메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 95, Issue 3, 2011, Pages 715-781

Regulation in the behavioral era

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79955941623     PISSN: 00265535     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (34)

References (419)
  • 3
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics
    • Christine Jolls et al., A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471, 1471 (1998); (Pubitemid 128421723)
    • (1998) Stanford Law Review , vol.50 , Issue.5 , pp. 1471
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 4
    • 0041906967 scopus 로고
    • Choices, values, and frames
    • 341
    • Daniel Kahneman & Amos Tversky, Choices, Values, and Frames, 39 AM. PSYCHOLOGIST 341, 341 (1984);
    • (1984) Am. Psychologist , vol.39 , pp. 341
    • Kahneman, D.1    Tversky, A.2
  • 5
    • 0002309280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Psychology and economics
    • 11
    • Matthew Rabin, Psychology and Economics, 36 J. ECON. LITERATURE 11, 11 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Econ. Literature , vol.36 , pp. 11
    • Rabin, M.1
  • 6
    • 68949201722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leaping the efficiency gap
    • For recent accounts in popular literature, see
    • For recent accounts in popular literature, see Dan Charles, Leaping the Efficiency Gap, 325 SCIENCE 804 (2009)
    • (2009) Science , vol.325 , pp. 804
    • Charles, D.1
  • 7
    • 65549087561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Obama is using the science of change
    • Apr.13
    • and Michael Grunwald, How Obama Is Using the Science of Change, TIME, Apr.13, 2009, at 28.
    • (2009) Time , pp. 28
    • Grunwald, M.1
  • 8
    • 79955935406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Letter from Cass R. Sunstein, Adm'r, Office of Info. & Regulatory Affairs, to the Honorable David Strickland, Adm'r, Nat'l Highway Traffic Safety Admin. Mar. 19, 2010, available at, encouraging the Agency to complete comprehensive studies that reflect principles of behavioral economics, such as promoting easy comparison shopping
    • See, e.g., Letter from Cass R. Sunstein, Adm'r, Office of Info. & Regulatory Affairs, to the Honorable David Strickland, Adm'r, Nat'l Highway Traffic Safety Admin. (Mar. 19, 2010), available at http://www.reginfo.gov/ public/postreview/Tire-Fuel-Efficiency-Consumer-Information-Final-Rule.pdf (encouraging the Agency to complete comprehensive studies that reflect principles of behavioral economics, such as promoting easy comparison shopping).
  • 9
    • 79955932850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, EXEC, available at, "OMB recommends consideration of behaviorally informed approaches to regulation. Such approaches, rooted in several decades of work in social science, can serve to improve rules by incorporating insights that come from relaxing assumptions usually invoked in neoclassical economic theory. With an accurate understanding of human behavior, agencies would be in a position to suggest innovative, effective, and low-cost methods of achieving regulatory goals."
    • See, e.g., OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, EXEC. OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT, 2009 REPORT TO CONGRESS ON THE BENEFITS AND COSTS OF FEDERAL REGULATIONS AND UNFUNDED MANDATES ON STATE, LOCAL, AND TRIBAL ENTITIES 35 (2010), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/assets/legislative-reports/ 2009-final-BC-Report-01272010.pdf ("OMB recommends consideration of behaviorally informed approaches to regulation. Such approaches, rooted in several decades of work in social science, can serve to improve rules by incorporating insights that come from relaxing assumptions usually invoked in neoclassical economic theory. With an accurate understanding of human behavior, agencies would be in a position to suggest innovative, effective, and low-cost methods of achieving regulatory goals.");
    • (2010) Office of the President, 2009 Report to Congress on the Benefits and Costs of Federal Regulations and Unfunded Mandates on State, Local, and Tribal Entities , pp. 35
  • 10
    • 84928081542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Memorandum from, June 18, hereinafter 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, available at, providing "guidance to inform the use of disclosure and simplification in the regulatory process"
    • see also Memorandum from Cass R. Sunstein, Adm'r, Office of Info. & Regulatory Affairs, to the Heads of Executive Departments and Agencies 1 (June 18, 2010) [hereinafter 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo], available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/assets/inforeg/ disclosure-principles.pdf (providing "guidance to inform the use of disclosure and simplification in the regulatory process").
    • (2010) Adm'R, Office of Info. & Regulatory Affairs, to the Heads of Executive Departments and Agencies , pp. 1
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 11
    • 77749279701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavior and energy policy
    • Behavioral economics incorporates many of cognitive psychology's findings, and it has become common in the media to apply the term "behavioral economics" to the findings of several fields. See, e.g., &, 1204-05
    • Behavioral economics incorporates many of cognitive psychology's findings, and it has become common in the media to apply the term "behavioral economics" to the findings of several fields. See, e.g., Hunt Allcott & Sendhil Mullainathan, Behavior and Energy Policy, 327 SCIENCE 1204, 1204-05 (2010);
    • (2010) Science , vol.327 , pp. 1204
    • Allcott, H.1    Mullainathan, S.2
  • 12
    • 75749113380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grunwald, supra note 3, at 28. For widely read recent works in social psychology, see
    • Grunwald, supra note 3, at 28. For widely read recent works in social psychology, see NOAH J. GOLDSTEIN ET AL., YES: 50 SCIENTIFICALLY PROVEN WAYS TO BE PERSUASIVE (2008);
    • (2008) Yes: 50 Scientifically Proven Ways to Be Persuasive
    • Goldstein, N.J.1
  • 15
    • 0002791064 scopus 로고
    • Resolving risk tradeoffs
    • 241-68 John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener eds., describing regulatory efforts that take into account human behavior
    • John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener, Resolving Risk Tradeoffs, in RISK VERSUS RISK 226, 241-68 (John D. Graham & Jonathan Baert Wiener eds., 1995) (describing regulatory efforts that take into account human behavior);
    • (1995) Risk Versus Risk , pp. 226
    • Graham, J.D.1    Wiener, J.B.2
  • 16
    • 0347107211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cognition and cost-benefit analysis
    • 1077-88, noting that one role of cost-benefit analysis is to correct for decisionmaking by policymakers under pressure from non-rational public responses to risk
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Cognition and Cost-Benefit Analysis, 29 J. LEGAL STUD. 1059, 1077-88 (2000) (noting that one role of cost-benefit analysis is to correct for decisionmaking by policymakers under pressure from non-rational public responses to risk).
    • (2000) J. Legal Stud. , vol.29 , pp. 1059
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 17
    • 0037808402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We include a number of fields in the term "behavioral science." See, e.g., &, economic sociology
    • We include a number of fields in the term "behavioral science." See, e.g., GARY S. BECKER & KEVIN M. MURPHY, SOCIAL ECONOMICS (2000) (economic sociology);
    • (2000) Social Economics
    • Becker, G.S.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 18
    • 79955934269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • GOLDSTEIN et AL., supra note 6 social psychology
    • GOLDSTEIN et AL., supra note 6 (social psychology);
  • 19
    • 79955940673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2 cognitive psychology
    • Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2 (cognitive psychology);
  • 20
    • 41549154805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neuroeconomics
    • neuroeconomics
    • George Loewenstein et al., Neuroeconomics, 59 ANN. REV. PSYCHOL. 647 (2008) (neuroeconomics).
    • (2008) Ann. Rev. Psychol. , vol.59 , pp. 647
    • Loewenstein, G.1
  • 21
    • 79953812429 scopus 로고
    • Section 6 a 3 C iii of Executive Order 12, 866 directs agencies to analyze "potentially effective and reasonably feasible alternatives to the planned regulation. " Exec. Order No. 12, 866 §6 a 3 C iii, 645
    • Section 6 (a) (3) (C) (iii) of Executive Order 12, 866 directs agencies to analyze "potentially effective and reasonably feasible alternatives to the planned regulation. " Exec. Order No. 12, 866 §6 (a) (3) (C) (iii), 3 C. F. R. 638, 645 (1993)
    • (1993) C. F. R , vol.3 , pp. 638
  • 22
    • 77956371522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • reprinted in, §
    • reprinted in 5 U. S. C. § 601 (2006);
    • (2006) U. S. C , vol.5 , pp. 601
  • 23
    • 84878171506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mechanism choice
    • see also, in, &, O'Connell eds., forthcoming, manuscript at 30-31, available at, discussing the potential influence of behavioral insights on regulatory-instrument choice
    • see also Jonathan Baert Wiener, Mechanism Choice, in PUBLIC CHOICE AND PUBLIC LAW (Daniel A. Farber & Anne Joseph O'Connell eds., forthcoming 2010) (manuscript at 30-31), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm? abstract-id=1408163 (discussing the potential influence of behavioral insights on regulatory-instrument choice);
    • (2010) Public Choice and Public Law
    • Wiener, J.B.1    Farber, D.A.2    Joseph, A.3
  • 24
    • 79955929846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 5, 9 identifying principles to assist agencies' use of information disclosure, simplification, and default rules
    • OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 3, 9 (identifying principles to assist agencies' use of information disclosure, simplification, and default rules).
    • (2010) Oira Disclosure Memo , pp. 3
  • 25
    • 79955941287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Part III. A. We use the term "electric cars" to refer to all personal light-duty vehicles that draw some or all of their energy from the electric grid, including plug-in hybrids as well as standard electric cars. The Department of Energy has included deployment of 500, 000 plug-in hybrid electric vehicles per year by 2015 in its seven "high priority performance goals.", OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, EXEC. hereinafter ANALYTICAL PERSPECTIVES, available at, click on "Performance & Management" hyperlink
    • See discussion infra Part III. A. We use the term "electric cars" to refer to all personal light-duty vehicles that draw some or all of their energy from the electric grid, including plug-in hybrids as well as standard electric cars. The Department of Energy has included deployment of 500, 000 plug-in hybrid electric vehicles per year by 2015 in its seven "high priority performance goals." OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, EXEC. OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT, ANALYTICAL PERSPECTIVES, BUDGET OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT, FISCAL YEAR 2011, at 79 (2010) [hereinafter ANALYTICAL PERSPECTIVES], available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Analytical-Perspectives (click on "Performance & Management" hyperlink).
    • (2010) Office of the President, Analytical Perspectives, Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year , pp. 79
  • 26
    • 77951255767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Getting the engineering right is not always enough: Researching the human dimensions of the new energy technologies
    • See discussion infra Part III. A; see also, &, 2691
    • See discussion infra Part III. A; see also Thomas Webler & Seth P. Tuler, Getting the Engineering Right Is Not Always Enough: Researching the Human Dimensions of the New Energy Technologies, 38 ENERGY POL'Y 2690, 2691 (2010).
    • (2010) Energy Pol'Y , vol.38 , pp. 2690
    • Webler, T.1    Tuler, S.P.2
  • 27
    • 67649577650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • available at, noting that the level of off-peak to on-peak price shift needed to induce a reduction in peak load demand is often higher than utilities are willing to implement due to the fear of negative customer response
    • AHMAD FARUQUI & LISA WOOD, QUANTIFYING THE BENEFITS OF DYNAMIC PRICING IN THE MASS MARKET 30 (2008), available at http://www.eei.org/ourissues/ electricitydistribution/Documents/quantifying-benefits-final.pdf (noting that the level of off-peak to on-peak price shift needed to induce a reduction in peak load demand is often higher than utilities are willing to implement due to the fear of negative customer response).
    • (2008) Quantifying the Benefits of Dynamic Pricing in the Mass Market , pp. 30
    • Faruqui, A.1    Wood, L.2
  • 28
    • 79955939167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With irish tax, plastic bags go the way of the snakes
    • Some evidence for this effect can be found in programs that have paired economic disincentives, such as taxes or fines, with public education campaigns that highlight the moral case for adoption of the target behavior. For example, a tax on plastic grocery bags in Ireland paired with an aggressive media campaign led to a ninety-four percent drop in the use of plastic bags, Feb. 2
    • Some evidence for this effect can be found in programs that have paired economic disincentives, such as taxes or fines, with public education campaigns that highlight the moral case for adoption of the target behavior. For example, a tax on plastic grocery bags in Ireland paired with an aggressive media campaign led to a ninety-four percent drop in the use of plastic bags. Elisabeth Rosenthal, With Irish Tax, Plastic Bags Go the Way of the Snakes, N. Y. TIMES, Feb. 2, 2008, at A3
    • (2008) N. Y. Times
    • Rosenthal, E.1
  • 29
    • 79955933703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • available at
    • available at 2008 WL 1990925.
    • (2008) WL , pp. 1990925
  • 30
    • 84866246440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Exec. Order No. 12, 866 §6 a C iii, requiring that agencies "assess both the costs and the benefits of the intended regulation"
    • See Exec. Order No. 12, 866 §6 (a) (C) (iii), 3 C. F. R. at 646 (requiring that agencies "assess both the costs and the benefits of the intended regulation").
    • C. F. R , vol.3 , pp. 646
  • 32
    • 79955939896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sunstein, supra note 7, at 1096
    • See Sunstein, supra note 7, at 1096.
  • 33
    • 79955935338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1077-88
    • See id. at 1077-88;
  • 34
    • 5244347898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, supra note 10, "By drawing attention to the consequences of proposed courses of action, benefit-cost analysis can help the public to evaluate regulatory initiatives."
    • see also ANALYTICAL PERSPECTIVES, supra note 10, at 98 ("By drawing attention to the consequences of proposed courses of action, benefit-cost analysis can help the public to evaluate regulatory initiatives.").
    • Analytical Perspectives , pp. 98
  • 35
    • 79955937512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., available at, recommending that OIRA "enhance the role of social and behavioral sciences, regarding how and why people as individuals or groups behave and decide in response to risks, opportunities, and uncertainty"
    • See, e.g., SOC'Y FOR RISK ANALYSIS, COMMITTEE OF PAST PRESIDENTS' RECOMMENDATIONS TO OMB ON REGULATORY REVIEW 5 (2009), available at http://reginfo.gov/public/jsp/EO/fedRegReview/OIRA-EO-12866-revision-SRA- comments.pdf (recommending that OIRA "[e]nhance the role of social and behavioral sciences, regarding how and why people (as individuals or groups) behave and decide in response to risks, opportunities, and uncertainty");
    • (2009) Soc'Y For Risk Analysis, Committee of Past Presidents' Recommendations to Omb on Regulatory Review , pp. 5
  • 36
    • 79955929846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 5, providing guidance to agencies on use of behavioral principles in the regulatory process
    • OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 3-12 (providing guidance to agencies on use of behavioral principles in the regulatory process).
    • (2010) Oira Disclosure Memo , pp. 3-12
  • 37
    • 2342475901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is an ongoing debate as to whether the empirical observations reviewed here represent actual departures from rationality or are simply the result of other factors that are consistent with a rational, utility-maximizing agent. See, &, eds.
    • There is an ongoing debate as to whether the empirical observations reviewed here represent actual departures from rationality or are simply the result of other factors that are consistent with a rational, utility-maximizing agent. See BOUNDED RATIONALITY 10 (Gerd Gigerenzer & Reinhard Selten eds., 2001);
    • (2001) Bounded Rationality , pp. 10
    • Gigerenzer, G.1    Selten, R.2
  • 38
    • 0347487318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law
    • Richard A. Posner, Rational Choice, Behavioral Economics, and the Law, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1551, 1552 (1998). In this Article, we contrast empirical findings from social and behavioral findings with the "thick" conceptions of rationality that have dominated, implicitly if not explicitly, much of the study of law and economics. (Pubitemid 128421724)
    • (1998) Stanford Law Review , vol.50 , Issue.5 , pp. 1551
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 39
    • 0042409519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and behavioral science: Removing the rationality assumption from law and economics
    • 1066, 1070-73, We do not intend to engage in the debate over the definition of rationality. Instead, we hope to offer a framework for incorporating a greater degree of behavioral realism regardless of how labeled into the process of regulatory development, review, and selection. For ease of discussion, we refer to this set of behavioral tendencies as "extra-rational behavior."
    • See Russell B. Korobkin & Thomas S. Ulen, Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics, 88 CALIF. L. REV. 1051, 1066, 1070-73 (2000). We do not intend to engage in the debate over the definition of rationality. Instead, we hope to offer a framework for incorporating a greater degree of behavioral realism (regardless of how labeled) into the process of regulatory development, review, and selection. For ease of discussion, we refer to this set of behavioral tendencies as "extra-rational behavior."
    • (2000) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 1051
    • Korobkin, R.B.1    Ulen, T.S.2
  • 40
    • 79955938022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded rationality and legal scholarship
    • See, e.g., in, 137, Mark D. White ed., identifying the need for legal scholars to account for bounded rationality in the development of legal prescriptions
    • See, e.g., Matthew D. Adler, Bounded Rationality and Legal Scholarship, in THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 137, 137 (Mark D. White ed., 2010) (identifying the need for legal scholars to account for bounded rationality in the development of legal prescriptions);
    • (2010) Theoretical Foundations of Law and Economics , pp. 137
    • Adler, M.D.1
  • 41
    • 55149106504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and economics after behavioral economics
    • 660-67, proposing a behavioral framework that emphasizes the context of human action as an independent factor in the regulatory process
    • Grant M. Hayden & Stephen E. Ellis, Law and Economics After Behavioral Economics, 55 U. KAN. L. REV. 629, 660-67 (2007) (proposing a behavioral framework that emphasizes the context of human action as an independent factor in the regulatory process);
    • (2007) U. Kan. L. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 629
    • Hayden, G.M.1    Ellis, S.E.2
  • 42
    • 79955929120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1476 providing a framework for the use of behavioral economics research in law
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1476 (providing a framework for the use of behavioral economics research in law).
