메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 124, Issue 3, 2011, Pages 657-746

Parchment and politics: The positive puzzle of constitutional commitment

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79951690171     PISSN: 0017811X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (142)

References (522)
  • 1
    • 79951703888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This skeptical question dates back at least to Thomas Hobbes, who doubted whether Leviathan could be bound by any kind of law. Hobbes's logic is simple and still compelling though far from dispositive: "For Leviathan having power to make, and repeale Lawes, he may when he pleaseth, free himselfe from that subjection, by repealing those Lawes that trouble him, and making of new.... He that is bound to himselfe onely, is not bound."
    • This skeptical question dates back at least to Thomas Hobbes, who doubted whether Leviathan could be bound by any kind of law. Hobbes's logic is simple and still compelling (though far from dispositive): "For [Leviathan] having power to make, and repeale Lawes, he may when he pleaseth, free himselfe from that subjection, by repealing those Lawes that trouble him, and making of new.... [H]e that is bound to himselfe onely, is not bound."
  • 2
    • 79951703889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard Tuck ed., Cambridge Univ. Press rev. student ed
    • THOMAS HOBBES, LEVIATHAN 184 (Richard Tuck ed., Cambridge Univ. Press rev. student ed. 1996) (1651).
    • (1996) Leviathan , vol.184 , Issue.1651
    • Thomas, H.1
  • 3
    • 70350033690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutional constraints
    • See, noting the normative orientation of constitutional theorists and their lack of attention to the general topic of "constitutional constraints"
    • See Richard H. Fallon, Jr., Constitutional Constraints, 97 CALIF. L. REV. 975, 977 (2009) (noting the normative orientation of constitutional theorists and their lack of attention to the general topic of "constitutional constraints").
    • (2009) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.97 , Issue.977 , pp. 975
    • Fallon Jr., H.F.1
  • 6
    • 79951705581 scopus 로고
    • We the people: Foundations
    • See, hereinafter Ack-ERMAN, FOUNDATIONS
    • See I BRUCE ACKERMAN, WE THE PEOPLE: FOUNDATIONS (1991) [hereinafter Ack-ERMAN, FOUNDATIONS]; 2 BRUCE ACKERMAN, WE THE PEOPLE: TRANSFORMATIONS (1998).
    • (1991) Bruce Ackerman, We the People: Transformations , vol.2
    • Bruce, I.A.1
  • 7
    • 42049097720 scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Carolene Prods. Co., 152
    • See United States v. Carolene Prods. Co., 304 U. S. 144, 152 n. 4 (1938);
    • (1938) U. S , vol.304 , Issue.4 , pp. 144
  • 9
    • 79951693637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ulysses rebound
    • See, 161
    • See Scott J. Shapiro, Ulysses Rebound, 18 ECON. & PHIL. 157, 161 (2002).
    • (2002) Econ. & Phil. , vol.18 , pp. 157
    • Shapiro, S.J.1
  • 11
    • 0042170056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "When the devil turns... ": The political foundations of independent judicial review
    • 60
    • Matthew C. Stephenson, "When the Devil Turns... ": The Political Foundations of Independent Judicial Review, 32 J. LEGAL STUD. 59, 60 (2003);
    • (2003) J. Legal Stud , vol.32 , pp. 59
    • Stephenson, M.C.1
  • 12
    • 79951702192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, observing that "the Court cannot stand outside of politics and exercise a unique role as guardian of constitutional verities" because "the Court's judgments will have no force unless other powerful political actors accept the. priority of the judicial voice"
    • see also KEITH E. WHITTINGTON, POLITICAL FOUNDATIONS OF JUDICIAL SUPREMACY 26 (2007) (observing that "[t]he Court cannot stand outside of politics and exercise a unique role as guardian of constitutional verities" because "the Court's judgments will have no force unless other powerful political actors accept the... priority of the judicial voice").
    • (2007) Political Foundations of Judicial Supremacy , vol.26
    • Keith, E.W.1
  • 13
    • 84894630583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Madison Clinton Rossiter ed.
    • THE FEDERALIST NO. 48, at 305 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 2003).
    • (2003) The Federalist No. 48 , pp. 305
  • 15
    • 79951696474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 163, Madison's illustration was prescient: "Should a Rebellion or insurrection alarm the people as well as the Government, and a suspension of the writ of habeas corpus be dictated by the alarm, no written prohibitions on earth would prevent the measure."
    • Id. at 163. Madison's illustration was prescient: "Should a Rebellion or insurrection alarm the people as well as the Government, and a suspension of the [writ of habeas corpus] be dictated by the alarm, no written prohibitions on earth would prevent the measure."
  • 16
    • 79951706941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 17
    • 79951685140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Further limits were suggested by Madison's skepticism about the capacity of political actors for moral self-restraint:, It was futile, he argued, to expect restraint from ordinary legislators who typically sought office for ambition and self-interest. Even less faith could be placed in the people at large. Experience taught that neither "a prudent regard" for the general good nor "respect for character" nor even religion could deter an impassioned or interested majority from pursuing "unjust violations of the rights and interests of the minority, or of individuals."
    • Further limits were suggested by Madison's skepticism about the capacity of political actors for moral self-restraint: It was futile, he argued, to expect restraint from ordinary legislators who typically sought office for ambition and self-interest.... Even less faith could be placed in the people at large. Experience taught that neither "a prudent regard" for the general good nor "respect for character" nor even religion could deter an impassioned or interested majority from pursuing "unjust violations of the rights and interests of the minority, or of individuals."
  • 19
    • 79952956944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • classic statement of this general concern is Madison's
    • The classic statement of this general concern is Madison's The Federalist No. 10.
    • The Federalist No. 10
  • 23
    • 79951715251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison's view was based in large part on the experience of state governments in the decade leading up to the Constitutional Convention
    • Madison's view was based in large part on the experience of state governments in the decade leading up to the Constitutional Convention. JACK N. RAKOVE, ORIGINAL MEANINGS 290, 313-16 (1996).
    • (1996) Original Meanings , vol.290 , pp. 313-316
    • Jack, N.R.1
  • 24
    • 79951690540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 161-62
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 161-62.
  • 25
    • 79951691640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 161
    • Id. at 161.
  • 26
    • 79951696684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra p. 668 Other Federalists shared Madison's view
    • See infra p. 668 Other Federalists shared Madison's view.
  • 27
    • 79951701053 scopus 로고
    • See, recounting Noah Webster's rollicking argument to the same effect. as Roger Sherman put the basic point: "No bill of rights ever yet bound the supreme power longer than the honeymoon of a new married couple, unless the rulers were interested in preserving the rights...."
    • See GORDON S. WOOD, THE CREATION OF THE AMERICAN REPUBLIC, 1776-1787, at 376-82 (1969) (recounting Noah Webster's rollicking argument to the same effect). as Roger Sherman put the basic point: "No bill of rights ever yet bound the supreme power longer than the honeymoon of a new married couple, unless the rulers were interested in preserving the rights...."
    • (1969) Wood, the Creation of the American Republic , vol.1776-1787 , pp. 376-382
    • Gordon, S.1
  • 29
    • 79951684751 scopus 로고
    • reprinted in, Paul Leicester Ford ed., Brooklyn, Historical Printing Club, emphases omitted
    • reprinted in ESSAYS ON THE CONSTITUTION OF THE UNITED STATES 218, 219 (Paul Leicester Ford ed., Brooklyn, Historical Printing Club 1892) (emphases omitted).
    • (1892) Essays On the Constitution of the United States , vol.218 , pp. 219
  • 30
    • 79951701054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162.
  • 31
    • 79951694366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See AMAR, supra note 13, at 3-133
    • See AMAR, supra note 13, at 3-133.
  • 32
    • 79951719429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162. This assumption might seem peculiar given that, throughout history, minority rule-by means of superior wealth, arms, or organization-has probably been the norm. Still, the assumption that the majority would ultimately win out, through force if not politics, has been a common and important premise of much political and legal theory
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162. This assumption might seem peculiar given that, throughout history, minority rule-by means of superior wealth, arms, or organization-has probably been the norm. Still, the assumption that the majority would ultimately win out, through force if not politics, has been a common and important premise of much political and legal theory.
  • 33
    • 77958116726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The force of majority rule
    • See, Working Paper No. 08-48, available at
    • See Adrian Vermeule, The Force of Majority Rule (Harvard Law Sch. Pub. Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series, Working Paper No. 08-48, 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1280201.
    • (2008) Harvard Law Sch. Pub. Law & Legal Theory Research Paper Series
    • Vermeule, A.1
  • 34
    • 79951698420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162.
  • 37
    • 79951706367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Madison explained: Extend the sphere and you take in a greater variety of parties and interests; you make it less probable that a majority of the whole will have a common motive to invade the rights of other citizens; or if such a common motive exists, it will be more difficult for all who feel it to discover their own strength and to act in unison with each other
    • Id. Madison explained: Extend the sphere and you take in a greater variety of parties and interests; you make it less probable that a majority of the whole will have a common motive to invade the rights of other citizens; or if such a common motive exists, it will be more difficult for all who feel it to discover their own strength and to act in unison with each other.
  • 38
    • 79951717521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 39
    • 0346584258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, supra note 9, "The society itself will be broken into so many parts, interests and classes of citizens, that the rights of individuals, or of the minority, will be in little danger from interested combinations of the majority."
    • see also THE FEDERALIST NO. 51 (James Madison), supra note 9, at 321 ("[T]he society itself will be broken into so many parts, interests and classes of citizens, that the rights of individuals, or of the minority, will be in little danger from interested combinations of the majority.").
    • The Federalist No 51 , pp. 321
    • Madison, J.1
  • 43
    • 84935178662 scopus 로고
    • Interest groups in American public law
    • see also, 41-42
    • see also Cass R. Sunstein, Interest Groups in American Public Law, 38 STAN. L. REV. 29, 41-42 (1985).
    • (1985) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.38 , pp. 29
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 44
    • 79951705999 scopus 로고
    • Speech to the virginia constitutional convention
    • Ralph Ketcham ed.
    • James Madison, Speech to the Virginia Constitutional Convention (1829), in SELECTED WRITINGS OF JAMES MADISON 354, 355 (Ralph Ketcham ed., 2006).
    • (1829) Selected Writings of James Madison , vol.354 , pp. 355
    • Madison, J.1
  • 45
    • 0346584258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 9, Courts and constitutional theorists continue to believe that the competition between the legislative and executive branches results in a self-enforcing balance of power
    • THE FEDERALIST NO. 51 (James Madison), supra note 9, at 319. Courts and constitutional theorists continue to believe that the competition between the legislative and executive branches results in a self-enforcing balance of power.
    • The Federalist No. 51 , pp. 319
    • Madison, J.1
  • 46
    • 13244256992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empire-building government in constitutional law
    • See, 950-51
    • See Daryl J. Levinson, Empire-Building Government in Constitutional Law, 118 HARV. L. REV. 915, 950-51 (2005).
    • (2005) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.118 , pp. 915
    • Levinson, D.J.1
  • 47
    • 0040329316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 9, Here too, courts and constitutional theorists continue to believe that competition for power between the states and the federal government will create a self-enforcing set of "political safeguards" for federalism
    • See THE FEDERALIST NO. 45 (James Madison), supra note 9, at 285-90. Here too, courts and constitutional theorists continue to believe that competition for power between the states and the federal government will create a self-enforcing set of "political safeguards" for federalism.
    • The Federalist No. 45 , pp. 285-290
    • Madison, J.1
  • 48
    • 79951688341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 938-40
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 938-40.
  • 51
    • 79951705211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 7, using "incentive compatibility" in this sense
    • See TUSHNET, supra note 7, at 95-96 (using "incentive compatibility" in this sense).
    • Tushnet , pp. 95-96
  • 53
    • 79951707907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 319
    • Id. at 319.
  • 54
    • 79951718497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 926-32, 950-53
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 926-32, 950-53.
  • 55
    • 79951711417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 231-53 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 231-53 and accompanying text.
  • 56
    • 79951714142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enumeration and other constitutional strategies for protecting rights: The view from 1787/1791
    • See, 361-66, explicating the Framers' belief that structural protection for constitutional rights and values would be more secure than enumerating rights, though without explaining the basis for this belief
    • See Mark A. Graber, Enumeration and Other Constitutional Strategies for Protecting Rights: The View from 1787/1791, 9 U. PA. J. CONST. L. 357, 361-66 (2007) (explicating the Framers' belief that structural protection for constitutional rights and values would be more secure than enumerating rights, though without explaining the basis for this belief).
    • (2007) U. Pa. J. Const. L , vol.9 , pp. 357
    • Graber, M.A.1
  • 59
    • 54749158216 scopus 로고
    • Contract law and the state of nature
    • See, 11-20
    • See Anthony T. Kronman, Contract Law and the State of Nature, 1 J. L. Econ. & Org. 5, 11-20 (1985).
    • (1985) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.1 , pp. 5
    • Kronman, A.T.1
  • 60
    • 0000079986 scopus 로고
    • Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry
    • see, e.g.
    • see, e.g., Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115 (1992);
    • (1992) J. Legal Stud. , vol.21 , pp. 115
    • Bernstein, L.1
  • 61
    • 0001103387 scopus 로고
    • Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The maghribi traders' coalition
    • Avner Greif, Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 525 (1993);
    • (1993) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 525
    • Greif, A.1
  • 62
    • 84924196668 scopus 로고
    • Coordination, commitment, and enforcement: The case of the merchant guild
    • Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994);
    • (1994) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.102 , pp. 745
    • Greif, A.1
  • 63
    • 84984499607 scopus 로고
    • The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The law merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs
    • Paul R. Milgrom et al., The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 ECON. & POL. 1 (1990).
    • (1990) Econ. & Pol. , vol.2 , pp. 1
    • Milgrom, P.R.1
  • 64
    • 0000643498 scopus 로고
    • Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans
    • See, &, 477, Kydland and Prescott offer this widely cited example:, Suppose the socially desirable outcome is not to have houses built in a particular flood plain but, given that they are there, to take certain costly flood-control measures. If the government's policy were not to build the dams and levees needed for flood protection and agents knew this was the case, even if houses were built there, rational agents would not live in the flood plains. But the rational agent knows that, if he and others build houses there, the government will take the necessary flood-control measures. Consequently, in the absence of a law prohibiting the construction of houses in the flood plain, houses are built there, and the army corps of engineers subsequently builds the dams and levees
    • See Finn E. Kydland & Edward C. Prescott, Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans, 85 J. POL. ECON. 473, 477 (1977). Kydland and Prescott offer this widely cited example: [S]uppose the socially desirable outcome is not to have houses built in a particular flood plain but, given that they are there, to take certain costly flood-control measures. If the government's policy were not to build the dams and levees needed for flood protection and agents knew this was the case, even if houses were built there, rational agents would not live in the flood plains. But the rational agent knows that, if he and others build houses there, the government will take the necessary flood-control measures. Consequently, in the absence of a law prohibiting the construction of houses in the flood plain, houses are built there, and the army corps of engineers subsequently builds the dams and levees.
    • (1977) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.85 , pp. 473
    • Kydland, F.E.1    Prescott, E.C.2
  • 65
    • 79951718271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 66
    • 0347911960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why not a political coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics
    • See, 633-38
    • See Daron Acemoglu, Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics, 31 J. COMP. ECON. 620, 633-38 (2003);
    • (2003) J. Comp. Econ. , vol.31 , pp. 620
    • Acemoglu, D.1
  • 67
    • 0003076801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sources of inefficiency in a representative democracy: A dynamic analysis
    • Timothy Besley & Stephen Coate, Sources of Inefficiency in a Representative Democracy: A Dynamic Analysis, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 139 (1998);
    • (1998) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 139
    • Besley, T.1    Coate, S.2
  • 68
    • 0347809840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The private uses of public interests: Incentives and institutions
    • Spring, 8-11
    • Joseph Stiglitz, The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions, J. ECON. PERSP., Spring 1998, at 3, 8-11.
    • (1998) J. Econ. Persp. , pp. 3
    • Stiglitz, J.1
  • 69
    • 0001984417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commitment problems and the spread of ethnic conflict
    • See, in, David A. Lake & Donald Rothchild eds.
    • See James D. Fearon, Commitment Problems and the Spread of Ethnic Conflict, in THE INTERNATIONAL SPREAD OF ETHNIC CONFLICT 107 (David A. Lake & Donald Rothchild eds., 1998);
    • (1998) The International Spread of Ethnic Conflict , pp. 107
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 70
    • 84972159336 scopus 로고
    • Rationalist explanations for war
    • 401-09
    • James D. Fearon, Rationalist Explanations for War, 49 INT'L ORG. 379, 401-09 (1995).
    • (1995) Int'L Org. , vol.49 , pp. 379
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 73
    • 79951696290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOLMES, supra note 3, at 161-75
    • See HOLMES, supra note 3, at 161-75.
  • 74
    • 79951709023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 202-35
    • See id. at 202-35.
