Orchard Hills, Inc., 435 A.2d 1022 (Conn. 1980), are in this mold. In Britton, a worker abandoned a contract for a year's employment after working nine and one-half months.
    • and Vines v. Orchard Hills, Inc., 435 A.2d 1022 (Conn. 1980), are in this mold. In Britton, a worker abandoned a contract for a year's employment after working nine and one-half months.
  • 146
    • 74849111993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Britton, 6 N. H. at 482. In Vines, a condominium buyer backed out of the contract after paying a hefty deposit.
    • Britton, 6 N. H. at 482. In Vines, a condominium buyer backed out of the contract after paying a hefty deposit.
  • 147
    • 84868071012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vines, 435 A.2d at 1025. Both cases allow the defaulter to recover for the value of his part performance less whatever holdback is necessary to put the other party in the promised position. Construction contracts are no different. A builder who abandons a job may recover the contract price less the other party's cost of completing the work. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 348 illus. 2 (1981).
    • Vines, 435 A.2d at 1025. Both cases allow the defaulter to recover for the value of his part performance less whatever holdback is necessary to put the other party in the promised position. Construction contracts are no different. A builder who abandons a job may recover the contract price less the other party's cost of completing the work. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 348 illus. 2 (1981).
  • 148
    • 74849108971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is true even in New York, which usually is stern towards a builder who knowingly deviates from a contract. Mirisis v. Renda, 441 N. Y. S.2d 138, 139 App. Div. 1981
    • This is true even in New York, which usually is stern towards a builder who knowingly deviates from a contract. Mirisis v. Renda, 441 N. Y. S.2d 138, 139 (App. Div. 1981).
  • 149
    • 74849105411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That the aggrieved party is generally indifferent to who completes performance so long as he pays no more than the contract price for what he buys or receives no less than the contract price for what he sells might explain why forfeiture is unjustified in these situation. In these cases, default does not expose the aggrieved party to risk of uncompensated loss
    • That the aggrieved party is generally indifferent to who completes performance so long as he pays no more than the contract price for what he buys or receives no less than the contract price for what he sells might explain why forfeiture is unjustified in these situation. In these cases, default does not expose the aggrieved party to risk of uncompensated loss.
  • 150
    • 84868052493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 cmt. (a) (1981) (This Section therefore states circumstances, not rules, which are to be considered in determining whether a particular failure is material.);
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 241 cmt. (a) (1981) ("This Section therefore states circumstances, not rules, which are to be considered in determining whether a particular failure is material.");
  • 151
    • 84868084608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 241 cmt. b ([N]o simple rule based on the ratio of the one to the other can be laid down, and here, as elsewhere under this Section, all relevant circumstances must be considered.).
    • id. § 241 cmt. b ("[N]o simple rule based on the ratio of the one to the other can be laid down, and here, as elsewhere under this Section, all relevant circumstances must be considered.").
  • 152
    • 74849120184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.
    • See supra Part I.
  • 153
    • 84868052490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U. C. C. § 2-601 (2002) (stating the perfect tender rule).
    • U. C. C. § 2-601 (2002) (stating the "perfect tender" rule).
  • 154
    • 84868084609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 2-608 (1). The United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (CISG) has a fundamental default standard. United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods art. 25, Apr. 11, 1980, S. TREATY DOC. NO. 98-9 (1988), 1489 U. N. T. S. 3.
    • Id. § 2-608 (1). The United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods ("CISG") has a fundamental default standard. United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods art. 25, Apr. 11, 1980, S. TREATY DOC. NO. 98-9 (1988), 1489 U. N. T. S. 3.
  • 155
    • 74849093577 scopus 로고
    • Rejection, Revocation, and Cure Under Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code: Some Modest Proposals, 84
    • John A. Sebert, Jr., Rejection, Revocation, and Cure Under Article 2 of the Uniform Commercial Code: Some Modest Proposals, 84 NW. U. L. REV. 375, 399-08 (1990);
    • (1990) NW. U. L. REV , vol.375 , pp. 399-408
    • Sebert Jr., J.A.1
  • 156
    • 74849104184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Donald W. Garland, Determining Whether a Nonconformity Substantially Impairs the Value of Goods: Some Guidelines, 26 UCC L. J. 129, 143 (1993).
    • see also Donald W. Garland, Determining Whether a Nonconformity Substantially Impairs the Value of Goods: Some Guidelines, 26 UCC L. J. 129, 143 (1993).
  • 157
    • 74849125829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 362 N. W.2d 704 (Mich. 1984).
    • 362 N. W.2d 704 (Mich. 1984).
  • 158
    • 74849118059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 705
    • Id. at 705.
  • 159
    • 74849101626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 160
    • 74849128456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The dealer and the manufacturer thought Miller was returning the car on a pretext and that he knew it came without a spare. Id. at 706. The case took place in Detroit where local newspapers and television had reported that dealers were delivering new cars without spares because of the auto workers' strike. STEWART MACCAULEY, JOHN KIDWELL & WILLIAM WHITFORD, CONTRACTS LAW IN ACTION: THE CONCISE COURSE 130-31 2d ed. 2003
    • The dealer and the manufacturer thought Miller was returning the car on a pretext and that he knew it came without a spare. Id. at 706. The case took place in Detroit where local newspapers and television had reported that dealers were delivering new cars without spares because of the auto workers' strike. STEWART MACCAULEY, JOHN KIDWELL & WILLIAM WHITFORD, CONTRACTS LAW IN ACTION: THE CONCISE COURSE 130-31 (2d ed. 2003).
  • 161
    • 74849126129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 103 N. W.2d 296 (Wis. 1960).
    • 103 N. W.2d 296 (Wis. 1960).
  • 162
    • 74849091535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 297
    • Id. at 297.
  • 163
    • 74849122195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 299
    • Id. at 299.
  • 164
    • 74849099825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 298-99
    • Id. at 298-99.
  • 165
    • 74849094552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal & Mining Co., 382 P.2d 109 (Okla. 1962), is a famous and troublesome illustration of an application of the second rule. Garland failed to fulfill its promise to restore seven acres of farmland that it had strip-mined.
    • Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal & Mining Co., 382 P.2d 109 (Okla. 1962), is a famous and troublesome illustration of an application of the second rule. Garland failed to fulfill its promise to restore seven acres of farmland that it had strip-mined.
  • 166
    • 84868052491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 111. The Peevyhouses were left with a large water-filled pit that barred access to other land they owned and leased. The estimated cost of restoring the land was $29, 000 while the diminution in market value of the seven acres was only $300.
    • Id. at 111. The Peevyhouses were left with a large water-filled pit that barred access to other land they owned and leased. The estimated cost of restoring the land was $29, 000 while the diminution in market value of the seven acres was only $300.
  • 167
    • 84868071010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 111-12. The jury awarded the Peevyhouses $5000.
    • Id. at 111-12. The jury awarded the Peevyhouses $5000.
  • 169
    • 74849100447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peevyhouse often is paired with Groves v. John Wunder Co., 286 N. W. 235 (Minn. 1939), which holds that a defendant who willfully fails to perform must pay the remedial cost though it is far in excess of loss in market value.
    • Peevyhouse often is paired with Groves v. John Wunder Co., 286 N. W. 235 (Minn. 1939), which holds that a defendant who willfully fails to perform must pay the remedial cost though it is far in excess of loss in market value.
  • 170
    • 74849133962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 236. Decisions such as Peevyhouse and Groves are further testament to the value placed on remedial simplicity in American law. Often in these cases, the loss to the plaintiff, if converted to dollars, would be an amount between the remedial cost and the loss in market value. The rule requires choosing one or the other objective measure of damages though we are confident one over-compensates and the other under-compensates. The plaintiff is entitled to submit evidence that he has abnormal interests or preferences that justify an award of remedial costs. The rule only requires choosing one of two objective measures of damages, which makes it possible for the court to resolve the issue. See, e.g, Peevyhouse, 382 P.2d at 111 (articulating the question on appeal as whether the plaintiff will receive the cost to obtain performance of the work or the diminution in value of the property caused by the incomplete work);
    • Id. at 236. Decisions such as Peevyhouse and Groves are further testament to the value placed on remedial simplicity in American law. Often in these cases, the loss to the plaintiff, if converted to dollars, would be an amount between the remedial cost and the loss in market value. The rule requires choosing one or the other objective measure of damages though we are confident one over-compensates and the other under-compensates. The plaintiff is entitled to submit evidence that he has abnormal interests or preferences that justify an award of remedial costs. The rule only requires choosing one of two objective measures of damages, which makes it possible for the court to resolve the issue. See, e.g., Peevyhouse, 382 P.2d at 111 (articulating the question on appeal as whether the plaintiff will receive the cost to obtain performance of the work or the diminution in value of the property caused by the incomplete work);
  • 171
    • 74849106801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Ruxley Elecs. & Constr. Ltd. v. Forsyth, [1996] A. C. 344, 361 (H. L.) (appeal taken from Eng.) (U. K.) (adopting a middle-ground award of damages for loss of amenity where cost was great and affect on market value was zero of deepening swimming pool to unusual depth specified by tall buyer in contract). This middle-ground is possible because there is no jury trial in civil litigation in the United Kingdom. See, e.g., id.
    • cf. Ruxley Elecs. & Constr. Ltd. v. Forsyth, [1996] A. C. 344, 361 (H. L.) (appeal taken from Eng.) (U. K.) (adopting a middle-ground award of damages "for loss of amenity" where cost was great and affect on market value was zero of deepening swimming pool to unusual depth specified by tall buyer in contract). This middle-ground is possible because there is no jury trial in civil litigation in the United Kingdom. See, e.g., id.
  • 172
    • 74849096747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carol Chomsky, Of Spoil Pits and Swimming Pools: Reconsidering the Measure of Damages for Construction Contracts, 75 MINN. L. REV. 1445, 1451-60 (1991), reviews many similar cases and argues that the primary focus of the courts is avoiding economic waste. Professor Chomsky favors a rule that would permit the owner to recover remedial cost if a court was persuaded the owner was likely to do the remedial work. Id. at 1497-98.
    • Carol Chomsky, Of Spoil Pits and Swimming Pools: Reconsidering the Measure of Damages for Construction Contracts, 75 MINN. L. REV. 1445, 1451-60 (1991), reviews many similar cases and argues that the primary focus of the courts is avoiding economic waste. Professor Chomsky favors a rule that would permit the owner to recover remedial cost if a court was persuaded the owner was likely to do the remedial work. Id. at 1497-98.
  • 173
    • 84868084606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 348 cmt. c (1981) (It is sometimes said that the award would involve 'economic waste,' but this is a misleading expression since an injured party will not, even if awarded an excessive amount of damages, usually pay to have the defects remedied if to do so will cost him more than the resulting increase in value to him.);
    • See, e.g., RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 348 cmt. c (1981) ("It is sometimes said that the award would involve 'economic waste,' but this is a misleading expression since an injured party will not, even if awarded an excessive amount of damages, usually pay to have the defects remedied if to do so will cost him more than the resulting increase in value to him.");
  • 174
    • 74849097317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FARNSWORTH, supra note 59, at 619 ([T]he concept of substantial, as opposed to strict, performance evolved in response to the risk of forfeiture....). Hancock v. Northcutt, 808 P.2d 251, 256 (Alaska 1991), follows this reasoning to the logical conclusion that if the jury finds that the claimant will make the repair, it must award cost of repair regardless of the loss in market value.
    • FARNSWORTH, supra note 59, at 619 ("[T]he concept of substantial, as opposed to strict, performance evolved in response to the risk of forfeiture...."). Hancock v. Northcutt, 808 P.2d 251, 256 (Alaska 1991), follows this reasoning to the logical conclusion that if the jury finds that the claimant will make the repair, it must award cost of repair regardless of the loss in market value.
  • 175
    • 74749110170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Plante, 103 N. W.2d at 299.
    • See Plante, 103 N. W.2d at 299.
  • 176
    • 74849102862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • My impression is that few Contracts teachers are aware of this rule. The treatment of Jacobs & Young v. Kent, 129 N. E. 889, 891 (N. Y. 1921) (refusing to award the cost of replacing piping from an incorrect factory because the defect was insubstantial and the cost of replacing the piping would have been great), by RICHARD DANZIG & GEOFFREY R. WATSON, THE CAPABILITY PROBLEM OF CONTRACT LAW 95-118 (2d ed. 2004), and by Schwartz &
    • My impression is that few Contracts teachers are aware of this rule. The treatment of Jacobs & Young v. Kent, 129 N. E. 889, 891 (N. Y. 1921) (refusing to award the cost of replacing piping from an incorrect factory because the defect was insubstantial and the cost of replacing the piping would have been great), by RICHARD DANZIG & GEOFFREY R. WATSON, THE CAPABILITY PROBLEM OF CONTRACT LAW 95-118 (2d ed. 2004), and by Schwartz &
  • 177
    • 74849120186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott, supra note 8, at 614-16, is indicative. Schwartz and Scott argue that courts should tolerate a risk of forfeiture when a final payment is withheld after an architect refuses to certify a builder's performance. This enables parties to use the mechanisms of payment holdback and third-party certification to solve the problem of the unverifiability of the adequacy of the builder's performance. Id. Danzig and Watson delve into the background of the case and make the counter-argument that Judge Cardozo's opinion was correct on the facts because it was clear that the purpose of the condition had been served and that the owner was not harmed by the substitution of the pipe. DANZIG & WATSON, supra, at 95-118. Neither treatment of the topic mentions the owner's right to repair the defect and withhold or collect the cost. While the existence of such a right is not decisive, it is worth mentioning; it buttresses the Danzig-Watson position and somew
    • Scott, supra note 8, at 614-16, is indicative. Schwartz and Scott argue that courts should tolerate a risk of forfeiture when a final payment is withheld after an architect refuses to certify a builder's performance. This enables parties to use the mechanisms of payment holdback and third-party certification to solve the problem of the unverifiability of the adequacy of the builder's performance. Id. Danzig and Watson delve into the background of the case and make the counter-argument that Judge Cardozo's opinion was correct on the facts because it was clear that the purpose of the condition had been served and that the owner was not harmed by the substitution of the pipe. DANZIG & WATSON, supra, at 95-118. Neither treatment of the topic mentions the owner's right to repair the defect and withhold or collect the cost. While the existence of such a right is not decisive, it is worth mentioning; it buttresses the Danzig-Watson position and somewhat undercuts the Schwartz-Scott position. An owner's right to repair uncertified work and withhold or collect the cost provides the owner some protection from unverifiable defects or observable defects that cause unverifiable harm. If an owner does not exercise the right, then this is some evidence that the defect did not harm him.
