메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 63, Issue 4, 2010, Pages 1003-1045

Breach is for suckers

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 78650845742     PISSN: 00422533     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (58)

References (189)
  • 1
    • 0001417422 scopus 로고
    • The path of the law, address at the dedication of the new hall at boston university school of law
    • Justice, Supreme Judicial Court of Mass., (Jan. 8, 1897), 462
    • Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr., Justice, Supreme Judicial Court of Mass., The Path of the Law, Address at the Dedication of the New Hall at Boston University School of Law (Jan. 8, 1897), in 10 HARV. L. REV. 457, 462 (1897)
    • (1897) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 457
    • Holmes Jr., O.W.1
  • 2
    • 78650826760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see infra notes 9-20 and accompanying text.
    • see infra notes 9-20 and accompanying text.
  • 3
    • 66749166121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moral judgment and moral heuristics in breach of contract
    • 405
    • Tess Wilkinson-Ryan & Jonathan Baron, Moral Judgment and Moral Heuristics in Breach of Contract, 6 J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD. 405, 405 (2009).
    • (2009) J. Empirical Legal Stud. , vol.6 , pp. 405
    • Wilkinson-Ryan, T.1    Baron, J.2
  • 4
    • 78650824250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 413, 417, 422
    • Id. at 413, 417, 422.
  • 5
    • 78650823454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., id. at 420-21
    • E.g., id. at 420-21 (finding in an empirical study of the moral implications of contractual breach that "[s]ubjects distinguished between cases in which the promisor breaches in order to avoid a loss of some kind and in cases in which the promisor has been given a better offer; they imposed higher damages on the latter and indicated that he should feel guiltier for the breach").
  • 6
    • 2442545138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The logic of reciprocity: Trust, collective action, and law
    • For a thorough overview of the role of reciprocity in legal decision-making, see
    • For a thorough overview of the role of reciprocity in legal decision-making, see Dan M. Kahan, The Logic of Reciprocity: Trust, Collective Action, and Law, 102 MICH. L. REV. 71 (2003).
    • (2003) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.102 , pp. 71
    • Kahan, D.M.1
  • 7
    • 78650833536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 73-74
    • Id. at 73-74.
  • 8
    • 78650812843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 27-40 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 27-40 and accompanying text.
  • 9
    • 78650831917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 27-30
    • See infra notes 27-30.
  • 10
    • 0041557629 scopus 로고
    • The reliance interest in contract damages
    • 54
    • Lon L. Fuller & William R. Perdue, The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages, 46 YALE L.J. 52, 54 (1936).
    • (1936) Yale L.J. , vol.46 , pp. 52
    • Fuller, L.L.1    Perdue, W.R.2
  • 11
    • 21844526836 scopus 로고
    • The fault lines in contract damages
    • The point is often expressed. See, e.g., 1228-29
    • The point is often expressed. See, e.g., George M. Cohen, The Fault Lines in Contract Damages, 80 VA. L. REV. 1225, 1228-29 (1994) (discussing reasons for undercompensatory expectation awards)
    • (1994) Va. L. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 1225
    • Cohen, G.M.1
  • 12
    • 0013379330 scopus 로고
    • Reassessing the economic efficiency of compensatory damages for breach of contract
    • 1444-45
    • Daniel A. Farber, Reassessing the Economic Efficiency of Compensatory Damages for Breach of Contract, 66 VA. L. REV. 1443, 1444-45 (1980) (asserting that "every prospective plaintiff is not fully compensated" and that "contracts are underenforced");
    • (1980) Va. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 1443
    • Farber, D.A.1
  • 13
    • 26644448912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The reliance interest and the world outside the law schools' doors
    • 251-53
    • Stewart Macaulay, The Reliance Interest and the World Outside the Law Schools' Doors, 1991 WIS. L. REV. 247, 251-53 (calling litigation an "expensive game of chance" and disparaging expectation as an "ideology," not a reality).
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1991 , pp. 247
    • Macaulay, S.1
  • 14
    • 34047248219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The missing interest: Restoration of the contractual equivalence
    • Other candidates occasionally vie to join the trinity. See, e.g., 62
    • Other candidates occasionally vie to join the trinity. See, e.g., Eyal Zamir, The Missing Interest: Restoration of the Contractual Equivalence, 93 VA. L. REV. 59, 62 (2007) (advocating for awards based on a restoration interest whereby "courts and legislatures strive to put the injured party in a position similar to the one she would have occupied had the parties made and performed a contract in which their obligations were adjusted to the actual performance by the breaching party, while maintaining the contractual equivalence in terms of the agreed value of performance, the chronological relation between their respective obligations, etc."). Richard Craswell, on the other hand, would reduce the trinity by refocusing on expectation alone.
    • (2007) Va. L. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 59
    • Zamir, E.1
  • 15
    • 0346302281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Against fuller and perdue
    • 109-11
    • See Richard Craswell, Against Fuller and Perdue, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 99, 109-11 (2000) (proposing that damages be understood as above expectation, approximating "true expectation" and below expectation).
    • (2000) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 99
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 16
    • 78650812279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zamir, supra note 11, at 66.
    • Zamir, supra note 11, at 66.
  • 17
    • 78650821425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 18
    • 78650835484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What to compensate? some surprisingly unappreciated reasons why the problem is so hard
    • See generally 1360-62
    • See generally Leo Katz, What to Compensate? Some Surprisingly Unappreciated Reasons Why the Problem Is So Hard, 40 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 1345, 1360-62 (2003) ('The expectation entitlement seems a good deal more ethereal than the entitlement not to be subjected to slander, or alienation of affections, or the intentional infliction of emotional distress.").
    • (2003) San Diego L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 1345
    • Katz, L.1
  • 19
    • 78650838719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fuller & Perdue, supra note 9, at 57
    • Fuller & Perdue, supra note 9, at 57.
  • 20
    • 78650814971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 21
    • 78650818530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 58 (concluding that though it may be assumed that the impulse to assuage disappointment is one shared by those who make and influence the law, this impulse can hardly be regarded as the key which solves the whole problem of the protection accorded by the law to the expectation interest)
    • See id. at 58 (concluding that "though it may be assumed that the impulse to assuage disappointment is one shared by those who make and influence the law, this impulse can hardly be regarded as the key which solves the whole problem of the protection accorded by the law to the expectation interest").
  • 22
    • 78650852295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 57-58
    • Id. at 57-58.
