메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 64, Issue 4, 2012, Pages 797-850

The tragedy of the carrots: Economics and politics in the choice of price instruments

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84861462930     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (30)

References (464)
  • 1
    • 84861465563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Malachi 3:8-9.
    • , vol.3 , pp. 8-9
  • 2
    • 84861472802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Malachi 3:10-12.
    • , vol.3 , pp. 10-12
  • 3
    • 84861462726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. § 170 (2006).
    • (2006)
  • 4
    • 84861470175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This proposal passed the U.S. House of Representatives. American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009, H.R. 2454, 111th Cong. (2009).
    • (2009)
  • 6
    • 84861471807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an overview of the many provisions.
  • 7
    • 84861476114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see STAFF OF J. COMM. ON TAXATION, 111TH CONG., TAX EXPENDITURES FOR ENERGY PRODUCTION AND CONSERVATION 21-107 (Comm. Print 2009), available at http://finance.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/042309jctdoc1.pdf.
    • (2009) , pp. 21-107
  • 10
    • 43049159538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Payments for Environmental Services in Theory and Practice: An Overview of the Issues
    • Stefanie Engel et al., Designing Payments for Environmental Services in Theory and Practice: An Overview of the Issues, 65 ECOLOGICAL ECON. 663, 663-74 (2008).
    • (2008) ECOLOGICAL ECON , vol.65 , pp. 663-674
    • Engel, S.1
  • 11
    • 0037549078 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Trade Measures to Protect the Global Environment
    • note
    • see also Howard F. Chang, An Economic Analysis of Trade Measures to Protect the Global Environment, 83 GEO. L.J. 2131, 2149-64 (1995) (comparing subsidies and penalties as tools for encouraging international climate agreements).
    • (1995) GEO. L.J , vol.83 , pp. 2149-2164
    • Chang, H.F.1
  • 12
    • 0042715443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context
    • note
    • Jonathan Baert Wiener, Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context, 108 YALE L.J. 677, 701-96 (1999) (examining subsidies together with other policy options for containing global warming). For the most part that literature is descriptive.
    • (1999) YALE L.J , vol.108 , pp. 701-796
    • Jonathan, B.W.1
  • 13
    • 84861475759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Engel et al., supra, at 664, although Chang, Sterner, and Weiner ask explicitly whether subsidies are ever normatively preferable to penalties.
  • 14
    • 84861473588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Other writers have also investigated the relative cost-effectiveness of taxes and subsidies. An early economics literature examined the so-called "output" effect, which is one of the several factors I examine here.
  • 16
    • 84861474036 scopus 로고
    • When Subsidies for Pollution
    • note
    • Robert E. Kohn, When Subsidies for Pollution 1975 Abatement Increase Total Emissions, 59 S. ECON. J. 77 (1992).
    • (1975) Abatement Increase Total Emissions , vol.59 , pp. 77
    • Kohn, R.E.1
  • 17
    • 0020335981 scopus 로고
    • Production Externalities and Corrective Subsidies: A General Equilibrium Analysis
    • Stuart Mestelman, Production Externalities and Corrective Subsidies: A General Equilibrium Analysis, 9 J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT. 186 (1982).
    • (1982) J. ENVTL. ECON. & MGMT , vol.9 , pp. 186
    • Mestelman, S.1
  • 18
    • 0000702613 scopus 로고
    • Notes on the Symmetry of Taxes and Subsidies in Pollution Control
    • note
    • Mitchell Polinsky, Notes on the Symmetry of Taxes and Subsidies in Pollution Control, 12 CAN. J. ECON. 75 (1979). Others consider the transaction costs of the two systems.
    • (1979) CAN. J. ECON , vol.75
    • Polinsky, M.1
  • 19
    • 0347047560 scopus 로고
    • Liability for Harm or Restitution for Benefit
    • note
    • See, e.g., Donald Wittman, Liability for Harm or Restitution for Benefit?, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 57, 62-65 (1984).
    • (1984) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.13 , pp. 62-65
    • Wittman, D.1
  • 20
    • 84861464759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Gerrit De Geest & Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci, Carrots Versus Sticks 8-31 (Wash. Univ. in St. Louis Sch. of Law Legal Studies Research Paper Series, Paper No. 09-09-03, Aug. 2009) [hereinafter De Geest & Dari-Mattiacci, Carrots Versus Sticks], available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1470129.
    • Carrots Versus Sticks , pp. 8-31
    • De Gerrit, G.1    Dari-Mattiacci, G.2
  • 21
    • 77953825919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrots, Sticks, and the Multiplication Effect
    • note
    • The most recent evolution of that project is Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Gerrit De Geest, Carrots, Sticks, and the Multiplication Effect, 26 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 365 (2009) [hereinafter Dari-Mattiacci & De Geest, Multiplication Effect], which argues that the relative price-efficacy of sticks is a reason to prefer them to carrots, and that theirs is the first sustained attempt to distinguish normatively between the two instruments.
    • (2009) J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.26 , pp. 365
    • Dari-Mattiacci, G.1    De Gerrit, G.2
  • 22
    • 84861472613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrots, Sticks, and the Multiplication Effect
    • note
    • The most recent evolution of that project is Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Gerrit De Geest, Carrots, Sticks, and the Multiplication Effect, 26 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 365 (2009) [hereinafter Dari-Mattiacci & De Geest, Multiplication Effect], which argues that the relative price-efficacy of sticks is a reason to prefer them to carrots, and that theirs is the first sustained attempt to distinguish normatively between the two instruments. at 367-68.
    • (2009) J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.26 , pp. 367-368
    • Dari-Mattiacci, G.1    De Gerrit, G.2
  • 23
    • 84861471320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I agree on both fronts, but there are a number of other relevant factors in the debate, some of which may point in the opposite direction.
  • 24
    • 50249085077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Meaningful U.S. Cap-and-Trade System to Address Climate Change
    • note
    • Compare Robert N. Stavins, A Meaningful U.S. Cap-and-Trade System to Address Climate Change, 32 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 293, 348-53 (2008) (quantity).
    • (2008) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.32 , pp. 348-353
    • Compare, R.N.S.1
  • 25
    • 48549094521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To Tax or Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming
    • note
    • William D. Nordhaus, To Tax or Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming, 1 REV. ENVTL. ECON. & POL'Y 26 (2007) (price).
    • (2007) REV. ENVTL. ECON. & POL'Y , pp. 26
    • William, D.N.1
  • 26
    • 0000121214 scopus 로고
    • Effluent Charges and Licenses Under Uncertainty
    • note
    • Marc J. Roberts & Michael Spence, Effluent Charges and Licenses Under Uncertainty, 5 J. PUB. ECON. 193 (1976) (price).
    • (1976) J. PUB. ECON , vol.5 , pp. 193
    • Marc, J.R.1    Michael, S.2
  • 27
    • 84959805745 scopus 로고
    • Prices vs. Quantities
    • note
    • Martin L. Weitzman, Prices vs. Quantities, 41 REV. ECON. STUD. 477 (1974) (price).
    • (1974) REV. ECON. STUD , vol.41 , pp. 477
    • Martin, L.W.1
  • 28
    • 84861475620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Tax Expenditures and Fiscal Language
    • note
    • Compare Daniel N. Shaviro, Rethinking Tax Expenditures and Fiscal Language, 57 TAX L. REV. 187, 192-99, 206-21 (2004). (suggesting some merits to use of the tax system for policy implementation)
    • TAX L. REV , vol.57 , pp. 192-199
    • Compare, D.N.S.1
  • 29
    • 84861467886 scopus 로고
    • James Madison and Public Choice at Gucci Gulch: A Procedural Defense of Tax Expenditures and Tax Institutions
    • note
    • Edward A. Zelinsky, James Madison and Public Choice at Gucci Gulch: A Procedural Defense of Tax Expenditures and Tax Institutions, 102 YALE L.J. 1165, 1175-84 (1993) (same).
    • (1993) YALE L.J , vol.102 , pp. 1175-1184
    • Edward, A.Z.1
  • 30
    • 84858854680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Can Tax Expenditure Analysis Be Divorced from a Normative Tax Base?: A Critique of the "New Paradigm" and Its Denouement
    • note
    • J. Clifton Fleming, Jr. & Robert D. Peroni, Can Tax Expenditure Analysis Be Divorced from a Normative Tax Base?: A Critique of the "New Paradigm" and Its Denouement, 30 VA. TAX REV. 135, 172-79 (2010) (criticizing use of tax system for non-tax policy goals).
    • (2010) VA. TAX REV , vol.30 , pp. 172-179
    • Clifton, F.J.1    Peroni, R.D.2
  • 31
    • 79251606225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Congress Within the Congress: How Tax Expenditures Distort Our Budget and Our Political Process
    • note
    • Edward D. Kleinbard, The Congress Within the Congress: How Tax Expenditures Distort Our Budget and Our Political Process, 36 OHIO N. UNIV. L. REV. 1, 4-30 (2010) (same).
    • (2010) OHIO N. UNIV. L. REV , vol.36 , pp. 4-30
    • Edward, K.D.1
  • 33
    • 84861463688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • JONATHAN GRUBER, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC POLICY 134 (2d ed. 2007).
    • (2007) , pp. 134
    • Jonathan, G.1
  • 34
    • 84861466291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • JONATHAN GRUBER, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC POLICY. at 134-35.
    • Jonathan, G.1
  • 35
    • 84861466494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • JONATHAN GRUBER, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC POLICY. at 122.
    • Jonathan, G.1
  • 36
    • 84861462810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • JONATHAN GRUBER, PUBLIC FINANCE AND PUBLIC POLICY. at 422.
    • Jonathan, G.1
  • 37
    • 84861462514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. No. 111-148 §§ 1401(a), 1402(a)-(c), 1421(a), 2001(a), 124 Stat. 119, 213, 220, 237, 271 (codified as amended in scattered sections of the U.S. Code).
  • 38
    • 84861473217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. § 5000(a) (Supp. IV 2010).
    • (2010) , Issue.4
  • 39
    • 84861474630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For more detail on the points in this paragraph, see Part III below.
  • 40
    • 84861477186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To be sure, there are literally dozens of other sources that discuss "carrots and sticks." But in nearly all cases these other works merely discuss the role of incentives in human behavior, rather than attempting to distinguish between the two mechanisms. Ian Ayres's recent book, intended for popular audiences, does suggest differences between carrots and sticks as policy tools, but heavily emphasizes the difference in framing between the two and does not discuss the considerations addressed here.
    • Ian Ayres's Recent Book
  • 41
    • 84861469451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrots, Sticks, and International Externalities
    • note
    • IAN AYRES, CARROTS AND STICKS: UNLOCKING THE POWER OF INCENTIVES TO GET THINGS DONE 45-72 (2010). Another cousin is Howard F. Chang, Carrots, Sticks, and International Externalities, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 309 (1997), which considers the strategic incentives of nations bargaining over international environmental law. Both Chang and Ayres have insights to contribute to my project, but their main focus is elsewhere.
    • (2010) INT'L REV. L. & ECON , vol.17 , pp. 45-72
    • Howard, C.F.1
  • 42
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Chang, supra note 7, at 2150-64.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 2150-2164
  • 43
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wiener, supra note 7, at 726-27, 755.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 726-727
  • 44
    • 84861474370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As far as I am aware, Wittman's brief discussion is the only prior example of any analysis of the carrot/stick decision for positive externalities, and he limits his discussion to transaction costs.
  • 45
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wittman, supra note 7, at 71, 79.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 71
  • 46
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., BAUMOL & OATES, supra note 7, at 213.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 213
  • 47
    • 0001609162 scopus 로고
    • Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral
    • Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1115-24 (1972).
    • (1089) HARV. L. REV , vol.85 , pp. 1115-1124
    • Calabresi, G.1    Douglas, M.A.2
  • 49
    • 0346302271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Television and the Public Interest
    • note
    • A possible exception is Cass R. Sunstein, Television and the Public Interest, 88 CALIF. L. REV. 499, 543-48 (2000), which, although framed as a choice among different kinds of property rules, does briefly discuss a few factors influencing the choice among price mechanisms and other options for encouraging the production of public interest programming. Some authors have considered why the tort system punishes wrongdoing but does not require restitution for gratuitous good deeds.
    • (2000) CALIF. L. REV , vol.88 , pp. 543-548
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 50
    • 62749107564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Negative Liability
    • note
    • see, e.g., Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci, Negative Liability, 38 J. LEGAL STUD. 21, 26-30 (2009) (discussing prior literature), but these studies do not consider whether the best incentives for good deeds would instead be sticks for failure to provide the good.
    • (2009) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.38 , pp. 26-30
    • Dari-Mattiacci, G.1
  • 51
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For discussion of the points in this paragraph, see Part V below. Prior literature does include some discussion of the political economy of the choice between carrots and sticks, most notably STERNER, supra note 7, at 180-202.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 180-202
  • 52
    • 0000143382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Essay on Fiscal Federalism
    • note
    • For definitive reviews, see Wallace E. Oates, An Essay on Fiscal Federalism, 37 J. ECON. LITERATURE 1120 (1999).
    • (1999) J. ECON. LITERATURE , vol.37 , pp. 1120
    • Wallace, O.E.1
  • 53
    • 23744501341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a Second-Generation Theory of Fiscal Federalism
    • Wallace E. Oates, Toward a Second-Generation Theory of Fiscal Federalism, 12 INT'L TAX & PUB. FIN. 349 (2005).
    • (2005) INT'L TAX & PUB. FIN , vol.12
    • Wallace, O.E.1
  • 54
    • 77949833563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laboratories of Democracy? Policy Innovation in Decentralized Governments
    • note
    • See Brian Galle & Joseph Leahy, Laboratories of Democracy? Policy Innovation in Decentralized Governments, 58 EMORY L.J. 1333, 1335-37 (2009) (describing the backand-forth claims).