  • 178
    • 84868052492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., R. K. Cooper Builders, Inc. v. Free-Lock Ceilings, Inc., 219 So. 2d 87, 88-89 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1969) (allowing owner to recover $5681 completion cost, despite the trial court's finding that the work could have been done for $2500, reasoning that any expenditures made in good faith should be recovered);
    • See, e.g., R. K. Cooper Builders, Inc. v. Free-Lock Ceilings, Inc., 219 So. 2d 87, 88-89 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1969) (allowing owner to recover $5681 completion cost, despite the trial court's finding that the work could have been done for $2500, reasoning that any expenditures made in good faith should be recovered);
  • 179
    • 84868071011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kirkpatrick v. Temme, 654 P.2d 1011, 1013 (Nev. 1982) (awarding $84, 333.73 spent to complete construction where contract price was $175, 000 despite defaulter's testimony that the work was 80% complete and that he could have finished for $39, 200 where the owner and the architect testified that the original plans and specifications were followed). If the owner does additional work, then only the amount that the owner would have paid for the original work is recoverable. Temple Beth Sholom & Jewish Ctr., Inc. v. Thyne Constr. Corp., 399 So. 2d 525, 526 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1981);
    • Kirkpatrick v. Temme, 654 P.2d 1011, 1013 (Nev. 1982) (awarding $84, 333.73 spent to complete construction where contract price was $175, 000 despite defaulter's testimony that the work was 80% complete and that he could have finished for $39, 200 where the owner and the architect testified that the original plans and specifications were followed). If the owner does additional work, then only the amount that the owner would have paid for the original work is recoverable. Temple Beth Sholom & Jewish Ctr., Inc. v. Thyne Constr. Corp., 399 So. 2d 525, 526 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1981);
  • 180
    • 74849133963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • St. Joseph Hosp. v. Corbetta Constr. Co., 316 N. E.2d 51, 62 (Ill. App. Ct. 1974);
    • St. Joseph Hosp. v. Corbetta Constr. Co., 316 N. E.2d 51, 62 (Ill. App. Ct. 1974);
  • 181
    • 74849136681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bachman v. Parkin, 471 N. E.2d 759, 760 (Mass. App. Ct. 1984);
    • Bachman v. Parkin, 471 N. E.2d 759, 760 (Mass. App. Ct. 1984);
  • 182
    • 74849096291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Martin v. Phillips, 440 A.2d 1124, 1125 (N. H. 1982). Alternatively, the enhanced value may be subtracted. State Prop. & Bldg. Comm'n v. H. W. Miller Constr. Co., 385 S. W.2d 211, 215 (Ky. 1964).
    • Martin v. Phillips, 440 A.2d 1124, 1125 (N. H. 1982). Alternatively, the enhanced value may be subtracted. State Prop. & Bldg. Comm'n v. H. W. Miller Constr. Co., 385 S. W.2d 211, 215 (Ky. 1964).
  • 183
    • 74849087050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hi-Valley Constructors, Inc. v. Heyser, 428 P.2d 354, 357 (Colo. 1967) (awarding cost of repainting exterior of house);
    • Hi-Valley Constructors, Inc. v. Heyser, 428 P.2d 354, 357 (Colo. 1967) (awarding cost of repainting exterior of house);
  • 184
    • 84868071007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carlin v. Comstock, 450 A.2d 875, 876 (Conn. Super. Ct. 1982) (awarding approximately $2000 to repair porch though only $143 was due on the original contract).
    • Carlin v. Comstock, 450 A.2d 875, 876 (Conn. Super. Ct. 1982) (awarding approximately $2000 to repair porch though only $143 was due on the original contract).
  • 185
    • 84868052483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Together, the rule and the exception give an aggrieved party an incentive to repair a defect to avoid being under-compensated for a subjective loss. For example, the rules would give the Jacobses an incentive to spend $4000 to move the wall, though they place only a $1000 value on having the wall moved, because they bear the $1000 loss if the wall is not moved while Plante bears the $4000 cost of moving the wall. To some extent the law tempers the incentive to make wasteful repairs by allowing the Jacobses to keep the balance due on the contract or recover remedial cost as damages if they can establish the value of moving the wall is sufficiently great to them. For example, if the Jacobses had personal reasons to move the wall that would justify them spending a sum as substantial as $1000, then they might think they have a fair chance of keeping the $5000 balance due if they do not make the repairs and present their reasons for wanting the wall
    • Together, the rule and the exception give an aggrieved party an incentive to repair a defect to avoid being under-compensated for a subjective loss. For example, the rules would give the Jacobses an incentive to spend $4000 to move the wall, though they place only a $1000 value on having the wall moved, because they bear the $1000 loss if the wall is not moved while Plante bears the $4000 cost of moving the wall. To some extent the law tempers the incentive to make wasteful repairs by allowing the Jacobses to keep the balance due on the contract or recover remedial cost as damages if they can establish the value of moving the wall is sufficiently great to them. For example, if the Jacobses had personal reasons to move the wall that would justify them spending a sum as substantial as $1000, then they might think they have a fair chance of keeping the $5000 balance due if they do not make the repairs and present their reasons for wanting the wall moved as compelling enough to retain the balance. Your guess is as good as mine as to how people actually respond to these rules. Personally, I would pay to move the wall only if the value to me was a large fraction of the cost and I had the money in hand as a holdback of the contractor's payment.
  • 186
    • 74849093578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parker v. Twentieth Century-Fox Film Corp., 474 P.2d 689, 693-94 (Cal. 1970).
    • Parker v. Twentieth Century-Fox Film Corp., 474 P.2d 689, 693-94 (Cal. 1970).
  • 187
    • 74849083916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bomberger v. McKelvey, 220 P.2d 729, 734 (Cal. 1950).
    • Bomberger v. McKelvey, 220 P.2d 729, 734 (Cal. 1950).
  • 188
    • 74849088755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 82-84.
    • See supra notes 82-84.
  • 189
    • 84868052484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Granite Construction Co. v. United States, 962 F.2d 998 (Fed. Cir. 1992), is a contract case that does not fit the pattern. A contractor redid work at a cost of $3.8 million to comply with specifications for a water stop on a dam under pressure from the government.
    • Granite Construction Co. v. United States, 962 F.2d 998 (Fed. Cir. 1992), is a contract case that does not fit the pattern. A contractor redid work at a cost of $3.8 million to comply with specifications for a water stop on a dam under pressure from the government.
  • 190
    • 74849094288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1000. The court held the contractor was entitled to recover the cost because it was unreasonable for the government to insist upon strict compliance with the specifications. Id. at 1007-08.
    • Id. at 1000. The court held the contractor was entitled to recover the cost because it was unreasonable for the government to insist upon strict compliance with the specifications. Id. at 1007-08.
  • 191
    • 74849086180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are numerous recent cases limiting damages to loss in market value when the plaintiff does not repair the property at greater cost but may have good reason to do so. E.g, Poffenbarger v. Merit Energy Co, 972 So. 2d 792 (Ala. 2007, involving environmental contamination);
    • There are numerous recent cases limiting damages to loss in market value when the plaintiff does not repair the property at greater cost but may have good reason to do so. E.g., Poffenbarger v. Merit Energy Co., 972 So. 2d 792 (Ala. 2007) (involving environmental contamination);
  • 192
    • 74849113469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Millers Mut. Fire Ins. Co. v. Wildish Constr. Co., 758 P.2d 836 (Or. 1988) (involving destruction of home);
    • Millers Mut. Fire Ins. Co. v. Wildish Constr. Co., 758 P.2d 836 (Or. 1988) (involving destruction of home);
  • 193
    • 74849137370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Primrose Operating Co. v. Senn, 161 S. W.3d 258 (Tex. App. 2005) (involving environmental contamination from oil and gas operations);
    • Primrose Operating Co. v. Senn, 161 S. W.3d 258 (Tex. App. 2005) (involving environmental contamination from oil and gas operations);
  • 194
    • 84868084602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also DAN B. DOBBS, HANDBOOK ON THE LAW OF REMEDIES § 5.2 (1973).
    • see also DAN B. DOBBS, HANDBOOK ON THE LAW OF REMEDIES § 5.2 (1973).
  • 195
    • 74849108968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many cases pay lip service to the rule. See, e.g., Sprinkle v. N. C. Wildlife Res. Comm'n, 600 S. E.2d 473, 477 (N. C. 2004) (North Carolina is committed to the general rule that the measure of damages for injury to personal property is the difference between the market value of the damaged property immediately before and immediately after the injury.).
    • Many cases pay lip service to the rule. See, e.g., Sprinkle v. N. C. Wildlife Res. Comm'n, 600 S. E.2d 473, 477 (N. C. 2004) ("North Carolina is committed to the general rule that the measure of damages for injury to personal property is the difference between the market value of the damaged property immediately before and immediately after the injury.").
  • 196
    • 74849125210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thompson v. King Feed & Nutrition Serv., Inc., 105 P.3d 378, 383 (Wash. 2005) (holding that the lesser than rule does not apply when the improvement is a component of larger property that is destroyed).
    • Thompson v. King Feed & Nutrition Serv., Inc., 105 P.3d 378, 383 (Wash. 2005) (holding that the "lesser than" rule does not apply when the improvement is a component of larger property that is destroyed).
  • 197
    • 74849120731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See In re September 11th Litig., 590 F. Supp. 2d 535, 541 (S. D. N. Y. 2008) (New York courts follow the 'lesser of two' rule: a plaintiff whose property has been injured may recover the lesser of the diminution of the property's market value or its replacement cost.).
    • See In re September 11th Litig., 590 F. Supp. 2d 535, 541 (S. D. N. Y. 2008) ("New York courts follow the 'lesser of two' rule: a plaintiff whose property has been injured may recover the lesser of the diminution of the property's market value or its replacement cost.").
  • 198
    • 74849102222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Fifty Acres of Land, 469 U. S. 24, 35 (1984).
    • United States v. Fifty Acres of Land, 469 U. S. 24, 35 (1984).
  • 199
    • 74849136678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A generally recognized exception covers property that is an integral part of a business on the taken property and the adjacent property. See United States v. Ebinger, 386 F.2d 557, 560-61 2d Cir. 1967
    • A generally recognized exception covers property that is an integral part of a business on the taken property and the adjacent property. See United States v. Ebinger, 386 F.2d 557, 560-61 (2d Cir. 1967).
  • 200
    • 74849111361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another less generally accepted exception covers special purpose property owned by a public or non-profit entity. See Newton Girl Scout Council, Inc. v. Mass. Tpk. Auth., 138 N. E.2d 769, 774 (Mass. 1956).
    • Another less generally accepted exception covers "special purpose property" owned by a public or non-profit entity. See Newton Girl Scout Council, Inc. v. Mass. Tpk. Auth., 138 N. E.2d 769, 774 (Mass. 1956).
  • 201
    • 84868084597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O'Brien Bros., Inc. v. The Helen B. Moran, 160 F.2d 502 (2d Cir. 1947), is a well known example. A United States government vessel collided with and sunk the plaintiffs barge valued at $16, 000, which was the purchase price less depreciation.
    • O'Brien Bros., Inc. v. The Helen B. Moran, 160 F.2d 502 (2d Cir. 1947), is a well known example. A United States government vessel collided with and sunk the plaintiffs barge valued at $16, 000, which was the purchase price less depreciation.
  • 202
    • 84868057797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 503. The plaintiff spent $7000 to raise the barge and $43, 000 to repair it, which may have been reasonable because it was wartime and no barges could be purchased at any price.
    • Id. at 503. The plaintiff spent $7000 to raise the barge and $43, 000 to repair it, which may have been reasonable because it was wartime and no barges could be purchased at any price.
  • 203
    • 74849113160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 504. The trial court awarded repair cost. Id. at 503. The court of appeals reversed, ruling that damages were limited to the value of the barge plus the cost of raising the barge (which was required to clear the waterway).
    • Id. at 504. The trial court awarded repair cost. Id. at 503. The court of appeals reversed, ruling that damages were limited to the value of the barge plus the cost of raising the barge (which was required to clear the waterway).
  • 205
    • 74849103571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 505;
    • Id. at 505;
  • 206
    • 74849134555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Warren v. Heartland Auto ServS., Inc., 144 P.3d 73, 76 (Kan. Ct. App. 2006) (limiting damages to the market value of the used automobile where plaintiff repaired the used automobile and rented a replacement);
    • see also Warren v. Heartland Auto ServS., Inc., 144 P.3d 73, 76 (Kan. Ct. App. 2006) (limiting damages to the market value of the used automobile where plaintiff repaired the used automobile and rented a replacement);
  • 207
    • 84868071004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fisher v. Qualico Contracting Corp., 779 N. E.2d 178, 182 (N. Y. 2002) (assuming that home owners who spent $1, 330, 000 to replace a home destroyed by a fire could recover only the $480, 000 diminution in market value of the home resulting from the fire).
    • Fisher v. Qualico Contracting Corp., 779 N. E.2d 178, 182 (N. Y. 2002) (assuming that home owners who spent $1, 330, 000 to replace a home destroyed by a fire could recover only the $480, 000 diminution in market value of the home resulting from the fire).
  • 208
    • 74849103570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law of takings may be sui generis for the remedy is understood to be noncompensatory. Under federal law still and at one time under the law of most states, consequential damages were not available for a taking. See, e.g., Yuba Natural Res., Inc. v. United States, 904 F.2d 1577, 1581 (Fed. Cir. 1990);
    • The law of takings may be sui generis for the remedy is understood to be noncompensatory. Under federal law still and at one time under the law of most states, consequential damages were not available for a taking. See, e.g., Yuba Natural Res., Inc. v. United States, 904 F.2d 1577, 1581 (Fed. Cir. 1990);
  • 209
    • 74849115472 scopus 로고
    • Recovery of Consequential Damages in Eminent Domain, 48
    • Emerson G. Spies & John C. McCoid, II, Recovery of Consequential Damages in Eminent Domain, 48 VA. L. REV. 437, 441 (1962).