  • 43
    • 0001609162 scopus 로고
    • Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: One view of the cathedral
    • For a more general framework, see Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1508-45. For the classic example of the development and application of a rigorous framework for legal analysis, see, &, 1090-111
    • For a more general framework, see Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1508-45. For the classic example of the development and application of a rigorous framework for legal analysis, see Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 HARV. L. REV. 1089, 1090-111 (1972).
    • (1972) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1089
    • Calabresi, G.1    Melamed, A.D.2
  • 44
    • 0021648107 scopus 로고
    • The lulling effect: The impact of child-resistant packaging on aspirin and analgesic ingestions
    • See, e.g., 326-27, documenting that the proportion of accidental aspirin ingestions from safety-capped bottles rose sharply after the introduction of childresistant bottle caps
    • See, e.g., W. Kip Viscusi, The Lulling Effect: The Impact of Child-Resistant Packaging on Aspirin and Analgesic Ingestions, 74 AM. ECON. REV. 324, 326-27 (1984) (documenting that the proportion of accidental aspirin ingestions from safety-capped bottles rose sharply after the introduction of childresistant bottle caps);
    • (1984) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 324
    • Viscusi, W.K.1
  • 45
    • 84968580386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Safety behavior and consumer responses to cigarette lighter safety mechanisms
    • 456, suggesting that regulators consider consumer responses to product safety improvements and consider pairing technological approaches with hazard warnings and consumer education
    • W. Kip Viscusi & Gerald Cavallo, Safety Behavior and Consumer Responses to Cigarette Lighter Safety Mechanisms, 17 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 441, 456 (1996) (suggesting that regulators consider consumer responses to product safety improvements and consider pairing technological approaches with hazard warnings and consumer education).
    • (1996) Managerial & Decision Econ , vol.17 , pp. 441
    • Kip Viscusi, W.1    Cavallo, G.2
  • 46
    • 33750070312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inside the administrative state: A critical look at the practice of presidential control
    • 94-95, noting that the selective presidential control of agency regulation, as exercised in part through OIRA, can undermine the legitimacy of such regulation. A related danger is that ad hoc review will enable agencies to overvalue one consideration at the expense of others. Many have argued that OIRA overemphasizes consideration of costs at the expense of benefits, which can tilt regulation in an antiregulatory direction
    • See Lisa Schultz Bressman & Michael P. Vandenbergh, Inside the Administrative State: A Critical Look at the Practice of Presidential Control, 105 MICH. L. REV. 47, 94-95 (2006) (noting that the selective presidential control of agency regulation, as exercised in part through OIRA, can undermine the legitimacy of such regulation). A related danger is that ad hoc review will enable agencies to overvalue one consideration at the expense of others. Many have argued that OIRA overemphasizes consideration of costs at the expense of benefits, which can tilt regulation in an antiregulatory direction.
    • (2006) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.105 , pp. 47
    • Bressman, L.S.1    Vandenbergh, M.P.2
  • 47
    • 33751251369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centralized oversight of the regulatory state
    • See, e.g., &, 1262-63, arguing that uneven application of cost-benefit analysis by OIRA can lead to a deregulatory bias
    • See, e.g., Nicholas Bagley & Richard L. Revesz, Centralized Oversight of the Regulatory State, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1260, 1262-63 (2006) (arguing that uneven application of cost-benefit analysis by OIRA can lead to a deregulatory bias).
    • (2006) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.106 , pp. 1260
    • Bagley, N.1    Revesz, R.L.2
  • 48
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential administration
    • See, 2331-39, noting the importance of transparency in the OMB and of greater White House control of agency regulation
    • See Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 HARV. L. REV. 2245, 2331-39 (2001) (noting the importance of transparency in the OMB and of greater White House control of agency regulation).
    • (2001) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.114 , pp. 2245
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 49
    • 77958396817 scopus 로고
    • Administrative procedures as instruments of political control
    • See, 254-58, arguing that congressional monitoring of agency regulation depends in part on constituent access to information about such regulation
    • See Mathew D. McCubbins et al., Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control, 3 J. L. ECON. & ORG. 243, 254-58 (1987) (arguing that congressional monitoring of agency regulation depends in part on constituent access to information about such regulation).
    • (1987) J. L. Econ. & Org. , vol.3 , pp. 243
    • McCubbins, M.D.1
  • 50
    • 38049169581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Procedures as politics in administrative law
    • See, 1805-07, arguing that congressional oversight, particularly when coupled with White House regulatory review, can improve the accountability of agency regulation
    • See Lisa Schultz Bressman, Procedures as Politics in Administrative Law, 107 COLUM. L. REV. 1749, 1805-07 (2007) (arguing that congressional oversight, particularly when coupled with White House regulatory review, can improve the accountability of agency regulation).
    • (2007) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.107 , pp. 1749
    • Bressman, L.S.1
  • 51
    • 79955930489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In developing our framework, we build on earlier work that examined the implications of behavioral economics for cost-benefit analysis. See Adler, supra note 20, at 155-62
    • In developing our framework, we build on earlier work that examined the implications of behavioral economics for cost-benefit analysis. See Adler, supra note 20, at 155-62;
  • 52
    • 79955941584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1481-85
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1481-85;
  • 53
    • 79955932247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sunstein, supra note 7, at 1060-61
    • Sunstein, supra note 7, at 1060-61;
  • 54
    • 44849130548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Willingness to pay vs. welfare
    • 315-16
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Willingness to Pay vs. Welfare, 1 HARV. L. & POL'Y REV. 303, 315-16 (2007).
    • (2007) Harv. L. & Pol'Y Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 303
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 55
    • 0141761212 scopus 로고
    • An economic model of moral motivation
    • For instance, the desires for fairness, altruistic tendencies, and morality have been extensively researched within economics. See, e.g., examining the role of moral self-image in influencing prosocial behavior
    • For instance, the desires for fairness, altruistic tendencies, and morality have been extensively researched within economics. See, e.g., Kjell Arne Brekke et al., An Economic Model of Moral Motivation, 87 J. PUB. ECON. 1967, 1968 (2003) (examining the role of moral self-image in influencing prosocial behavior);
    • (1968) J. Pub. Econ , vol.87 , pp. 1967
    • Brekke, K.A.1
  • 56
    • 0030268941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Altruism in anonymous dictator games
    • 188, examining altruism as a motivating factor in behavior
    • Catherine C. Eckel & Philip J. Grossman, Altruism in Anonymous Dictator Games, 16 GAMES & ECON. BEHAV. 181, 188 (1996) (examining altruism as a motivating factor in behavior);
    • (1996) Games & Econ. Behav. , vol.16 , pp. 181
    • Eckel, C.C.1    Grossman, P.J.2
  • 57
    • 0000832255 scopus 로고
    • Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics
    • 1282, presenting a framework to study implications of fairness in economic situations
    • Matthew Rabin, Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 1281, 1282 (1993) (presenting a framework to study implications of fairness in economic situations).
    • (1993) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 1281
    • Rabin, M.1
  • 58
    • 0242267471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A perspective on judgment and choice: Mapping bounded rationality
    • See, e.g., 697-720 using the term "bounded rationality" as the notion that human decisionmaking is bounded by cognitive and informational constraints
    • See, e.g., Daniel Kahneman, A Perspective on Judgment and Choice: Mapping Bounded Rationality, 58 AM. PSYCHOLOGIST 697, 697-720 (using the term "bounded rationality" as the notion that human decisionmaking is bounded by cognitive and informational constraints).
    • Am. Psychologist , vol.58 , pp. 697
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 60
    • 79955942047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adler, supra note 20, at 160 noting that cost-benefit analysis is "the traditional technique for implementing wealth-maximization and Kaldor-Hicks efficiency"
    • Adler, supra note 20, at 160 (noting that cost-benefit analysis is "the traditional technique for implementing wealth-maximization and Kaldor-Hicks efficiency").
  • 61
    • 79955934114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1119-20 identifying a matrix including property rules and liability rules with entitlements assigned to polluters or victims, and noting that the framework leads to the insight that a liability-rule-protected entitlement might be assigned to a polluter as well as a victim. The importance of analyzing non-rational responses to social outcome maximization emerges from our framework in a similar way. See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b
    • Cf. Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1119-20 (identifying a matrix including property rules and liability rules with entitlements assigned to polluters or victims, and noting that the framework leads to the insight that a liability-rule-protected entitlement might be assigned to a polluter as well as a victim). The importance of analyzing non-rational responses to social outcome maximization emerges from our framework in a similar way. See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.
  • 62
    • 79955942544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 1, at 68-69
    • See THALER & SUNSTEIN, supra note 1, at 68-69.
  • 63
    • 73249134816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Household actions can provide a behavioral wedge to rapidly reduce U. S. carbon emissions
    • Individual and household behavioral changes could reduce U. S. carbon emissions by seven percent in ten years. See, &, 452, at 18, 452
    • Individual and household behavioral changes could reduce U. S. carbon emissions by seven percent in ten years. See Thomas Dietz, Gerald T. Gardner, Jonathan Gilligan, Paul C. Stern & Michael P. Vandenbergh, Household Actions Can Provide a Behavioral Wedge to Rapidly Reduce U. S. Carbon Emissions, 106 PROC. NAT'L ACAD. SCI. 18, 452, at 18, 452 (2009).
    • (2009) Proc. Nat'L Acad. Sci. , vol.106 , pp. 18
    • Dietz, T.1    Gardner, G.T.2    Gilligan, J.3    Stern, P.C.4    Vandenbergh, M.P.5
  • 64
    • 0035998097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A new executive order for improving federal regulation? Deeper and wider cost-benefit analysis
    • In the Carter Administration, economic analysis of regulations was conducted to determine only the cost effectiveness of regulatory actions. See, &, 1505-06, Benefits analysis was added in the Reagan Administration. Id.
    • In the Carter Administration, economic analysis of regulations was conducted to determine only the cost effectiveness of regulatory actions. See Robert W. Hahn & Cass R. Sunstein, A New Executive Order for Improving Federal Regulation? Deeper and Wider Cost-Benefit Analysis, 150 U. PA. L. REV. 1489, 1505-06 (2002). Benefits analysis was added in the Reagan Administration. Id.
    • (2002) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.150 , pp. 1489
    • Hahn, R.W.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 65
    • 0347507137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Risk equity
    • see also, 854
    • see also W. Kip Viscusi, Risk Equity, 29 J. LEGAL STUD. 843, 854 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Legal Stud. , vol.29 , pp. 843
    • Viscusi, W.K.1
  • 66
    • 0042715443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global environmental regulation: Instrument choice in legal context
    • For a discussion of regulatory instrument choice, see, 679-80, 704-35
    • For a discussion of regulatory instrument choice, see Jonathan Baert Wiener, Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context, 108 YALE L. J. 677, 679-80, 704-35 (1999).
    • (1999) Yale L. J , vol.108 , pp. 677
    • Wiener, J.B.1
  • 67
    • 79955936765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The recent OIRA memorandum on the use of behavioral approaches notes the importance of consulting with behavioral scientists and of conducting rigorous empirical studies. See 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 5
    • The recent OIRA memorandum on the use of behavioral approaches notes the importance of consulting with behavioral scientists and of conducting rigorous empirical studies. See 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 5.
  • 68
    • 79955928866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 69
    • 79957505041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, §
    • See 5 U. S. C. § 706 (2) (2007);
    • (2007) U. S. C , vol.5 , Issue.2 , pp. 706
  • 70
    • 29844454098 scopus 로고
    • Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 42-43, interpreting the "arbitrary and capricious standard" of the Administrative Procedure Act to require that agencies demonstrate that they have considered all relevant factors and all important aspects of a problem
    • Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U. S. 29, 42-43 (1983) (interpreting the "arbitrary and capricious standard" of the Administrative Procedure Act to require that agencies demonstrate that they have considered all relevant factors and all important aspects of a problem).
    • (1983) U. S , vol.463 , pp. 29
  • 71
    • 72549115067 scopus 로고
    • See SEC v. Chenery Corp., 95, requiring the Agency to reveal the actual basis on which it relied and declining to uphold the agency's decision on any other basis
    • See SEC v. Chenery Corp., 318 U. S. 80, 95 (1943) (requiring the Agency to reveal the actual basis on which it relied and declining to uphold the agency's decision on any other basis).
    • (1943) U. S , vol.318 , pp. 80
  • 72
    • 47049115280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From politics to expertise
    • Likewise, we do not and cannot address whether behavioral or traditional economic analysis should prevail in cases of conflict. Our framework does not purport to provide a fully integrated model; indeed, pursuit of such a model is akin to pursuit of the Holy Grail. These sorts of issues are not exclusive to behavioral analysis. In some sense, they are present in the classic conflict between agency expertise and political accountability in administrative law. See, &, Massachusetts v. EPA
    • Likewise, we do not and cannot address whether behavioral or traditional economic analysis should prevail in cases of conflict. Our framework does not purport to provide a fully integrated model; indeed, pursuit of such a model is akin to pursuit of the Holy Grail. These sorts of issues are not exclusive to behavioral analysis. In some sense, they are present in the classic conflict between agency expertise and political accountability in administrative law. See Jody Freeman & Adrian Vermeule, Massachusetts v. EPA: From Politics to Expertise, 2007 SUP. CT. REV. 51 (2008)
    • (2007) Sup. Ct. Rev. , pp. 51
    • Freeman, J.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 73
    • 70749157283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • using the Supreme Court's decision in Massachusetts v. EPA, to discuss the tension between administrative expertise and political accountability. When technocratic judgment and political responsiveness point in different directions, agencies are forced to make a choice and sometimes courts may have a say as well
    • (using the Supreme Court's decision in Massachusetts v. EPA, 549 U. S. 497 (2007), to discuss the tension between administrative expertise and political accountability). When technocratic judgment and political responsiveness point in different directions, agencies are forced to make a choice (and sometimes courts may have a say as well).
    • (2007) U. S , vol.549 , pp. 497
  • 74
    • 79955937179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ADLER & POSNER, supra note 30, at 68-100
    • See, e.g., ADLER & POSNER, supra note 30, at 68-100.
  • 75
    • 77952107125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking the role of cost-benefit analysis
    • See, e.g., 1379-96, arguing that the European regulatory model is a superior alternative to cost-benefit analysis for regulating toxic chemicals
    • See, e.g., Daniel A. Farber, Rethinking the Role of Cost-Benefit Analysis, 76 U. CHI. L. REV. 1355, 1379-96 (2009) (arguing that the European regulatory model is a superior alternative to cost-benefit analysis for regulating toxic chemicals).
    • (2009) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 1355
    • Farber, D.A.1
  • 76
    • 79955929845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Kahneman, supra note 29, at 705-06 discussing how assumptions about and models of human behavior frame decisions that aim to maximize utility
    • Cf. Kahneman, supra note 29, at 705-06 (discussing how assumptions about and models of human behavior frame decisions that aim to maximize utility).
  • 77
    • 79955941502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fatal flaw of cost-benefit analysis: The problem of person-altering consequences
    • Cf, 703, at 10, 703, "Prospective cost-benefit analyses of rulemaking initiatives and subsequent OIRA review and, upon occasion, also judicial review now appear to be entrenched as a significant feature of the federal regulatory process." citation omitted
    • Cf. Gregory Scott Crespi, The Fatal Flaw of Cost-Benefit Analysis: The Problem of Person-Altering Consequences, 38 ENVTL. L. REP. 10, 703, at 10, 703 n. 1 (2008) ("Prospective cost-benefit analyses of rulemaking initiatives and subsequent OIRA review (and, upon occasion, also judicial review) now appear to be entrenched as a significant feature of the federal regulatory process." (citation omitted)).
    • (2008) Envtl. L. Rep. , vol.38 , Issue.1 , pp. 10
    • Crespi, G.S.1
  • 78
    • 0034473324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a coherent theory of environmentally significant behavior
    • See, 419-20
    • See Paul C. Stern, Toward a Coherent Theory of Environmentally Significant Behavior, 56 J. SOC. ISSUES 407, 419-20 (2000);
    • (2000) J. Soc. Issues , vol.56 , pp. 407
    • Stern, P.C.1
  • 79
    • 23844550364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Order without social norms: How personal norms can protect the environment
    • 1103-06
    • Michael P. Vandenbergh, Order Without Social Norms: How Personal Norms Can Protect the Environment, 99 NW. U. L. REV. 1101, 1103-06 (2005);
    • (2005) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 1101
    • Vandenbergh, M.P.1
  • 80
    • 37049012645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Models of decision making and residential energy use
    • 189
    • Charlie Wilson & Hadi Dowlatabadi, Models of Decision Making and Residential Energy Use, 32 ANN. REV. ENV'T & RESOURCES 169, 189 (2007).