    • (2009) EMORY L.J , vol.58 , pp. 1335-1337
    • Galle, B.1    Leahy, J.2
  • 55
    • 84861466854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Typically, in the United States, our employers are obliged to do this for us, a procedure known as income tax withholding. IRS, PUBLICATION 15, (CIRCULAR E), EMPLOYER'S TAX GUIDE (2011).
    • (2011)
  • 56
    • 84861464737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Actually, when the author purchased his Prius, the tax credit was $3150.
  • 57
    • 84861472282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Summary of the Credit for Qualified Hybrid Vehicles, IRS, http://www.irs.gov/newsroom/article/0,id=157557,00.html (last updated Nov. 8, 2007).
    • (2007)
  • 58
    • 84861473894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also 26 U.S.C. § 30B (2006 & Supp. IV 2010) (establishing the credit).
  • 59
    • 84861471839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Assuming, of course, that the dealer doesn't increase its price by $1000 in anticipation of my windfall. Sometimes the economic benefits of a carrot go to a party other than the one the law assigns them to. But that doesn't reduce the efficacy of the carrot, as I'll explain shortly.
  • 60
    • 84861477336 scopus 로고
    • The Tax Expenditure Concept: Current Developments and Emerging Issues
    • Stanley S. Surrey & Paul R. McDaniel, The Tax Expenditure Concept: Current Developments and Emerging Issues, 20 B.C. L. REV. 225, 228 (1979).
    • (1979) B.C. L. REV , vol.20 , pp. 225
    • Surrey, S.S.1    Paul, M.R.2
  • 61
    • 84861465205 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 29.483 U.S. 203 (1987).
    • (1987)
  • 62
    • 84861476215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On the withholding of an expected carrot as equivalent to a stick.
  • 63
    • 57649222297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • eputation Nation: Law in an Era of Ubiquitous Personal Information
    • note
    • see Lior Jacob Strahilevitz, Reputation Nation: Law in an Era of Ubiquitous Personal Information, 102 NW. U. L. REV. 1667, 1712 (2008).
    • (2008) NW. U. L. REV , vol.102 , pp. 1667
    • Lior, J.S.1
  • 65
    • 0038239485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Truth in Government: Beyond the Tax Expenditure Budget
    • Julie Roin, Truth in Government: Beyond the Tax Expenditure Budget, 54 HASTINGS L.J. 603, 610-22 (2003).
    • (2003) HASTINGS L.J , vol.54 , pp. 610-622
    • Roin, J.1
  • 66
    • 0000316467 scopus 로고
    • The Empty Idea of Equality
    • Peter Westen, The Empty Idea of Equality, 95 HARV. L. REV. 537, 547 (1982).
    • (1982) HARV. L. REV , vol.95 , pp. 537
    • Westen, P.1
  • 67
    • 84861464533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. § 5000A(a)-(b) (Supp. IV 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 68
    • 84861475245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. § 5000A(a)-(b). § 5000A(c).
  • 69
    • 84861476816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional Kreplach
    • note
    • Edward D. Kleinbard, Constitutional Kreplach, 128 TAX NOTES 755 (2010) (pointing out that these two structures are economically identical).
    • (2010) TAX NOTES , vol.128
    • Edward, K.D.1
  • 70
    • 84861468678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A "marginal" price is just the cost for the purchase of one incremental unit of some good.
  • 71
  • 72
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For more nuance, see BAUMOL & OATES, supra note 7, at 15-18.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 15-18
  • 73
    • 84861472745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The author denies that this ever happened while he lived in Florida, Bob.
  • 74
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • note
    • See Ronald H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960), reprinted in R.H. COASE, THE FIRM, THE MARKET, AND THE LAW 95 (1988). And really, Bob, that was uncalled for.
    • (1960) J.L. & ECON , vol.3 , pp. 1
    • Ronald, C.H.1
  • 75
  • 76
  • 77
    • 84861472294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another tool, which I omit here for simplicity, is a so-called "quantity" regulation. In that case, society would simply determine how many trees I should grow, and force or incentivize me to grow that many. The mechanisms can be similar in many respects, but do differ in some important ways, as others have ably explained.
  • 78
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., STERNER, supra note 7, at 136-47.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 136-147
  • 79
    • 17644407632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Superiority of Corrective Taxes to Quantity Regulation
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, On the Superiority of Corrective Taxes to Quantity Regulation, 4 AM. L. & ECON. REV. 1, 2-15 (2002).
    • (2002) AM. L. & ECON. REV , vol.4 , pp. 2-15
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 80
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wiener, supra note 7, at 727-34.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 727-734
  • 81
  • 82
    • 84907056687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplow &Shavell, supra note 42, at 4.
    • Supra Note 42 , pp. 4
  • 83
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wiener, supra note 7, 714-15 (describing this point as the general consensus of economists).
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 714-715
  • 84
    • 84861474493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Unjustified pruning threats notwithstanding. Actually, even bargaining between two parties can fail for a variety of reasons, including strategic behavior and the possibility that the parties assign different utility to an identical amount of dollars. Herbert Hovenkamp,
  • 85
    • 84861466755 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Marginal Utility and the Coase Theorem, 75 CORNELL L. REV. 783, 789-806 (1990).
    • (1990) CORNELL L. REV , vol.75 , pp. 789-806
  • 86
    • 0346581482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property Rules Versus Liability Rules: An Economic Analysis
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Property Rules Versus Liability Rules: An Economic Analysis, 109 HARV. L. REV. 713, 724, 734 (1996).
    • (1996) HARV. L. REV , vol.109 , pp. 713
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 87
    • 84861472232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1107-10.
    • Supra Note 21 , pp. 1107-1110
  • 88
    • 84935026252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 45, at 749.
    • Supra Note 45 , pp. 749
  • 90
    • 84861472183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Interchangeability also requires that the tax system treat sticks and carrots identically, which it does not always do.
  • 91
    • 78149462829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taxing Punitive Damages
    • note
    • See Gregg D. Polsky & Dan Markel, Taxing Punitive Damages, 96 VA. L. REV. 1295, 1302-27 (2010) (explaining how the federal tax system may distort intended incentive effects of state tort law).
    • (2010) VA. L. REV , vol.96 , pp. 1302-1327
    • Gregg, P.D.1    Markel, D.2
  • 92
    • 52249099501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taxing Cap-and-Trade Environmental Regulation
    • note
    • Ethan Yale, Taxing Cap-and-Trade Environmental Regulation, 37 J. LEGAL STUD. 535, 548 (2008) (examining interactions between corporate income tax and environmental controls).
    • (2008) LEGAL STUD , vol.37 , pp. 535
    • Yale, E.1
  • 99
    • 84861469498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • JONATHAN BARON, THINKING AND DECIDING 269-70 (4th ed. 2007) (summarizing studies). at 267 & n.8.
    • (2007) THINKING and DECIDING , vol.8 , pp. 269-270
    • Jonathan, B.1
  • 100
  • 101
    • 84861477416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GRUBER, supra note 11. at 36 n.1.
    • Supra Note 11 , vol.1 , pp. 36
  • 102
    • 84861472843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mo Money Mo Problems
    • note
    • see THE NOTORIOUS B.I.G., Mo Money Mo Problems, on LIFE AFTER DEATH (Bad Boy Records 1997).
    • (1997) LIFE AFTER DEATH
    • Notorious, B.I.G.1
  • 103
    • 84861467959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GRUBER, supra note 11, at 36 n.1.
    • Supra Note 11 , vol.1 , pp. 36
  • 104
    • 84861463494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See POSNER, supra note 48, at 7 & n.8 (noting that no one has successfully identified an inferior good for which the income effect would exceed the substitution effect).
    • Supra Note 48 , vol.8 , pp. 7
  • 105
    • 84861472232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1095-96 (observing that assigning a legal entitlement enriches the entitled party and so may change its preferences).
    • Supra Note 21 , pp. 1095-1096
    • Calabresi, C.1
  • 106
    • 84861475807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Inelastic" means simply that demand doesn't change much when price changes. GRUBER, supra note 11, at 45-46.
    • Supra Note 11 , pp. 45-46
  • 107
    • 84861463631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Costs of Cigarettes: The Economic Case for Ex Post Incentive-Based Regulation
    • note
    • See Jon D. Hanson & Kyle D. Logue, The Costs of Cigarettes: The Economic Case for Ex Post Incentive-Based Regulation, 107 YALE L.J. 1163, 1218-20 n.254 (1998) (analyzing studies of price elasticity of tobacco products).
    • (1998) YALE L.J , vol.107 , pp. 1218-1220
    • Jon, H.D.1    Kyle, L.D.2
  • 108
    • 79956352607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is Cap-and-Trade Fair to the Poor? Shortsighted Households and the Timing of Consumption Taxes
    • note
    • Cf. Brian Galle & Manuel Utset, Is Cap-and-Trade Fair to the Poor? Shortsighted Households and the Timing of Consumption Taxes, 79 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 33, 68-71 (2010) (surveying studies of the relationship between timing of income and household consumption). Another way to put this point is that, if saving and borrowing are costless, a household will base purchasing decisions on expected lifetime income. Borrowing, however, may be limited by transaction costs and psychological barriers, see id., so that perceived income shrinks to the amount available to satisfy budget demands within a relatively short period.
    • (2010) GEO. WASH. L. REV , vol.79 , pp. 68-71
    • Brian, G.1    Manuel, U.2
  • 109
    • 84972799962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • STERNER, supra note 7, at 167-70.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 167-170
  • 110
    • 84861470933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I assume here a competitive market. In an oligopolistic market, producers with market power can constrain supply to a level below the unrestricted equilibrium, allowing them to capture more of the subsidy in profit rather than passing along the cost savings to consumers. In the long run, though, even that scenario often will result in greater output, since eventually entrepreneurs will recognize the superior profits to be had in the industry and, assuming the oligopolists cannot easily keep them out, they will compete away the higher profits. For a detailed discussion of the effect of subsidies in oligopolistic markets.
  • 111
    • 38249005469 scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Emission Taxes and Abatement Subsidies on Market Structure
    • note
    • see Klaus Conrad & Jianmin Wang, The Effect of Emission Taxes and Abatement Subsidies on Market Structure, 11 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 499, 500-18 (1993).
    • (1993) INT'L J. INDUS. ORG , vol.11 , pp. 500-518
    • Klaus, C.1    Jianmin, W.2
  • 112
    • 84861469083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In some situations, such as when components of the taxed good can be divided up and thereby escape a portion of the tax, taxes may actually decrease the price of the original (now unbundled) good.
  • 113
    • 0347684358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ambiguous Quality Changes from Taxes and Legal Rules
    • note
    • See Henry E. Smith, Ambiguous Quality Changes from Taxes and Legal Rules, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 647, 649-50 (2000).
    • (2000) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.67 , pp. 649-650
    • Henry, E.S.1
  • 114
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See STERNER, supra note 7, at 167-68.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 167-168
  • 115
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See BAUMOL & OATES, supra note 7, at 217-30.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 217-230
  • 116
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Wiener, supra note 7, at 727.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 727
  • 117
    • 84861464127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Role of Administrative Issues in Tax Reform: Simplicity, Compliance, and Administration
    • note
    • See, e.g., William G. Gale & Janet Holtzblatt, The Role of Administrative Issues in Tax Reform: Simplicity, Compliance, and Administration, in UNITED STATES TAX REFORM IN THE 21ST CENTURY 179, 179-80 (George R. Zodrow & Peter Mieszkowski eds., 2002).
    • (2002) UNITED STATES TAX REFORM IN the 21ST CENTURY , vol.179 , pp. 179-180
    • William, G.G.1    Janet, H.2
  • 118
    • 0009109662 scopus 로고
    • The Compliance Cost of the U.S. Individual Income Tax System
    • Joel Slemrod & Nikki Sorum, The Compliance Cost of the U.S. Individual Income Tax System, 37 NAT'L TAX J. 461, 462-74 (1985).
    • (1985) NAT'L TAX J , vol.37 , pp. 462-474
    • Slemrod, J.1    Sorum, N.2
  • 119
    • 84861476776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On Amsterdam's skinny homes.
  • 120
    • 0003774953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see HARVEY S. ROSEN & TED GAYER, PUBLIC FINANCE 371 (8th ed. 2008). To watch Axel Foley wreck most of downtown Detroit in his pursuit of untaxed cigarettes.
    • (2008) PUBLIC FINANCE , pp. 371
    • Harvey S., R.1    Ted, G.2
  • 121
    • 84861477365 scopus 로고
    • note
    • see BEVERLY HILLS COP (Paramount Pictures 1984).
    • (1984)
    • Beverly, H.1
  • 122
    • 84978635301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GRUBER, supra note 11, at 578-79.
    • Supra Note 11 , pp. 578-579
  • 123
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The classic analysis of the differing transaction costs between the two is Wittman, supra note 7, at 62-65.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 62-65
  • 124
    • 84861471524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wittman asserts that it is more efficient to choose the rule affecting fewer actors-for example, punishing theft instead of paying for non-theft, if most people comply with the law.
  • 125
    • 84861465590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wittman asserts that it is more efficient to choose the rule affecting fewer actors-for example, punishing theft instead of paying for non-theft, if most people comply with the law. at 64-65.
  • 126
    • 84861465360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It should already be clear that this analysis is seriously incomplete. For one, in the case where Wittman would prescribe paying, his analysis fails to account for the deadweight loss involved in raising revenues for payoffs. This loss might exceed any administrative savings achieved by reducing the number of affected actors.
  • 127
    • 84861472232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1121.
    • Supra Note 21 , pp. 1121
  • 128
    • 84861475807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See GRUBER, supra note 11, at 53.
    • Supra Note 11 , pp. 53
  • 129
    • 84861472232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1102-03.
    • Supra Note 21 , pp. 1102-1103
  • 130
    • 84861475801 scopus 로고
    • Carrying a Big Carrot: Linking Multilateral Disarmament and Development Assistance
    • note
    • See, e.g., David A. Koplow & Philip G. Schrag, Carrying a Big Carrot: Linking Multilateral Disarmament and Development Assistance, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 993, 1026-42 (1991).
