메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 122, Issue 6, 2009, Pages 1571-1633

Foreseeability and copyright incentives

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66049145259     PISSN: 0017811X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Conference Paper
Times cited : (78)

References (448)
  • 1
    • 84868951107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. CONST, art. I, § 8, cl. 8 authorizing Congress To promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries
    • See U.S. CONST, art. I, § 8, cl. 8 (authorizing Congress "To promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries");
  • 2
    • 0038628726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and a Democratic Civil Society, 106
    • To encourage authors to create and disseminate original expression, copyright law accords them a bundle of proprietary rights in their works
    • Neil Weinstock Netanel, Copyright and a Democratic Civil Society, 106 YALE L.J. 283, 285 (1996) ("To encourage authors to create and disseminate original expression, copyright law accords them a bundle of proprietary rights in their works.").
    • (1996) YALE L.J , vol.283 , pp. 285
    • Weinstock Netanel, N.1
  • 3
    • 0346403985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and Control over New Technologies of Dissemination, 101
    • For a discussion of new uses in the context of new technologies, see
    • For a discussion of new uses in the context of new technologies, see Jane C. Ginsburg, Copyright and Control over New Technologies of Dissemination, 101 COLUM. L. REV. 1613 (2001).
    • (2001) COLUM. L. REV , vol.1613
    • Ginsburg, J.C.1
  • 4
    • 66049103916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., BENJAMIN KAPLAN, AN UNHURRIED VIEW OF COPYRIGHT 101-25 (1967) (discussing the evolution of copyright in light of contemporary and future technologies);
    • See, e.g., BENJAMIN KAPLAN, AN UNHURRIED VIEW OF COPYRIGHT 101-25 (1967) (discussing the evolution of copyright in light of contemporary and future technologies);
  • 5
    • 66049109800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MARK ROSE, AUTHORS AND OWNERS: THE INVENTION OF COPYRIGHT 3-5 (1993) (discussing the emergence of copyright in the era of the printing press). Many prominent cases have faced the question of markets for new uses.
    • MARK ROSE, AUTHORS AND OWNERS: THE INVENTION OF COPYRIGHT 3-5 (1993) (discussing the emergence of copyright in the era of the printing press). Many prominent cases have faced the question of markets for new uses.
  • 6
    • 66049136292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417 (1984) (dealing with the video recorder);
    • See, e.g., Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417 (1984) (dealing with the video recorder);
  • 7
    • 66049102149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fortnightly Corp. v. United Artists Television, Inc., 392 U.S. 390 (1968) (dealing with cable retransmissions);
    • Fortnightly Corp. v. United Artists Television, Inc., 392 U.S. 390 (1968) (dealing with cable retransmissions);
  • 8
    • 66049111255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • White-Smith Music Publ'g Co. v. Apollo Co., 209 U.S. 1 (1908) (dealing with the market for piano rolls);
    • White-Smith Music Publ'g Co. v. Apollo Co., 209 U.S. 1 (1908) (dealing with the market for piano rolls);
  • 9
    • 66049159027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kelly v. Arriba Soft Corp., 336 F.3d 811 (9th Cir. 2003) (dealing with the market for thumbnails of copyrighted photographs);
    • Kelly v. Arriba Soft Corp., 336 F.3d 811 (9th Cir. 2003) (dealing with the market for thumbnails of copyrighted photographs);
  • 10
    • 66049133783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ty, Inc. v. Publ'ns Int'l Ltd., 292 F.3d 512 (7th Cir. 2002) (dealing with the photographic cataloging of plush toys);
    • Ty, Inc. v. Publ'ns Int'l Ltd., 292 F.3d 512 (7th Cir. 2002) (dealing with the photographic cataloging of plush toys);
  • 11
    • 66049101110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • UMG Recordings, Inc. v. MP3.com, Inc., 92 F. Supp. 2d 349 (S.D.N.Y. 2000) (dealing with the market for digital music). Perhaps the best known cases in the recent past include those filed against Google.
    • UMG Recordings, Inc. v. MP3.com, Inc., 92 F. Supp. 2d 349 (S.D.N.Y. 2000) (dealing with the market for digital music). Perhaps the best known cases in the recent past include those filed against Google.
  • 12
    • 66049133838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Complaint, McGraw-Hill Co. v. Google Inc., No. 05 CV 8881 (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 19, 2005);
    • See Complaint, McGraw-Hill Co. v. Google Inc., No. 05 CV 8881 (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 19, 2005);
  • 13
    • 66049150534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Complaint, Author's Guild v. Google Inc., No. 05 CV 8136 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 20, 2005). These two cases have been combined for the purposes of a provisional settlement agreement. Settlement Agreement, Author's Guild, No. 05 CV 8136-JES (Oct. 28, 2008), http://www.googlebooksettlement.com/Settlement- Agreement.pdf.
    • Complaint, Author's Guild v. Google Inc., No. 05 CV 8136 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 20, 2005). These two cases have been combined for the purposes of a provisional settlement agreement. Settlement Agreement, Author's Guild, No. 05 CV 8136-JES (Oct. 28, 2008), http://www.googlebooksettlement.com/Settlement- Agreement.pdf.
  • 14
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 101 2006, defining a derivative work
    • See 17 U.S.C. § 101 (2006) (defining a "derivative work").
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 15
    • 66049112048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Teleprompter Corp. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 415 U.S. 394 (1974);
    • See Teleprompter Corp. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 415 U.S. 394 (1974);
  • 16
  • 18
    • 64949144320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 2, at, noting courts' inconsistency in articulating a basis for these decisions
    • See Ginsburg, supra note 2, at 1619-26 (noting courts' inconsistency in articulating a basis for these decisions).
    • supra , pp. 1619-1626
    • Ginsburg1
  • 19
    • 33947720730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • section II.A, pp
    • See infra section II.A, pp. 1577-81.
    • See infra , pp. 1577-1581
  • 20
    • 66049117507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most prominent use of foreseeability has of course been in tort law. See KENNETH S. ABRAHAM, THE FORMS AND FUNCTIONS OF TORT LAW 125 (3d ed. 2007);
    • The most prominent use of foreseeability has of course been in tort law. See KENNETH S. ABRAHAM, THE FORMS AND FUNCTIONS OF TORT LAW 125 (3d ed. 2007);
  • 21
    • 84868951170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 3 FOWLER V. HARPER ET AL., THE LAW OF TORTS § 16.9, at 467 (2d ed. 1986);
    • 3 FOWLER V. HARPER ET AL., THE LAW OF TORTS § 16.9, at 467 (2d ed. 1986);
  • 22
    • 66049103436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leon Green, Foreseeability in Negligence Law, 61 COLUM. L. REV. 1401 (1961). For an analysis of its use in other contexts, see infra sections III.A.2-5, pp. 1597-1600.
    • Leon Green, Foreseeability in Negligence Law, 61 COLUM. L. REV. 1401 (1961). For an analysis of its use in other contexts, see infra sections III.A.2-5, pp. 1597-1600.
  • 23
    • 34548304404 scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court, 1083 Term - Foreword: The Court and the Economic System, 98
    • describing these as the ex post and ex ante perspectives, respectively, See
    • See Frank H. Easterbrook, The Supreme Court, 1083 Term - Foreword: The Court and the Economic System, 98 HARV. L. REV. 4, 10 (1984) (describing these as the "ex post" and "ex ante" perspectives, respectively).
    • (1984) HARV. L. REV , vol.4 , pp. 10
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 24
    • 66049148303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See A. MITCHELL POLINSKY, AN INTRODUCTION TO LAW AND ECONOMICS 130 (2d ed. 1989) (referring to this as the incentive question underlying a rule).
    • See A. MITCHELL POLINSKY, AN INTRODUCTION TO LAW AND ECONOMICS 130 (2d ed. 1989) (referring to this as the "incentive question" underlying a rule).
  • 25
    • 0242511031 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It remains common consensus among copyright scholars that the fair use doctrine, as it is structured and applied today, remains deeply flawed. See, e.g, Paul Goldstein, Fair Use in a Changing World, 50 J. COPYRIGHT SOC'Y U.S.A. 133, 133-34 (2003);
    • It remains common consensus among copyright scholars that the fair use doctrine - as it is structured and applied today - remains deeply flawed. See, e.g., Paul Goldstein, Fair Use in a Changing World, 50 J. COPYRIGHT SOC'Y U.S.A. 133, 133-34 (2003);
  • 26
    • 67650879725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keynote: Fair Use: Threat or Threatened?, 55
    • Wendy J. Gordon, Keynote: Fair Use: Threat or Threatened?, 55 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 903 (2005);
    • (2005) CASE W. RES. L. REV , vol.903
    • Gordon, W.J.1
  • 27
    • 66049119713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lydia Pallas Loren, Redefining the Market Failure Approach to Fair Use in an Era of Copyright Permission Systems, 5 J. INTELL. PROP. L. 1 (1997);
    • Lydia Pallas Loren, Redefining the Market Failure Approach to Fair Use in an Era of Copyright Permission Systems, 5 J. INTELL. PROP. L. 1 (1997);
  • 28
    • 0036811659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fair Use and Market Failure: Sony Revisited, 82
    • Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., Fair Use and Market Failure: Sony Revisited, 82 B.U. L. REV. 975 (2002);
    • (2002) B.U. L. REV , vol.975
    • Lunney Jr., G.S.1
  • 29
    • 33749125435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fairest of Them All and Other Fairy Tales of Fair Use
    • Winter/Spring, at
    • David Nimmer, "Fairest of Them All" and Other Fairy Tales of Fair Use, LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., Winter/Spring 2003, at 263;
    • (2003) LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS , pp. 263
    • Nimmer, D.1
  • 30
    • 34047182439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright As Trade Regulation, 155
    • Sara K. Stadler, Copyright As Trade Regulation, 155 U. PA. L. REV. 899 (2007).
    • (2007) U. PA. L. REV , vol.899
    • Stadler, S.K.1
  • 31
    • 66049116833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LEON E. SELTZER, EXEMPTIONS AND FAIR USE IN COPYRIGHT 24-25, 37-38 (1978) (identifying certain kinds of uses as intrinsic);
    • See LEON E. SELTZER, EXEMPTIONS AND FAIR USE IN COPYRIGHT 24-25, 37-38 (1978) (identifying certain kinds of uses as "intrinsic");
  • 32
    • 66049150535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra section II.B.2, pp. 1584-89.
    • infra section II.B.2, pp. 1584-89.
  • 33
    • 66049096169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the copyright-property linkage, see JAMES BOYLE, SHAMANS, SOFTWARE, AND SPLEENS: LAW AND THE CONSTRUCTION OF THE INFORMATION SOCIETY (1996);
    • For an overview of the copyright-property linkage, see JAMES BOYLE, SHAMANS, SOFTWARE, AND SPLEENS: LAW AND THE CONSTRUCTION OF THE INFORMATION SOCIETY (1996);
  • 34
    • 33748930422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and Incomplete Historiographies: Of Piracy, Propertization, and Thomas Jefferson, 79
    • and Justin Hughes, Copyright and Incomplete Historiographies: Of Piracy, Propertization, and Thomas Jefferson, 79 S. CAL. L. REV. 993, 1046-69 (2006).
    • (2006) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.993 , pp. 1046-1069
    • Hughes, J.1
  • 35
    • 66049094438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wendy J. Gordon, An Inquiry into the Merits of Copyright: The Challenges of Consistency, Consent, and Encouragement Theory, 41 STAN. L. REV. 1343, 1365-77 (1989). Some of these doctrines include: the idea-expression dichotomy, the originality requirement, the rule of fixation, and the temporally limited nature of the grant.
    • See Wendy J. Gordon, An Inquiry into the Merits of Copyright: The Challenges of Consistency, Consent, and Encouragement Theory, 41 STAN. L. REV. 1343, 1365-77 (1989). Some of these doctrines include: the idea-expression dichotomy, the originality requirement, the rule of fixation, and the temporally limited nature of the grant.
  • 36
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 101, 102, 302-05 2006
    • See 17 U.S.C. §§ 101, 102, 302-05 (2006).
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 37
    • 0001413547 scopus 로고
    • The Philosophy of Intellectual Property, 77
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Justin Hughes, The Philosophy of Intellectual Property, 77 GEO. L.J. 287 (1988);
    • (1988) GEO. L.J , vol.287
    • Hughes, J.1
  • 38
    • 66049153688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Linda J. Lacey, Of Bread and Roses and Copyrights, 1989 DUKE L.J. 1532;
    • Linda J. Lacey, Of Bread and Roses and Copyrights, 1989 DUKE L.J. 1532;
  • 39
    • 66049089659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alfred C. Yen, Restoring the Natural Law: Copyright As Labor and Possession, 51 OHIO ST. L.J. 517 (1990);
    • Alfred C. Yen, Restoring the Natural Law: Copyright As Labor and Possession, 51 OHIO ST. L.J. 517 (1990);
  • 40
    • 66049141761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barbara Friedman, Note, From Deontology to Dialogue: The Cultural Consequences of Copyright, 13 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 157 (1994).
    • Barbara Friedman, Note, From Deontology to Dialogue: The Cultural Consequences of Copyright, 13 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 157 (1994).
  • 41
    • 84868951165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, this instrumental mandate derives from copyright's constitutional origins. See U.S. CONST, art. I, § 8, cl. 8.
    • Indeed, this instrumental mandate derives from copyright's constitutional origins. See U.S. CONST, art. I, § 8, cl. 8.
  • 42
    • 66049135855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977);
    • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977);
  • 43
    • 0345704132 scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Antitrust Injury, 42
    • see
    • see Roger D. Blair & Jeffrey L. Harrison, Rethinking Antitrust Injury, 42 VAND. L. REV. 1539 (1989).
    • (1989) VAND. L. REV , vol.1539
    • Blair, R.D.1    Harrison, J.L.2
  • 44
    • 0038006406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fair Use Across Time, 50
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Justin Hughes, Fair Use Across Time, 50 UCLA L. REV. 775, 797 (2003);
    • (2003) UCLA L. REV , vol.775 , pp. 797
    • Hughes, J.1
  • 45
    • 2442485518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and Time: A Proposal, 101
    • Joseph P. Liu, Copyright and Time: A Proposal, 101 MICH. L. REV. 409, 428 (2002).
    • (2002) MICH. L. REV , vol.409 , pp. 428
    • Liu, J.P.1
  • 46
    • 0039866217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Stewart E. Sterk, Rhetoric and Reality in Copyright Law, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1197, 1198-1204 (1996) (describing the use of incentives rhetoric to justify copyright since its inception).
    • See generally Stewart E. Sterk, Rhetoric and Reality in Copyright Law, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1197, 1198-1204 (1996) (describing the use of incentives rhetoric to justify copyright since its inception).
  • 47
    • 66049157985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 13 (2003).
    • WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 13 (2003).
  • 48
    • 66049110267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19
    • Id. at 19.
  • 49
    • 84881815286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a concise discussion of these effects, see YOCHAI BENKLER, THE WEALTH OF NETWORKS: HOW SOCIAL PRODUCTION TRANSFORMS MARKETS AND FREEDOM 35-37 (2006).
    • For a concise discussion of these effects, see YOCHAI BENKLER, THE WEALTH OF NETWORKS: HOW SOCIAL PRODUCTION TRANSFORMS MARKETS AND FREEDOM 35-37 (2006).
  • 50
    • 66049090915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Niva Elkin-Koren, Copyright Policy and the Limits of Freedom of Contract, 12 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 93, 99-100 (1997);
    • See Niva Elkin-Koren, Copyright Policy and the Limits of Freedom of Contract, 12 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 93, 99-100 (1997);
  • 51
    • 84889906323 scopus 로고
    • Reconstructing the Fair Use Doctrine, 101
    • William W. Fisher III, Reconstructing the Fair Use Doctrine, 101 HARV. L. REV. 1659, 1702 (1988).
    • (1988) HARV. L. REV , vol.1659 , pp. 1702
    • Fisher III, W.W.1
  • 52
    • 66049130909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BENKLER, supra note 22, at 36-37
    • See BENKLER, supra note 22, at 36-37.
  • 53
    • 66049129624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LANDES & POSNER, supra note 20, at 20-21
    • LANDES & POSNER, supra note 20, at 20-21.
  • 54
    • 66049161002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kenneth J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in NAT'L BUREAU OF ECON. RESEARCH, THE RATE AND DIRECTION OF INVENTIVE ACTIVITY 609 (1962).
    • See Kenneth J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in NAT'L BUREAU OF ECON. RESEARCH, THE RATE AND DIRECTION OF INVENTIVE ACTIVITY 609 (1962).
  • 55
    • 66049100347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scholarly work in the copyright area has often focused on the tradeoff and attempted to determine the optimal amount of protection (principally through the idea of price discrimination) as a consequence of the tradeoff. See Fisher, supra note 23, at 1700-05 [T]o avoid underproduction of original works, it is necessary to empower the creators of such works to charge fees for the privilege of using them, but granting the creators that right causes monopoly losses, which vary between types of copyrighted works.
    • Scholarly work in the copyright area has often focused on the tradeoff and attempted to determine the optimal amount of protection (principally through the idea of price discrimination) as a consequence of the tradeoff. See Fisher, supra note 23, at 1700-05 ("[T]o avoid underproduction of original works, it is necessary to empower the creators of such works to charge fees for the privilege of using them, but granting the creators that right causes monopoly losses, which vary between types of copyrighted works."