  • 23
    • 78650817749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 60-61
    • Id. at 60-61.
  • 24
    • 78650844664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Generally speaking, contract law was, until quite recently, a field marked by a lack of sustained empirical study
    • Generally speaking, contract law was, until quite recently, a field marked by a lack of sustained empirical study.
  • 25
    • 0347740316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The limits of behavioral decision theory in legal analysis: The case of liquidated damages
    • See 718
    • See Robert A. Hillman, The Limits of Behavioral Decision Theory in Legal Analysis: The Case of Liquidated Damages, 85 CORNELL L. REV. 717, 718 (2000) (explaining difficulties in importing behavioral theory into contract law theory)
    • (2000) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 717
    • Hillman, R.A.1
  • 26
    • 0036992581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical scholarship in contract law: Possibilities and pitfalls
    • 1036
    • Russell Korobkin, Empirical Scholarship in Contract Law: Possibilities and Pitfalls, 2002 U. ILL. L. REV. 1033, 1036 ("[A]lthough there is a very large body of empirical studies of contracting, there is extremely little empirical contract law scholarship being produced in the legal academy today.").
    • U. Ill. L. Rev. , vol.2002 , pp. 1033
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 27
    • 78650850505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The common-law history of non-economic damages in breach of contract actions versus willful breach of contract actions
    • 492-93
    • Mara Kent, The Common-Law History of Non-Economic Damages in Breach of Contract Actions Versus Willful Breach of Contract Actions, 11 TEX. WESLEYAN L. REV. 481, 492-93 (2005)
    • (2005) Tex. Wesleyan L. Rev. , vol.11 , pp. 481
    • Kent, M.1
  • 28
    • 0000626130 scopus 로고
    • The myth that promisees prefer supracompensatory remedies: An analysis of contracting for damage measures
    • 391
    • Alan Schwartz, The Myth that Promisees Prefer Supracompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100 YALE L.J. 369, 391 (1990).
    • (1990) Yale L.J. , vol.100 , pp. 369
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 29
    • 78650851207 scopus 로고
    • S.L.T. (Sh. Ct.) 49 (Scot.) (providing recovery for breach of contract by a wedding photographer that resulted in emotional injury to the plaintiff)
    • E.g., Diesen v. Samson, [1971] S.L.T. (Sh. Ct.) 49 (Scot.) (providing recovery for breach of contract by a wedding photographer that resulted in emotional injury to the plaintiff).
    • (1971) Diesen v. Samson
  • 31
    • 78650821705 scopus 로고
    • 55 S.E.2d 810, 813-14 N.C
    • Lamm v. Shingleton, 55 S.E.2d 810, 813-14 (N.C 1949) (holding that damages for mental anguish were appropriate where workmen were "on notice that a failure on their part to inter the body properly would probably produce mental suffering" on the part of plaintiff widow).
    • (1949) Lamm V. Shingleton
  • 32
    • 78650812022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent defenses of consideration: Commodification and collaboration
    • 15
    • Mark B. Wessman, Recent Defenses of Consideration: Commodification and Collaboration, 41 IND. L. REV. 9, 15 n.52 (2008).
    • (2008) Ind. L. Rev. , vol.41 , Issue.52 , pp. 9
    • Wessman, M.B.1
  • 33
    • 78650842337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good overview of such normative work, see Craswell, supra note 11, at 107-36
    • For a good overview of such normative work, see Craswell, supra note 11, at 107-36.
  • 34
    • 70349467005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Can law and economics be both practical and principled?
    • 340-45
    • See David A. Hoffman & Michael P. O'Shea, Can Law and Economics Be Both Practical and Principled?, 53 ALA. L. REV. 335, 340-45 (2002) (describing wealth maximization as the main principled norm for mainstream law and economics).
    • (2002) Ala. L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 335
    • Hoffman, D.A.1    O'Shea, M.P.2
  • 36
    • 0030532796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cadillac contracts and up-front payments: Efficient investment under expectation damages
    • See, e.g., 98
    • See, e.g., Aaron S. Edlin, Cadillac Contracts and Up-Front Payments: Efficient Investment Under Expectation Damages, 12 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 98, 98 (1996)
    • (1996) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.12 , pp. 98
    • Edlin, A.S.1
  • 37
    • 84925976807 scopus 로고
    • Efficient breach of contract: Circles in the sky
    • cf. 950-53
    • cf. Ian R. Macneil, Efficient Breach of Contract: Circles in the Sky, 68 VA. L. REV. 947, 950-53 (1982) (disputing efficiency of efficient breach).
    • (1982) Va. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 947
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 38
    • 22544435816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic analysis of contract law after three decades: Success or failure?
    • 832
    • Eric Posner, Economic Analysis of Contract Law After Three Decades: Success or Failure?, 112 YALE L.J. 829, 832 (2003). Of course, other interests have their adherents.
    • (2003) Yale L.J. , vol.112 , pp. 829
    • Posner, E.1
  • 39
    • 78650851478 scopus 로고
    • Restitution in the second restatement of contracts
    • See, e.g., 51
    • See, e.g., Joseph M. Perillo, Restitution in the Second Restatement of Contracts, 81 COLUM. L. REV. 37, 51 (1981) (advocating the approach taken by the Second Restatement on restitution)
    • (1981) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 37
    • Perillo, J.M.1
  • 40
    • 33646673572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specific performance versus damages for breach of contract: An economic analysis
    • 847-54
    • Steven Shavell, Specific Performance Versus Damages for Breach of Contract: An Economic Analysis, 84 TEX. L. REV. 831, 847-54 (2006) (arguing that an economic analysis supports specific performance as a remedy for breach of contracts to convey property)
    • (2006) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 831
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 41
    • 33846833905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The divergence of contract and promise
    • 714
    • Seana Shiffrin, The Divergence of Contract and Promise, 120 HARV. L. REV. 709, 714 (2007) (elaborating a general theory of the moral commitment to perform). The underlying moral bases for evaluating contract damages are a recurring subject of contention.
    • (2007) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.120 , pp. 709
    • Shiffrin, S.1
  • 42
    • 73049117279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The failure of economic interpretations of the law of contract damages
    • See, e.g., 851-59
    • See, e.g., Nathan B. Oman, The Failure of Economic Interpretations of the Law of Contract Damages, 64 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 829, 851-59 (2007).