  • 75
    • 79951688340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We might view personal identity in the same way, as comprising multiple selves, and we might find it similarly problematic when an earlier self binds a future self, for example by becoming addicted to drugs
    • We might view personal identity in the same way, as comprising multiple selves, and we might find it similarly problematic when an earlier self binds a future self, for example by becoming addicted to drugs.
  • 78
    • 84924098879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are we one self or multiple selves? Implications for law and public policy
    • Richard A. Posner, Are We One Self or Multiple Selves? Implications for Law and Public Policy, 3 LEGAL THEORY 23 (1997).
    • (1997) Legal Theory , vol.3 , pp. 23
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 79
    • 79951712229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELSTER, supra note 3, at 88-94
    • See ELSTER, supra note 3, at 88-94.
  • 80
    • 79951701052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 88-174
    • See id. at 88-174;
  • 81
    • 79951708840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOLMES, supra note 3, at 134-77
    • HOLMES, supra note 3, at 134-77.
  • 84
    • 38049173948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judicial selection, appointments gridlock, and the nuclear option
    • See, &, 70-71
    • See David S. Law & Lawrence B. Solum, Judicial Selection, Appointments Gridlock, and the Nuclear Option, 15 J. CONTEMP. LEGAL ISSUES 51, 70-71 (2006).
    • (2006) J. Contemp. Legal Issues , vol.15 , pp. 51
    • Law, D.S.1    Solum, L.B.2
  • 85
    • 0010771515 scopus 로고
    • On the stability of logrolling outcomes in stochastic games
    • See Peter Bernholz, On the Stability of Logrolling Outcomes in Stochastic Games, 33 PUB. CHOICE 65 (1978).
    • (1978) Pub. Choice , vol.33 , pp. 65
    • Bernholz, P.1
  • 86
    • 79951686624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra p. 685
    • See infra p. 685.
  • 87
    • 84974486152 scopus 로고
    • Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England
    • Douglass C. North & Barry R. Weingast, Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England, 49 J. ECON. HIST. 803 (1989).
    • (1989) J. Econ. Hist. , vol.49 , pp. 803
    • North, D.C.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 88
    • 0039395559 scopus 로고
    • The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development
    • Barry R. Weingast, The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development, 11 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 1 (1995).
    • (1995) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.11 , pp. 1
    • Weingast, B.R.1
  • 90
    • 0001047705 scopus 로고
    • The independent judiciary in an interest-group perspective
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective, 18 J. L. & ECON. 875 (1975).
    • (1975) J. L. & Econ. , vol.18 , pp. 875
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 92
    • 0036735373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How political parties can use the courts to advance their agendas: Federal courts in the United States, 1875-1891
    • Howard Gillman, How Political Parties Can use the Courts to Advance Their Agendas: Federal Courts in the United States, 1875-1891, 96 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 511 (2002).
    • (2002) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 511
    • Gillman, H.1
  • 95
    • 0003110110 scopus 로고
    • The politics of structural choice: Toward a theory of public bureaucracy
    • see also, in, Oliver E. Williamson ed.
    • see also Terry M. Moe, The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy, in ORGANIZATION THEORY: FROM CHESTER BARNARD TO THE PRESENT AND BEYOND 116 (Oliver E. Williamson ed., 1990);
    • (1990) Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond , vol.116
    • Moe, T.M.1
  • 96
    • 0001521599 scopus 로고
    • Bureaucratic drift, coalitional drift, and time consistency: A comment on macey
    • Kenneth A. Shepsle, Bureaucratic Drift, Coalitional Drift, and Time Consistency: A Comment on Macey, 8 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 111 (1992).
    • (1992) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.8 , pp. 111
    • Shepsle, K.A.1
  • 97
    • 0033461097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political origins of the administrative procedure act
    • McNollgast, The Political Origins of the Administrative Procedure Act, 15 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 180 (1999).
    • (1999) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.15 , pp. 180
    • McNollgast1
  • 99
    • 84947586303 scopus 로고
    • The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target
    • Kenneth Rogoff, The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target, 100 Q. J. ECON. 1169 (1985).
    • (1985) Q. J. Econ. , vol.100 , pp. 1169
    • Rogoff, K.1
  • 100
    • 70350083829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The domestic origins of international agreements
    • See, 511-24
    • See Rachel Brewster, The Domestic Origins of International Agreements, 44 VA. J. INT'L L. 501, 511-24 (2004);
    • (2004) Va. J. Int'L L , vol.44 , pp. 501
    • Brewster, R.1
  • 101
    • 85049714327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Locking in democracy: Constitutions, commitment, and international law
    • see also
    • see also Tom Ginsburg, Locking in Democracy: Constitutions, Commitment, and International Law, 38 N. Y. U. J. INT'L L. & POL. 707 (2006);
    • (2006) N. Y. U. J. Int'L L. & Pol. , vol.38 , pp. 707
    • Ginsburg, T.1
  • 102
    • 77952401261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credible commitments and the international criminal court
    • As Brewster, among others, emphasizes, international delegations can be used to entrench policies that benefit specific interest groups as well as further more public-regarding or widely shared goals
    • Beth A. Simmons & Allison Danner, Credible Commitments and the International Criminal Court, 64 INT'L ORG. 225 (2010). As Brewster, among others, emphasizes, international delegations can be used to entrench policies that benefit specific interest groups as well as further more public-regarding or widely shared goals.
    • (2010) Int'L Org. , vol.64 , pp. 225
    • Simmons, B.A.1    Danner, A.2
  • 103
    • 79951711598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brewster, supra, at 542
    • See Brewster, supra, at 542.
  • 104
    • 0141640092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, complementing North and Weingast's theory by describing how the credibility of the British government's commitment to repay debt was contingent upon the political preferences of members of Parliament and patterns of coalition formation
    • See DAVID STASAVAGE, PUBLIC DEBT AND THE BIRTH OF THE DEMOCRATIC STATE (2003) (complementing North and Weingast's theory by describing how the credibility of the British government's commitment to repay debt was contingent upon the political preferences of members of Parliament and patterns of coalition formation).
    • (2003) David Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic State
    • Stasavage, D.1
  • 105
    • 0011671821 scopus 로고
    • Transaction costs and the normative elements of the public choice model: An application to constitutional theory
    • See, 496-98, pointing out the omission in Landes and Posner's theory of any viable explanation of why judges would be inclined to uphold legislative bargains
    • See Jonathan R. Macey, Transaction Costs and the Normative Elements of the Public Choice Model: An Application to Constitutional Theory, 74 VA. L. REV. 471, 496-98 (1988) (pointing out the omission in Landes and Posner's theory of any viable explanation of why judges would be inclined to uphold legislative bargains).
    • (1988) Va. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 471
    • Macey, J.R.1
  • 107
    • 0039500397 scopus 로고
    • Order and change
    • see also, 93, identifying the central characteristic of an "institution" as the persistence of its rules through time and the creation of "durable norms and dependable structures"
    • see also Stephen Skowronek, Order and Change, 28 POLITY 91, 93 (1995) (identifying the central characteristic of an "institution" as the persistence of its rules through time and the creation of "durable norms and dependable structures").
    • (1995) Polity , vol.28 , pp. 91
    • Skowronek, S.1
  • 108
    • 84973758736 scopus 로고
    • Sovereignty: An institutional perspective
    • See, 81, noting that one "task of an institutionalist perspective involves explaining how institutions persist over time, even though their environments may change"
    • See Stephen D. Krasner, Sovereignty: An Institutional Perspective, 21 COMP. POL. STUD. 66, 81 (1988) (noting that one "task of an institutionalist perspective involves explaining how institutions persist over time, even though their environments may change");
    • (1988) Comp. Pol. Stud. , vol.21 , pp. 66
    • Krasner, S.D.1
  • 109
    • 0002430674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political institutions: An overview
    • 152 Robert E. Goodin & Hans-Dieter Klingemann eds., "If institutions changed as the structure of power or other social forces surrounding them changed, then there would simply be no need for a separate analysis of institutions." citation omitted
    • Bo Rothstein, Political Institutions: An Overview, in A NEW HANDBOOK OF POLITICAL SCIENCE 133, 152 (Robert E. Goodin & Hans-Dieter Klingemann eds., 1996) ("If institutions changed as the structure of power or other social forces surrounding them changed, then there would simply be no need for a separate analysis of institutions." (citation omitted)).
    • (1996) A New Handbook of Political Science , pp. 133
    • Rothstein, B.1
  • 110
    • 0000981744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political institutions: Rational choice perspectives
    • See, in, supra note 70, 175 noting that "most studies of institutions ignore" the question of "what makes institutions resistant to change" by "assuming that institutions are fixed and hence cannot be altered by individuals"
    • See Barry R. Weingast, Political Institutions: Rational Choice Perspectives, in A NEW HANDBOOK OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, supra note 70, at 167, 175 (noting that "[m]ost studies of institutions ignore" the question of "what makes institutions resistant to change" by "assuming that institutions are fixed and hence cannot be altered by individuals").
    • A New Handbook of Political Science , pp. 167
    • Weingast, B.R.1
  • 111
    • 34250241742 scopus 로고
    • Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice
    • See, e.g., &
    • See, e.g., Kenneth A. Shepsle & Barry R. Weingast, Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice, 37 PUB. CHOICE 503 (1981).
    • (1981) Pub. Choice , vol.37 , pp. 503
    • Shepsle, K.A.1    Weingast, B.R.2
  • 112
    • 84971145641 scopus 로고
    • Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions
    • 443-44
    • William H. Riker, Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of Institutions, 74 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 432, 443-44 (1980);
    • (1980) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 432
    • Riker, W.H.1
  • 116
    • 21844491800 scopus 로고
    • The false promise of international institutions
    • See John J. Mearsheimer, The False Promise of International Institutions, 19 INT'L SECURITY 5 (1994).
    • (1994) Int'L Security , vol.19 , pp. 5
    • Mearsheimer, J.J.1
  • 117
    • 79951687403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weingast, supra note 57, at 3. Weingast goes on to provide some context-specific reasons for why systems of federalism became stabilized in several different countries during specific time periods
    • Weingast, supra note 57, at 3. Weingast goes on to provide some context-specific reasons for why systems of federalism became stabilized in several different countries during specific time periods.
  • 118
    • 79951718095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10-21
    • Id. at 10-21;
  • 120
    • 79951701597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 58
    • See ACEMOGLU & ROBINSON, supra note 58, at 177-78.
    • Acemoglu & Robinson , pp. 177-178
  • 121
    • 0012593308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, "It is not obvious why democracy rather than a commitment to more redistribution in the future is harder for the elite to reverse.". Acemoglu and Robinson recognize the importance of this question in passing and gesture toward possible answers based on asset-specific investments and political feedback effects, along the lines discussed below
    • See CARLES BOIX, DEMOCRACY AND REDISTRIBUTION 11 (2003) ("[I]t is not obvious why democracy rather than a commitment to more redistribution in the future is harder for the elite to reverse...."). Acemoglu and Robinson recognize the importance of this question in passing and gesture toward possible answers based on asset-specific investments and political feedback effects, along the lines discussed below.
    • (2003) Democracy and Redistribution , vol.11
    • Carles, B.1
  • 122
    • 79951701597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 58
    • See ACEMOGLU & ROBINSON, supra note 58, at 179.
    • Acemoglu & Robinson , pp. 179
  • 123
    • 79951690903 scopus 로고
    • The federalists have retired into the judiciary as a stronghold and from that battery all the works of republicanism are to be beaten down and erased
    • Historians of the U. S. Constitution will immediately think of the failed attempt by the outgoing Federalist Party to entrench itself in the judiciary. Newly elected President Jefferson recognized the entrenchment strategy in terms similar to Hirschl's:, supra note 61, quoting Letter from, to, Dec. 19, But of course Jefferson and his fellow Republicans had no intention of allowing this strategy to succeed. The Republican Congress promptly repealed the 1801 Judiciary Act, began impeaching Federalist judges, and successfully intimidated the Federalistcontrolled Supreme Court into political docility
    • Historians of the U. S. Constitution will immediately think of the failed attempt by the outgoing Federalist Party to entrench itself in the judiciary. Newly elected President Jefferson recognized the entrenchment strategy in terms similar to Hirschl's: "The Federalists have retired into the judiciary as a stronghold and from that battery all the works of republicanism are to be beaten down and erased." Gillman, supra note 61, at 521 (quoting Letter from Thomas Jefferson to John Dickinson (Dec. 19, 1801)). But of course Jefferson and his fellow Republicans had no intention of allowing this strategy to succeed. The Republican Congress promptly repealed the 1801 Judiciary Act, began impeaching Federalist judges, and successfully intimidated the Federalistcontrolled Supreme Court into political docility.
    • (1801) Gillman , pp. 521
    • Jefferson, T.1    Dickinson, J.2
  • 124
    • 79951694713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 125
    • 79951708623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For two exceptionally ambitious efforts in this regard
    • For two exceptionally ambitious efforts in this regard
  • 128
    • 3042748389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, surveying and supplementing the relevant literature to identify a number of general sources of "institutional resilience, "
    • See PAUL PIERSON, POLITICS IN TIME 133-66 (2004) (surveying and supplementing the relevant literature to identify a number of general sources of "institutional resilience, "
    • (2004) Politics in Time , pp. 133-166
    • Paul, P.1
  • 129
    • 79951718291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 151
    • id. at 151).
  • 130
    • 79951690522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • precise game-theoretical logic could coincide with any of a number of games in the coordination family, including battle of the sexes, stag hunt, and hawk/dove. For a useful overview of coordination games and their application to law
    • The precise game-theoretical logic could coincide with any of a number of games in the coordination family, including battle of the sexes, stag hunt, and hawk/dove. For a useful overview of coordination games and their application to law
  • 131
    • 62549087027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond the prisoners' dilemma: Coordination, game theory, and law
    • see Richard H. McAdams, Beyond the Prisoners' Dilemma: Coordination, Game Theory, and Law, 82 S. CAL. L. REV. 209 (2009).
    • (2009) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 209
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 132
    • 79951702208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For examples of models along these lines
    • For examples of models along these lines
  • 133
    • 0031507203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law
    • see Barry R. Weingast, The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law, 91 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 245 (1997);
    • (1997) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 245
    • Weingast, B.R.1
  • 134
    • 74149083367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aug. 24, unpublished manuscript on file with the Harvard Law School Library
    • and James D. Fearon, Self-Enforcing Democracy 2 (Aug. 24, 2006) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with the Harvard Law School Library).
    • (2006) Self-enforcing Democracy , vol.2
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 135
    • 79951685683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GUZMAN, supra note 52, at 71-117
    • See GUZMAN, supra note 52, at 71-117.
  • 136
    • 79951686622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KEOHANE, supra note 74
    • See KEOHANE, supra note 74.
  • 138
    • 79951712211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Weingast, supra note 57
    • See Weingast, supra note 57;
  • 140
    • 0000241339 scopus 로고
    • The puzzling (in) dependence of courts: A comparative approach
    • See J. Mark Ramseyer, The Puzzling (In) Dependence of Courts: A Comparative Approach, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 721 (1994);
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , Issue.2
    • Ramseyer, J.M.1
  • 141
    • 79951698245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephenson, supra note 8
    • Stephenson, supra note 8.
  • 142
    • 79951693437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the availability of coordination or cooperative benefits is not sufficient to create political agreement. Among other barriers to agreement is the need to settle distributive disagreements over how to divide the surplus or over which of a number of coordinating or cooperative arrangements, each with different distributive consequences, will be implemented
    • Of course, the availability of coordination or cooperative benefits is not sufficient to create political agreement. Among other barriers to agreement is the need to settle distributive disagreements over how to divide the surplus (or over which of a number of coordinating or cooperative arrangements, each with different distributive consequences, will be implemented).
  • 143
    • 0032355311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining, enforcement, and international cooperation
    • See, 274
    • See James D. Fearon, Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation, 52 INT'L ORG. 269, 274 (1998).
    • (1998) Int'L Org. , vol.52 , pp. 269
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 144
    • 79951698418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 69
    • See NORTH, supra note 69, at 95;
    • North , pp. 95
  • 145
    • 79951708839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIERSON, supra note 81, at 24-25
    • PIERSON, supra note 81, at 24-25.
  • 146
    • 79951702010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PIERSON, supra note 81, at 148-49
    • See PIERSON, supra note 81, at 148-49;
  • 147
    • 79951701611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Asset specificity and institutional development
    • As Karen Orren and Stephen Skowronek describe: Social interests that thrive by filling a niche within established institutional forms or by discovering a channel for action made available by them have little interest in seeking major changes in the governing arrangements that favor them; on the contrary, they can be expected to hold politics to the present path, pressing only for those adaptations that promise to maintain the current relationship between institutional politics and public policy
    • Paul Pierson & Shannon O'Neil Trowbridge, Asset Specificity and Institutional Development (2002) (prepared for delivery at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association). As Karen Orren and Stephen Skowronek describe: Social interests that thrive by filling a niche within established institutional forms or by discovering a channel for action made available by them have little interest in seeking major changes in the governing arrangements that favor them; on the contrary, they can be expected to hold politics to the present path, pressing only for those adaptations that promise to maintain the current relationship between institutional politics and public policy.