    • (1991) COLUM. L. REV , vol.91 , pp. 1026-1042
    • David, K.A.1    Philip, S.G.2
  • 131
  • 132
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wiener, supra note 7, at 726.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 726
  • 133
    • 0002877397 scopus 로고
    • Takings, Insurance, and Michelman: Comments on Economic Interpretations of "Just Compensation" Law
    • note
    • See William A. Fischel & Perry Shapiro, Takings, Insurance, and Michelman: Comments on Economic Interpretations of "Just Compensation" Law, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 269, 290-91 & n.48 (1988) (suggesting that failure to compensate for takings may discourage investment).
    • (1988) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.17 , Issue.48 , pp. 290-291
    • William, A.F.1    Perry, S.2
  • 134
    • 84907056687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 42, at 4, 9.
    • Supra Note 42 , pp. 4
  • 135
    • 84907056687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 42. at 7.
    • Supra Note 42 , pp. 7
  • 136
    • 0040097456 scopus 로고
    • A Note on Subsidizing Gifts
    • note
    • See Louis Kaplow, A Note on Subsidizing Gifts, 58 J. PUB. ECON. 469, 472 (1995) (noting that if subsidy amounts vary inversely with donors' observed willingness to give, some donors may give less in order to extract greater subsidies).
    • (1995) J. PUB. ECON , vol.58 , pp. 469
    • Louis, K.1
  • 137
    • 84907056687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 42, at 5-6 (claiming this is only the case when the government is constrained to use a linear tax schedule).
    • Supra Note 42 , pp. 5-6
  • 138
    • 81255199113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Smith, supra note 65, at 683-96 (suggesting this is also the case when producers can effectively conceal a portion of the harm they produce).
    • Supra Note 65 , pp. 683-696
  • 139
    • 84861468717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In some instances, the added difficulty of measuring producer costs may end up being an argument for abandoning Pigouvian pricing altogether and using some other instrument, such as a quantity rule.
  • 140
    • 84861471013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See In some instances, the added difficulty of measuring producer costs may end up being an argument for abandoning Pigouvian pricing altogether and using some other instrument, such as a quantity rule. at 685.
  • 141
    • 43049130008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Asymmetric Information and Contract Design for Payments for Environmental Services
    • note
    • See Paul J. Ferraro, Asymmetric Information and Contract Design for Payments for Environmental Services, 65 ECOLOGICAL ECON. 810, 811 (2008).
    • (2008) ECOLOGICAL ECON , vol.65 , pp. 810
    • Paul, J.F.1
  • 142
    • 77950313763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reconciling Theory and Practice: An Alternative Conceptual Framework for Understanding Payments for Environmental Services
    • Roldan Muradian et al., Reconciling Theory and Practice: An Alternative Conceptual Framework for Understanding Payments for Environmental Services, 69 ECOLOGICAL ECON. 1202, 1204 (2010).
    • (2010) ECOLOGICAL ECON , vol.69 , pp. 1202
    • Roldan, M.1
  • 143
    • 84861468916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ferraro, supra note 82, at 811.
    • Supra Note 82 , pp. 811
  • 145
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See STERNER, supra note 7, at 153.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 153
  • 146
    • 84861472232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sunstein, supra note 21, at 546-47. Hanson and Logue argue that the government can reduce opportunities for producers to conceal information by imposing sticks ex post, rather than setting a price ex ante.
    • Supra Note 21 , pp. 546-547
  • 147
    • 81255199151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hanson & Logue, supra note 61, at 1273-74. While they may be right that measuring is easier than predicting, it is unclear why an ex post system would reduce producer incentives to conceal harms as they are happening.
    • Supra Note 61 , pp. 1273-1274
  • 148
    • 84861472323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For empirical evidence of this theory.
  • 149
    • 43949162582 scopus 로고
    • The Marginal Efficiency Effects of Taxes and Subsidies in the Presence of Externalities: A Computational General Equilibrium Approach
    • note
    • see Charles L. Ballard & Steven G. Medema, The Marginal Efficiency Effects of Taxes and Subsidies in the Presence of Externalities: A Computational General Equilibrium Approach, 52 J. PUB. ECON. 199 (1993).
    • (1993) J. PUB. ECON , vol.52 , pp. 199
    • Charles, L.B.1    Steven, G.M.2
  • 150
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Wiener, supra note 7, at 730.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 730
  • 151
    • 84861473791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Metcalf & Weisbach, supra note 5, at 513-14 & n.66.
    • Supra Note 5 , vol.66 , pp. 513-514
  • 152
    • 0039779274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Distributional Analysis of Green Tax Reforms
    • note
    • Gilbert E. Metcalf, A Distributional Analysis of Green Tax Reforms, 52 NAT'L TAX J. 655, 663 (1999). The climate change bill that passed the U.S. House of Representatives also had this feature. American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009, H.R. 2454, 111th Cong. § 431 (2009).
    • (1999) NAT'L TAX J , vol.52 , pp. 655
    • Gilbert, E.M.1
  • 153
    • 76649096925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • STERNER, supra note 7, at 175. Additionally, most economists would claim that a consumption tax cannot be more efficient than an income tax, because both ultimately reduce the amount of after-tax goods that workers can consume, and therefore both equally distort the decision of how hard to work. Thus, if carbon-tax revenues simply replace income tax revenues, there is no net gain in efficiency. My own view is that there is some reason to doubt that consumption taxes are as distortive of labor/leisure decisions as income taxes, because workers may not be as aware of the cumulative burden of consumption taxes.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 175
  • 154
    • 84861475960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hidden Taxes
    • note
    • See Brian Galle, Hidden Taxes, 87 WASH. U. L. REV. 59, 77-81 (2009) (describing possible welfare effects of unnoticed taxation). Because they do not tax savings, consumption taxes also might avoid the income tax's impact on personal savings decisions, which may be efficient in some situations.
    • (2009) WASH. U. L. REV , vol.87 , pp. 77-81
    • Brian, G.1
  • 155
    • 40749127530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond the Pro-Consumption Tax Consensus
    • note
    • See Daniel Shaviro, Beyond the Pro-Consumption Tax Consensus, 60 STAN. L. REV. 745, 783-88 (2007). In any event, switching to a consumption-tax stick can be efficient if it replaces taxes other than the individual income tax, such as by reducing the corporate income tax.
    • (2007) STAN. L. REV , vol.60 , pp. 783-788
    • Daniel, S.1
  • 156
    • 84861466707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One form of stick that might require revenue expenditures is criminal fines. To make the stick credible, the government must have enforcement officers, judges, finecollectors, and so on.
  • 157
    • 84861477237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Multiplication Effect
    • Dari-Mattiacci & De Geest, Multiplication Effect, supra note 7, at 369-76.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 369-376
  • 158
    • 81455130359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also AYRES, supra note 18, at 50 (calling this a "pretty obvious point").
    • Supra Note 18 , pp. 50
  • 159
    • 84861474800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Multiplication Effect
    • Dari-Mattiacci & De Geest, Multiplication Effect, supra note 7, at 366.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 366
  • 160
    • 84861466836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Multiplication Effect
    • note
    • See Dari-Mattiacci & De Geest, Multiplication Effect, supra note 7. at 368.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 368
  • 161
    • 84861478050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Multiplication Effect
    • note
    • Cf. See Dari-Mattiacci & De Geest, Multiplication Effect, supra note 7. at 376 (noting that the advantage of sticks is smaller when agents act cooperatively to resist).
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 376
  • 163
    • 84861468916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See TREASURY INSPECTOR GEN. FOR TAX ADMIN., ADDITIONAL STEPS ARE NEEDED TO PREVENT AND RECOVER ERRONEOUS CLAIMS FOR THE FIRST-TIME HOMEBUYER CREDIT 4-11 (2010), available at http://www.treasury.gov/tigta/auditreports/2010reports/201041069fr.pdf. On the opportunistic behavior of carrot recipients, see Ferraro, supra note 82, at 811.
    • (2010) Supra Note 82 , pp. 811
  • 164
    • 0347109859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining Market Mechanisms
    • note
    • Cf. Thomas W. Merrill, Explaining Market Mechanisms, 2000 U. ILL. L. REV. 275, 287 ("[T]here is little basis for thinking that the management costs associated with one type of market mechanism. are materially lower than those associated with other types").
    • (2000) U. ILL. L. REV , pp. 275
    • Thomas, W.M.1
  • 165
    • 84861477906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, actors may not expend the same effort to pursue gain as to avoid loss if they are more averse to losses than they are attracted to gains. But firms, at least, are typically held by a diversified group of shareholders and so are risk-neutral.
  • 166
    • 0040225532 scopus 로고
    • Shareholders Versus Managers: The Strain in the Corporate Web
    • See John C. Coffee, Jr., Shareholders Versus Managers: The Strain in the Corporate Web, 85 MICH. L. REV. 1, 19 (1986).
    • (1986) MICH. L. REV. 1 , vol.85 , pp. 19
    • John, C.1    Coffee, J.2
  • 167
    • 84861463525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrots Versus Sticks
    • note
    • See De Geest & Dari-Mattiacci, Carrots Versus Sticks, supra note 7, at 17, 22.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 17
  • 168
    • 84861469796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. POSNER, supra note 48, at 282 (arguing that efficient criminal law adds punishment for efforts to conceal crime).
    • Supra Note 48 , pp. 282
  • 169
    • 84861465225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrots Versus Sticks
    • note
    • De Geest & Dari-Mattiacci, Carrots Versus Sticks, supra note 7, at 23-24. Some of the potential costs include not only pure administrative losses, but also unwanted redistribution from those who cannot easily comply with a penalty regime to those who can.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 23-24
  • 170
    • 84861465225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrots Versus Sticks
    • note
    • De Geest & Dari-Mattiacci, Carrots Versus Sticks, supra note 7, at 23-24. Some of the potential costs include not only pure administrative losses, but also unwanted redistribution from those who cannot easily comply with a penalty regime to those who can.
    • Supra Note 7 , pp. 23-24
  • 171
    • 84861474053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On the other hand, as Henry Smith explains, multi-attribute goods are especially expensive to monitor when we use subsidies, because of the added possibility that producers will manipulate quantity or quality to extract more subsidies per unit of the subsidized good.
  • 172
    • 81255199113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Smith, supra note 65, at 698-700.
    • Supra Note 65 , pp. 698-700
  • 174
    • 84930063848 scopus 로고
    • The Disposition to Sell Winners Too Early and Ride Losers Too Long: Theory and Evidence
    • note
    • See Hersh Shefrin & Meir Statman, The Disposition to Sell Winners Too Early and Ride Losers Too Long: Theory and Evidence, 40 J. FIN. 777, 782 (1985). 103.
    • (1985) 40 J. FIN , vol.777 , Issue.782 , pp. 103
    • Hersh, S.1    Meir, S.2
  • 175
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See STERNER, supra note 7, at 167.
    • Supra Note , pp. 167
  • 177
    • 33344466705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Influences on Software Piracy: Evidence from the Various United States
    • note
    • See Trisha L. Bezmen & Craig A. Depken II, Influences on Software Piracy: Evidence from the Various United States, 90 ECON. LETTERS 356, 359 (2006). 106.
    • (2006) 90 ECON. LETTERS , vol.356 , Issue.359 , pp. 106
    • Trisha L., B.1    Craig, A.2
  • 178
    • 84861476909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See R. Glenn Hubbard et al., Banks Need Fewer Carrots and More Sticks, WALL ST. J., May 6, 2009, at A15. For the history of the development of a similar norm in the envi-ronmental context.
    • (2009) Banks Need Fewer Carrots and More Sticks
    • Glenn, H.R.1
  • 179
    • 0346685326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Too Much Market? Conflict Between Tradable Pollution Allowances and the "Polluter Pays" Principle
    • note
    • see Jonathan Remy Nash, Too Much Market? Conflict Between Tradable Pollution Allowances and the "Polluter Pays" Principle, 24 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 465, 467-78 (2000).
    • (2000) 24 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.465 , pp. 467-478
    • Jonathan, R.N.1
  • 180
    • 29044449535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Constitutional Status of Tort Law: Due Process and the Right to a Law for the Redress of Wrongs
    • note
    • See, e.g., John C.P. Goldberg, The Constitutional Status of Tort Law: Due Process and the Right to a Law for the Redress of Wrongs, 115 YALE L.J. 524, 532-58 (2005).
    • (2005) 115 YALE L.J , vol.524 , pp. 532-558
    • John, C.P.G.1
  • 181
    • 76849108842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Equal Accountability Through Tort Law
    • Jason M. Solomon, Equal Accountability Through Tort Law, 103 NW. U. L. REV. 1765, 1784-1811 (2009).
    • (2009) 103 NW. U. L. REV , vol.1765 , pp. 1784-1811
    • Jason, M.S.1
  • 182
    • 0032350230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rights, Wrongs, and Recourse in the Law of Torts
    • note
    • see also Benjamin C. Zipursky, Rights, Wrongs, and Recourse in the Law of Torts, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1, 6 (1998).
    • 51 VAND. L. REV , vol.1 , Issue.6 , pp. 1998
    • Benjamin, C.Z.1
  • 183
    • 84861477086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Goldberg, supra note 107, at 602-03.
  • 184
    • 84861464279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Or, more generally, when a stick program combined with dedicated spending from the stick-generated revenues is on net regressive. Imperfect enforcement can also lead to redistribution, when carrots or sticks are applied to only a subset of the producer population. But under realistic assumptions, this effect appears no more likely under carrots than under sticks.
  • 186
    • 84861463633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The efficiency case for redistribution in favor of the poor is based on the diminishing marginal utility of wealth. That is, the richer people already are, the less each additional dollar gained or lost is worth in utility terms. For example, if Josephine has $1000 and loses $500, she is in serious trouble, and may face hunger or eviction. If she has $1 million and loses $500, she is a little bummed.