  • 56
    • 66049140513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1703
    • Id. at 1703.);
  • 57
    • 0347740473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Unhurried View of Private Ordering in Information Transactions, 53
    • see also
    • see also Yochai Benkler, An Unhurried View of Private Ordering in Information Transactions, 53 VAND. L. REV. 2063 (2000);
    • (2000) VAND. L. REV. 2063
    • Benkler, Y.1
  • 58
    • 0347740474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cruel, Mean, or Lavish? Economic Analysis, Price Discrimination and Digital Intellectual Property, 53
    • James Boyle, Cruel, Mean, or Lavish? Economic Analysis, Price Discrimination and Digital Intellectual Property, 53 VAND. L. REV. 2007 (2000);
    • (2000) VAND. L. REV. 2007
    • Boyle, J.1
  • 59
    • 0346479828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and the Perfect Curve, 53
    • Julie E. Cohen, Copyright and the Perfect Curve, 53 VAND. L. REV. 1799 (2000);
    • (2000) VAND. L. REV , vol.1799
    • Cohen, J.E.1
  • 60
    • 0345986820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reexamining Copyright's Incentives-Access Paradigm, 49
    • Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., Reexamining Copyright's Incentives-Access Paradigm, 49 VAND. L. REV. 483 (1996);
    • (1996) VAND. L. REV , vol.483
    • Lunney Jr., G.S.1
  • 61
    • 0038685308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright Law and Price Discrimination, 23
    • Michael J. Meurer, Copyright Law and Price Discrimination, 23 CARDOZO L. REV. 55 (2001);
    • (2001) CARDOZO L. REV , vol.55
    • Meurer, M.J.1
  • 62
    • 21944443068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price Discrimination, Personal Use and Piracy: Copyright Protection of Digital Works, 45
    • Michael J. Meurer, Price Discrimination, Personal Use and Piracy: Copyright Protection of Digital Works, 45 BUFF. L. REV. 845, 869-76 (1997);
    • (1997) BUFF. L. REV , vol.845 , pp. 869-876
    • Meurer, M.J.1
  • 63
    • 66049094437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Louis Kaplow, The Patent-Antitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97 HARV. L. REV. 1813 (1984) (discussing the tradeoff in the patent law context).
    • cf. Louis Kaplow, The Patent-Antitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97 HARV. L. REV. 1813 (1984) (discussing the tradeoff in the patent law context).
  • 64
    • 74349128770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a clear statement of the endogenous version of the tradeoff that identifies incentives and access as the twin, progress-driven goals of the copyright system, see note 27, at, Not surprisingly, those who accept the tradeoff in exogenous terms remain less convinced of its centrality
    • For a clear statement of the endogenous version of the tradeoff that identifies incentives and access as the twin, progress-driven goals of the copyright system, see Cohen, supra note 27, at 1801. Not surprisingly, those who accept the tradeoff in exogenous terms remain less convinced of its centrality.
    • supra , pp. 1801
    • Cohen1
  • 65
    • 0039506176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jane C. Ginsburg, Authors and Users in Copyright, 45 J. COPYRIGHT SOC'Y U.S.A. 1 (1997).
    • See Jane C. Ginsburg, Authors and Users in Copyright, 45 J. COPYRIGHT SOC'Y U.S.A. 1 (1997).
  • 66
    • 66049087516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a sample of some economic literature debating this question, see WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS, INVENTION, GROWTH, AND WELFARE (1969), which argues that temporal limits best capture an incentives analysis.
    • For a sample of some economic literature debating this question, see WILLIAM D. NORDHAUS, INVENTION, GROWTH, AND WELFARE (1969), which argues that temporal limits best capture an incentives analysis.
  • 67
    • 34547759046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Complex Economics of
    • See also, Patent Scope, 90 COLUM. L. REV. 839 1990, arguing that incentives analysis necessitates limits on a patent's scope
    • See also Robert P. Merges & Richard R. Nelson, On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope, 90 COLUM. L. REV. 839 (1990) (arguing that incentives analysis necessitates limits on a patent's scope).
    • Merges, R.P.1    Nelson, R.R.2
  • 68
    • 66049128961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This phenomenon is often referred to as copyright's one-way ratchet. See Jessica Litman, War Stories, 20 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 337, 344 (2002);
    • This phenomenon is often referred to as copyright's "one-way ratchet." See Jessica Litman, War Stories, 20 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 337, 344 (2002);
  • 69
    • 34047113848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Incentive and Expectation in Copyright, 58
    • Sara K. Stadler, Incentive and Expectation in Copyright, 58 HASTINGS L.J. 433, 435 (2007);
    • (2007) HASTINGS L.J , vol.433 , pp. 435
    • Stadler, S.K.1
  • 70
    • 22744444521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copy This Essay: How Fair Use Doctrine Harms Free Speech and How Copying Serves It, 114
    • Rebecca Tushnet, Copy This Essay: How Fair Use Doctrine Harms Free Speech and How Copying Serves It, 114 YALE L.J. 535, 543 (2004);
    • (2004) YALE L.J , vol.535 , pp. 543
    • Tushnet, R.1
  • 71
    • 66049105597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Diane Leenheer Zimmerman, Adrift in the Digital Millennium Copyright Act: The Sequel, 26 U. DAYTON L. REV. 279, 290 (2001).
    • Diane Leenheer Zimmerman, Adrift in the Digital Millennium Copyright Act: The Sequel, 26 U. DAYTON L. REV. 279, 290 (2001).
  • 72
    • 66049130001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Litman, supra note 30, at 344
    • Litman, supra note 30, at 344.
  • 73
    • 66049148302 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 74
    • 66049121898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Netanel, supra note i, at 306-07. More recently, others have referred to this as the Dem-setzian turn in copyright law, a reference to the seminal work by Professor Harold Demsetz describing the evolution of ownership and property rights as mechanisms to minimize transaction costs and internalize both positive and negative externalities associated with certain actions.
    • Netanel, supra note i, at 306-07. More recently, others have referred to this as the "Dem-setzian" turn in copyright law, a reference to the seminal work by Professor Harold Demsetz describing the evolution of ownership and property rights as mechanisms to minimize transaction costs and internalize both positive and negative externalities associated with certain actions.
  • 75
    • 38049119794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brett M. Frischmann, Evaluating the Demsetzian Trend in Copyright Law, 3 REV. L. & ECON. 649 (2007). For a response by Professor Demsetz, see Harold Demsetz, Frischmann's View of Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 4 REV. L. & ECON. 127 (2008).
    • See Brett M. Frischmann, Evaluating the Demsetzian Trend in Copyright Law, 3 REV. L. & ECON. 649 (2007). For a response by Professor Demsetz, see Harold Demsetz, Frischmann's View of "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," 4 REV. L. & ECON. 127 (2008).
  • 76
    • 66049141328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 471 U.S. 539 (1985). In the twenty-four years since the decision, in excess of fifty federal courts have relied on Harper & Row's fair use analysis in one way or another. As Professor Fisher predicted a few years after the decision in relation to the Court's reliance on the theory of incentives, [t]he imprimatur of the majority opinion in Harper & Row will undoubtedly contribute to the currency and influence of the theory. Fisher, supra note 23, at 1689 (citation omitted).
    • 471 U.S. 539 (1985). In the twenty-four years since the decision, in excess of fifty federal courts have relied on Harper & Row's fair use analysis in one way or another. As Professor Fisher predicted a few years after the decision in relation to the Court's reliance on the theory of incentives, "[t]he imprimatur of the majority opinion in Harper & Row will undoubtedly contribute to the currency and influence of the theory." Fisher, supra note 23, at 1689 (citation omitted).
  • 77
    • 66049143601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 542-45.
    • Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 542-45.
  • 78
    • 66049150533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 557-59
    • Id. at 557-59.
  • 79
    • 66049151794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Court has, since then, used copyright's incentive structure purely as a rhetorical device on more than one instance. See, e.g., Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U.S. 186, 212 n. 18 (2003) ([C]opyright law serves public ends by providing individuals with an incentive to pursue private ones.);
    • The Court has, since then, used copyright's incentive structure purely as a rhetorical device on more than one instance. See, e.g., Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U.S. 186, 212 n. 18 (2003) ("[C]opyright law serves public ends by providing individuals with an incentive to pursue private ones.");
  • 80
    • 66049154655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569, 593 (1994) ([Substantial harm to [the market for derivatives] would weigh against a finding of fair use, because the licensing of derivatives is an important economic incentive to the creation of originals. (citation omitted)). To be sure, courts do occasionally treat the incentives-access tradeoff as a meaningful basis by which to-understand copyright's incentive structure, but these decisions are rare. A few notable examples include Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417 (1984);
    • Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569, 593 (1994) ("[Substantial harm to [the market for derivatives] would weigh against a finding of fair use, because the licensing of derivatives is an important economic incentive to the creation of originals." (citation omitted)). To be sure, courts do occasionally treat the incentives-access tradeoff as a meaningful basis by which to-understand copyright's incentive structure, but these decisions are rare. A few notable examples include Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417 (1984);
  • 81
    • 66049110266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Suntrust Bank v. Houghton Mifflin Co., 268 F.3d 1257 (nth Cir. 2001).
    • and Suntrust Bank v. Houghton Mifflin Co., 268 F.3d 1257 (nth Cir. 2001).
  • 82
    • 66049146190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ringgold v. Black Entm't Television, Inc., 126 F.3d 70, 73 (2d Cir. 1997) (In the absence of defenses, these exclusive rights normally give a copyright owner the right to seek royalties from others who wish to use the copyrighted work.);
    • See, e.g., Ringgold v. Black Entm't Television, Inc., 126 F.3d 70, 73 (2d Cir. 1997) ("In the absence of defenses, these exclusive rights normally give a copyright owner the right to seek royalties from others who wish to use the copyrighted work.");
  • 83
    • 84868940884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Am. Geophysical Union v. Texaco Inc., 60 F.3d 913, 929 (2d Cir. 1995) (It is indisputable that, as a general matter, a copyright holder is entitled to demand a royalty for licensing others to use its copyrighted work ⋯.);
    • Am. Geophysical Union v. Texaco Inc., 60 F.3d 913, 929 (2d Cir. 1995) ("It is indisputable that, as a general matter, a copyright holder is entitled to demand a royalty for licensing others to use its copyrighted work ⋯.");
  • 84
    • 84868951153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • D.C. Comics Inc. v. Reel Fantasy, Inc., 696 F.2d 24, 28 (2d Cir. 1982) ([O]ne of the benefits of ownership of copyrighted material is the right to license its use for a fee ⋯.).
    • D.C. Comics Inc. v. Reel Fantasy, Inc., 696 F.2d 24, 28 (2d Cir. 1982) ("[O]ne of the benefits of ownership of copyrighted material is the right to license its use for a fee ⋯.").
  • 85
    • 66049155097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Campbell, 510 U.S. at 598 (Kennedy, J., concurring);
    • See, e.g., Campbell, 510 U.S. at 598 (Kennedy, J., concurring);
  • 86
    • 66049106874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 557.
    • Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 557.
  • 87
    • 66049084854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By correlative here, I mean that the inquiry is done relationally, by reference to the plaintiff and the defendant. The idea of correlativity is generally used to describe tort law's entitlement structure, where liability is an attempt to connect the defendant's actions to the plaintiff's harm through the law's underlying normative goals. Professor Ernest Weinrib's account of correlativity is perhaps the most widely accepted exposition of the idea. See ERNEST J. WEINRIB, THE IDEA OF PRIVATE LAW (1995);
    • By "correlative" here, I mean that the inquiry is done relationally, by reference to the plaintiff and the defendant. The idea of correlativity is generally used to describe tort law's entitlement structure, where liability is an attempt to connect the defendant's actions to the plaintiff's harm through the law's underlying normative goals. Professor Ernest Weinrib's account of correlativity is perhaps the most widely accepted exposition of the idea. See ERNEST J. WEINRIB, THE IDEA OF PRIVATE LAW (1995);
  • 88
    • 66049161001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ernest J. Weinrib, Punishment and Disgorgement As Contract Remedies, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 55 (2003).
    • Ernest J. Weinrib, Punishment and Disgorgement As Contract Remedies, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 55 (2003).
  • 89
    • 77950303862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 19, at
    • See Sterk, supra note 19, at 1210-13 (1996).
    • (1996) supra , pp. 1210-1213
    • Sterk1
  • 90
    • 66049119240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Perris v. Hexamer, 99 U.S. 674, 675-76 (1879);
    • Perris v. Hexamer, 99 U.S. 674, 675-76 (1879);
  • 91
    • 84868940885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4 MELVILLE B. NIMMER & DAVID NIMMER, NIMMER ON COPYRIGHT § 13.01[B] (2007).
    • 4 MELVILLE B. NIMMER & DAVID NIMMER, NIMMER ON COPYRIGHT § 13.01[B] (2007).
  • 92
    • 84868940886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 8.01[A], at 8-15 ([A]bsent copying, there can be no infringement of copyright, regardless of the extent of similarity. (footnotes omitted)).
    • 2 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 8.01[A], at 8-15 ("[A]bsent copying, there can be no infringement of copyright, regardless of the extent of similarity." (footnotes omitted)).
  • 93
    • 84868946234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4 id. § 13.01[B], at 13-8 (noting that few courts or commentators have historically differentiated between the factual and normative dimensions of copying (footnote omitted)).
    • 4 id. § 13.01[B], at 13-8 (noting that "few courts or commentators have historically differentiated" between the factual and normative dimensions of copying (footnote omitted)).
  • 94
    • 66049118824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 13-9.
    • See id. at 13-9.
  • 95
    • 84868951152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBERT C. OSTERBERG & ERIC C. OSTERBERG, SUBSTANTIAL SIMILARITY IN COPYRIGHT LAW § 1:1, at 1-1 to -4 (2008).
    • ROBERT C. OSTERBERG & ERIC C. OSTERBERG, SUBSTANTIAL SIMILARITY IN COPYRIGHT LAW § 1:1, at 1-1 to -4 (2008).
  • 96
    • 66049124785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Country Kids 'N City Slicks, Inc. v. Sheen, 77 F.3d 1280, 1288 (10th Cir. 1996) (quoting Atari, Inc. v. N. Am. Philips Consumer Elecs. Corp., 672 F.2d 607, 614 (7th Cir. 1982)).
    • Country Kids 'N City Slicks, Inc. v. Sheen, 77 F.3d 1280, 1288 (10th Cir. 1996) (quoting Atari, Inc. v. N. Am. Philips Consumer Elecs. Corp., 672 F.2d 607, 614 (7th Cir. 1982)).
  • 97
    • 84868946235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OSTERBERG & OSTERBERG, supra note 46, § 1:1, at 1-2 (Substantial similarity is an elusive concept.);
    • See OSTERBERG & OSTERBERG, supra note 46, § 1:1, at 1-2 ("Substantial similarity is an elusive concept.");
  • 98
    • 66049132523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Peter Pan Fabrics, Inc. v. Martin Weiner Corp., 274 F.2d 487, 489 (2d Cir. 1960) (L. Hand, J.) (noting that the determination must inevitably be ad hoc).
    • see also Peter Pan Fabrics, Inc. v. Martin Weiner Corp., 274 F.2d 487, 489 (2d Cir. 1960) (L. Hand, J.) (noting that the determination must "inevitably be ad hoc").
  • 99
    • 84868951150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.03[A][1], at 13-36.
    • See 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.03[A][1], at 13-36.
  • 100
    • 84868940883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 13.03[A][2].
    • Id. § 13.03[A][2].
  • 101
    • 66049115515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 13-54. He notes that, as a consequence, the line between the two requirements often gets blurred.
    • Id. at 13-54. He notes that, as a consequence, the line between the two requirements often gets blurred.
  • 102
    • 66049154180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Nelson v. PRN Prods., Inc., 873 F.2d 1141, 1143 (8th Cir. 1989) (rejecting an attempt to conflate the two and alter the burden of proof).
    • But see Nelson v. PRN Prods., Inc., 873 F.2d 1141, 1143 (8th Cir. 1989) (rejecting an attempt to conflate the two and alter the burden of proof).
  • 103
    • 84868951151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OSTERBERG & OSTERBERG, supra note 46, § 2:1, at 2-1 (observing that substantial similarity always entails a comparison of the works).
    • See OSTERBERG & OSTERBERG, supra note 46, § 2:1, at 2-1 (observing that substantial similarity always entails a "comparison of the works").
  • 104
    • 66049097018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The substantial similarity requirement is applied even to derivative works, which by their very nature involve a different purpose, pointing to the general irrelevance of the purpose and use to which the work is put
    • The substantial similarity requirement is applied even to derivative works, which by their very nature involve a different purpose, pointing to the general irrelevance of the purpose and use to which the work is put.
  • 105
    • 84868946233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 15:1, at 15-1, 15-2 n. 2.
    • See id. § 15:1, at 15-1, 15-2 n. 2.
  • 106
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 107 (2006, In general terms the four factors are: (1) the purpose and character of the defendant's use; (2) the nature of the protected work; (3) the amount and substantiality of the portion of the work used; and (4) the impact of the defendant's actions on the actual and potential market for the protected work
    • See 17 U.S.C. § 107 (2006). In general terms the four factors are: (1) the purpose and character of the defendant's use; (2) the nature of the protected work; (3) the amount and substantiality of the portion of the work used; and (4) the impact of the defendant's actions on the actual and potential market for the protected work.