    • (2007) Wash. & Lee L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 829
    • Oman, N.B.1
  • 43
    • 0043027985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why there is no law of relational contracts
    • See 812-13
    • See Melvin A. Eisenberg, Why There is No Law of Relational Contracts, 94 NW. U. L. REV. 805, 812-13 (2000) (describing the foundations of relational contract theory).
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 805
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1
  • 44
    • 78650807527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 817-18
    • See id. at 817-18 (explaining the definitional problem).
  • 46
    • 22444453012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational contract theory and the concept of exchange
    • 765
    • Paul J. Gudel, Relational Contract Theory and the Concept of Exchange, 46 BUFF. L. REV. 763, 765 (1998).
    • (1998) Buff. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 763
    • Gudel, P.J.1
  • 47
    • 0041525057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational contracts floating on a sea of custom? thoughts about the ideas of ian macneil and lisa bernstein
    • 775-84
    • Stewart Macaulay, Relational Contracts Floating on a Sea of Custom? Thoughts About the Ideas of Ian Macneil and Lisa Bernstein, 94 Nw. U. L. REV. 775, 775-84 (2000) (contending that the most realistic theory of the behavior of contracting parties consists of an admixture of the relational approach with cognizance that, in certain contexts, the tenets of that theory are empirically false).
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 775
    • Macaulay, S.1
  • 48
    • 78650812023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 782.
    • Id. at 782.
  • 49
    • 0003643930 scopus 로고
    • IAN R. MACNEIL, THE NEW SOCIAL CONTRACT 62 (1980) (criticizing enforcement of expectancy interest as inconsistent with relational expectations).
    • (1980) The New Social Contract , pp. 62
    • Macneil, I.R.1
  • 50
    • 0037550032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Macaulay, macneil, and the discovery of solidarity and power in contract law
    • 569.
    • Robert W. Gordon, Macaulay, Macneil, and the Discovery of Solidarity and Power in Contract Law, 1985 WIS. L. REV. 565, 569.
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1985 , pp. 565
    • Gordon, R.W.1
  • 51
    • 0001875669 scopus 로고
    • Non-contractual relations in business: A preliminary study
    • The early work on this problem is Stewart Macaulay's classic
    • The early work on this problem is Stewart Macaulay's classic, Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 AM. SOC. REV. 55 (1963).
    • (1963) Am. Soc. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 55
  • 52
    • 0345916159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exploring the battle of the forms in action
    • Later work includes Daniel Keating
    • Later work includes Daniel Keating, Exploring the Battle of the Forms in Action, 98 MICH. L. REV. 2678 (2000)
    • (2000) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 2678
  • 53
    • 0042237492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring sales law against sales practice: A reality check
    • Daniel Keating, Measuring Sales Law Against Sales Practice: A Reality Check, 17 J.L. & COM. 99 (1997)
    • (1997) J.L. & Com. , vol.17 , pp. 99
    • Keating, D.1
  • 54
    • 0042237540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A survey of contract practice and policy
    • Russell J. Weintraub, A Survey of Contract Practice and Policy, 1992 WIS. L. REV. 1. A different set of papers examines contract terms embedded in actual agreements.
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1992 , pp. 1
    • Weintraub, R.J.1
  • 55
    • 0345847770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standardization and innovation in corporate contracting (or the economics of boilerplate)
    • See, e.g.
    • See, e.g., Marcel Kahan & Michael Klausner, Standardization and Innovation in Corporate Contracting (Or "The Economics of Boilerplate"), 83 VA. L. REV. 713 (1997).
    • (1997) Va. L. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 713
    • Kahan, M.1    Klausner, M.2
  • 56
    • 77956144354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The real and the paper deal: Empirical pictures of relationships, complexity and the urge for transparent simple rules
    • See, e.g., 51 David Campbell et al. eds., ('Often, however, the paper deal will not reflect the real deal: a writing can be inconsistent with the actual expectations of the parties.)
    • See, e.g., Stewart Macaulay, The Real and the Paper Deal: Empirical Pictures of Relationships, Complexity and the Urge for Transparent Simple Rules, in IMPLICIT DIMENSIONS OF CONTRACT: DISCRETE, RELATIONAL AND NETWORK CONTRACTS 51, 51 (David Campbell et al. eds., 2003) ('Often, however, the paper deal will not reflect the real deal: a writing can be inconsistent with the actual expectations of the parties.").
    • (2003) Implicit Dimensions Of Contract: Discrete, Relational And Network Contracts , pp. 51
    • Macaulay, S.1
  • 57
    • 0345884686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The secret ambition of deterrence
    • Cf. 413-19 (arguing that deterrence-talk plays a similar role in criminal law)
    • Cf. Dan M. Kahan, The Secret Ambition of Deterrence, 113 HARV. L. REV. 413, 413-19 (1999) (arguing that deterrence-talk plays a similar role in criminal law).
    • (1999) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.113 , pp. 413
    • Kahan, D.M.1
  • 58
    • 78650835206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unlike Kahan's discussion of the idiom of criminal deterrence, it isn't as clear that public (as opposed to scholarly and judicial) discussions of breach revolve around prevention. Cf. id
    • Unlike Kahan's discussion of the idiom of criminal deterrence, it isn't as clear that public (as opposed to scholarly and judicial) discussions of breach revolve around prevention. Cf. id.
  • 59
    • 78650831365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To those professors who may think that this is a farfetched possibility, we would ask you to consider how different the atmosphere of the traditional contract class is on the day that unconscionability is discussed
    • To those professors who may think that this is a farfetched possibility, we would ask you to consider how different the atmosphere of the traditional contract class is on the day that unconscionability is discussed.
  • 60
    • 66749090300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When is a willful breach willful? the link between definitions and damage
    • 1506 (internal quotations omitted). Notably, Craswell does not adopt this position, but simply notes it as a possible solution to the existence of lay preferences about contracts. Id
    • Richard Craswell, When is a Willful Breach "Willful"? The Link Between Definitions and Damage, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1501, 1506 (2009) (internal quotations omitted). Notably, Craswell does not adopt this position, but simply notes it as a possible solution to the existence of lay preferences about contracts. Id.
    • (2009) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1501
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 61
    • 78650851206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Forgiving breach: Understanding the preference for damages over specific performance
    • See, e.g., Note, 541-45
    • See, e.g., Benjamin Taibleson, Note, Forgiving Breach: Understanding the Preference For Damages Over Specific Performance, 27 QUINNIPIAC L. REV. 541, 541-45 (2009) (examining the validity, bases, and usefulness of one such informed preference).