    • (2002) Prepared For Delivery at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association
    • Pierson, P.1    O'Neil Trowbridge, S.2
  • 149
    • 79951701597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 58
    • See ACEMOGLU & ROBINSON, supra note 58, at 179;
    • Acemoglu & Robinson , pp. 179
  • 151
    • 79951717510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FILIPPOV ET AL., supra note 76, at 38-39.
    • FILIPPOV ET AL., supra note 76, at 38-39.
  • 152
    • 79951703672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pierson, & Trowbridge, supra note 91, at 22-23
    • Pierson & Trowbridge, supra note 91, at 22-23.
  • 153
    • 79951711090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare the difficulty of moving after living somewhere for a year with the difficulty of uprooting after several decades
    • Compare the difficulty of moving after living somewhere for a year with the difficulty of uprooting after several decades.
  • 154
    • 79951687955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • inverse effect is also possible: negative political feedback
    • The inverse effect is also possible: negative political feedback.
  • 155
    • 79951704671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra p. 744 and sources cited infra notes 335-37 discussing public backlash against the Supreme Court
    • See infra p. 744 and sources cited infra notes 335-37 (discussing public backlash against the Supreme Court);
  • 156
    • 0347989498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essay, backlash
    • see also, describing the possibility that efficient economic arrangements will create self-defeating political backlashes
    • see also Mark J. Roe, Essay, Backlash, 98 COLUM. L. REV. 217 (1998) (describing the possibility that efficient economic arrangements will create self-defeating political backlashes);
    • (1998) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 217
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 157
    • 23244445490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essay, selection effects in constitutional law
    • 991-95, noting the possibility that liberal democratic tolerance of intolerant groups will be politically self-defeating
    • Adrian Vermeule, Essay, Selection Effects in Constitutional Law, 91 VA. L. REV. 953, 991-95 (2005) (noting the possibility that liberal democratic tolerance of intolerant groups will be politically self-defeating).
    • (2005) Va. L. Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 953
    • Vermeule, A.1
  • 158
    • 79951716934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An opportunity to consider if homeowners get too many breaks
    • See, Nov. 17, at C3. Their commitment comes from some combination of material asset-specific investments and psychological endowment effects; their capability from both the greater resources and the enhanced collective action capacity that the entitlement itself provides. On political endowment effects
    • See Hal R. Varian, An Opportunity to Consider if Homeowners Get Too Many Breaks, N. Y. TIMES, Nov. 17, 2005, at C3. Their commitment comes from some combination of material asset-specific investments and psychological endowment effects; their capability from both the greater resources and the enhanced collective action capacity that the entitlement itself provides. On political endowment effects
    • (2005) N. Y. Times
    • Varian, H.R.1
  • 159
    • 0032349366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lock-in effects in law and norms
    • see, 827-28
    • see Clayton P. Gillette, Lock-In Effects in Law and Norms, 78 B. U. L. REV. 813, 827-28 (1998);
    • (1998) B. U. L. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 813
    • Gillette, C.P.1
  • 160
    • 0029753187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new politics of the welfare state
    • 144-46
    • and Paul Pierson, The New Politics of the Welfare State, 48 WORLD POL. 143, 144-46 (1996).
    • (1996) World Pol. , vol.48 , pp. 143
    • Pierson, P.1
  • 162
    • 79951703154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pierson, supra note 96
    • Pierson, supra note 96;
  • 163
    • 3042723633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Privatizing risk without privatizing the welfare state: The hidden politics of social policy retrenchment in the United States
    • cf, describing political strategies for welfare state retrenchment or subversion that have partially succeeded in the United States
    • cf. Jacob S. Hacker, Privatizing Risk Without Privatizing the Welfare State: The Hidden Politics of Social Policy Retrenchment in the United States, 98 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 243 (2004) (describing political strategies for welfare state retrenchment or subversion that have partially succeeded in the United States).
    • (2004) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 243
    • Hacker, J.S.1
  • 164
    • 0346684472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of path dependence in corporate ownership and governance
    • See, &, 157-60
    • See Lucian Arye Bebchuk & Mark J. Roe, A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Ownership and Governance, 52 STAN. L. REV. 127, 157-60 (1999).
    • (1999) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.52 , pp. 127
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1    Roe, M.J.2
  • 166
    • 79951697861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 110-35
    • See id. at 110-35.
  • 167
    • 79951715619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Vermeule, supra note 95
    • See generally Vermeule, supra note 95.
  • 168
    • 0037327839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The mechanisms of the slippery slope
    • See, 1116-18 These examples can be generalized to many municipal-level decisions about policy and public goods provision, given Tiebout sorting dynamics
    • See Eugene Volokh, The Mechanisms of the Slippery Slope, 116 HARV. L. REV. 1026, 1116-18 (2003). These examples can be generalized to many municipal-level decisions about policy and public goods provision, given Tiebout sorting dynamics.
    • (2003) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.116 , pp. 1026
    • Volokh, E.1
  • 169
    • 79951688538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1119
    • See id. at 1119.
  • 170
    • 79951692229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This phenomenon is transparent when it happens through the legislative redistricting process, which effectively allows legislators to choose their voters. For a contrasting example
    • This phenomenon is transparent when it happens through the legislative redistricting process, which effectively allows legislators to choose their voters. For a contrasting example
  • 171
    • 38349046599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gentrification changing face of new Atlanta
    • see, Mar. 11, quoting a community leader as saying that African American mayors of Atlanta have "cut their own throats" by encouraging gentrification that has decreased the percentage of black voters in the city
    • see Shaila Dewan, Gentrification Changing Face of New Atlanta, N. Y. TIMES, Mar. 11, 2006, at A1, quoting a community leader as saying that African American mayors of Atlanta have "cut [their] own throat[s]" by encouraging gentrification that has decreased the percentage of black voters in the city.
    • (2006) N. Y. Times
    • Dewan, S.1
  • 172
    • 79951705996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at A12
    • Id. at A12.
  • 173
    • 25844493602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The curley effect: The economics of shaping the electorate
    • Edward L. Glaeser & Andrei Shleifer, The Curley Effect: The Economics of Shaping the Electorate, 21 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 1 (2005).
    • (2005) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.21 , pp. 1
    • Glaeser, E.L.1    Shleifer, A.2
  • 174
    • 79951709803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vermeule, supra note 95, at 976. Of course, groups can be effectively disenfranchised extrademocratically. The entrenchment effect of enfranchisement operates within a system of democracy but does not entrench the system itself
    • See Vermeule, supra note 95, at 976. Of course, groups can be effectively disenfranchised extrademocratically. The entrenchment effect of enfranchisement operates within a system of democracy but does not entrench the system itself.
  • 175
    • 0347141445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Majoritarian Judicial Review: The Entrenchment Problem
    • See Michael J. Klarman, Majoritarian Judicial Review: The Entrenchment Problem, 85 GEO. L. J. 491, 509-28 (1997). (Pubitemid 127437011)
    • (1997) Georgetown Law Journal , vol.85 , Issue.3 , pp. 491
    • Klarman, M.J.1
  • 176
    • 30844436826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change, and economic
    • Daron Acemoglu et al., The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth, 95 AM. ECON. REV. 546 (2005).
    • (2005) Growth , vol.95 , pp. 546
    • Acemoglu, D.1
  • 177
    • 35348840389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, describing how this political-economic dynamic has worked in the contemporary United States
    • See LARRY M. BARTELS, UNEQUAL DEMOCRACY: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE NEW GILDED AGE (2008) (describing how this political-economic dynamic has worked in the contemporary United States).
    • (2008) Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age
    • Larry, M.B.1
  • 179
    • 79951717315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See NORTH, supra note 69, at 95-96
    • See NORTH, supra note 69, at 95-96.
  • 180
    • 79951717129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIERSON, supra note 81, at 24
    • PIERSON, supra note 81, at 24.
  • 182
    • 85024536192 scopus 로고
    • Clio and the economics of qwerty
    • See Paul A. David, Clio and the Economics of QWERTY, 75 AM. ECON. REV. 332 (1985).
    • (1985) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 332
    • David, P.A.1
  • 183
    • 79951713553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Pierson, supra note 81, at 17-53
    • See generally Pierson, supra note 81, at 17-53.
  • 184
    • 79951692810 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g.
    • See, e.g., JON ELSTER, SOUR GRAPES (1983);
    • (1983)
    • Jon, E.1    Sour, G.2
  • 185
    • 70049103353 scopus 로고
    • Legal interference with private preferences
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Legal Interference with Private Preferences, 53 U. CHI. L. REV. Pag 1129 (1986).
    • (1986) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.53 , Issue.4
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 186
    • 0001331917 scopus 로고
    • Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias
    • See, e.g.
    • See, e.g., Daniel Kahneman et al., Anomalies: The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias, 5 J. ECON. PERSP. 193 (1991).
    • (1991) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.5 , pp. 193
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 188
    • 79951719794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relevant in this regard is Madison's response in The Federalist No. 49 to Jefferson's call for frequent constitutional conventions: "Frequent appeals to the people would, in great measure, deprive the government of that veneration which time bestows on everything, and without which perhaps the wisest and freest governments would not possess the requisite stability." The Federalist No. 49 James Madison, supra note 9, at 311
    • Relevant in this regard is Madison's response in The Federalist No. 49 to Jefferson's call for frequent constitutional conventions: "[F]requent appeals [to the people] would, in great measure, deprive the government of that veneration which time bestows on everything, and without which perhaps the wisest and freest governments would not possess the requisite stability." The Federalist No. 49 (James Madison), supra note 9, at 311.
  • 189
    • 79951718093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Greif, supra note 80, at 189
    • See Greif, supra note 80, at 189.
  • 190
    • 79951698803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 189-94
    • See id. at 189-94.
  • 192
    • 0003596712 scopus 로고
    • see also, describing how "policies transform politics, "
    • see also THEDA SKOCPOL, PROTECTING SOLDIERS AND MOTHERS 57-60 (1992) (describing how "[p]olicies [t]ransform [p]olitics, "
    • (1992) Protecting Soldiers and Mothers , pp. 57-60
    • Theda, S.1
  • 193
    • 79951690904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 57
    • id. at 57).
  • 194
    • 79951699234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Here again, this analysis is agnostic toward the criteria that might be used to assess these outcomes. Such criteria could be self-interested and materialist or other-regarding and moralistic
    • Here again, this analysis is agnostic toward the criteria that might be used to assess these outcomes. Such criteria could be self-interested and materialist or other-regarding and moralistic.
  • 195
    • 79951686071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • some contexts, of course, political actors will in fact have intrinsic preferences about political decisionmaking processes. Where this is the case, such "processes" should be treated as substantive outcomes for purposes of this analysis
    • In some contexts, of course, political actors will in fact have intrinsic preferences about political decisionmaking processes. Where this is the case, such "processes" should be treated as substantive outcomes for purposes of this analysis.
  • 196
    • 79951697484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • a brief discussion, Kenneth Shepsle emphasizes the relative uncertainty and riskiness of institutional change compared to policy change, though he does not spell out precisely why institutional uncertainty is greater or how uncertainty bears on the incentives of political actors
    • In a brief discussion, Kenneth Shepsle emphasizes the relative uncertainty and riskiness of institutional change compared to policy change, though he does not spell out precisely why institutional uncertainty is greater or how uncertainty bears on the incentives of political actors.
  • 197
    • 0002433588 scopus 로고
    • Institutional equilibrium and equilibrium institutions
    • See, in, Herbert F. Weisberg ed., recognizing the need to "drive a wedge between choice of policy and choice of institutional arrangements, "
    • See Kenneth A. Shepsle, Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions, in POLITICAL SCIENCE: THE SCIENCE OF POLITICS 51 (Herbert F. Weisberg ed., 1986) (recognizing the need to "drive a wedge between choice of policy and choice of institutional arrangements, "
    • (1986) Political Science: The Science of Politics , vol.51
    • Shepsle, K.A.1
  • 198
    • 79951718869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 69. Of course, policies also may have uncertain or unpredictable distributional consequences at the time of enactment. The comparison in the text is relative and on average
    • id. at 69). Of course, policies also may have uncertain or unpredictable distributional consequences at the time of enactment. The comparison in the text is relative and on average.
  • 202
    • 0004048289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, rev. ed, Note that Rawls's famous "veil of ignorance" shields decisionmakers not from knowledge of the distributive consequences of the basic structure they agree upon but from knowledge of their position in society and thus the distributional outcomes that they themselves will experience
    • see also JOHN RAWLS, A THEORY OF JUSTICE 118-23 (rev. ed. 1999). Note that Rawls's famous "veil of ignorance" shields decisionmakers not from knowledge of the distributive consequences of the basic structure they agree upon but from knowledge of their position in society and thus the distributional outcomes that they themselves will experience.
    • (1999) A Theory of Justice , pp. 118-123
    • John, R.1
  • 203
    • 0347617358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Veil of ignorance rules in constitutional law
    • See, 399
    • See Adrian Vermeule, Veil of Ignorance Rules in Constitutional Law, 111 YALE L. J. 399, 399 (2001).
    • (2001) Yale L. J , vol.111 , pp. 399
    • Vermeule, A.1
  • 204
    • 79951711812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For direct analogies
    • For direct analogies
  • 205
    • 79951705209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Keohane, supra note 74, at 85-109, viewing international regimes in this light
    • see Keohane, supra note 74, at 85-109 (viewing international regimes in this light);
  • 206
    • 84936180133 scopus 로고
    • The industrial organization of congress; Or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets
    • viewing the congressional committee system in this light
    • and Barry R. Weingast & William J. Marshall, The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets, 96 J. POL. ECON. 132 (1988) (viewing the congressional committee system in this light).
    • (1988) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.96 , pp. 132
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Marshall, W.J.2
  • 207
    • 79951710873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, unpublished manuscript on file with the Harvard Law School Library suggestively conceptualizing constitutional principles as bundles of outcome commitments backed by coalitions of supporters of these outcomes
    • See Roderick M. Hills, Jr., Federalism and Self-Restraint 140-45 (unpublished manuscript) (on file with the Harvard Law School Library) (suggestively conceptualizing constitutional principles as bundles of outcome commitments backed by coalitions of supporters of these outcomes).
    • Federalism and Self-restraint , pp. 140-145
    • Hills Jr., R.M.1
  • 208
    • 79951716369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To carry over the example, we should assume away tenure and imagine each appointment as reversible
    • To carry over the example, we should assume away tenure and imagine each appointment as reversible.
  • 209
    • 79951690150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Entrenchment in this formal, legal sense is clearly a matter of degree - specifically, the degree of difficulty of legal change imposed by a given set of procedural requirements. One extreme of legal entrenchment is marked by the explicitly unamendable provisions of a constitution (for instance, Article V's requirement of equal state suffrage in the Senate). The other extreme in the U. S. legal system might be occupied by an executive decision or order issued and unilaterally revocable by the President. Somewhere in the middle, protected by various levels of procedural barriers to change, are amendable constitutional rules (subject to the Article V procedures), judicial decisions (subject to norms of stare decisis), and ordinary federal statutes (which can be changed through the Article I, Section 7 procedural gamut, supplemented by internal congressional rules and other intrabranch procedural hurdles). Legal theory invites confusion, therefore, when it describes some rule or arrangement as "entrenched" (full stop). This description must reflect an implicit comparison with some other, less cumbersome set of procedural requirements for effecting legal change. Sometimes the baseline is set by the procedural difficulty of enacting the same policy in the first place.
  • 210
    • 0041805374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Essay, legislative entrenchment: A reappraisal
    • See, &, 1667, When constitutional law is described as "entrenched", however, the implicit baseline must be the set of procedural requirements for creating or changing some other type of law. Constitutional law might be considered entrenched in this sense relative to federal statutes, just as U. S. statutes are entrenched relative to statutes in parliamentary systems such as Britain's which do not present the obstacles of bicam-eralism or presentment or to executive orders
    • See Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Essay, Legislative Entrenchment: A Reappraisal, 111 YALE L. J. 1665, 1667 (2002). When constitutional law is described as "entrenched", however, the implicit baseline must be the set of procedural requirements for creating or changing some other type of law. Constitutional law might be considered entrenched in this sense relative to federal statutes, just as U. S. statutes are entrenched relative to statutes in parliamentary systems such as Britain's (which do not present the obstacles of bicam-eralism or presentment) or to executive orders.
    • (2002) Yale L. J , vol.111 , pp. 1665
    • Posner, E.A.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 211
    • 79951719239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Like formal entrenchment, functional entrenchment is obviously a matter of degree. Also like formal entrenchment, the baseline for defining and measuring functional entrenchment might be set by the political difficulty of enacting the law or policy in the first place, or - more commonly, but also more ambiguously - by implicit reference to some "ordinary" level of difficulty of changing political course
    • Like formal entrenchment, functional entrenchment is obviously a matter of degree. Also like formal entrenchment, the baseline for defining and measuring functional entrenchment might be set by the political difficulty of enacting the law or policy in the first place, or - more commonly, but also more ambiguously - by implicit reference to some "ordinary" level of difficulty of changing political course.