  • 187
    • 84861470420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There remains a lively debate over whether designers of legal rules should be concerned about distributional effects, or whether instead all distributive considerations should simply be taken care of in the income tax system.
  • 188
    • 0003206208 scopus 로고
    • Why the Legal System Is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income
    • note
    • Compare Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Why the Legal System Is Less Efficient than the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 667, 669 (1994).
    • (1994) 23 J. LEGAL STUD , vol.667 , pp. 669
    • Louis, K.1    Steven, S.2
  • 189
    • 0037412575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should Legal Rules Be Used to Redistribute Income?
    • David A. Weisbach, Should Legal Rules Be Used to Redistribute Income?, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 439, 446-53 (2003).
    • (2003) 70 U. CHI. L. REV , vol.439 , pp. 446-453
    • David, A.W.1
  • 190
    • 84861464122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Kaplow and Shavell's "Double-Distortion Argument" Articles Are Wrong
    • Richard S. Markovits, Why Kaplow and Shavell's "Double-Distortion Argument" Articles Are Wrong, 13 GEO. MASON L. REV. 511, 550-55 (2005).
    • (2005) 13 GEO. MASON L. REV , vol.511 , pp. 550-555
    • Richard, M.S.1
  • 191
    • 0346327394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Economists' New Arguments
    • Brett H. McDonnell, The Economists' New Arguments, 88 MINN. L. REV. 86, 111 (2003).
    • (2003) 88 MINN. L. REV , vol.86 , pp. 111
    • Brett, M.H.1
  • 192
    • 0347079849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deconstructing the New Efficiency Rationale
    • Chris William Sanchirico, Deconstructing the New Efficiency Rationale, 86 CORNELL L. REV. 1003, 1006-11 (2001).
    • (2001) 86 CORNELL L. REV , vol.1003 , pp. 1006-1011
    • Chris, S.W.1
  • 193
    • 84861472683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I tend to agree with those who argue that legal rules should account for distributive considerations, for reasons including those I have explained elsewhere.
  • 194
    • 84861473526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is Local Consumer Protection Law a Better Redistributive Mechanism than the Tax System?
    • Brian Galle, Is Local Consumer Protection Law a Better Redistributive Mechanism than the Tax System?, 65 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. 525, 530-40 (2010).
    • (2010) 65 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L , vol.525 , pp. 530-540
    • Brian, G.1
  • 195
    • 84861466284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a survey of the evidence on these points.
  • 196
    • 84861476708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Galle & Utset, supra note 62, at 48-60, 78-82.
    • Supra Note , vol.48-60 , pp. 78-82
  • 197
    • 79251538927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sin Taxes: When the State Becomes the Sinner
    • note
    • See Andrew J. Haile, Sin Taxes: When the State Becomes the Sinner, 82 TEMP. L. REV. 1041, 1050 (2009) (summarizing these arguments). It is not entirely clear that the criticism is cogent. The consumer, or at least her future self, suffers a large portion of the harm from tobacco and alcohol, but may simply lack the willpower to stop. These harms can be thought of as "internalities." If the diminishing marginal utility of wealth makes the sin tax's bite sharper, it is the consumer herself who benefits more.
    • (2009) 82 TEMP. L. REV , vol.1041 , pp. 1050
    • Andrew, H.J.1
  • 198
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 45, at 739-40.
    • Supra Note , pp. 739-740
  • 200
    • 33745723793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysis
    • note
    • Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysis, 111 HARV. L. REV. 869, 913 (1998). Presumably, carrots also are disproportionately tempting for poorer households. But this can be an advantage for policymakers, since it allows the government to achieve the desired marginal effects with a smaller outlay.
    • (1998) 111 HARV. L. REV , vol.869 , pp. 913
    • Mitchell, P.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 201
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Engel et al., supra note 7, at 672 (suggesting that subsidies can help to alleviate poverty).
    • Supra Note , pp. 672
  • 203
    • 84861473791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Metcalf & Weisbach, supra note 5, at 513-14 & n.66.
    • Supra Not , vol.66 , pp. 513-514
  • 204
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Metcalf, supra note 88, at 664.
    • Supra Note , pp. 664
  • 205
    • 65649125988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Impact of Cap-and-Trade Policies for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions on U.S. Households
    • note
    • See Md Rumi Shammin & Clark W. Bullard, Impact of Cap-and-Trade Policies for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions on U.S. Households, 68 ECOLOGICAL ECON. 2432, 2437 (2009).
    • (2009) 68 ECOLOGICAL ECON , vol.2432 , pp. 2437
    • Rumi, S.M.1    Clark, B.W.2
  • 206
    • 0040076432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributional Effects of Carbon Allowance Trading: How Government Decisions Determine Winners and Losers
    • note
    • Cf. Terry Dinan & Diane Lim Rogers, Distributional Effects of Carbon Allowance Trading: How Government Decisions Determine Winners and Losers, 55 NAT'L TAX J. 199, 206 (2002) (modeling revenue effects of rebate proposals). Basically, the rebate would cost more than the tax if the tax were very effective at getting producers to reduce carbon in ways that resulted in no tax paid but were still expensive for the producers, and the producers passed these costs on to customers.
    • (2002) 55 NAT'L TAX J , vol.199 , pp. 206
    • Terry, D.1    Diane, L.R.2
  • 210
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Dari-Mattiacci, supra note 21, at 25.
    • Supra Note , pp. 25
  • 211
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Engel et al., supra note 7, at 670.
    • Supra Note , pp. 670
  • 212
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Engel et al., supra note 7, at 670. There are a number of reasons producers might mitigate negative externalities in the absence of a subsidy. Some changes in business processes can both benefit the firm and also reduce externalities (think of switching from an outmoded coal power plant to a modernized hydrothermal one). Absent government action, private actors subject to the externality might bargain directly with the producer. Finally, the producer might altruistically avoid harming its neighbors. Although few firms likely act out of feelings of altruism held by their principals, being perceived as "eco-friendly" or "dolphin-safe" also has branding benefits.
    • Supra Note , pp. 670
  • 213
    • 84861466842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • De Geest and Dari-Mattiacci. Appear to argue that inframarginality, or what they call "overpayment," can be reduced by tailoring the amount of the carrot to an individual producer's cost of production.
    • De Geest1    Dari-Mattiacci2
  • 215
    • 84861475785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • De Geest & Dari-Mattiacci, Carrots Versus Sticks, supra note 7, at 21-24. Considering that producers can manipulate the information available to the government, and that if carrots vary with their effort cost then producers would have a strong incentive to engage in manipulation, that is a large assumption. But it may not be implausible. For a discussion of how the government can elicit information producers would prefer to keep concealed.
    • Carrots Versus Sticks, Supra Note , pp. 21-24
    • De Geest and Dari-Mattiacci1
  • 217
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See BAUMOL & OATES, supra note 7, at 212.
    • Supra Note , pp. 212
  • 218
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wiener, supra note 7, at 726.
    • Supra Note , pp. 726
  • 219
    • 84900727539 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions
    • note
    • See Louis Kaplow, An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions, 99 HARV. L. REV. 509, 529-31 (1986).
    • (1986) 99 HARV. L. REV , vol.509 , pp. 529-531
    • Louis, K.1
  • 220
    • 84861477055 scopus 로고
    • Compensation for Takings: An Economic Analysis
    • note
    • see also Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Compensation for Takings: An Economic Analysis, 72 CALIF. L. REV. 569, 590-92 (1984) (pointing out that guaranteed compensation for government takings induces overinvestment in property likely to be subject to regulation).
    • (1984) 72 CALIF. L. REV , vol.569 , pp. 590-592
    • Lawrence, B.1    Daniel, L.R.2
  • 221
    • 57149086909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systemic Risk
    • note
    • Cf. Steven L. Schwarcz, Systemic Risk, 97 GEO. L.J. 193, 206 (2008) (describing how externalities contributed to the financial crisis).
    • (2008) 97 GEO. L.J , vol.193 , pp. 206
    • Steven, L.S.1
  • 222
    • 84861476573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Foreclosures produce downward spirals because homeowners are more likely to default when the value of their home is less than their outstanding mortgage. Since foreclosures in a neighborhood drive down prices of neighboring homes (the negative externality that motivates government intervention), a few foreclosures can trigger a cascade.
  • 223
    • 70350700854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rewriting Frankenstein Contracts: Workout Prohibitions in Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities
    • note
    • See Anna Gelpern & Adam J. Levitin, Rewriting Frankenstein Contracts: Workout Prohibitions in Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities, 82 S. CAL. L. REV. 1075, 1125-26 (2009).
    • (2009) 82 S. CAL. L. REV , vol.1075 , pp. 1125-1126
    • Anna, G.1    Adam, J.L.2
  • 224
    • 70350700854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rewriting Frankenstein Contracts: Workout Prohibitions in Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities
    • note
    • See Anna Gelpern & Adam J. Levitin, Rewriting Frankenstein Contracts: Workout Prohibitions in Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities, 82 S. CAL. L. REV. (2009). at 1102-03, 1127 (noting deliberate use of inflexible mortgage securitization contracts by lenders).
    • (2009) 82 S. CAL. L. REV , vol.1127 , pp. 1102-1103
    • Anna, G.1    Adam, J.L.2
  • 225
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Posner, supra note 48, at 68-69.
    • Supra Note , pp. 68-69
  • 226
    • 0346703088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Changes, Anticipations, and Reparations
    • note
    • See Saul Levmore, Changes, Anticipations, and Reparations, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 1657, 1663 (1999).
    • (1999) 99 COLUM. L. REV , vol.1657 , pp. 1663
    • Saul, L.1
  • 227
    • 0033220501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation
    • note
    • See Edward L. Deci et al., A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation, 125 PSYCHOL. BULL. 627, 658-59 (1999) (summarizing their meta-analysis of other studies).
    • (1999) 125 PSYCHOL. BULL , vol.627 , pp. 658-659
    • Edward, L.D.1
  • 228
    • 84861469065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Incentive Contracts Undermine Voluntary Cooperation?, 30-31 (Inst. for Empirical Research in Econ
    • note
    • Ernst Fehr & Simon Gächter, Do Incentive Contracts Undermine Voluntary Cooperation?, 30-31 (Inst. for Empirical Research in Econ., Univ. of Zurich, Working Paper No. 34, 2002) (finding larger crowding-out effect for penalties than for bonuses), available at http://www.iew.uzh.ch/wp/iewwp034.pdf.
    • (2002) Univ. of Zurich, Working Paper , pp. 34
    • Ernst, F.1    Simon, G.2
  • 229
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kaplow, supra note 127, at 551-52.
    • Supra Note , pp. 551-552
  • 230
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Fischel & Shapiro, supra note 77, at 269.
    • Supra Note , pp. 269
  • 231
    • 84861469722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In effect, the carrot substitutes for unavailable private insurance. Promising to use a carrot takes the cost of the risk of newly discovered dangers off of producers, and distributes it to society as a whole. This risk-spreading is efficient because of the diminishing marginal utility of wealth: when everyone in society suffers a small loss, the total social utility lost is less than if one person suffered a loss of the same total size. GUIDO CALABRESI, THE COSTS OF ACCIDENTS 39 (1970). Typically, moral hazard is a serious concern with these forms of implied government bailouts.
  • 232
    • 0347450521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs
    • note
    • Daryl J. Levinson, Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U. CHI. L. REV. 345, 390 (2000). But by assumption, we have no moral hazard in the unforeseeable-risk scenario.
    • (2000) 67 U. CHI. L. REV , vol.345 , pp. 390
    • Daryl, J.L.1
  • 233
    • 84861474851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The analysis is similar if we shift from wholly unforeseeable to nearly unforeseeable events. Low-probability outcomes remain difficult to privately insure against because the transaction costs of insurance will eat up any risk-spreading gains.
  • 234
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow, supra note 127, at 594. While moral hazard will not be zero, it will still be very small. Thus, we do not need to distinguish much between different degrees of near unforeseeability.
    • Supra Note , pp. 594
  • 235
    • 84861470911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even if hazards were unforeseeable, it might be argued that the expected change in behavior from outcomes that cannot be predicted would be small, since the cost of far-future events would be heavily discounted. POSNER, supra note 48, at 69.
  • 236
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Levmore, supra note 132, at 1663.
    • Supra Note , pp. 1663
  • 237
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Levmore, supra note 132. at 1665 (noting that parties who anticipate regulation that disadvantages them may work to delay its implementation). Probably the more complete way of stating this point is that producers will choose among strategies involving mixes of concealment, lobbying, and real change. If change is cheaper than concealment and lobbying, the producer may simply change. But given the government's difficulty in gathering private information, it seems plausible that concealment will often be a low-cost strategy-unless the government penalizes it. More on that in a moment.
    • Supra Note , pp. 1665
  • 238
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Ferraro, supra note 82, at 811.
    • Supra Note , pp. 811
  • 239
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Chang, supra note 18, at 310-24 (arguing that nations offered carrots by other nations will overestimate the costs of environmental mitigation, while sticks will not have this effect).
    • Supra Note , pp. 310-324
  • 240
    • 84861463098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hanson & Logue, supra note 61, at 1274 n.458 (arguing that the government should probably not ignore information from producers, even if it is suspected to be false, because producers have more information).
    • Supra Note , vol.458 , pp. 1274
  • 241
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See STERNER, supra note 7, at 159 (offering bottle deposits as an example of an information-revealing carrot).
    • Supra Note , pp. 159
  • 242
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ferraro, supra note 82, at 812 (suggesting separating equilibrium contracts or auctions to screen out exaggerators).
    • Supra Note , pp. 812
  • 243
    • 84861476926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even if carrots are available to all incumbents, at some point new information is only marginally useful, and so latecomers should get sticks. To eliminate competitive advantages for incumbents, policy can shift so that every producer faces sticks over time. Incumbents may rationally predict that eventually the government will transition to sticks. Assuming any degree of time discounting on their part, though, the fact that sticks arrive rather later than carrots should make them more amenable to revealing their private information.