    • (1962) VA. L. REV , vol.437 , pp. 441
    • Spies, E.G.1    McCoid II, J.C.2
  • 210
    • 74849139994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As for why eminent domain is sui generis, that is more difficult to say. If you assume the purpose of eminent domain is compensation, or internalizing to the government the full private cost of a taking, then it is difficult to make a case that public takings are categorically different from private conduct harming property when the conduct is of a type that is not thought to merit punishment
    • As for why eminent domain is sui generis, that is more difficult to say. If you assume the purpose of eminent domain is compensation, or internalizing to the government the full private cost of a taking, then it is difficult to make a case that public takings are categorically different from private conduct harming property when the conduct is of a type that is not thought to merit punishment.
  • 211
    • 74849102519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Am. Serv. Ctr. Assocs. v. Helton, 867 A.2d 235, 243, 240 n. 4 (D. C. 2005) (allowing damages for cost of repairing an automobile plus damages for residual loss of market value, while noting that the lesser than rule is unprecedented in any of the court's rulings).
    • Am. Serv. Ctr. Assocs. v. Helton, 867 A.2d 235, 243, 240 n. 4 (D. C. 2005) (allowing damages for cost of repairing an automobile plus damages for residual loss of market value, while noting that the "lesser than" rule is unprecedented in any of the court's rulings).
  • 212
    • 74849109267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many of these cases implicate environmental concerns. See, e.g., Osborne v. Herst, 947 P.2d 1356, 1360 (Alaska 1997);
    • Many of these cases implicate environmental concerns. See, e.g., Osborne v. Herst, 947 P.2d 1356, 1360 (Alaska 1997);
  • 213
    • 74849129163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Felton Oil Co. v. Gee, 182 S. W.3d 72, 80 (Ark. 2004);
    • Felton Oil Co. v. Gee, 182 S. W.3d 72, 80 (Ark. 2004);
  • 214
    • 74849128136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leavitt v. Cont'l Tel. Co., 559 A.2d 786, 788 (Me. 1989);
    • Leavitt v. Cont'l Tel. Co., 559 A.2d 786, 788 (Me. 1989);
  • 215
    • 74849119030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunburst Sch. Dist. No. 2 v. Texaco, Inc., 165 P.3d 1079, 1088 (Mont. 2007);
    • Sunburst Sch. Dist. No. 2 v. Texaco, Inc., 165 P.3d 1079, 1088 (Mont. 2007);
  • 216
    • 74849092136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keitges v. VanDermeulen, 483 N. W.2d 137, 143 (Neb. 1992);
    • Keitges v. VanDermeulen, 483 N. W.2d 137, 143 (Neb. 1992);
  • 217
    • 74849115473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vaught v. A. O. Hardee & Sons, 623 S. E.2d 373, 378 (S. C. 2005).
    • Vaught v. A. O. Hardee & Sons, 623 S. E.2d 373, 378 (S. C. 2005).
  • 218
    • 56249138140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 89, § 5.2 1, 2
    • See DOBBS, supra note 89, § 5.2 (1), (2);
    • supra
    • DOBBS1
  • 219
    • 74849101624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LAYCOCK, supra note 26, at 23-26
    • LAYCOCK, supra note 26, at 23-26.
  • 220
    • 74849129759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When there is an objective basis for the intermediate measure, the solution is to use a measure of damages between replacement or repair cost and loss of market value. For example, when a plaintiff replaces used property with new, damages can be measured by replacement cost of the new less a factor to account for depreciation of the old. See, e.g., Penn. Dep't of Gen. Servs. v. U. S. Mineral Prods. Co., 898 A.2d 590, 598 (Pa. 2006).
    • When there is an objective basis for the intermediate measure, the solution is to use a measure of damages between replacement or repair cost and loss of market value. For example, when a plaintiff replaces used property with new, damages can be measured by replacement cost of the new less a factor to account for depreciation of the old. See, e.g., Penn. Dep't of Gen. Servs. v. U. S. Mineral Prods. Co., 898 A.2d 590, 598 (Pa. 2006).
  • 221
    • 74849090068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lack of consideration is the argument eventually adopted in Hackley v. Headley, 14 N. W. 693, 693-95 (Mich. 1883), to excuse a creditor from a release extracted by the debtor by a threat to withhold money that was not in dispute.
    • Lack of consideration is the argument eventually adopted in Hackley v. Headley, 14 N. W. 693, 693-95 (Mich. 1883), to excuse a creditor from a release extracted by the debtor by a threat to withhold money that was not in dispute.
  • 222
    • 74849103168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a similar, more recent case, see Wickman v. Kane, 766 A.2d 241, 249 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 2001), which found no valid accord and satisfaction where an undisputed sum was paid to obtain release of a disputed claim on grounds of lack of consideration.
    • For a similar, more recent case, see Wickman v. Kane, 766 A.2d 241, 249 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 2001), which found no valid accord and satisfaction where an undisputed sum was paid to obtain release of a disputed claim on grounds of lack of consideration.
  • 223
    • 74849084768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The weight of authority holds that refusal to pay money, even in bad faith, is not economic duress. E.g., Selmer Co. v. Blakeslee-Midwest Co., 704 F.2d 924, 927 (7th Cir. 1983) (asserting that finding otherwise would make an inference of duress inescapable in any negotiation where one party makes an offer from which it refuses to budge).
    • The weight of authority holds that refusal to pay money, even in bad faith, is not economic duress. E.g., Selmer Co. v. Blakeslee-Midwest Co., 704 F.2d 924, 927 (7th Cir. 1983) (asserting that finding otherwise would "make an inference of duress inescapable in any negotiation where one party makes an offer from which it refuses to budge").
  • 224
    • 74849125831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an unusual case to the contrary, see Capps v. Georgia Pacific Corp., 453 P.2d 935, 938-39 (Or. 1969), which adopted a rule allowing statements of a duress defense to be tried on its facts.
    • For an unusual case to the contrary, see Capps v. Georgia Pacific Corp., 453 P.2d 935, 938-39 (Or. 1969), which adopted a rule allowing statements of a duress defense to be tried on its facts.
  • 226
    • 74749110168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Williams v. Mut. Benefit Health & Accident Ass'n, 100 F.2d 264, 264-65 (5th Cir. 1938) (When one who is obligated by contract to make money payments to another, absolutely repudiates and abandons the obligation without just excuse, the obligee is 'entitled to maintain his action in damages at once for the entire breach....' (quoting Pollack v. Pollack, 39 S. W.2d 853, 855 (Tex. App. 1931)));
    • see also Williams v. Mut. Benefit Health & Accident Ass'n, 100 F.2d 264, 264-65 (5th Cir. 1938) ("When one who is obligated by contract to make money payments to another, absolutely repudiates and abandons the obligation without just excuse, the obligee is 'entitled to maintain his action in damages at once for the entire breach....'" (quoting Pollack v. Pollack, 39 S. W.2d 853, 855 (Tex. App. 1931)));
  • 227
    • 74849098276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Needham v. Am. Nat. Ins. Co, 97 S. W.2d 1016, 1021 (Tex. App. 1936).
    • Needham v. Am. Nat. Ins. Co, 97 S. W.2d 1016, 1021 (Tex. App. 1936).
  • 228
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 57 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 57 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 229
    • 74849116260 scopus 로고
    • Summit Constr. Co., 422 F.2d 242
    • See Peter Kiewit Sons' Co. v
    • See Peter Kiewit Sons' Co. v. Summit Constr. Co., 422 F.2d 242, 257 (8th Cir. 1969);
    • (1969) 257 (8th Cir
  • 230
    • 74849110736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pac. Coast Eng'g Co. v. Merritt-Chapman & Scott Corp, 411 F.2d 889, 896 (9th Cir. 1969) (holding that the persistent assertion of a position that the party had previously been told by third parties was unjustified constitutes a repudiation). Good faith assertion of a claim or position is not normally a breach of contract even though the claim or position is invalid. See Reiss v. Murchison, 503 F.2d 999, 1007-08 (9th Cir. 1974) (holding that the filing of a claim of total breach does not give the party against whom the claim is asserted the right to halt performance);
    • Pac. Coast Eng'g Co. v. Merritt-Chapman & Scott Corp, 411 F.2d 889, 896 (9th Cir. 1969) (holding that the persistent assertion of a position that the party had previously been told by third parties was unjustified constitutes a repudiation). Good faith assertion of a claim or position is not normally a breach of contract even though the claim or position is invalid. See Reiss v. Murchison, 503 F.2d 999, 1007-08 (9th Cir. 1974) (holding that the filing of a claim of total breach does not give the party against whom the claim is asserted the right to halt performance);
  • 231
    • 74849125508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Chateaugay Corp, 104 B. R. 637, 643 (Bankr. S. D. N. Y. 1989);
    • In re Chateaugay Corp, 104 B. R. 637, 643 (Bankr. S. D. N. Y. 1989);
  • 232
    • 74849089183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dixie Roof Decks, Inc. v. Borggren/Dickson Constr, Inc., 395 S. E.2d 19, 20 (Ga. Ct. App. 1990) (Borggren/Dickson could not commit an anticipatory breach... because the duty to pay didn't arise until Dixie Roof Decks was to have produced the requisite documentation. );
    • Dixie Roof Decks, Inc. v. Borggren/Dickson Constr, Inc., 395 S. E.2d 19, 20 (Ga. Ct. App. 1990) ("Borggren/Dickson could not commit an anticipatory breach... because the duty to pay didn't arise until Dixie Roof Decks was to have produced the requisite documentation. ");
  • 233
    • 74849100151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oak Ridge Const. Co. v. Tolley, 504 A.2d 1343, 1347-48 (Pa. Super. Ct. 1985) (asserting that where one party's communication did not constitute a definite and unconditional repudiation or breach of the contract, the other party's failure to perform constitutes a breach). Similarly, it is not a breach of contract or a tort to use the legal process to resolve a dispute or to protect one's position pending resolution of a dispute even if the use of the legal process harms the other party, so long as the process is used in good faith. Wachter v. Gratech Co., 608 N. W.2d 279, 288-89 (N. D. 2000) (holding that it is not abuse of process to file a mechanic's lien that turned out to be grossly excessive in amount if the filing was done in good faith).
    • Oak Ridge Const. Co. v. Tolley, 504 A.2d 1343, 1347-48 (Pa. Super. Ct. 1985) (asserting that where one party's communication did not constitute a "definite and unconditional repudiation" or breach of the contract, the other party's failure to perform constitutes a breach). Similarly, it is not a breach of contract or a tort to use the legal process to resolve a dispute or to protect one's position pending resolution of a dispute even if the use of the legal process harms the other party, so long as the process is used in good faith. Wachter v. Gratech Co., 608 N. W.2d 279, 288-89 (N. D. 2000) (holding that it is not abuse of process to file a mechanic's lien that turned out to be grossly excessive in amount if the filing was done in good faith).
  • 234
    • 74849124206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Around half the states allow the claim. See Erie Ins. Co. v. Hickman by Smith, 622 N. E.2d 515, 519 n. 1 (Ind. 1993).
    • Around half the states allow the claim. See Erie Ins. Co. v. Hickman by Smith, 622 N. E.2d 515, 519 n. 1 (Ind. 1993).
  • 235
    • 74849096290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comunale v. Traders & General Insurance Co., 328 P.2d 198, 202 (Cal. 1958), is an early case. In states in which a tort action is available for bad faith breach, the action generally is limited to nonpayment of insurance, and in many of these states, it is further limited to nonpayment of first party insurance.
    • Comunale v. Traders & General Insurance Co., 328 P.2d 198, 202 (Cal. 1958), is an early case. In states in which a tort action is available for bad faith breach, the action generally is limited to nonpayment of insurance, and in many of these states, it is further limited to nonpayment of first party insurance.
  • 236
    • 74849119029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Gruenberg v. Aetna Ins. Co., 510 P.2d 1032, 1039 (Cal. 1973) (Obviously, the non-insurer defendants were not parties to the agreements for insurance; therefore, they are not, as such, subject to an implied duty of good faith and fair dealing.). Often when a breach of contract is egregious, a plaintiff will be able to make out a claim for some other tort for which punitive damages are available, such as fraud. Empirical studies show that punitive damages are levied much more often in business tort cases than personal injury cases. For a summary of the studies, see generally Michael L. Rustad, Unraveling Punitive Damages: Current Data and Further Inquiry, 1998 WIS. L. REV. 15.
    • E.g., Gruenberg v. Aetna Ins. Co., 510 P.2d 1032, 1039 (Cal. 1973) ("Obviously, the non-insurer defendants were not parties to the agreements for insurance; therefore, they are not, as such, subject to an implied duty of good faith and fair dealing."). Often when a breach of contract is egregious, a plaintiff will be able to make out a claim for some other tort for which punitive damages are available, such as fraud. Empirical studies show that punitive damages are levied much more often in business tort cases than personal injury cases. For a summary of the studies, see generally Michael L. Rustad, Unraveling Punitive Damages: Current Data and Further Inquiry, 1998 WIS. L. REV. 15.
  • 237
    • 74849132929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the most doctrinally granulated data, see ERIK MOLLER, NICHOLAS M. PACE & STEPHEN J. CARROLL, PUNITIVE DAMAGES IN FINANCIAL INJURY JURY VERDICTS 20 (1997), which compiles data from jury verdict reports from six states for the period 1985 to 1994.
    • For the most doctrinally granulated data, see ERIK MOLLER, NICHOLAS M. PACE & STEPHEN J. CARROLL, PUNITIVE DAMAGES IN FINANCIAL INJURY JURY VERDICTS 20 (1997), which compiles data from jury verdict reports from six states for the period 1985 to 1994.