  • 212
    • 79951716554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recognizing the possibility of functional entrenchment makes longstanding normative debates about the constitutionality and democratic legitimacy of formal legislative entrenchments seem rather academic. Many constitutional theorists have argued that it would be unconstitutional and democratically illegitimate for a legislature to limit the legislative authority of its successors by passing a statute that declared itself to be unamendable or that required a special su-permajority to override it
    • Recognizing the possibility of functional entrenchment makes longstanding normative debates about the constitutionality and democratic legitimacy of formal legislative entrenchments seem rather academic. Many constitutional theorists have argued that it would be unconstitutional and democratically illegitimate for a legislature to limit the legislative authority of its successors by passing a statute that declared itself to be unamendable or that required a special su-permajority to override it.
  • 213
  • 214
    • 0006671891 scopus 로고
    • Temporal limits on the legislative mandate: Entrenchment and retroactivity
    • But given that functional entrenchment strategies are freely available to legislatures, it becomes difficult to explain why formal strategies that accomplish the same thing must be condemned. If Congress is free, for example, to structure farm subsidies in a way that strengthens powerful interest groups certain to resist any retrenchment, then what is so different about embedding these subsidies in a statute that requires a supermajority to be revoked
    • Julian N. Eule, Temporal Limits on the Legislative Mandate: Entrenchment and Retroactivity, 1987 AM. B. FOUND. RES. J. 379, 384-427. But given that functional entrenchment strategies are freely available to legislatures, it becomes difficult to explain why formal strategies that accomplish the same thing must be condemned. If Congress is free, for example, to structure farm subsidies in a way that strengthens powerful interest groups certain to resist any retrenchment, then what is so different about embedding these subsidies in a statute that requires a supermajority to be revoked?
    • (1987) Am. B. Found. Res. J , vol.379 , pp. 384-427
    • Eule, J.N.1
  • 215
    • 79951706744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Posner, & Vermeule, supra note 128, at 1705
    • See Posner & Vermeule, supra note 128, at 1705.
  • 216
    • 79956068924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Constitutions
    • See, in, Peter Cane & Herbert M. Kritzer eds., forthcoming 2010 surveying empirical studies that collectively fail to demonstrate a strong correlation, let alone a causal relationship, between formal constitutional rules and actual government behavior
    • See David S. Law, Constitutions, in THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF EMPIRICAL LEGAL RESEARCH (Peter Cane & Herbert M. Kritzer eds., forthcoming 2010)
    • The Oxford Handbook of Empirical Legal Research
    • Law, D.S.1
  • 218
    • 79951712030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H. L. A. Hart and subsequent legal positivists have had surprisingly little to say about what might motivate official and public acceptance of the ultimate rule s or practices of recognition
    • H. L. A. Hart and subsequent legal positivists have had surprisingly little to say about what might motivate official and public acceptance of the ultimate rule (s) or practices of recognition.
  • 219
    • 0038751705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., recognizing in passing a wide and open-ended set of reasons for why people might benefit from committing to a legal system, but bracketing this question as beside the point of positivist analysis
    • See, e.g., JULES L. COLEMAN, THE PRACTICE OF PRINCIPLE 93 (2001) (recognizing in passing a wide and open-ended set of reasons for why people might benefit from committing to a legal system, but bracketing this question as beside the point of positivist analysis).
    • (2001) The Practice of Principle , vol.93
    • Jules, L.C.1
  • 220
    • 79751496094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, &, eds., bringing a Hartian perspective to bear on U. S. constitutional law and theory
    • See generally THE RULE OF RECOGNITION AND THE U. S. CONSTITUTION (Matthew D. Adler & Kenneth Einar Himma eds., 2009) (bringing a Hartian perspective to bear on U. S. constitutional law and theory).
    • (2009) The Rule of Recognition and the U. S. Constitution
    • Adler, M.D.1    Himma, K.E.2
  • 222
    • 79951708114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moreover, many of the formal amendments that have been enacted appear to have accomplished little more than memorializing changes in constitutional norms that occurred independently of the text. For example, the Thirteenth Amendment recognized the abolition of slavery that had been effected for all practical purposes by the Civil War
    • Moreover, many of the formal amendments that have been enacted appear to have accomplished little more than memorializing changes in constitutional norms that occurred independently of the text. For example, the Thirteenth Amendment recognized the abolition of slavery that had been effected for all practical purposes by the Civil War.
  • 223
    • 0041920709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The irrelevance of constitutional amendments
    • See David A. Strauss, The Irrelevance of Constitutional Amendments, 114 HARV. L. REV. 1457, 1459, 1478-81 (2001). (Pubitemid 33638717)
    • (2001) Harvard Law Review , vol.115 , Issue.5 , pp. 1457
    • Strauss, D.A.1
  • 224
    • 79951718496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Elkins et al., supra note 92, at 38-47
    • See Elkins et al., supra note 92, at 38-47.
  • 225
    • 37449001451 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The constitution outside the constitution
    • See, 417-20, showing how a "constitutive" criterion for functional constitutionality might encompass any number of formally ordinary legal instruments and political practices, such as those creating and regulating the administrative state, the electoral system, the internal organization of Congress, political parties, and the like
    • See Ernest A. Young, The Constitution Outside the Constitution, 117 YALE L. J. 408, 417-20 (2007) (showing how a "constitutive" criterion for functional constitutionality might encompass any number of formally ordinary legal instruments and political practices, such as those creating and regulating the administrative state, the electoral system, the internal organization of Congress, political parties, and the like);
    • (2007) Yale L. J , vol.117-408
    • Young, E.A.1
  • 226
    • 79951706755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, defining "constitutional subject matter" to include "organic structures of government, the distribution of political powers, individual and collective rights, structures of political participation/ citizenship, jurisdiction, the role of domestic government, and international posture"
    • see also KEITH E. WHITTINGTON, CONSTITUTIONAL CONSTRUCTION 9 (1999) (defining "constitutional subject matter" to include "organic structures [of government], the distribution of political powers, individual and collective rights, structures of political participation/citizenship, jurisdiction, the role of domestic government, and international posture").
    • (1999) Constitutional Construction , vol.9
    • Keith, E.W.1
  • 227
    • 79951710690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, Mark Tushnet defines a "constitutional order" or "regime" as "a reasonably stable set of institutions through which a nation's fundamental decisions are made over a sustained period, and the principles that guide those decisions. These institutions and principles provide the structure within which ordinary political contention occurs, which is why I call them constitutional rather than merely political.", first and second emphases added footnote omitted
    • Thus, Mark Tushnet defines a "constitutional order" or "regime" as "a reasonably stable set of institutions through which a nation's fundamental decisions are made over a sustained period, and the principles that guide those decisions. These institutions and principles provide the structure within which ordinary political contention occurs, which is why I call them constitutional rather than merely political." MARK TUSHNET, THE NEW CONSTITUTIONAL ORDER 1 (2003) (first and second emphases added) (footnote omitted).
    • (2003) The New Constitutional Order , vol.1
    • Mark, T.1
  • 228
    • 79951693965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ACKERMAN, FOUNDATIONS, supra note 4
    • See ACKERMAN, FOUNDATIONS, supra note 4;
  • 229
    • 34249951655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The living constitution
    • Bruce Ackerman, The Living Constitution, 120 HARV. L. REV. 1737 (2007).
    • (2007) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.120 , pp. 1737
    • Ackerman, B.1
  • 230
    • 79951712018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ackerman, The Living Constitution, supra note 140, at 1757-93
    • See Ackerman, The Living Constitution, supra note 140, at 1757-93.
  • 231
    • 79951709787 scopus 로고
    • U. S
    • 347 U. S. 483 (1954);
    • (1954) , vol.347 , pp. 483
  • 232
    • 79951686982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Ackerman, The Living Constitution, supra note 140, at 1752
    • see Ackerman, The Living Constitution, supra note 140, at 1752.
  • 233
    • 79951714487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, The Living Constitution, supra note 140, at 1789
    • Ackerman, The Living Constitution, supra note 140, at 1789.
  • 235
    • 79951719782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1270
    • Id. at 1270.
  • 236
    • 79951703327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1216
    • Id. at 1216.
  • 237
    • 0002018204 scopus 로고
    • The constitution as an institution
    • 28-29
    • K. N. Llewellyn, The Constitution as an Institution, 34 COLUM. L. REV. 1, 28-29 (1934).
    • (1934) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.34 , pp. 1
    • Llewellyn, K.N.1
  • 238
    • 79951689110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Young, supra note 138, at 426
    • Young, supra note 138, at 426.
  • 239
    • 79951714497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 427
    • Id. at 427.
  • 240
    • 79951716739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • fact, during periods when these commitments were not embraced by politically empowered majorities, such as the post-Reconstruction era with respect to race, they ceased to be part of the operational constitution
    • In fact, during periods when these commitments were not embraced by politically empowered majorities, such as the post-Reconstruction era with respect to race, they ceased to be part of the operational constitution.
  • 241
    • 79951711811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra p. 687. Here again, we should recognize the possibility that Social Security is hard to change simply because political support for the goal of providing financial security to people in old age has not diminished since the program's inception in 1935. Admittedly, the conceptual difference between persistent popularity of this kind and genuine political entrenchment can be slippery. Suppose Social Security persists in part because it has become more popular, as Americans have learned from their experience under the program about the solidaristic and other benefits of universally framed welfare programs. That dynamic would be an instance of political entrenchment through adaptation and endogenous preference change, as opposed to the kind of popularity that might persist or even grow for reasons exogenous to the enactment of the law itself - though disentangling causation along these lines is obviously difficult
    • See supra p. 687. Here again, we should recognize the possibility that Social Security is hard to change simply because political support for the goal of providing financial security to people in old age has not diminished since the program's inception in 1935. Admittedly, the conceptual difference between persistent popularity of this kind and genuine political entrenchment can be slippery. Suppose Social Security persists in part because it has become more popular, as Americans have learned from their experience under the program about the solidaristic and other benefits of universally framed welfare programs. That dynamic would be an instance of political entrenchment through adaptation and endogenous preference change, as opposed to the kind of popularity that might persist or even grow for reasons exogenous to the enactment of the law itself - though disentangling causation along these lines is obviously difficult.
  • 242
    • 79951690337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra pp. 687-90
    • See supra pp. 687-90.
  • 243
    • 79951691086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, supra note 140, at 1788
    • Ackerman, supra note 140, at 1788.
  • 244
    • 79951710888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • his earlier work, Ackerman cast courts in the "preservationist" role of "blocking efforts to repeal established constitutional principles by the simple expedient of passing a normal statute", thus forcing constitutional reformers "to move onto the higher lawmaking track if they wish to question the judgments previously made by We the People."
    • In his earlier work, Ackerman cast courts in the " preservationist" role of "block[ing] efforts to repeal established constitutional principles by the simple expedient of passing a normal statute", thus forcing constitutional reformers "to move onto the higher lawmaking track if they wish to question the judgments previously made by We the People."
  • 245
    • 79951716933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ackerman, Foundations, supra note 4, at 10. Unfortunately, Ackerman never explained what institutional incentives judges would have to play this role, or how they would be able to resist ordinary majoritarian political pressures for change
    • Ackerman, Foundations, supra note 4, at 10. Unfortunately, Ackerman never explained what institutional incentives judges would have to play this role, or how they would be able to resist ordinary majoritarian political pressures for change.
  • 246
    • 0345818664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the constitutional revolution
    • See Jack M. Balkin & Sanford Levinson, Understanding the Constitutional Revolution, 87 VA. L. REV. 1045, 1083 (2001) (criticizing Ackerman for ignoring the possibility of "constitutional retrenchment" when the "dominant party starts losing Presidential elections", and thus "its grip on control of the judiciary"); (Pubitemid 33656658)
    • (2001) Virginia Law Review , vol.87 , Issue.6 , pp. 1045
    • Balkin, J.M.1    Levinson, S.2
  • 247
    • 10044224521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The importance of being positive: The nature and function of judicial review
    • 1288, "Ackerman's judges would have to be superhuman to enforce a past set of commitments against a government set on its immediate policy."
    • Barry Friedman, The Importance of Being Positive: The Nature and Function of Judicial Review, 72 U. CIN. L. REV. 1257, 1288 (2004) ("[Ackerman's j]udges would have to be superhuman to enforce a past set of commitments against a government set on its immediate policy.");
    • (2004) U. Cin. L. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 1257
    • Friedman, B.1
  • 248
    • 79951687402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also infra section IV. B, pp. 733-44
    • see also infra section IV. B, pp. 733-44.
  • 249
    • 79951698244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This recurring dynamic is the focus of Patashnik, supra note 99. The book presents a number of case studies, including the Tax Reform Act of 1986
    • This recurring dynamic is the focus of Patashnik, supra note 99. The book presents a number of case studies, including the Tax Reform Act of 1986
  • 250
    • 79951687184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 35-54, and the 1996 "Freedom to Farm" law
    • id. at 35-54, and the 1996 "Freedom to Farm" law
  • 251
    • 79951686995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 55-71. It is not difficult to envision a similar dynamic operating with respect to, for instance, the 2010 financial reform legislation
    • id. at 55-71. It is not difficult to envision a similar dynamic operating with respect to, for instance, the 2010 financial reform legislation.
  • 252
    • 79951691637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra p. 688
    • See supra p. 688.
  • 253
    • 79951706187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an influential conceptualization of constitutional law as the second-level rules of a first-level political game
    • For an influential conceptualization of constitutional law as the second-level rules of a first-level political game
  • 254
    • 79951706567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Brennan & Buchanan, supra note 124, at 8-9, 19
    • see Brennan & Buchanan, supra note 124, at 8-9, 19.
  • 255
    • 43949120447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dead hand arguments and constitutional interpretation
    • See, 655-60, surveying the contractarian account of U. S. constitutionalism
    • See Adam M. Samaha, Dead Hand Arguments and Constitutional Interpretation, 108 COLUM. L. REV. 606, 655-60 (2008) (surveying the contractarian account of U. S. constitutionalism).
    • (2008) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.108 , pp. 606
    • Samaha, A.M.1
  • 256
    • 79951716362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas Jefferson famously argued to Madison that no society can make a perpetual constitution. The earth belongs always to the living generation. "
    • Thomas Jefferson famously argued to Madison that no society can make a perpetual constitution.... The earth belongs always to the living generation. "
  • 257
    • 0347103198 scopus 로고
    • Letter from, to, Sept. 6, in, 8-9 Paul Leicester Ford ed.
    • Letter from Thomas Jefferson to James Madison (Sept. 6, 1789), in 6 THE WORKS OF THOMAS JEFFERSON 3, 8-9 (Paul Leicester Ford ed., 1904).
    • (1789) The Works of Thomas Jefferson , vol.6 , pp. 3
    • Jefferson, T.1    Madison, J.2
  • 259
    • 0003294352 scopus 로고
    • Legal obligation and the duty of fair play
    • See, in, Sidney Hook ed.
    • See John Rawls, Legal Obligation and the Duty of Fair Play, in LAW AND PHILOSOPHY 3 (Sidney Hook ed., 1964).
    • (1964) Law and Philosophy , pp. 3
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 260
    • 79951690902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a skeptical survey of possible justifications for the moral legitimacy of the Constitution and a corresponding duty to comply with it
    • For a skeptical survey of possible justifications for the moral legitimacy of the Constitution and a corresponding duty to comply with it
  • 261
    • 18144406540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legitimacy and the constitution
    • see, 1796-1813, For a skeptical survey of approaches to legal obligation more broadly
    • see Richard H. Fallon, Jr., Legitimacy and the Constitution, 118 HARV. L. REV. 1787, 1796-1813 (2005). For a skeptical survey of approaches to legal obligation more broadly
    • (2005) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.118 , pp. 1787
    • Fallon Jr., R.H.1
  • 262
    • 84860552002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal obligation and authority
    • see, in, Some political philosophers conclude that there is no general moral obligation to obey the law
    • see Leslie Green, Legal Obligation and Authority, in STANFORD ENCYCLOPEDIA OF PHILOSOPHY (2003), http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/legal- obligation. Some political philosophers conclude that there is no general moral obligation to obey the law.
    • (2003) Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy
    • Green, L.1
  • 267
    • 0001417422 scopus 로고
    • The path of the law
    • Oliver Wendell Holmes famously argued that law was designed for the amoral "bad man. ", 459
    • Oliver Wendell Holmes famously argued that law was designed for the amoral "bad man. " Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr., The Path of the Law, 10 HARV. L. REV. 457, 459 (1897).
    • (1897) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 457
    • Holmes Jr., O.W.1
  • 268
    • 79955042039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When and how (if at all) does law constrain official action? (the sibley lecture)
    • See, forthcoming
    • See Frederick Schauer, When and How (If at All) Does Law Constrain Official Action? (The Sibley Lecture), 45 GA. L. REV. (forthcoming 2010).
    • (2010) Ga. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Schauer, F.1
  • 270
    • 79951694710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra note 12. Kant's similar but stronger aspiration was to design a constitution that could make even "a nation of devils... inhibit one another in such a way that the public conduct of the citizens will be the same as if they did not have such evil attitudes."