    • (2007) Ann. Rev. Env'T & Resources , vol.32 , pp. 169
    • Wilson, C.1    Dowlatabadi, H.2
  • 81
    • 79952845605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics behaving badly
    • Our focus here is on individuals and households, although many of the behavioral insights are relevant to the behavior of small businesses, large corporations, and nonprofit organizations as well. Of course, behavioral analysis could just provide policymakers with a means to "avoid painful but more effective solutions rooted in traditional economics, " such as removing subsidies or introducing taxes, &, July 15, available at 2010 WLNR 14148206
    • Our focus here is on individuals and households, although many of the behavioral insights are relevant to the behavior of small businesses, large corporations, and nonprofit organizations as well. Of course, behavioral analysis could just provide policymakers with a means to "avoid painful but more effective solutions rooted in traditional economics, " such as removing subsidies or introducing taxes. George Loewenstein & Peter Ubel, Economics Behaving Badly, N. Y. TIMES, July 15, 2010, at A31, available at 2010 WLNR 14148206;
    • (2010) N. Y. Times
    • Loewenstein, G.1    Ubel, P.2
  • 82
    • 0036874075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why law and economics' perfect rationality should not be traded for behavioral law and economics' equal incompetence
    • see also, 72, positing that a middle ground between perfect rationality and equal incompetence illuminates ways the legal system may foster rational or counter-irrational behavior. We note that behavioral measures need not displace traditional regulatory measures, however. In many cases, behavioral measures may supplement traditional measures or may fill gaps when public support is lacking for such measures
    • see also Gregory Mitchell, Why Law and Economics' Perfect Rationality Should Not Be Traded for Behavioral Law and Economics' Equal Incompetence, 91 GEO. L. J. 67, 72 (2002) (positing that a middle ground between perfect rationality and equal incompetence illuminates ways the legal system may foster rational or counter-irrational behavior). We note that behavioral measures need not displace traditional regulatory measures, however. In many cases, behavioral measures may supplement traditional measures or may fill gaps when public support is lacking for such measures.
    • (2002) Geo. L. J , vol.91 , pp. 67
    • Mitchell, G.1
  • 83
    • 84977315121 scopus 로고
    • Blind spots in policy analysis: What economics doesn't say about energy use
    • See, e.g., 210-11, noting that when the monetary value of price incentives for energy efficiency investments are held constant, participation rates can vary by a factor of ten due to non-price-related factors
    • See, e.g., Paul C. Stern, Blind Spots in Policy Analysis: What Economics Doesn't Say About Energy Use, 5 J. POL'Y ANALYSIS & MGMT. 200, 210-11 (1986) (noting that when the monetary value of price incentives for energy efficiency investments are held constant, participation rates can vary by a factor of ten due to non-price-related factors).
    • (1986) J. Pol'Y Analysis & MGMT , vol.5 , pp. 200
    • Stern, P.C.1
  • 84
    • 75449117340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Analysis of policies to reduce oil consumption and greenhouse-gas emissions from the U. S. transportation sector
    • See, e.g., 1317-18, concluding that a price of gasoline between $5.00 and $7.00 per gallon would be necessary to achieve a fourteen percent U. S. reduction in greenhouse gas emissions below 2005 levels by 2025
    • See, e.g., W. Ross Morrow et al., Analysis of Policies to Reduce Oil Consumption and Greenhouse-Gas Emissions from the U. S. Transportation Sector, 38 ENERGY POL'Y 1305, 1317-18 (2010) (concluding that a price of gasoline between $5.00 and $7.00 per gallon would be necessary to achieve a fourteen percent U. S. reduction in greenhouse gas emissions below 2005 levels by 2025).
    • (2010) Energy Pol'Y , vol.38 , pp. 1305
    • Morrow, W.R.1
  • 85
    • 0041917494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crafting normative messages to protect the environment
    • See, e.g., 108-09, noting that public education campaigns that communicate that an undesirable behavior is "regrettably frequent" can lead to an increase in the undesirable behavior by sending the descriptively normative message that the behavior is common and therefore acceptable
    • See, e.g., Robert B. Cialdini, Crafting Normative Messages to Protect the Environment, 12 CURRENT DIRECTIONS PSYCHOL. SCI. 105, 108-09 (2003) (noting that public education campaigns that communicate that an undesirable behavior is "regrettably frequent" can lead to an increase in the undesirable behavior by sending the descriptively normative message that the behavior is common and therefore acceptable);
    • (2003) Current Directions Psychol. Sci. , vol.12 , pp. 105
    • Cialdini, R.B.1
  • 86
    • 10044229707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond elegance: A testable typology of social norms in corporate environmental compliance
    • 104-05, 115, discussing studies on the unintended effects of regulatory interventions on tax compliance; Viscusi, supra note 22, at 326-27 discussing unintended consequences of childresistant bottle caps
    • Michael P. Vandenbergh, Beyond Elegance: A Testable Typology of Social Norms in Corporate Environmental Compliance, 22 STAN. ENVTL. L. J. 55, 104-05, 115 (2003) (discussing studies on the unintended effects of regulatory interventions on tax compliance); Viscusi, supra note 22, at 326-27 (discussing unintended consequences of childresistant bottle caps).
    • (2003) Stan. Envtl. L. J , vol.22 , pp. 55
    • Vandenbergh, M.P.1
  • 87
    • 79955935729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the interpretations of the rational-actor model, see Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1070-74
    • For a discussion of the interpretations of the rational-actor model, see Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1070-74.
  • 88
    • 0242467980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cooperation, psychological game theory, and limitations of rationality in social interaction
    • For a discussion of the assumptions and variations of rational choice theory, see, 139-43
    • For a discussion of the assumptions and variations of rational choice theory, see Andrew M. Colman, Cooperation, Psychological Game Theory, and Limitations of Rationality in Social Interaction, 26 BEHAV. & BRAIN SCI. 139, 139-43 (2003)
    • (2003) Behav. & Brain Sci. , vol.26 , pp. 139
    • Colman, A.M.1
  • 89
    • 79955940205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1060-66
    • and Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1060-66.
  • 90
    • 0003587441 scopus 로고
    • For a more detailed discussion of rational choice theory, see
    • For a more detailed discussion of rational choice theory, see GARY S. BECKER, THE ECONOMIC APPROACH TO HUMAN BEHAVIOR 3-14 (1976);
    • (1976) The Economic Approach to Human Behavior , pp. 3-14
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 91
    • 79955941950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Colman, supra note 50, at 139-43
    • Colman, supra note 50, at 139-43;
  • 92
    • 79955930937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1060-66
    • and Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1060-66.
  • 93
    • 79955934413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Adler, supra note 20, at 158-59
    • See Adler, supra note 20, at 158-59;
  • 94
    • 79955942760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1064-65
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1064-65;
  • 95
    • 0346403980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recycling norms
    • see also, 1237-38, &, noting that measuring utility entirely based on monetary incentives is often described as a "thick" approach to utility
    • see also Ann E. Carlson, Recycling Norms, 89 CALIF. L. REV. 1231, 1237-38 & n. 12 (2001) (noting that measuring utility entirely based on monetary incentives is often described as a "thick" approach to utility).
    • (2001) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.89 , Issue.12 , pp. 1231
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 96
    • 79955930247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1065
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1065.
  • 97
    • 79955935267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Loewenstein et al., supra note 8, at 661 noting that the position that individuals act only according to pure self-interest is a minority position within economics
    • See, e.g., Loewenstein et al., supra note 8, at 661 (noting that the position that individuals act only according to pure self-interest is a minority position within economics);
  • 98
    • 79955943033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 19, at 1551-52 explaining his broadly defined interpretation of rational action as well as the point that the economic analysis of law has "long ago abandoned the model of hyper rational, emotionless, unsocial, supremely egoistic, nonstrategic man or woman "
    • Posner, supra note 19, at 1551-52 (explaining his broadly defined interpretation of rational action as well as the point that the economic analysis of law has "long ago abandoned the model of hyper rational, emotionless, unsocial, supremely egoistic, nonstrategic man (or woman) ").
  • 99
    • 0346479805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The limits of behavioral theories of law and social norms
    • See, 1622
    • See Robert E. Scott, The Limits of Behavioral Theories of Law and Social Norms, 86 VA. L. REV. 1603, 1622 n. 39 (2000);
    • (2000) Va. L. Rev. , vol.86 , Issue.39 , pp. 1603
    • Scott, R.E.1
  • 100
    • 79955941737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Loewenstein & Ubel, supra note 45, at A31
    • see also Loewenstein & Ubel, supra note 45, at A31.
  • 101
    • 79955938244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1057 n. 18 positing that aggregate behavior follows predictions of rational choice theory even where individuals deviate from that behavior, so long as those deviations are symmetrically distributed
    • See Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1057 n. 18 (positing that aggregate behavior follows predictions of rational choice theory even where individuals deviate from that behavior, so long as those deviations are symmetrically distributed).
  • 102
    • 79955929119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carlson, supra note 52, at 1237-38 noting that this is often described as a "thin" approach to utility. For a discussion of thin conceptions of utility
    • See Carlson, supra note 52, at 1237-38 (noting that this is often described as a "thin" approach to utility). For a discussion of thin conceptions of utility
  • 103
    • 79955928644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1479 discussing "bounded selfinterest"
    • see Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1479 (discussing "bounded selfinterest")
  • 104
    • 79955929453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1061-62
    • and Korobkin & Ulen, supra note 19, at 1061-62.
  • 105
    • 0012483307 scopus 로고
    • Social dilemmas
    • See, 175-78, discussing an expanded definition of utility that includes nonmonetary outcomes
    • See Robyn M. Dawes, Social Dilemmas, 31 ANN. REV. PSYCHOL. 169, 175-78 (1980) (discussing an expanded definition of utility that includes nonmonetary outcomes);
    • (1980) Ann. Rev. Psychol. , vol.31 , pp. 169
    • Dawes, R.M.1
  • 106
    • 79955937007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 19, at 1551-52
    • Posner, supra note 19, at 1551-52.
  • 107
  • 108
    • 84961577887 scopus 로고
    • Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: A meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992
    • In a meta-analysis of over one hundred social dilemma experiments, David Sally found an average cooperation rate of forty-seven percent within one-shot Prisoner's Dilemma games, although cooperation varied widely depending on the situational variables manipulated in the studies, 60-62, In their review of this literature, Robyn Dawes and Richard Thaler state that cooperation rates in one-shot social dilemmas typically range between forty and sixty percent, even though rational choice theory where utility is measured by monetary self-interest would predict a zero percent cooperation rate
    • In a meta-analysis of over one hundred social dilemma experiments, David Sally found an average cooperation rate of forty-seven percent within one-shot Prisoner's Dilemma games, although cooperation varied widely depending on the situational variables manipulated in the studies. David Sally, Conversation and Cooperation in Social Dilemmas: A Meta-Analysis of Experiments From 1958 to 1992, 7 RATIONALITY & SOC'Y 58, 60-62 (1995). In their review of this literature, Robyn Dawes and Richard Thaler state that cooperation rates in one-shot social dilemmas typically range between forty and sixty percent, even though rational choice theory (where utility is measured by monetary self-interest) would predict a zero percent cooperation rate.
    • (1995) Rationality & Soc'Y , vol.7 , pp. 58
    • Sally, D.1
  • 109
    • 0001164303 scopus 로고
    • Anomalies: Cooperation
    • 188-89
    • Robyn M. Dawes & Richard H. Thaler, Anomalies: Cooperation, 2 J. ECON. PERSP. 187, 188-89 (1988).
    • (1988) J. Econ. Persp , vol.2 , pp. 187
    • Dawes, R.M.1    Thaler, R.H.2
  • 110
    • 0034348648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social dilemmas
    • 114, noting that social identification with others involved in social dilemmas leads to greater levels of cooperation
    • See Robyn M. Dawes & David M. Messick, Social Dilemmas, 35 INT'L J. PSYCHOL. 111, 114 (2000) (noting that social identification with others involved in social dilemmas leads to greater levels of cooperation);
    • (2000) Int'L J. Psychol. , vol.35 , pp. 111
    • Dawes, R.M.1    Messick, D.M.2
  • 111
    • 1542710569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social dilemmas: The anatomy of cooperation
    • 195-97, reviewing literature on the influence of reciprocity norms on decisionmaking in social dilemmas
    • Peter Kollock, Social Dilemmas: The Anatomy of Cooperation, 24 ANN. REV. SOC. 183, 195-97 (1998) (reviewing literature on the influence of reciprocity norms on decisionmaking in social dilemmas).
    • (1998) Ann. Rev. Soc , vol.24 , pp. 183
    • Kollock, P.1
  • 112
    • 0002276495 scopus 로고
    • Effects of group pressure upon the modification and distortion of judgments
    • For example, Solomon Asch demonstrated that roughly one-third of individuals will give an obviously incorrect answer to a simple line judgment task when that answer is given by the others in the room, in, 177-81, 186 Howard Guetzkow ed.
    • For example, Solomon Asch demonstrated that roughly one-third of individuals will give an obviously incorrect answer to a simple line judgment task when that answer is given by the others in the room. Solomon E. Asch, Effects of Group Pressure Upon the Modification and Distortion of Judgments, in GROUPS, LEADERSHIP AND MEN 177, 177-81, 186 (Howard Guetzkow ed., 1951).
    • (1951) Groups, Leadership and Men , pp. 177
    • Asch, S.E.1
  • 113
    • 0242676963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Party over policy: The dominating impact of group influence on political beliefs
    • Geoffrey Cohen has found that support of a welfare policy among liberals and conservatives depends more on whether the policy is endorsed by a Republican or Democrat than on the actual content of the policy, 819
    • Geoffrey Cohen has found that support of a welfare policy among liberals and conservatives depends more on whether the policy is endorsed by a Republican or Democrat than on the actual content of the policy. Geoffrey L. Cohen, Party Over Policy: The Dominating Impact of Group Influence on Political Beliefs, 85 J. PERS. & SOC. PSYCHOL. 808, 819 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Pers. & Soc. Psychol. , vol.85 , pp. 808
    • Cohen, G.L.1
  • 114
    • 0000352263 scopus 로고
    • Time-inconsistent preferences and consumer self-control
    • 497, discussing the impact of temporal proximity on consumer preferences
    • See Stephen J. Hoch & George F. Loewenstein, Time-Inconsistent Preferences and Consumer Self-Control, 17 J. CONSUMER RES. 492, 497 (1991) (discussing the impact of temporal proximity on consumer preferences);
    • (1991) J. Consumer Res , vol.17 , pp. 492
    • Hoch, S.J.1    Loewenstein, G.F.2
  • 115
    • 79955939393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2, at 143-44 discussing how the framing of possible outcomes may change individual preferences
    • Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2, at 143-44 (discussing how the framing of possible outcomes may change individual preferences);
  • 116
    • 0019392722 scopus 로고
    • The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice
    • 453-58, discussing how the framing of prospects, contingencies, and outcomes can lead to preference reversals
    • Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice, 211 SCIENCE 453, 453-58 (1985) (discussing how the framing of prospects, contingencies, and outcomes can lead to preference reversals).
    • (1985) Science , vol.211 , pp. 453
    • Tversky, A.1    Kahneman, D.2
  • 117
    • 0002177405 scopus 로고
    • Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases
    • See, e.g., &, in, 3-20 Daniel Kahneman et al. eds., reviewing several judgmental heuristics and the cognitive biases they tend to produce. For a review of cognitive heuristics in decisionmaking
    • See, e.g., Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, in JUDGMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY: HEURISTICS AND BIASES 3, 3-20 (Daniel Kahneman et al. eds., 1982) (reviewing several judgmental heuristics and the cognitive biases they tend to produce). For a review of cognitive heuristics in decisionmaking
    • (1982) Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases , pp. 3
    • Tversky, A.1    Kahneman, D.2
  • 118
    • 2942700268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics
    • see
    • see Daniel Kahneman, Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics, 93 AM. ECON. REV. 1449 (2003).
    • (2003) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 1449
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 119
    • 44849118549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Normative social influence is underdetected
    • Jessica Nolan and her coauthors found that while individuals believed that the behavior of their neighbors had little impact on their own energy-use behaviors, the data showed that descriptive norms were the strongest predictor of actual behavior, 920-21
    • Jessica Nolan and her coauthors found that while individuals believed that the behavior of their neighbors had little impact on their own energy-use behaviors, the data showed that descriptive norms were the strongest predictor of actual behavior. Jessica M. Nolan et al., Normative Social Influence Is Underdetected, 34 PERSONALITY SOC. PSYCHOL. BULL. 913, 920-21 (2008).
    • (2008) Personality Soc. Psychol. Bull , vol.34 , pp. 913
    • Nolan, J.M.1
  • 120
    • 79955930074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 45, at 172 analyzing rational choice as a building block of economic theory
    • See Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 45, at 172 (analyzing rational choice as a building block of economic theory).
  • 121
    • 79955937180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Rabin, supra note 2, at 12 listing multiple theories of economically relevant psychology that he does not apply to his analysis
    • See, e.g., Rabin, supra note 2, at 12 (listing multiple theories of economically relevant psychology that he does not apply to his analysis).