  • 244
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 45, at 738.
    • Supra Note , pp. 738
  • 245
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See POSNER, supra note 48, at 63-67 (discussing the train example).
    • Supra Note , pp. 63-67
  • 246
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Blume & Rubinfeld, supra note 127, at 590-91 (observing that tax payments to fund compensated takings are the equivalent of insurance premiums). 147. For instance, suppose five farmers live near a railroad track. The railroad does $100 in damage to each farmer's crops by using a cheap, spark-prone engine. To discourage the railroad from operating in that risky manner, the farmers each pay a tax of $100 to the government, which then pays the railroad to cease. Now, suppose that each farmer can move his crops far enough from the tracks to avoid any damage. If any one farmer mitigates, total damage drops to $400, making the per-farmer tax only $80.
    • Supra Note , pp. 590-591
  • 247
    • 84861471871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This point is similar to the argument sometimes made in favor of requiring the government to pay when its regulations reduce the value of a regulated party's property: if the government must internalize the budget costs of both sides of the externality ledger, it will only regulate when regulation increases total welfare.
  • 248
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Blume & Rubinfeld, supra note 127, at 620-22.
    • Supra Note , pp. 620-622
  • 249
    • 84861465667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow and Shavell hint at a similar idea, stating in passing that "property rule protection of injurers' right to cause harm" would give victims "strong incentives to avoid exposure."
    • Strong Incentives to Avoid Exposure
  • 250
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kaplow & Shavell, supra note 45, at
    • Supra Note , pp. 45
  • 251
    • 84861466861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a discussion of the role of group cohesion and social institutions in coordinating for the production of public goods.
  • 253
    • 0346934925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Institutions for Old Neighborhoods
    • Robert C. Ellickson, New Institutions for Old Neighborhoods, 48 DUKE L.J. 75, 78-90 (1998)
    • (1998) 48 DUKE L.J , vol.75 , pp. 78-90
    • Robert, C.E.1
  • 254
    • 0020287245 scopus 로고
    • Self-Interest and Collective Action: The Economics and Psychology of Public Goods
    • Wolfgang Stroebe & Bruno S. Frey, Self-Interest and Collective Action: The Economics and Psychology of Public Goods, 21 BRIT. J. SOC. PSYCHOL. 121, 131-35 (1982).
    • (1982) 21 BRIT. J. SOC. PSYCHOL , vol.121 , pp. 131-135
    • Wolfgang, S.1    Bruno, S.F.2
  • 255
    • 84861468128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • More precisely, and putting aside any game-theory-inspired interactions with the incentives of other victims, an individual victim mitigates where mitigation costs are less than the damage per victim divided by the number of taxpayer-victims. That situation is probably unusual, since if mitigation is cheaper than voters' proportional share of the tax, they presumably would mitigate rather than vote for the tax. But there might be some heterogeneity in mitigation expenses or tax burden. Returning to our farmer example, suppose it costs only $15 for one of the farmers to move crops away from the fiery tracks. Since that farmer can now pay $15 to achieve a $20 tax savings, she will do so (unless she believes that by not mitigating she can induce other farmers to mitigate). Note, though, that if there were ten farmers, the total tax would be $1000, and mitigation by one farmer would still save $100. Each farmer's individual mitigation efforts therefore reduce each tax bill by only $10, meaning that mitigation would no longer be cost-effective, even for the low-cost farmer. Again, then, mitigation incentives depend on the size of the group of taxpayer-victims.
  • 256
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., BAUMOL & OATES, supra note 7, at 230-31.
    • Supra Note , pp. 230-231
  • 257
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Wittman, supra note 7, at 67-68 (examining this point in the tort context).
    • Supra Note , pp. 67-68
  • 258
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Wittman, supra note 7, at 67-68. To see this, consider a house husband who is hanging his laundry outside to dry. Suppose that it costs him $1 in quarters and wasted time to dry them at the laundromat instead. Suppose also that factory smoke causes $2 in damage to shirts left outside. What if the husband is not compensated for his damaged shirts, but instead the factory pays a fine? Then he will dry them at the laundromat, because each damaged shirt leaves him out $2, which is more than the cost of quarters. But what if he is compensated by the factory? Then he leaves the shirts outside and collects the money. In that scenario, the husband loses $2 and gains $2, for a net of zero per shirt, while laundering represents a loss of $1 per shirt. This could be a socially inefficient result-for example, if it would cost the factory more than $1 per shirt to avoid the damage, and $1 has the same utility value for factory investors and shirt washers.
    • Supra Note , pp. 67-68
  • 259
    • 84861477275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consider the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), an insurance pool for banks funded by banks. Suppose we have ten banks contributing to the pool and that total operating costs are $100 million annually. Say also that if any one bank defaults it jeopardizes the operations of other banks, for instance by worrying depositors and causing withdrawals and even runs, costing each other bank $5 million. So let us now say that the FDIC imposes a fine of $45 million (9 × $5 million) on a bank that defaults, payable to the funding pool. In effect, then, a default by one bank fully compensates each other bank by reducing their individual shares of the annual operating costs of the pool from $10 million to $5 million. If banks can, at some cost, reduce their exposure to damage from a competitor's default, this is an inefficient result, because banks will have no incentive to invest in mitigation.
  • 260
    • 84861476083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To illustrate, imagine a $100 million fine on a water polluter, shared equally among 100 million taxpayers nationwide. Presumably the fine is set at this level because the marginal damage is also $100 million. If each taxpayer experiences an equal amount of that harm, their net cost or benefit from the pollution and fine is zero ($1 in tax saved less $1 in damage). If the mitigation is at all costly-say, the price of a Brita filter-then no taxpayer has any incentive to mitigate. A more likely scenario is that some households, such as those with children, are more vulnerable. Households bearing a disproportionate share of the marginal damage may suffer a net loss as a result of the combined pollution and fine, and therefore conceivably have some incentives to mitigate. But other portions of the population still would not. Transaction costs somewhat weaken the equivalence, because they presumably would reduce the amount of net revenue benefits from imposing a fine. But on the other hand if fines permit lower tax rates then society experiences less deadweight tax loss.
  • 261
    • 64749111099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Least-Cost Avoidance: The Tragedy of Common Safety
    • note
    • Cf. Giuseppe Dari-Mattiacci & Nuno Garoupa, Least-Cost Avoidance: The Tragedy of Common Safety, 25 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 235, 258 (2007) (noting that victims' failure to mitigate is itself a negative fiscal externality imposed on producers).
    • (2007) 25 J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.235 , pp. 258
    • Giuseppe, D.-M.1    Nuno, G.2
  • 262
    • 84861476562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I should acknowledge that carrots can also encourage victims to conceal their ability to mitigate. However, once we recognize that victims help to fund carrots, it is evident that the problem is more significant for sticks. Since victims bear a portion of the cost of the carrot, they internalize at least some of society's total cost of mitigating the externality, making them more likely to prefer the most efficient result. For example, if victims fully internalize the cost, they will always prefer to assign mitigation to the least-cost avoider. They therefore would have no economic interest in concealing their costs of mitigation.
  • 263
    • 38149145158 scopus 로고
    • Cooperation in Intergroup and SingleGroup Social Dilemmas
    • note
    • See Gary Bornstein & Meyrav Ben-Yossef, Cooperation in Intergroup and SingleGroup Social Dilemmas, 30 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL. 52, 63 (1994). In part this is because in that setting groups use greater intragroup incentives to force cooperation.
    • (1994) 30 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL , vol.52 , pp. 63
    • Gary, B.1    Meyrav, B.-Y.2
  • 264
    • 38149145158 scopus 로고
    • Cooperation in Intergroup and SingleGroup Social Dilemmas
    • note
    • See Gary Bornstein & Meyrav Ben-Yossef, Cooperation in Intergroup and SingleGroup Social Dilemmas, 30 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL. 52, 63 (1994), and in part it may result from psychological pressure to conform.
    • (1994) 30 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL , vol.52 , pp. 63
    • Gary, B.1    Meyrav, B.-Y.2
  • 265
    • 38149145158 scopus 로고
    • Cooperation in Intergroup and SingleGroup Social Dilemmas
    • note
    • See Gary Bornstein & Meyrav Ben-Yossef, Cooperation in Intergroup and SingleGroup Social Dilemmas, 30 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL. 52, 63 (1994). at 64.
    • (1994) 30 J. EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL , vol.52 , pp. 63
    • Gary, B.1    Meyrav, B.-Y.2
  • 266
    • 84861463576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For consideration of whether subsidies might be defensible because they are more politically achievable.
  • 267
    • 84861465878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see text accompanying notes 260-66 below. 158. On the question of whether price regulation would be better in this context than command-and-control regulation, such as caps on spending.
    • Text Accompanying Notes , pp. 260-266
  • 268
    • 22744444497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note, Taxing Political Donations: The Case for Corrective Taxes in Campaign Finance
    • note
    • see David S. Gamage, Note, Taxing Political Donations: The Case for Corrective Taxes in Campaign Finance, 113 YALE L.J. 1283, 1296-321 (2004). Whether such a policy would be constitutional is a different question, which I leave for others.
    • (2004) 113 YALE L.J , vol.1283 , pp. 1296-1321
    • David, G.S.1
  • 269
    • 84861467392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a description of the National Flood Insurance Program and its struggles with moral hazard.
  • 271
    • 84861471652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • staff of j. Comm. On taxation, 111TH CONG., ESTIMATES OF FEDERAL TAX EXPENDITURES FOR FISCAL YEARS 2010-2014, at 49 (Comm. Print 2010). Some commentators would argue that the benefits for retirement savings are not subsidies, but instead should be viewed as a step towards a normatively correct tax system in which all savings are untaxed.
    • (2010) ON TAXATION, 111TH CONG., ESTIMATES of FEDERAL TAX EXPENDITURES FOR FISCAL YEARS , pp. 2010-2014
  • 272
    • 84861476253 scopus 로고
    • Discrimination Rules for Qualified Retirement Plans: Good Intentions Confront Economic Reality
    • note
    • Compare Bruce Wolk, Discrimination Rules for Qualified Retirement Plans: Good Intentions Confront Economic Reality, 70 VA. L. REV. 419, 421-22 (1984) (concluding the current tax treatment of qualified pension plans is a subsidy)
    • (1984) 70 VA. L. REV , vol.419 , pp. 421-422
    • Bruce, W.1
  • 273
    • 84861463989 scopus 로고
    • The Tax Treatment of Qualified Plans: A Classic Defense of the Status Quo
    • note
    • Edward A. Zelinsky, The Tax Treatment of Qualified Plans: A Classic Defense of the Status Quo, 66 N.C. L. REV. 315, 315-16 (1988) (concluding the current tax treatment of qualified pension plans is not a tax expenditure). This illustrates again the normative instability of any given baseline. My point here is only that retirement preferences depart from the current baseline in which most saving is taxed.
    • (1988) 66 N.C. L. REV , vol.315 , pp. 315-316
    • Edward, Z.A.1
  • 274
    • 84861469796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See POSNER, supra note 48, at 638-39 (noting burdens of poverty on altruists).
    • Supra Note 48 , pp. 638-639
  • 275
  • 276
    • 84861467263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Superiority of an Ideal Consumption Tax over an Ideal Income Tax
    • note
    • E.g., Joseph Bankman & David Weisbach, The Superiority of an Ideal Consumption Tax over an Ideal Income Tax, 58 STAN. L. REV. 1413, 1455 (2006).
    • (2006) 58 STAN. L. REV , vol.1413 , pp. 1455
    • Joseph, B.1    David, W.2
  • 277
    • 84861463033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010) (codified as amended in scattered sections of the U.S. Code).
    • (2010) , pp. 111-148
  • 279
    • 84861462677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an accessible summary.
  • 282
    • 84861463300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The legislation expands Medicaid eligibility to all non-Medicare qualified adults earning less than 133% of the federal poverty limit, and offers subsidies toward private insurance for households between 133% and 400% of the federal poverty limit.
  • 283
    • 84861471492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • HENRY J. KAISER FAMILY FOUND., supra note 165, at 1-2.
    • Supra Note , vol.165 , pp. 1-2
    • Henry, J.1
  • 284
    • 84861465013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another aspect of underinsurance, of course, is that being even partially uninsured is harmful for one's health and peace of mind.
  • 285
    • 84861472834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Oregon Health Insurance Experiment: Evidence from the First Year 4
    • note
    • Amy Finkelstein et al., The Oregon Health Insurance Experiment: Evidence from the First Year 4 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 17,190, 2011), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w17190.pdf. Arguably, it should be possible to alleviate those concerns without encouraging overconsumption of health care.
    • (2011) Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research , vol.17 , pp. 190
    • Amy, F.1
  • 287
    • 67349273290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Junk-Food, Home Cooking, Physical Activity and Obesity: The Effect of the Fat Tax and the Thin Subsidy
    • Gideon Yaniv et al., Junk-Food, Home Cooking, Physical Activity and Obesity: The Effect of the Fat Tax and the Thin Subsidy, 93 J. PUB. ECON. 823, 824 (2009).
    • (2009) 93 J. PUB. ECON , vol.823 , pp. 824
    • Gideon, Y.1
  • 288
    • 84861466473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an explanation of why traffic is the result of negative externalities.
  • 289
    • 84861476716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Efficiency Versus Public Choice: The Case of Property Rights in Road Traffic Management
    • note
    • see Jona-Than Remy Nash, Economic Efficiency Versus Public Choice: The Case of Property Rights in Road Traffic Management, 49 B.C. L. REV. 673, 687-94 (2008).
    • (2008) 49 B.C. L. REV , vol.673 , pp. 687-694
    • Jona-Than, R.N.1
  • 290
    • 84861476119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, Axel used bananas.
  • 292
    • 36048990803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF TRANSP., CONGESTION PRICING: A PRIMER 2-3 (2006), available at http://www.ops.fhwa.dot.gov/publications/congestionpricing/congestionpricing.pdf (describing San Diego's policy of granting free access to express lanes for vehicles with multiple passengers).