  • 238
    • 74849128457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They report that half of the cases in which punitive damages were levied involved financial injury and that punitive damages were levied in fourteen percent of financial injury verdicts and twenty-two percent of the verdicts in which the plaintiff won
    • They report that half of the cases in which punitive damages were levied involved financial injury and that punitive damages were levied in fourteen percent of financial injury verdicts and twenty-two percent of the verdicts in which the plaintiff won.
  • 239
    • 74849083920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Their breakdown of the data barely makes it possible to discern the nature of the legal claim on which punitive damages were levied. In non-employment cases, fraud is the most common basis, followed by insurance bad faith (broadly defined by the authors to include both claims for wrongful failure to pay first party claims by an insured and claims for failure to settle third party liability claims against an insured), breach of fiduciary duty, and interference with contractual relations. Id.
    • Id. Their breakdown of the data barely makes it possible to discern the nature of the legal claim on which punitive damages were levied. In non-employment cases, fraud is the most common basis, followed by insurance bad faith (broadly defined by the authors to include both claims for wrongful failure to pay "first party" claims by an insured and claims for failure to settle "third party" liability claims against an insured), breach of fiduciary duty, and interference with contractual relations. Id.
  • 240
    • 74849121589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See William T. Barker, Evidentiary Insufficiency in Insurance Bad Faith Suits, 6 CONN. INS. L. J. 81, 110 (1999) (exploring the problem in the context of insurance bad faith). In practice, the key problem is defining the quantum of doubt about an obligation that justifies dismissing a bad faith claim on a motion for summary judgment. See id. at 99-100.
    • See William T. Barker, Evidentiary Insufficiency in Insurance Bad Faith Suits, 6 CONN. INS. L. J. 81, 110 (1999) (exploring the problem in the context of insurance bad faith). In practice, the key problem is defining the quantum of doubt about an obligation that justifies dismissing a bad faith claim on a motion for summary judgment. See id. at 99-100.
  • 241
    • 74849121590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barker concludes that an insurer has the privilege to test an objectively questionable claim in court no matter how hard the decision to fight may be on the insured and no matter how small the claim. Id. at 110
    • Barker concludes that an insurer has the privilege to test an objectively questionable claim in court no matter how hard the decision to fight may be on the insured and no matter how small the claim. Id. at 110.
  • 242
    • 84868052470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 6 cmt. e, illus. 18 (Tentative Draft No. 1, 2001) (stating and providing authority that the voluntary payment rule will bar recovery of payment of a disputed claim).
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 6 cmt. e, illus. 18 (Tentative Draft No. 1, 2001) (stating and providing authority that the voluntary payment rule will bar recovery of payment of a disputed claim).
  • 243
    • 74849097953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randazzo v. Harris Bank Palatine, N. A., 262 F.3d 663, 668 (7th Cir. 2001).
    • Randazzo v. Harris Bank Palatine, N. A., 262 F.3d 663, 668 (7th Cir. 2001).
  • 244
    • 84868050784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The history of Uniform Commercial Code section 1-207 attests to the strength of this practice. The statute allows a party to reserve his rights while accepting performance offered by the other party. U. C. C. § 1-207 (1990).
    • The history of Uniform Commercial Code section 1-207 attests to the strength of this practice. The statute allows a party to reserve his rights while accepting performance offered by the other party. U. C. C. § 1-207 (1990).
  • 245
    • 74849090889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Though the statute made no exception, many courts held this provision did not apply to an accord and satisfaction. Courts had split on whether the statute changed the common law doctrine of accord and satisfaction. Air Van Lines, Inc. v. Buster, 673 P.2d 774, 779 Alaska 1984, is a leading case holding that the statute did not alter the common law rule
    • Though the statute made no exception, many courts held this provision did not apply to an accord and satisfaction. Courts had split on whether the statute changed the common law doctrine of accord and satisfaction. Air Van Lines, Inc. v. Buster, 673 P.2d 774, 779 (Alaska 1984), is a leading case holding that the statute did not alter the common law rule.
  • 246
    • 74849117775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a contrary case mat reviews the arguments and authority on both sides, see Horn Waterproofing Corp. v. Brunswick Iron & Steel Co., 488 N. E.2d 56, 57-58 (N. Y. 1985).
    • For a contrary case mat reviews the arguments and authority on both sides, see Horn Waterproofing Corp. v. Brunswick Iron & Steel Co., 488 N. E.2d 56, 57-58 (N. Y. 1985).
  • 247
    • 84868084592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An explicit exception was added in 1990. U. C. C. § 1-207 1
    • An explicit exception was added in 1990. U. C. C. § 1-207 (1).
  • 248
    • 74849104185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JAMES WHITE & ROBERT S. SUMMERS, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW UNDER THE UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE 544 (2d ed. 1980).
    • JAMES WHITE & ROBERT S. SUMMERS, HANDBOOK OF THE LAW UNDER THE UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE 544 (2d ed. 1980).
  • 249
    • 74849140538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This sentiment is echoed in Horn Waterproofing, 488 N. E.2d at 59
    • This sentiment is echoed in Horn Waterproofing, 488 N. E.2d at 59.
  • 250
    • 74849140857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An often litigated question involves the effectiveness of a release given by a creditor to settle a disputed debt when, in exchange for the release, the debtor pays a sum that was not in dispute. The weight of the authority is that a release is valid in these circumstances if there is a single debt or if the debts are closely related. E.g, Kilander v. Blickle Co, 571 P.2d 503, 505 Or. 1977
    • An often litigated question involves the effectiveness of a release given by a creditor to settle a disputed debt when, in exchange for the release, the debtor pays a sum that was not in dispute. The weight of the authority is that a release is valid in these circumstances if there is a single debt or if the debts are closely related. E.g., Kilander v. Blickle Co., 571 P.2d 503, 505 (Or. 1977).
  • 251
    • 74849106802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, there is authority that circumstances of unfair pressure or economic coercion cut in the other direction. Flagel v. Sw. Clinical Physiatrists, P. C., 755 P.2d 1184, 1190 (Ariz. Ct. App. 1988).
    • However, there is authority that "circumstances of unfair pressure or economic coercion" cut in the other direction. Flagel v. Sw. Clinical Physiatrists, P. C., 755 P.2d 1184, 1190 (Ariz. Ct. App. 1988).
  • 252
    • 74849112606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clear statements that a reservation of rights does not avoid the voluntary payment doctrine may be found in Rowe v. Union Central Life Insurance Co, 12 So. 2d 431, 433-34 Miss. 1943
    • Clear statements that a reservation of rights does not avoid the voluntary payment doctrine may be found in Rowe v. Union Central Life Insurance Co., 12 So. 2d 431, 433-34 (Miss. 1943),
  • 253
    • 74849090067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Comment Note, Relaxation of Common-Law Rule Regarding Recovery of Voluntary Payment, 75 A. L. R. 658, 658 (1931),
    • and Comment Note, Relaxation of Common-Law Rule Regarding Recovery of Voluntary Payment, 75 A. L. R. 658, 658 (1931),
  • 254
    • 84868050781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • which states that a payment may not be recovered though the payer makes the payment with an express reservation of his right to litigate the claim. The rule is codified in Georgia. GA. CODE ANN. § 13-1-13 (1982).
    • which states that a payment may not be recovered "though the payer makes the payment with an express reservation of his right to litigate the claim." The rule is codified in Georgia. GA. CODE ANN. § 13-1-13 (1982).
  • 255
    • 74849088441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A handful of cases hold that a reservation of rights avoids the bar of the voluntary payment doctrine. See Avianca, Inc. v. Cornea, Civ. A. No. 85-3277 (RCL, 1992 WL 93128, at *7 D. D. C. April 13, 1992, The voluntary payment doctrine does not generally apply, however, when a party has expressly reserved a right to take some legal action or when the party has paid under protest
    • *7 (D. D. C. April 13, 1992) ("The voluntary payment doctrine does not generally apply, however, when a party has expressly reserved a right to take some legal action or when the party has paid under protest.");
  • 256
    • 74849124837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cmty. Convalescent Ctr., Inc., v. First Interstate Mortgage Co., 537 N. E.2d 1162, 1164 (Ill. App. Ct. 1989) ([S]ince plaintiff paid the 30 days' interest 'under protest,' plaintiff is not barred from recovery under the voluntarypayment doctrine.). A few other cases state in dicta that a debtor could have reserved his rights. Randazzo, 262 F.3d at 671 (admitting that Illinois recognizes protest as particularly good evidence of duress, but that the appellee's protest here was not an assertion of a legal right but an appeal to the appellant's business judgment);
    • Cmty. Convalescent Ctr., Inc., v. First Interstate Mortgage Co., 537 N. E.2d 1162, 1164 (Ill. App. Ct. 1989) ("[S]ince plaintiff paid the 30 days' interest 'under protest,' plaintiff is not barred from recovery under the voluntarypayment doctrine."). A few other cases state in dicta that a debtor could have reserved his rights. Randazzo, 262 F.3d at 671 (admitting that Illinois recognizes protest as particularly good evidence of duress, but that the appellee's protest here was not an assertion of a legal right but an appeal to the appellant's business judgment);
  • 257
    • 74849093302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prenalta Corp. v. Colo. Interstate Gas Co., 944 F.2d 677, 685-86 (10th Cir. 1991); City of Miami v. Keton, 115 So. 2d 547, 551 (Fla. 1959);
    • Prenalta Corp. v. Colo. Interstate Gas Co., 944 F.2d 677, 685-86 (10th Cir. 1991); City of Miami v. Keton, 115 So. 2d 547, 551 (Fla. 1959);
  • 258
    • 74849121302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putnam v. Time Warner Cable, 663 N. W.2d 254, 263 (Wis. Ct. App. 2001) ([E]ven if the late fees were improper - either unreasonable in amount or unlawful, in full, under state or federal regulations - the customers paid without protest, and Time Warner relied on those payments.). The older cases tend to treat a protest as evidence of duress. See Getto v. City of Chicago, 426 N. E.2d 844, 850 (Ill. 1981).
    • Putnam v. Time Warner Cable, 663 N. W.2d 254, 263 (Wis. Ct. App. 2001) ("[E]ven if the late fees were improper - either unreasonable in amount or unlawful, in full, under state or federal regulations - the customers paid without protest, and Time Warner relied on those payments."). The older cases tend to treat a protest as evidence of duress. See Getto v. City of Chicago, 426 N. E.2d 844, 850 (Ill. 1981).
  • 259
    • 84868057778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This comes from framing the issue as a problem in restitution. If the issue is framed as a problem in contract, then the question is what it takes to establish an agreement by the payee that the payment is conditional upon the validity of his claim. There is no doubt that an agreement that a payment is not final avoids the bar of the voluntary payment doctrine. RESTATEMENT OF RESTITUTION § 45 cmt. e 1937, The rule stated in this Section does not apply if the parties have agreed that the payment is conditional upon the validity of the transferee's claim, Approaching the problem from the perspective of contract law places pressure on the rule that a payor cannot unilaterally reserve the right to recover a payment by noting on the payment that this right is reserved. Under the general principle that the offeror is master of the offer, the payee assents to this reservation when he takes the payment. E.g, Prenalta Corp, 944 F.2d at 685-86
    • This comes from framing the issue as a problem in restitution. If the issue is framed as a problem in contract, then the question is what it takes to establish an agreement by the payee that the payment is conditional upon the validity of his claim. There is no doubt that an agreement that a payment is not final avoids the bar of the voluntary payment doctrine. RESTATEMENT OF RESTITUTION § 45 cmt. e (1937) ("The rule stated in this Section does not apply if the parties have agreed that the payment is conditional upon the validity of the transferee's claim."). Approaching the problem from the perspective of contract law places pressure on the rule that a payor cannot unilaterally reserve the right to recover a payment by noting on the payment that this right is reserved. Under the general principle that the offeror is master of the offer, the payee assents to this reservation when he takes the payment. E.g., Prenalta Corp., 944 F.2d at 685-86.
  • 260
    • 74849113861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 170 P. 1135 (Cal. 1918).
    • 170 P. 1135 (Cal. 1918).
  • 262
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 129-32 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 129-32 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 263
    • 74849117225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henrici, 170 P. at 1136.
    • Henrici, 170 P. at 1136.
  • 264
    • 74849135371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1138
    • Id. at 1138.
  • 265
    • 74849126721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1.7 Id. at 1136.
    • 1.7 Id. at 1136.
  • 266
    • 74849102517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1.8 Id. (By paying the excessive price without conceding its correctness, he could have saved his trees, vines, and crops, and reduced his damage to a comparatively trifling sum.).
    • 1.8 Id. ("By paying the excessive price without conceding its correctness, he could have saved his trees, vines, and crops, and reduced his damage to a comparatively trifling sum.").
  • 267
    • 74849131874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 268
    • 84868057781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This assumes the voluntary payment doctrine does not preclude the claim, a point the court did not address. The typical explanation why the voluntary payment doctrine would not prohibit the claim is that Henrici's payment is not considered voluntary. What makes a payment involuntary is not developed in the cases. If the test is similar to that for duress, then arguably South Feather did nothing improper in demanding a payment thought to be within its rights and that Henrici had other options that would have adequately protected his interests. A stronger basis for the restitution claim can be found in RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 35 cmt. b Council Draft No. 5, 2003
    • This assumes the voluntary payment doctrine does not preclude the claim, a point the court did not address. The typical explanation why the voluntary payment doctrine would not prohibit the claim is that Henrici's payment is not considered voluntary. What makes a payment involuntary is not developed in the cases. If the test is similar to that for duress, then arguably South Feather did nothing improper in demanding a payment thought to be within its rights and that Henrici had other options that would have adequately protected his interests. A stronger basis for the restitution claim can be found in RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 35 cmt. b (Council Draft No. 5, 2003).
  • 269
    • 74849110443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rule addresses the case where a party renders performance he disputes he owes and later brings a restitution claim to recover its value. Id. The rule allows the restitution claim but only if nonperformance by either party would impose consequential harms
    • The rule addresses the case where a party renders performance he disputes he owes and later brings a restitution claim to recover its value. Id. The rule allows the restitution claim but only if nonperformance by either party would impose consequential harms.