  • 122
    • 84933496216 scopus 로고
    • Beyond rational choice: The social dynamics of how people seek help
    • See, 1102, describing how certain actions or choices are targeted for testing, while others are ignored
    • See Bernice A. Pescosolido, Beyond Rational Choice: The Social Dynamics of How People Seek Help, 97 AM. J. SOC. 1096, 1102 (1992) (describing how certain actions or choices are targeted for testing, while others are ignored).
    • (1992) Am. J. Soc , vol.97 , pp. 1096
    • Pescosolido, B.A.1
  • 123
    • 0345848930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and social norms: The case of tax compliance
    • See, e.g., 1788-89, concluding that the effects of personal norms are not valuable for explaining tax behavior
    • See, e.g., Eric A. Posner, Law and Social Norms: The Case of Tax Compliance, 86 VA. L. REV. 1781, 1788-89 (2000) (concluding that the effects of personal norms are not valuable for explaining tax behavior);
    • (2000) Va. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 1781
    • Posner, E.A.1
  • 124
    • 79955940951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott, supra note 55, at 1622 n. 39 explaining that personal norms are not consistent with environmental behavior
    • Scott, supra note 55, at 1622 n. 39 (explaining that personal norms are not consistent with environmental behavior).
  • 125
    • 79955933704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 45, at 172 describing rational choice theory as background to economics and policy decisions
    • See, e.g., Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 45, at 172 (describing rational choice theory as background to economics and policy decisions).
  • 126
    • 79955937181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Rabin, supra note 2, at 12 listing a multitude of psychology theories that researchers use to explain behavior
    • See, e.g., Rabin, supra note 2, at 12 (listing a multitude of psychology theories that researchers use to explain behavior).
  • 127
    • 0005312217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Three tasks for personality psychology
    • This problem has been noted by multiple researchers within psychology and is sometimes referred to as the "jangle fallacy." See, e.g., in, 156-57 Lars R. Bergman et al. eds.
    • This problem has been noted by multiple researchers within psychology and is sometimes referred to as the "jangle fallacy." See, e.g., Jack Block, Three Tasks for Personality Psychology, in DEVELOPMENTAL SCIENCE AND THE HOLISTIC APPROACH 155, 156-57 (Lars R. Bergman et al. eds., 2000);
    • (2000) Developmental Science and the Holistic Approach , pp. 155
    • Block, J.1
  • 128
    • 85047673371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The rhetoric of psychological research and the problem of unification in psychology
    • see also, 264-69
    • see also Michael W. Katzko, The Rhetoric of Psychological Research and the Problem of Unification in Psychology, 57 AM. PSYCHOL. 262, 264-69 (2002).
    • (2002) Am. Psychol. , vol.57 , pp. 262
    • Katzko, M.W.1
  • 129
    • 79955931021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stern, supra note 46, at 200-01 explaining how policy analysts use the simplified rational-actor theory
    • See Stern, supra note 46, at 200-01 (explaining how policy analysts use the simplified rational-actor theory).
  • 130
    • 79955932495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Morrow et al., supra note 47, at 1307-08 examining several federal programs using financial incentives to influence individual behavior
    • See, e.g., Morrow et al., supra note 47, at 1307-08 (examining several federal programs using financial incentives to influence individual behavior).
  • 133
    • 79955939024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wiener, supra note 35, at 704-35 discussing economic theory and other instruments of regulation
    • Wiener, supra note 35, at 704-35 (discussing economic theory and other instruments of regulation).
  • 134
    • 79955929368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5See Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 45, at 172
    • 5See Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 45, at 172.
  • 135
    • 79955928785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 136
    • 0035501353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market failures and barriers as a basis for clean energy policies
    • See, 1198-99
    • See Marilyn A. Brown, Market Failures and Barriers as a Basis for Clean Energy Policies, 29 ENERGY POL'Y 1197, 1198-99 (2001);
    • (2001) Energy Pol'Y , vol.29 , pp. 1197
    • Brown, M.A.1
  • 137
    • 79955931179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles, supra note 3, at 810-11
    • Charles, supra note 3, at 810-11.
  • 138
    • 0009059125 scopus 로고
    • The influence of price and attitude on shifting residential electricity consumption from on-to off-peak periods
    • 125
    • See Thomas A. Heberlein & G. Keith Warriner, The Influence of Price and Attitude on Shifting Residential Electricity Consumption From On-to Off-Peak Periods, 4 J. ECON. PSYCHOL. 107, 125 (1983);
    • (1983) J. Econ. Psychol. , vol.4 , pp. 107
    • Heberlein, T.A.1    Warriner, G.K.2
  • 139
    • 79955938093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nolan et al., supra note 65, at 921
    • Nolan et al., supra note 65, at 921.
  • 140
    • 79955929284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rosenthal, supra note 13, at A3
    • See Rosenthal, supra note 13, at A3.
  • 141
    • 79955937651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stern, supra note 45, at 210-11
    • See Stern, supra note 45, at 210-11.
  • 142
    • 79955938693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 143
    • 79955936764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 46, at 174 explaining how individual preferences are not fixed
    • See Wilson & Dowlatabadi, supra note 46, at 174 (explaining how individual preferences are not fixed).
  • 144
    • 79955931771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 174-75 discussing the importance of framing the decisions available to consumers in intervention programs
    • Id. at 174-75 (discussing the importance of framing the decisions available to consumers in intervention programs).
  • 145
    • 79955931867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally id. at 175 emphasizing how consumers are influenced more by comfort and fulfilled desires than by energy efficiency when renovating their homes
    • See generally id. at 175 (emphasizing how consumers are influenced more by comfort and fulfilled desires than by energy efficiency when renovating their homes).
  • 146
    • 33845800493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dormitory residents reduce electricity consumption when exposed to real-time visual feedback and incentives
    • For a workplace example, see Amanda R. Carrico & Manuel Riemer, Motivating Pro-Environmental Behavior in an Organizational Setting: The use of Feedback and Peer Education to Reduce Energy use 2009 unpublished abstract on file with author. For a dormitory example, see, 29, For a military base example
    • For a workplace example, see Amanda R. Carrico & Manuel Riemer, Motivating Pro-Environmental Behavior in an Organizational Setting: The use of Feedback and Peer Education to Reduce Energy use (2009) (unpublished abstract) (on file with author). For a dormitory example, see John E. Petersen et al., Dormitory Residents Reduce Electricity Consumption When Exposed to Real-Time Visual Feedback and Incentives, 8 INT'L. J. SUSTAINABILITY HIGHER EDUC. 16, 29 (2007). For a military base example
    • (2007) Int'L. J. Sustainability Higher Educ , vol.8 , pp. 16
    • Petersen, J.E.1
  • 147
    • 0036828480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motivating residents to conserve energy without financial incentives
    • see, 856
    • see Andrea H. McMakin et al., Motivating Residents to Conserve Energy Without Financial Incentives, 34 ENVTL. BEHAV. 848, 856 (2002).
    • (2002) Envtl. Behav. , vol.34 , pp. 848
    • McMakin, A.H.1
  • 148
    • 79955936938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McMakin et al., supra note 86, at 849
    • See McMakin et al., supra note 86, at 849;
  • 149
    • 79955938399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Petersen et al., supra note 86, at 18
    • Petersen et al., supra note 86, at 18;
  • 150
    • 79955941026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carrico & Riemer, supra note 86
    • Carrico & Riemer, supra note 86.
  • 151
    • 28244486115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A review of intervention studies aimed at household energy conservation
    • For a review, see, 278-79
    • For a review, see Wokje Abrahamse et al., A Review of Intervention Studies Aimed at Household Energy Conservation, 25 J. ENV'T PSYCH. 273, 278-79 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Env'T Psych. , vol.25 , pp. 273
    • Abrahamse, W.1
  • 152
    • 79955940133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., infra note 122 and accompanying text
    • See, e.g., infra note 122 and accompanying text.
  • 153
    • 0037213638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eco-labeling for energy efficiency and sustainability: A meta-evaluation of us programs
    • 111-12, describing the purpose of various energy conservation policies
    • See Abhijit Banerjee & Barry D. Solomon, Eco-Labeling for Energy Efficiency and Sustainability: A Meta-Evaluation of US Programs, 31 ENERGY POL'Y 109, 111-12 (2003) (describing the purpose of various energy conservation policies).
    • (2003) Energy Pol'Y , vol.31 , pp. 109
    • Banerjee, A.1    Solomon, B.D.2
  • 154
    • 79955930076 scopus 로고
    • See, explaining how individual behavior associated with energy use is often not incorporated into policy analysis, but should be in new programs and policies
    • See NAT'L RESEARCH COUNCIL, ENERGY USE: THE HUMAN DIMENSION 184 (1984) (explaining how individual behavior associated with energy use is often not incorporated into policy analysis, but should be in new programs and policies).
    • (1984) Nat'L Research Council, Energy Use: The Human Dimension , pp. 184
  • 155
    • 79955930075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Brown, supra note 78, at 1198
    • See, e.g., Brown, supra note 78, at 1198
  • 156
    • 79955938850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing a study where the majority of consumers did not purchase the energy efficient appliances, but instead purchased cheaper appliances that consumed more energy in the long run
    • (citing a study where the majority of consumers did not purchase the energy efficient appliances, but instead purchased cheaper appliances that consumed more energy in the long run).
  • 157
    • 0035154607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Technological progress and sustainable development: What about the rebound effect?
    • See, e.g., 130
    • See, e.g., Mathias Binswanger, Technological Progress and Sustainable Development: What About the Rebound Effect?, 36 ECOLOGICAL ECON. 119, 130 (2001);
    • (2001) Ecological Econ. , vol.36 , pp. 119
    • Binswanger, M.1
  • 158
    • 18844415595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Energy efficiency-a critical view
    • 12
    • Horace Herring, Energy Efficiency-A Critical View, 31 ENERGY 10, 12 (2006).
    • (2006) Energy , vol.31 , pp. 10
    • Herring, H.1
  • 159
    • 33750482272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Putting energy efficiency in a sustainability context
    • For a review, see, 12
    • For a review, see Jack N. Barkenbus, Putting Energy Efficiency in a Sustainability Context, 48 ENVIRONMENT 10, 12 (2006).
    • (2006) Environment , vol.48 , pp. 10
    • Barkenbus, J.N.1
  • 160
    • 79955935081 scopus 로고
    • According to surveys conducted by the Energy Information Administration, thirteen percent of households surveyed in 1987 owned two or more refrigerators compared to twenty-two percent of those surveyed in 2005. See U. S. DEP'T OF ENERGY, available at
    • According to surveys conducted by the Energy Information Administration, thirteen percent of households surveyed in 1987 owned two or more refrigerators compared to twenty-two percent of those surveyed in 2005. See U. S. DEP'T OF ENERGY, ENERGY INFO. ADMIN., RESIDENTIAL ENERGY CONSUMPTION SURVEY, PRESENCE OF APPLIANCES (1987), available at http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/recs/recspubuse87/ 87publicuse.html;
    • (1987) Energy Info. Admin., Residential Energy Consumption Survey, Presence of Appliances
  • 162
    • 79955938094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Md.'s Veto of advance meter deployment stuns smart grid advocates
    • See, June 23
    • See Peter Behr, Md.'s Veto of Advance Meter Deployment Stuns Smart Grid Advocates, CLIMATE WIRE (June 23, 2010), http://www.eenews.net/public/ climatewire/2010/06/23/1.
    • (2010) Climate Wire
    • Behr, P.1
  • 163
    • 79955938398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Md. Smart meter plan advances with consumer benefits as a measure
    • See id. "While some state utility commissions are willing to back smart meter deployment, they are reluctant to approve new 'dynamic' electricity rate plans that allow prices to rise during the day when power demand
    • See id. ("While some state utility commissions are willing to back smart meter deployment, they are reluctant to approve new 'dynamic' electricity rate plans that allow prices to rise during the day when power demand peaks."). The utility later modified the program and obtained regulatory approval. See Peter Behr, Md. Smart Meter Plan Advances with Consumer Benefits as a Measure, CLIMATE WIRE (Aug. 18, 2010), http://www.eenews.net/cw/(search "ClimateWire" for "Md. Smart Meter Plan Advances"; then follow "Grid" hyperlink) ("The commission emphasized, 'the success of this initiative, and the likelihood that customers will actually see the benefits this project promises, depend centrally on the success of the company's customer education and communication effort.'").
    • (2010) Climate Wire
    • Behr, P.1
  • 164
    • 79955930149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., supra note 91, demonstrating how feedback on energy use, without cost savings, may be insufficient to get customers to change their energy usage
    • See, e.g., NAT'L RESEARCH COUNCIL, supra note 91, at 39-41 (demonstrating how feedback on energy use, without cost savings, may be insufficient to get customers to change their energy usage).
    • Nat'L Research Council , pp. 39-41
  • 165
    • 79955930641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nearly identical incentive programs directed toward home efficiency improvements within similar geographic areas have varied by a factor of ten. For a review, see Stern, supra note 46, at 210-11. Differential success rates of these programs have been primarily attributed to marketing and implementation of the program
    • Nearly identical incentive programs directed toward home efficiency improvements within similar geographic areas have varied by a factor of ten. For a review, see Stern, supra note 46, at 210-11. Differential success rates of these programs have been primarily attributed to marketing and implementation of the program.
  • 166
    • 79955934025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 167
    • 0024606425 scopus 로고
    • The hood river conservation project: A unique research and demonstration effort
    • 8
    • Eric Hirst, The Hood River Conservation Project: A Unique Research and Demonstration Effort, 13 ENERGY & BUILDINGS 3, 8 (1989).
    • (1989) Energy & Buildings , vol.13 , pp. 3
    • Hirst, E.1
  • 168
    • 79955940056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Using mass media to influence energy consumption behavior: California's 2001
    • For a review of California's Flex Your Power campaign in response to the energy crisis of 2001, see, 15, 8.17, available at, examining the campaign's formulation, implementation, and strategic evolution of its themes. For a brief description of California's utility-sponsored demand side management programs, including programs targeted at promoting efficiency adoption and energy curtailment
    • For a review of California's Flex Your Power campaign in response to the energy crisis of 2001, see Sylvia L. Bender et al., Using Mass Media to Influence Energy Consumption Behavior: California's 2001 Flex Your Power Campaign as a Case Study 8. 15, 8.17 (2002), available at http://citeseerx.ist. psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.156.8308&rep=rep1&type=pdf (examining the campaign's formulation, implementation, and strategic evolution of its themes). For a brief description of California's utility-sponsored demand side management programs, including programs targeted at promoting efficiency adoption and energy curtailment
    • (2002) Flex Your Power Campaign As A Case Study , pp. 8
    • Bender, S.L.1
  • 169
    • 0030242849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DSM accomplishments in California: PG&E's experience
    • see, 1296
    • see Elsia O. Galawish, DSM Accomplishments in California: PG&E's Experience, 9 RENEWABLE ENERGY 1295, 1296 (1996).
    • (1996) Renewable Energy , vol.9 , pp. 1295
    • Galawish, E.O.1
  • 170
    • 79955931627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Charles, supra note 3, at 805
    • See Charles, supra note 3, at 805.
  • 171
    • 79955942911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 172
    • 79955941206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • June 1, unpublished manuscript, available at
    • James Sweeney & Anant Sudarshan, Deconstructing the "Rosenfeld Curve" 1 (June 1, 2008) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://piee.stanford.edu/cgi-bin/docs/publications/Deconstructing-the-Rosenfeld- Curve.pdf.
    • (2008) Deconstructing the "Rosenfeld Curve" , pp. 1
    • Sweeney, J.1    Sudarshan, A.2
  • 174
    • 79955931624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. noting OMB recommendation to agencies to consider "behaviorally informed approaches to regulation"
    • See, e.g., id. (noting OMB recommendation to agencies to consider "behaviorally informed approaches to regulation");
  • 175
    • 79955929846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 5, providing guidance to agencies
    • OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 2-12 (providing guidance to agencies).
    • (2010) Oira Disclosure Memo , pp. 2-12
  • 176
    • 79955942541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Adler, supra note 20, at 142-43 noting the importance of bounded rationality for regulatory decisionmakers
    • Cf. Adler, supra note 20, at 142-43 (noting the importance of bounded rationality for regulatory decisionmakers);
  • 177
    • 79955942042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1508-45 providing a general framework for use of behavioral economics in development of legal prescriptions
    • Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1508-45 (providing a general framework for use of behavioral economics in development of legal prescriptions).
  • 178
    • 79955929369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Adler, supra note 20, at 155-57
    • See Adler, supra note 20, at 155-57.
  • 180
    • 79955930248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Adler, supra note 20, at 158-59
    • See Adler, supra note 20, at 158-59;
  • 181
    • 79955936846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott, supra note 55, at 1621-22
    • Scott, supra note 55, at 1621-22.
  • 182
    • 66349099019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Costly myths: An analysis of idling beliefs and behavior in personal motor vehicles
    • 2885
    • Amanda R. Carrico et al., Costly Myths: An Analysis of Idling Beliefs and Behavior in Personal Motor Vehicles, 37 ENERGY POL'Y 2881, 2885 (2009).