    • see also supra note 12. Kant's similar but stronger aspiration was to design a constitution that could make even "a nation of devils... inhibit one another in such a way that the public conduct of the citizens will be the same as if they did not have such evil attitudes."
  • 271
    • 0003335371 scopus 로고
    • Perpetual peace: A philosophical sketch
    • 112-13 Hans Reiss ed., H. B. Nisbet trans.
    • IMMANUEL KANT, Perpetual Peace: A Philosophical Sketch, in KANT'S POLITICAL WRITINGS 93, 112-13 (Hans Reiss ed., H. B. Nisbet trans., 1970).
    • (1970) Kant'S Political Writings , pp. 93
    • Immanuel, K.1
  • 272
    • 0003921539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • most sustained work on constitutionalism as coordination is
    • The most sustained work on constitutionalism as coordination is RUSSELL HARDIN, LIBERALISM, CONSTITUTIONALISM, AND DEMOCRACY 82-140 (1999).
    • (1999) Liberalism, Constitutionalism, and Democracy , pp. 82-140
    • Russell, H.1
  • 273
    • 79951685138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Eric A. Posner, Constitutional Evolution unpublished manuscript on file with the Harvard Law School Library modeling constitutional rules as coordination equilibria
    • See also Eric A. Posner, Constitutional Evolution (unpublished manuscript) (on file with the Harvard Law School Library) (modeling constitutional rules as coordination equilibria).
  • 274
    • 79951688536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What counts as an interpretation of the constitutional text as opposed to a nontextual norm or convention depends on the operative theory of interpretation. Constitutional lawyers, judges, and theorists perpetually disagree about what that theory should be-whether interpreters should look to original understandings or expectations, subsequent historical understandings, traditional practices, moral philosophical analyses, functional inferences from our basic structure of government, or other sources of constitutional meaning-and therefore about which norms count as valid interpretations of the text and which should be understood as extratextual. Fortunately, nothing in the present discussion turns on the existence or location of the line between interpretation and extratextualism. For an introduction to the conceptual debate
    • What counts as an interpretation of the constitutional text as opposed to a nontextual norm or convention depends on the operative theory of interpretation. Constitutional lawyers, judges, and theorists perpetually disagree about what that theory should be-whether interpreters should look to original understandings or expectations, subsequent historical understandings, traditional practices, moral philosophical analyses, functional inferences from our basic structure of government, or other sources of constitutional meaning-and therefore about which norms count as valid interpretations of the text and which should be understood as extratextual. Fortunately, nothing in the present discussion turns on the existence or location of the line between interpretation and extratextualism. For an introduction to the conceptual debate
  • 275
    • 0011659497 scopus 로고
    • Do we have an unwritten constitution?
    • see generally
    • see generally Thomas C. Grey, Do We Have an Unwritten Constitution?, 27 STAN. L. REV. 703 (1975).
    • (1975) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.27 , pp. 703
    • Grey, T.C.1
  • 276
    • 79951688523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Here again, which provisions are understood to be "reasonably clear and specific" and what these provisions "mean" or "say" depend on the operative approach to interpretation. Despite deep disagreements over how constitutional interpretation should proceed, however, there does appear to be overlapping consensus on the "plain meaning" of a fair number of constitutional provisions
    • Here again, which provisions are understood to be "reasonably clear and specific" and what these provisions "mean" or "say" depend on the operative approach to interpretation. Despite deep disagreements over how constitutional interpretation should proceed, however, there does appear to be overlapping consensus on the "plain meaning" of a fair number of constitutional provisions.
  • 277
    • 0039567711 scopus 로고
    • Easy cases
    • See Frederick Schauer, Easy Cases, 58 S. CAL. L. REV. 399 (1985).
    • (1985) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 399
    • Schauer, F.1
  • 278
    • 0347419824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Common Law Constitutional Interpretation
    • See David A. Strauss, Common Law Constitutional Interpretation, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 877, 906-08 (1996). (Pubitemid 126408724)
    • (1996) University of Chicago Law Review , vol.63 , Issue.3 , pp. 877
    • Strauss, D.A.1
  • 279
    • 79951698792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • constitutional system of the United Kingdom fits this description
    • The constitutional system of the United Kingdom fits this description.
  • 281
    • 0040182733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parchment, equilibria, and institutions
    • See, Strauss, supra note 169, at 907-11
    • See John M. Carey, Parchment, Equilibria, and Institutions, 33 COMP. POL. STUD. 735 (2000); Strauss, supra note 169, at 907-11.
    • (2000) Comp. Pol. Stud. , vol.33 , pp. 735
    • Carey, J.M.1
  • 282
    • 22744441097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Common law, common ground, and jefferson's principle
    • See David A. Strauss, Common Law, Common Ground, and Jefferson's Principle, 112 YALE L. J. 1717, 1741-44 (2003).
    • (2003) Yale L. J , vol.112-1717 , pp. 1741-1744
    • Strauss, D.A.1
  • 283
    • 79951708420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss, supra note 169, at 916
    • Strauss, supra note 169, at 916;
  • 284
    • 79951708838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 916-19
    • see also id. at 916-19.
  • 285
    • 79951686070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Strauss, supra note 172, at 1741-43
    • See Strauss, supra note 172, at 1741-43.
  • 286
    • 79951684514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1734-35
    • Id. at 1734-35.
  • 287
    • 79951686280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Departing from the text will not necessarily sacrifice the benefits of constitutional coordination more generally, since there are other potential focal points besides the constitutional text: judicial precedents, well-established practices, and the status quo, among others
    • Departing from the text will not necessarily sacrifice the benefits of constitutional coordination more generally, since there are other potential focal points besides the constitutional text: judicial precedents, well-established practices, and the status quo, among others.
  • 288
    • 79951686454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, political actors will often have further reasons for accepting constitutional rules and arrangements that correspond to the text of the Constitution: these rules and arrangements may be coincident with their substantive political interests or may have become politically entrenched through any of the mechanisms described above and elaborated below. But the same may be true of those rules and arrangements that cannot be plausibly derived from the text but are widely accepted as part of little-c constitutional law. We should be careful to distinguish the political entrenchment and stability of the big-C constitutional text from that of the rules and arrangements that correspond to textual provisions
    • Of course, political actors will often have further reasons for accepting constitutional rules and arrangements that correspond to the text of the Constitution: these rules and arrangements may be coincident with their substantive political interests or may have become politically entrenched through any of the mechanisms described above and elaborated below. But the same may be true of those rules and arrangements that cannot be plausibly derived from the text but are widely accepted as part of little-c constitutional law. We should be careful to distinguish the political entrenchment and stability of the big-C constitutional text from that of the rules and arrangements that correspond to textual provisions.
  • 289
    • 0040904886 scopus 로고
    • Regulation and the American common market
    • See, in, A. Dan Tarlock ed.
    • See Edmund W. Kitch, Regulation and the American Common Market, in REGULATION, FEDERALISM, AND INTERSTATE COMMERCE 9, 9-19 (A. Dan Tarlock ed., 1981).
    • (1981) Regulation, Federalism, and Interstate Commerce , vol.9 , pp. 9-19
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 290
    • 79951718272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Weingast, supra note 83
    • See Weingast, supra note 83;
  • 292
    • 79951683739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Weingast, supra note 83, at 246-51
    • See Weingast, supra note 83, at 246-51.
  • 293
    • 79951719427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 3
    • See HOLMES, supra note 3, at 6-8.
    • Holmes , pp. 6-8
  • 294
    • 79951701227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, unpublished manuscript on file with the Harvard Law School Library, available at
    • See generally Stephen Holmes, Parables of Self-Restraint (unpublished manuscript) (on file with the Harvard Law School Library), available at http://www.law.nyu.edu/ecm-dlv1/groups/public/@nyu-law-website-academics- colloquia-constitutional-theory/documents/documents/ecm-pro-063857.pdf.
    • Parables of Self-restraint
    • Holmes, S.1
  • 295
    • 79951699416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 296
    • 79951718492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • prospects of success for groups that defect from constitutional bargains will depend on factors such as the size, power economic or military, and capacity for independence of the relevant group, all of which will affect their bargaining power in renegotiations
    • The prospects of success for groups that defect from constitutional bargains will depend on factors such as the size, power (economic or military), and capacity for independence of the relevant group, all of which will affect their bargaining power in renegotiations.
  • 298
    • 79951694354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at xvii. Of course, there are limits to how bad the bargain can be; at some point even violent secession becomes preferable. After the election of 1860, for example, Southerners determined that the costs of breaking from the Union, including both the short-term costs of war and the longer-term costs of foregone cooperation particularly free trade with the North, were still less than the anticipated costs of being forced to give up slavery
    • id. at xvii). Of course, there are limits to how bad the bargain can be; at some point even violent secession becomes preferable. After the election of 1860, for example, Southerners determined that the costs of breaking from the Union, including both the short-term costs of war and the longer-term costs of foregone cooperation (particularly free trade) with the North, were still less than the anticipated costs of being forced to give up slavery.
  • 299
    • 79951694544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 193-215
    • See id. at 193-215.
  • 300
    • 79951711414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Examples include the Washington Administration's suppression of the Whiskey Rebellion and the Adams Administration's use of the 1798 Sedition Act to suppress Jeffersonian opposition
    • Examples include the Washington Administration's suppression of the Whiskey Rebellion and the Adams Administration's use of the 1798 Sedition Act to suppress Jeffersonian opposition.
  • 301
    • 79951703333 scopus 로고
    • See, &, Another Federalist strategy was to use the appointment power of the federal government to generate political support through patronage
    • See STANLEY ELKINS & ERIC MCKITRICK, THE AGE OF FEDERALISM 461-88, 694-706 (1993). Another Federalist strategy was to use the appointment power of the federal government to generate political support through patronage.
    • (1993) The Age of Federalism , vol.88-461 , pp. 694-706
    • Stanley, E.1    Eric, M.2
  • 303
    • 79951703686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 92 and accompanying text. For a description of how political parties in the United States emerged and developed around the constitutional structure of government
    • See sources cited supra note 92 and accompanying text. For a description of how political parties in the United States emerged and developed around the constitutional structure of government
  • 305
    • 79951711798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Elkins et al., supra note 92, at 19-20
    • See Elkins et al., supra note 92, at 19-20.
  • 306
    • 79951694920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 90-91
    • See id. at 90-91.
  • 307
    • 79951706929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recall the definitional distinction between political commitment, which entails intentionality and therefore, at least from someone's perspective, functional efficacy, and entrenchment, which does not necessarily imply either intentionality or functional efficacy
    • Recall the definitional distinction between political commitment, which entails intentionality (and therefore, at least from someone's perspective, functional efficacy), and entrenchment, which does not necessarily imply either intentionality or functional efficacy.
  • 308
    • 79951702007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra p. 672. The obsolescence of the political commitments embodied in constitutions does not disentrench them
    • See supra p. 672. The obsolescence of the political commitments embodied in constitutions does not disentrench them.
  • 310
    • 79951715810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 25-38, 49-62
    • See id. at 25-38, 49-62.
  • 311
    • 79951704469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For general criticisms of the constitutional structure of government
    • For general criticisms of the constitutional structure of government
  • 313
    • 70349151978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 192
    • and LEVINSON, supra note 192.
    • Levinson
  • 314
    • 79951707897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • same is true of nonconstitutional law. More than one-tenth of laws in effect in Britain at the beginning of the 1980s had been enacted before the reign of Queen Victoria in 1837
    • The same is true of nonconstitutional law. More than one-tenth of laws in effect in Britain at the beginning of the 1980s had been enacted before the reign of Queen Victoria in 1837.
  • 315
    • 84965400523 scopus 로고
    • Inheritance before choice in public policy
    • See, 266
    • See Richard Rose, Inheritance Before Choice in Public Policy, 2 J. THEORETICAL POL. 263, 266 (1990).
    • (1990) J. Theoretical Pol. , vol.2 , pp. 263
    • Rose, R.1
  • 316
    • 0042244186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commitment and constitutionalism
    • 1945
    • John Ferejohn & Lawrence Sager, Commitment and Constitutionalism, 81 TEX. L. REV. 1929, 1945 (2003).
    • (2003) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 1929
    • Ferejohn, J.1    Sager, L.2
  • 317
    • 79951690523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1948-49
    • Id. at 1948-49.
  • 318
    • 79951686272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Graber, supra note 39
    • See Graber, supra note 39.
  • 319
    • 79951706560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 15-28 and accompanying text. A further argument made by Federalists against rights and in favor of structure was that the scope of rights could not be clearly specified in advance
    • See supra notes 15-28 and accompanying text. A further argument made by Federalists against rights and in favor of structure was that the scope of rights could not be clearly specified in advance.
  • 320
    • 79951702194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THE FEDERALIST No. 84 Alexander Hamilton, supra note 9, at 513 "Who can give a right any definition which would not leave the utmost latitude for evasion?"
    • See THE FEDERALIST No. 84 (Alexander Hamilton), supra note 9, at 513 ("Who can give [a right] any definition which would not leave the utmost latitude for evasion?").
  • 321
    • 79951693027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELY, supra note 5, at 87
    • ELY, supra note 5, at 87.
  • 322
    • 79951687401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 88
    • Id. at 88.
  • 323
    • 79951692617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 324
    • 79951691253 scopus 로고
    • The constitution and the bill of rights
    • 128 Joseph M. Bessette ed.
    • HERBERT J. STORING, The Constitution and the Bill of Rights, in TOWARD A MORE PERFECT UNION 108, 128 (Joseph M. Bessette ed., 1995);
    • (1995) Toward A More Perfect Union , pp. 108
    • Herbert, J.S.1
  • 325
    • 79951687774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra p. 717. For another example, consider Sanford Levinson's argument that a number of structural features of the Constitution including bicameralism, equal state representation in the Senate, and the Electoral College system are dysfunctional, yet also fixed in place by the Constitution and very difficult to change
    • see also supra p. 717. For another example, consider Sanford Levinson's argument that a number of structural features of the Constitution (including bicameralism, equal state representation in the Senate, and the Electoral College system) are dysfunctional, yet also fixed in place by the Constitution and very difficult to change.
  • 326
    • 79951689502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LEVINSON, supra note 192, at 29-38, 49-62, 81-97. Levinson views constitutional rights, in contrast, as relatively unproblematic because "it is always the case that courts are perpetually open to new arguments about rights - whether those of gays and lesbians or of property owners - that reflect the dominant public opinion of the day." Id. at 5
    • See LEVINSON, supra note 192, at 29-38, 49-62, 81-97. Levinson views constitutional rights, in contrast, as relatively unproblematic because "[i]t is always the case that courts are perpetually open to new arguments about rights - whether those of gays and lesbians or of property owners - that reflect the dominant public opinion of the day." Id. at 5.
  • 327
    • 79951692226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 9
    • A prerequisite to a full assessment of the relative stability of structure and rights would be to sort out some tricky definitional issues. Which parts of the Constitution count as "structural" and which count as "rights" is not self-evident. An immediate ambiguity arises in how to classify the constitutional powers of Congress and the President. Do these changes code as transformations of the structure of Congress and the presidency? Or should we follow the Federalists and view powers as more closely related to rights? (Federalist constitutional theory held that rights and powers were two sides of the same coin; rights began where powers ended. See The Federalist No. 84 (Alexander Hamilton), supra note 9, at 513.) Also complicating the classification, some nominal rights, particularly those that operate in the context of voting and elections, seem inseparable from what is conventionally understood to be part of the structural constitution. Ely's overlapping distinction between constitutional provisions governing "substance" versus "process" further muddies the water, as many nominal rights, such as procedural due process, criminal procedure protections, and voting rights, address political decisionmaking procedures and thus might be classified as structural.
    • The Federalist No. 84 Alexander Hamilton , pp. 513
  • 328
    • 33745296062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Popular constitutionalism and the rule of recognition: Whose practices ground u. S. Law?
    • Cf, 767-68, noticing that groups that disagree about many other aspects of constitutional law share convergent understandings of authoritative government institutions, such as the President and Congress
    • Cf. Matthew D. Adler, Popular Constitutionalism and the Rule of Recognition: Whose Practices Ground U. S. Law?, 100 NW. U. L. REV. 719, 767-68 (2006) (noticing that groups that disagree about many other aspects of constitutional law share convergent understandings of authoritative government institutions, such as the President and Congress).
    • (2006) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 719
    • Adler, M.D.1
  • 329
    • 79951686994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra pp. 713-15
    • See supra pp. 713-15.