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 107
    • 66049113703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 108
    • 73849092129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 3, note 42, § 12.11[F
    • 3 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 12.11[F].
    • supra
    • NIMMER1    NIMMER2
  • 109
    • 66049116803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, if the defendant were not to raise the defense, courts would operate on the assumption that the plaintiff is entitled to control the market in which the defendant is operating. For a recent example, see Twentieth Century Fox Film Corp. v. Cablevision Systems Corp., 478 F. Supp. 2d 607 (S.D.N.Y. 2007). There, the defendant agreed not to raise the defense of fair use,
    • Thus, if the defendant were not to raise the defense, courts would operate on the assumption that the plaintiff is entitled to control the market in which the defendant is operating. For a recent example, see Twentieth Century Fox Film Corp. v. Cablevision Systems Corp., 478 F. Supp. 2d 607 (S.D.N.Y. 2007). There, the defendant agreed not to raise the defense of fair use,
  • 111
    • 66049131269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 616, 622.
    • See id. at 616, 622.
  • 112
    • 84868946232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interestingly, fair use originated as a common law doctrine, see Folsom v. Marsh, 9 F. Cas. 342 (1841, and was codified in the 1976 Copyright Act, 17 U.S.C. § 107 2006
    • Interestingly, fair use originated as a common law doctrine, see Folsom v. Marsh, 9 F. Cas. 342 (1841), and was codified in the 1976 Copyright Act, 17 U.S.C. § 107 (2006).
  • 113
    • 66049118359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dellar v. Samuel Goldwyn, Inc., 104 F.2d 661, 662 (2d Cir. 1939);
    • Dellar v. Samuel Goldwyn, Inc., 104 F.2d 661, 662 (2d Cir. 1939);
  • 114
    • 66049135085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 475 (Blackmun, J., dissenting).
    • see also Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 475 (Blackmun, J., dissenting).
  • 115
    • 66049109375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton Univ. Press v. Mich. Document Servs., Inc., 99 F.3d 1381, 1392 (6th Cir. 1996) (quoting Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F. Supp. 130, 144 (S.D.N.Y. 1968)) (internal quotation mark omitted).
    • Princeton Univ. Press v. Mich. Document Servs., Inc., 99 F.3d 1381, 1392 (6th Cir. 1996) (quoting Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F. Supp. 130, 144 (S.D.N.Y. 1968)) (internal quotation mark omitted).
  • 116
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1071
    • 17 U.S.C. § 107(1).
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 117
    • 39749110260 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Fair Use Standard, 103
    • Pierre N. Leval, Toward a Fair Use Standard, 103 HARV. L. REV. 1105, 1111 (1990).
    • (1990) HARV. L. REV , vol.1105 , pp. 1111
    • Leval, P.N.1
  • 118
    • 66049098274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. The Supreme Court endorsed Judge Leval's test in Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569 (1994), drawing a distinction between superseding and transformative uses of a work based on market substitution.
    • Id. The Supreme Court endorsed Judge Leval's test in Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569 (1994), drawing a distinction between superseding and transformative uses of a work based on market substitution.
  • 119
    • 33947409220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright and Public Good Economics: A Misunderstood Relation, 155
    • See generally
    • See generally Christopher S. Yoo, Copyright and Public Good Economics: A Misunderstood Relation, 155 U. PA. L. REV. 635, 711-12 (2007).
    • (2007) U. PA. L. REV , vol.635 , pp. 711-712
    • Yoo, C.S.1
  • 120
    • 66049160662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Second Circuit's decision in Castle Rock Entertainment v. Carol Publishing Group, Inc., 150 F.3d 132 (2d Cir. 1998), is aptly illustrative of this trend. In concluding that the defendant's use of the protected work, which involved creating an aptitude test centering around a well-known television series, was not a form of transformative use, the court concluded that the defendant had failed to discharge its burden of showing that its use involved a significant transformative purpose.
    • The Second Circuit's decision in Castle Rock Entertainment v. Carol Publishing Group, Inc., 150 F.3d 132 (2d Cir. 1998), is aptly illustrative of this trend. In concluding that the defendant's use of the protected work, which involved creating an aptitude test centering around a well-known television series, was not a form of transformative use, the court concluded that the defendant had failed to discharge its burden of showing that its use involved a significant "transformative purpose."
  • 123
    • 66049087518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Matt Williams, Recent Second Circuit Opinions Indicate that Google's Library Project Is Not Transformative, 25 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 303, 318 (2007) (arguing that the Supreme Court's decision in Campbell is necessarily restricted to such an examination).
    • See Matt Williams, Recent Second Circuit Opinions Indicate that Google's Library Project Is Not Transformative, 25 CARDOZO ARTS & ENT. L.J. 303, 318 (2007) (arguing that the Supreme Court's decision in Campbell is necessarily restricted to such an examination).
  • 124
    • 66049118793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This conclusion derives from the Court's emphasis in Campbell on the fact that the test is whether the defendant creates a new work [that] is 'transformative, by altering the first with new expression, meaning, or message. Campbell, 510 U.S. at 579 (quoting Leval, supra note 61, at 111);
    • This conclusion derives from the Court's emphasis in Campbell on the fact that the test is whether the defendant creates a "new work [that] is 'transformative,'" by "altering the first with new expression, meaning, or message." Campbell, 510 U.S. at 579 (quoting Leval, supra note 61, at 111);
  • 125
    • 66049109814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Stadler, supra note n, at 906-07 (noting how the Campbell Court intended the standard to apply only when a defendant takes expression from a copyrighted work and adds expression of her own);
    • see also Stadler, supra note n, at 906-07 (noting how the Campbell Court intended the standard to apply only when a defendant "takes expression from a copyrighted work and adds expression of her own");
  • 126
    • 84922574706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 63, at, Additionally, cases that have found the standard to have been satisfied seem to emphasize this fact
    • Williams, supra note 63, at 319-30. Additionally, cases that have found the standard to have been satisfied seem to emphasize this fact.
    • supra , pp. 319-330
    • Williams1
  • 128
    • 66049152589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bill Graham Archives v. Dorling Kindersley Ltd., 448 F.3d 60s (2d Cir. 2006). Two recent decisions of the Ninth Circuit, however, seem to have glossed over this requirement altogether. It is not clear that they apply the test as formulated in Campbell. See Perfect 10, Inc. v. Amazon.com, Inc., 487 F.3d 701 (9th Cir. 2007);
    • Bill Graham Archives v. Dorling Kindersley Ltd., 448 F.3d 60s (2d Cir. 2006). Two recent decisions of the Ninth Circuit, however, seem to have glossed over this requirement altogether. It is not clear that they apply the test as formulated in Campbell. See Perfect 10, Inc. v. Amazon.com, Inc., 487 F.3d 701 (9th Cir. 2007);
  • 129
    • 66049115502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kelly v. Arriba Soft Corp., 336 F.3d 811 (9th Cir. 2003);
    • Kelly v. Arriba Soft Corp., 336 F.3d 811 (9th Cir. 2003);
  • 130
    • 84868951148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also 4 WILLIAM F. PATRY, PATRY ON COPYRIGHT § 10:21, at 10-79 n-33 (2008) (characterizing the Kelly holding as novel and its reliance on public benefit as part of the transformative use test as perplexing);
    • see also 4 WILLIAM F. PATRY, PATRY ON COPYRIGHT § 10:21, at 10-79 n-33 (2008) (characterizing the Kelly holding as "novel" and its reliance on public benefit as part of the transformative use test as "perplexing");
  • 131
    • 29544438663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Justin Hughes, Size Matters (or Should) in Copyright Law, 74 FORDHAM L. REV. 575-619 n. 254 (2005) (noting that the Kelly decision sits uneasily with the Supreme Court's interpretation of transformative);
    • Justin Hughes, Size Matters (or Should) in Copyright Law, 74 FORDHAM L. REV. 575-619 n. 254 (2005) (noting that the Kelly decision "sits uneasily" with the Supreme Court's interpretation of "transformative");
  • 132
    • 66049154213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Williams, supra note 63, at 317-19 (characterizing the Kelly case as a misapplication).
    • Williams, supra note 63, at 317-19 (characterizing the Kelly case as a "misapplication").
  • 133
    • 66049122754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus, translations of a work from one language to another have been held insufficient to meet the standard. See, e.g., Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Inc. v. Comline Bus. Data, Inc., 166 F.3d 65, 72 (2d Cir. 1999). Converting a work from one media format to another is considered equally nontransformative.
    • Thus, translations of a work from one language to another have been held insufficient to meet the standard. See, e.g., Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Inc. v. Comline Bus. Data, Inc., 166 F.3d 65, 72 (2d Cir. 1999). Converting a work from one media format to another is considered equally nontransformative.
  • 134
    • 66049130003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Infinity Broadcast Corp. v. Kirkwood, 150 F.3d 104, 108 (2d Cir. 1998);
    • See, e.g., Infinity Broadcast Corp. v. Kirkwood, 150 F.3d 104, 108 (2d Cir. 1998);
  • 135
    • 66049099884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Hughes, supra note 64, at 619 n. 254 ([I]t is the work, not the distribution mechanism, that needs to be transformative.).
    • see also Hughes, supra note 64, at 619 n. 254 ("[I]t is the work, not the distribution mechanism, that needs to be transformative.").
  • 136
    • 66049101517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Jonathan Band, The Google Library Project: Both Sides of the Story, 1 PLAGIARY 1, 3-7 (2007) (describing Google's fair use argument in the actual litigation).
    • See generally Jonathan Band, The Google Library Project: Both Sides of the Story, 1 PLAGIARY 1, 3-7 (2007) (describing Google's fair use argument in the actual litigation).
  • 137
    • 66049132557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Williams, supra note 63, at 330-32
    • See Williams, supra note 63, at 330-32.
  • 138
    • 66049124752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wendy J. Gordon, Fair Use As Market Failure: A Structural and Economic Analysis of the Betamax Case and Its Predecessors, 82 Colum. L. REV. 1600 (1982) [hereinafter Gordon, Fair Use]. The dissenting opinion in Sony Corp. (arguing that the defendant's use was not fair use) relies on Gordon's article.
    • See Wendy J. Gordon, Fair Use As Market Failure: A Structural and Economic Analysis of the Betamax Case and Its Predecessors, 82 Colum. L. REV. 1600 (1982) [hereinafter Gordon, Fair Use]. The dissenting opinion in Sony Corp. (arguing that the defendant's use was not fair use) relies on Gordon's article.
  • 139
    • 66049126812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 478 (1984) (Blackmun, J., dissenting). More recently, Gordon has clarified her position.
    • See Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 478 (1984) (Blackmun, J., dissenting). More recently, Gordon has clarified her position.
  • 140
    • 0036812008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wendy J. Gordon, Market Failure and Intellectual Property: A Response to Professor Lunney, 82 B.U. L. REV. 1031 (2002).
    • See Wendy J. Gordon, Market Failure and Intellectual Property: A Response to Professor Lunney, 82 B.U. L. REV. 1031 (2002).
  • 141
    • 66049089628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gordon, Fair Use, supra note 68, at 1614-15;
    • Gordon, Fair Use, supra note 68, at 1614-15;
  • 142
    • 34250655779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robin A. Moore, Note, Fair Use and Innovation Policy, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 944, 950 (2007).
    • Robin A. Moore, Note, Fair Use and Innovation Policy, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 944, 950 (2007).
  • 143
    • 66049110242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gordon, Fair Use, supra note 68, at 1614
    • Gordon, Fair Use, supra note 68, at 1614.
  • 144
    • 84868940880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following is perhaps illustrative: New technologies will make certain copyrighted works more valuable ⋯. If copyright protection is denied because of an otherwise curable market failure, then the additional revenues that would have flowed from the new technological use will not appear. If the authors' revenues fail to reflect the additional value that new technology gives to such works, then insufficient resources may be drawn into their creation.
    • The following is perhaps illustrative: New technologies will make certain copyrighted works more valuable ⋯. If copyright protection is denied because of an otherwise curable market failure, then the additional revenues that would have flowed from the new technological use will not appear. If the authors' revenues fail to reflect the additional value that new technology gives to such works, then insufficient resources may be drawn into their creation.
  • 145
    • 66049138148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1621
    • Id. at 1621.
  • 146
    • 66049114475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hughes, note 18, at, A somewhat more elaborate version of the proposal was made around the same time by Professor Joseph Liu
    • See Hughes, supra note 18, at 778. A somewhat more elaborate version of the proposal was made around the same time by Professor Joseph Liu.
    • supra , pp. 778
  • 147
    • 66049084009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Liu, supra note 18. Yet, unlike Hughes, Liu bases his proposal not on the need to bring copyright doctrine closer to its theory of incentives, but rather on the problems associated with the extension of copyright's term of protection.
    • See Liu, supra note 18. Yet, unlike Hughes, Liu bases his proposal not on the need to bring copyright doctrine closer to its theory of incentives, but rather on the problems associated with the extension of copyright's term of protection.
  • 148
    • 66049110243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 411-12 & n. 10 (noting this difference).
    • Id. at 411-12 & n. 10 (noting this difference).
  • 149
    • 66049097850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hughes, supra note 18, at 782-83
    • Hughes, supra note 18, at 782-83.
  • 150
    • 66049108526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 778
    • Id. at 778.
  • 151
    • 66049111226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 782
    • Id. at 782.
  • 152
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1074, 2006, listing as a factor for fair use the effect of the use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work
    • See 17 U.S.C. § 107(4) (2006) (listing as a factor for fair use "the effect of the use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work").
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 153
    • 66049090092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ringgold v. Black Entm't Television, Inc., 126 F.3d 70, 81 (2d Cir. 1997);
    • See, e.g., Ringgold v. Black Entm't Television, Inc., 126 F.3d 70, 81 (2d Cir. 1997);
  • 154
    • 38749086123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Document Servs., Inc., 99 F.3d 1381
    • Princeton Univ. Press v. Mich. Document Servs., Inc., 99 F.3d 1381, 1388 (6th Cir. 1996);
    • (1996) 1388 (6th Cir
    • Univ, P.1    Mich, P.V.2
  • 155
    • 66049114582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Am. Geophysical Union v. Texaco Inc., 60 F.3d 913, 929-30 (2d Cir. 1994).
    • Am. Geophysical Union v. Texaco Inc., 60 F.3d 913, 929-30 (2d Cir. 1994).
  • 156
    • 84868946231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For more on this circularity problem, see 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.05[A][4], at 13-196 to -198;
    • For more on this circularity problem, see 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.05[A][4], at 13-196 to -198;
  • 157
    • 0042761645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Misuse of Licensing Evidence in Fair Use Analysis: New Technologies, New Markets, and the Courts, 88
    • Matthew Africa, The Misuse of Licensing Evidence in Fair Use Analysis: New Technologies, New Markets, and the Courts, 88 CAL. L. REV. 1145, 1160 (2000);
    • (2000) CAL. L. REV , vol.1145 , pp. 1160
    • Africa, M.1
  • 158
    • 66049128527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fisher, supra note 23, at 1671;
    • Fisher, supra note 23, at 1671;
  • 159
    • 35248858873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should a Licensing Market Require Licensing?
    • Spring, at
    • Mark Lemley, Should a Licensing Market Require Licensing?, LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., Spring 2007, at 185, 190;
    • (2007) LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS
    • Lemley, M.1
  • 160
    • 66049151763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Loren, supra note 11, at 38-41;
    • Loren, supra note 11, at 38-41;
  • 161
    • 66049097404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lunney, supra note 11, at 1021;
    • Lunney, supra note 11, at 1021;
  • 162
    • 66049093152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Stadler, supra note 11, at 903-04.
    • and Stadler, supra note 11, at 903-04.
  • 163
    • 66049153663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Am. Geophysical Union, 60 F.3d at 930;
    • Am. Geophysical Union, 60 F.3d at 930;
  • 164
    • 66049152206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Harper & Row, Publishers, Inc. v. Nation Enters., 471 U.S. 539, 568 (1985) (using a similar normal market criterion).
    • see also Harper & Row, Publishers, Inc. v. Nation Enters., 471 U.S. 539, 568 (1985) (using a similar "normal market" criterion).
  • 165
    • 66049148721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As a historical matter, interestingly, the common law standard seems to have required relating fair use to the time of publication. See Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 550 ([The] fair use doctrine was predicated on the author's implied consent to 'reasonable and customary' use when he released his work for public consumption. (emphasis added)).
    • As a historical matter, interestingly, the common law standard seems to have required relating fair use to the time of publication. See Harper & Row, 471 U.S. at 550 ("[The] fair use doctrine was predicated on the author's implied consent to 'reasonable and customary' use when he released his work for public consumption." (emphasis added)).
  • 166
    • 0348214815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Eric Kades, Windfalls, 108 YALE L.J. 1489, 1491 (1999) (defining windfalls as economic gains independent of work, planning, or other productive activities that society wishes to reward (emphasis omitted)).
    • See Eric Kades, Windfalls, 108 YALE L.J. 1489, 1491 (1999) (defining windfalls as "economic gains independent of work, planning, or other productive activities that society wishes to reward" (emphasis omitted)).