    • (2009) Energy Pol'Y , vol.37 , pp. 2881
    • Carrico, A.R.1
  • 184
    • 33947231768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preemption by preamble: Federal agencies and the federalization of tort law
    • See, 230, discussing mandatory agency safety requirements such as "product performance, design, labeling, warnings, and instructions"
    • See Catherine M. Sharkey, Preemption By Preamble: Federal Agencies and the Federalization of Tort Law, 56 DEPAUL L. REV. 227, 230 (2007) (discussing mandatory agency safety requirements such as "product performance, design, labeling, warnings, and instructions").
    • (2007) Depaul L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 227
    • Sharkey, C.M.1
  • 185
    • 79955937006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCKENZIE-MOHR ASSOCS., available at
    • MCKENZIE-MOHR ASSOCS., ANTI-IDLING FINAL REPORT 4 (2003), available at http://www.greatersudbury.ca/content/earthcare/documents/Sudbury-finalreport. pdf.
    • (2003) Anti-Idling Final Report , pp. 4
  • 186
    • 79955929846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OIRA recently described these types of informational regulatory tools as "summary disclosure.", supra note 5, identifying the seven principles for agency use of summary disclosure as a regulatory tool. It may be important not only to provide more information, but also to attend to the way in which the information is provided. Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1533-34
    • OIRA recently described these types of informational regulatory tools as "summary disclosure." 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 3-6 (identifying the seven principles for agency use of summary disclosure as a regulatory tool). It may be important not only to provide more information, but also to attend to the way in which the information is provided. Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1533-34.
    • (2010) Oira Disclosure Memo , pp. 3-6
  • 187
  • 188
    • 79955938487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing studies that show that most energy users are ill informed of appliance energy usage under aggregate billing systems
    • (citing studies that show that most energy users are ill informed of appliance energy usage under aggregate billing systems).
  • 189
    • 79955938932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 36 explaining how energy bills are received infrequently and aggregate energy use into one total
    • Id. at 36 (explaining how energy bills are received infrequently and aggregate energy use into one total).
  • 190
    • 79955940057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 36-38
    • See id. at 36-38;
  • 191
    • 0020191275 scopus 로고
    • Folk quantification of energy
    • 817
    • Willett Kempton & Laura Montgomery, Folk Quantification of Energy, 7 ENERGY 817, 817 (1982).
    • (1982) Energy , vol.7 , pp. 817
    • Kempton, W.1    Montgomery, L.2
  • 192
    • 79955929846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OIRA recently recognized that agencies "should take steps to provide people with relevant information when they are actually making the decision or taking the action in question. ", supra note 5, at 4 stating that Principle Four is that "disclosed information should be properly placed and timed"
    • OIRA recently recognized that agencies "should take steps to provide people with relevant information when they are actually making the decision or taking the action in question. " 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4 (stating that Principle Four is that "[d]isclosed information should be properly placed and timed").
    • (2010) Oira Disclosure Memo
  • 193
    • 77957998601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Public perceptions of energy consumption and savings
    • 054, 055
    • Shahzeen Z. Attari et al., Public Perceptions of Energy Consumption and Savings, 107 PROC. NAT'L ACAD. SCI. 16, 054, at 16, 055 (2010);
    • (2010) Proc. Nat'L Acad. Sci. , vol.16-107 , pp. 16
    • Attari, S.Z.1
  • 194
    • 84953605739 scopus 로고
    • Do consumers know "What Works" in energy conservation?
    • 115-33
    • Willett Kempton et al., Do Consumers Know "What Works" in Energy Conservation?, 9 MARRIAGE FAM. REV. 115, 115-33 (1985).
    • (1985) Marriage Fam. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 115
    • Kempton, W.1
  • 196
    • 0018737095 scopus 로고
    • Energy conservation effects of continuous in-home feedback in all-electric homes
    • 169-73
    • Lou McClelland & Stuart W. Cook, Energy Conservation Effects of Continuous In-Home Feedback in All-Electric Homes, 9 J. ENVTL. SYS. 169, 169-73 (1979).
    • (1979) J. Envtl. Sys , vol.9 , pp. 169
    • McClelland, L.1    Cook, S.W.2
  • 197
    • 72249118871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eco-driving: An overlooked climate change initiative
    • See, 765-66, showing a ten-percent gain in fuel economy
    • See Jack N. Barkenbus, Eco-Driving: An Overlooked Climate Change Initiative, 38 ENERGY POL'Y 762, 765-66 (2010) (showing a ten-percent gain in fuel economy);
    • (2010) Energy Pol'Y , vol.38 , pp. 762
    • Barkenbus, J.N.1
  • 198
    • 0035427698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A prototype of fuel-efficiency support tool
    • 279, showing a sixteen-percent gain
    • Mascha van der Voort et al., A Prototype of Fuel-Efficiency Support Tool, 9 C. TRANSP. RES. 279, 279 (2001) (showing a sixteen-percent gain);
    • (2001) C. Transp. Res , vol.9 , pp. 279
    • Van Der Voort, M.1
  • 199
    • 79955942759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Scania Grp., Scania Takes Eco-Driving to a New Level with Its Latest Digital Performance Coaching Technology Sept. 17, 2009, available at
    • Press Release, Scania Grp., Scania Takes Eco-Driving to a New Level with Its Latest Digital Performance Coaching Technology (Sept. 17, 2009), available at http://www.scania.com/media/pressreleases/n09025en.aspx.
  • 200
    • 79955935266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Behr, supra note 96
    • See Behr, supra note 96.
  • 201
    • 79955942290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ARIELY, supra note 2, at xxix-xxx
    • See, e.g., ARIELY, supra note 2, at xxix-xxx;
  • 202
    • 79955933950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabin, supra note 2, at 13-32
    • Rabin, supra note 2, at 13-32;
  • 203
    • 79955942465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 452
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 452.
  • 204
    • 78049244052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Energy efficiency economics and policy
    • See, 605-07
    • See Kenneth Gillingham et al., Energy Efficiency Economics and Policy, 1 ANN. REV. RESOURCE ECON. 597, 605-07 (2009);
    • (2009) Ann. Rev. Resource Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 597
    • Gillingham, K.1
  • 205
    • 0002329238 scopus 로고
    • Individual discount rates and the purchase and utilization of energy-using durables
    • 50
    • Jerry A. Hausman, Individual Discount Rates and the Purchase and Utilization of Energy-Using Durables, 10 BELL J. ECON. 33, 50 (1979);
    • (1979) Bell J. Econ. , vol.10 , pp. 33
    • Hausman, J.A.1
  • 206
    • 85005199414 scopus 로고
    • Discount rates and energy efficiency
    • 101
    • Richard Howarth & Alan H. Sanstad, Discount Rates and Energy Efficiency, 13 CONTEMP. ECON. POL'Y 101, 101 (1995);
    • (1995) Contemp. Econ. Pol'Y , vol.13 , pp. 101
    • Howarth, R.1    Sanstad, A.H.2
  • 207
    • 0028529691 scopus 로고
    • Technical evidence for assessing the performance of markets affecting energy efficiency
    • 828-30
    • Jonathan G. Koomey & Alan H. Sanstad, Technical Evidence for Assessing the Performance of Markets Affecting Energy Efficiency, 22 ENERGY POL'Y 826, 828-30 (1994);
    • (1994) Energy Pol'Y , vol.22 , pp. 826
    • Koomey, J.G.1    Sanstad, A.H.2
  • 208
    • 0030094212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Individual discounting, energy conservation, and household demand for lighting
    • 112
    • Peter Kooreman, Individual Discounting, Energy Conservation, and Household Demand for Lighting, 18 RESOURCE & ENERGY ECON. 103, 112 (1996).
    • (1996) Resource & Energy Econ. , vol.18 , pp. 103
    • Kooreman, P.1
  • 209
    • 77954654495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economics of energy efficiency
    • See, in, 85-86 Cutler Cleveland ed.
    • See Adam B. Jaffe et al., The Economics of Energy Efficiency, in ENCYCLOPEDIA OF ENERGY 79, 85-86 (Cutler Cleveland ed., 2004);
    • (2004) Encyclopedia of Energy , pp. 79
    • Jaffe, A.B.1
  • 210
    • 0001893493 scopus 로고
    • Market barriers to energy-efficiency investments
    • 31
    • Ronald J. Sutherland, Market Barriers to Energy-Efficiency Investments, 12 ENERGY J. 15, 31 (1991).
    • (1991) Energy J , vol.12 , pp. 15
    • Sutherland, R.J.1
  • 211
    • 72749087038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A blind spot in driving decisions: How neglecting costs puts us in overdrive
    • 289
    • See Daniel C. Feiler & Jack B. Soll, A Blind Spot in Driving Decisions: How Neglecting Costs Puts Us in Overdrive, 98 CLIMATIC CHANGE 285, 289 (2010);
    • (2010) Climatic Change , vol.98 , pp. 285
    • Feiler, D.C.1    Soll, J.B.2
  • 212
    • 17044376351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and behavioral biology
    • 444-45
    • Owen D. Jones & Timothy H. Goldsmith, Law and Behavioral Biology, 105 COLUM. L. REV. 405, 444-45 (2005).
    • (2005) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.105 , pp. 405
    • Jones, O.D.1    Goldsmith, T.H.2
  • 213
    • 0027092224 scopus 로고
    • I always turn it on "Super": User decisions about when and how to operate room air conditioners
    • See, 189-90
    • See Willet Kempton et al., I Always Turn It on "Super": User Decisions About When and How to Operate Room Air Conditioners, 18 ENERGY & BUILDINGS 177, 189-90 (1992);
    • (1992) Energy & Buildings , vol.18 , pp. 177
    • Kempton, W.1
  • 214
    • 79955935337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kempton & Montgomery, supra note 118, at 826
    • Kempton & Montgomery, supra note 118, at 826.
  • 215
    • 79955939257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Feiler & Soll, supra note 127, at 289
    • Feiler & Soll, supra note 127, at 289.
  • 216
    • 79955937719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OIRA recently recognized the importance of considering cognitive costs during regulatory development. See 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4, 10 noting that "people have limited time and attention" and thus "may not participate in important programs simply because the required steps for participation are complex and daunting; agencies can often improve outcomes by reducing unnecessary paperwork burdens and simplifying choices"
    • OIRA recently recognized the importance of considering cognitive costs during regulatory development. See 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4, 10 (noting that "[p]eople have limited time and attention" and thus "may not participate in important programs simply because the required steps for participation are complex and daunting; agencies can often improve outcomes by reducing unnecessary paperwork burdens and simplifying choices").
  • 217
    • 84984157636 scopus 로고
    • Barriers to individual environmental action: The influence of attitudes and social experiences
    • 477
    • Glenda Wall, Barriers to Individual Environmental Action: The Influence of Attitudes and Social Experiences, 32 CANADIAN REV. SOC. & ANTHROPOLOGY 465, 477 (1995).
    • (1995) Canadian Rev. Soc. & Anthropology , vol.32 , pp. 465
    • Wall, G.1
  • 218
    • 0042905287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Increasing recycling in academic buildings: A systematic replication
    • 683
    • Timothy D. Ludwig et al., Increasing Recycling in Academic Buildings: A Systematic Replication, 31 J. APPLIED BEHAV. ANALYSIS 683, 683 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Applied Behav. Analysis , vol.31 , pp. 683
    • Ludwig, T.D.1
  • 219
    • 0642284005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do defaults save lives?
    • 1339, OIRA recently included default settings among the alternatives that agencies should consider when designing regulatory options. 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 9 noting that regulatory outcomes "sometimes... can be achieved by selecting appropriate starting points or 'default rules'"
    • Eric J. Johnson & Daniel Goldstein, Do Defaults Save Lives?, 302 SCIENCE 1338, 1339 (2003). OIRA recently included default settings among the alternatives that agencies should consider when designing regulatory options. 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 9 (noting that regulatory outcomes "sometimes... can be achieved by selecting appropriate starting points or 'default rules'").
    • (2003) Science , vol.302 , pp. 1338
    • Johnson, E.J.1    Goldstein, D.2
  • 220
    • 0005928667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Information, incentives, and proenvironmental consumer behavior
    • 469
    • Paul C. Stern, Information, Incentives, and Proenvironmental Consumer Behavior, 22 J. CONSUMER POL'Y. 461, 469 (1999).
    • (1999) J. Consumer Pol'Y , vol.22 , pp. 461
    • Stern, P.C.1
  • 221
    • 84973848932 scopus 로고
    • The effectiveness of incentives for residential energy conservation
    • 159, hereinafter Stern et al., Effectiveness of Incentives
    • Paul C. Stern et al., The Effectiveness of Incentives for Residential Energy Conservation, 10 EVALUATION REV. 147, 159 (1986) [hereinafter Stern et al., Effectiveness of Incentives];
    • (1986) Evaluation Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 147
    • Stern, P.C.1
  • 222
    • 77954308528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Design principles for carbon emissions reduction programs
    • 4848, hereinafter Stern et al., Design Principles
    • Paul C. Stern, Gerald T. Gardner, Michael P. Vandenbergh, Thomas Dietz & Jonathan M. Gilligan, Design Principles for Carbon Emissions Reduction Programs, 44 ENVTL. SCI. & TECH. 4847, 4848 (2010) [hereinafter Stern et al., Design Principles].
    • (2010) Envtl. Sci. & Tech. , vol.44 , pp. 4847
    • Stern, P.C.1    Gardner, G.T.2    Vandenbergh, M.P.3    Dietz, T.4    Gilligan, J.M.5
  • 223
    • 79955933949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §
    • 49 U. S. C. § 32901 (2010).
    • (2010) U. S. C , vol.49 , pp. 32901
  • 224
    • 79955933461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When it comes to being green, cash for clunkers is a lemon
    • See, e.g., Op-Ed., last visited Nov. 29, 2010
    • See, e.g., Lee Schipper, Op-Ed., When It Comes to Being Green, Cash for Clunkers Is a Lemon, WASH. POST, http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/ graphic/2009/08/08/GR2009080802658.html (last visited Nov. 29, 2010).
    • Wash. Post
    • Schipper, L.1
  • 225
    • 79955936061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, §
    • See 49 U. S. C. § 32901 (b).
    • U. S. C , vol.49
  • 226
    • 79955938769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 227
    • 79955942045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. §32901 c - d
    • See id. §32901 (c) - (d).
  • 228
    • 77958022479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Implementing the behavioral wedge: Designing and adopting effective carbon emissions reduction programs
    • See, 547, at 10, 551
    • See Michael P. Vandenbergh et al., Implementing the Behavioral Wedge: Designing and Adopting Effective Carbon Emissions Reduction Programs, 40 ENVTL. L. REP. 10, 547, at 10, 551 (2010).
    • (2010) Envtl. L. Rep. , vol.40 , pp. 10
    • Vandenbergh, M.P.1
  • 229
    • 79955930791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more detailed review, see, supra note 135
    • For a more detailed review, see Stern et al., Design Principles, supra note 135, at 4847-48.
    • Design Principles , pp. 4847-4848
    • Stern1
  • 230
    • 79955943186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2, at 343-44
    • See Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2, at 343-44;
  • 231
    • 79955932324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 453. OIRA recently noted the need for agencies to consider framing and loss aversion in the design of summary disclosure regulatory measures
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 453. OIRA recently noted the need for agencies to consider framing and loss aversion in the design of summary disclosure regulatory measures.
  • 232
    • 79955933788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4 "If a potential outcome is presented as a loss, for example, people may pay more attention than if it is presented as a gain. "
    • See 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4 ("[I]f a potential outcome is presented as a loss, for example, people may pay more attention than if it is presented as a gain. ").
  • 233
    • 0000485795 scopus 로고
    • How consumers are affected by the framing of attribute information before and after consuming the product
    • 375-77
    • Irwin P. Levin & Gary J. Gaeth, How Consumers Are Affected by the Framing of Attribute Information Before and After Consuming the Product, 15 J. CONSUMER RES. 374, 375-77 (1988).
    • (1988) J. Consumer Res. , vol.15 , pp. 374
    • Levin, I.P.1    Gaeth, G.J.2
  • 234
    • 79955938246 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2, at 342
    • See Kahneman & Tversky, supra note 2, at 342;
  • 235
    • 79955935080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 456
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 456.
  • 236
    • 79955941208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 453 "The definition of rationality has been much debated, but there is general agreement that rational choices should satisfy some elementary requirements of consistency and coherence."
    • See, e.g., Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 453 ("The definition of rationality has been much debated, but there is general agreement that rational choices should satisfy some elementary requirements of consistency and coherence.").
  • 237
    • 79955931626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 454
    • See, e.g., id. at 454.
  • 238
    • 0023319318 scopus 로고
    • Empathy-based helping: Is it selflessly or selfishly motivated?
    • See, e.g., 749-50, arguing that the empathy for another in need leads to the experience of sadness in the observer, motivating him or her to relieve that sadness through helping, and providing data to suggest that empathy is associated with sadness and those who were led to believe that helping would not reduce empathy were less likely to help others
    • See, e.g., Robert B. Cialdini et al., Empathy-Based Helping: Is It Selflessly or Selfishly Motivated?, 52 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 749, 749-50 (1987) (arguing that the empathy for another in need leads to the experience of sadness in the observer, motivating him or her to relieve that sadness through helping, and providing data to suggest that empathy is associated with sadness and those who were led to believe that helping would not reduce empathy were less likely to help others).