    • (2006) CONGESTION PRICING: A PRIMER , pp. 2-3
  • 293
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash, supra note 171, at 704 n.200 (describing subsidy programs in Maryland and Washington, D.C.).
    • Supra Note , pp. 200
  • 294
    • 84861475890 scopus 로고
    • Pricing Urban Transportation
    • note
    • E.g., Richard Arnott, Pricing Urban Transportation, in PUBLIC ECONOMICS: SELECTED PAPERS BY WILLIAM VICKREY 271, 271-75 (Richard Arnott et al. eds., 1994) (describing Vickrey's efforts in support of congestion pricing).
    • (1994) PUBLIC ECONOMICS: SELECTED PAPERS BY WILLIAM VICKREY , vol.271 , pp. 271-275
    • Richard, A.1
  • 295
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash, supra note 171, at 676.
    • Supra Note , pp. 676
  • 296
    • 84861471360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash, supra note 171, at 713 n.256, 727.
    • Supra Note , vol.256 , pp. 727
  • 297
    • 84861477892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For other suggestions.
  • 298
    • 0347705209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Changes in Property Regimes Influence Social Norms: Commodifying California's Carpool Lanes
    • note
    • see Lior Jacob Strahilevitz, How Changes in Property Regimes Influence Social Norms: Commodifying California's Carpool Lanes, 75 IND. L.J. 1231, 1246-47 (2000).
    • (2000) 75 IND. L.J , vol.1231 , pp. 1246-1247
    • Lior, S.J.1
  • 299
    • 84861476344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For reviews.
  • 302
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Supra note, at 291, 317-20.
    • Supra Note , pp. 317-320
  • 303
    • 84861473045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For more on business improvement districts.
  • 304
    • 0348223991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Government for Our Time? Business Improvement Districts and Urban Governance
    • note
    • see Richard Briffault, A Government for Our Time? Business Improvement Districts and Urban Governance, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 365, 377-414 (1999).
    • (1999) 99 COLUM. L. REV , vol.365 , pp. 377-414
    • Richard, B.1
  • 305
    • 29144523773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Marketing of Philanthropy and the Charitable Contributions Deduction: Integrating Theories for the Deduction and Tax Exemption
    • note
    • E.g., John D. Colombo, The Marketing of Philanthropy and the Charitable Contributions Deduction: Integrating Theories for the Deduction and Tax Exemption, 36 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 657, 698 (2001).
    • (2001) 36 WAKE FOREST L. REV , vol.657 , pp. 698
    • John, D.C.1
  • 306
    • 78649300806 scopus 로고
    • The Case for a Charitable Contributions Deduction
    • Mark P. Gergen, The Case for a Charitable Contributions Deduction, 74 VA. L. REV. 1393, 1397-98 (1988).
    • (1988) 74 VA. L. REV , vol.1393 , pp. 1397-1398
    • Mark, P.G.1
  • 307
    • 84861477410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. § 4942 (2006 & Supp. I 2007). The text above considerably simplifies the workings of the tax, but the details are not of interest here.
    • (2006) , Issue.1
  • 308
    • 84861477342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a review of the available evidence on foundation giving patterns.
  • 312
    • 84861469815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. § 164 (2006 & Supp. IV 2010).
    • (2010) , Issue.4
  • 313
    • 78650409892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recessions and the Social Safety Net: The Alternative Minimum Tax as a Countercyclical Fiscal Stabilizer
    • note
    • See Brian Galle & Jonathan Klick, Recessions and the Social Safety Net: The Alternative Minimum Tax as a Countercyclical Fiscal Stabilizer, 63 STAN. L. REV. 187, 226-35 (2010).
    • (2010) 63 STAN. L. REV , vol.187 , pp. 226-235
    • Brian, G.1    Jonathan, K.2
  • 314
    • 85005274189 scopus 로고
    • Demand for National Public Goods: Estimates from Surveys
    • Daniel Hewitt, Demand for National Public Goods: Estimates from Surveys, 23 ECON. INQUIRY 487, 503 (1985).
    • (1985) 23 ECON. INQUIRY , vol.487 , pp. 503
    • Daniel, H.1
  • 315
    • 0347212487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wittman, supra note 7, at 71, 79.
    • Supra Note , pp. 79
  • 317
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Engel et al., supra note 7, at 670.
    • Supra Note , pp. 670
  • 318
    • 84861466345 scopus 로고
    • Posner, Salvors, Finders, Good Samaritans, and Other Rescuers: An Economic Study of Law and Altruism
    • note
    • see also William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Salvors, Finders, Good Samaritans, and Other Rescuers: An Economic Study of Law and Altruism, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 83, 99 (1978) (showing that paid rescue crowds out altruistic rescue).
    • (1978) 7 J. LEGAL STUD , vol.83 , pp. 99
    • William, M.L.1    Richard, A.2
  • 319
    • 0001723491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Signaling Explanation for Charity
    • note
    • E.g., Amihai Glazer & Kai A. Konrad, A Signaling Explanation for Charity, 86 AM. ECON. REV. 1019, 1019-21 (1996).
    • (1996) 86 AM. ECON. REV , vol.1019 , pp. 1019-1021
    • Amihai, G.1    Kai, A.K.2
  • 320
    • 0000341886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Altruism, Nonprofits, and Economic Theory
    • Susan Rose-Ackerman, Altruism, Nonprofits, and Economic Theory, 34 J. ECON. LIT. 701, 717 (1996).
    • (1996) 34 J. ECON. LIT , vol.701 , pp. 717
    • Susan, R.-A.1
  • 321
    • 84861476997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Obviously, this is a generalization. For example, there is a market in carbon offsets. KATHERINE HAMILTON ET AL., ECOSYSTEM MARKETPLACE & NEW CARBON FIN., FORGING A FRONTIER: STATE OF THE VOLUNTARY CARBON MARKETS 2008, at 33 (2008), available at http://www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/documents/cms_documents/2008_StateofVoluntaryCarbonMarket2.pdf
    • (2008)
  • 322
    • 84990113767 scopus 로고
    • Public Radio Stations Are Really, Really Not Public Goods: Charitable Contributions and Impure Altruism
    • note
    • See, e.g., Bruce R. Kingma & Robert McClelland, Public Radio Stations Are Really, Really Not Public Goods: Charitable Contributions and Impure Altruism, 66 ANNALS PUB. & COOPERATIVE ECON. 65, 66-67, 73-74 (1995) (identifying several reasons donors may contribute to charity, and reporting evidence that these motives are indeed important to observed giving).
    • (1995) 66 ANNALS PUB. & COOPERATIVE ECON , vol.66-67 , Issue.65 , pp. 73-74
    • Bruce, R.K.1    Robert, M.2
  • 323
    • 84861470190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Landes & Posner, supra note 188, at 99.
    • Supra Note , vol.99
  • 324
    • 78649245793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keep Charity Charitable
    • note
    • see also Brian Galle, Keep Charity Charitable, 88 TEX. L. REV. 1213, 1224-25, 1233 (2010) (making this point about the charitable contribution deduction).
    • (2010) 88 TEX. L. REV , vol.1233 , Issue.1213 , pp. 1224-1225
    • Brian, G.1
  • 325
    • 33750519220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two Models of Tort (and Takings
    • note
    • Cf. Scott Hershovitz, Two Models of Tort (and Takings), 92 VA. L. REV. 1147, 1175-78 (2006) (arguing that tort law does not require compensation for gratuitous benefits because there is no moral duty to do so).
    • (2006) 92 VA. L. REV , vol.1147 , pp. 1175-1178
    • Scott, H.1
  • 326
    • 84861474841 scopus 로고
    • Altruism in Nonprofit Organizations
    • Rob Atkinson, Altruism in Nonprofit Organizations, 31 B.C. L. REV. 501, 629 (1990).
    • (1990) 31 B.C. L. REV , vol.501 , pp. 629
    • Rob, A.1
  • 327
    • 0035212713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motivation Crowding Theory
    • note
    • Compare Bruno S. Frey & Reto Jegen, Motivation Crowding Theory, 15 J. ECON. SURVS. 589, 599-600 (2001) (reporting a handful of studies that find penalties crowd out altruistic behavior).
    • (2001) 15 J. ECON. SURVS , vol.589 , pp. 599-600
    • Bruno, S.F.1    Reto, J.2
  • 328
    • 78649340892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Incentives Matrix: The Comparative Effectiveness of Rewards, Liabilities, Duties, and Protections for Reporting Illegality
    • note
    • with Yuval Feldman & Orly Lobel, The Incentives Matrix: The Comparative Effectiveness of Rewards, Liabilities, Duties, and Protections for Reporting Illegality, 88 TEX. L. REV. 1151, 1205-06 (2010) (finding no crowd-out from penalties).
    • (2010) 88 TEX. L. REV , vol.1151 , pp. 1205-1206
    • Yuval, F.1    Orly, L.2
  • 329
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sunstein, supra note 21, at 546.
    • Supra Note , pp. 546
  • 330
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Nash, supra note 106, at 479 (arguing that assigning the obligation to pay to those who are responsible for producing negative externalities encourages personal responsibility and trust in government).
    • Supra Note , pp. 479
  • 331
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Frey & Jegen, supra note 195, at 598-607.
    • Supra Note , pp. 598-607
  • 332
    • 0000511919 scopus 로고
    • Undermining Children's Intrinsic Interest with Extrinsic Reward: A Test of the "Overjustification" Hypothesis
    • note
    • Mark R. Lepper et al., Undermining Children's Intrinsic Interest with Extrinsic Reward: A Test of the "Overjustification" Hypothesis, 28 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 129 (1973). There is a small but developing literature aimed at studying how to provide Pigouvian pricing without also crowding out intrinsic motivations.
    • (1973) 28 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL , vol.129
    • Mark, R.L.1
  • 333
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Muradian et al., supra note 82, at 1205-07 (describing some recent suggestions and case studies).
    • Supra Note , pp. 1205-1207
  • 334
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Sunstein, supra note 21, at 546-47 (describing incentive effects of paying broadcasters to produce public interest programming).
    • Supra Note , pp. 546-547
  • 335
    • 84861473478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Treasury Shifts Target of Wall Street Rescue Plan
    • note
    • Kevin G. Hall, Treasury Shifts Target of Wall Street Rescue Plan, KNIGHT RIDDER, Nov. 13, 2008, available at 2008 WLNR 21699361.
    • (2008) KNIGHT RIDDER, Nov , vol.13
    • Kevin, G.H.1
  • 336
    • 77249150775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lehman and the Financial Crisis
    • note
    • See John H. Cochrane & Luigi Zingales, Lehman and the Financial Crisis, WALL ST. J., Sept. 15, 2009, at A21.
    • (2009) WALL ST. J , vol.15
    • John, H.C.1    Luigi, Z.2
  • 337
    • 84861469345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, imminent expiration of temporary tax subsidies accelerates the subsidized activity.
  • 338
    • 0036626406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fiscal Policy and Uncertainty
    • Alan J. Auerbach & Kevin A. Hassett, Fiscal Policy and Uncertainty, 5 INT'L FIN. 229, 231-36 (2002).
    • (2002) 5 INT'L FIN , vol.229 , pp. 231-236
    • Alan, J.A.1    Kevin, A.H.2
  • 339
    • 64549163911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Temporary Investment Tax Incentives: Theory with Evidence from Bonus Depreciation
    • Christopher L. House & Matthew D. Shapiro, Temporary Investment Tax Incentives: Theory with Evidence from Bonus Depreciation, 98 AM. ECON. REV. 737, 762-63 (2008).
    • (2008) 98 AM. ECON. REV , vol.737 , pp. 762-763
    • Christopher, L.H.1    Matthew, D.S.2
  • 341
    • 84861476872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In more technical terms, what is happening in the positive externality context is the intrusion of a zero lower bound on the degree of crowd-out. Anticipated sticks might crowd out productive activities when those activities are already under way. But if there are no regulable activities in progress, there is nothing to crowd out.
  • 342
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Levmore, supra note 132, at 1678 (noting that the government should want to compensate manufacturers of goods useful during crises, in order to avoid discouraging investments in producing those goods).
    • Supra Note , pp. 1678
  • 343
    • 84861470850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wittman, supra note 7, at 70 n.37 (suggesting that a duty to rescue might discourage people from entering areas where others may be likely to need rescuing).
    • Supra Note , vol.70 , pp. 37
  • 344
    • 84861468996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Dari-Mattiacci, supra note 21, at 33-40, 54. 206.
    • Supra Note , vol.206 , Issue.54 , pp. 33-40
  • 345
    • 84861474781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Dari-Mattiacci, supra note 21, at. 38.54. 206
    • Supra Note , vol.38 , Issue.54 , pp. 206
  • 347
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See POSNER, supra note 48, at 52-53.
    • Supra Note , pp. 52-53
  • 348
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See POSNER, supra note 48. at 202.
    • Supra Note , pp. 202
  • 349
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. Wittman, supra note 7, at 71 (arguing that it may be difficult to employ sticks to produce positive externalities because of difficulty in identifying whom to punish). 211.
    • Supra Note , pp. 71
  • 350
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. BAUMOL & OATES, supra note 7, at 214 (noting that subsidies require the gov-ernment to specify the benchmark amount of goods to be produced).
    • Supra Note , pp. 214
  • 351
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sunstein, supra note 21, at 545 (noting the difficulty of designing a price instrument that captures the uncertain mar-ginal value of another unit of public interest television).
    • Supra Note , pp. 545
  • 352
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wittman, supra note 7, at 68-69 (pointing out that it may be difficult to find and pay all potential producers). 212.