  • 167
    • 34250618352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gideon Parchomovsky, Peter Siegelman & Steve Thel, Of Equal Wrongs and Half Rights, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 738, 756 (2007) (describing windfalls in terms of the perceivable costs and benefits of undertaking an action to bring about or avoid an event). Professors Parchomovsky, Siegelman, and Thel connect their description to tort law's well-known formulation of incentives to take care (that is, the Learned Hand formula).
    • See Gideon Parchomovsky, Peter Siegelman & Steve Thel, Of Equal Wrongs and Half Rights, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 738, 756 (2007) (describing windfalls in terms of the perceivable costs and benefits of undertaking an action to bring about or avoid an event). Professors Parchomovsky, Siegelman, and Thel connect their description to tort law's well-known formulation of incentives to take care (that is, the Learned Hand formula).
  • 168
    • 84868951143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ex ante > G.P. The expected benefits are therefore insufficient ex ante to independently generate an incentive to bring about the event causally.
    • ex ante > G.P. The expected benefits are therefore insufficient ex ante to independently generate an incentive to bring about the event causally.
  • 169
    • 66049084840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, in Mills Music, Inc. v. Snyder, 469 U.S. 153 (1985), a dissenting minority of four justices made the exact same argument.
    • Indeed, in Mills Music, Inc. v. Snyder, 469 U.S. 153 (1985), a dissenting minority of four justices made the exact same argument.
  • 170
    • 66049100318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 187-88 (White, J., dissenting). The Court there was concerned with the allocation of royalties between an author and a publisher following the partial termination of a license. The work had been created and licensed well in advance of the Copyright Act of 1976, which extended the term of protection by an additional period.
    • Id. at 187-88 (White, J., dissenting). The Court there was concerned with the allocation of royalties between an author and a publisher following the partial termination of a license. The work had been created and licensed well in advance of the Copyright Act of 1976, which extended the term of protection by an additional period.
  • 171
    • 84868946229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • reliance" on the additional benefits since they were not anticipated, and the gains thus represented a "windfall
    • Consequently, the parties could not have acted in that needed to be allocated
    • Id. Consequently, the parties could not have acted in "reliance" on the additional benefits since they were not anticipated, and the gains thus represented a "windfall" that needed to be allocated.
  • 172
    • 66049153437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 188
    • Id. at 188.
  • 173
    • 66049140477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 189, 194-96
    • See, & eds
    • See Wendy J. Gordon & Robert G. Bone, Copyright, in 2 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 189, 194-96 (Boudewijn Bouckaert & Gerrit De Geest eds., 2000);
    • (2000) Copyright, in
    • Gordon, W.J.1    Bone, R.G.2
  • 174
    • 18144362124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding, 83
    • elaborating on these costs
    • Mark A. Lemley, Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding, 83 TEX. L. REV. 1031, 1058-59 (2005) (elaborating on these costs).
    • (2005) TEX. L. REV , vol.1031 , pp. 1058-1059
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 175
    • 66049135820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See William W. Fisher III, Property and Contract on the Internet, 73 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1203, 1249 (1998).
    • See William W. Fisher III, Property and Contract on the Internet, 73 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1203, 1249 (1998).
  • 176
    • 66049112482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kades, supra note 81, at 1521
    • See Kades, supra note 81, at 1521.
  • 177
    • 66049108081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Teleprompter Corp. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 415 U.S. 394 (1974);
    • See, e.g., Teleprompter Corp. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 415 U.S. 394 (1974);
  • 178
    • 66049144930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fortnightly Corp. v. United Artists Television, Inc., 392 U.S. 390 (1968);
    • Fortnightly Corp. v. United Artists Television, Inc., 392 U.S. 390 (1968);
  • 179
    • 17044413553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copyright's Communications Policy, 103
    • see also
    • see also Tim Wu, Copyright's Communications Policy, 103 MICH. L. REV. 278, 279 (2004).
    • (2004) MICH. L. REV , vol.278 , pp. 279
    • Wu, T.1
  • 180
    • 66049148708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417 (1984).
    • See, e.g., Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417 (1984).
  • 181
    • 66049118810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 660 (7th ed. 1999).
    • BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 660 (7th ed. 1999).
  • 182
    • 66049107316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some scholars refer to this process as the social engineering function of the common law. See Howard A. Latin, Problem-Solving Behavior and Theories of Tort Liability, 73 CAL. L. REV. 677, 677 n. 2 (1985). Others refer to it as an issue of incentives.
    • Some scholars refer to this process as the "social engineering" function of the common law. See Howard A. Latin, Problem-Solving Behavior and Theories of Tort Liability, 73 CAL. L. REV. 677, 677 n. 2 (1985). Others refer to it as an issue of incentives.
  • 183
    • 66049152601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See POLINSKY, supra note 10, at 130;
    • See POLINSKY, supra note 10, at 130;
  • 184
    • 0000135697 scopus 로고
    • Causation and Incentives To Take Care Under the Negligence Rule, 18
    • Marcel Kahan, Causation and Incentives To Take Care Under the Negligence Rule, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 427 (1989).
    • (1989) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.427
    • Kahan, M.1
  • 185
    • 66049157115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Latin, supra note 90, at 677 (laying out the basic postulates of the idea of behavioral modification).
    • See Latin, supra note 90, at 677 (laying out the basic postulates of the idea of behavioral modification).
  • 186
    • 84959810873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Herbert Simon is credited with developing the idea of bounded rationality, beginning in the 1950s. See Herbert A. Simon, A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, 69 Q.J. ECON. 99 (1955);
    • Professor Herbert Simon is credited with developing the idea of bounded rationality, beginning in the 1950s. See Herbert A. Simon, A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, 69 Q.J. ECON. 99 (1955);
  • 187
    • 84973985993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Herbert A. Simon, Human Nature in Politics: The Dialogue of Psychology with Political Science, 79 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 293 (1985);
    • Herbert A. Simon, Human Nature in Politics: The Dialogue of Psychology with Political Science, 79 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 293 (1985);
  • 188
    • 0003374149 scopus 로고
    • On the Behavioral and Rational Foundations of Economic Dynamics, 5
    • Herbert A. Simon, On the Behavioral and Rational Foundations of Economic Dynamics, 5 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 35 (1984);
    • (1984) J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG , vol.35
    • Simon, H.A.1
  • 189
    • 0000732084 scopus 로고
    • Rationality in Psychology and Economics, 59
    • S
    • Herbert A. Simon, Rationality in Psychology and Economics, 59 J. BUS. S209 (1986).
    • (1986) J. BUS , pp. 209
    • Simon, H.A.1
  • 190
    • 0016264378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 185 SCIENCE 1124 (1974). For work extending these ideas to the analysis of law, see Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471 (1998);
    • See Amos Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 185 SCIENCE 1124 (1974). For work extending these ideas to the analysis of law, see Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 STAN. L. REV. 1471 (1998);
  • 191
    • 0042409519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics, 88
    • Russell B. Korobkin & Thomas S. Ulen, Law and Behavioral Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics, 88 CAL. L. REV. 1051 (2000);
    • (2000) CAL. L. REV , vol.1051
    • Korobkin, R.B.1    Ulen, T.S.2
  • 192
    • 0346408819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Growing Pains of Behavioral Law and Economics, 51
    • and Thomas S. Ulen, The Growing Pains of Behavioral Law and Economics, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1747 (1998).
    • (1998) VAND. L. REV , vol.1747
    • Ulen, T.S.1
  • 193
    • 84903035283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also RICHARD H. THALER & CASS R. SUNSTEIN, NUDGE: IMPROVING DECISIONS ABOUT HEALTH, WEALTH, AND HAPPINESS (2008).
    • See also RICHARD H. THALER & CASS R. SUNSTEIN, NUDGE: IMPROVING DECISIONS ABOUT HEALTH, WEALTH, AND HAPPINESS (2008).
  • 194
    • 66049096600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OLIVER WILLIAMSON, ANTITRUST ECONOMICS: MERGERS, CONTRACTING, AND STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR 74-78 (1987);
    • See OLIVER WILLIAMSON, ANTITRUST ECONOMICS: MERGERS, CONTRACTING, AND STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR 74-78 (1987);
  • 196
    • 0000409508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oliver E. Williamson, The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead, 38 J. ECON. LITERATURE 595, 600 (2000) (There is close to unanimity within the [new institutional economics] on the idea of limited cognitive competence - often referred to as bounded rationality.).
    • Oliver E. Williamson, The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead, 38 J. ECON. LITERATURE 595, 600 (2000) ("There is close to unanimity within the [new institutional economics] on the idea of limited cognitive competence - often referred to as bounded rationality.").
  • 197
    • 66049153424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For uses of this term in different contexts deriving from bounded rationality, see RICHARD R. NELSON & SIDNEY G. WINTER, AN EVOLUTIONARY THEORY OF ECONOMIC CHANGE 88 (1982);
    • For uses of this term in different contexts deriving from bounded rationality, see RICHARD R. NELSON & SIDNEY G. WINTER, AN EVOLUTIONARY THEORY OF ECONOMIC CHANGE 88 (1982);
  • 198
    • 66049106873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adam B. Badawi, Interpretive Preferences and the Limits of the New Formalism, 6 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. (forthcoming 2009) (manuscript at 9, on file with the Harvard Law School Library);
    • Adam B. Badawi, Interpretive Preferences and the Limits of the New Formalism, 6 BERKELEY BUS. L.J. (forthcoming 2009) (manuscript at 9, on file with the Harvard Law School Library);
  • 199
    • 0006055568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty and Values: The Case of Environmental Impact Assessment
    • 70
    • and Tomas Hellström & Merle Jacob, Uncertainty and Values: The Case of Environmental Impact Assessment, 9 KNOWLEDGE & POL'Y 70, 76 (1996).
    • (1996) KNOWLEDGE & POL'Y , vol.9 , pp. 76
    • Hellström, T.1    Jacob, M.2
  • 200
    • 1542609884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, its use in this context has spawned a secondary body of literature attempting to understand the role it plays in the overall analysis. See, e.g., John Conlisk, Why Bounded Rationality?, 34 J. ECON. LITERATURE 669 (1996);
    • Indeed, its use in this context has spawned a secondary body of literature attempting to understand the role it plays in the overall analysis. See, e.g., John Conlisk, Why Bounded Rationality?, 34 J. ECON. LITERATURE 669 (1996);
  • 201
    • 0012127968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nicolai J. Foss, Bounded Rationality in the Economics of Organization: Present Use and (Some) Future Possibilities, 5 J. MGMT. & GOVERNANCE 401 (2001);
    • Nicolai J. Foss, Bounded Rationality in the Economics of Organization: Present Use and (Some) Future Possibilities, 5 J. MGMT. & GOVERNANCE 401 (2001);
  • 202
    • 84868956754 scopus 로고
    • Is "Bounded Rationality" an Important Element of a Theory of Institutions?, 146 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON
    • the situation where multiple solutions to a single problem exist
    • Oliver Hart, Is "Bounded Rationality" an Important Element of a Theory of Institutions?, 146 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL ECON. 696 (1990). Some scholars additionally attempt to distinguish between bounded rationality and "indeterminacy, " the situation where multiple solutions to a single problem exist.
    • (1990) Some scholars additionally attempt to distinguish between bounded rationality and indeterminacy , vol.696
    • Hart, O.1
  • 203
    • 0001521535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded Rationality, Indeterminacy, and the Theory of the Firm, 106
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Roy Radner, Bounded Rationality, Indeterminacy, and the Theory of the Firm, 106 ECON. J. 1360 (1996).
    • (1996) ECON. J , vol.1360
    • Radner, R.1
  • 204
    • 0040908085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foundations of Incomplete Contracts, 66
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Oliver Hart & John Moore, Foundations of Incomplete Contracts, 66 REV. ECON. STUD. 115 (1999);
    • (1999) REV. ECON. STUD , vol.115
    • Hart, O.1    Moore, J.2
  • 205
    • 17944377188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts, 66
    • Eric Maskin & Jean Tirole, Unforeseen Contingencies and Incomplete Contracts, 66 REV. ECON. STUD. 83 (1999).
    • (1999) REV. ECON. STUD , vol.83
    • Maskin, E.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 206
    • 66049139637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Maskin & Tirole, supra note 97, at 83-84
    • See Maskin & Tirole, supra note 97, at 83-84.
  • 207
    • 66049149989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM 46 (1985).
    • See OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF CAPITALISM 46 (1985).
  • 208
    • 84868951140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, Williamson notes that the use of bounded rationality in the organizational context actually enlarges ⋯ the scope for rationality analysis in the traditional economic account. Oliver E. Williamson, Assessing Contract, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 177, 180 (1985). Some refer to this as the thin conception of bounded rationality, as opposed to its use as a thick conception in the world of behavioral economics. See Nicolai J. Foss, Bounded Rationality in the Economics of Organization: Much Cited and Little Used, 24 J. ECON. PSYCH. 245, 246 (2003);
    • Indeed, Williamson notes that the use of bounded rationality in the organizational context actually "enlarges ⋯ the scope for rationality analysis" in the traditional economic account. Oliver E. Williamson, Assessing Contract, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 177, 180 (1985). Some refer to this as the "thin" conception of bounded rationality, as opposed to its use as a "thick" conception in the world of behavioral economics. See Nicolai J. Foss, Bounded Rationality in the Economics of Organization: "Much Cited and Little Used," 24 J. ECON. PSYCH. 245, 246 (2003);
  • 209
    • 66049119680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 96, at, Indeed, some believe that since it does little independent work in the analysis, its use is somewhat unnecessary
    • Foss, supra note 96, at 402. Indeed, some believe that since it does little independent work in the analysis, its use is somewhat unnecessary.
    • supra , pp. 402
    • Foss1
  • 210
    • 66049104753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hart, supra note 96, at 700-01. Yet, as its advocates continue to emphasize, it provides rhetorical support to an otherwise intuitive part of the basic model. Foss, supra note 96, at 406. It is in principally te same vein that I attempt to connect it to the idea of foreseeability. Additionally, scholars in the tradition of organizational economics attempting to model bounded rationality in legal terms have long made this connection in the literature.
    • See Hart, supra note 96, at 700-01. Yet, as its advocates continue to emphasize, it provides rhetorical support to an otherwise intuitive part of the basic model. Foss, supra note 96, at 406. It is in principally te same vein that I attempt to connect it to the idea of foreseeability. Additionally, scholars in the tradition of organizational economics attempting to model bounded rationality in legal terms have long made this connection in the literature.
  • 211
    • 1842807879 scopus 로고
    • Commercial Impossibility, the Uranium Market and the Westinghouse Case, 6
    • The foreseeability requirement may only make sense if we introduce the concept of 'bounded rationality., See
    • See Paul L. Joskow, Commercial Impossibility, the Uranium Market and the Westinghouse Case, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 119, 157 (1977) ("The foreseeability requirement may only make sense if we introduce the concept of 'bounded rationality.'").
    • (1977) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.119 , pp. 157
    • Joskow, P.L.1
  • 212
    • 29144532053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Purging Foreseeability, 58
    • See
    • See W. Jonathan Cardi, Purging Foreseeability, 58 VAND. L. REV. 739, 747-50, 755-67 (2005).
    • (2005) VAND. L. REV , vol.739 , Issue.747-750 , pp. 755-767
    • Jonathan Cardi, W.1
  • 213
    • 66049135835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Palsgraf v. Long Island R.R. Co., 162 N.E. 99 (N.Y. 1928).
    • See, e.g., Palsgraf v. Long Island R.R. Co., 162 N.E. 99 (N.Y. 1928).
  • 214
    • 84868940875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DAN B. DOBBS, THE LAW OF TORTS § 180, at 443 (2001);
    • See DAN B. DOBBS, THE LAW OF TORTS § 180, at 443 (2001);
  • 215
    • 84868946226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • W. PAGE KEETON ET AL., PROSSER AND KEETON ON THE LAW OF TORTS § 41, at 264 (5th ed. 1984) ('Proximate Cause' - in itself an unfortunate term - is merely the limitation which the courts have placed upon the actor's responsibility for the consequences of the actor's conduct⋯. Some boundary must be set to liability for the consequences of any act, upon the basis of some social idea of justice or policy).
    • W. PAGE KEETON ET AL., PROSSER AND KEETON ON THE LAW OF TORTS § 41, at 264 (5th ed. 1984) ("'Proximate Cause' - in itself an unfortunate term - is merely the limitation which the courts have placed upon the actor's responsibility for the consequences of the actor's conduct⋯. Some boundary must be set to liability for the consequences of any act, upon the basis of some social idea of justice or policy").
  • 216
    • 66049151765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ballard v. Uribe, 715 P.2d 624, 628 n. 6 (Cal. 1986) (en bane);
    • See, e.g., Ballard v. Uribe, 715 P.2d 624, 628 n. 6 (Cal. 1986) (en bane);
  • 217
    • 66049144915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neering v. 111. Cent. R.R. Co., 50 N.E.2d 497, 503 (111. 1943);
    • Neering v. 111. Cent. R.R. Co., 50 N.E.2d 497, 503 (111. 1943);
  • 218
    • 66049117120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Osborne v. Atl. Ice & Coal Co., 177 S.E. 796, 796 (N.C. 1935);
    • Osborne v. Atl. Ice & Coal Co., 177 S.E. 796, 796 (N.C. 1935);
  • 219
    • 66049084421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mudrich v. Standard Oil Co., 90 N.E.2d 859, 863 (Ohio 1950);
    • Mudrich v. Standard Oil Co., 90 N.E.2d 859, 863 (Ohio 1950);
  • 220
    • 66049155814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Read v. Scott Fetzer Co., 990 S.W.2d 732, 737 (Tex. 1998);
    • Read v. Scott Fetzer Co., 990 S.W.2d 732, 737 (Tex. 1998);
  • 221
    • 66049147855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doe v. Boys Clubs of Greater Dallas, Inc., 907 S.W.2d 472, 478 (Tex. 1995).