  • 330
    • 79951715820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • central dynamic with respect to rights, of course, was the post-New Deal demise of antiregulatory, economic liberty rights, giving way to modern civil rights focused on racial equality, free speech, criminal procedure, religious liberty, and the like. For a richly textured historical account of how the political forces surrounding the state-building project of the Progressive and New Deal eras affected the development of modern civil rights
    • The central dynamic with respect to rights, of course, was the post-New Deal demise of antiregulatory, economic liberty rights, giving way to modern civil rights focused on racial equality, free speech, criminal procedure, religious liberty, and the like. For a richly textured historical account of how the political forces surrounding the state-building project of the Progressive and New Deal eras affected the development of modern civil rights
  • 333
    • 29444447370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brown and lawrence (and goodridge)
    • See, 443-45, sexual orientation
    • See Michael J. Klarman, Brown and Lawrence (and Goodridge), 104 MICH. L. REV. 431, 443-45 (2005) (sexual orientation);
    • (2005) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.104 , pp. 431
    • Klarman, M.J.1
  • 334
    • 0348199092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking the civil rights and civil liberties revolutions
    • Michael J. Klarman, Rethinking the Civil Rights and Civil Liberties Revolutions, 82 VA. L. REV. 1, 9 (1996) [hereinafter Klarman, Rethinking] (gender). (Pubitemid 126408571)
    • (1996) Virginia Law Review , vol.82 , Issue.1 , pp. 1
    • Klarman, M.J.1
  • 335
    • 0041413213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A political history of the establishment clause
    • See, &
    • See John C. Jeffries, Jr. & James E. Ryan, A Political History of the Establishment Clause, 100 MICH. L. REV. 279 (2001);
    • (2001) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 279
    • Jeffries Jr., J.C.1    Ryan, J.E.2
  • 336
    • 84887348081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 209, at
    • Klarman, Rethinking, supra note 209, at 15-16.
    • Rethinking , pp. 15-16
    • Klarman1
  • 337
    • 84887348081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 209, at
    • Klarman, Rethinking, supra note 209, at 35;
    • Rethinking , pp. 35
    • Klarman1
  • 338
    • 79951716932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 34-35
    • see also id. at 34-35.
  • 339
    • 79951697098 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., offering a now-standard political account of the Supreme Court's repudiation of economic liberty rights
    • See, e.g., ROBERT G. MCCLOSKEY, THE AmeriCAN SUPREME COURT 161-79 (1960) (offering a now-standard political account of the Supreme Court's repudiation of economic liberty rights).
    • (1960) The American Supreme Court , pp. 161-179
    • Robert, G.M.1
  • 340
    • 0004112235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see, arguing against the primacy of political forces in explaining the Court's post-New Deal turn
    • But see BARRY CUSHMAN, RETHINKING THE NEW DEAL COURT (1998) (arguing against the primacy of political forces in explaining the Court's post-New Deal turn).
    • (1998) Rethinking the New Deal Court
    • Barry, C.1
  • 341
    • 0002520343 scopus 로고
    • Slavery and the constitutional convention: Making a covenant with death
    • On the debates over slavery during the Convention, see generally, in, Richard Beeman et al. eds.
    • On the debates over slavery during the Convention, see generally Paul Finkelman, Slavery and the Constitutional Convention: Making a Covenant with Death, in BEYOND CONFEDERATION: ORIGINS OF THE CONSTITUTION AND AmeriCAN NATIONAL IDENTITY 188 (Richard Beeman et al. eds., 1987).
    • (1987) Beyond Confederation: Origins of the Constitution and American National Identity , pp. 188
    • Finkelman, P.1
  • 342
    • 79951703673 scopus 로고
    • James Madison, Power of Congress to Prohibit the Slave Trade, Speech of James Madison at the Constitutional Convention Aug. 25, 1787, in, 157 Robert A. Rutland et al. eds.
    • James Madison, Power of Congress to Prohibit the Slave Trade, Speech of James Madison at the Constitutional Convention (Aug. 25, 1787), in 10 THE PAPERS OF JAMES MADISON 157, 157 (Robert A. Rutland et al. eds., 1977).
    • (1977) The Papers of James Madison , vol.10 , pp. 157
  • 344
    • 79951719426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 101-06
    • See id. at 101-06.
  • 345
    • 79951699404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 102
    • Id. at 102.
  • 346
    • 79951691632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 126-27
    • Id. at 126-27.
  • 347
    • 79951719595 scopus 로고
    • See, at 89-92 Univ. of S. C. Press
    • See JESSE T. CARPENTER, THE SOUTH as A CONSCIOUS MINORITY, 1789-1861, at 89-92 (Univ. of S. C. Press 1990) (1930).
    • (1930) The South As A Conscious Minority , pp. 1789-1861
    • Jesse, T.C.1
  • 348
    • 79951699580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Graber, supra note 215, at 140-44
    • See Graber, supra note 215, at 140-44;
  • 349
    • 0000299808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political stability and civil war: Institutions, commitment, and American democracy
    • Robert H. Bates et al., 153-55, Notice that the balance rule was motivated by a rather obvious political feedback effect: every free territory created the potential for a free state that could enter the Union and shift the balance of power in the Senate, allowing the North to dominate national politics and threaten slavery, or vice versa
    • Barry R. Weingast, Political Stability and Civil War: Institutions, Commitment, and American Democracy, in Robert H. Bates et al., ANALYTIC NARRATIVES 148, 153-55 (1998). Notice that the balance rule was motivated by a rather obvious political feedback effect: every free territory created the potential for a free state that could enter the Union and shift the balance of power in the Senate, allowing the North to dominate national politics and threaten slavery, or vice versa.
    • (1998) Analytic Narratives , pp. 148
    • Weingast, B.R.1
  • 350
    • 79951706175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Weingast, supra note 220, at 156-59
    • See Weingast, supra note 220, at 156-59.
  • 351
    • 79951684293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GRABER, supra note 215, at 137-40
    • See GRABER, supra note 215, at 137-40.
  • 352
    • 79951696879 scopus 로고
    • 42 ANNALS OF CONG. 2361 (1824)
    • (1824) Annals of Cong , vol.42 , pp. 2361
  • 353
    • 79951689492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quoted in GRABER, supra note 215, at 139-40
    • quoted in GRABER, supra note 215, at 139-40.
  • 354
    • 79951714348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CARPENTER, supra note 219, at 141
    • CARPENTER, supra note 219, at 141.
  • 356
    • 79951685700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally CARPENTER, supra note 219, at 77-126
    • See generally CARPENTER, supra note 219, at 77-126;
  • 358
    • 79951711799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CARPENTER, supra note 219, at 94-95
    • See CARPENTER, supra note 219, at 94-95.
  • 359
    • 79951696890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 98-99
    • See id. at 98-99.
  • 360
    • 79951716923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Adler, supra note 205, at 767
    • See, e.g., Adler, supra note 205, at 767;
  • 361
    • 79951693803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strauss, supra note 172, at 1741
    • Strauss, supra note 172, at 1741.
  • 362
    • 79951706745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra pp. 709-11
    • See supra pp. 709-11.
  • 363
    • 79951714347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To the extent that the Framers chose to be more specific about structure than rights in the constitutional text, this decision might have been a reflection rather than a cause of their predictions about the relative stability of the two types
    • To the extent that the Framers chose to be more specific about structure than rights in the constitutional text, this decision might have been a reflection rather than a cause of their predictions about the relative stability of the two types.
  • 364
    • 79951706185 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., emphasizing the importance of separating powers to give each of the branches the "tools necessary to limit the excesses of its rivals"
    • See, e.g., MARTIN H. REDISH, THE CONSTITUTION as POLITICAL STRUCTURE 106 (1995) (emphasizing the importance of separating powers to give each of the branches the "tools necessary to limit the excesses of its rivals");
    • (1995) The Constitution As Political Structure , pp. 106
    • Martin, H.R.1
  • 365
    • 84937308408 scopus 로고
    • Checks and balances in an era of presidential lawmaking
    • 156
    • Abner S. Greene, Checks and Balances in an Era of Presidential Lawmaking, 61 U. CHI. L. REV. 123, 156 (1994);
    • (1994) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 123
    • Greene, A.S.1
  • 366
    • 79957865585 scopus 로고
    • The place of agencies in government: Separation of powers and the fourth branch
    • 578
    • Peter L. Strauss, The Place of Agencies in Government: Separation of Powers and the Fourth Branch, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 573, 578 (1984).
    • (1984) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 573
    • Strauss, P.L.1
  • 367
    • 79951698048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This idea was originally advanced by Madison and other Federalists. See The Federalist Nos. 45-46 James Madison. Herbert Wechsler's theory of "the political safeguards of federalism" reinvigorated the idea, which has served as perhaps the primary justification for the demise of serious judicial attempts to enforce constitutional federalism limitations after the New Deal
    • This idea was originally advanced by Madison and other Federalists. See The Federalist Nos. 45-46 (James Madison). Herbert Wechsler's theory of "the political safeguards of federalism" reinvigorated the idea, which has served as perhaps the primary justification for the demise of serious judicial attempts to enforce constitutional federalism limitations after the New Deal.
  • 368
    • 0011412477 scopus 로고
    • The political safeguards of federalism: The role of the states in the composition and selection of the national government
    • See Herbert Wechsler, The Political Safeguards of Federalism: The Role of the States in the Composition and Selection of the National Government, 54 COLUM. L. REV. 543 (1954);
    • (1954) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.54-543
    • Wechsler, H.1
  • 369
    • 23044520762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putting the politics back into the political safeguards of federalism
    • see also, 217, describing the political safeguards argument as "the dominant post-New Deal theory of judicial review and federalism"
    • see also Larry D. Kramer, Putting the Politics Back into the Political Safeguards of Federalism, 100 COLUM. L. REV. 215, 217 (2000) (describing the political safeguards argument as "the dominant post-New Deal theory of judicial review and federalism").
    • (2000) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 215
    • Kramer, L.D.1
  • 370
    • 79951701797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra pp. 670-71
    • See supra pp. 670-71.
  • 371
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential administration
    • See, 2314, "The partisan and constituency interests of individual members of Congress usually prevent them from acting collectively to preserve congressional power - or, what is almost the same thing, to deny authority to the other branches of government."
    • See Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 HARV. L. REV. 2245, 2314 (2001) ("The partisan and constituency interests of individual members of Congress usually prevent them from acting collectively to preserve congressional power - or, what is almost the same thing, to deny authority to the other branches of government.");
    • (2001) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.114 , pp. 2245
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 372
    • 0033465758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The presidential power of unilateral action
    • 144, explaining that members of Congress will object to executive orders only if those orders are detrimental to their constituencies, and noting that the "fact that the order might well be seen as usurping Congress's lawmaking powers, or that it has the effect of expanding presidential power, will for most legislators be quite beside the point"
    • Terry M. Moe & William G. Howell, The Presidential Power of Unilateral Action, 15 J. L. Econ. & Org. 132, 144 (1999) (explaining that members of Congress will object to executive orders only if those orders are detrimental to their constituencies, and noting that the "fact that [the] order might well be seen as usurping Congress's lawmaking powers, or that it has the effect of expanding presidential power, will for most legislators be quite beside the point").
    • (1999) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.15 , pp. 132
    • Moe, T.M.1    Howell, W.G.2
  • 373
    • 79951689098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 928
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 928.
  • 374
    • 79951702195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an extended version of the argument that follows, see Levinson, supra note 30
    • For an extended version of the argument that follows, see Levinson, supra note 30.
  • 375
    • 0040146716 scopus 로고
    • Federal deference to local regulators and the economic theory of regulation: Toward a public-choice explanation of federalism
    • See generally
    • See generally Jonathan R. Macey, Federal Deference to Local Regulators and the Economic Theory of Regulation: Toward a Public-Choice Explanation of Federalism, 76 VA. L. REV. 265 (1990).
    • (1990) Va. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 265
    • Macey, J.R.1
  • 376
    • 79951707130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 276-80
    • See id. at 276-80.
  • 377
    • 79951689947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 281-82
    • See id. at 281-82.
  • 379
    • 0042877947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valuing federalism
    • See Barry Friedman, Valuing Federalism, 82 MINN. L. REV. 317, 365-78 (1997). (Pubitemid 127423564)
    • (1997) Minnesota Law Review , vol.82 , Issue.2 , pp. 317
    • Friedman, B.1
  • 380
    • 0039540523 scopus 로고
    • The article I, section 7 game
    • See, &, 534-40
    • See William N. Eskridge, Jr. & John Ferejohn, The Article I, Section 7 Game, 80 GEO. L. J. 523, 534-40 (1992);
    • (1992) Geo. L. J , vol.80 , pp. 523
    • Eskridge Jr., W.N.1    Ferejohn, J.2
  • 381
    • 0041557883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most dangerous branch
    • 1819-21
    • Martin S. Flaherty, The Most Dangerous Branch, 105 YALE L. J. 1725, 1819-21 (1996);
    • (1996) Yale L. J , vol.105 , pp. 1725
    • Flaherty, M.S.1
  • 382
    • 0042578750 scopus 로고
    • The rise and rise of the administrative state
    • cf, 1237-41
    • cf. Gary Lawson, The Rise and Rise of the Administrative State, 107 HARV. L. REV. 1231, 1237-41 (1994).
    • (1994) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1231
    • Lawson, G.1
  • 387
    • 79951685124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELY, supra note 244, at ix
    • ELY, supra note 244, at ix.
  • 388
    • 79951698230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. "The legislative surrender was a self-interested one...."
    • Id. ("[T]he legislative surrender was a self-interested one....").
  • 389
    • 79951718273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See POSNER & VERMEULE, supra note 245, at 47
    • See POSNER & VERMEULE, supra note 245, at 47.
  • 390
    • 79951685506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELY, supra note 244, at 52-54
    • See ELY, supra note 244, at 52-54.
  • 391
    • 79951693036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KOH, supra note 244, at 133 describing how, when President Reagan took military action in Grenada and Libya "without complying with the terms of the War Powers Resolution,. advocates of his policy decision remained quiet rather than contest his procedural violation"
    • See KOH, supra note 244, at 133 (describing how, when President Reagan took military action in Grenada and Libya "without complying with the terms of the War Powers Resolution,... advocates of his policy decision remained quiet rather than contest his procedural violation");
  • 392
    • 79951715811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also ELY, supra note 244, at 175 n. 34 "Separation of powers issues are not the sort voters get exercised about."
    • see also ELY, supra note 244, at 175 n. 34 ("Separation of powers issues are not the sort voters get exercised about.").
  • 393
    • 79951690524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even so, many of the benefits of enhancing the power of the presidency will be externalized onto future occupants and spread among other policymaking officials in the executive branch
    • Even so, many of the benefits of enhancing the power of the presidency will be externalized onto future occupants and spread among other policymaking officials in the executive branch.
  • 394
    • 79951710509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kagan, supra note 234, at 2310 pointing to the fact that "Congress repeatedly has failed to demonstrate sustained capacity for political leadership" as one explanation for the public pressure on modern Presidents to assert control over political decisionmaking
    • See Kagan, supra note 234, at 2310 (pointing to the fact that "Congress repeatedly has failed to demonstrate sustained capacity for political leadership" as one explanation for the public pressure on modern Presidents to assert control over political decisionmaking).
  • 395
    • 79951705206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2310-11, 2335-36
    • See id. at 2310-11, 2335-36;
  • 396
    • 79951696678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moe & Howell, supra note 234
    • Moe & Howell, supra note 234.
  • 397
    • 0347510831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A self-enforcing model of corporate law
    • It is telling that legal theorists in areas far removed from constitutional law and the constitutional text seem to share this intuition. For instance, Bernard Black and Reinier Kraakman offer a "self-enforcing" approach to corporate law for emerging capitalist economies in which judicial enforcement is unreliable. See, &, Their basic strategy is to focus on "structural" rules creating corporate decisionmaking processes that empower minority shareholders and other vulnerable stakeholders to protect themselves through voting and other mechanisms
    • It is telling that legal theorists in areas far removed from constitutional law (and the constitutional text) seem to share this intuition. For instance, Bernard Black and Reinier Kraakman offer a "self- enforcing" approach to corporate law for emerging capitalist economies in which judicial enforcement is unreliable. See Bernard Black & Reinier Kraakman, A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law, 109 HARV. L. REV. 1911 (1996). Their basic strategy is to focus on "structural" rules creating corporate decisionmaking processes that empower minority shareholders and other vulnerable stakeholders to protect themselves through voting and other mechanisms.
    • (1996) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.109 , pp. 1911
    • Black, B.1    Kraakman, R.2
  • 398
    • 79951692225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1932-37. Black and Kraakman contrast this approach with a "prohibitive model", which effectively grants these vulnerable stakeholders rights against particular corporate behaviors that create the potential for abuse
    • Id. at 1932-37. Black and Kraakman contrast this approach with a "prohibitive model", which effectively grants these vulnerable stakeholders rights against particular corporate behaviors that create the potential for abuse.
  • 399
    • 79951717128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1929-31. The premise of the article is that rules about structure and process for example, shareholder voting requirements will constrain corporate insiders more effectively and command greater compliance than rights against specific corporate abuses. Whatever is supposed to account for the greater efficacy of rules related to structure and process in this setting, it cannot be the specificity of textual expression. Black and Kraakman are clear in their belief that rights are likely to be evaded or ignored even when they are specified in "considerable detail."
    • Id. at 1929-31. The premise of the article is that rules about structure and process (for example, shareholder voting requirements) will constrain corporate insiders more effectively and command greater compliance than rights against specific corporate abuses. Whatever is supposed to account for the greater efficacy of rules related to structure and process in this setting, it cannot be the specificity of textual expression. Black and Kraakman are clear in their belief that rights are likely to be evaded or ignored even when they are specified in "considerable detail."