    • (2009) Quinnipiac L. Rev. , vol.27 , pp. 541
    • Taibleson, B.1
  • 62
    • 0348199163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contractarians, community, and the tort of interference with contract
    • See 1156-60
    • See William J. Woodward, Contractarians, Community, and the Tort of Interference with Contract, 80 MINN. L. REV. 1103, 1156-60 (1996) (describing "empirical vacuum" about the amount of damages that would make promisees indifferent to breach, and the resulting strength of the case for the tort of interference with contract).
    • (1996) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 1103
    • Woodward, W.J.1
  • 63
    • 78650826759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 147-158
    • See infra text accompanying notes 147-158.
  • 64
    • 84985275062 scopus 로고
    • Violating the psychological contract: Not the exception but the norm
    • See, e.g., 245, 249-52
    • See, e.g., Sandra L. Robinson & Denise M. Rousseau, Violating the Psychological Contract: Not the Exception but the Norm, 15 J. ORG. BEHAV. 245, 245, 249-52 (1994) (surveying employees about their understanding of employment contracts and their reactions to perceived breaches of their respective agreements)
    • (1994) J. Org. Behav. , vol.15 , pp. 245
    • Robinson, S.L.1    Rousseau, D.M.2
  • 65
    • 66749126951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is breach of contract immoral?
    • 439-42
    • Steven Shavell, Is Breach of Contract Immoral?, 56 EMORY L.J. 439, 439-42 (2006) (reporting the results of a survey study of moral judgments of breach)
    • (2006) Emory L.J. , vol.56 , pp. 439
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 66
    • 78650840287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 412-19
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 412-19 (using experimental manipulations of variables like breacher motivation, timing of breach, and relationship of promisor and promisee to evaluate responses to breach).
  • 67
    • 78650801291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 420-23
    • See Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 420-23 (finding that subjects' chosen damages awards for breach varied in response to framing effects).
  • 68
    • 78650813857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 414, 420-21
    • Id. at 414, 420-21.
  • 69
    • 78650811757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 417-19
    • Id. at 417-19.
  • 70
    • 78650840829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 419-20
    • Id. at 419-20.
  • 71
    • 78650834294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 72
    • 78650850235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 412-13, 417-20
    • Id. at 412-13, 417-20.
  • 73
    • 78650845952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 420
    • Id. at 420.
  • 74
    • 78650806596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 75
    • 78650813859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Holmes, supra note 1, at 462
    • See, e.g., Holmes, supra note 1, at 462 ("[T]he duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay damages if you do not keep it-and nothing else.").
  • 76
    • 78650830586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 418-19
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 418-19.
  • 77
    • 78650843989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 422
    • Id. at 422.
  • 78
    • 78650833776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 420-23
    • Id. at 420-23.
  • 79
    • 78650847810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 80
    • 78650818017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Daniel Markovits, Solidarity at Arm's Length 3 (Oct. 30, 2008) (unpublished manuscript), available at ('Promise-promise-making and promise-keeping-is a form of social solidarity, a way for persons to engage one another through their intentions.)
    • See Daniel Markovits, Solidarity at Arm's Length 3 (Oct. 30, 2008) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.law.upenn.edu/academics/ institutes/ilp/2008papers/ MarkovitsSolidarityatArmsLength.pdf ('Promise-promise-making and promise-keeping-is a form of social solidarity, a way for persons to engage one another through their intentions.").
  • 81
    • 78650834296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moral psychology of contracts
    • See (Omri Ben-Shahar & Ariel Porat eds.)
    • See Tess Wilkinson-Ryan, Moral Psychology of Contracts, in FAULT IN AMERICAN CONTRACT LAW (Omri Ben-Shahar & Ariel Porat eds.) (forthcoming Sept. 2010) (showing survey data in which respondents routinely reported that a judge would award specific performance and/or supracompensatory damages).
    • Fault In American Contract Law
    • Wilkinson-Ryan, T.1
  • 82
    • 78650829189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 405
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 405.
  • 83
    • 0031007861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard form contracts and contract schemas: A preliminary investigation of the effects of exculpatory clauses
    • 91-93
    • Dennis P. Stolle & Andrew J. Slain, Standard Form Contracts and Contract Schemas: A Preliminary Investigation of the Effects of Exculpatory Clauses, 15 BEHAV. SCI. & L. 83, 91-93 (1997).
    • (1997) Behav. Sci. & L. , vol.15 , pp. 83
    • Stolle, D.P.1    Slain, A.J.2
  • 84
    • 78650805516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MACNEIL, supra note 37, at 16-17 (discussing the obligations inherent in contractual relationships)
    • See MACNEIL, supra note 37, at 16-17 (discussing the obligations inherent in contractual relationships).
  • 85
    • 0032800597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trust, contract and economic cooperation
    • See 301304, 314-15
    • See Edward Lorenz, Trust, Contract and Economic Cooperation, 23 CAMBRIDGE J. ECON. 301, 301-304, 314-15 (1999) (finding evidence that trust enhances the social surplus in contracts).
    • (1999) Cambridge J. Econ. , vol.23 , pp. 301
    • Lorenz, E.1
  • 86
    • 0030305884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social cognition is thinking about relationships
    • See Oct. 1996, 143-48
    • See Alan P. Fiske & Nick Haslam, Social Cognition is Thinking About Relationships, CURRENT DIRECTIONS IN PSYCHOL. SCI., Oct. 1996, at 143, 143-48 (1996) (arguing that cognition about social interactions is strongly governed by the type of relationship a party believes to exist between herself and her co-party and that one's conception of the type of relationship one has with another will strongly influence the behavior towards that other).
    • (1996) Current Directions In Psychol. Sci. , pp. 143
    • Fiske, A.P.1    Haslam, N.2
  • 87
    • 78650806079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational contract theory
    • See Symposium
    • See Symposium, Relational Contract Theory, 94 Nw. L. REV. 735 (2000)
    • (2000) Nw. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 735
  • 88
    • 0043027986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational contract theory in context
    • 737-48
    • e.g., Jay M. Feinman, Relational Contract Theory in Context, 94 Nw. L. REV. 737, 737-48 (2000) (discussing the development of relational contract theory within the broader context of the evolution of modern contract law in general).
    • (2000) Nw. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 737
    • Feinman, J.M.1
  • 89
    • 78650816339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Markovits, supra note 62, at 3
    • See Markovits, supra note 62, at 3 (arguing that breach of contract represents an alienation of human solidarity).