    • Supra Note , pp. 68-69
  • 354
    • 84881824864 scopus 로고
    • Prices and Sanctions
    • note
    • But see Robert Cooter, Prices and Sanctions, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1523, 1533-34 (1984) (arguing that policymakers can determine the correct level of production of a good by observing social consensus, even if marginal costs are not observable). A problem with Cooter's argument is that community behavior may be distorted by biases and fixed in place by path dependence, such as the happenstance of prior law and institutional arrangements. Also, as he acknowledges, long-held standards simply do not exist for new policy choices, such as the extension of copyright in my example. Admittedly, even if society does not know the precise marginal social benefit of a good, if society knows the general slopes of the supply and demand curves for the good, then the regulator could make reasonable predictions about whether overproduction or underproduction is the greater danger. If we expect that the social benefit curve is relatively steep, then the risk of underproduction is worse, assuming equal chances of underand overproduction. Reciprocally, the risk of overproduction is worse if the curve is relatively flat.
    • (1984) 84 COLUM. L. REV , vol.1523 , pp. 1533-1534
    • Robert, C.1
  • 355
    • 84861471298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Pub. L. No. 105-298, § 102, 112 Stat. 287 (1998) (codified as amended at 17 U.S.C. §§ 301-304 (2006 & Supp. IV 2010)).
    • (2010) , Issue.4 , pp. 301-304
  • 356
    • 84861462545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and Time: A Proposal
    • note
    • See Joseph P. Liu, Copyright and Time: A Proposal, 101 MICH. L. REV. 409, 413-22 (2002). One thing that does seem clear is that granting the extension retroactively did not spur any new creations by dead artists.
    • (2002) 101 MICH. L. REV , vol.409 , pp. 413-422
    • Joseph, P.L.1
  • 357
    • 84861476271 scopus 로고
    • Reforming Cy Pres Reform
    • note
    • See Rob Atkinson, Reforming Cy Pres Reform, 44 HASTINGS L.J. 1111, 1123 & n.38 (1993).
    • (1993) 44 HASTINGS L.J , vol.1111 , Issue.38 , pp. 1123
    • Rob, A.1
  • 358
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., POSNER, supra note 48, at 697.
    • Supra Note , pp. 697
  • 359
    • 84861471214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Limiting Dead Hand Control of Charitable Trusts: Expanding the Use of the Cy Pres Doctrine
    • Alex M. Johnson, Jr., Limiting Dead Hand Control of Charitable Trusts: Expanding the Use of the Cy Pres Doctrine, 21 U. HAW. L. REV. 353, 379-91 (1999).
    • (1999) 21 U. HAW. L. REV , vol.353 , pp. 379-391
    • Alex, M.1    Johnson, J.2
  • 360
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See CALABRESI, supra note 136, at 150-52.
    • Supra Note , pp. 150-152
  • 361
    • 84861468720 scopus 로고
    • Explaining Restitution
    • note
    • see also Saul Levmore, Explaining Restitution, 71 VA. L. REV. 65, 73 (1985) (extending least-cost avoider analysis to those who provide benefits to others).
    • (1985) 71 VA. L. REV , vol.65 , pp. 73
    • Saul, L.1
  • 362
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Wittman, supra note 7, at 71.
    • Supra Note , pp. 71
  • 363
    • 84861471041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 26 U.S.C. §§ 167-199 (2006 & Supp. IV 2010).
    • (2010) , vol.4 , pp. 167-199
  • 364
    • 84861470277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Office of Aviation Analysis, Essential Air Service Program, U.S. DEP'T TRANSP., http://ostpxweb.dot.gov/aviation/x-50%20role_files/essentialairservice.htm (last visited Apr. 13, 2012).
    • (2012) Essential Air Service Program
  • 365
    • 84861464613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • HOME and Low Income Housing Tax Credits (LIHTC), U.S. DEP'T HOUSING & URB. DEV., http://www.hud.gov/offices/cpd/affordablehousing/training/web/lihtc (last visited Apr. 13, 2012).
    • (2012) Low Income Housing Tax Credits (LIHTC)
  • 366
    • 84861474562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subsidizing the Press
    • note
    • See David M. Schizer, Subsidizing the Press, 3 J. LEGAL ANALYSIS 1 (2011).
    • (2011) 3 J. LEGAL ANALYSIS , vol.1
    • David, M.S.1
  • 368
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Schizer, supra note 222, at 5-16.
    • Supra Note , pp. 5-16
  • 369
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sunstein, supra note 21, at 539-42.
    • Supra Note , pp. 539-542
  • 370
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Sunstein, supra note. at 544.
    • Supra Note , pp. 544
  • 371
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cf. STERNER, supra note 7, at 171 (noting that subsidies affect output by attracting new investment in the regulated field).
    • Supra Note , pp. 171
  • 372
    • 84861472245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Frans L. Leeuw, The Carrot: Subsidies as a Tool of GovernmentTheory and Practice, in CARROTS, STICKS, AND SERMONS: POLICY INSTRUMENTS AND THEIR EVALUATION 77, 77 (Marie-Louise Bemelmans-Videc et al. eds., 2007) (reporting that major European countries spend between twenty and thirty-five percent of their GDP on grants and subsidies)
    • (2007) The Carrot: Subsidies As a Tool of GovernmentTheory and Practice , vol.77 , pp. 77
    • Frans, L.L.1
  • 373
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • cf. Calabresi &Melamed, supra note 21, at 1117 (noting that a rule under which victims compensate polluters for limiting their right to pollute "may well be the most frequent device employed").
    • Supra Note , pp. 1117
  • 374
    • 84861470098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For overviews.
  • 377
    • 0141621425 scopus 로고
    • The Coase Theorem in a Rent-Seeking Society
    • note
    • See Chulho Jung et al., The Coase Theorem in a Rent-Seeking Society, 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 259, 261 (1995) (noting that dispersed interests are less likely to be able to defend an efficient choice of policy instrument that favors them).
    • (1995) 15 INT'L REV. L. & ECON , vol.259 , pp. 261
    • Chulho, J.1
  • 378
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Merrill, supra note 97, at 287-89 (arguing that public choice theory explains successful political opposition to a carbon tax).
    • Supra Note , pp. 287-289
  • 379
    • 84861463271 scopus 로고
    • Public Choice and Just Compensation
    • note
    • See Daniel A. Farber, Public Choice and Just Compensation, 9 CONST. COMMENT. 279, 292-93 (1992) (arguing that requiring compensation for takings increases takings because the costs of compensation are not paid for by direct beneficiaries but instead come from the federal treasury).
    • (1992) 9 CONST. COMMENT , vol.279 , pp. 292-293
    • Daniel, A.F.1
  • 380
    • 0347776234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy
    • note
    • Nathaniel O. Keohane et al., The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy, 22 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 313, 347-48 (1998) (explaining that firms may oppose efficient regulations when redistribution from the firm exceeds the firm's share of social welfare gains).
    • (1998) 22 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV , vol.313 , pp. 347-348
    • Nathaniel, O.K.1
  • 382
    • 3142707241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Common Interest Tragedies
    • note
    • see Lee Anne Fennell, Common Interest Tragedies, 98 NW. U. L. REV. 907, 913-25 (2004).
    • (2004) 98 NW. U. L. REV , vol.907 , pp. 913-925
    • Lee, A.F.1
  • 385
    • 84861475875 scopus 로고
    • Poverty, Democracy, and Constitutional Law
    • note
    • See Stephen Loffredo, Poverty, Democracy, and Constitutional Law, 141 U. PA. L. REV. 1277, 1327-28 (1993). If the group of beneficiaries is relatively easy to organize, however, an initial lack of resources may be unimportant. Entrepreneurs might be willing to organize and advocate for the beneficiaries in exchange for their political support, or for a portion of the other expected proceeds of their victory.
    • (1993) 141 U. PA. L. REV , vol.1277 , pp. 1327-1328
    • Stephen, L.1
  • 386
    • 0346934154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harnessing Politics: The Dynamics of Offset Requirements in the Tax Legislative Process
    • note
    • See Elizabeth Garrett, Harnessing Politics: The Dynamics of Offset Requirements in the Tax Legislative Process, 65 U. CHI. L. REV. 501, 518-19 (1998).
    • (1998) 65 U. CHI. L. REV , vol.501 , pp. 518-519
    • Elizabeth, G.1
  • 387
    • 0347528336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schroeder, Rational Choice Versus Republican MomentExplanations for Environmental Laws
    • note
    • See Christopher H. Schroeder, Rational Choice Versus Republican MomentExplanations for Environmental Laws, 1969-73, 9 DUKE ENVTL. L. & POL'Y F. 29, 49-56 (1998).
    • (1998) 9 DUKE ENVTL. L. & POL'Y F , vol.29 , pp. 49-56
    • Christopher, H.1
  • 388
    • 84861467438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The basic problem is that if the state persists in redistribution efforts, those who are burdened in excess of their local benefits will leave, threatening local prosperity and local officials' electoral prospects.
  • 390
    • 45949113367 scopus 로고
    • Assistance to the Poor in a Federal System
    • note
    • See Charles C. Brown & Wallace E. Oates, Assistance to the Poor in a Federal System, 32 J. PUB. ECON. 307, 328 (1987).
    • (1987) 32 J. PUB. ECON , vol.307 , pp. 328
    • Charles, C.B.1    Wallace, E.O.2
  • 391
    • 36348936243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Role in State Taxation: A Normative Approach
    • William F. Fox & John A. Swain, The Federal Role in State Taxation: A Normative Approach, 60 NAT'L TAX J. 611, 614-15 (2007).
    • (2007) 60 NAT'L TAX J , vol.611 , pp. 614-615
    • William, F.F.1    John, A.S.2
  • 392
    • 84861463138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This tactic is not unheard of. For example, the Charlotte Bobcats reportedly signed a contract with the City of Charlotte agreeing to pay a $200 million termination fee if they break the lease on their arena and move to another city. A Look at Potential NBA Relocation Candidates, SEATTLE TIMES (July 13, 2008, 12:00 AM), http://seattletimes.nwsource.com/html/nba/2008048569_sonichart13.html.
    • (2008) A Look At Potential NBA Relocation Candidates
  • 393
    • 84861470129 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Am. Trucking Ass'ns v. Scheiner, 483 U.S. 266, 284 (1987) (holding that states cannot "plac[e] a financial barrier" at their borders). On the Court's willingness to abide incentives for entry.
    • (1987) , vol.266 , pp. 284
  • 395
    • 84861464354 scopus 로고
    • note
    • and Allied Stores of Ohio, Inc. v. Bowers, 358 U.S. 522, 532-33 (1959) (Brennan, J., concurring) (suggesting that the Court's equal protection decisions could be reconciled on the grounds that states can reward newcomers but not punish them).
    • (1959) Allied Stores of Ohio, Inc. V. Bowers , vol.522 , pp. 532-533
  • 396
    • 84861466433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • But see Cuno v. DaimlerChrysler, Inc., 386 F.3d 738, 742-48 (6th Cir. 2004) (holding that selective state tax benefit for in-state manufacturer violated the dormant Commerce Clause), rev'd on other grounds, 547 U.S. 332 (2006).
    • (2004) Cuno V. DaimLerChrysler, Inc , vol.738 , pp. 742-748
  • 397
    • 0043189804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enrich, Saving the States from Themselves: Commerce Clause Constraints on State Tax Incentives for Business
    • note
    • See Peter D. Enrich, Saving the States from Themselves: Commerce Clause Constraints on State Tax Incentives for Business, 110 HARV. L. REV. 377, 382-405, 440-48 (1996) (arguing against state-level relocation incentives).
    • (1996) 110 HARV. L. REV , vol.377 , pp. 382-405
    • Peter, D.1
  • 398
    • 84861467022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For overviews of the doctrines.
  • 402
    • 0348199093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Precommitment Politics
    • note
    • see also Saul Levmore, Precommitment Politics, 82 VA. L. REV. 567, 571-72, 581 (1996).
    • (1996) 82 VA. L. REV , vol.567 , Issue.581 , pp. 571-572
    • Saul, L.1
  • 403
    • 84861465550 scopus 로고
    • On the Accelerating Rate and Decreasing Durability of Tax Reform
    • note
    • See Richard L. Doernberg & Fred S. McChesney, On the Accelerating Rate and Decreasing Durability of Tax Reform, 71 MINN. L. REV. 913, 946 (1987).
    • (1987) 71 MINN. L. REV , vol.913 , pp. 946
    • Richard, L.D.1    Fred, S.M.2
  • 404
    • 84861464800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I say "in their archetypical forms" here because my framework also defines a stick as any painful departure from the status quo. So a stick may simply be a reduction in a preexisting carrot program, in which case the sharp ease-of-monitoring distinction between the two instruments fades.
  • 405
    • 84861465290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a cogent summary of the law on suits to force government action.
  • 406
    • 10844252962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judicial Review of Agency Inaction: An Arbitrariness Approach
    • note
    • see Lisa Schultz Bressman, Judicial Review of Agency Inaction: An Arbitrariness Approach, 79 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1657, 1664-74 (2004). On the questionable status of private suits by thirdparty beneficiaries.
    • (2004) 79 N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.1657 , pp. 1664-1674
    • Lisa, S.B.1
  • 407
    • 63849131867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spending Clause Litigation in the Roberts Court
    • note
    • see Samuel R. Bagenstos, Spending Clause Litigation in the Roberts Court, 58 DUKE L.J. 345, 385-93 (2008).
    • (2008) 58 DUKE L.J , vol.345 , pp. 385-393
    • Samuel, R.B.1
  • 408
    • 84861477949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public Rights and Private Rights of Action: The Enforcement of Federal Election Laws
    • note
    • and Daniel P. Tokaji, Public Rights and Private Rights of Action: The Enforcement of Federal Election Laws, 44 IND. L. REV. 113, 125-37 (2010).
    • (2010) 44 IND. L. REV , vol.113 , pp. 125-137
    • Daniel, P.T.1
  • 409
    • 84861466393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two Wrongs Don't Add Up to Rights: The Importance of Preserving Due Process in Light of Recent Welfare Reform Measures
    • note
    • See Rebecca E. Zietlow, Two Wrongs Don't Add Up to Rights: The Importance of Preserving Due Process in Light of Recent Welfare Reform Measures, 45 AM. U. L. REV. 1111, 1121-26, 1137-39 (1996) (explaining the right to challenge an individualized denial and summarizing case law distinguishing that right from the opportunity to challenge general government policy shifts).