    • (1987) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.52 , pp. 749
    • Cialdini, R.B.1
  • 239
    • 0042412879 scopus 로고
    • Free riding versus cooperation
    • See, in, 90 Richard J. Zeckhauser ed., "The possibilities... could come either from imposing a risk of punishment on those who fail to cooperate or offering the promise of reward for those who do."
    • See Howard Margolis, Free Riding Versus Cooperation, in STRATEGY AND CHOICE 84, 90 (Richard J. Zeckhauser ed., 1991) ("[T]he possibilities... could come either from imposing a risk of punishment on those who fail to cooperate or offering the promise of reward for those who do.");
    • (1991) Strategy and Choice , pp. 84
    • Margolis, H.1
  • 240
    • 0002666119 scopus 로고
    • Social norms and economic theory
    • cf, Fall, 100 noting that social norms are "enforced by members of the general community" and are "sustained by the approval and disapproval of others" and providing several examples
    • cf. Jon Elster, Social Norms and Economic Theory, J. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1989, at 99, 100 (noting that social norms are "enforced by members of the general community" and are "sustained by the approval and disapproval of others" and providing several examples).
    • (1989) J. Econ. Persp. , pp. 99
    • Elster, J.1
  • 241
    • 79955933948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Margolis, supra note 149, at 90-95
    • See Margolis, supra note 149, at 90-95.
  • 242
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., discussing the roles of labels, hierarchies, stereotypes, and reputation
    • See, e.g., ROBERT M. AXELROD, THE EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION 146-54 (1984) (discussing the roles of labels, hierarchies, stereotypes, and reputation).
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation , pp. 146-154
    • Axelrod, R.M.1
  • 243
    • 79955933549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1116 noting how the use of a legal analytical framework identified the overlooked importance of an entitlement in the case of a polluter protected by a liability rule
    • Cf. Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 21, at 1116 (noting how the use of a legal analytical framework identified the overlooked importance of an entitlement in the case of a polluter protected by a liability rule).
  • 244
    • 79955939486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 109-45 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 109-45 and accompanying text.
  • 246
    • 79955932325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 247
    • 79955942289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 248
    • 0000093320 scopus 로고
    • Pluralistic ignorance and white estimates of white support for racial segregation
    • In addition to the example of college drinking that follows, social scientists have speculated that pluralistic ignorance was responsible for the widespread public support for segregation among white Americans during the 1960's, 330, as well as the support of communism within the Soviet Union
    • In addition to the example of college drinking that follows, social scientists have speculated that pluralistic ignorance was responsible for the widespread public support for segregation among white Americans during the 1960's, Hubert J. O'Gorman, Pluralistic Ignorance and White Estimates of White Support for Racial Segregation, 39 PUB. OPINION Q. 313, 330 (1975), as well as the support of communism within the Soviet Union
    • (1975) Pub. Opinion Q , vol.39 , pp. 313
    • O'Gorman, H.J.1
  • 250
    • 0027549978 scopus 로고
    • Pluralistic ignorance and alcohol use on campuses: Some consequences of misperceiving the social norm
    • 245
    • Deborah A. Prentice & Dale T. Miller, Pluralistic Ignorance and Alcohol use on Campuses: Some Consequences of Misperceiving the Social Norm, 64 J. PERSONALITY & SOC. PSYCHOL. 243, 245 (1993);
    • (1993) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.64 , pp. 243
    • Prentice, D.A.1    Miller, D.T.2
  • 251
    • 0032325529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exposing pluralistic ignorance to reduce alcohol use among college students
    • 2170-74
    • Christine M. Schroeder & Deborah A. Prentice, Exposing Pluralistic Ignorance to Reduce Alcohol use Among College Students, 28 J. APPLIED SOC. PSYCHOL. 2150, 2170-74 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Applied Soc. Psychol. , vol.28 , pp. 2150
    • Schroeder, C.M.1    Prentice, D.A.2
  • 252
    • 79955939724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schroeder & Prentice, supra note 158, at 2170-74
    • Schroeder & Prentice, supra note 158, at 2170-74.
  • 253
    • 79955940708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 254
    • 79955929679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Asch, supra note 62, at 181-82
    • Asch, supra note 62, at 181-82.
  • 255
    • 53549103013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A room with a viewpoint: Using social norms to motivate environmental conservation in hotels
    • 479-80, finding that prescriptive norms increased participation in hotel energy conservation programs
    • Noah J. Goldstein et al., A Room with a Viewpoint: Using Social Norms to Motivate Environmental Conservation in Hotels, 35 J. CONSUMER RES. 472, 479-80 (2008) (finding that prescriptive norms increased participation in hotel energy conservation programs);
    • (2008) J. Consumer Res. , vol.35 , pp. 472
    • Goldstein, N.J.1
  • 256
    • 85047670904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Changing behavior with normative feedback interventions: A field experiment on curbside recycling
    • 31-33, hereinafter Schultz, Changing Behavior finding that individual feedback increased curbside recycling
    • P. Wesley Schultz, Changing Behavior With Normative Feedback Interventions: A Field Experiment on Curbside Recycling, 21 BASIC & APPLIED SOC. PSYCHOL. 25, 31-33 (1998) [hereinafter Schultz, Changing Behavior] (finding that individual feedback increased curbside recycling);
    • (1998) Basic & Applied Soc. Psychol. , vol.21 , pp. 25
    • Wesley Schultz, P.1
  • 257
    • 34250333040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms
    • 432, hereinafter Schultz et al., Power of Social Norms finding that providing residents with normative feedback decreased home energy usage
    • P. Wesley Schultz et al., The Constructive, Destructive, and Reconstructive Power of Social Norms, 18 PSYCHOL. SCI. 429, 432 (2007) [hereinafter Schultz et al., Power of Social Norms] (finding that providing residents with normative feedback decreased home energy usage).
    • (2007) Psychol. Sci. , vol.18 , pp. 429
    • Wesley Schultz, P.1
  • 258
    • 83155177794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Evidence from two large field experiments that peer comparison feedback can reduce residential energy usage
    • Working Paper No. 15 available at
    • Ian Ayres et al., Evidence from Two Large Field Experiments that Peer Comparison Feedback Can Reduce Residential Energy Usage 5 (Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 15, 386, 2009), available at http://www.nber.org/ papers/w15386.
    • (2009) Nat'L Bureau of Econ. Research , vol.5 , pp. 386
    • Ayres, I.1
  • 259
    • 79955931552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 260
    • 79955937266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 261
    • 77957089545 scopus 로고
    • A focus theory of normative conduct: A theoretical refinement and reevaluation of the role of norms in human behavior
    • see also, 208-09, noting the perverse side effect of an antilittering campaign that implicitly acknowledged that many people litter
    • see also Robert B. Cialdini et al., A Focus Theory of Normative Conduct: A Theoretical Refinement and Reevaluation of the Role of Norms in Human Behavior, 24 ADVANCES EXPERIMENTAL SOC. PSYCHOL. 202, 208-09 (1991) (noting the perverse side effect of an antilittering campaign that implicitly acknowledged that many people litter).
    • (1991) Advances Experimental Soc. Psychol. , vol.24 , pp. 202
    • Cialdini, R.B.1
  • 262
    • 0001695934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The origin, development, and regulation of norms
    • Cf, 340
    • Cf. Richard H. McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 MICH. L. REV. 338, 340 (1997)
    • (1997) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 338
    • McAdams, R.H.1
  • 263
    • 79955938486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing law and economics research that acknowledges the occasional trumping power of internalized norms over external incentives
    • (citing law and economics research that acknowledges the occasional trumping power of internalized norms over external incentives);
  • 264
    • 79955939022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 69, at 1781 acknowledging the role of internalized norms in tax compliance
    • Posner, supra note 69, at 1781 (acknowledging the role of internalized norms in tax compliance).
  • 265
    • 0041917494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crafting normative messages to protect the environment
    • 107
    • Robert B. Cialdini, Crafting Normative Messages to Protect the Environment, 12 CURRENT DIRECTIONS PSYCHOL. SCI. 105, 107 (2003).
    • (2003) Current Directions Psychol. Sci. , vol.12 , pp. 105
    • Cialdini, R.B.1
  • 266
    • 79955935891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 267
    • 79955929767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 268
    • 44949274046 scopus 로고
    • The theory of planned behavior
    • See, e.g., 180, noting the relatively poor predictive power of dispositions as well as general attitudes in predicting specific behaviors
    • See, e.g., Icek Ajzen, The Theory of Planned Behavior, 50 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 179, 180 (1991) (noting the relatively poor predictive power of dispositions as well as general attitudes in predicting specific behaviors).
    • (1991) Organizational Behav. & Hum. Decision Processes , vol.50 , pp. 179
    • Ajzen, I.1
  • 269
    • 79955943482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 6
    • See MCKENZIE-MOHR & SMITH, supra note 6, at 122-32.
    • Mckenzie-Mohr & Smith , pp. 122-132
  • 270
    • 79955942044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 272
    • 46249113019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Policies designed for self-interested citizens may undermine "the moral sentiments": Evidence from economic experiments
    • See, 1609
    • See Samuel Bowles, Policies Designed for Self-Interested Citizens May Undermine "The Moral Sentiments": Evidence from Economic Experiments, 320 SCIENCE 1605, 1609 (2008);
    • (2008) Science , vol.320 , pp. 1605
    • Bowles, S.1
  • 273
    • 0033220501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A meta-analytic review of experiments examining the effects of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation
    • 658-59
    • Edward L. Deci et al., A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation, 125 PSYCHOL. BULL. 627, 658-59 (1999);
    • (1999) Psychol. Bull , vol.125 , pp. 627
    • Deci, E.L.1
  • 274
    • 38249000630 scopus 로고
    • Motivation as a limit to pricing
    • 658
    • Bruno S. Frey, Motivation as a Limit to Pricing, 14 J. ECON. PSYCHOL. 635, 658 (1993);
    • (1993) J. Econ. Psychol. , vol.14 , pp. 635
    • Frey, B.S.1
  • 275
    • 0033235167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sanctioning systems, decision frames, and cooperation
    • 704
    • Ann E. Tenbrunsel & David M. Messick, Sanctioning Systems, Decision Frames, and Cooperation, 44 ADMIN. SCI. Q. 684, 704 (1999).
    • (1999) Admin. Sci. Q , vol.44 , pp. 684
    • Tenbrunsel, A.E.1    Messick, D.M.2
  • 276
    • 79955935006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gneezy & Rustichini, supra note 173, at 3-8
    • See Gneezy & Rustichini, supra note 173, at 3-8.
  • 277
    • 79955931866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, available at, advising that both voluntary and regulatory approaches should be used in tandem
    • See LURA CONSULTING, THE CARROT, THE STICK, AND THE COMBO: A RECIPE FOR REDUCING VEHICLE IDLING IN CANADIAN COMMUNITIES 6-7 (2005), available at http://oee.nrcan.gc.ca/communities-government/transportation/ municipal-communities/reports/carrot-stick-combo/carrot-stick-combo.pdf (advising that both voluntary and regulatory approaches should be used in tandem);
    • (2005) The Carrot, the Stick, and the Combo: A Recipe For Reducing Vehicle Idling in Canadian Communities , pp. 6-7
    • Consulting, L.1
  • 278
    • 4043155791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effects of tobacco control policies on smoking rates: A tobacco control scorecard
    • 346-49, "The most successful tobacco control strategies appear to involve multiple policies implemented as part of a comprehensive strategy."
    • David T. Levy et al., The Effects of Tobacco Control Policies on Smoking Rates: A Tobacco Control Scorecard, 10 J. PUB. HEALTH MGMT. PRAC. 338, 346-49 (2004) ("[T]he most successful tobacco control strategies appear to involve multiple policies implemented as part of a comprehensive strategy.").
    • (2004) J. Pub. Health MGMT. Prac. , vol.10 , pp. 338
    • Levy, D.T.1
  • 279
    • 79955933460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rosenthal, supra note 13, at A3. Similarly, combining public education with regulatory measures has also been successfully used to reduce vehicle idling in a number of Canadian communities. See, supra note 176
    • See Rosenthal, supra note 13, at A3. Similarly, combining public education with regulatory measures has also been successfully used to reduce vehicle idling in a number of Canadian communities. See LURA CONSULTING, supra note 176, at 8-20.
    • Lura Consulting , pp. 8-20
  • 280
    • 79955934112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rosenthal, supra note 13, at A3 "And then something happened that was bigger than the sum of these parts."
    • See Rosenthal, supra note 13, at A3 ("And then something happened that was bigger than the sum of these parts.").
  • 281
    • 79955933637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 282
    • 79955943185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts II. A.2.b.i-iii
    • See infra Parts II. A.2.b.i-iii.
  • 283
    • 79955928496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.i
    • See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.i.
  • 284
    • 79955942218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.ii
    • See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.ii.
  • 285
    • 79955942543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.iii
    • See discussion infra Part II. A.2.b.iii.
  • 286
    • 77955573367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Descriptive normative beliefs and conservation behavior: The moderating roles of personal involvement and injunctive normative beliefs
    • See, 517, describing the moderating effect of personal involvement on behavioral change and information processing
    • See Susanne Göckeritz et al., Descriptive Normative Beliefs and Conservation Behavior: The Moderating Roles of Personal Involvement and Injunctive Normative Beliefs, 40 EUR. J. SOC. PSYCHOL. 514, 517 (2010) (describing the moderating effect of personal involvement on behavioral change and information processing).
    • (2010) Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. , vol.40 , pp. 514
    • Göckeritz, S.1
  • 287
    • 77951289646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A dirty word or a dirty world? Attribute framing, political affiliation, and query theory
    • 88
    • David J. Hardisty et al., A Dirty Word or a Dirty World? Attribute Framing, Political Affiliation, and Query Theory, 21 PSYCHOL. SCI. 86, 88 (2010);
    • (2010) Psychol. Sci. , vol.21 , pp. 86
    • Hardisty, D.J.1
  • 288
    • 79955931770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4 "Agencies should be aware of the importance of how information is presented."
    • see also 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 4 ("Agencies should be aware of the importance of how information is presented....").
  • 289
    • 79955939897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hardisty et al., supra note 185, at 86, 89
    • Hardisty et al., supra note 185, at 86, 89.
  • 290
    • 70350257003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oct. 3, unpublished manuscript, available at
    • Dan M. Kahan et al., The Second National Risk and Culture Study 4-6 (Oct. 3, 2007) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ papers.cfm?abstract-id=1017189.
    • (2007) The Second National Risk and Culture Study 4-6
    • Kahan, D.M.1
  • 291
    • 79955938397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2, 16
    • See id. at 2, 16.
  • 292
    • 0000065210 scopus 로고
    • Differentiation and consolidation theory of human decision making: A frame of reference for the study of pre-and post-decision processes
    • 145-46
    • Ola Svenson, Differentiation and Consolidation Theory of Human Decision Making: A Frame of Reference for the Study of Pre-and Post-Decision Processes, 80 ACTA PSYCHOLOGICA 143, 145-46 (1992).
    • (1992) Acta Psychologica , vol.80 , pp. 143
    • Svenson, O.1
  • 293
    • 79955937652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 294
    • 0003169323 scopus 로고
    • Attitudes, decisions, and habits as determinants of repeated behavior
    • 219 Anthony R. Pratkanis et al. eds., For a discussion of habits in law and economics noting the work of Kenneth Arrow and concluding that habits "can be incorporated into a theory by supposing that people choose goods with an eye towards minimizing changes in their consumption"
    • David L. Ronis et al., Attitudes, Decisions, and Habits as Determinants of Repeated Behavior, in ATTITUDE STRUCTURE AND FUNCTION 213, 219 (Anthony R. Pratkanis et al. eds., 1989). For a discussion of habits in law and economics noting the work of Kenneth Arrow and concluding that habits "can be incorporated into a theory by supposing that people choose goods with an eye towards minimizing changes in their consumption"
    • (1989) Attitude Structure and Function , pp. 213
    • Ronis, D.L.1
  • 295
    • 79955937944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1478
    • see Jolls et al., supra note 2, at 1478.
  • 296
    • 0032346280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predicting behavior from actions in the past: Repeated decision making or a matter of habit?
    • See, 1358-61
    • See Henk Aarts et al., Predicting Behavior from Actions in the Past: Repeated Decision Making or a Matter of Habit?, 28 J. APPLIED SOC. PSYCHOL. 1355, 1358-61 (1998);
    • (1998) J. Applied Soc. Psychol. , vol.28 , pp. 1355
    • Aarts, H.1
  • 297
    • 0013400993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The influence of culture on pro-environmental knowledge, attitudes, and behavior: A Canadian perspective
    • 196
    • Michel Laroche et al., The Influence of Culture on Pro-Environmental Knowledge, Attitudes, and Behavior: A Canadian Perspective, 23 ADVANCES CONSUMER RES. 196, 196 (1996).