    • Doe v. Boys Clubs of Greater Dallas, Inc., 907 S.W.2d 472, 478 (Tex. 1995).
  • 222
    • 66049101787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Saul Levmore, The Wagon Mound Cases: Foreseeability, Causation, and Mrs. Palsgraf, in TORTS STORIES 129, 132 (Robert L. Rabin & Stephen D. Sugarman eds., 2003).
    • Saul Levmore, The Wagon Mound Cases: Foreseeability, Causation, and Mrs. Palsgraf, in TORTS STORIES 129, 132 (Robert L. Rabin & Stephen D. Sugarman eds., 2003).
  • 223
    • 84868946227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KEETON ET AL., supra note 103, § 41, at 264 (noting that the consequences of an act go forward to eternity, and the causes of an event go back to the dawn of human events, and beyond, so that the lack of a limiting rule would result in infinite liability for all wrongful acts).
    • See KEETON ET AL., supra note 103, § 41, at 264 (noting that "the consequences of an act go forward to eternity, and the causes of an event go back to the dawn of human events, and beyond," so that the lack of a limiting rule "would result in infinite liability for all wrongful acts").
  • 224
    • 84868942440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 4, at
    • See id. § 4, at 25-26.
    • See id , pp. 25-26
  • 225
    • 66049160970 scopus 로고
    • Proximate Cause and the Law of Negligence, 69
    • For an elaboration of this idea, see
    • For an elaboration of this idea, see Mark F. Grady, Proximate Cause and the Law of Negligence, 69 IOWA L. REV. 363, 385-91 (1984);
    • (1984) IOWA L. REV , vol.363 , pp. 385-391
    • Grady, M.F.1
  • 226
    • 0032350230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rights, Wrongs, and Recourse in the Law of Torts, 51
    • and Benjamin C. Zipursky, Rights, Wrongs, and Recourse in the Law of Torts, 51 VAND. L. REV. 1, 46-47 (1998).
    • (1998) VAND. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 46-47
    • Zipursky, B.C.1
  • 227
    • 66049130882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF TORT LAW 246-47 (1987);
    • See WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF TORT LAW 246-47 (1987);
  • 228
    • 66049146574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grady, supra note 108, at 388;
    • Grady, supra note 108, at 388;
  • 229
    • 0000500588 scopus 로고
    • Liability and the Incentive To Obtain Information About Risk, 21
    • Steven Shavell, Liability and the Incentive To Obtain Information About Risk, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 259 (1992).
    • (1992) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.259
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 230
    • 66049124754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LANDES & POSNER, supra note 109, at 247
    • See LANDES & POSNER, supra note 109, at 247.
  • 231
    • 66049152208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grady, supra note 108, at 388-89
    • Grady, supra note 108, at 388-89.
  • 232
    • 66049083561 scopus 로고
    • The Principle of Hadley v. Baxendale, 80
    • See
    • See Melvin Aron Eisenberg, The Principle of Hadley v. Baxendale, 80 CAL. L. REV. 563, 565 (1992).
    • (1992) CAL. L. REV , vol.563 , pp. 565
    • Aron Eisenberg, M.1
  • 233
    • 66049135424 scopus 로고
    • Ex. 341, 156 Eng. Rep
    • 9
    • Hadley v. Baxendale, 9 Ex. 341, 156 Eng. Rep. 145, 151 (1854).
    • (1854) , vol.145 , pp. 151
    • Baxendale, H.V.1
  • 234
    • 0011651519 scopus 로고
    • Breach of Contract and the Foreseeability Doctrine of Hadley v. Baxendale, 10
    • See
    • See Jeffrey M. Perloff, Breach of Contract and the Foreseeability Doctrine of Hadley v. Baxendale, 10 J. LEGAL STUD. 39 (1981).
    • (1981) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.39
    • Perloff, J.M.1
  • 235
    • 66049162218 scopus 로고
    • The Development of the Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance, 18
    • For more on the doctrine and its development, see
    • For more on the doctrine and its development, see William Herbert Page, The Development of the Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance, 18 MICH. L. REV. 589 (1920);
    • (1920) MICH. L. REV , vol.589
    • Herbert Page, W.1
  • 236
    • 43149085506 scopus 로고
    • Contract Breach and Contract Discharge Due to Impossibility: A Unified Theory, 17
    • Michelle J. White, Contract Breach and Contract Discharge Due to Impossibility: A Unified Theory, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 353 (1988);
    • (1988) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.353
    • White, M.J.1
  • 237
    • 77951951794 scopus 로고
    • Common Law and Uncommon Events: The Development of the Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance in English Contract Law, 75
    • John D. Wladis, Common Law and Uncommon Events: The Development of the Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance in English Contract Law, 75 GEO. L.J. 1575 (1987);
    • (1987) GEO. L.J , vol.1575
    • Wladis, J.D.1
  • 238
    • 66049138136 scopus 로고
    • Impracticability As Risk Allocation: The Effect of Changed Circumstances upon Contract Obligations for the Sale of Goods, 22
    • and John D. Wladis, Impracticability As Risk Allocation: The Effect of Changed Circumstances upon Contract Obligations for the Sale of Goods, 22 GA. L. REV. 503 (1988).
    • (1988) GA. L. REV , vol.503
    • Wladis, J.D.1
  • 239
    • 66049132978 scopus 로고
    • Corp. v. CRS Group Eng'rs, Inc
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Waldinger Corp. v. CRS Group Eng'rs, Inc., 775 F.2d 781 (7th Cir. 1985);
    • (1985) 775 F.2d 781 (7th Cir
    • Waldinger1
  • 240
    • 66049149987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lloyd v. Murphy, 153 P.2d 47 (Cal. 1944);
    • Lloyd v. Murphy, 153 P.2d 47 (Cal. 1944);
  • 241
    • 66049104337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Farm Credit Bank of St. Louis v. Dorr, 620 N.E.2d 549, 555-56 (Ill. App. Ct. 1993);
    • Farm Credit Bank of St. Louis v. Dorr, 620 N.E.2d 549, 555-56 (Ill. App. Ct. 1993);
  • 242
    • 66049095291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • City of Starkville v. 4-County Elec. Power Ass'n, 819 So.2d 1216, 1223 (Miss. 2002);
    • City of Starkville v. 4-County Elec. Power Ass'n, 819 So.2d 1216, 1223 (Miss. 2002);
  • 243
    • 66049155502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alamance County Bd. of Educ. v. Bobby Murray Chevrolet, Inc., 465 S.E.2d 306, 311 (N.C. Ct. App. 1996);
    • Alamance County Bd. of Educ. v. Bobby Murray Chevrolet, Inc., 465 S.E.2d 306, 311 (N.C. Ct. App. 1996);
  • 244
    • 66049110660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grady v. Grady, 504 A.2d 444, 447 (R.I. 1986);
    • Grady v. Grady, 504 A.2d 444, 447 (R.I. 1986);
  • 245
    • 66049119226 scopus 로고
    • Disputes Over Omission in Contracts, 68
    • see also
    • see also E. Allan Farnsworth, Disputes Over Omission in Contracts, 68 COLUM. L. REV. 860 (1968);
    • (1968) COLUM. L. REV , vol.860
    • Allan Farnsworth, E.1
  • 246
    • 66049115910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mary Sue Bloomfield, Comment, The Role of Foreseeability in Allocation of Risk Under U.C.C. 2-615, Excuse by Failure of Presupposed Conditions, 21 S. TEX. L.J. 441 (1981);
    • Mary Sue Bloomfield, Comment, The Role of Foreseeability in Allocation of Risk Under U.C.C. 2-615, Excuse by Failure of Presupposed Conditions, 21 S. TEX. L.J. 441 (1981);
  • 247
    • 66049122307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles G. Brown, Note, The Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance and the Foreseeability Test, 6 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 575 (1975). This test came to be codified in the Uniform Commercial Code.
    • Charles G. Brown, Note, The Doctrine of Impossibility of Performance and the Foreseeability Test, 6 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 575 (1975). This test came to be codified in the Uniform Commercial Code.
  • 248
    • 84868940868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.C.C. § 2-15 (2003).
    • See U.C.C. § 2-15 (2003).
  • 249
    • 0042039132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Elofson, The Dilemma of Changed Circumstances in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis of the Foreseeability and Superior Risk Bearer Tests, 30 COLUM. J.L. & SOC. PROBS. 1, 4 (1996).
    • John Elofson, The Dilemma of Changed Circumstances in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis of the Foreseeability and Superior Risk Bearer Tests, 30 COLUM. J.L. & SOC. PROBS. 1, 4 (1996).
  • 250
    • 66049108094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 251
    • 66049131279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Joskow, supra note 100, at 157 (The foreseeability requirement may only make sense if we introduce the concept of 'bounded rationality.');
    • See Joskow, supra note 100, at 157 ("The foreseeability requirement may only make sense if we introduce the concept of 'bounded rationality.'");
  • 252
    • 55349125178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Outgrowing Impossibility: Examining the Impossibility Doctrine in the Wake of Hurricane Katrina, 56
    • see also
    • see also Shirley R. Brener, Comment, Outgrowing Impossibility: Examining the Impossibility Doctrine in the Wake of Hurricane Katrina, 56 EMORY L.J. 461, 469, 477-80 (2006);
    • (2006) EMORY L.J , vol.461 , Issue.469 , pp. 477-480
    • Shirley, R.1    Brener, C.2
  • 253
    • 66049085676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aaron J. Wright, Note, Rendered Impracticable: Behavioral Economics and the Impracticability Doctrine, 26 CARDOZO L. REV. 2183, 2200 (2005).
    • Aaron J. Wright, Note, Rendered Impracticable: Behavioral Economics and the Impracticability Doctrine, 26 CARDOZO L. REV. 2183, 2200 (2005).
  • 254
    • 66049157543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Joskow, supra note 100, at 157
    • See Joskow, supra note 100, at 157.
  • 255
    • 84868958924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally UNIF. PREMARITAL AGREEMENT ACT § 1(1), 9C U.L.A. 39 (1983);
    • See generally UNIF. PREMARITAL AGREEMENT ACT § 1(1), 9C U.L.A. 39 (1983);
  • 256
    • 84868940869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 ALEXANDER LINDEY & LOUIS I. PARLEY, LINDEY AND PARLEY ON SEPARATION AGREEMENTS AND ANTENUPTIAL CONTRACTS § 110.70(2)(d) (2d ed. 2002).
    • 2 ALEXANDER LINDEY & LOUIS I. PARLEY, LINDEY AND PARLEY ON SEPARATION AGREEMENTS AND ANTENUPTIAL CONTRACTS § 110.70(2)(d) (2d ed. 2002).
  • 257
    • 0347683678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Allison A. Marston, Note, Planning for Love: The Politics of Prenuptial Agreements, 49 STAN. L. REV. 887, 897-901 (1997).
    • See Allison A. Marston, Note, Planning for Love: The Politics of Prenuptial Agreements, 49 STAN. L. REV. 887, 897-901 (1997).
  • 258
    • 18444380615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Karen Servidea, Note, Reviewing Premarital Agreements To Protect the State's Interest in Marriage, 91 VA. L. REV. 535, 545 (2005).
    • See Karen Servidea, Note, Reviewing Premarital Agreements To Protect the State's Interest in Marriage, 91 VA. L. REV. 535, 545 (2005).
  • 259
    • 66049152995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., McKee-Johnson v. Johnson, 444 N.W.2d 259, 267 (Minn. 1989);
    • See, e.g., McKee-Johnson v. Johnson, 444 N.W.2d 259, 267 (Minn. 1989);
  • 260
    • 66049152996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gant v. Gant, 329 S.E.2d 106, 115 (W. Va. 1985);
    • Gant v. Gant, 329 S.E.2d 106, 115 (W. Va. 1985);
  • 261
    • 66049109803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Button v. Button, 388 N.W.2d 546, 552 (Wis. 1986).
    • Button v. Button, 388 N.W.2d 546, 552 (Wis. 1986).
  • 262
    • 66049126822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Servidea, supra note 123, at 547, 549 (referring to this approach as the bounded-rationality approach).
    • See Servidea, supra note 123, at 547, 549 (referring to this approach as the "bounded-rationality" approach).
  • 263
    • 66049153436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For more on the doctrine, see Roy E. Cordato, Time Passage and the Economics of Coming to the Nuisance: Reassessing the Coasean Perspective, 20 CAMPBELL L. REV. 273 (1998);
    • For more on the doctrine, see Roy E. Cordato, Time Passage and the Economics of Coming to the Nuisance: Reassessing the Coasean Perspective, 20 CAMPBELL L. REV. 273 (1998);
  • 264
    • 0344081245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coming to the Nuisance: An Economic Analysis from an Incomplete Contracts Perspective, 19
    • Rohan Pitchford & Christopher M. Snyder, Coming to the Nuisance: An Economic Analysis from an Incomplete Contracts Perspective, 19 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 491 (2003);
    • (2003) J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.491
    • Pitchford, R.1    Snyder, C.M.2
  • 265
    • 0011005671 scopus 로고
    • First Come, First Served: An Economic Analysis of "Coming to the Nuisance," 9
    • and Donald Wittman, First Come, First Served: An Economic Analysis of "Coming to the Nuisance," 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 557 (1980).
    • (1980) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.557
    • Wittman, D.1
  • 266
    • 84868946221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of TORTS § 840D (1979) (noting that the preexistence of the nuisance is but one of several factors to be considered, and not by itself a bar to relief).
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) of TORTS § 840D (1979) (noting that the preexistence of the nuisance is but one of several factors to be considered, and not by itself a bar to relief).
  • 267
    • 66049091309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Wittman, supra note 126, at 565. The case of East St. John's Shingle Co. v. City of Portland, 246 P.2d 554 (Or. 1952), is illustrative. There, the plaintiff acquired a parcel of land adjoining a slough that was being polluted by the city's sewage system. After moving onto the land, the plaintiff complained that an increase in sewage levels in the slough was interfering with its business and causing a special nuisance to it. The court concluded that since the pollution, its continuance, and its increase were all reasonably foreseen by the plaintiff, the claim was barred.
    • See Wittman, supra note 126, at 565. The case of East St. John's Shingle Co. v. City of Portland, 246 P.2d 554 (Or. 1952), is illustrative. There, the plaintiff acquired a parcel of land adjoining a slough that was being polluted by the city's sewage system. After moving onto the land, the plaintiff complained that an increase in sewage levels in the slough was interfering with its business and causing a special nuisance to it. The court concluded that since the pollution, its continuance, and its increase were all "reasonably foreseen" by the plaintiff, the claim was barred.
  • 268
    • 66049152997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 563-64
    • Id. at 563-64.
  • 269
    • 66049150953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bove v. Donner-Hanna Coke Corp., 258 N.Y.S. 229, 233 (App. Div. 1932);
    • See Bove v. Donner-Hanna Coke Corp., 258 N.Y.S. 229, 233 (App. Div. 1932);
  • 270
    • 66049147856 scopus 로고
    • 38 Ohio Ct. App
    • Gau v. Ley, 38 Ohio Ct. App. 235, 239 (1916);
    • (1916) , vol.235 , pp. 239
    • Ley, G.V.1
  • 271
    • 66049160984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wittman, supra note 126, at 565 n. 20.
    • Wittman, supra note 126, at 565 n. 20.
  • 272
    • 66049127703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Graver Tank & Mfg. Co. v. Linde Air Prods. Co., 339 U.S. 605, 607 (1950).
    • Graver Tank & Mfg. Co. v. Linde Air Prods. Co., 339 U.S. 605, 607 (1950).
  • 273
    • 66049090478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 607-08.
    • See id. at 607-08.
  • 274
    • 66049130006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Warner-Jenkinson Co. v. Hilton Davis Chem. Co., 520 U.S. 17, 30-31 (1997).
    • See Warner-Jenkinson Co. v. Hilton Davis Chem. Co., 520 U.S. 17, 30-31 (1997).
  • 275
    • 1842764747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Prosecution History Estoppel, 71
    • Douglas Lichtman, Rethinking Prosecution History Estoppel, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 151, 153 (2004).
    • (2004) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.151 , pp. 153
    • Lichtman, D.1
  • 276
    • 66049105175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foreseeability in
    • For early analyses of this trend, see, Patent Law, 16 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1045 2001
    • For early analyses of this trend, see Matthew J. Conigliaro et al., Foreseeability in Patent Law, 16 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1045 (2001);
    • Conigliaro, M.J.1
  • 277
    • 66049150507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Andrew C. Greenberg & Jeffrey R. Kuester, The Palsgraffing of Patent Law: Foreseeability and the Doctrine of Equivalents, INTELL. PROP. TODAY, June 1998, at 17
    • and Andrew C. Greenberg & Jeffrey R. Kuester, The "Palsgraffing" of Patent Law: Foreseeability and the Doctrine of Equivalents, INTELL. PROP. TODAY, June 1998, at 17.