  • 90
    • 0026937953 scopus 로고
    • The four elementary forms of sociality: Framework for a unified theory of social relations
    • 706-08
    • Alan P. Fiske, The Four Elementary Forms of Sociality: Framework For a Unified Theory of Social Relations, 99 PSYCHOL. REV. 689, 706-08 (1992) (making distinctions between relationships based on market transactions as opposed to communal forms of exchange, among others).
    • (1992) Psychol. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 689
    • Fiske, A.P.1
  • 91
    • 0001443561 scopus 로고
    • Motivation losses in small groups: A social dilemma analysis
    • 821-23
    • See N.L. Kerr, Motivation Losses in Small Groups: A Social Dilemma Analysis, 45 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 819, 821-23 (1983) (using small-group projects to study the effects of shirking by one participant on the effort levels of other participants).
    • (1983) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.45 , pp. 819
    • Kerr, N.L.1
  • 92
    • 0037049973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Altruistic punishment in humans
    • 137
    • Ernst Fehr & Simon Gachter, Altruistic Punishment in Humans, 415 NATURE 137, 137 (2002).
    • (2002) Nature , vol.415 , pp. 137
    • Fehr, E.1    Gachter, S.2
  • 93
    • 78650842627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A schema is a mental representation of a concept
    • A schema is a mental representation of a concept.
  • 94
    • 34548814757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Feeling duped: Emotional, motivational, and cognitive aspects of being exploited by others
    • 128-39
    • Kathleen D. Vohs et al., Feeling Duped: Emotional, Motivational, and Cognitive Aspects of Being Exploited by Others, 11 REV. GEN. PSYCHOL. 127, 128-39 (2007).
    • (2007) Rev. Gen. Psychol. , vol.11 , pp. 127
    • Vohs, K.D.1
  • 95
    • 78650828343 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 128
    • Id. at 128.
  • 96
    • 26644474098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moral heuristics
    • See 537-38
    • See Cass Sunstein, Moral Heuristics, 28 BEHAV. & BRAIN SCI. 531, 537-38 (2005) (discussing betrayal of trust as being perceived as an independent harm).
    • (2005) Behav. & Brain Sci. , vol.28 , pp. 531
    • Sunstein, C.1
  • 97
    • 23744457896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • False friends are worse than bitter enemies: Altruistic punishment of in-group members
    • 388-91
    • Mizuho Shinada et al., False Friends are Worse than Bitter Enemies: "Altruistic" Punishment of In-Group Members, 25 EVOL. & HUM. BEHAV. 379, 388-91 (2004).
    • (2004) Evol. & Hum. Behav. , vol.25 , pp. 379
    • Shinada, M.1
  • 99
    • 78650848672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The game was as follows: Players had to decide between two options, either accept a guaranteed medium reward or take a gamble that would yield either a high or a low payoff. The first player, the decisionmaker, was told to decide on a minimum acceptable probability of receiving the high payoff, such that he would prefer the gamble to the sure thing. Experimenters chose a random number from 1 to 100; that was the probability of high payoff for a given round. If the decisionmaker had chosen a higher threshold, he got the sure thing; if he had chosen a lower threshold, he got to play the gamble. This game included a second player, the recipient. If the decisionmaker got the sure thing, the recipient would receive an identical payoff. If the decisionmaker played the gamble, the recipient received more money when the decisionmaker got the low payoff and less when the decisionmaker got the high payoff. In the control condition, the recipient was passive. In the trust condition, the outcome of the gamble was determined by the recipients; the probability of success in the gamble was established by the proportion of recipients in a round who indicated that they would choose the high payoff for the decisionmaker. The average minimum probability of high payoff required by decisionmakers in the control condition was 30 percent; in the trust condition it was 50 percent. The researchers suggested that the difference was a kind of betrayal discount.
  • 100
    • 78650821704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 472-80
    • Id. at 472-80.
  • 101
    • 0000744908 scopus 로고
    • Fairness as a constraint on profit-seeking: Entitlements in the market
    • 731-32
    • Daniel Kahneman et al., Fairness as a Constraint on Profit-Seeking: Entitlements in the Market, 76 AM. ECON. REV. 728, 731-32 (1986).
    • (1986) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 728
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 102
    • 78650849981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 103
    • 78650807133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 104
    • 78650815796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 739-40
    • Id. at 739-40.
  • 105
    • 0001291721 scopus 로고
    • FaIrness and the assumptions of economics
    • S288-89
    • Daniel Kahneman et al., Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics, 59 J. BUS. S285, S288-89 (1986).
    • (1986) J. Bus. , vol.59
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 106
    • 78650817748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 107
    • 78650852002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 108
    • 0001578263 scopus 로고
    • PreFerences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games
    • 367-68
    • Elizabeth Hoffman et al., Preferences, Property Rights, and Anonymity in Bargaining Games, 7 GAMES & ECON. BEHAV. 346, 367-68 (1994).
    • (1994) Games & Econ. Behav. , vol.7 , pp. 346
    • Hoffman, E.1
  • 109
    • 78650848936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 362.
    • Id. at 362.
  • 110
    • 0037259179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the nature of fair behavior
    • Armin Falk et al., On the Nature of Fair Behavior, 41 ECON. INQUIRY 20 (2003).
    • (2003) Econ. Inquiry , vol.41 , pp. 20
    • Falk, A.1
  • 111
    • 78650805241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 405
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 405.
  • 112
    • 84935322680 scopus 로고
    • Prices and sanctions
    • E.g., 1544
    • E.g., Robert Cooter, Prices and Sanctions, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1523, 1544 (1985) ("If the promisor breaches and pays perfect expectation damages and nothing more, then the promisee will get none of the surplus and the promisor will get all of it.").
    • (1985) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1523
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 114
    • 0000249677 scopus 로고
    • When social outcomes aren't fair: The effect of causal attributions on preferences
    • 134
    • Sally Blount, When Social Outcomes Aren't Fair: The Effect of Causal Attributions on Preferences, 63 ORG. BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 131, 134 (1995).
    • (1995) Org. Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes , vol.63 , pp. 131
    • Blount, S.1
  • 115
    • 78650840830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 116
    • 78650849472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 135, 136 fig.1.
    • Id. at 135, 136 fig.1.
  • 117
    • 78650812278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 118
    • 78650839235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kerr, supra note 72, at 825.
    • Kerr, supra note 72, at 825.
  • 119
    • 78650813357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 417-20.
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 417-20.