  • 270
  • 271
    • 74849087048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 100-04 and accompanying text. A breach is not material if damages adequately protect the promisee's interest in performance, particularly if withholding performance would impose a significant harm on the defaulter and the breach is in good faith.
    • See supra notes 100-04 and accompanying text. A breach is not material if damages adequately protect the promisee's interest in performance, particularly if withholding performance would impose a significant harm on the defaulter and the breach is in good faith.
  • 272
    • 84868057774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 350 cmt. e (1981) (If the party in breach offers to perform the contract for a different price, this may amount to a suitable alternative. But this is not the case if the offer is conditioned on surrender by the injured party of his claim for breach.);
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 350 cmt. e (1981) ("If the party in breach offers to perform the contract for a different price, this may amount to a suitable alternative. But this is not the case if the offer is conditioned on surrender by the injured party of his claim for breach.");
  • 273
    • 74849112928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at illus. 15 (describing Gilson v. F. S. Royster Guano Co., 1 F.2d 82 (3d Cir. 1924));
    • id. at illus. 15 (describing Gilson v. F. S. Royster Guano Co., 1 F.2d 82 (3d Cir. 1924));
  • 274
    • 84868057775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also ARTHUR LINTON CORBIN, CORBIN ON CONTRACTS § 1043 (West Publishing Co. 1964) (1951) (stating that there is no duty to take substitute performance from the defaulting party if it would involve a surrender of rights, compromise, or accord and satisfaction).
    • see also ARTHUR LINTON CORBIN, CORBIN ON CONTRACTS § 1043 (West Publishing Co. 1964) (1951) (stating that there is no duty to take substitute performance from the defaulting party if it would involve a surrender of rights, compromise, or accord and satisfaction).
  • 275
    • 84868052462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U. C. C. § 1-308 (2005) (former version at U. C. C § 1-207 (1999)).
    • U. C. C. § 1-308 (2005) (former version at U. C. C § 1-207 (1999)).
  • 276
    • 74849124525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is little case law on the respective fields of this rule and the rule on accord and satisfaction. Air Van Lines, Inc. v. Busters, 673 P.2d 774, 779 (Alaska 1984), takes the position that section 1-308 (1) applies when there is a continuing dispute on an executory contract. Under this view, Henrici could not have accepted a one-time delivery of water tendered on the condition that he agree to South Feather's price by accepting with a reservation of rights.
    • There is little case law on the respective fields of this rule and the rule on accord and satisfaction. Air Van Lines, Inc. v. Busters, 673 P.2d 774, 779 (Alaska 1984), takes the position that section 1-308 (1) applies when there is a continuing dispute on an executory contract. Under this view, Henrici could not have accepted a one-time delivery of water tendered on the condition that he agree to South Feather's price by accepting with a reservation of rights.
  • 277
    • 84868057776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 176 (2) (a) (1981) (defining a threat as improper if the resulting exchange is not on fair terms and the threatened act would harm the recipient and would not significantly benefit the party making the threat).
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 176 (2) (a) (1981) (defining a threat as improper "if the resulting exchange is not on fair terms" and "the threatened act would harm the recipient and would not significantly benefit the party making the threat").
  • 278
    • 74849136983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Silsbee v. Webber, 50 N. E. 555, 555-56 (Mass. 1898),
    • Silsbee v. Webber, 50 N. E. 555, 555-56 (Mass. 1898),
  • 279
    • 74849121591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • which concerns a threat by the employer directed at the employee's mother to tell employee's ill father of employee's theft if mother did not pay off the loss, is an example in the nature of blackmail. John Dawson, Economic Duress - An Essay in Perspective, 45 MICH. L. REV. 253, 258-59 (1947),
    • which concerns a threat by the employer directed at the employee's mother to tell employee's ill father of employee's theft if mother did not pay off the loss, is an example in the nature of blackmail. John Dawson, Economic Duress - An Essay in Perspective, 45 MICH. L. REV. 253, 258-59 (1947),
  • 280
    • 84868050779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • proposes disproportionality as an organizing principle. A threat to cut off water to a farm that has no alternative source of supply to gain leverage in a dispute over pennies certainly is disproportionate. The Restatement misfires by suggesting the concern is with malice or vindictiveness rather than with coercion. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 176 cmt. f (1981).
    • proposes disproportionality as an organizing principle. A threat to cut off water to a farm that has no alternative source of supply to gain leverage in a dispute over pennies certainly is disproportionate. The Restatement misfires by suggesting the concern is with malice or vindictiveness rather than with coercion. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 176 cmt. f (1981).
  • 281
    • 74849118391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Illustration 12 gives an example reminiscent of Silsbee in which an employer threatens to prevent an employee from working elsewhere if the employee does not release a claim. Id. at illus. 12.
    • Illustration 12 gives an example reminiscent of Silsbee in which an employer threatens to prevent an employee from working elsewhere if the employee does not release a claim. Id. at illus. 12.
  • 282
    • 74849135372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The employer makes the threat for his own gain and not out of malice. If he carries out the threat, he probably does it to retain his credibility. On the other hand, that rescission on grounds of duress may not be possible in this situation, is suggested by cases that state categorically that it is not duress for a party to insist upon what he believes to be his legal rights. Jacobs v. Atlantco Ltd. P'ship No. 1, 373 A.2d 1255, 1261 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 1977).
    • The employer makes the threat for his own gain and not out of malice. If he carries out the threat, he probably does it to retain his credibility. On the other hand, that rescission on grounds of duress may not be possible in this situation, is suggested by cases that state categorically that "it is not duress for a party to insist upon what he believes to be his legal rights." Jacobs v. Atlantco Ltd. P'ship No. 1, 373 A.2d 1255, 1261 (Md. Ct. Spec. App. 1977).
  • 283
    • 74849124526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subha Narasimhan, Modification: The Self-Help Specific Performance Remedy, 97 YALE L. J. 61, 77 (1987),
    • Subha Narasimhan, Modification: The Self-Help Specific Performance Remedy, 97 YALE L. J. 61, 77 (1987),
  • 284
    • 74849123088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • recognizes the deceptive nature of agreeing to a modification and then disavowing it by claiming duress. The article comes to the remarkable conclusion that courts should not permit such deception because it undercuts efficient breach unless the circumstances are such that a court would have ordered specific performance. Id. at 82
    • recognizes the deceptive nature of agreeing to a modification and then disavowing it by claiming duress. The article comes to the remarkable conclusion that courts should not permit such deception because it undercuts efficient breach unless the circumstances are such that a court would have ordered specific performance. Id. at 82.
  • 285
    • 84868072753 scopus 로고
    • Contract Modification and "Self-Help Specific Performance": A Reaction to Professor Narasimhan, 75
    • A basic fallacy in the argument is the assumption that the limitations on court-ordered specific performance should apply to self-help specific performance. For a critical response, see
    • For a critical response, see Robert A. Hillman, Contract Modification and "Self-Help Specific Performance": A Reaction to Professor Narasimhan, 75 CORNELL L. REV. 62 (1989). A basic fallacy in the argument is the assumption that the limitations on court-ordered specific performance should apply to self-help specific performance.
    • (1989) CORNELL L. REV , vol.62
    • Hillman, R.A.1
  • 286
    • 74849083280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 100-04 and accompanying text. A breach is not material if damages adequately protect the promisee's interest in performance, particularly if withholding performance would impose a significant harm on the defaulter and the breach is in good faith.
    • See supra notes 100-04 and accompanying text. A breach is not material if damages adequately protect the promisee's interest in performance, particularly if withholding performance would impose a significant harm on the defaulter and the breach is in good faith.
  • 287
    • 84868052458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 250 cmt. d (1981) might be read to cast the loss on Henrici in this situation. It states that [g]enerally, a party acts at his peril if, insisting on what he mistakenly believes to be his rights, he refuses to perform his duty. Id.
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 250 cmt. d (1981) might be read to cast the loss on Henrici in this situation. It states that "[g]enerally, a party acts at his peril if, insisting on what he mistakenly believes to be his rights, he refuses to perform his duty." Id.
  • 288
    • 84868052459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The argument would be that Henrici's act is a repudiation, which would justify withholding delivery. Corbin argues the contrary point: Disputes often arise as to what performance the contract requires; and the plaintiffs breach is not willful if he performs in accordance with his own honest interpretation, even though he knows that the other party holds a different one. CORBIN, supra note 122, § 1122.
    • The argument would be that Henrici's act is a repudiation, which would justify withholding delivery. Corbin argues the contrary point: "Disputes often arise as to what performance the contract requires; and the plaintiffs breach is not willful if he performs in accordance with his own honest interpretation, even though he knows that the other party holds a different one." CORBIN, supra note 122, § 1122.
  • 289
    • 74849116953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Each proposition is true to a point. The apparent contradiction largely disappears once you realize they are speaking of different responses to breach. The Restatement speaks to whether a defaulter's belief that he performed his obligation saves him from liability to the other for damages. The answer generally is no. Corbin speaks to whether a defaulter's belief that he performed his obligation is relevant to deciding whether his breach was material, giving the other the power to exit. The answer is yes, but it is only one factor among several. Corbin does not cite case authority for his point, which is the pertinent point in this context. For cases discussing this point, see Walker v. Shasta Minerals & Chemical Co., 352 F.2d 634, 638 (10th Cir. 1965);
    • Each proposition is true to a point. The apparent contradiction largely disappears once you realize they are speaking of different responses to breach. The Restatement speaks to whether a defaulter's belief that he performed his obligation saves him from liability to the other for damages. The answer generally is no. Corbin speaks to whether a defaulter's belief that he performed his obligation is relevant to deciding whether his breach was material, giving the other the power to exit. The answer is yes, but it is only one factor among several. Corbin does not cite case authority for his point, which is the pertinent point in this context. For cases discussing this point, see Walker v. Shasta Minerals & Chemical Co., 352 F.2d 634, 638 (10th Cir. 1965);
  • 290
    • 74849096746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Golf Carts, Inc. v. Mid-Pacific Country Club, 493 P.2d 1338, 1340 (Haw. 1972);
    • Golf Carts, Inc. v. Mid-Pacific Country Club, 493 P.2d 1338, 1340 (Haw. 1972);
  • 291
    • 74849111660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hanson v. Duffy, 435 N. E.2d 1373, 1378 (Ill. App. Ct. 1982);
    • Hanson v. Duffy, 435 N. E.2d 1373, 1378 (Ill. App. Ct. 1982);
  • 292
    • 74849108739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berke & Co. v. Griffin, Inc., 367 A.2d 583, 586-87 (N. H. 1976);
    • Berke & Co. v. Griffin, Inc., 367 A.2d 583, 586-87 (N. H. 1976);
  • 293
    • 74849127845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kiriakides v. United Artists Communications, Inc., 440 S. E.2d 364, 367 (S. C. 1994).
    • Kiriakides v. United Artists Communications, Inc., 440 S. E.2d 364, 367 (S. C. 1994).
  • 294
    • 74849105683 scopus 로고
    • is a leading case holding that an insured cannot accelerate payments due under an insurance policy when the insurer fails to make a payment in the honest belief it is not due. Justice Cardozo explained: Repudiation there was none as the term is known to the law. Petitioner did not disclaim the intention or the duty to shape its conduct in accordance with the provisions of the contract, S
    • New York Life Insurance Co. v. Viglas, 297 U. S. 672 (1936), is a leading case holding that an insured cannot accelerate payments due under an insurance policy when the insurer fails to make a payment in the honest belief it is not due. Justice Cardozo explained: Repudiation there was none as the term is known to the law. Petitioner did not disclaim the intention or the duty to shape its conduct in accordance with the provisions of the contract.
    • (1936) New York Life Insurance Co. v. Viglas , vol.297 , Issue.U , pp. 672
  • 295
    • 74849093038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Far from repudiating those provisions, it appealed to their authority and endeavored to apply them, If it made a mistake, there was a breach of a provision of the policy with liability for any damages appropriate thereto. We do not pause at the moment to fix the proper measure. Enough in this connection that at that stage of the transaction there had been no renunciation or abandonment of the contract as a whole. Id. at 676-77
    • Far from repudiating those provisions, it appealed to their authority and endeavored to apply them.... If it made a mistake, there was a breach of a provision of the policy with liability for any damages appropriate thereto. We do not pause at the moment to fix the proper measure. Enough in this connection that at that stage of the transaction there had been no renunciation or abandonment of the contract as a whole. Id. at 676-77.
  • 296
    • 74849119598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a similar confusion of the different issues in Woodar Investment Development Ltd. v. Wimpey Construction U. K. Ltd., [1980] 1 W. L. R. 277, 283.
    • There is a similar confusion of the different issues in Woodar Investment Development Ltd. v. Wimpey Construction U. K. Ltd., [1980] 1 W. L. R. 277, 283.
  • 297
    • 74849123577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lord Wilberforce echoes the proposition just above: [I]t would be a regrettable development of the law of contract to hold that a party who bona fide relies on an express stipulation in a contract in order to rescind or terminate a contract should, by that fact alone, be treated as having repudiated his contractual obligations if he turns out to be mistaken as to his rights. Id.
    • Lord Wilberforce echoes the proposition just above: [I]t would be a regrettable development of the law of contract to hold that a party who bona fide relies on an express stipulation in a contract in order to rescind or terminate a contract should, by that fact alone, be treated as having repudiated his contractual obligations if he turns out to be mistaken as to his rights. Id.
  • 298
    • 74849098277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lord Salmon, quoting Lord Denning from an earlier case, echoes the Restatement: I have yet to learn that a party who breaks his contract can excuse himself by saying that he did it on advice of his lawyers; or that he was under an honest misapprehension. Nor can he excuse himself on those grounds from the consequences of a repudiation. Id. at 287.
    • Lord Salmon, quoting Lord Denning from an earlier case, echoes the Restatement: "I have yet to learn that a party who breaks his contract can excuse himself by saying that he did it on advice of his lawyers; or that he was under an honest misapprehension. Nor can he excuse himself on those grounds from the consequences of a repudiation." Id. at 287.
  • 299
    • 74849093039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an illustration of this point, see K&G Construction Co. v. Harris, 164 A.2d 451 (Md. 1960).