  • 278
    • 66049103081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inc. v. Devon Indus., Inc
    • See also, Fed. Cir
    • See also Sage Prods., Inc. v. Devon Indus., Inc., 126 F.3d 1420 (Fed. Cir. 1997);
    • (1997) 126 F.3d 1420
    • Prods, S.1
  • 279
    • 66049136742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael J. Meurer & Craig Allen Nard, Invention, Refinement and Patent Claim Scope: A New Perspective on the Doctrine of Equivalents, 93 GEO. L.J. 1947, 1970 (2005). The test was adopted by the Supreme Court in Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co., 535 U.S. 722 (2002).
    • Michael J. Meurer & Craig Allen Nard, Invention, Refinement and Patent Claim Scope: A New Perspective on the Doctrine of Equivalents, 93 GEO. L.J. 1947, 1970 (2005). The test was adopted by the Supreme Court in Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co., 535 U.S. 722 (2002).
  • 280
    • 66049142290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Festo, 535 U.S. at 738;
    • See Festo, 535 U.S. at 738;
  • 281
    • 66049160250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lichtman, supra note 133, at 154;
    • Lichtman, supra note 133, at 154;
  • 282
    • 77952629076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard Warburg et al., What Territory Is Surrendered?, 21 BIOTECH. L. REP. 551, 552 (2002).
    • Richard Warburg et al., What Territory Is Surrendered?, 21 BIOTECH. L. REP. 551, 552 (2002).
  • 283
    • 66049136741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Outcome responsibility argues that liability does no more than attribute legal responsibility for specific outcomes to identifiable individuals, as a reflection of the law's basic commitment to human agency and moral authorship of individual actions. See John Gardner, Obligations and Outcomes in the Law of Torts, in RELATING TO RESPONSIBILITY: ESSAYS FOR TONY HONORE ON HIS EIGHTIETH BIRTHDAY 111 (Peter Cane & John Gardner eds, 2001);
    • Outcome responsibility argues that liability does no more than attribute legal responsibility for specific outcomes to identifiable individuals, as a reflection of the law's basic commitment to human agency and moral authorship of individual actions. See John Gardner, Obligations and Outcomes in the Law of Torts, in RELATING TO RESPONSIBILITY: ESSAYS FOR TONY HONORE ON HIS EIGHTIETH BIRTHDAY 111 (Peter Cane & John Gardner eds., 2001);
  • 284
    • 66049109386 scopus 로고
    • Responsibility and Luck, 104 LAW
    • Tony Honore, Responsibility and Luck, 104 LAW Q. REV. 530 (1988).
    • (1988) Q. REV , vol.530
    • Honore, T.1
  • 285
    • 66049145333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professor Stephen Perry, a well-known proponent of outcome responsibility, connects this to the idea of avoidability, that liability should be limited to events and outcomes that might in a sense be considered avoidable ex ante. Avoidability, for Perry, involves an agent having the ability and opportunity to take steps to avoid the harm on the basis of what could have been foreseen. Stephen R. Perry, Responsibility for Outcomes, Risk, and the Law of Torts, in PHILOSOPHY AND THE LAW OF TORTS 72, 91 Gerald J. Postema ed, 2001, Foreseeability thus plays a major role here, based on the notion of epistemic probability, or the idea that individuals base their decisions not on objective assessments of probability, but rather on intersubjective standards of inductive reasoning
    • Professor Stephen Perry, a well-known proponent of outcome responsibility, connects this to the idea of "avoidability" - that liability should be limited to events and outcomes that might in a sense be considered avoidable ex ante. Avoidability, for Perry, involves an agent having the "ability and opportunity to take steps" to avoid the harm "on the basis of what could have been foreseen." Stephen R. Perry, Responsibility for Outcomes, Risk, and the Law of Torts, in PHILOSOPHY AND THE LAW OF TORTS 72, 91 (Gerald J. Postema ed., 2001). Foreseeability thus plays a major role here, based on the notion of "epistemic probability" - or the idea that individuals base their decisions not on objective assessments of probability, but rather on intersubjective standards of inductive reasoning.
  • 286
    • 66049119693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 97-98. To impose liability for (that is, to have people internalize the costs or benefits of) events that were not objectively avoidable then becomes a matter of chance, or a windfall, since it bears no connection to the actor's actual behavior.
    • Id. at 97-98. To impose liability for (that is, to have people internalize the costs or benefits of) events that were not objectively avoidable then becomes a matter of chance, or a windfall, since it bears no connection to the actor's actual behavior.
  • 287
    • 66049126027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wendy J. Gordon, On Owning Information: Intellectual Property and the Restitutionary Impulse, 78 VA. L. REV. 149, 238 & n. 337 (1992) [hereinafter Gordon, On Owning Information]. Gordon does not specify what foreseeability might indeed come to mean in the copyright context (specifically given its use elsewhere) and seems to equate foreseeability with the idea of expected markets, thereby converting it into a subjective test, specific to individual creators. Gordon, supra note 14, at 1385 (internal quotation marks omitted);
    • Wendy J. Gordon, On Owning Information: Intellectual Property and the Restitutionary Impulse, 78 VA. L. REV. 149, 238 & n. 337 (1992) [hereinafter Gordon, On Owning Information]. Gordon does not specify what foreseeability might indeed come to mean in the copyright context (specifically given its use elsewhere) and seems to equate foreseeability with the idea of "expected markets," thereby converting it into a subjective test, specific to individual creators. Gordon, supra note 14, at 1385 (internal quotation marks omitted);
  • 288
    • 66049127235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also
    • see also id. at 1385 nn. 192-93;
    • at 1385 nn , pp. 192-193
  • 289
    • 66049161811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gordon, On Owning Information, supra, at 238 n. 337. She does note, however, that the idea is perhaps desirable in the abstract since new markets might be irrelevant to creative incentives.
    • Gordon, On Owning Information, supra, at 238 n. 337. She does note, however, that the idea is "perhaps desirable in the abstract" since new markets might be irrelevant to creative incentives.
  • 290
    • 0037872065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 238. Interestingly, Gordon recognizes in her later work that the idea of foreseeability as used in tort law does represent an outer limit to incentives. However, she argues that copyright's limited term gives effect to this limit independently, seemingly obviating the need for its independent incorporation into copyright doctrine. See Wendy J. Gordon, Copyright As Tort Law's Mirror Image: Harms, Benefits, and the Uses and Limits of Analogy, 34 MCGEORGE L, REV. 533, 538-39 (2003, In a similar vein, Landes and Posner note that eliminating unforeseen markets from the copyright entitlement is likely to dampen creator incentives since an incentive ordinarily extends to a class of markets. William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Indefinitely Renewable Copyright, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 471, 476 n. 14 (2003, It would appear that an objective as opposed to subjective
    • Id. at 238. Interestingly, Gordon recognizes in her later work that the idea of foreseeability as used in tort law does represent an outer limit to incentives. However, she argues that copyright's limited term gives effect to this limit independently, seemingly obviating the need for its independent incorporation into copyright doctrine. See Wendy J. Gordon, Copyright As Tort Law's Mirror Image: "Harms," "Benefits, " and the Uses and Limits of Analogy, 34 MCGEORGE L, REV. 533, 538-39 (2003). In a similar vein, Landes and Posner note that eliminating "unforeseen" markets from the copyright entitlement is likely to dampen creator incentives since an incentive ordinarily extends to a "class of markets." William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Indefinitely Renewable Copyright, 70 U. CHI. L. REV. 471, 476 n. 14 (2003). It would appear that an objective (as opposed to subjective) foreseeability test would function precisely in this manner, allowing a creator to capture not just present markets, but also those cognately related to them.
  • 291
    • 66049118374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shyamkrishna Balganesh, Rethinking Copyright: Property Through the Lenses of Unjust Enrichment and Unfair C mpetition, 156 U. PA. L. REV. PENNUMBRA 345, 349-50 & n. 23 (2008), http://www.pennumbra. com/responses/01-2008/Balganesh.pdf;
    • See Shyamkrishna Balganesh, Rethinking Copyright: Property Through the Lenses of Unjust Enrichment and Unfair C mpetition, 156 U. PA. L. REV. PENNUMBRA 345, 349-50 & n. 23 (2008), http://www.pennumbra. com/responses/01-2008/Balganesh.pdf;
  • 292
    • 66049103473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Christina Bohannan, Copyright Harm, Foreseeability, and Fair Use, 85 WASH. U. L. REV. 969, 973-74 (2007) (using the idea indirectly in arguing that the fair use analysis should focus on the occurrence or absence of copyright harm to the plaintiff).
    • see also Christina Bohannan, Copyright Harm, Foreseeability, and Fair Use, 85 WASH. U. L. REV. 969, 973-74 (2007) (using the idea indirectly in arguing that the fair use analysis should focus on the occurrence or absence of "copyright harm" to the plaintiff).
  • 293
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 101 2006
    • See 17 U.S.C. § 101 (2006).
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 294
    • 84868946222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. §§ 106, 501.
    • §§ , vol.106 , pp. 501
  • 295
    • 84868946223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.01, at 13-4 to -5.
    • See 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.01, at 13-4 to -5.
  • 296
    • 84868951133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 13.01[A]
    • See
    • See id. § 13.01[A], at 13-6 to -7.
    • at 13-6 to -7
  • 297
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 410c, 411
    • 17 U.S.C. §§ 410(c), 411.
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 298
    • 34548062973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4, note 42, § 13.01[B, at, to -9
    • 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.01[B], at 13-8 to -9.
    • supra , pp. 13-18
    • NIMMER1    NIMMER2
  • 299
    • 66049128972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hindsight bias is a phenomenon that many scholars argue influences the infringement question in all of intellectual property law. See infra section V.D, pp. 1630-32
    • Hindsight bias is a phenomenon that many scholars argue influences the infringement question in all of intellectual property law. See infra section V.D., pp. 1630-32.
  • 300
    • 66049149149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Benn v. Thomas, 512 N.W.2d 537 (Iowa 1994);
    • See Benn v. Thomas, 512 N.W.2d 537 (Iowa 1994);
  • 301
    • 66049099462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vosberg v. Putney, 47 N.W. 99 (Wis. 1890).
    • Vosberg v. Putney, 47 N.W. 99 (Wis. 1890).
  • 302
    • 66049111650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Bohannan, supra note 138, at 1003 (attempting to understand copyright harm as foreseeable harm). Professor Christina Bohannan seems to implicitly connect the idea to inferences of market substitutability. As a consequence, foreseeability ceases to function as an independent behavioral limit, since unforeseeable uses in her model could still form part of the entitlement upon an independent showing of substitution.
    • See, e.g., Bohannan, supra note 138, at 1003 (attempting to understand copyright harm as "foreseeable harm"). Professor Christina Bohannan seems to implicitly connect the idea to inferences of market substitutability. As a consequence, foreseeability ceases to function as an independent behavioral limit, since unforeseeable uses in her model could still form part of the entitlement upon an independent showing of substitution.
  • 303
    • 66049131278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 989.
    • See id. at 989.
  • 304
    • 0347891948 scopus 로고
    • Of Harms and Benefits: Torts, Restitution, and Intellectual Property, 21
    • For a useful discussion of some of these ideas as applied to copyright, see
    • For a useful discussion of some of these ideas as applied to copyright, see Wendy J. Gordon, Of Harms and Benefits: Torts, Restitution, and Intellectual Property, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 449 (1992).
    • (1992) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.449
    • Gordon, W.J.1
  • 305
    • 66049123946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Band, supra note 66, at 6
    • See Band, supra note 66, at 6.
  • 306
    • 73849092129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 3, note 42, § 12.11[F
    • 3 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 12.11[F].
    • supra
    • NIMMER1    NIMMER2
  • 307
    • 84926280966 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Market Definition: An Integrated Approach, 72
    • See generally
    • See generally Robert G. Harris & Thomas M. Jorde, Antitrust Market Definition: An Integrated Approach, 72 CAL. L. REV. 1 (1984);
    • (1984) CAL. L. REV , vol.1
    • Harris, R.G.1    Jorde, T.M.2
  • 308
    • 84875128652 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, 94 HARV. L. REV. 937 (1981).
    • (1981) HARV. L. REV , vol.937
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 309
    • 66049096144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Harris & Jorde, supra note 151, at 18-19
    • See Harris & Jorde, supra note 151, at 18-19.
  • 310
    • 66049133399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This might be graphically represented by the following table: Table Presented It is also perhaps worth mentioning that situations in Scenario 4 typically are also the subject of the transformative use defense under current fair use law. See supra pp. 1585-86. The foreseeable copying test would not replace transformative use, but would posit a preliminary question: whether the creator's entitlement extends to the market for the transformation to begin with in simple terms, a question of whether the specific market for that transformation was foreseeable, Only if the question is answered in the affirmative would the foreseeable copying test allow the transformative use defense to proceed to a social welfare analysis to decide whether to find the existence of infringement or exempt the action as independently creative. Thanks to Adam Badawi and Arden Rowell for discussions that resulted in this table
    • This might be graphically represented by the following table: Table Presented It is also perhaps worth mentioning that situations in Scenario 4 typically are also the subject of the transformative use defense under current fair use law. See supra pp. 1585-86. The foreseeable copying test would not replace transformative use, but would posit a preliminary question: whether the creator's entitlement extends to the market for the transformation to begin with (in simple terms, a question of whether the specific market for that transformation was foreseeable). Only if the question is answered in the affirmative would the foreseeable copying test allow the transformative use defense to proceed to a social welfare analysis to decide whether to find the existence of infringement or exempt the action as independently creative. Thanks to Adam Badawi and Arden Rowell for discussions that resulted in this table.
  • 311
    • 2442473072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harm from market substitution derives largely (if not entirely) from demand diversion, making this distinction very relevant. See Christopher S. Yoo, Copyright and Product Differentiation, 79 N.Y.U. L. REV. 212, 272 (2004) (noting the connection between the two).
    • Harm from market substitution derives largely (if not entirely) from demand diversion, making this distinction very relevant. See Christopher S. Yoo, Copyright and Product Differentiation, 79 N.Y.U. L. REV. 212, 272 (2004) (noting the connection between the two).
  • 312
    • 66049104336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 260
    • Id. at 260.
  • 313
    • 66049163267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sidney A. Rosenzweig, Comment, Don't Put My Article Online!: Extending Copyright's New-Use Doctrine to the Electronic Publishing Media and Beyond, 143 U. PA. L. REV. 899, 915 (1995) (In determining whether the new technology falls within the scope of the explicitly granted or preexisting technology, courts examine the foreseeability of the new medium.).
    • See Sidney A. Rosenzweig, Comment, Don't Put My Article Online!: Extending Copyright's New-Use Doctrine to the Electronic Publishing Media and Beyond, 143 U. PA. L. REV. 899, 915 (1995) ("In determining whether the new technology falls within the scope of the explicitly granted or preexisting technology, courts examine the foreseeability of the new medium.").
  • 314
    • 66049118809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 391 F.2d 150 (2d Cir. 1968). For a more recent application of the doctrine, see Boosey & Hawkes Music Publishers, Ltd. v. Walt Disney Co., 145 F.3d 481, 486 (2d Cir. 1998).
    • 391 F.2d 150 (2d Cir. 1968). For a more recent application of the doctrine, see Boosey & Hawkes Music Publishers, Ltd. v. Walt Disney Co., 145 F.3d 481, 486 (2d Cir. 1998).
  • 315
    • 66049106024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bartsch, 391 F.2d at 154 (finding that the law will not charge a grantor with the duty of expressly saving [some] rights when he could not know of the invention's existence and finding no case holding that an experienced businessman is not bound by the natural implications of the language he accepted when he had reason to know of the new medium's potential).
    • Bartsch, 391 F.2d at 154 (finding that the law "will not charge a grantor with the duty of expressly saving [some] rights when he could not know of the invention's existence" and finding "no case holding that an experienced businessman" is "not bound by the natural implications of the language he accepted when he had reason to know of the new medium's potential").
  • 316
    • 66049146582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bartsch v. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer, Inc., 270 F. Supp. 896, 900 (S.D.N.Y. 1967).
    • Bartsch v. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer, Inc., 270 F. Supp. 896, 900 (S.D.N.Y. 1967).
  • 317
    • 66049144928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 900-01
    • Id. at 900-01.
  • 318
    • 66049084004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bartsch, 391 F.2d at 154.
    • Bartsch, 391 F.2d at 154.
  • 319
    • 66049116813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • for different approaches to this corollary, see, for example, Rey v. Lafferty, 990 F.2d 1379, 1388 (Ist Cir. 1993);
    • for different approaches to this corollary, see, for example, Rey v. Lafferty, 990 F.2d 1379, 1388 (Ist Cir. 1993);
  • 320
    • 66049115072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cohen v. Paramount Pictures Corp., 845 F.2d 851, 854 (9th Cir. 1988);
    • Cohen v. Paramount Pictures Corp., 845 F.2d 851, 854 (9th Cir. 1988);
  • 321
    • 66049122319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ABKCO Music, Inc. v. Westminster Music, Ltd., 838 F. Supp. 153, 156 (S.D.N.Y. 1993);
    • ABKCO Music, Inc. v. Westminster Music, Ltd., 838 F. Supp. 153, 156 (S.D.N.Y. 1993);
  • 322
    • 66049099459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Platinum Record Co. v. Lucasfilm, Ltd., 566 F. Supp. 226, 227 (D.N.J. 1983);
    • Platinum Record Co. v. Lucasfilm, Ltd., 566 F. Supp. 226, 227 (D.N.J. 1983);
  • 323
    • 66049087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Kirke La Shelle Co. v. Paul Armstrong Co., 188 N.E. 163, 165-66 (N.Y. 1933).