  • 400
    • 79951699413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1929
    • Id. at 1929.
  • 402
    • 0004274314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A particularly striking example is the successful lobbying by copyright holders such as Disney for greater protection for their intellectual property. See
    • A particularly striking example is the successful lobbying by copyright holders such as Disney for greater protection for their intellectual property. See JESSICA LITMAN, DIGITAL COPYRIGHT 23-24 (2001);
    • (2001) Digital Copyright , pp. 23-24
    • Jessica, L.1
  • 403
    • 23044526679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright's first amendment
    • 1065, terming the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998 the "Mickey Mouse Protection Act"
    • Lawrence Lessig, Copyright's First Amendment, 48 UCLA L. REV. 1057, 1065 (2001) (terming the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998 the "Mickey Mouse Protection Act").
    • (2001) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 1057
    • Lessig, L.1
  • 404
    • 79951704267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 121-25 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 121-25 and accompanying text.
  • 405
    • 79951697671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carpenter, supra note 219, at 89-97
    • See Carpenter, supra note 219, at 89-97.
  • 406
    • 79951701610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Weingast, supra note 220, at 154-55
    • See Weingast, supra note 220, at 154-55.
  • 407
    • 79951696104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GRABER, supra note 215, at 144-48
    • See GRABER, supra note 215, at 144-48;
  • 408
    • 79951715434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 155-56 examining the demise of national parties' ability to maintain bisectionalism during the 1850s
    • id. at 155-56 (examining the demise of national parties' ability to maintain bisectionalism during the 1850s).
  • 409
    • 0042154319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stopping time: The pro-slavery and "irrevocable" thirteenth amendment
    • 1861, in a last-ditch attempt to prevent more Southern states from seceding, Congress proposed, President Lincoln endorsed, and three states ratified a constitutional amendment known as the Corwin Amendment that made explicit Congress's lack of power to interfere with or abolish slavery in any state, and that prohibited any subsequent constitutional amendment to the contrary. Southerners were dismissive of this proposed thirteenth amendment, and it did nothing to prevent secession and war. See generally, Interestingly, Southerners had been much more receptive to the Crittenden Compromise, an earlier package of proposed "unamendable" amendments highlighted by a reinstatement and extension of the Missouri Compromise line that would have protected slavery in the Southern territories. The Crittenden Compromise was rejected by Republicans
    • In 1861, in a last-ditch attempt to prevent more Southern states from seceding, Congress proposed, President Lincoln endorsed, and three states ratified a constitutional amendment (known as the Corwin Amendment) that made explicit Congress's lack of power to interfere with or abolish slavery in any state, and that prohibited any subsequent constitutional amendment to the contrary. Southerners were dismissive of this proposed thirteenth amendment, and it did nothing to prevent secession and war. See generally A. Christopher Bryant, Stopping Time: The Pro-Slavery and "Irrevocable" Thirteenth Amendment, 26 HARV. J. L. & PUB. POL'Y 501 (2003). Interestingly, Southerners had been much more receptive to the Crittenden Compromise, an earlier package of proposed "unamendable" amendments highlighted by a reinstatement and extension of the Missouri Compromise line that would have protected slavery in the Southern territories. The Crittenden Compromise was rejected by Republicans.
    • (2003) Harv. J. L. & Pub. Pol'Y , vol.26 , pp. 501
    • Bryant, A.C.1
  • 410
    • 79951715247 scopus 로고
    • See, at, 549-54 Don E. Fehrenbacher ed.
    • See DAVID M. POTTER, THE IMPENDING CRISIS, 1848-1861, at 531-35, 549-54 (Don E. Fehrenbacher ed., 1976).
    • (1976) The Impending Crisis, 1848-1861 , pp. 531-535
    • David, M.P.1
  • 411
    • 79951685699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Having been stripped of both the franchise and the rights they had briefly enjoyed during Reconstruction, Southern blacks must have been acutely aware of durability and political resilience as important variables in thinking about how to advance civil rights
    • Having been stripped of both the franchise and the rights they had briefly enjoyed during Reconstruction, Southern blacks must have been acutely aware of durability and political resilience as important variables in thinking about how to advance civil rights.
  • 412
    • 79951686799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Weingast, supra note 57; supra p. 677
    • See Weingast, supra note 57; supra p. 677.
  • 413
    • 79951697483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussion in this section will refer to the Supreme Court as shorthand for the entire judiciary. Much of what is said will be equally applicable to the highest or constitutional courts of other countries
    • The discussion in this section will refer to the Supreme Court as shorthand for the entire judiciary. Much of what is said will be equally applicable to the highest or constitutional courts of other countries.
  • 414
    • 79951719983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judicial review as a constitutional commitment mechanism also depends on incentive compatibility: judges must be motivated to enforce constitutional rights instead of doing something else entirely. While the focus of this section is on institutional stability, some of what follows is also relevant to the question of judicial motivation
    • Judicial review as a constitutional commitment mechanism also depends on incentive compatibility: judges must be motivated to enforce constitutional rights instead of doing something else entirely. While the focus of this section is on institutional stability, some of what follows is also relevant to the question of judicial motivation.
  • 415
    • 79951706363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 26 "Political actors must have reasons for allowing the Court to 'win.' They... must see some political value in deferring to the Court and helping to construct a space for judicial autonomy."
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 26 ("[P]olitical actors must have reasons for allowing the Court to 'win.' [They]... must see some political value in deferring to the Court and helping to construct a space for judicial autonomy.");
  • 416
    • 35148830694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining de facto judicial independence
    • 269-74, emphasizing that the judiciary can serve as a constitutional commitment mechanism only if political actors maintain a higher-order commitment to judicial independence
    • Bernd Hayo & Stefan Voigt, Explaining de Facto Judicial Independence, 27 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 269, 269-74 (2007) (emphasizing that the judiciary can serve as a constitutional commitment mechanism only if political actors maintain a higher-order commitment to judicial independence).
    • (2007) Int'L Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.27 , pp. 269
    • Hayo, B.1    Voigt, S.2
  • 417
    • 79951701050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fallon, supra note 2, at 1016 collecting examples
    • See Fallon, supra note 2, at 1016 (collecting examples);
  • 418
    • 79951706754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 27 "We can easily imagine presidents dismissing the authority of the Court and ignoring its opinions."
    • see also WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 27 ("We can easily imagine presidents dismissing the authority of the Court and ignoring its opinions....").
  • 419
    • 0036807863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Independent judges, dependent judiciary: Institutionalizing judicial restraint
    • See, &, 986-89
    • See John A. Ferejohn & Larry D. Kramer, Independent Judges, Dependent Judiciary: Institutionalizing Judicial Restraint, 77 N. Y. U. L. REV. 962, 986-89 (2002).
    • (2002) N. Y. U. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 962
    • Ferejohn, J.A.1    Kramer, L.D.2
  • 420
    • 79951700876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 981-82
    • Id. at 981-82.
  • 421
    • 33645478717 scopus 로고
    • 60 U. S. (19 How.) 393 (1857).
    • (1857) U. S. (19 How.) , vol.60 , pp. 393
  • 422
    • 77956730671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, discussing Dred Scott
    • See BARRY FRIEDMAN, THE WILL OF THE PEOPLE 110-21 (2009) (discussing Dred Scott);
    • (2009) The Will of the People , pp. 110-121
    • Barry, F.1
  • 423
    • 79951693975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KLARMAN, supra note 208, at 385-421 discussing Brown
    • KLARMAN, supra note 208, at 385-421 (discussing Brown).
  • 425
    • 79951690335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 11
    • WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 11.
  • 426
    • 79951712412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MCCLOSKEY, supra note 212, at 224 "It is hard to find a single historical instance when the Court has stood firm for very long against a really clear wave of public demand."
    • See MCCLOSKEY, supra note 212, at 224 ("[I]t is hard to find a single historical instance when the Court has stood firm for very long against a really clear wave of public demand.");
  • 427
    • 0000770507 scopus 로고
    • Decision-making in a democracy: The supreme court as a national policy-maker
    • 285, "The policy views dominant on the Court are never for long out of line with the policy views dominant among the lawmaking majorities of the United States."
    • Robert A. Dahl, Decision-Making in a Democracy: The Supreme Court as a National Policy-Maker, 6 J. PUB. L. 279, 285 (1957) ("[T]he policy views dominant on the Court are never for long out of line with the policy views dominant among the lawmaking majorities of the United States.").
    • (1957) J. Pub. L , vol.6 , pp. 279
    • Dahl, R.A.1
  • 428
    • 33646367984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, &, 47-66, Of course, federal judges serve for long periods of time, and their political preferences may fall out of line as different coalitions become dominant. Thus, Dahl predicted that the Court would come into serious conflict with the political branches only during rare periods of electoral instability, when a newly dominant electoral coalition confronted Justices appointed by their defeated ideological rivals. The New Deal was Dahl's paradigm case
    • See LEE EPSTEIN & JEFFREY A. SEGAL, ADVICE AND CONSENT: THE POLITICS OF JUDICIAL APPOINTMENTS 26-27, 47-66 (2005). Of course, federal judges serve for long periods of time, and their political preferences may fall out of line as different coalitions become dominant. Thus, Dahl predicted that the Court would come into serious conflict with the political branches only during rare periods of electoral instability, when a newly dominant electoral coalition confronted Justices appointed by their defeated ideological rivals. The New Deal was Dahl's paradigm case.
    • (2005) Advice and Consent: The Politics of Judicial Appointments , pp. 26-27
    • Lee, E.1    Jeffrey, A.S.2
  • 429
    • 79951705806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dahl, supra note 274, at 285. This pattern seems to have held true less than Dahl expected, however
    • Dahl, supra note 274, at 285. This pattern seems to have held true less than Dahl expected, however.
  • 430
    • 79951702622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Whittington, supra note 8, at 12
    • See Whittington, supra note 8, at 12.
  • 431
    • 79951699232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ferejohn & Kramer, supra note 268, at 994 "Taken as a whole, the miscellaneous devices available to the political branches to obstruct the courts afford ample means to cow or even cripple the federal judiciary."
    • See Ferejohn & Kramer, supra note 268, at 994 ("Taken as a whole, the miscellaneous devices available to the political branches to obstruct the courts afford ample means to cow or even cripple the federal judiciary.");
  • 432
    • 47049107976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, observing that Justices are constrained by "an awareness, conscious or unconscious, that they cannot go 'too far' without inviting reprisals by the other branches of government spurred on by an indignant public"
    • see also RICHARD A. POSNER, HOW JUDGES THINK 375 (2008) (observing that Justices are constrained by "an awareness, conscious or unconscious, that they cannot go 'too far' without inviting reprisals by the other branches of government spurred on by an indignant public").
    • (2008) How Judges Think , pp. 375
    • Richard, A.P.1
  • 433
    • 41549084694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The supreme court in American democracy: Unraveling the linkages between public opinion and judicial decision making
    • A growing empirical literature attempts to sort out the contributions of indirect selection and direct political control on judicial behavior. For recent surveys of and contributions to this debate, see, and
    • A growing empirical literature attempts to sort out the contributions of indirect selection and direct political control on judicial behavior. For recent surveys of (and contributions to) this debate, see Micheal W. Giles et al., The Supreme Court in American Democracy: Unraveling the Linkages Between Public Opinion and Judicial Decision Making, 70 J. POL. 293 (2008);
    • (2008) J. Pol. , vol.70 , pp. 293
    • Giles, M.W.1
  • 435
    • 79951688339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally FRIEDMAN, supra note 271
    • See generally FRIEDMAN, supra note 271.
  • 436
    • 33947096855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The supreme court, 2005 term - Foreword: The court's agenda - And the nation's
    • See Frederick Schauer, The Supreme Court, 2005 Term - Foreword: The Court's Agenda - and the Nation's, 120 HARV. L. REV. 4 (2006).
    • (2006) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.120 , pp. 4
    • Schauer, F.1
  • 437
    • 79951714683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conceivably, the Justices might lack the inclination because the Constitution simply does not speak to these salient and high-stakes political issues. as a purely legal matter, however, the constitutional case against executive power to detain enemy combatants in Guantánamo or the open-ended delegation of authority to the Secretary of the Treasury to manage the financial crisis seems at least as strong as the constitutional case against voluntary school integration, gendersegregated public colleges, or sodomy laws
    • Conceivably, the Justices might lack the inclination because the Constitution simply does not speak to these salient and high-stakes political issues. as a purely legal matter, however, the constitutional case against executive power to detain enemy combatants in Guantánamo or the open-ended delegation of authority to the Secretary of the Treasury to manage the financial crisis seems at least as strong as the constitutional case against voluntary school integration, gendersegregated public colleges, or sodomy laws.
  • 439
    • 84887348081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 209, at
    • Klarman, Rethinking, supra note 209, at 16-17.
    • Rethinking , pp. 16-17
    • Klarman1
  • 440
    • 23844549426 scopus 로고
    • 410 U. S. 113 (1973).
    • (1973) U. S , vol.410 , pp. 113
  • 441
    • 33646691324 scopus 로고
    • 438 U. S. 265 (1978).
    • (1978) U. S , vol.438 , pp. 265
  • 442
    • 15744397664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • per curiam
    • 531 U. S. 98 (2000) (per curiam).
    • (2000) U. S , vol.531 , pp. 98
  • 443
    • 0041329886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Through the lens of constitutional history
    • See, Bush v. Gore, 1749-50
    • See Michael J. Klarman, Bush v. Gore Through the Lens of Constitutional History, 89 CALIF. L. REV. 1721, 1749-50 (2001).
    • (2001) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 1721
    • Klarman, M.J.1
  • 444
    • 79951689687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dahl, supra note 274, at 293
    • Dahl, supra note 274, at 293.
  • 445
    • 79951700503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Klarman, supra note 285, at 1750. While these decisions have been modestly countermajoritarian, it is still the case that substantial minorities of the country have supported them. For more detailed information about public opinion in each of these contexts
    • See Klarman, supra note 285, at 1750. While these decisions have been modestly countermajoritarian, it is still the case that substantial minorities of the country have supported them. For more detailed information about public opinion in each of these contexts
  • 447
    • 84934563603 scopus 로고
    • The etiology of public support for the supreme court
    • 636
    • Gregory A. Caldeira & James L. Gibson, The Etiology of Public Support for the Supreme Court, 36 AM. J. POL. SCI. 635, 636 (1992);
    • (1992) Am. J. Pol. Sci , vol.36 , pp. 635
    • Caldeira, G.A.1    Gibson, J.L.2
  • 448
    • 32244434850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The politics of judicial review
    • see also, 325-28, surveying the political science literature on diffuse support
    • see also Barry Friedman, The Politics of Judicial Review, 84 TEX. L. REV. 257, 325-28 (2005) (surveying the political science literature on diffuse support).
    • (2005) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 257
    • Friedman, B.1
  • 449
    • 79951713754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Caldeira & Gibson, supra note 288, at 637
    • Caldeira & Gibson, supra note 288, at 637.
  • 450
    • 79951702802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the political history of the New Deal Court-packing episode, see FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 195-236; and
    • On the political history of the New Deal Court-packing episode, see FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 195-236; and
  • 451
    • 79751483260 scopus 로고
    • As Ely summarizes, "The message is mixed, but what now seems important about the episode is that an immensely popular President riding an immensely popular cause had his lance badly blunted by his assault on judicial independence."
    • WILLIAM E. LEUCHTENBURG, THE SUPREME COURT REBORN: THE CONSTITUTIONAL REVOLUTION IN THE AGE OF ROOSEVELT (1995). As Ely summarizes, "The message is mixed, but what now seems important about the episode is that an immensely popular President riding an immensely popular cause had his lance badly blunted by his assault on judicial independence."
    • (1995) The Supreme Court Reborn: The Constitutional Revolution in the Age of Roosevelt
    • William, E.L.1
  • 452
    • 79951714891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELY, supra note 5, at 46
    • ELY, supra note 5, at 46.
  • 453
    • 79951694149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 373-74 noting this empirical deficit. Existing quantitative measures of judicial independence are highly imperfect. For an example of the state of the art
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 373-74 (noting this empirical deficit). Existing quantitative measures of judicial independence are highly imperfect. For an example of the state of the art
  • 454
    • 79951714133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Hayo & Voigt, supra note 266, at 279-80
    • see Hayo & Voigt, supra note 266, at 279-80.
  • 455
    • 79951712787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even those who are inclined toward this extreme would grant that the frictions of the ordinary political process will generate at least some degree of slack. Justices serve for long periods, and redirecting the Court through appointments takes time. Political attacks on judicial independence require statutes, which can be blocked by a majority or even a well-situated minority in either chamber of Congress, or by the President's veto. Only during periods of strongly unified government can a single political party wage a successful partisan war against the Court. as for the public, collective action in defiance of the Court is hard to mobilize, and it requires a population that is well informed and intensely opposed to what the Court is doing. All of these factors will inevitably create at least a modest political buffer around the Court
    • Even those who are inclined toward this extreme would grant that the frictions of the ordinary political process will generate at least some degree of slack. Justices serve for long periods, and redirecting the Court through appointments takes time. Political attacks on judicial independence require statutes, which can be blocked by a majority (or even a well-situated minority) in either chamber of Congress, or by the President's veto. Only during periods of strongly unified government can a single political party wage a successful partisan war against the Court. as for the public, collective action in defiance of the Court is hard to mobilize, and it requires a population that is well informed and intensely opposed to what the Court is doing. All of these factors will inevitably create at least a modest political buffer around the Court.