    • For an illustration of this point, see K&G Construction Co. v. Harris, 164 A.2d 451 (Md. 1960).
  • 300
    • 74849111659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harris had a contract with K&G to excavate and move dirt in K&G's multihouse construction project, at
    • Harris had a contract with K&G to excavate and move dirt in K&G's multihouse construction project. Id. at 453.
    • Id , pp. 453
  • 301
    • 74849084239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harris's bulldozer damaged a house and Harris and his insurer denied liability. In response, K&G withheld progress payments totaling less than the amount of its claim. Harris in turn stopped work and K&G hired another company to finish the job. Both parties suffered a loss. K&G paid the substitute more than it would have paid Harris; Harris lost the profit he would have made completing the job.
    • Harris's bulldozer damaged a house and Harris and his insurer denied liability. In response, K&G withheld progress payments totaling less than the amount of its claim. Harris in turn stopped work and K&G hired another company to finish the job. Both parties suffered a loss. K&G paid the substitute more than it would have paid Harris; Harris lost the profit he would have made completing the job.
  • 303
    • 74849133961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 456
    • Id. at 456.
  • 304
    • 74849134260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • K&G recovered the additional cost of the substitute. Id. at 456-57.
    • K&G recovered the additional cost of the substitute. Id. at 456-57.
  • 305
    • 30144439128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Uncertainty, Economic Efficiency, and the Preliminary Injunction Doctrine, 58
    • For an argument that courts should apply an interim-efficiency rule in passing on a motion for preliminary injunction, see
    • For an argument that courts should apply an "interim-efficiency rule" in passing on a motion for preliminary injunction, see Richard R. W. Brooks & Warren F. Schwartz, Legal Uncertainty, Economic Efficiency, and the Preliminary Injunction Doctrine, 58 STAN. L. REV. 381, 409 (2005).
    • (2005) STAN. L. REV , vol.381 , pp. 409
    • Brooks, R.R.W.1    Schwartz, W.F.2
  • 306
    • 74849130375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A duty to cooperate is similar to the interim efficiency rule; both are designed to encourage the parties to perform in whatever manner is in their joint interest in the face of legal uncertainty. The authors note their proposal is a radically different perspective than that articulated in judicial opinions and prior legal scholarship. Id. at 382
    • A duty to cooperate is similar to the interim efficiency rule; both are designed to encourage the parties to perform in whatever manner is in their joint interest in the face of legal uncertainty. The authors note their proposal is "a radically different perspective than that articulated in judicial opinions and prior legal scholarship". Id. at 382.
  • 307
    • 74849125211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 474 p 2d 689 (Cal. 1970);
    • 474 p 2d 689 (Cal. 1970);
  • 308
    • 33846582209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 15-27 and accompanying text
    • see also supra notes 15-27 and accompanying text.
    • see also supra
  • 309
    • 74849114456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hope's Architectural Prods. Inc. v. Lundy's Constr., Inc., 781 F. Supp. 711, 714-17 (D. Kan. 1991).
    • See Hope's Architectural Prods. Inc. v. Lundy's Constr., Inc., 781 F. Supp. 711, 714-17 (D. Kan. 1991).
  • 310
    • 74849104818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This case involves specially manufactured windows and a dispute over the parties' respective rights and obligations when the windows were delivered later than the buyer expected. Id. at 712
    • This case involves specially manufactured windows and a dispute over the parties' respective rights and obligations when the windows were delivered later than the buyer expected. Id. at 712.
  • 311
    • 74849124205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The decision casts the loss on the seller after thoughtfully working through who was in the right in the underlying disputes. Id. at 717
    • The decision casts the loss on the seller after thoughtfully working through who was in the right in the underlying disputes. Id. at 717.
  • 312
    • 74849112608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A prologue to the opinion observes: This case presents a familiar situation in the field of construction contracts. Two parties, who disagreed over the meaning of their contract, held their positions to the brink, with litigation and loss the predictable result of the dispute. What is rarely predictable, however, (and what leads to a compromise resolution of many construction disputes when cool heads hold sway) is which party will ultimately prevail. The stakes become winner-take-all. Id. at 711-12.
    • A prologue to the opinion observes: This case presents a familiar situation in the field of construction contracts. Two parties, who disagreed over the meaning of their contract, held their positions to the brink, with litigation and loss the predictable result of the dispute. What is rarely predictable, however, (and what leads to a compromise resolution of many construction disputes when cool heads hold sway) is which party will ultimately prevail. The stakes become winner-take-all. Id. at 711-12.
  • 313
    • 74849129480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The principle of construction in Jacobs & Young v. Kent, 129 N. E. 889, 891 (N. Y. 1921), also is a warning: Intention not otherwise revealed may be presumed to hold in contemplation the reasonable and probable. If something else is in view, it must not be left to implication. There will be no assumption of a purpose to visit venial faults with oppressive retribution.
    • The principle of construction in Jacobs & Young v. Kent, 129 N. E. 889, 891 (N. Y. 1921), also is a warning: "Intention not otherwise revealed may be presumed to hold in contemplation the reasonable and probable. If something else is in view, it must not be left to implication. There will be no assumption of a purpose to visit venial faults with oppressive retribution. "
  • 314
    • 74849089786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eisenberg, supra note 7, at 223-40
    • Eisenberg, supra note 7, at 223-40.
  • 315
    • 74849110134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE 8 (1981).
    • See CHARLES FRIED, CONTRACT AS PROMISE 8 (1981).
  • 316
    • 74849096289 scopus 로고
    • A Consent Theory of Contracts, 86
    • See
    • See Randy E. Barnett, A Consent Theory of Contracts, 86 COLUM. L. REV. 269, 270 (1986);
    • (1986) COLUM. L. REV , vol.269 , pp. 270
    • Barnett, R.E.1
  • 317
    • 0042934066 scopus 로고
    • The Sound of Silence: Default Rules and Contractual Consent, 78
    • Randy E. Barnett, The Sound of Silence: Default Rules and Contractual Consent, 78 VA. L. REV. 821, 827-28 (1992).
    • (1992) VA. L. REV , vol.821 , pp. 827-828
    • Barnett, R.E.1
  • 318
    • 74849083281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See P. S. ATIYAH, ESSAYS ON CONTRACT 42-43, 80-82 (1988).
    • See P. S. ATIYAH, ESSAYS ON CONTRACT 42-43, 80-82 (1988).
  • 319
    • 74849097316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See STEPHEN A. SMITH, CONTRACT THEORY 42-49 (2004) (observing that this sort of typology conflates the analytical question of what is the legal basis (or causative event) of contractual obligation - e.g., promise, reliance, transfer, etc. - and the normative question of the justification for imposing an obligation upon the relevant causative event and embracing a rights-based theory);
    • See STEPHEN A. SMITH, CONTRACT THEORY 42-49 (2004) (observing that this sort of typology conflates the analytical question of what is the legal basis (or causative event) of contractual obligation - e.g., promise, reliance, transfer, etc. - and the normative question of the justification for imposing an obligation upon the relevant causative event and embracing a rights-based theory);
  • 320
    • 74849137968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peter Benson, Contract, in A COMPANION TO PHILOSOPHY OF LAW AND LEGAL THEORY 24, 33-43 (Dennis Patterson ed., 1996);
    • Peter Benson, Contract, in A COMPANION TO PHILOSOPHY OF LAW AND LEGAL THEORY 24, 33-43 (Dennis Patterson ed., 1996);
  • 321
    • 74849090890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peter Benson, The Unity of Contract Law, in THE THEORY OF CONTRACT LAW 118, 163 (Peter Benson ed., 2001).
    • Peter Benson, The Unity of Contract Law, in THE THEORY OF CONTRACT LAW 118, 163 (Peter Benson ed., 2001).
  • 322
    • 74849123380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A libertarian theory of contract grounds legal obligation on an actor's manifested consent to be under a legal obligation. For a theory along these lines, see Barnett, supra note 135, at 270
    • A libertarian theory of contract grounds legal obligation on an actor's manifested consent to be under a legal obligation. For a theory along these lines, see Barnett, supra note 135, at 270.
  • 323
    • 74849123578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-described natural law theories of contract include JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991) and HENRY MATHER, CONTRACT LAW AND MORALITY (1999).
    • Self-described natural law theories of contract include JAMES GORDLEY, THE PHILOSOPHICAL ORIGINS OF MODERN CONTRACT DOCTRINE (1991) and HENRY MATHER, CONTRACT LAW AND MORALITY (1999).
  • 324
    • 34250873362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reconciling Strict Liability with Corrective Justice in Contract Law, 75
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Curtis Bridgeman, Reconciling Strict Liability with Corrective Justice in Contract Law, 75 FORDHAM L. REV. 3013, 3022 (2007).
    • (2007) FORDHAM L. REV , vol.3013 , pp. 3022
    • Bridgeman, C.1
  • 325
    • 74849121035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bridgeman argues a corrective justice theory of contract is immune from the problem that besets a corrective justice theory of torts, which is explaining the grounds for making an actor responsible for harm the actor causes, because [b]inding contracts create entitlements in the promisee, and any loss of those entitlements becomes the promisor's responsibility to repair. Id
    • Bridgeman argues a corrective justice theory of contract is immune from the problem that besets a corrective justice theory of torts, which is explaining the grounds for making an actor responsible for harm the actor causes, because "[b]inding contracts create entitlements in the promisee, and any loss of those entitlements becomes the promisor's responsibility to repair." Id.
  • 326
    • 74849115474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As for why this is so, Bridgeman leaves it at the widely held intuition that individuals are generally free to assume obligations if they so desire. Id.
    • As for why this is so, Bridgeman leaves it at "the widely held intuition that individuals are generally free to assume obligations if they so desire." Id.
  • 327
    • 74849125511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eisenberg, supra note 7, at 223
    • Eisenberg, supra note 7, at 223.
  • 328
    • 74849107078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The obvious alternatives to autonomy theories are non-economic theories or moral theories. Both names cede too much ground to economic theories. Non-economic theories defines the group by what they are not. A prescriptive economic theory is a moral theory.
    • The obvious alternatives to "autonomy theories" are "non-economic theories" or "moral theories." Both names cede too much ground to economic theories. "Non-economic theories" defines the group by what they are not. A prescriptive economic theory is a moral theory.
  • 329
    • 74849083589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • VICTOR GOLDBERG, FRAMING CONTRACT LAW 1 (2006).
    • VICTOR GOLDBERG, FRAMING CONTRACT LAW 1 (2006).
  • 330
    • 74849109902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, two of Fuller's three functions of contract formalities - the cautionary and channeling functions - emphasize the ability of formal rules to empower individuals to determine their legal obligations. Lon L. Fuller, Consideration and Form, 41 COLUM. L. REV. 799, 800, 801 (1941)
    • For example, two of Fuller's three functions of contract formalities - the cautionary and channeling functions - emphasize the ability of formal rules to empower individuals to determine their legal obligations. Lon L. Fuller, Consideration and Form, 41 COLUM. L. REV. 799, 800, 801 (1941)
  • 331
    • 74849106516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing the cautionary function as a mechanism for inducing the circumspective frame of mind appropriate in one pledging his future and the channeling function as a simple and external test of enforceability). This could be a species of a liberal consequential theory that has the goal of designing contract law rules to best enable individuals to live fulfilling lives. Professor Smith classifies all consequentialist theories as utilitarian in the broad sense he uses the term. See SMITH, supra note 137, at 46-47.
    • (describing the cautionary function as a mechanism for "inducing the circumspective frame of mind appropriate in one pledging his future" and the channeling function as a "simple and external test of enforceability"). This could be a species of a liberal consequential theory that has the goal of designing contract law rules to best enable individuals to live fulfilling lives. Professor Smith classifies all consequentialist theories as utilitarian "in the broad sense" he uses the term. See SMITH, supra note 137, at 46-47.
  • 332
    • 74849089041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While American readers will find this use of the term utilitarian jarring, it does emphasize the tension in a rights-based theory of having courts self-consciously decide rights-claims before them with an eye on how a decision will affect future behavior
    • While American readers will find this use of the term "utilitarian" jarring, it does emphasize the tension in a rights-based theory of having courts self-consciously decide rights-claims before them with an eye on how a decision will affect future behavior.
  • 333
    • 74849120185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SMITH, supra note 137, at 54 helpfully characterizes many such theories of contract as addressing the analytic question of the nature of contract law, meaning the distinctive features of contract as a species of obligation. Smith groups these theories into three categories - promissory theories, reliance theories, and transfer theories. Smith correctly distinguishes such theories from theories that try to justify contractual obligation.
    • SMITH, supra note 137, at 54 helpfully characterizes many such theories of contract as addressing the "analytic question" of the nature of contract law, meaning the distinctive features of contract as a species of obligation. Smith groups these theories into three categories - promissory theories, reliance theories, and transfer theories. Smith correctly distinguishes such theories from theories that try to justify contractual obligation.
  • 334
    • 0041812393 scopus 로고
    • The Efficient Breach Fallacy, 18
    • For an argument that the theory is descriptively inaccurate for other reasons, see
    • For an argument that the theory is descriptively inaccurate for other reasons, see Daniel Friedmann, The Efficient Breach Fallacy, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 18-23 (1989).
    • (1989) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.1 , pp. 18-23
    • Friedmann, D.1
  • 335
    • 33846600262 scopus 로고
    • The duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay damages if you do not keep it, - and nothing else. Oliver Wendell Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10
    • The classic statement of the view is by
    • The classic statement of the view is by Holmes: "The duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay damages if you do not keep it, - and nothing else." Oliver Wendell Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 HARV. L. REV. 457, 462 (1897).
    • (1897) HARV. L. REV , vol.457 , pp. 462
    • Holmes1
  • 336
    • 74849137369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holmes said this in a lecture to beginning law students to dispel a confusion between morality and law. Id. at 459.
    • Holmes said this in a lecture to beginning law students to "dispel a confusion between morality and law." Id. at 459.
  • 337
    • 74849106803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holmes understood that his audience (like most people) thought breach of contract was immoral. He was telling them to try to put their views on the immorality of breach aside in learning contract rules defining the legal consequences of breach. Id.