    • and Kirke La Shelle Co. v. Paul Armstrong Co., 188 N.E. 163, 165-66 (N.Y. 1933).
  • 324
    • 66049160980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rey, 990 F.2d at 1388 citing Cohen, 845 F.2d at 854;
    • Rey, 990 F.2d at 1388 (citing Cohen, 845 F.2d at 854;
  • 325
    • 66049140918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kirke La Shelle Co., 188 N.E. at 163.
    • Kirke La Shelle Co., 188 N.E. at 163).
  • 326
    • 34548860003 scopus 로고
    • The Bargain Principle and Its Limits, 95
    • See
    • See Melvin Aron Eisenberg, The Bargain Principle and Its Limits, 95 HARV. L. REV. 741 (1982);
    • (1982) HARV. L. REV , vol.741
    • Aron Eisenberg, M.1
  • 327
    • 66049099036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Rosenzweig, supra note 156, at 917 (noting that the open-ended nature of the analysis allows courts to manipulate the determination).
    • cf. Rosenzweig, supra note 156, at 917 (noting that the open-ended nature of the analysis allows courts to "manipulate" the determination).
  • 328
    • 66049085257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cohen, 845 F.2d at 854 (quoting Neil R. Nagano, Comment, Past Copyright Licenses and the New Video Software Medium, 29 UCLA L. REV. 1160, 1184 (1982)) (internal quotation mark omitted).
    • Cohen, 845 F.2d at 854 (quoting Neil R. Nagano, Comment, Past Copyright Licenses and the New Video Software Medium, 29 UCLA L. REV. 1160, 1184 (1982)) (internal quotation mark omitted).
  • 329
    • 66049120237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, much of contract law has concerned itself with the move from a model of subjective intention to one of objective intention, which some view as in itself problematic and detracting from contract law's avowed emphasis on the ideas of consent and party autonomy. For more on objective intention in construing contractual terms, see
    • Indeed, much of contract law has concerned itself with the move from a model of subjective intention to one of objective intention, which some view as in itself problematic and detracting from contract law's avowed emphasis on the ideas of consent and party autonomy. For more on objective intention in construing contractual terms, see LARRY A. DIMATTEO, CONTRACT THEORY: THE EVOLUTION OF CONTRACTUAL INTENT (1998);
    • (1998)
    • DIMATTEO, L.A.1    THEORY, C.2    EVOLUTION, T.3    CONTRACTUAL INTENT, O.4
  • 330
    • 66049090084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LON L. FULLER & MELVIN ARON EISENBERG, BASIC CONTRACT LAW 743-46 (7th ed. 2001);
    • LON L. FULLER & MELVIN ARON EISENBERG, BASIC CONTRACT LAW 743-46 (7th ed. 2001);
  • 331
    • 66049101786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Larry A. DiMatteo, The Counterpoise of Contracts: The Reasonable Person Standard and the Subjectivity of Judgment, 48 S.C. L. REV. 293 (1997);
    • Larry A. DiMatteo, The Counterpoise of Contracts: The Reasonable Person Standard and the Subjectivity of Judgment, 48 S.C. L. REV. 293 (1997);
  • 332
    • 66049137744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Nancy Kim, Mistakes, Changed Circumstances and Intent, 56 U. KAN. L. REV. 473 (2008).
    • and Nancy Kim, Mistakes, Changed Circumstances and Intent, 56 U. KAN. L. REV. 473 (2008).
  • 333
    • 33947306484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 103(a, 2006, For more on the PHOSITA standard, see Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Obvious to Whom? Evaluating Inventions from the Perspective of PHOSITA, 19 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 885 2004
    • 35 U.S.C. § 103(a) (2006). For more on the PHOSITA standard, see Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Obvious to Whom? Evaluating Inventions from the Perspective of PHOSITA, 19 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 885 (2004).
    • 35 U.S.C
  • 334
    • 66049098278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See In re Kotzab, 217 F.3d 1365, 1369 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (noting the importance of relying on then-accepted wisdom in the field in making the determination);
    • See In re Kotzab, 217 F.3d 1365, 1369 (Fed. Cir. 2000) (noting the importance of relying on "then-accepted wisdom in the field" in making the determination);
  • 335
    • 66049101781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Dembiczak, 175 F.3d 994, 999 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (noting the importance of casting the mind back to the time of invention);
    • In re Dembiczak, 175 F.3d 994, 999 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (noting the importance of "casting the mind back to the time of invention");
  • 336
    • 66049160982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kloster Speedsteel AB v. Crucible Inc., 793 F.2d 1565, 1574 (Fed. Cir. 1986) (emphasizing the importance of focusing the decisionmaker's mind on what would have been obvious when the invention was made).
    • Kloster Speedsteel AB v. Crucible Inc., 793 F.2d 1565, 1574 (Fed. Cir. 1986) (emphasizing the importance of focusing the decisionmaker's mind on what would have been obvious "when the invention was made").
  • 337
    • 66049117934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The hypothetical here tracks the facts of a well-known licensing dispute, in which the question was whether the grant of television rights covered the right to distribute the content on vid-eocassettes. The court, using a foreseeability standard, answered the question in the negative. Cohen, 845 F.2d at 851.
    • The hypothetical here tracks the facts of a well-known licensing dispute, in which the question was whether the grant of television rights covered the right to distribute the content on vid-eocassettes. The court, using a foreseeability standard, answered the question in the negative. Cohen, 845 F.2d at 851.
  • 338
    • 66049147443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 854.
    • See id. at 854.
  • 339
    • 66049104749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A secondary, yet important, question relates to the defendant's - that is, N's - own creativity and the way in which the copyright system needs to evaluate that as part of the process. Once foreseeable copying works to delineate a creator's incentive-driven markets, the analysis of whether the social utility from N's creation is enough reason to generate an exception, in light of the costs and benefits of giving a creator control over it, is best accomplished by the traditional fair use analysis.
    • A secondary, yet important, question relates to the defendant's - that is, N's - own creativity and the way in which the copyright system needs to evaluate that as part of the process. Once foreseeable copying works to delineate a creator's incentive-driven markets, the analysis of whether the social utility from N's creation is enough reason to generate an exception, in light of the costs and benefits of giving a creator control over it, is best accomplished by the traditional fair use analysis.
  • 340
    • 66049096593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the Supreme Court seems to have adopted precisely such an argument in its validation of the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act. See Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U.S. 186, 215 (2003). The Court there recognized the possibility of future term extensions forming a part of copyright's incentive structure. In addition, the Court referred to Congress's consistent historical practice of extending copyright's term and applying the extension retroactively.
    • Indeed, the Supreme Court seems to have adopted precisely such an argument in its validation of the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act. See Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U.S. 186, 215 (2003). The Court there recognized the possibility of future term extensions forming a part of copyright's incentive structure. In addition, the Court referred to Congress's "consistent historical practice" of extending copyright's term and applying the extension retroactively.
  • 341
    • 66049154639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 204
    • Id. at 204.
  • 342
    • 66049154194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To the extent that it is indeed grounded in an awareness of the industry in question and technological developments therein, it is likely to be characterized as foreseeable under the standard and test described earlier. The discussion here, therefore, is restricted to predictions and expectations that are not grounded in such an awareness
    • To the extent that it is indeed grounded in an awareness of the industry in question and technological developments therein, it is likely to be characterized as foreseeable under the standard and test described earlier. The discussion here, therefore, is restricted to predictions and expectations that are not grounded in such an awareness.
  • 343
    • 33947310729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stadler, supra note 30, at 454-56. For a slightly different argument on how expectations influence risk aversion, thereby feeding back into the scope of the rights granted, see James Gibson, Risk Aversion and Rights Accretion in Intellectual Property Law, 116 YALE L.J. 882 (2007).
    • Stadler, supra note 30, at 454-56. For a slightly different argument on how expectations influence risk aversion, thereby feeding back into the scope of the rights granted, see James Gibson, Risk Aversion and Rights Accretion in Intellectual Property Law, 116 YALE L.J. 882 (2007).
  • 344
    • 66049117118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stadler, supra note 30, at 440
    • Stadler, supra note 30, at 440.
  • 345
    • 84909430670 scopus 로고
    • The Model of Rules, 35
    • For an overview of the rule-standard distinction, see
    • For an overview of the rule-standard distinction, see Ronald Dworkin, The Model of Rules, 35 U. CHI. L. REV. 14, 22-29 (1967);
    • (1967) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.14 , pp. 22-29
    • Dworkin, R.1
  • 346
    • 21144468370 scopus 로고
    • Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42
    • Louis Kaplow, Rules Versus Standards: An Economic Analysis, 42 DUKE L.J. 557 (1992);
    • (1992) DUKE L.J , vol.557
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 347
    • 0001272681 scopus 로고
    • Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication, 89
    • Duncan Kennedy, Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication, 89 HARV. L. REV. 1685, 1687-1701 (1976);
    • (1976) HARV. L. REV , vol.1685 , pp. 1687-1701
    • Kennedy, D.1
  • 348
    • 33846647656 scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court, 1991 Term - Foreword: The Justices of Rules and Standards, 106
    • Kathleen M. Sullivan, The Supreme Court, 1991 Term - Foreword: The Justices of Rules and Standards, 106 HARV. L. REV. 22 (1992);
    • (1992) HARV. L. REV , vol.22
    • Sullivan, K.M.1
  • 349
    • 33846583791 scopus 로고
    • Problems with Rules, 83
    • and Cass R. Sunstein, Problems with Rules, 83 CAL. L. REV. 953 (1995).
    • (1995) CAL. L. REV , vol.953
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 350
    • 66049153434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kaplow, supra note 176, at 560
    • See Kaplow, supra note 176, at 560.
  • 351
    • 66049130890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 353
    • 0041669218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This distinction between rules and standards translates most directly into the difference between the strategies of exclusion and governance that property law uses to allocate and enforce its grant of rights. See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion Versus Governance: Two Strategies for Delineating Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S453 2002, Exclusion strategies such as trespass, much like rules, entail high upfront delineation costs and low ex post enforcement costs, while governance strategies such as nuisance do just the opposite
    • This distinction between rules and standards translates most directly into the difference between the strategies of "exclusion" and "governance" that property law uses to allocate and enforce its grant of rights. See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion Versus Governance: Two Strategies for Delineating Property Rights, 31 J. LEGAL STUD. S453 (2002). Exclusion strategies such as trespass, much like rules, entail high upfront delineation costs and low ex post enforcement costs, while governance strategies such as nuisance do just the opposite.
  • 354
    • 3042734240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusion and Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90
    • Governance strategies enable courts to carry out balancing exercises as circumstances demand and thereby contextualize the entitlement to an exogenously defined purpose. See
    • See Henry E. Smith, Exclusion and Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90 VA. L. REV. 965 (2004). Governance strategies enable courts to carry out balancing exercises as circumstances demand and thereby contextualize the entitlement to an exogenously defined purpose.
    • (2004) VA. L. REV , vol.965
    • Smith, H.E.1
  • 355
    • 66049157554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Carroll identifies this as the problem of uniformity cost in intellectual property law and notes that context-specific standards serve to minimize these costs. See Michael W. Carroll, One For All: The Problem of Uniformity Cost in Intellectual Property Law, 55 AM. U. L. REV. 845, 856-61, 890-92 (2006).
    • Michael Carroll identifies this as the problem of "uniformity cost" in intellectual property law and notes that context-specific standards serve to minimize these costs. See Michael W. Carroll, One For All: The Problem of Uniformity Cost in Intellectual Property Law, 55 AM. U. L. REV. 845, 856-61, 890-92 (2006).
  • 356
    • 0346053795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is seen most prominently in the absence of an independent invention defense and a fair use limitation in patent law. For more on this, see Maureen A. O'Rourke, Toward a Doctrine of Fair Use in Patent Law, 100 COLUM. L. REV. 1177, 1184-87 2000
    • This is seen most prominently in the absence of an independent invention defense and a fair use limitation in patent law. For more on this, see Maureen A. O'Rourke, Toward a Doctrine of Fair Use in Patent Law, 100 COLUM. L. REV. 1177, 1184-87 (2000).
  • 357
    • 22144437353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Probabilistic Patents, 19
    • On the probabilistic nature of property and intellectual property rights, see
    • On the probabilistic nature of property and intellectual property rights, see Mark A. Lemley & Carl Shapiro, Probabilistic Patents, 19 J. ECON. PERSP. 75 (2005);
    • (2005) J. ECON. PERSP , vol.75
    • Lemley, M.A.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 358
    • 66049099033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Probabilistic Nature of
    • Patent Rights: In Response to Kevin McDonald, ANTITRUST, Summer 2003, at 77
    • and Keith Leffler & Cristo-fer Leffler, The Probabilistic Nature of Patent Rights: In Response to Kevin McDonald, ANTITRUST, Summer 2003, at 77.
    • Leffler, K.1    Leffler, C.-F.2
  • 359
    • 0042361801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Limiting Patentees' Market Power Without Reducing Innovation Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive Remedies, 97
    • See
    • See Ian Ayres & Paul Klemperer, Limiting Patentees' Market Power Without Reducing Innovation Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive Remedies, 97 MICH. L. REV. 985 (1999).
    • (1999) MICH. L. REV , vol.985
    • Ayres, I.1    Klemperer, P.2
  • 360
    • 66049096141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1025
    • Id. at 1025.
  • 361
    • 66049122763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1025-26.
  • 362
    • 66049151777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1001
    • Id. at 1001.
  • 363
    • 66049113314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1026-27. Ramsey pricing involves pricing goods inversely to the elasticity of demand for the firm's products but without a profit constraint. See LANDES & POSNER, supra note 20, at 40 n. 6. Translated to the intellectual property context, this concept implies that if a monopolist's profits are held constant, consumers would be better off living under oligopolistic pricing for a longer period than monopoly pricing for a shorter period. Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 184, at 991. The deadweight losses, then, get spread over a long duration, but their severity at any given point in time is reduced.
    • Id. at 1026-27. Ramsey pricing involves pricing goods inversely to the elasticity of demand for the firm's products but without a profit constraint. See LANDES & POSNER, supra note 20, at 40 n. 6. Translated to the intellectual property context, this concept implies that if a monopolist's profits are held constant, "consumers would be better off living under oligopolistic pricing for a longer period than monopoly pricing for a shorter period." Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 184, at 991. The deadweight losses, then, get spread over a long duration, but their severity at any given point in time is reduced.
  • 364
    • 66049099897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 184, at 1026-28
    • Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 184, at 1026-28.
  • 365
    • 66049128973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 989-90. This is the intuition that small deviations from a monopolist's profit-maximizing price or quantity will have less of an effect on a monopolist's overall benefits, but wili have a larger effect on minimizing deadweight losses, thereby producing a net welfare gain.
    • See id. at 989-90. This is the intuition that small deviations from a monopolist's profit-maximizing price or quantity will have less of an effect on a monopolist's overall benefits, but wili have a larger effect on minimizing deadweight losses, thereby producing a net welfare gain.
  • 366
    • 66049138569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Merges, Intellectual Property Rights and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents, 62 TENN. L. REV. 75, 101-03 (1994).
    • Robert Merges, Intellectual Property Rights and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents, 62 TENN. L. REV. 75, 101-03 (1994).
  • 367
    • 66049149986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Michael J. Meurer & Craig Allen Nard, Invention, Refinement and Patent Claim Scope: A New Perspective on the Doctrine of Equivalents, 93 GEO. L.J. 1947, 1996-97 (2005);
    • See Michael J. Meurer & Craig Allen Nard, Invention, Refinement and Patent Claim Scope: A New Perspective on the Doctrine of Equivalents, 93 GEO. L.J. 1947, 1996-97 (2005);
  • 368
    • 0042526807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patent Scope and Innovation in the Software Industry, 89
    • see also
    • see also Julie E. Cohen & Mark A. Lemley, Patent Scope and Innovation in the Software Industry, 89 CAL. L. REV. 1, 50 (2001).
    • (2001) CAL. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 50
    • Cohen, J.E.1    Lemley, M.A.2
  • 369
    • 66049102199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Meurer & Nard, supra note 192, at 1997
    • Meurer & Nard, supra note 192, at 1997.
  • 370
    • 66049098605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1998
    • Id. at 1998.
  • 371
    • 84888708325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 107 2006
    • See 17 U.S.C. § 107 (2006).
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 372
    • 0346053745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Douglas Lichtman, Property Rights in Emerging Platform Technologies, 29 J. LEGAL STUD. 615, 637-38 (2000) observing that fair use excuses infringement whenever public policy favors that result,
    • See Douglas Lichtman, Property Rights in Emerging Platform Technologies, 29 J. LEGAL STUD. 615, 637-38 (2000) (observing that fair use excuses infringement whenever "public policy favors that result,"
  • 374
    • 66049119689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 638
    • id. at 638).