  • 120
    • 78650829188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subjects in all experiments in this Article were members of a panel recruited over a tenyear period, mostly through their own efforts at searching for ways to earn money by completing questionnaires. Approximately 90 percent of subjects were U.S. residents (with the rest mostly from Canada). The panel is roughly representative of the adult U.S. population in terms of income, age, and education, but not in terms of sex, because (for unknown reasons) women predominate in this respondent pool.
    • Subjects in all experiments in this Article were members of a panel recruited over a tenyear period, mostly through their own efforts at searching for ways to earn money by completing questionnaires. Approximately 90 percent of subjects were U.S. residents (with the rest mostly from Canada). The panel is roughly representative of the adult U.S. population in terms of income, age, and education, but not in terms of sex, because (for unknown reasons) women predominate in this respondent pool.
  • 121
    • 78650829476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For each study, an email was sent to about five hundred members of the panel, saying how much the study paid and where to find it on the World Wide Web. Each study was a series of separate web pages, programmed in JavaScript. The first page provided brief instructions. Each of the others presented a case, until the last, which asked for (optional) comments and sometimes contained additional questions. Each case had a space for optional comments. Otherwise, the subjects had to answer all questions to proceed. The study was removed when about one hundred responses had been submitted in each case. In Experiment One, eighty-three subjects were paid $1.50 to complete a five-minute study. 73.4 percent of subjects were female. Subjects ranged in age from twenty-three to sixty-five, with a median age of forty-three.
  • 122
    • 78650808078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The t-statistic was 3.465 with 77.42 degrees of freedom, p < 0.001.
    • The t-statistic was 3.465 with 77.42 degrees of freedom, p < 0.001.
  • 123
    • 78650818801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The t-statistic was 1.899 with 70.26 degrees of freedom, p = 0.062.
    • The t-statistic was 1.899 with 70.26 degrees of freedom, p = 0.062.
  • 124
    • 78650818529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We also wanted to know how each variable affected the damages responses. We regressed the damages question each of the eight variables, including a variable for subject fixed effects. Of the eight variables, the only reliable predictor of damages, holding all other variables constant, was the Sucker variable (coefficient = 188.49, t = 1.959, p = 0.054). This regression is not reported for Experiments Two and Three.
  • 125
    • 78650816063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Subjects were paid $2 to complete a five-minute questionnaire about contracts cases. 100 subjects participated in Experiment Two, thirty-four of whom were male. Ages ranged from twenty-one to seventy with a median age of forty.
  • 126
    • 78650821990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The t-statistic was 3.865, with 96.83 degrees of freedom, p < 0.001.
    • The t-statistic was 3.865, with 96.83 degrees of freedom, p < 0.001.
  • 127
    • 78650829763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The mean response to the Angry variable was 6.06 in the Loss case and 7.31 in the Gain case. The t-statistic was 2.607 with 94.66 degrees of freedom, p = 0.011. The mean response to the Embarrass variable was 4.80 in the Loss condition and 5.73 in the Gain condition. The tstatistic was 2.051 with 97.48 degrees of freedom, p = 0.043. 107. Subjects were paid $6 to complete a thirty-minute questionnaire about contracts cases. 199 subjects participated in Experiment Three, 26.1 percent of whom were male. Ages ranged from twenty-four to seventy-five with a median age of forty-five. (Some items on that questionnaire are not reported here, and were used as pilot data for other research).
  • 128
    • 78650847084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • t = 2.632, df = 198, p = 0.0092. Note that this study used an entirely within-subjects design, so we are comparing a given subject's responses to the two conditions.
    • t = 2.632, df = 198, p = 0.0092. Note that this study used an entirely within-subjects design, so we are comparing a given subject's responses to the two conditions.
  • 129
    • 78650830037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • t = 1.774, df= 196.60, p = 0.078.
    • t = 1.774, df= 196.60, p = 0.078.
  • 130
    • 78650850504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interestingly, in both conditions, the amount demanded was greater than the expectation award. However, we used only a single set of cases, so it is unclear if subjects found both accidental and unintentional breach objectionable, or if they objected to something particular about the facts of the plumbing contract in question.
    • Interestingly, in both conditions, the amount demanded was greater than the expectation award. However, we used only a single set of cases, so it is unclear if subjects found both accidental and unintentional breach objectionable, or if they objected to something particular about the facts of the plumbing contract in question.
  • 131
    • 78650803177 scopus 로고
    • (Mark DeWolfe Howe ed., Harvard University Press 1963)
    • OLIVER WENDELL HOLMES, JR., THE COMMON LAW 7 (Mark DeWolfe Howe ed., Harvard University Press 1963) (1881).
    • (1881) The Common Law , pp. 7
    • Holmes Jr., O.W.1
  • 132
    • 17544376308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The situational character: A critical realist perspective on the human animal
    • See generally 63-65 (explaining attribution theory in legal settings).
    • See generally Jon Hanson & David Yosifon, The Situational Character: A Critical Realist Perspective on the Human Animal, 93 GEO. L.J. 1, 63-65 (2004) (explaining attribution theory in legal settings).
    • (2004) Geo. L.J. , vol.93 , pp. 1
    • Hanson, J.1    Yosifon, D.2
  • 133
    • 0347020596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do parties to nuisance cases bargain after judgment? a glimpse inside the cathedral
    • For an interesting case-study approach that analyzed the rarity of post-decision bargaining, see
    • For an interesting case-study approach that analyzed the rarity of post-decision bargaining, see Ward Farns worth, Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain After Judgment? A Glimpse Inside the Cathedral, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 373 (1999).
    • (1999) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 373
    • Worth, W.F.1
  • 134
    • 0032391326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shared outrage and erratic awards: The psychology of punitive damages
    • See, e.g., 51-53
    • See, e.g., Daniel Kahneman et al., Shared Outrage and Erratic Awards: The Psychology of Punitive Damages, 16 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 49, 51-53 (1998) (summarizing a theoretical model in which outrage is a driving factor in punitive impulses).
    • (1998) J. Risk & Uncertainty , vol.16 , pp. 49
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 135
    • 78650832162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vohs et al., supra note 75, at 134
    • See Vohs et al., supra note 75, at 134 (describing anger and a possibility of retaliatory attack as likely responses to being duped).
  • 136
    • 78650829762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kahan, supra note 5, at 71
    • See Kahan, supra note 5, at 71 ("When . . . [people] perceive that others are shirking or otherwise taking advantage of them, individuals are moved by resentment and pride to withhold their own cooperation and even to engage in personally costly forms of retaliation.")