  • 456
    • 0041937099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What's so great about constitutionalism?
    • disproportionate political influence of elites is one straightforward explanation for the Court's apparently countermajoritarian decisions with respect to free speech, gay rights, and school prayer. These decisions track public opinion among the affluent and well educated. See, 190-91
    • The disproportionate political influence of elites is one straightforward explanation for the Court's apparently countermajoritarian decisions with respect to free speech, gay rights, and school prayer. These decisions track public opinion among the affluent and well educated. See Michael J. Klarman, What's So Great About Constitutionalism?, 93 NW. U. L. REV. 145, 190-91 (1998).
    • (1998) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 145
    • Klarman, M.J.1
  • 457
    • 1842815198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mediated popular constitutionalism
    • More generally, the low salience of most judicial decisions allows diffuse support to persist until the public is informed and organized by political elites. See, 2617-20, citing studies. Consequently, even strongly countermajoritarian decisions that serve the interests of elites may be insulated against public disapproval
    • More generally, the low salience of most judicial decisions allows diffuse support to persist until the public is informed and organized by political elites. See Barry Friedman, Mediated Popular Constitutionalism, 101 MICH. L. REV. 2596, 2617-20 (2003) (citing studies). Consequently, even strongly countermajoritarian decisions that serve the interests of elites may be insulated against public disapproval.
    • (2003) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.101 , pp. 2596
    • Friedman, B.1
  • 458
    • 79951701796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271;
  • 460
    • 79951700867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klarman, supra note 285, at 1749-50
    • Klarman, supra note 285, at 1749-50.
  • 461
    • 33644650824 scopus 로고
    • Planned Parenthood of Se. Pa. v. Casey, 865
    • Planned Parenthood of Se. Pa. v. Casey, 505 U. S. 833, 865 (1992).
    • (1992) U. S , vol.505 , pp. 833
  • 462
    • 79951692030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KRAMER, supra note 272, at 230-31
    • See KRAMER, supra note 272, at 230-31.
  • 463
    • 33646568221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Casey, at, "The Court must take care to speak and act in ways that allow people to accept its decisions on the terms the Court claims for them, as grounded truly in principle, not as compromises with social and political pressures....". For a discussion of the promiscuity of the term "legitimacy" in constitutional law and theory and a useful analytic parsing of its various meanings
    • See, e.g., Casey, 505 U. S. at 865 ("The Court must take care to speak and act in ways that allow people to accept its decisions on the terms the Court claims for them, as grounded truly in principle, not as compromises with social and political pressures...."). For a discussion of the promiscuity of the term "legitimacy" in constitutional law and theory and a useful analytic parsing of its various meanings
    • U. S , vol.505 , pp. 865
  • 464
    • 18144406540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legitimacy and the constitution
    • see generally
    • see generally Richard H. Fallon, Jr., Legitimacy and the Constitution, 118 HARV. L. REV. 1787 (2005).
    • (2005) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.118 , pp. 1787
    • Fallon Jr., R.H.1
  • 465
    • 79951702196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KRAMER, supra note 272, at 229-31
    • See KRAMER, supra note 272, at 229-31.
  • 466
    • 0028382387 scopus 로고
    • Legitimacy and the empowerment of discretionary legal authority: The United States supreme court and abortion rights
    • See, &
    • See Tom R. Tyler & Gregory Mitchell, Legitimacy and the Empowerment of Discretionary Legal Authority: The United States Supreme Court and Abortion Rights, 43 DUKE L. J. 703 (1994).
    • (1994) Duke L. J , vol.43 , pp. 703
    • Tyler, T.R.1    Mitchell, G.2
  • 467
    • 79951704087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Klarman, supra note 285, at 1722-23
    • See Klarman, supra note 285, at 1722-23.
  • 468
    • 79951706176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162
    • Letter from James Madison to Thomas Jefferson, supra note 10, at 162.
  • 469
    • 79951710704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FEDERALIST No. 51 James Madison, supra note 9, at 320
    • THE FEDERALIST No. 51 (James Madison), supra note 9, at 320;
  • 470
    • 79951704467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra p. 667
    • see also supra p. 667.
  • 471
    • 64949192850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of judicial power and judicial review
    • See David S. Law, A Theory of Judicial Power and Judicial Review, 97 GEO. L. J. 723 (2009);
    • (2009) Geo. L. J , vol.97 , pp. 723
    • Law, D.S.1
  • 472
    • 79951694355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weingast, supra note 83
    • Weingast, supra note 83.
  • 473
    • 79951705397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Law, supra note 303, at 786
    • See Law, supra note 303, at 786.
  • 474
    • 79951712597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 731
    • Id. at 731.
  • 475
    • 79951713551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey of this evidence, see id. at 729-30 nn. 19-20. This account also resonates with anecdotal observations that the Court, during times of war and crisis, has been markedly more aggressive in standing up to unpopular and politically weak Presidents. See POSNER & VERMEULE, supra note 245, at 50-51
    • For a survey of this evidence, see id. at 729-30 nn. 19-20. This account also resonates with anecdotal observations that the Court, during times of war and crisis, has been markedly more aggressive in standing up to unpopular and politically weak Presidents. See POSNER & VERMEULE, supra note 245, at 50-51.
  • 476
    • 79951718274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 971-72
    • See Levinson, supra note 30, at 971-72.
  • 477
    • 79951686278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • the special context of voting and election law, where representatives have especially strong self-serving incentives, constitutional scholars have emphasized the strong normative case for judicial enforcement of agency-focused "anti-entrenchment" rules. See generally Klarman, supra note 107. The complementary descriptive observation is that public support for judicial enforcement of these rules will come naturally
    • In the special context of voting and election law, where representatives have especially strong self-serving incentives, constitutional scholars have emphasized the strong normative case for judicial enforcement of agency-focused "anti-entrenchment" rules. See generally Klarman, supra note 107. The complementary descriptive observation is that public support for judicial enforcement of these rules will come naturally.
  • 478
    • 79951708618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 166-77 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 166-77 and accompanying text.
  • 479
    • 0347419773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On extrajudicial constitutional interpretation
    • See Larry Alexander & Frederick Schauer, On Extrajudicial Constitutional Interpretation, 110 HARV. L. REV. 1359, 1377 (1997). (Pubitemid 127437500)
    • (1997) Harvard Law Review , vol.111 , Issue.3 , pp. 1359
    • Alexander, L.1    Schauer, F.2
  • 480
    • 79951708125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELKINS et AL., supra note 92, at 106-08
    • See ELKINS et AL., supra note 92, at 106-08.
  • 481
    • 79951714883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf, defending the Court's intervention in Bush v. Gore as pragmatically necessary to avert a constitutional and political crisis
    • Cf. RICHARD A. POSNER, BREAKING THE DEADLOCK 150-89 (2001) (defending the Court's intervention in Bush v. Gore as pragmatically necessary to avert a constitutional and political crisis).
    • (2001) Breaking the Deadlock , pp. 150-189
    • Richard, A.P.1
  • 482
    • 79951706937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ramseyer, supra note 88; Stephenson, supra note 8
    • Ramseyer, supra note 88; Stephenson, supra note 8.
  • 484
    • 79951690889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Here again, the value added by judicial review lies in coordinating actors' understandings and expectations of what counts as a constitutional violation. See Stephenson, supra note 8, at 68-70
    • Here again, the value added by judicial review lies in coordinating actors' understandings and expectations of what counts as a constitutional violation. See Stephenson, supra note 8, at 68-70.
  • 485
    • 79951694161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ramseyer, supra note 88, at 742-43
    • See Ramseyer, supra note 88, at 742-43.
  • 486
    • 79951717302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the apparent rise of judicial supremacy in recent decades, see KRAMER, supra note 272, at 219-26
    • On the apparent rise of judicial supremacy in recent decades, see KRAMER, supra note 272, at 219-26.
  • 487
    • 79951706930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 287-88
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 287-88;
  • 488
    • 84972487467 scopus 로고
    • The nonmajoritarian difficulty: Legislative deference to the judiciary
    • 58-65
    • Mark A. Graber, The Nonmajoritarian Difficulty: Legislative Deference to the Judiciary, 7 STUD. AM. POL. DEV. 35, 58-65 (1993);
    • (1993) Stud. Am. Pol. Dev , vol.7 , pp. 35
    • Graber, M.A.1
  • 489
    • 30944438168 scopus 로고
    • A positive analysis of the doctrine of separation of powers, or: Why do we have an independent judiciary?
    • Eli M. Salzberger, A Positive Analysis of the Doctrine of Separation of Powers, or: Why Do We Have an Independent Judiciary?, 13 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 349 (1993);
    • (1993) Int'L Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.13 , pp. 349
    • Salzberger, E.M.1
  • 490
    • 33644880047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Interpose your friendly hand": Political supports for the exercise of judicial review by the United States supreme court
    • 584-86
    • Keith E. Whittington, "Interpose Your Friendly Hand": Political Supports for the Exercise of Judicial Review by the United States Supreme Court, 99 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 583, 584-86 (2005).
    • (2005) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 583
    • Whittington, K.E.1
  • 491
    • 79951698231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 105-20
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 105-20.
  • 492
    • 79951711076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Whittington, supra note 318, at 589-91
    • See Whittington, supra note 318, at 589-91.
  • 493
    • 79951686993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 130-34
    • See WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 130-34.
  • 494
    • 79951706184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 134-52
    • See id. at 134-52;
  • 495
    • 79951693807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Graber, supra note 318
    • Graber, supra note 318;
  • 496
    • 79951698241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whittington, supra note 318, at 591-93
    • Whittington, supra note 318, at 591-93.
  • 497
    • 79951714693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 147
    • WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 147.
  • 498
    • 79951685867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Graber, supra note 318, at 46-50
    • See Graber, supra note 318, at 46-50.
  • 499
    • 79951684115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 218-22
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 218-22;
  • 500
    • 79951694537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 269-70. For another example, Klarman hypothesizes that one reason the Rehnquist Court "survived Bush v. Gore reasonably unscathed, was because the remainder of the Court's constitutional jurisprudence has been such a political grab bag of results", including liberal decisions on abortion, school prayer, gender discrimination, and free speech. Klarman, supra note 285, at 1763
    • WHITTINGTON, supra note 8, at 269-70. For another example, Klarman hypothesizes that one reason the Rehnquist Court "survive[d] Bush v. Gore reasonably unscathed, [was] because the remainder of the Court's constitutional jurisprudence has been such a political grab bag of results", including liberal decisions on abortion, school prayer, gender discrimination, and free speech. Klarman, supra note 285, at 1763;
  • 501
    • 22144492797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, describing the Rehnquist Court's activism in enforcing both liberal and conservative rights
    • see also THOMAS M. KECK, THE MOST ACTIVIST SUPREME COURT IN HISTORY 199-253 (2004) (describing the Rehnquist Court's activism in enforcing both liberal and conservative rights).
    • (2004) The Most Activist Supreme Court in History , pp. 199-253
    • Thomas, M.K.1
  • 502
    • 33745226693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political constraints on supreme court reform
    • 1162, alterations in original
    • Adrian Vermeule, Essay, Political Constraints on Supreme Court Reform, 90 MINN. L. REV. 1154, 1162 (2006) (alterations in original)
    • (2006) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.90 , pp. 1154
    • Vermeule, A.E.1
  • 503
    • 84928841242 scopus 로고
    • The president and the court: Reinterpreting the court-packing episode of 1937
    • quoting, 276, internal quotation marks omitted
    • (quoting Michael Nelson, The President and the Court: Reinterpreting the Court-Packing Episode of 1937, 103 Pol. Sci. Q. 267, 276 (1988)) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • (1988) Pol. Sci. Q , vol.103 , pp. 267
    • Nelson, M.1
  • 504
    • 0038783000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring attitudes toward the United States supreme court
    • See, 364
    • See James L. Gibson et al., Measuring Attitudes Toward the United States Supreme Court, 47 Am. J. Pol. Sci. 354, 364 (2003).
    • (2003) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.47 , pp. 354
    • Gibson, J.L.1
  • 505
    • 84972344654 scopus 로고
    • Blacks and the United States supreme court: Models of diffuse support
    • See, &, One interpretation is that this cohort has been slow to update its beliefs about the expected value of judicial review. Another is that the experience of the Warren Court reminds them of the potentially positive value of judicial review in the future
    • See James L. Gibson & Gregory A. Caldeira, Blacks and the United States Supreme Court: Models of Diffuse Support, 54 J. Pol. 1120 (1992). One interpretation is that this cohort has been slow to update its beliefs about the expected value of judicial review. Another is that the experience of the Warren Court reminds them of the potentially positive value of judicial review in the future.
    • (1992) J. Pol. , vol.54 , pp. 1120
    • Gibson, J.L.1    Caldeira, G.A.2
  • 506
    • 79951684931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. An analogous anecdotal observation is commonly made about law professors
    • See id. An analogous anecdotal observation is commonly made about law professors.
  • 507
    • 0031326637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Border patrol: Reflections on the turn to history in legal scholarship
    • See, e.g., 90, "Because of the nation's experience with the Warren Court, legal liberalism has been linked to political liberalism since mid-century."
    • See, e.g., Laura Kalman, Border Patrol: Reflections on the Turn to History in Legal Scholarship, 66 FORDHAM L. REV. 87, 90 (1997) ("Because of the nation's experience with the Warren Court, legal liberalism has been linked to political liberalism since mid-century.").
    • (1997) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 87
    • Kalman, L.1
  • 508
    • 0003983215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, "Support, respect, and reverence for the Supreme Court remain strong today among American lawyers and constitute one of the main pillars of the Court's power."
    • See STEPHEN M. GRIFFIN, AmeriCAN CONSTITUTIONALISM: FROM THEORY TO POLITICS 98-99 (1996) ("Support, respect, and reverence for the Supreme Court remain strong today among American lawyers and constitute[] one of the main pillars of the Court's power."
    • (1996) American Constitutionalism: From Theory to Politics , pp. 98-99
    • Stephen, M.G.1
  • 509
    • 79951685330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 99.
    • Id. at 99.);
  • 510
    • 79951696274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The resilience of marbury v. Madison: Why judicial review has survived so many attacks
    • 763
    • William G. Ross, The Resilience of Marbury v. Madison: Why Judicial Review Has Survived So Many Attacks, 38 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 733, 763 (2003).
    • (2003) Wake Forest L. Rev. , vol.38 , pp. 733
    • Ross, W.G.1
  • 512
    • 79951697679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 268-69
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 268-69.
  • 513
    • 79951716193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KLARMAN, supra note 285, at 1754-55
    • See KLARMAN, supra note 285, at 1754-55.
  • 514
    • 79951719791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 171-87
    • See FRIEDMAN, supra note 271, at 171-87.
  • 515
    • 79951685698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 95
    • See supra note 95.
  • 516
    • 79951693966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael J. Klarman, Why Backlash? Aug. 2010 unpublished manuscript on file with the Harvard Law School Library
    • See Michael J. Klarman, Why Backlash? (Aug. 2010) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with the Harvard Law School Library).
  • 517
    • 79951695876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.;
  • 518
    • 34548620028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roe rage: Democratic constitutionalism and backlash
    • see also, &, surveying the literature on the political history of reaction to Roe and assessing the backlash hypothesis
    • see also Robert Post & Reva Siegel, Roe Rage: Democratic Constitutionalism and Backlash, 42 HARV. C. R.-C. L. L. REV. 373 (2007) (surveying the literature on the political history of reaction to Roe and assessing the backlash hypothesis).
    • (2007) Harv. C. R.-C. L. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 373
    • Post, R.1    Siegel, R.2
  • 519
    • 79951716551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOHN C. JEFFRIES, JR., JUSTICE LEWIS F. POWELL, JR. 358 1994
    • JOHN C. JEFFRIES, JR., JUSTICE LEWIS F. POWELL, JR. 358 (1994).
  • 520
    • 79951713949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ELKINS et AL., supra note 92, at 1-2 also noting the coincidence that nineteen years was Thomas Jefferson's proposed expiration date for constitutions, on the principle that the "dead should not govern the living, "
    • ELKINS et AL., supra note 92, at 1-2 (also noting the coincidence that nineteen years was Thomas Jefferson's proposed expiration date for constitutions, on the principle that the "dead should not govern the living, "
  • 521
    • 79951704466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 1 quoting Letter from Thomas Jefferson to James Madison Sept. 6, 1789 internal quotation marks omitted
    • id. at 1 (quoting Letter from Thomas Jefferson to James Madison (Sept. 6, 1789)) (internal quotation marks omitted)).
  • 522
    • 79951707129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., sources cited supra note 4
    • See, e.g., sources cited supra note 4.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.