    • (1996) Advances Consumer Res. , vol.23 , pp. 196
    • Laroche, M.1
  • 298
    • 79955938396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the case of motor vehicle idling, it was once considered more costeffective to idle for a period of time before driving or while waiting. See Carrico et al., supra note 111, at 2882. With improvements in modern fuel-injection engines, that is no longer the case
    • In the case of motor vehicle idling, it was once considered more costeffective to idle for a period of time before driving or while waiting. See Carrico et al., supra note 111, at 2882. With improvements in modern fuel-injection engines, that is no longer the case.
  • 299
    • 79955936845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. However, many individuals are acting based on outdated information and old habits
    • See id. However, many individuals are acting based on outdated information and old habits.
  • 300
    • 79955941207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 301
    • 79955941501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of this technology, see id. at 2887
    • For a discussion of this technology, see id. at 2887.
  • 303
    • 79955936762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 3
    • See id. at 3.
  • 304
    • 79955931178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2
    • See id. at 2.
  • 305
    • 79955935728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 18-23
    • See id. at 18-23.
  • 306
    • 79955940952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2
    • See id. at 2.
  • 307
    • 79955929921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 308
    • 84991195081 scopus 로고
    • Using cognitive dissonance to encourage water conservation
    • See, 852
    • See Chris Ann Dickerson et al., Using Cognitive Dissonance to Encourage Water Conservation, 22 J. APPLIED SOC. PSYCHOL. 841, 852 (1992);
    • (1992) J. Applied Soc. Psychol. , vol.22 , pp. 841
    • Dickerson, C.A.1
  • 309
    • 0039625860 scopus 로고
    • Cognitive dissonance and energy conservation
    • 421
    • S. J. Kantola et al., Cognitive Dissonance and Energy Conservation, 69 J. APPLIED PSYCHOL. 416, 421 (1984).
    • (1984) J. Applied Psychol. , vol.69 , pp. 416
    • Kantola, S.J.1
  • 310
    • 79955933098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dickerson et al., supra note 201, at 841
    • See Dickerson et al., supra note 201, at 841.
  • 311
    • 85011640363 scopus 로고
    • Comparing the effects of monetary incentives and foot-in-the-door strategies in promoting residential electricity conservation
    • 24-25
    • See Richard D. Katzev & Theodore R. Johnson, Comparing the Effects of Monetary Incentives and Foot-in-the-Door Strategies in Promoting Residential Electricity Conservation, 14 J. APPL. SOC. PSYCHOL. 12, 24-25 (1984);
    • (1984) J. Appl. Soc. Psychol. , vol.14 , pp. 12
    • Katzev, R.D.1    Johnson, T.R.2
  • 312
  • 313
    • 79955932927 scopus 로고
    • Ask the experts: Monthly pledge systems-a fundraising idea for nonprofits?
    • See, May-June, 4-5 explaining how monthly pledge systems can be easily set up and provide significant increases in revenue and core donor involvement
    • See Elizabeth G. Warner, Ask the Experts: Monthly Pledge Systems-A Fundraising Idea for Nonprofits?, NONPROFIT WORLD, May-June, 1994, 4, 4-5 (explaining how monthly pledge systems can be easily set up and provide significant increases in revenue and core donor involvement).
    • (1994) Nonprofit World , pp. 4
    • Warner, E.G.1
  • 314
    • 58149409999 scopus 로고
    • Feedback as a means of decreasing residential energy consumption
    • 366-67
    • See Clive Seligman & John M. Darley, Feedback as a Means of Decreasing Residential Energy Consumption, 62 J. APPLIED PSYCHOL. 363, 366-67 (1977).
    • (1977) J. Applied Psychol. , vol.62 , pp. 363
    • Seligman, C.1    Darley, J.M.2
  • 315
    • 79955930857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion supra Part II. A.2.b
    • See discussion supra Part II. A.2.b.
  • 316
    • 79955929118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OIRA has recently noted the importance of understanding the effects of informational regulatory tools on subpopulations. For example, it has noted that with regard to default rules it may be important for agencies to "distinguish among, and to suit the diverse situations of, members of the affected group. For example, geographic or demographic information such as age might be taken into account if it helps to increase the likelihood that the default rule will be suited to the situations of those to whom it applies."
    • OIRA has recently noted the importance of understanding the effects of informational regulatory tools on subpopulations. For example, it has noted that with regard to default rules it may be important for agencies to "distinguish among, and to suit the diverse situations of, members of the affected group. For example, geographic or demographic information (such as age) might be taken into account if it helps to increase the likelihood that the default rule will be suited to the situations of those to whom it applies."
  • 317
    • 79955929846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 5, at 11
    • OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 11.
    • (2010) Oira Disclosure Memo
  • 318
    • 0003937621 scopus 로고
    • Socio-ecological frameworks have been relied upon by researchers working in the areas of developmental psychology, community psychology, health psychology, and public health. See, e.g., applying an ecological framework to the field of developmental psychology. For an example in public health literature applying an ecological framework in identifying environmental influences on physical activity
    • Socio-ecological frameworks have been relied upon by researchers working in the areas of developmental psychology, community psychology, health psychology, and public health. See, e.g., URIE BRONFENBRENNER, THE ECOLOGY OF HUMAN DEVELOPMENT (1979) (applying an ecological framework to the field of developmental psychology). For an example in public health literature applying an ecological framework in identifying environmental influences on physical activity
    • (1979) The Ecology of Human Development
    • Urie, B.1
  • 319
    • 33645802201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An ecological approach to creating active living communities
    • see James F. Sallis et al., An Ecological Approach to Creating Active Living Communities, 27 ANN. REV. PUB. HEALTH 297 (2006).
    • (2006) Ann. Rev. Pub. Health , vol.27 , pp. 297
    • Sallis, J.F.1
  • 320
    • 79955940132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., supra note 208, describing his conceptual framework as "a set of nested structures, each inside the next, like a set of Russian dolls"
    • See, e.g., BRONFENBRENNER, supra note 208, at 3-4 (describing his conceptual framework as "a set of nested structures, each inside the next, like a set of Russian dolls").
    • Bronfenbrenner , pp. 3-4
  • 321
    • 79955930001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 322
    • 79955934412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 177-79 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 177-79 and accompanying text.
  • 323
    • 79955938245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congestion mitigation and air quality (CMAQ) improvement program
    • See, e.g., last modified Sept. 22, 2009 discussing the traffic-grant program, which includes guidelines limiting spending to areas such as carpooling that have high-technical potential but low-behavioral plasticity
    • See, e.g., Congestion Mitigation and Air Quality (CMAQ) Improvement Program, FED. HIGHWAY ADMIN., http://www.fhwa.dot.gov/environment/cmaqpgs/(last modified Sept. 22, 2009) (discussing the traffic-grant program, which includes guidelines limiting spending to areas such as carpooling that have high-technical potential but low-behavioral plasticity).
    • Fed. Highway Admin.
  • 325
    • 79955942464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commissioner Rosch's really weak case for "Behavioral Antitrust, "
    • see, July 16, 12:46 PM
    • see Geoffrey Manne, Commissioner Rosch's Really Weak Case for "Behavioral Antitrust, " TRUTH ON MARKET (July 16, 2010, 12:46 PM), http://truthonthemarket.com/2010/07/16/commissioner-roschs-really-weak-case-for- behavioral-antitrust/.
    • (2010) Truth on Market
    • Manne, G.1
  • 326
    • 79955937265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, Feb, available at, describing incentives for small businesses to switch to automatic enrollment of employees in 401 k plans, with opt-out provisions
    • See also EMP. BENEFITS SEC. ADMIN., U. S. DEP'T OF LABOR & IRS, AUTOMATIC ENROLLMENT 401 (K) PLANS FOR SMALL BUSINESSES 3 (Feb. 2010), available at http://www.dol.gov/ebsa/pdf/automaticenrollment401kplans.pdf (describing incentives for small businesses to switch to automatic enrollment of employees in 401 (k) plans, with opt-out provisions);
    • (2010) Emp. Benefits Sec. Admin., U. S. Dep'T of Labor & Irs, Automatic Enrollment 401 (K) Plans For Small Businesses , pp. 3
  • 327
    • 0002025043 scopus 로고
    • Status quo bias in decision making
    • 26-31, identifying status quo bias in health insurance purchases
    • William Samuelson & Richard Zeckhauser, Status Quo Bias in Decision Making, 1 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 7, 26-31 (1988) (identifying status quo bias in health insurance purchases);
    • (1988) J. Risk & Uncertainty , vol.1 , pp. 7
    • Samuelson, W.1    Zeckhauser, R.2
  • 328
    • 79955942043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Obama outlines new initiatives intended to make it easier to save for retirement
    • Sept. 6
    • Edmund L. Andrews, Obama Outlines New Initiatives Intended to Make It Easier to Save for Retirement, N. Y. TIMES, Sept. 6, 2009, at A20
    • (2009) N. Y. Times
    • Andrews, E.L.1
  • 329
    • 79955939809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • available at, In this Part, we apply the monetary and social prongs of our proposed framework to electric car recharging and tankless water heater purchases, but in the interest of brevity we do not apply a social ecological framework to these actions
    • available at 2009 WL 17481341. In this Part, we apply the monetary and social prongs of our proposed framework to electric car recharging and tankless water heater purchases, but in the interest of brevity we do not apply a social ecological framework to these actions.
    • (2009) WL , pp. 17481341
  • 330
    • 77954302161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Powering the planet, keynote speech at the california clean innovation conference
    • See, May 11, in, 19 2007 "Lowering demand... is going to pay off much sooner than clean energy supplies."
    • See Nathan S. Lewis, Powering the Planet, Keynote Speech at the California Clean Innovation Conference (May 11, 2007), in 2 ENGINEERING & SCI. 12, 19 (2007) ("[L]owering demand... is going to pay off much sooner than clean energy supplies.");
    • (2007) Engineering & Sci. , vol.2 , pp. 12
    • Lewis, N.S.1
  • 331
    • 4043100553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stabilization wedges: Solving the climate problem for the next 50 years with current technologies
    • 969, "Improvements in efficiency and conservation probably offer the greatest potential."
    • S. Pacala & R. Socolow, Stabilization Wedges: Solving the Climate Problem for the Next 50 Years with Current Technologies, 305 SCIENCE 968, 969 (2004) ("Improvements in efficiency and conservation probably offer the greatest potential....").
    • (2004) Science , vol.305 , pp. 968
    • Pacala, S.1    Socolow, R.2
  • 333
    • 77749298865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The residential sector. offers a slightly disproportionate thirtyfive percent of the end-use efficiency potential."
    • HANNAH CHOI GRANADE ET AL., MCKINSEY & CO., UNLOCKING ENERGY EFFICIENCY IN THE U. S. ECONOMY 10 (2009) ("The residential sector... offers a slightly disproportionate thirtyfive percent of the end-use efficiency potential.").
    • (2009) Mckinsey & Co., Unlocking Energy Efficiency in the U. S. Economy , pp. 10
    • Granade, H.C.1
  • 335
    • 51349139960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The short list: The most effective actions U. S. households can take to curb climate change
    • 2008, 16
    • Gerald T. Gardner & Paul C. Stern, The Short List: The Most Effective Actions U. S. Households Can Take to Curb Climate Change, 50 ENVIRONMENT, no. 5, 2008 at 12, 16;
    • Environment , vol.50 , Issue.5 , pp. 12
    • Gardner, G.T.1    Stern, P.C.2
  • 337
    • 79955929597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dietz et al., supra note 33, at 18, 452
    • Dietz et al., supra note 33, at 18, 452.
  • 338
    • 79955936530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 18, 452-53
    • Id. at 18, 452-53.
  • 339
    • 79955932674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BRESSAND et AL., supra note 215, at 57
    • See BRESSAND et AL., supra note 215, at 57;
  • 340
    • 79955931177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allcott & Mullainathan, supra note 6, at 1204-05
    • Allcott & Mullainathan, supra note 6, at 1204-05;
  • 341
    • 53349095845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Individual carbon emissions: The low-hanging fruit
    • 1758
    • Michael P. Vandenbergh et al., Individual Carbon Emissions: The Low-Hanging Fruit, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1701, 1758 (2008).
    • (2008) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 1701
    • Vandenbergh, M.P.1
  • 342
    • 79955929768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a summary of the household energy efficiency measures in the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115, which incorporates the Energy Improvement and Extension Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343
    • For a summary of the household energy efficiency measures in the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115, which incorporates the Energy Improvement and Extension Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343, 122 Stat. 3807
    • Stat , vol.122 , pp. 3807
  • 344
    • 0036522557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bridging environmental science with environmental policy: Plasticity of population, affluence, and technology
    • See, 31, "Plasticity is a tool for bridging science with policy."
    • See Richard York et al., Bridging Environmental Science with Environmental Policy: Plasticity of Population, Affluence, and Technology, 83 SOC. SCI. Q. 18, 31 (2002) ("Plasticity is a tool for bridging science with policy.").
    • (2002) Soc. Sci. Q , vol.83 , pp. 18
    • York, R.1
  • 345
    • 79955939645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vandenbergh et al., supra note 141, at 10, 551
    • See Vandenbergh et al., supra note 141, at 10, 551.
  • 346
    • 79955929678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Too much of the discussion to date has focused on behaviors that have high-technical potential but low plasticity, such as shifting from individually driven cars to carpooling. See Dietz et al., supra note 33, at 18, 453
    • Too much of the discussion to date has focused on behaviors that have high-technical potential but low plasticity, such as shifting from individually driven cars to carpooling. See Dietz et al., supra note 33, at 18, 453.
  • 347
    • 79955931625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra Part III. A and Part III. B
    • See discussion infra Part III. A and Part III. B.
  • 348
    • 79955938165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Vandenbergh et al., supra note 141, at 10, 551
    • Cf. Vandenbergh et al., supra note 141, at 10, 551.
  • 351
    • 79955940055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELGOWAINY et AL., supra note 226, at 7
    • See ELGOWAINY et AL., supra note 226, at 7;
  • 352
    • 79955940455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MCCARTHY et AL., supra note 227, at 7
    • MCCARTHY et AL., supra note 227, at 7;
  • 354
    • 79955936763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., noting the importance of recharging time for capacity and other impacts
    • See, e.g., BETTINA KAMPMAN ET AL., CE DELFT, GREEN POWER FOR ELECTRIC CARS 41-42 (2010) (noting the importance of recharging time for capacity and other impacts);
    • (2010) Ce Delft, Green Power For Electric Cars , pp. 41-42
    • Kampman, B.1
  • 356
    • 79955933248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 152, 13, 156 Mar. 26, to be codified at 18 C. F. R. ch. 1 "If charging takes place during peak periods it could require a large investment in new generation, demand response resources and/or transmission capacity to meet the resulting higher peak loads. However, charging off-peak could actually improve the operation of the electric system, for example by improving existing generation asset utilization or by providing an electricity storage solution to address the potential for over-generation by variable resources in off-peak periods."
    • See, e.g., Smart Grid Policy, 74 Fed. Reg. 13, 152, 13, 156 (Mar. 26, 2009) (to be codified at 18 C. F. R. ch. 1) ("If charging takes place during peak periods it could require a large investment in new generation, demand response resources and/or transmission capacity to meet the resulting higher peak loads. However, charging off-peak could actually improve the operation of the electric system, for example by improving existing generation asset utilization or by providing an electricity storage solution to address the potential for over-generation by variable resources in off-peak periods.").
    • (2009) Fed. Reg , vol.74 , pp. 13
    • Policy, S.G.1
  • 357
    • 79955937601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Table 1 is based on data presented in, &, 48-50, The regions identified in the left-hand column of the table are as follows: ECAR-East Central Area Reliability Coordination Agreement; ERCOT-Electric Reliability Council of Texas; MAAC-Mid-Atlantic Area Council; MAIN-Mid-America Interconnected Network; MAPP-Mid-Continent Area Power Pool; NPCC-NY-Northeast Power Coordinating Council/NY; NPCC-NE-Northeast Power Coordinating Council/New England; FRCC-Florida Reliability Coordinating Council; SERC-Southeastern Electric Reliability Council; SPP-Southwest Power Pool; WECC-NW-Western Electricity Coordinating Council/Northwest Power Pool Area; WECC-RMP/ANM-Western Electricity Coordinating Council/Rocky Mountain Power Area and Arizona-New Mexico-Southern Nevada Power Area; WECC-CA-Western Electricity Coordinating Council/California
    • Table 1 is based on data presented in STANTON W. HADLEY & ALEXANDRA TSVETKOVA, OAK RIDGE NAT'L LAB., POTENTIAL IMPACTS OF PLUG-IN HYBRID ELECTRIC VEHICLES ON REGIONAL POWER GENERATION 18-19, 48-50 (2008). The regions identified in the left-hand column of the table are as follows: ECAR-East Central Area Reliability Coordination Agreement; ERCOT-Electric Reliability Council of Texas; MAAC-Mid-Atlantic Area Council; MAIN-Mid-America Interconnected Network; MAPP-Mid-Continent Area Power Pool; NPCC-NY-Northeast Power Coordinating Council/NY; NPCC-NE-Northeast Power Coordinating Council/New England; FRCC-Florida Reliability Coordinating Council; SERC-Southeastern Electric Reliability Council; SPP-Southwest Power Pool; WECC-NW-Western Electricity Coordinating Council/Northwest Power Pool Area; WECC-RMP/ANM-Western Electricity Coordinating Council/Rocky Mountain Power Area and Arizona-New Mexico-Southern Nevada Power Area; WECC-CA-Western Electricity Coordinating Council/California.