  • 137
    • 78650832415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fehr & Gachter, supra note 73, at 137-39.
    • See Fehr & Gachter, supra note 73, at 137-39.
  • 138
    • 78650828583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 76-80.
    • See supra text accompanying notes 76-80.
  • 139
    • 78650840286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vohs et al., supra note 75, at 134
    • Vohs et al., supra note 75, at 134 (describing anger and frustration with the self as well as shame and guilt as among the prime aversive emotions likely evoked by feeling duped).
  • 140
    • 78650838242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 134-36.
    • Id. at 134-36.
  • 142
    • 18944385479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law and economics of contract interpretation
    • See, e.g., 1583-84
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Posner, The Law and Economics of Contract Interpretation, 83 TEX. L. REV. 1581, 1583-84 (2005) (describing the costs incurred at the time of drafting a contract).
    • (2005) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 1581
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 143
    • 84977378511 scopus 로고
    • Does monitoring increase work effort? the rivalry with trust and loyalty
    • 665
    • Bruno S. Frey, Does Monitoring Increase Work Effort? The Rivalry with Trust and Loyalty, 31 ECON. INQUIRY 663, 665 (1993).
    • (1993) Econ. Inquiry , vol.31 , pp. 663
    • Frey, B.S.1
  • 144
    • 78650842084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahan, supra note 5, at 72.
    • Kahan, supra note 5, at 72.
  • 145
    • 0347036725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond exit and voice: User participation in the production of local public goods
    • 26-29
    • Lee Anne Fennell, Beyond Exit and Voice: User Participation in the Production of Local Public Goods, 80 TEX. L. REV. 1, 26-29 (2001)
    • (2001) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 1
    • Fennell, L.A.1
  • 146
    • 84874420935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fear and greed in tax policy: A qualitative research agenda
    • 99-100
    • Christopher C. Fennel & Lee Anne Fennell, Fear and Greed in Tax Policy: A Qualitative Research Agenda, 13 WASH. U. J.L. & POL'Y 75, 99-100 (2006).
    • (2006) Wash. U. J.L. & Pol'y , vol.13 , pp. 75
    • Fennel, C.C.1    Fennell, L.A.2
  • 147
    • 74849096289 scopus 로고
    • A consent theory of contract
    • See, e.g., 317
    • See, e.g., Randy E. Barnett, A Consent Theory of Contract, 86 COLUM. L. REV. 269, 317 (1986) (criticizing court's refusal to enforce liquidated damages clauses on consent grounds).
    • (1986) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 269
    • Barnett, R.E.1
  • 148
    • 78650846234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shiffrin, supra note 30, at 734-35
    • See Shiffrin, supra note 30, at 734-35 (explaining and critiquing this argument).
  • 149
    • 77949991240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do liquidated damages encourage efficient breach? a psychological experiment
    • See forthcoming Mar. available at (manuscript at 11-15) (summarizing and commenting upon various efficiency and rationality analyses of liquidated damages clauses specifically with respect to the concept of efficient breach).
    • See Tess Wilkinson-Ryan, Do Liquidated Damages Encourage Efficient Breach? A Psychological Experiment, 108 MICH. L. REV. (forthcoming Mar. 2010), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/so13/papers.cfm?abstract-id-1299817 (manuscript at 11-15) (summarizing and commenting upon various efficiency and rationality analyses of liquidated damages clauses specifically with respect to the concept of efficient breach).
    • (2010) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.108
    • Wilkinson-Ryan, T.1
  • 150
    • 78650849471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 151
    • 78650846517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 33.
    • Id. at 33.
  • 152
    • 78650811758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 31-32.
    • Id. at 31-32.
  • 153
    • 78650839234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 34-38.
    • Id. at 34-38.
  • 154
    • 78650826758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 38.
    • Id. at 38.
  • 155
    • 78650802097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This analysis depends, of course, on subsequent work on the relationship between liquidated damage clauses and pre- and post-breach behavior.
    • This analysis depends, of course, on subsequent work on the relationship between liquidated damage clauses and pre- and post-breach behavior.
  • 156
    • 1542627833 scopus 로고
    • Reliance in the revised restatement: The proliferation of promissory estoppel
    • See, e.g., 53
    • See, e.g., Charles L. Knapp, Reliance in the Revised Restatement: The Proliferation of Promissory Estoppel, 81 COLUM. L. REV. 52, 53 (1981) ("[PE] has become perhaps the most radical and expansive development of this century in the law of promissory liability.")
    • (1981) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 52
    • Knapp, C.L.1
  • 157
    • 78650812842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Promissory estoppel: The life history of an ideal legal transplant
    • cf.
    • cf. Joel M. Ngugi, Promissory Estoppel: The Life History of an Ideal Legal Transplant, 41 U. RICH. L. REV. 425 (2007) (providing an intellectual history of the doctrine).
    • (2007) U. Rich. L. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 425
    • Ngugi, J.M.1
  • 158
    • 0346935093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Questioning the new consensus on promissory estoppel: An empirical and theoretical study
    • 588-96
    • Robert A. Hillman, Questioning the "New Consensus" on Promissory Estoppel: An Empirical and Theoretical Study, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 580, 588-96 (1998) (empirically demonstrating the low win rate on PE claims).
    • (1998) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 580
    • Hillman, R.A.1
  • 159
    • 77951967628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise and fall of promissory estoppel or is promissory estoppel really as unsuccessful as scholars say it is: A new look at the data
    • See, e.g., 543-85
    • See, e.g., Juliet P. Kostritsky, The Rise and Fall of Promissory Estoppel or is Promissory Estoppel Really as Unsuccessful as Scholars Say It Is: A New Look at the Data, 37 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 531, 543-85 (2002) (examining different data and finding a higher win rate).
    • (2002) Wake Forest L. Rev. , vol.37 , pp. 531
    • Kostritsky, J.P.1
  • 160
    • 78650831916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Placid, clear-seeming words: Some realism about the new formalism (with particular reference to promissory estoppel)
    • Cf. 44
    • Cf. Sidney W. DeLong, Placid, Clear-Seeming Words: Some Realism About the New Formalism (With Particular Reference to Promissory Estoppel), 38 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 13, 44 (2001) (arguing that, in evaluating reliance, "courts employ implicit normative standards in the guise of purely causal reasoning").