    • Holmes understood that his audience (like most people) thought breach of contract was immoral. He was telling them to try to put their views on the immorality of breach aside in learning contract rules defining the legal consequences of breach. Id.
  • 338
    • 0034421255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When contemporaries interpreted Holmes as asserting a right to breach a contract so long as one paid the price (some call this the option theory of contract, he chided them for misunderstanding his point and responded that he considered breach of contract a wrong on par with a tort. Joseph M. Perillo, Misreading Oliver Wendell Holmes on Efficient Breach and Tortious Interference, 68 FORDHAM L. REV. 1085, 1086-90 2000
    • When contemporaries interpreted Holmes as asserting a right to breach a contract so long as one paid the price (some call this the "option theory of contract"), he chided them for misunderstanding his point and responded that he considered breach of contract a wrong on par with a tort. Joseph M. Perillo, Misreading Oliver Wendell Holmes on Efficient Breach and Tortious Interference, 68 FORDHAM L. REV. 1085, 1086-90 (2000).
  • 339
    • 74849087049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 4
    • See supra note 4.
  • 340
    • 0008992534 scopus 로고
    • Precontractual Investigation as an Optimal Precaution Problem, 17
    • Richard Craswell, Precontractual Investigation as an Optimal Precaution Problem, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 401, 412 (1988);
    • (1988) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.401 , pp. 412
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 341
    • 84928845999 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Alternative Damage Rules for Breach of Contract, 32
    • David J. Friedman, An Economic Analysis of Alternative Damage Rules for Breach of Contract, 32 J. L. & ECON. 281, 284 (1989).
    • (1989) J. L. & ECON , vol.281 , pp. 284
    • Friedman, D.J.1
  • 342
    • 85075685760 scopus 로고
    • Efficient Reliance and Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 15
    • William P. Rogerson, Efficient Reliance and Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 15 RAND J. ECON. 39, 47 (1984).
    • (1984) RAND J. ECON , vol.39 , pp. 47
    • Rogerson, W.P.1
  • 343
    • 74849108969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Douglas Laycock summarizes the state of the debate at the turn of the century as it looked to a non-economist: Scholars on all sides of the controversy have mostly recognized that if there were no transaction costs, the parties would always transfer the carrots to the party with the most valuable use. Thus, the economic wisdom was to select the rule with the lowest transaction costs, and much of the literature turned on ever-more-detailed speculative analyses of the likely transaction costs of each remedy. LAYCOCK, supra note 26, at 390
    • Douglas Laycock summarizes the state of the debate at the turn of the century as it looked to a non-economist: Scholars on all sides of the controversy have mostly recognized that if there were no transaction costs, the parties would always transfer the carrots to the party with the most valuable use. Thus, the economic wisdom was to select the rule with the lowest transaction costs, and much of the literature turned on ever-more-detailed speculative analyses of the likely transaction costs of each remedy. LAYCOCK, supra note 26, at 390.
  • 344
    • 8744279274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Scott and Triantis, focusing on two-party situations, make a similar point with a different twist: The premise that parties can often renegotiate to efficient ex post outcomes is sufficiently well accepted that contract theorists have largely set aside the concern with efficient breach to focus on the hold-up problems caused by renegotiation. Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Embedded Options and the Case Against Compensation in Contract Law, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 1428, 1451 (2004).
    • Professors Scott and Triantis, focusing on two-party situations, make a similar point with a different twist: "The premise that parties can often renegotiate to efficient ex post outcomes is sufficiently well accepted that contract theorists have largely set aside the concern with efficient breach to focus on the hold-up problems caused by renegotiation". Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Embedded Options and the Case Against Compensation in Contract Law, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 1428, 1451 (2004).
  • 345
    • 74849112288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz, supra note 8, at 383-87
    • Schwartz, supra note 8, at 383-87.
  • 346
    • 74849095085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at 614-16
    • See Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at 614-16.
  • 347
    • 74849099038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 129 N. E. 889, 891 (N. Y. 1921) (refusing to award the cost of replacing piping from an incorrect factory because the defect was insubstantial and the cost of replacing the piping would have been great).
    • 129 N. E. 889, 891 (N. Y. 1921) (refusing to award the cost of replacing piping from an incorrect factory because the defect was insubstantial and the cost of replacing the piping would have been great).
  • 348
    • 74849083588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at 614-16
    • See Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at 614-16.
  • 349
    • 74849087641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 350
    • 74849092735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1429
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1429.
  • 351
    • 74849130057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Brooks, supra note 4, at 579 (The efficient breach hypothesis is premised on the Holmesian option theory of contract obligation....).
    • See, e.g., Brooks, supra note 4, at 579 ("The efficient breach hypothesis is premised on the Holmesian option theory of contract obligation....").
  • 352
    • 74849124836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1491
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1491.
  • 353
    • 74849123877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 233-42 (using the classic case of Neri v. Retail Marine Corp., 285 N. E.2d 311 (N. Y. 1972), to demonstrate the economic implications of compensatory damages for breach of contract when dealing with lost-retail sellers).
    • See GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 233-42 (using the classic case of Neri v. Retail Marine Corp., 285 N. E.2d 311 (N. Y. 1972), to demonstrate the economic implications of compensatory damages for breach of contract when dealing with lost-volume retail sellers).
  • 355
    • 74849132930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Tongish v. Thomas, 840 P.2d 471 (Kan. 1992), to illustrate the sometimes over-compensatory effect of damages in the case of middle-men).
    • and Tongish v. Thomas, 840 P.2d 471 (Kan. 1992), to illustrate the sometimes over-compensatory effect of damages in the case of middle-men).
  • 356
    • 74849133648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Scott and Triantis argue for a background rule of contract-market damages in thick markets in non-consumer contracts. See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1479-80
    • Professors Scott and Triantis argue for a background rule of contract-market damages in thick markets in non-consumer contracts. See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1479-80.
  • 357
    • 74849137969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They favor a background rule of no damages in a case of repudiation by a consumer of a purchase agreement with a merchant. They would allow a merchant to collect a nonrefundable deposit to recover the merchant's cost of giving a consumer a purchase option. See id. at 1488-90;
    • They favor a background rule of no damages in a case of repudiation by a consumer of a purchase agreement with a merchant. They would allow a merchant to collect a nonrefundable deposit to recover the merchant's cost of giving a consumer a purchase option. See id. at 1488-90;
  • 358
    • 74849111944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • accord GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 237-38. In thin markets in commercial contract, Professors Scott and Triantis propose a background rule of specific performance around which people could contract.
    • accord GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 237-38. In thin markets in commercial contract, Professors Scott and Triantis propose a background rule of specific performance around which people could contract.
  • 359
    • 74849109588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1486-88
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1486-88.
  • 360
    • 35648997334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, note 150, at, This rings true to me
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1436-47. This rings true to me.
    • supra , pp. 1436-1447
    • Scott1    Triantis2
  • 361
    • 74849116550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 474 P.2d 689, 694 (Cal. 1970).
    • 474 P.2d 689, 694 (Cal. 1970).
  • 362
    • 74849127013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 362 N. W.2d 704, 707 (Mich. 1984).
    • 362 N. W.2d 704, 707 (Mich. 1984).
  • 363
    • 74849118390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An example is when an over-booked airline charges a passenger a cancellation fee. While the cancellation fee would seem to be a windfall to the airline which was overbooked, the fee might well be the price the passenger pays for an option of a seat on the flight, which bears no relation to the airline's loss if the passenger cancels. Indeed, the more likely a flight will be over-booked, the more valuable the option to the passenger
    • An example is when an over-booked airline charges a passenger a cancellation fee. While the cancellation fee would seem to be a windfall to the airline (which was overbooked), the fee might well be the price the passenger pays for an option of a seat on the flight, which bears no relation to the airline's loss if the passenger cancels. Indeed, the more likely a flight will be over-booked, the more valuable the option to the passenger.
  • 364
    • 74849083919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1468-70
    • See Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1468-70.
  • 365
    • 74849114166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1433 (Courts are not well suited to set default contract damages either.).
    • Id. at 1433 ("Courts are not well suited to set default contract damages either.").
  • 366
    • 74849103865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They endorse a specific performance default for commercial contracts in thin markets because of the simplicity of the rule and because it will force parties to bargain for alternative termination terms
    • They endorse a specific performance default for commercial contracts in thin markets because of the simplicity of the rule and because it will force parties to bargain for alternative termination terms.
  • 367
    • 74849093301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1479-86.
    • See id. at 1479-86.
  • 368
    • 74849139394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In raising these questions about the expectation principle, Professors Scott and Triantis are extraordinarily provocative. That lawyers and legal theorists make too much of principle, or abstract legal maxims, is hardly news. Jack Dawson's observations about the principle opposing unjust enrichment come to mind. He warned the principle had the peculiar faculty of inducing quite sober citizens to jump right off the dock and attributed this to its strong appeal to the sense of equal justice [combined with] the delusive appearance of mathematical simplicity. JOHN P. DAWSON, UNJUST ENRICHMENT 8 (1951).
    • In raising these questions about the expectation principle, Professors Scott and Triantis are extraordinarily provocative. That lawyers and legal theorists make too much of principle, or abstract legal maxims, is hardly news. Jack Dawson's observations about the principle opposing unjust enrichment come to mind. He warned the principle "had the peculiar faculty of inducing quite sober citizens to jump right off the dock" and attributed this to its "strong appeal to the sense of equal justice [combined with] the delusive appearance of mathematical simplicity." JOHN P. DAWSON, UNJUST ENRICHMENT 8 (1951).
  • 369
    • 74749110169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The expectation principle has an even stronger pull. The idea that the remedy for a wrong is to place the wronged person in the position she would have been in had the wrong not been committed seems self-evidently correct. The idea unifies the fields of remedies and causation and transcends contract and tort. It is the organizing principle of the leading remedies casebook. LAYCOCK, supra note 26. Scott and Triantis may well be right in arguing that we have taken the principle too far. Lawyers, particularly academic lawyers, are prone to a hardening of the categories.
    • The expectation principle has an even stronger pull. The idea that the remedy for a wrong is to place the wronged person in the position she would have been in had the wrong not been committed seems self-evidently correct. The idea unifies the fields of remedies and causation and transcends contract and tort. It is the organizing principle of the leading remedies casebook. LAYCOCK, supra note 26. Scott and Triantis may well be right in arguing that we have taken the principle too far. Lawyers, particularly academic lawyers, are prone to a "hardening of the categories."
  • 370
    • 74849097651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 474 P.2d 689 (Cal. 1970).
    • 474 P.2d 689 (Cal. 1970).
  • 371
    • 74849120426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Goldberg, supra note 11, at 1052-53
    • See Goldberg, supra note 11, at 1052-53.
  • 372
    • 74849113471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 373
    • 74849134259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 284-86
    • See GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 284-86.
  • 374
    • 74849102518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 286.
    • See id. at 286.
  • 375
    • 74849112927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1429-30
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 150, at 1429-30.
  • 376
    • 74849107443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 286 (reporting statements of the trial court in Parker);
    • See GOLDBERG, supra note 142, at 286 (reporting statements of the trial court in Parker);
  • 382
    • 74849117513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT 15 (2d ed. 1995) (1974).
    • GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT 15 (2d ed. 1995) (1974).
  • 383
    • 74849108970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There has been movement to weaken or eliminate formal requirements for contract. The Uniform Commercial Code directs courts to try to enforce indefinite agreements if the parties appeared to intend to make a contract
    • There has been movement to weaken or eliminate formal requirements for contract. The Uniform Commercial Code directs courts to try to enforce indefinite agreements if the parties appeared to intend to make a contract.
  • 384
    • 84868082266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U. C. C. § 2-204 (3) (1977) (Even though one or more terms are left open a contract for sale does not fail for indefiniteness if the parties have intended to make a contract and there is a reasonably certain basis for giving an appropriate remedy.). The Code also weakens the statute of frauds by requiring little in the way of a writing to satisfy the statute.
    • See U. C. C. § 2-204 (3) (1977) ("Even though one or more terms are left open a contract for sale does not fail for indefiniteness if the parties have intended to make a contract and there is a reasonably certain basis for giving an appropriate remedy."). The Code also weakens the statute of frauds by requiring little in the way of a writing to satisfy the statute.
  • 385
    • 84868084572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 2-201 (1) & cmt. 1. Additionally, the U. C. C. abolishes the strict form of the mirror image rule; an apparent acceptance still will not create a contract if the acceptance states that it is conditional on assent to its terms.
    • See id. § 2-201 (1) & cmt. 1. Additionally, the U. C. C. abolishes the strict form of the mirror image rule; an apparent acceptance still will not create a contract if the acceptance states that it is conditional on assent to its terms.
  • 386
    • 84868084573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • See id. § 2-207 (1).
    • § 2-207
  • 387
    • 84868052453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Formal requirements for contract also are subject to qualifications that limit an actor's power to dishonor an agreement with impunity once the other party performs, and in some jurisdictions, once the other party relies. For example, if an agreement is unenforceable on grounds of indefiniteness, then a party may recover the reasonable cost of performance rendered on a restitution claim. RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 31 (2004).
    • Formal requirements for contract also are subject to qualifications that limit an actor's power to dishonor an agreement with impunity once the other party performs, and in some jurisdictions, once the other party relies. For example, if an agreement is unenforceable on grounds of indefiniteness, then a party may recover the reasonable cost of performance rendered on a restitution claim. RESTATEMENT (THIRD) of RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 31 (2004).
  • 388
    • 74849116954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • And in some jurisdictions, a promissory estoppel claim is available to recover expenses made in reliance on an indefinite agreement if the indefiniteness does not preclude a finding of breach
    • And in some jurisdictions, a promissory estoppel claim is available to recover expenses made in reliance on an indefinite agreement if the indefiniteness does not preclude a finding of breach.
  • 389
    • 74849134258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wheeler v. White, 398 S. W. 2d 93, 97 (Tex. 1965).
    • See, e.g., Wheeler v. White, 398 S. W. 2d 93, 97 (Tex. 1965).