    • (1996) 45 AM. U. L. REV , vol.1111 , pp. 1121-1126
    • Rebecca, E.Z.1
  • 410
    • 34948897219 scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Regan V. Taxation with Representation of Wash., 461 U.S. 540, 544 (1983). 250. United States v. Am. Library Ass'n, 539 U.S. 194, 212 (2003) (Rehnquist, C.J.) (plurality opinion).
    • (1983) Taxation With Representation of Wash , vol.540 , pp. 544
    • Regan, V.1
  • 411
    • 84861462907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Regan, 461 U.S. at 544.
    • Regan , pp. 544
  • 412
    • 46749096507 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rust V. Sullivan, 500 U.S. 173, 193 (1991).
    • (1991) Sullivan , vol.173 , pp. 193
    • Rust, V.1
  • 413
    • 84861476968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Citizens United v. FEC, 130 S. Ct. 876, 896-97 (2010).
    • (2010) FEC, 130 S. Ct , vol.876 , pp. 896-897
  • 414
    • 84861470594 scopus 로고
    • Lobbying and the Public Interest: Rethinking the Internal Revenue Code's Treatment of Legislative Activities
    • note
    • See Miriam Galston, Lobbying and the Public Interest: Rethinking the Internal Revenue Code's Treatment of Legislative Activities, 71 TEX. L. REV. 1269, 1282-1314 (1993).
    • (1993) 71 TEX. L. REV , vol.1269 , pp. 1282-1314
    • Miriam, G.1
  • 415
    • 84861475106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress, Public Values, and the Financing of Public Choice
    • note
    • E.g., Mary L. Heen, Congress, Public Values, and the Financing of Public Choice, 65 OHIO ST. L.J. 853, 898-910 (2004).
    • (2004) 65 OHIO ST. L.J , vol.853 , pp. 898-910
    • Mary, L.H.1
  • 416
    • 84861475635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kleinbard, supra note 9, at 18-20. 256.
    • Supra Note , vol.256 , pp. 18-20
  • 417
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Galle & Klick, supra note 185, at 237-38.
    • Supra Note , pp. 237-238
  • 418
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Galle & Klick, supra note 185, at 237-38.
    • Supra Note , pp. 237-238
  • 419
    • 84861476978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, in many cases sophisticates may be at odds with the interests of the general public.
  • 420
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Keohane et al., supra note 231, at 359 (claiming that hidden costs facilitate enactment of environmental regulations that disfavor the general public). In that situation, transparency would presumably increase lobbying by both the public and also the sophisticates who must attempt to outweigh them.
    • Supra Note , pp. 359
  • 421
    • 84861468100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For additional skepticism that tax-expenditure opacity can be cured simply by disclosure, and the comment that many other forms of government transfers are just as hidden.
  • 422
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Roin, supra note 31, at 624.
    • Supra Note , pp. 624
  • 423
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., STERNER, supra note 7, at 196.
    • Supra Note , pp. 196
  • 424
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Engel et al., supra note 7, at 669.
    • Supra Note , pp. 669
  • 425
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mestelman, supra note 7, at 187.
    • Supra Note , pp. 187
  • 426
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Levmore, supra note 132, at 1665-66 (suggesting that a commitment against occasional payoffs to "losers" of new regulatory policy would reduce the amount of good new policy overall).
    • Supra Note , pp. 1665-1666
  • 429
    • 0040912026 scopus 로고
    • Jobs and Environmental Quality: Some Implications for Instrument Choice
    • note
    • Cf. Robert W. Hahn, Jobs and Environmental Quality: Some Implications for Instrument Choice, 20 POL'Y SCI. 289, 299 (1987) (reporting that voters respond to the perceived, rather than actual, impact of costs and benefits).
    • (1987) 20 POL'Y SCI , vol.289 , pp. 299
    • Robert, W.H.1
  • 430
    • 0347745996 scopus 로고
    • Constituency Influences on Legislative Policy Choice
    • note
    • Mathew D. McCubbins & Terry Sullivan, Constituency Influences on Legislative Policy Choice, 18 QUALITY & QUANTITY 299, 301-02 (1984) (same).
    • (1984) 18 QUALITY & QUANTITY , vol.299 , pp. 301-302
    • Mathew, D.M.1    Sullivan, T.2
  • 431
    • 0000599191 scopus 로고
    • Selling Pollution, Forcing Democracy
    • note
    • See Lisa Heinzerling, Selling Pollution, Forcing Democracy, 14 STAN. ENVTL. L.J. 300, 330 (1995) (describing grandfathering of permits as a tool for winning political support from polluters).
    • (1995) 14 STAN. ENVTL. L.J , vol.300 , pp. 330
    • Lisa, H.1
  • 432
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Stavins, supra note 8, at 351 (describing the political advantage of cap and trade as avoiding a "focus" on higher costs).
    • Supra Note , pp. 351
  • 433
    • 84861472836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carbon's Power Brokers
    • note
    • See, e.g., George F. Will, Editorial, Carbon's Power Brokers, WASH. POST, June 1, 2008, at B7. For evidence on the importance of framing on public perception of energy taxes.
    • (2008) WASH. POST, June 1 , pp. 7
    • George, F.W.1
  • 434
    • 48949093821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pollution Tax Heuristics: An Empirical Study of Willingness to Pay Higher Gasoline Taxes
    • note
    • see Shi-Ling Hsu et al., Pollution Tax Heuristics: An Empirical Study of Willingness to Pay Higher Gasoline Taxes, 36 ENERGY POL'Y 3612, 3617-18 (2008).
    • (2008) 36 ENERGY POL'Y , vol.3612 , pp. 3617-3618
    • Shi-Ling, H.1
  • 435
    • 84861470973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I am grateful to Darien Shanske for this point.
  • 436
    • 26444550912 scopus 로고
    • Overt and Covert Bailouts: Developing a Public Bailout Policy
    • note
    • See, e.g., Cheryl D. Block, Overt and Covert Bailouts: Developing a Public Bailout Policy, 67 IND. L.J. 951, 968-72 (1992).
    • (1992) 67 IND. L.J , vol.951 , pp. 968-972
    • Cheryl, D.B.1
  • 437
    • 79951690171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parchment and Politics: The Positive Puzzle of Constitutional Commitment
    • Daryl J. Levinson, Parchment and Politics: The Positive Puzzle of Constitutional Commitment, 124 HARV. L. REV. 657, 672-97 (2011).
    • (2011) 124 HARV. L. REV , vol.657 , pp. 672-697
    • Daryl, J.L.1
  • 438
    • 84855442515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bankrupt Politics and the Politics of Bankruptcy
    • note
    • Adam Levitin, Bankrupt Politics and the Politics of Bankruptcy, 97 CORNELL L. REV. (forthcoming 2012) (manuscript at 19-23).
    • (2012) 97 CORNELL L. REV , pp. 19-23
    • Adam, A.L.1
  • 439
    • 79955570431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Failure Is an Option: An Ersatz-Antitrust Approach to Financial Regulation
    • Jonathan R. Macey & James P. Holdcroft, Jr., Failure Is an Option: An Ersatz-Antitrust Approach to Financial Regulation, 120 YALE L.J. 1368, 1375-90 (2011).
    • (2011) 120 YALE L.J , vol.1368 , pp. 1375-1390
    • Jonathan, R.M.1    James, P.H.2
  • 440
    • 84861476093 scopus 로고
    • The Welfare Loss of Excess Health Insurance
    • Martin S. Feldstein, The Welfare Loss of Excess Health Insurance, 81 J. POL. ECON. 251 (1973).
    • (1973) 81 J. POL. ECON , vol.251
    • Martin, S.F.1
  • 441
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., Macey & Holdcroft, supra note 267, at 1370.
    • Supra Note , pp. 1370
  • 442
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Galle & Klick, supra note 185, at 200-02 (explaining causes of present bias among state and local policymakers).
    • Supra Note , pp. 200-202
  • 443
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Levinson, supra note 267, at 661-62, 672-81.
    • Supra Note , pp. 661-662
  • 444
    • 0003110110 scopus 로고
    • The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy
    • note
    • Terry M. Moe, The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy, in ORGANIZATION THEORY: FROM CHESTER BARNARD TO THE PRESENT AND BEYOND 116, 137 (Oliver E. Williamson ed., 1990).
    • (1990) ORGANIZATION THEORY: , vol.116 , pp. 137
    • Terry, M.M.1
  • 445
    • 0001521599 scopus 로고
    • Bureaucratic Drift, Coalitional Drift, and Time Consistency: A Comment on Macey
    • Kenneth A. Shepsle, Bureaucratic Drift, Coalitional Drift, and Time Consistency: A Comment on Macey, 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 111, 114 (1992).
    • (1992) 8 J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.111 , pp. 114
    • Kenneth, A.S.1
  • 446
    • 0001047705 scopus 로고
    • The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective
    • note
    • See William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective, 18 J.L. & ECON. 875 (1975).
    • (1975) 18 J.L. & ECON , vol.875
    • William, M.L.1    Richard, A.P.2
  • 447
    • 79952750731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Insulating Agencies: Avoiding Capture Through Institutional Design
    • Rachel E. Barkow, Insulating Agencies: Avoiding Capture Through Institutional Design, 89 TEX. L. REV. 15, 21 (2010).
    • (2010) 89 TEX. L. REV , vol.15 , pp. 21
    • Rachel, E.B.1
  • 448
    • 77953266344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Agency Independence
    • Lisa Schultz Bressman & Robert B. Thompson, The Future of Agency Independence, 63 VAND. L. REV. 599, 613-14 (2010).
    • (2010) 63 VAND. L. REV , vol.599 , pp. 613-614
    • Lisa, S.B.1    Robert, B.2
  • 449
    • 84861475240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • E.g., POSNER, supra note 48, at 868-69, 871.
    • Supra Note , vol.871 , pp. 868-869
  • 450
    • 84861473952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Interstate Institutions: The Example of the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Agreement ("SSUTA")
    • note
    • Cf. Brian Galle, Designing Interstate Institutions: The Example of the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Agreement ("SSUTA"), 40 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 1381, 1414 (2007) (explaining entrenchment of appointed personnel as deriving from the value that the appointer assigns to the delegate's connections within and knowledge of their institution).
    • (2007) 40 U.C. DAVIS L. REV , vol.1381 , pp. 1414
    • Brian, G.1
  • 451
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Levinson, supra note 267, at 694-97 (suggesting that political institutions achieve insulation from politics in part because they are structured to favor certain outcomes).
    • Supra Note , pp. 694-697
  • 452
    • 84858661701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond Bailouts: Federal Tools for Preventing State Budget Crises
    • Brian Galle & Kirk J. Stark, Beyond Bailouts: Federal Tools for Preventing State Budget Crises, 87 IND. L.J. 599, 619-41 (2012).
    • (2012) 87 IND. L.J , vol.599 , pp. 619-641
    • Brian, G.1    Kirk, J.S.2
  • 453
    • 84860163305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commitment Bonds
    • Michael Abramowicz & Ian Ayres, Commitment Bonds, 100 GEO. L.J. 605, 622-44 (2012).
    • (2012) 100 GEO. L.J , vol.605 , pp. 622-644
    • Michael, A.1    Ian, A.2
  • 454
    • 84860163305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commitment Bonds
    • Michael Abramowicz & Ian Ayres, Commitment Bonds, 100 GEO. L.J. 605, 622-44 (2012). at 33.
    • (2012) 100 GEO. L.J , vol.605 , Issue.33 , pp. 622-644
    • Michael, A.1    Ian, A.2
  • 455
    • 84861475060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an example of a skilled combined analysis of several of these factors together.
  • 456
    • 67949120247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Taxing Sovereign Wealth
    • note
    • see Victor Fleischer, A Theory of Taxing Sovereign Wealth, 84 N.Y.U. L. REV. 440, 494-503 (2009). On the use of information as a regulatory tool.
    • (2009) 84 N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.440 , pp. 494-503
    • Victor, F.1
  • 457
    • 0347745194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Information as Environmental Regulation: TRI and Performance Benchmarking, Precursor to a New Paradigm?
    • note
    • see Bradley C. Karkkainen, Information as Environmental Regulation: TRI and Performance Benchmarking, Precursor to a New Paradigm?, 89 GEO. L.J. 257, 286-345 (2001).
    • (2001) 89 GEO. L.J , vol.257 , pp. 286-345
    • Bradley, C.K.1
  • 458
    • 84861476958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Sermon: Information Programs in the Public Policy Process-Choice, Effects, and Evaluation
    • note
    • Evert Vedung & Frans C.J. van der Doelen, The Sermon: Information Programs in the Public Policy Process-Choice, Effects, and Evaluation, in CARROTS, STICKS, AND SERMONS: POLICY INSTRUMENTS AND THEIR EVALUATION.
    • CARROTS, STICKS, and SERMONS
    • Evert, V.1    van der Frans, C.J.D.2
  • 459
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • supra note 228, at 103.
    • Supra Note , pp. 103
  • 460
    • 84861471491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For some prior discussions of carrot/stick combinations.
  • 461
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Engel et al., supra note 7, at 669.
    • Supra Note , pp. 669
  • 462
    • 84872536924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Smith, supra note 65, at 695-96.
    • Supra Note , pp. 695-696
  • 463
    • 0000172445 scopus 로고
    • Separation of Ownership and Control
    • note
    • See Eugene F. Fama & Michael C. Jensen, Separation of Ownership and Control, 26 J.L. & ECON. 301, 302-11 (1983).
    • (1983) 26 J.L. & ECON , vol.301 , pp. 302-311
    • Eugene, F.F.1    Michael, C.J.2
  • 464
    • 81255208366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Levinson, supra note 136, at 356-57.
    • Supra Note , pp. 356-357


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.