    • (2001) San Diego L. Rev. , vol.38 , pp. 13
    • DeLong, S.W.1
  • 161
    • 78650819843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Studies relying on opinions to determine success rates of claims are subject to wellknown selection biases.
    • Studies relying on opinions to determine success rates of claims are subject to wellknown selection biases.
  • 162
    • 78650805786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Disputing limited liability
    • See forthcoming available at
    • See Christina L. Boyd & David A. Hoffman, Disputing Limited Liability, 104 NW. U. L. REV.- (forthcoming 2010), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm? abstract-id=1483278.
    • (2010) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.104
    • Boyd, C.L.1    Hoffman, D.A.2
  • 164
    • 78650843710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The late 1970s to early 1980s were marked by boundary insecurity between other first year courses.
    • The late 1970s to early 1980s were marked by boundary insecurity between other first year courses.
  • 165
    • 0005034284 scopus 로고
    • The disintegration of property
    • See 71-72 J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds.
    • See Thomas Grey, The Disintegration of Property, in NOMOS XXII: PROPERTY 69, 71-72 (J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds., 1980) (listing different usages of the term "property," including by law students and law professors, and concluding that "discourse about property has fragmented into a set of discontinuous usages").
    • (1980) Nomos Xxii: Property , pp. 69
    • Grey, T.1
  • 166
    • 84928217792 scopus 로고
    • Beyond promissory estoppel: Contract law and the invisible handshake
    • For some, that's the point. See 906
    • For some, that's the point. See Daniel A. Farber & John H. Matheson, Beyond Promissory Estoppel: Contract Law and the "Invisible Handshake," 52 U. CHI. L. REV. 903, 906 (1985).
    • (1985) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 903
    • Farber, D.A.1    Matheson, J.H.2
  • 168
    • 78650820864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Hillman, supra note 135, at 601-02
    • Cf. Hillman, supra note 135, at 601-02 (finding reliance to be a common measure of damages).
  • 169
    • 78650818283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Promissory estoppel and the protection of interpersonal trust
    • Cf. 50-51
    • Cf. John J. Chung, Promissory Estoppel and the Protection of Interpersonal Trust, 56 CLEV. ST. L. REV. 37, 50-51 (2008) (discussing the differences between trust and reliance).
    • (2008) Clev. St. L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 37
    • Chung, J.J.1
  • 170
    • 0345847176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new requirement of enforcement reliance in commercial promissory estoppel: Section 90 as catch-22
    • See 959
    • See Sidney W. DeLong, The New Requirement of Enforcement Reliance in Commercial Promissory Estoppel: Section 90 as Catch-22, 1997 WIS. L. REV. 943, 959 (noting that some courts suggest that promisees must demonstrate that they believed a promise legally enforceable in order to obtain relief under section 90).
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1997 , pp. 943
    • DeLong, S.W.1
  • 171
    • 66749142872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foreword: Fault in american contract law
    • See 1342-43
    • See Omri Ben-Shahar & Ariel Porat, Foreword: Fault in American Contract Law, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1341, 1342-43 (2009) (summarizing participants' accounts).
    • (2009) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1341
    • Ben-Shahar, O.1    Porat, A.2
  • 172
    • 66749109789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An information theory of willful breach
    • See generally
    • See generally Oren Bar-Gill & Omri Ben-Shahar, An Information Theory of Willful Breach, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1479 (2009)
    • (2009) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1479
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Ben-Shahar, O.2
  • 173
    • 78650805787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Craswell, supra note 44
    • Craswell, supra note 44;
  • 174
    • 66749169948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Willfulness versus expectation: A promisor-based defense of willful breach doctrine
    • Steve Thel & Peter Siegelman, Willfulness Versus Expectation: A Promisor-Based Defense of Willful Breach Doctrine, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1517(2009).
    • (2009) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1517
    • Thel, S.1    Siegelman, P.2
  • 175
    • 78650817490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Bar-Gill & Ben-Shahar, supra note 147, at 1494
    • E.g., Bar-Gill & Ben-Shahar, supra note 147, at 1494 (arguing that, where the likelihood of breach detection is lower, supracompensatory damages may be the only way to prevent inefficient breach).
  • 176
    • 78650802617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 129 N.E. 889 (N.Y. 1921)
    • 129 N.E. 889 (N.Y. 1921).
  • 177
    • 78650813579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 382 P.2d 109 (Okla. 1962)
    • 382 P.2d 109 (Okla. 1962).
  • 178
    • 78650845167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 129 N.E. at 890
    • 129 N.E. at 890.
  • 179
    • 78650836879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 891
    • Id. at 891.
  • 180
    • 78650845702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 382P.2dat 111
    • 382P.2dat 111.
  • 181
    • 78650813858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 113
    • Id. at 113.
  • 182
    • 78650838968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Craswell, supra note 44, at 1502-04. In Jacobs & Young, the contractor could have invested more care in preventing the accidental breach, and could have freely decided to remediate the harm without the plaintiff seeking legal intervention, while in Peevyhouse, the mining company refused to make the promised repairs because it decided they would cost too much
    • See Craswell, supra note 44, at 1502-04. In Jacobs & Young, the contractor could have invested more care in preventing the " accidental" breach, and could have freely decided to remediate the harm without the plaintiff seeking legal intervention, while in Peevyhouse, the mining company refused to make the promised repairs because it decided they would cost too much.
  • 183
    • 78650833535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thel & Siegelman, supra note 147, at 1527
    • Thel & Siegelman, supra note 147, at 1527.
  • 184
    • 78650813101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Craswell, supra note 44, at 1506
    • Craswell, supra note 44, at 1506.
  • 185
    • 78650845456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shiffrin, supra note 30, at 740-49
    • See Shiffrin, supra note 30, at 740-49.
  • 186
    • 78650820600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 405
    • Wilkinson-Ryan & Baron, supra note 2, at 405.
  • 187
    • 78650808358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Macaulay, supra note 35, at 778
    • See Macaulay, supra note 35, at 778 ("In a [long-term] relational contract, often it is hard to say when the contract is formed. Moreover, it is not likely to be formed once and for all. Rather than a scene frozen in a still photograph, a relational contract is more like an ongoing motion picture.").
  • 188
    • 78650840545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vohs et al., supra note 75, at 132
    • See Vohs et al., supra note 75, at 132 ("[P]eople are reluctant to admit having been duped (because they blame themselves). . . .").
  • 189
    • 78650837686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 127
    • Id. at 127.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.