  • 390
    • 74849106002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The limited holding of Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores, Inc., 133 N. W.2d 267, 275 (Wis. 1965), is that a promissory estoppel claim is available to recover expenses made by the claimant in anticipation of receiving a franchise though there was no agreement on essential terms of the franchise.
    • The limited holding of Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores, Inc., 133 N. W.2d 267, 275 (Wis. 1965), is that a promissory estoppel claim is available to recover expenses made by the claimant in anticipation of receiving a franchise though there was no agreement on essential terms of the franchise.
  • 391
    • 74849113860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Scott, supra note 9, at 1645. Professor Scott begins with a descriptive claim based on his review of five years of cases in which the issue of indefiniteness is addressed. He finds that courts more often than not decline to enforce contracts with material uncertain terms.
    • See Scott, supra note 9, at 1645. Professor Scott begins with a descriptive claim based on his review of five years of cases in which the issue of indefiniteness is addressed. He finds that courts more often than not decline to enforce contracts with material uncertain terms.
  • 392
    • 74849083918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1644. Of eighty-nine cases found by Scott in which the issue is genuinely joined, courts decline to enforce the contract in fifty-five cases while they enforce the contract in thirty-four others.
    • Id. at 1644. Of eighty-nine cases found by Scott in which the issue is genuinely joined, courts decline to enforce the contract in fifty-five cases while they enforce the contract in thirty-four others.
  • 393
    • 74849086181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1652-53. Digging into the cases, Professor Scott finds an interesting pattern. Typically, when courts enforce an indefinite agreement, the parties have a good reason to leave a material term unspecified. These are complex transactions in which [t]he parties wrote as complete an agreement as they could under the circumstances.
    • Id. at 1652-53. Digging into the cases, Professor Scott finds an interesting pattern. Typically, when courts enforce an indefinite agreement, the parties have a good reason to leave a material term unspecified. These are complex transactions in which "[t]he parties wrote as complete an agreement as they could under the circumstances."
  • 394
    • 74849134554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1656. Courts do not enforce indefinite agreements if the parties leave a material term unresolved by oversight (which is rare) or if the parties deliberately chose an indefinite agreement over a more explicit and verifiable alternative.
    • Id. at 1656. Courts do not enforce indefinite agreements if the parties leave a material term unresolved by oversight (which is rare) or if the parties deliberately chose an indefinite agreement over a "more explicit and verifiable alternative."
  • 395
    • 74849098762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1657
    • Id. at 1657.
  • 396
    • 74849104507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1688.
    • See id. at 1688.
  • 397
    • 74849125509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (In short, any enforcement rule (or standard) that conditions on unverifiable factors (such as high quality) will produce an [economically] inferior outcome to a nonenforcement rule that leaves the parties' room for reciprocity.).
    • See id. ("In short, any enforcement rule (or standard) that conditions on unverifiable factors (such as high quality) will produce an [economically] inferior outcome to a nonenforcement rule that leaves the parties' room for reciprocity.").
  • 398
    • 74849102860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1661-63 (considering reciprocal fairness as a means of self-enforcement).
    • Id. at 1661-63 (considering reciprocal fairness as a means of self-enforcement).
  • 399
    • 74849097954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 400
    • 74849111005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1662 (In particular, the social preferences for reciprocity and equality of treatment are the strongest candidates for developing a theory that expands the range of selfenforcing contracts to include isolated interactions between relative strangers.).
    • See id. at 1662 ("In particular, the social preferences for reciprocity and equality of treatment are the strongest candidates for developing a theory that expands the range of selfenforcing contracts to include isolated interactions between relative strangers.").
  • 401
    • 74849119878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1645.
    • See id. at 1645.
  • 402
    • 74849089787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1687-88 (explaining how a policy of enforcing intentionally incomplete agreements may lead parties not to use an intentionally incomplete contract though it is preferable to the alternative fully specified contract).
    • See id. at 1687-88 (explaining how a policy of enforcing intentionally incomplete agreements may lead parties not to use an intentionally incomplete contract though it is preferable to the alternative fully specified contract).
  • 403
    • 74849119031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1690 (The explicit, ex-ante nature of legal sanctions may... undermine the instinct to reciprocate.).
    • See id. at 1690 ("The explicit, ex-ante nature of legal sanctions may... undermine the instinct to reciprocate.").
  • 404
    • 74849136679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 177, at, commenting on the expanding function of courts in contract disputes
    • See GILMORE, supra note 177, at 15 (commenting on the expanding function of courts in contract disputes).
    • supra , pp. 15
    • GILMORE1
  • 405
    • 74849106517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many formal requirements for contract have the effect of making unenforceable agreements infected with particular types of uncertainty. For example, the statute of frauds, by requiring reliable written evidence of the existence of a contract, makes unenforceable an oral agreement of disputed existence
    • Many formal requirements for contract have the effect of making unenforceable agreements infected with particular types of uncertainty. For example, the statute of frauds, by requiring reliable written evidence of the existence of a contract, makes unenforceable an oral agreement of disputed existence.
  • 406
    • 84868082262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 110 (1981). And the mirror image rule, by treating an apparent acceptance with new or different terms as a counter-offer, makes unenforceable an agreement that has uncertain terms because of discrepant communications.
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of CONTRACTS § 110 (1981). And the mirror image rule, by treating an apparent acceptance with new or different terms as a counter-offer, makes unenforceable an agreement that has uncertain terms because of discrepant communications.
  • 407
    • 84868081882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 59.
    • See id. § 59.
  • 408
    • 74849112607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pac. Gas & Elec. Co v. G. W. Thomas Drayage & Rigging Co., 442 P.2d 641, 646 (Cal. 1968);
    • See, e.g., Pac. Gas & Elec. Co v. G. W. Thomas Drayage & Rigging Co., 442 P.2d 641, 646 (Cal. 1968);
  • 409
    • 74849129479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores, 133 N. W.2d 267, 274-77 (Wis. 1965).
    • Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores, 133 N. W.2d 267, 274-77 (Wis. 1965).
  • 410
    • 74849104187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Scott, supra note 9, at 1692-93
    • See Scott, supra note 9, at 1692-93.
  • 411
    • 74849117776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some forms of autonomy theories do not disagree on the point. A germane counterexample is the liberal/libertarian forward-looking argument for formal rules that enable people to determine their contractual obligations
    • Some forms of autonomy theories do not disagree on the point. A germane counterexample is the liberal/libertarian forward-looking argument for formal rules that enable people to determine their contractual obligations.
  • 412
    • 74849129164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 143 (explaining certain aspects of Fuller's autonomy-based contract theory that are forward-looking rather than backward-looking).
    • See supra note 143 (explaining certain aspects of Fuller's autonomy-based contract theory that are forward-looking rather than backward-looking).
  • 413
    • 7444229294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., William C. Whitford, Relational Contracts and the New Formalism, 2004 WIS. L. REV. 631, 641-42.
    • See, e.g., William C. Whitford, Relational Contracts and the New Formalism, 2004 WIS. L. REV. 631, 641-42.
  • 414
    • 74849116261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert E. Scott, Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores and the Myth of Precontractual Reliance, in CONTRACTS STORIES, supra note 33, at 87.
    • See Robert E. Scott, Hoffman v. Red Owl Stores and the Myth of Precontractual Reliance, in CONTRACTS STORIES, supra note 33, at 87.
  • 415
    • 74849117226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 133 N. W.2d 267, 275 (Wis. 1965).
    • 133 N. W.2d 267, 275 (Wis. 1965).
  • 416
    • 74849085357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at 544-45 (narrowing claim that contract law should do no more, and no less, than facilitate the efforts of contracting parties to maximize the joint gains to economic entities that can be expected to understand how to make business contracts).
    • Schwartz & Scott, supra note 8, at 544-45 (narrowing claim that contract law should do no more, and no less, than "facilitate the efforts of contracting parties to maximize the joint gains" to "economic entities that can be expected to understand how to make business contracts").
  • 417
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 106-10 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 106-10 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 418
    • 74849094553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A commonplace example is an agreement retaining a professional to accomplish a general task, such as hiring a lawyer to defend a legal claim or hiring a doctor to treat an ailment. Successful contracts of this sort have three general characteristics: (1) the parties cannot specify the precise terms of performance ex ante, often because this depends on future events that are impossible or costly to predict; (2) the factors determning the desirable level of performance, and the actual quality of performance, are observable ex post by a court, which is likely to make accurate decisions; and (3) the court can accurately assess damages from inadequate performance.
    • A commonplace example is an agreement retaining a professional to accomplish a general task, such as hiring a lawyer to defend a legal claim or hiring a doctor to treat an ailment. Successful contracts of this sort have three general characteristics: (1) the parties cannot specify the precise terms of performance ex ante, often because this depends on future events that are impossible or costly to predict; (2) the factors determning the desirable level of performance, and the actual quality of performance, are observable ex post by a court, which is likely to make accurate decisions; and (3) the court can accurately assess damages from inadequate performance.
  • 419
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 106-10 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 106-10 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 420
    • 0001023260 scopus 로고
    • Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and Their Resolution, 27
    • See
    • See Robert D. Cooter & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and Their Resolution, 27 J. ECON. LITERATURE 1067, 1075-77 (1989).
    • (1989) J. ECON. LITERATURE , vol.1067 , pp. 1075-1077
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 421
    • 84868082257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT OF RESTITUTION § 45 cmt. e (1937) (The rule stated in this Section does not apply if the parties have agreed that the payment is conditional upon the validity of the transferee's claim.).
    • See RESTATEMENT OF RESTITUTION § 45 cmt. e (1937) ("The rule stated in this Section does not apply if the parties have agreed that the payment is conditional upon the validity of the transferee's claim.").
  • 422
    • 74849126130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Builders Contract Interiors, Inc. v. Hi-Lo Indus., Inc., 134 P.3d 795, 799 (N. M. Ct. App. 2006).
    • See, e.g., Builders Contract Interiors, Inc. v. Hi-Lo Indus., Inc., 134 P.3d 795, 799 (N. M. Ct. App. 2006).
  • 423
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 129-32 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 129-32 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 424
    • 74849119326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hope's Architectural Prods., Inc. v. Lundy's Const., Inc., 781 F. Supp. 711, 714-17 (D. Kan. 1991) (explaining that stakes become winner-takes-all when parties in a contract dispute hold their positions to the brink).
    • Hope's Architectural Prods., Inc. v. Lundy's Const., Inc., 781 F. Supp. 711, 714-17 (D. Kan. 1991) (explaining that stakes become winner-takes-all when parties in a contract dispute hold their positions to the brink).
  • 425
    • 74849087640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 51 F.3d 76 (7th Cir. 1995).
    • 51 F.3d 76 (7th Cir. 1995).
  • 426
    • 74849119597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 77
    • Id. at 77.
  • 427
    • 74849087917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 78
    • Id. at 78.
  • 428
    • 74849132342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coalfield argued that it could have put men back to work immediately. See id. at 80. The court inferred that the stoppage entailed at least an eight-day delay based on a Coalfield fax.
    • Coalfield argued that it could have put men back to work immediately. See id. at 80. The court inferred that the stoppage entailed at least an eight-day delay based on a Coalfield fax.
  • 429
    • 74849105122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 430
    • 74849134257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is not clear from the opinion how strongly Coalfield insisted upon this. On this potentially crucial point, the opinion says: [H]e appeared to condition this promise [to pay the invoice] on Coalfield's signing an 'acceptance letter' that Maddox enclosed.
    • It is not clear from the opinion how strongly Coalfield insisted upon this. On this potentially crucial point, the opinion says: "[H]e appeared to condition this promise [to pay the invoice] on Coalfield's signing an 'acceptance letter' that Maddox enclosed."
  • 431
    • 74849086490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 78
    • Id. at 78.
  • 432
    • 74849130056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 433
    • 74849119327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 78-79.
    • See id. at 78-79.
  • 434
    • 74849099826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A few of the specific factual arguments for the decision are questionable. The opinion concludes that the most plausible interpretation of Maddox's action is that it was seeking excuses for not paying Coalfield anything.
    • A few of the specific factual arguments for the decision are questionable. The opinion concludes "that the most plausible interpretation of Maddox's action is that it was seeking excuses for not paying Coalfield anything."
  • 435
    • 74849129478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 80. Maddox's failure to sign and return the contract hardly suggests this. Given Maddox's acquiescence in Coalfield starting, no one could reasonably question that there was some sort of contract under which Maddox would pay for the work that was done
    • Maddox offered to pay for the work done less ten percent of the contract price
    • Id. at 80. Maddox's failure to sign and return the contract hardly suggests this. Given Maddox's acquiescence in Coalfield starting, no one could reasonably question that there was some sort of contract under which Maddox would pay for the work that was done. Nor does the letter "demanding" that Coalfield agree to pay liquidated damages support the conclusion. Maddox offered to pay for the work done less ten percent of the contract price.
    • Nor does the letter demanding
  • 436
    • 84868082256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 78. Liquidated damages were only $1000 per day.
    • Id. at 78. Liquidated damages were only $1000 per day.
  • 437
    • 84868081875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Had the job taken the eight weeks predicted by Coalfield, liquidated damages would have been $28, 000 on a $230, 000 contract.
    • Id. Had the job taken the eight weeks predicted by Coalfield, liquidated damages would have been $28, 000 on a $230, 000 contract.
  • 438
    • 74849101625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 81-82.
    • See id. at 81-82.
  • 439
    • 74849120425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 80
    • Id. at 80.
  • 440
    • 74849096004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 80-81 (The principle of section 2-609['s]... applicability here is straightforward.);
    • See id. at 80-81 ("The principle of section 2-609['s]... applicability here is straightforward.");
  • 441
    • 84868050769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U. C. C. § 2-609 (1977).
    • U. C. C. § 2-609 (1977).
  • 442
    • 74849122196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • C. L. Maddox, 51 F.3d at 78.
    • C. L. Maddox, 51 F.3d at 78.
  • 443
    • 74849113161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 79
    • See id. at 79.
  • 444
    • 74849132343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 445
    • 84886338965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 185-96 and accompanying text discussing the doctrine of indefiniteness
    • See supra notes 185-96 and accompanying text (discussing the doctrine of indefiniteness).
    • See supra


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.