    • (2008) Oak Ridge Nat'L Lab., Potential Impacts of Plug-In Hybrid Electric Vehicles on Regional Power Generation , pp. 18-19
    • Stanton, W.H.1    Alexandra, T.2
  • 358
    • 0003621959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at xiv, xvi fig. ES-1 noting that the regions are as specified by the Energy Information Administration in the
    • See id. at xiv, xvi fig. ES-1 (noting that the regions are as specified by the Energy Information Administration in the Annual Energy Outlook 2007).
    • (2007) Annual Energy Outlook
  • 359
    • 79955931020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do you own an electric vehicle
    • See, e.g., EV?, last visited Nov. 29, 2010 offering time-of-use rates for electric vehicle users
    • See, e.g., Do You Own an Electric Vehicle (EV)?, S. CAL. EDISON, http://www.sce.com/CustomerService/rates/residential/electric-vehicles.htm (last visited Nov. 29, 2010) (offering time-of-use rates for electric vehicle users);
    • S. Cal. Edison
  • 360
    • 79955931176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Residential electric vehicle services
    • last visited Nov. 29, 2010 offering a discounted rate for off-peak electric vehicle charging
    • Residential Electric Vehicle Services, L. A. DEP'T WATER & POWER, http://www.ladwp.com/ladwp/cms/ladwp002056.jsp (last visited Nov. 29, 2010) (offering a discounted rate for off-peak electric vehicle charging).
    • L. A. Dep'T Water & Power
  • 361
    • 79955930337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., EV?, supra note 232 using such a strategy
    • See, e.g., Do You Own an Electric Vehicle (EV)?, supra note 232 (using such a strategy).
    • Do You Own An Electric Vehicle
  • 362
    • 79955935968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., HADLEY & TSVETKOVA, supra note 231, at 23 concluding that "simple time-of-day charging could easily place all end-of-day charging requirements into peak periods"
    • See, e.g., HADLEY & TSVETKOVA, supra note 231, at 23 (concluding that "simple time-of-day charging could easily place all end-of-day charging requirements into peak periods").
  • 363
    • 79955943483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. noting the potential for "smart chargers"
    • See, e.g., id. (noting the potential for "smart chargers");
  • 364
    • 79955938768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PARKS et AL., supra note 229, at 8 discussing use of timing devices to move charging to offpeak hours
    • PARKS et AL., supra note 229, at 8 (discussing use of timing devices to move charging to offpeak hours).
  • 365
    • 79955930148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 276-77
    • Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 276-77.
  • 366
    • 79955934340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 278-81 discussing the use of immediate feedback on motor vehicle and residential energy use
    • See id. at 278-81 (discussing the use of immediate feedback on motor vehicle and residential energy use).
  • 367
    • 79955930936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FARUQUI & WOOD, supra note 12, at 21 suggesting both that consumers are often satisfied after being introduced to variable pricing due to greater savings and that greater education prior to implementation may help consumers to adopt such pricing schemes
    • See FARUQUI & WOOD, supra note 12, at 21 (suggesting both that consumers are often satisfied after being introduced to variable pricing due to greater savings and that greater education prior to implementation may help consumers to adopt such pricing schemes);
  • 368
    • 79955928786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behr, supra note 96 discussing troubles with recent Maryland variable pricing and its smart meter initiative
    • Behr, supra note 96 (discussing troubles with recent Maryland variable pricing and its smart meter initiative);
  • 369
    • 77953685988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The effect of utility time-varying pricing and load control strategies on residential summer peak electricity use: A review
    • see also, &, 3294-95, concluding that the effectiveness of variable pricing schemes may be improved by targeting consumers more likely to respond to such schemes and by offering them greater support services
    • see also Guy R. Newsham & Brent G. Bowker, The Effect of Utility Time-Varying Pricing and Load Control Strategies on Residential Summer Peak Electricity Use: A Review, 38 ENERGY POL'Y 3289, 3294-95 (2010) (concluding that the effectiveness of variable pricing schemes may be improved by targeting consumers more likely to respond to such schemes and by offering them greater support services).
    • (2010) Energy Pol'Y , vol.38 , pp. 3289
    • Newsham, G.R.1    Bowker, B.G.2
  • 370
    • 79955931942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behr, supra note 96 discussing troubles with even less intrusive efforts
    • Behr, supra note 96 (discussing troubles with even less intrusive efforts).
  • 371
    • 79955930935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kempton et al., supra note 128, at 190
    • Kempton et al., supra note 128, at 190;
  • 372
    • 0034581774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Programmable thermostats that go berserk? Taking a social perspective on space heating in Wisconsin 8.233, 8.241
    • see also, &, Paper presented at Aug. 23-28, available at, noting that a large proportion of individuals interviewed were not interested in using the programmable features of their thermostat, and many considered these features to be a hassle
    • see also Monica J. Nevius & Scott Pigg, Programmable Thermostats That Go Berserk? Taking a Social Perspective on Space Heating in Wisconsin 8.233, 8.241, Paper presented at the American Council for Energy-Efficient Economy Summer Study on Energy Efficiency in Buildings: Washington DC (Aug. 23-28, 2000), available at http://www.ecw.org/ecwresults/berserk.pdf (noting that a large proportion of individuals interviewed were not interested in using the programmable features of their thermostat, and many considered these features to be a hassle).
    • (2000) The American Council For Energy-Efficient Economy Summer Study on Energy Efficiency in Buildings: Washington Dc
    • Nevius, M.J.1    Pigg, S.2
  • 373
    • 79955932494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Stern, supra note 46, at 208-09 discussing empirical studies of how consumers implicitly discount future values
    • Cf. Stern, supra note 46, at 208-09 (discussing empirical studies of how consumers implicitly discount future values).
  • 374
    • 79955940672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 278-82 discussing the effectiveness of feedback techniques on behavior
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 278-82 (discussing the effectiveness of feedback techniques on behavior).
  • 375
    • 79955942463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 276-77 discussing the effectiveness of information to promote proenvironmental behavior
    • See id. at 276-77 (discussing the effectiveness of information to promote proenvironmental behavior).
  • 376
    • 79955938848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ayres et al., supra note 163, at 14-15
    • Ayres et al., supra note 163, at 14-15.
  • 377
    • 79955939976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. concluding that such information changed behavior in other energy-saving contexts
    • See id. (concluding that such information changed behavior in other energy-saving contexts).
  • 378
    • 79955937511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gneezy & Rustichini, supra note 173, at 15-16 cautioning that the production of information to consumers does not always have the intended consequences on behavior
    • See Gneezy & Rustichini, supra note 173, at 15-16 (cautioning that the production of information to consumers does not always have the intended consequences on behavior).
  • 379
    • 79955934113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Newsham & Bowker, supra note 238, at 3294-95 arguing that similarly targeted strategies have worked to change the behavior of these kinds of people
    • See Newsham & Bowker, supra note 238, at 3294-95 (arguing that similarly targeted strategies have worked to change the behavior of these kinds of people).
  • 380
    • 79955939168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 456 noting that framing a problem in terms of loss is more likely to change behavior
    • See Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 456 (noting that framing a problem in terms of loss is more likely to change behavior).
  • 381
    • 79955937863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 275-76 discussing the successful use of commitment techniques to alter behavior
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 275-76 (discussing the successful use of commitment techniques to alter behavior).
  • 382
    • 79955934496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stern, supra note 134, at 468 discussing the success of such incentives in inducing consumers to invest in their homes
    • Stern, supra note 134, at 468 (discussing the success of such incentives in inducing consumers to invest in their homes).
  • 383
    • 79955940600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. cautioning that such barriers can prevent acting on socially desirable behaviors
    • Id. (cautioning that such barriers can prevent acting on socially desirable behaviors).
  • 384
    • 79955936610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 467-68 noting that credibility can be an important factor in getting behavior to change
    • Id. at 467-68 (noting that credibility can be an important factor in getting behavior to change).
  • 385
    • 79955943482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This includes principles of product marketing as well as social marketing. For a detailed discussion of the utility of social marketing techniques, see, supra note 6
    • This includes principles of product marketing as well as social marketing. For a detailed discussion of the utility of social marketing techniques, see MCKENZIE-MOHR & SMITH, supra note 6, at 82-92.
    • Mckenzie-Mohr & Smith , pp. 82-92
  • 386
    • 79955928865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of nonmonetary factors in encouraging participation on home efficiency incentive programs, including issues such as trust and credibility, see Stern, supra note 134, at 467-68
    • For a discussion of nonmonetary factors in encouraging participation on home efficiency incentive programs, including issues such as trust and credibility, see Stern, supra note 134, at 467-68
  • 388
    • 0019365646 scopus 로고
    • Diffusion of energy-conserving innovations
    • 159-66, discussing the role of social networks in one's decision to adopt certain technologies
    • See John M. Darley & James R. Beniger, Diffusion of Energy-Conserving Innovations, 37 J. SOC. ISSUES 150, 159-66 (1981) (discussing the role of social networks in one's decision to adopt certain technologies).
    • (1981) J. Soc. Issues , vol.37 , pp. 150
    • Darley, J.M.1    Beniger, J.R.2
  • 389
    • 79955942909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fact, this is the case particularly when the incentive package is attractive. See, supra note 135
    • In fact, this is the case particularly when the incentive package is attractive. See Stern et al., Effectiveness of Incentives, supra note 135, at 162.
    • Effectiveness of Incentives , pp. 162
    • Stern1
  • 390
    • 79955942696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 160
    • Id. at 160.
  • 391
    • 79955941500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stern, supra note 46, at 208-09 discussing "anomalous" implications of consumer adoption decisions and offering possible explanations for such decisions
    • See Stern, supra note 46, at 208-09 (discussing "anomalous" implications of consumer adoption decisions and offering possible explanations for such decisions).
  • 392
    • 79955936060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Feiler & Soll, supra note 127, at 289 concluding that consumers ignore costs both when they are decoupled from benefits and when they are hard to keep track of
    • See Feiler & Soll, supra note 127, at 289 (concluding that consumers ignore costs both when they are decoupled from benefits and when they are hard to keep track of).
  • 393
    • 79955934341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 456
    • Tversky & Kahneman, supra note 63, at 456.
  • 394
    • 0000861536 scopus 로고
    • Psychological dimensions of global environmental change
    • See, 291
    • See Paul C. Stern, Psychological Dimensions of Global Environmental Change, 43 ANN. REV. PSYCHOL. 269, 291 (1992)
    • (1992) Ann. Rev. Psychol. , vol.43 , pp. 269
    • Stern, P.C.1
  • 395
    • 0039910428 scopus 로고
    • citing, Jan. 1, unpublished doctoral dissertation on file with University of California, Santa Cruz noting the past success of framing investment decisions in terms of loss avoidance in changing investment behavior
    • (citing S. Yates, Using Prospect Theory to Create Persuasive Communications About Solar Water Heaters and Insulation (Jan. 1, 1982) (unpublished doctoral dissertation) (on file with University of California, Santa Cruz)) (noting the past success of framing investment decisions in terms of loss avoidance in changing investment behavior).
    • (1982) Using Prospect Theory to Create Persuasive Communications About Solar Water Heaters and Insulation
    • Yates, S.1
  • 396
    • 79955930791 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 135
    • Stern et al., Design Principles, supra note 135, at 4848.
    • Design Principles , pp. 4848
    • Stern1
  • 397
    • 79955940601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 398
    • 79955928643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. noting the importance of low cognitive costs for effective household energy efficiency programs
    • See, e.g., id. (noting the importance of low cognitive costs for effective household energy efficiency programs).
  • 399
    • 79955943034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. id. indicating that the less consumers have to do to effectuate a program, the more likely it will be successful
    • Cf. id. (indicating that the less consumers have to do to effectuate a program, the more likely it will be successful).
  • 400
    • 0038382615 scopus 로고
    • An integrative theory of intergroup conflict
    • For work on social identity theory, see, &, in, 40-47 William G. Austin & Stephen Worchel eds.
    • For work on social identity theory, see Henry Tajfel & John Turner, An Integrative Theory of Intergroup Conflict, in SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY OF INTERGROUP RELATIONS 33, 40-47 (William G. Austin & Stephen Worchel eds., 1979).
    • (1979) Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations , pp. 33
    • Tajfel, H.1    Turner, J.2
  • 401
    • 0004107016 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., noting that people are more influenced by ingroups to which they categorize themselves as belonging, and engage in behavior that exemplifies those ingroup norms
    • See, e.g., JOHN C. TURNER, SOCIAL INFLUENCE 163 (1991) (noting that people are more influenced by ingroups to which they categorize themselves as belonging, and engage in behavior that exemplifies those ingroup norms).
    • (1991) Social Influence , pp. 163
    • Turner, J.C.1
  • 402
    • 79955941025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. noting that identification with an ingroup makes it more likely for an actor to behave in conformance with group norms
    • See id. (noting that identification with an ingroup makes it more likely for an actor to behave in conformance with group norms).
  • 403
    • 0346044952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social norms and social roles
    • See Cass R. Sunstein, Social Norms and Social Roles, 96 COLUM. L. REV. 903, 915 n. 41 (1996). (Pubitemid 126406323)
    • (1996) Columbia Law Review , vol.96 , Issue.4 , pp. 903
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 404
    • 79955929370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For work on normative messaging and its impact on behavior, see Goldstein et al., supra note 162, at 482
    • For work on normative messaging and its impact on behavior, see Goldstein et al., supra note 162, at 482;
  • 407
    • 79955931943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bowles, supra note 174, at 1605 arguing that economic incentives that induce selfishness can be counterproductive
    • See Bowles, supra note 174, at 1605 (arguing that economic incentives that induce selfishness can be counterproductive);
  • 408
    • 79955942910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gneezy & Rustichini, supra note 173, at 10 finding that when actors frame their actions in terms of economic consequences, they tend to act in ways that ignore the social consequences of those actions
    • Gneezy & Rustichini, supra note 173, at 10 (finding that when actors frame their actions in terms of economic consequences, they tend to act in ways that ignore the social consequences of those actions).
  • 409
    • 79955933324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 276 discussing the successful use of goal-setting techniques in changing behavior
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 276 (discussing the successful use of goal-setting techniques in changing behavior).
  • 410
    • 79955928948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II. A.2.b
    • See supra Part II. A.2.b.
  • 411
    • 79955932849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, providing normative information in energy bills led to a reduction in energy use even though levels of energy consumption could not be directly observed by one's peers. Ayres et al., supra note 163, at 14-15
    • For example, providing normative information in energy bills led to a reduction in energy use even though levels of energy consumption could not be directly observed by one's peers. Ayres et al., supra note 163, at 14-15.
  • 412
    • 79955938849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Vandenbergh, supra note 45, at 1105-06 suggesting that personal norms may influence behaviors in situations where peers do not observe the harmful behavior
    • See Vandenbergh, supra note 45, at 1105-06 (suggesting that personal norms may influence behaviors in situations where peers do not observe the harmful behavior).
  • 413
    • 84987344532 scopus 로고
    • The discovery of pluralistic ignorance: An ironic lesson
    • See, 333-35, discussing pluralistic ignorance and its potential effects
    • See Hubert J. O'Gorman, The Discovery of Pluralistic Ignorance: An Ironic Lesson, 22 J. HIST. BEHAV. SCI. 333, 333-35 (1986) (discussing pluralistic ignorance and its potential effects).
    • (1986) J. Hist. Behav. Sci. , vol.22 , pp. 333
    • O'Gorman, H.J.1
  • 414
    • 79955932928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 334
    • See id. at 334
  • 415
    • 79955935814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • citing analogous examples
    • (citing analogous examples).
  • 416
    • 1442331902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A cognitive dissonance interpretation of consistencies and inconsistencies in environmentally responsible behavior
    • 94
    • John Thogerson, A Cognitive Dissonance Interpretation of Consistencies and Inconsistencies in Environmentally Responsible Behavior, 24 J. ENVTL. PSYCHOL. 93, 94 (2004).
    • (2004) J. Envtl. Psychol. , vol.24 , pp. 93
    • Thogerson, J.1
  • 417
    • 79955939392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. id. indicating that individuals would prefer to act in conformance with such norms
    • Cf. id. (indicating that individuals would prefer to act in conformance with such norms).
  • 418
    • 79955935491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 275-76 discussing commitment strategies
    • See Abrahamse et al., supra note 88, at 275-76 (discussing commitment strategies).
  • 419
    • 79955932411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OIRA recently noted that it is important to use "scientifically valid experiments" along with market surveys and focus groups to test the effects of summary disclosure, and that "consultation with experts can also be a valuable supplement to focus group testing." 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 5
    • OIRA recently noted that it is important to use "[s]cientifically valid experiments" along with market surveys and focus groups to test the effects of summary disclosure, and that "[c]onsultation with experts can also be a valuable supplement to focus group testing." 2010 OIRA Disclosure Memo, supra note 5, at 5.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.