  • 375
    • 66049092279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To the contrary, the dominant view appears to be that the fair use doctrine stifles innovation by not allowing defendants sufficient leeway to use protected works. See, e.g., Kevin M. Lemley, The Innovative Medium Defense: A Doctrine To Promote the Multiple Goals of Copyright in the Wake of Advancing Digital Technologies, 110 PENN. ST. L. REV. III, 128-29 (2005);
    • To the contrary, the dominant view appears to be that the fair use doctrine stifles innovation by not allowing defendants sufficient leeway to use protected works. See, e.g., Kevin M. Lemley, The Innovative Medium Defense: A Doctrine To Promote the Multiple Goals of Copyright in the Wake of Advancing Digital Technologies, 110 PENN. ST. L. REV. III, 128-29 (2005);
  • 376
    • 0006228874 scopus 로고
    • Fair Use and New Technology: The Appropriate Standards To Apply, 5
    • Adrienne J. Marsh, Fair Use and New Technology: The Appropriate Standards To Apply, 5 CARDOZO L. REV. 635, 643-44 (1984).
    • (1984) CARDOZO L. REV , vol.635 , pp. 643-644
    • Marsh, A.J.1
  • 377
    • 66049112490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Parchomovsky & Goldman, supra note 179, at 1498 (noting that the vagueness of the fair use standard causes actors to err on the side of safety and either overcomply (by minimizing the use of protected works) or overinvest in precautions).
    • See Parchomovsky & Goldman, supra note 179, at 1498 (noting that "the vagueness of the fair use standard" causes actors to "err on the side of safety and either overcomply (by minimizing the use of protected works) or overinvest in precautions").
  • 378
    • 66049090087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 184, at 1024 (noting how underinclusive standards are preferable to rules and overinclusive standards). Quite apart from interfering with creator incentives, replacing the current standards-based approach with a rule-based one would also likely alter a copyright owner's willingness to bargain with a potential user, as a consequence of the uncertainty being eliminated altogether.
    • See Ayres & Klemperer, supra note 184, at 1024 (noting how underinclusive standards are preferable to rules and overinclusive standards). Quite apart from interfering with creator incentives, replacing the current standards-based approach with a rule-based one would also likely alter a copyright owner's willingness to bargain with a potential user, as a consequence of the uncertainty being eliminated altogether.
  • 379
    • 2442520043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Muddy Rules for Cyberspace, 21
    • See
    • See Dan L. Burk, Muddy Rules for Cyberspace, 21 CARDOZO L. REV. 121, 140 (1999);
    • (1999) CARDOZO L. REV , vol.121 , pp. 140
    • Burk, D.L.1
  • 380
    • 21844484742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Jason Scott Johnston, Bargaining Under Rules Versus Standards, II J.L. ECON. & ORG. 256, 258 (199s). But cf. Parchomovsky & Goldman, supra note 179, at 1502 (advocating the introduction of specific contextual fair use rules into copyright doctrine).
    • cf. Jason Scott Johnston, Bargaining Under Rules Versus Standards, II J.L. ECON. & ORG. 256, 258 (199s). But cf. Parchomovsky & Goldman, supra note 179, at 1502 (advocating the introduction of specific contextual fair use rules into copyright doctrine).
  • 381
    • 66049134236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The prospect theory is attributed to the work of Professor Edmund Kitch. See Edmund W. Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & ECON. 265 1977
    • The prospect theory is attributed to the work of Professor Edmund Kitch. See Edmund W. Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & ECON. 265 (1977);
  • 382
    • 2942520956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking the Prospect Theory of Patents, 71
    • This theory bears no connection to the prospect theory in behavioral economics. see also
    • see also John F. Duffy, Rethinking the Prospect Theory of Patents, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 439 (2004). This theory bears no connection to the prospect theory in behavioral economics.
    • (2004) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.439
    • Duffy, J.F.1
  • 383
    • 41849121718 scopus 로고
    • Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk, 47
    • See
    • See Daniel Kahneman & Amos Tversky, Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk, 47 ECONOMETRICA 263 (1979).
    • (1979) ECONOMETRICA , vol.263
    • Kahneman, D.1    Tversky, A.2
  • 384
    • 66049118372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kitch, supra note 200, at 266
    • Kitch, supra note 200, at 266.
  • 385
    • 0345984391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75 TEX. L. REV. 989, 1047 (1997) (While Kitch makes his argument in the patent context, it is copyright rather than patent law that seems to have taken his theory to heart.). Professor Michael Abramowicz argues that the dominant theme in the prospect theory is the idea of avoiding wasteful rent dissipation, and attempts to use it to explain copyright law's protection for derivative works.
    • See Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75 TEX. L. REV. 989, 1047 (1997) ("While Kitch makes his argument in the patent context, it is copyright rather than patent law that seems to have taken his theory to heart."). Professor Michael Abramowicz argues that the dominant theme in the prospect theory is the idea of avoiding wasteful rent dissipation, and attempts to use it to explain copyright law's protection for derivative works.
  • 386
    • 31144432380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Copyright's Derivative Right and Related Doctrines, 90
    • See
    • See Michael Abramowicz, A Theory of Copyright's Derivative Right and Related Doctrines, 90 MINN. L. REV. 317, 351, 355-56 (2005).
    • (2005) MINN. L. REV , vol.317 , Issue.351 , pp. 355-356
    • Abramowicz, M.1
  • 387
    • 1842764749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property, 71
    • describing the use of this theory to justify copyright's retrospective term extension under the CTEA, See
    • See Mark A. Lemley, Ex Ante Versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property, 71 U. CHI. L. REV. 129, 132-35 (2004) (describing the use of this theory to justify copyright's retrospective term extension under the CTEA).
    • (2004) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.129 , pp. 132-135
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 388
    • 66049155077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 132
    • Id. at 132.
  • 389
    • 66049087095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 135-36. As Professor Mark Lemley rightly notes, this logic flies in the face of the fundamental idea that competition - and deconcentration in markets - is preferable for simple efficiency reasons
    • Id. at 135-36. As Professor Mark Lemley rightly notes, this logic flies in the face of the fundamental idea that competition - and deconcentration in markets - is preferable for simple efficiency reasons. Indeed, this principle dominates antitrust law's prohibition on tying and other forms of exclusive dealing arrangements.
    • Indeed, this principle dominates antitrust law's prohibition on tying and other forms of exclusive dealing arrangements
  • 390
    • 0002268909 scopus 로고
    • Tying Arrangements and the Leverage Problem, 67
    • For a few academic articles discussing tying, see
    • For a few academic articles discussing tying, see Ward S. Bowman, Jr., Tying Arrangements and the Leverage Problem, 67 YALE L.J. 19 (1957);
    • (1957) YALE L.J , vol.19
    • Bowman Jr., W.S.1
  • 391
    • 0842279661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tying and Innovation: A Dynamic Analysis of Tying Arrangements, 114
    • Jay Pil Choi, Tying and Innovation: A Dynamic Analysis of Tying Arrangements, 114 ECON. J. 83 (2004);
    • (2004) ECON. J , vol.83
    • Pil Choi, J.1
  • 392
    • 0035730228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision-Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 469 (2001).
    • and Keith N. Hylton & Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision-Theoretic Approach, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 469 (2001).
  • 393
    • 66049101783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley, supra note 203, at 137 & n. 29. He notes: Creators are often terrible managers. They frequently misunderstand the significance of their own invention and the uses to which it can be put.
    • See Lemley, supra note 203, at 137 & n. 29. He notes: "Creators are often terrible managers. They frequently misunderstand the significance of their own invention and the uses to which it can be put."
  • 394
    • 66049124763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 137
    • Id. at 137.
  • 395
    • 66049123517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See cases cited supra note 3
    • See cases cited supra note 3.
  • 396
    • 66049132535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, a new set of rights referred to as neighboring rights or related rights attempts to do precisely this by giving distributors exclusionary control over their investments. See Shyam-krishna Balganesh, The Social Costs of Property Rights in Broadcast (and Cable) Signals, 22 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1303, 1305-06 (2008). The most well-known neighboring rights are performers' rights, phonogram producers' rights, and broadcasters' rights.
    • Indeed, a new set of rights referred to as "neighboring rights" or "related rights" attempts to do precisely this by giving distributors exclusionary control over their investments. See Shyam-krishna Balganesh, The Social Costs of Property Rights in Broadcast (and Cable) Signals, 22 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1303, 1305-06 (2008). The most well-known neighboring rights are performers' rights, phonogram producers' rights, and broadcasters' rights.
  • 397
    • 66049094846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. passim;
    • See id. passim;
  • 398
    • 66049110658 scopus 로고
    • Protection of Neighboring Rights
    • Winter, at
    • George H.C. Bodenhausen, Protection of "Neighboring Rights," LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., Winter 1954, at 156.
    • (1954) LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS , pp. 156
    • Bodenhausen, G.H.C.1
  • 399
    • 84868940861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 202, at 352 In the absence of patent protection ⋯ [m]ore inventors may pursue a particular line of research than is socially optimal
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 202, at 352 ("In the absence of patent protection ⋯ [m]ore inventors may pursue a particular line of research than is socially optimal.").
  • 400
    • 0002322382 scopus 로고
    • Patent Law and Rent Dissipation, 78
    • See
    • See Mark F. Grady & Jay I. Alexander, Patent Law and Rent Dissipation, 78 VA. L. REV. 305, 318-20 (1992).
    • (1992) VA. L. REV , vol.305 , pp. 318-320
    • Grady, M.F.1    Alexander, J.I.2
  • 401
    • 2442452768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the doctrine and an economic explanation for it in terms of information cost theory, see Clarisa Long, Information Costs in Patent and Copyright, 90 VA. L. REV. 465, 528-29 (2004);
    • For an overview of the doctrine and an economic explanation for it in terms of information cost theory, see Clarisa Long, Information Costs in Patent and Copyright, 90 VA. L. REV. 465, 528-29 (2004);
  • 402
    • 34250678122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Intellectual Property As Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information, 116
    • and Henry E. Smith, Intellectual Property As Property: Delineating Entitlements in Information, 116 YALE L.J. 1742, 1810-11 (2007).
    • (2007) YALE L.J , vol.1742 , pp. 1810-1811
    • Smith, H.E.1
  • 403
    • 33845900231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Independent Invention As a Defense to
    • For an attempt to extend the idea to patent law, see, Patent Infringement, 105 MICH. L. REV. 475 2006
    • For an attempt to extend the idea to patent law, see Samson Vermont, Independent Invention As a Defense to Patent Infringement, 105 MICH. L. REV. 475 (2006).
    • Vermont, S.1
  • 404
    • 66049120658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 202, at 355 referring to the idea-expression dichotomy in copyright
    • See Abramowicz, supra note 202, at 355 (referring to the idea-expression dichotomy in copyright).
  • 405
    • 66049150504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the system would not want inventors to disclose information such that other systems of intellectual property (that is, patents and trade secrets) might later deny them protection. An alternative might thus be a mechanism for creators to make these disclosures to an administrative agency under conditions of secrecy; here, however, the social benefits of the disclosure are unlikely to be realized
    • Of course, the system would not want inventors to disclose information such that other systems of intellectual property (that is, patents and trade secrets) might later deny them protection. An alternative might thus be a mechanism for creators to make these disclosures to an administrative agency under conditions of secrecy; here, however, the social benefits of the disclosure are unlikely to be realized.
  • 406
    • 66049088395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Zipursky, supra note 108, at 47 noting how the acquisition of such information is socially inefficient
    • See Zipursky, supra note 108, at 47 (noting how the acquisition of such information is "socially inefficient").
  • 407
    • 0000949337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lucian Ayre Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284, 286 (1991) (observing that when one party's communication of information to the other is socially desirable, the foreseeability requirement in Hadley provides an incentive for it).
    • See Lucian Ayre Bebchuk & Steven Shavell, Information and the Scope of Liability for Breach of Contract: The Rule of Hadley v. Baxendale, 7 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 284, 286 (1991) (observing that when one party's communication of information to the other is "socially desirable," the foreseeability requirement in Hadley provides an incentive for it).
  • 408
    • 84868940860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 302 2006, For anonymous works, the term of protection is 95 years from the year of first publication, or 120 years from the year of its first creation, whichever expires earlier
    • 17 U.S.C. § 302 (2006). For anonymous works, the term of protection is 95 years from the year of first publication, or 120 years from the year of its first creation, whichever expires earlier.
    • 17 U.S.C
  • 409
    • 84868958916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 302(c). The most recent extension, the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act (CTEA), was the subject matter of a well-known Supreme Court decision. See Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U.S. 186 (2003).
    • Id. § 302(c). The most recent extension, the Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act (CTEA), was the subject matter of a well-known Supreme Court decision. See Eldred v. Ashcroft, 537 U.S. 186 (2003).
  • 410
    • 66049139114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Smith, note 211, at, discussing these differences
    • See Smith, supra note 211, at 1806-14 (discussing these differences);
    • supra , pp. 1806-1814
  • 411
    • 66049098607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also William M. Landes & Richard Posner, An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law, in ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE LAW 83, 94-96 (Donald A. Wittman ed., 2003).
    • see also William M. Landes & Richard Posner, An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law, in ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE LAW 83, 94-96 (Donald A. Wittman ed., 2003).
  • 412
    • 66049151414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Smith, supra note 211, at 1812
    • See Smith, supra note 211, at 1812.
  • 413
    • 66049098280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carroll, supra note 181, at 852-56;
    • See Carroll, supra note 181, at 852-56;
  • 414
    • 66049113712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., Patent Law, the Federal Circuit, and the Supreme Court: A Quiet Revolution, 11 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 1, 5 (2004).
    • see also Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., Patent Law, the Federal Circuit, and the Supreme Court: A Quiet Revolution, 11 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 1, 5 (2004).
  • 415
    • 49049118681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 181, at, distinguishing between Type I and Type II errors associated with uniformity
    • See Carroll, supra note 181, at 856-57 (distinguishing between Type I and Type II errors associated with uniformity).
    • supra , pp. 856-857
    • Carroll1
  • 416
    • 66049140489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Perry, supra note 137, at 99-101;
    • See Perry, supra note 137, at 99-101;
  • 417
    • 0346982697 scopus 로고
    • Beyond Foreseeability: Consequential Damages in the Law of Contract, 18
    • noting how foreseeability utterly lacks the descriptive content that allows it to be the principled basis for decision, see also
    • see also Richard A. Epstein, Beyond Foreseeability: Consequential Damages in the Law of Contract, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 105, 124 (1989) (noting how foreseeability "utterly lacks the descriptive content that allows it to be the principled basis for decision").
    • (1989) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.105 , pp. 124
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 418
    • 66049115501 scopus 로고
    • ACTION AND VALUE IN CRIMINAL LAW 125, 126
    • See, eds
    • See Michael S. Moore, Foreseeing Harm Opaquely, in ACTION AND VALUE IN CRIMINAL LAW 125, 126 (Stephen Shute et al. eds., 1993);
    • (1993) Foreseeing Harm Opaquely, in
    • Moore, M.S.1
  • 419
    • 84897742939 scopus 로고
    • Duty, Negligence and Causation, 101
    • see also
    • see also Clarence Morris, Duty, Negligence and Causation, 101 U. PA. L. REV. 189, 198 (1952).
    • (1952) U. PA. L. REV , vol.189 , pp. 198
    • Morris, C.1
  • 420
    • 66049146202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See CLARENCE MORRIS, MORRIS ON TORTS 174-77 (1953).
    • See CLARENCE MORRIS, MORRIS ON TORTS 174-77 (1953).
  • 421
    • 66049132134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.L.A. HART & TONY HONORE, CAUSATION IN THE LAW 258 (2d ed. 1985).
    • H.L.A. HART & TONY HONORE, CAUSATION IN THE LAW 258 (2d ed. 1985).
  • 422
    • 66049092281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J.L. AUSTIN, SENSE AND SENSIBILIA 7-8 (G.J. Warnock ed., 1962) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • J.L. AUSTIN, SENSE AND SENSIBILIA 7-8 (G.J. Warnock ed., 1962) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 423
    • 84868946219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.03[B], at 13-67 to -73;
    • See 4 NIMMER & NIMMER, supra note 42, § 13.03[B], at 13-67 to -73;
  • 424
    • 84868939294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 46, §, at, to -34;
    • OSTERBERG & OSTERBERG, supra note 46, § 2:6, at 2-32 to -34;
    • supra , vol.2
    • OSTERBERG1    OSTERBERG2
  • 425
    • 66049099035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Segrets, Inc. v. Gillman Knitwear Co., 207 F.3d 56, 65 (Ist Cir. 2000) (finding an alteration in color to be a trivial and insubstantial modification).
    • see also Segrets, Inc. v. Gillman Knitwear Co., 207 F.3d 56, 65 (Ist Cir. 2000) (finding an alteration in color to be a trivial and insubstantial modification).
  • 426
    • 84868958915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KEETON ET AL., supra note 103, § 96, at 685. This position is often referred to as the state-of-the-art defense to products liability. It should be noted that courts and scholars have disagreed on whether
    • See KEETON ET AL., supra note 103, § 96, at 685. This position is often referred to as the "state-of-the-art defense" to products liability. It should be noted that courts and scholars have disagreed on whether this approach ought to be abandoned in favor of one dependent entirely on hindsight, given tort law's concern with fairness and compensation. For an analysis of this trend, see James A. Henderson, Jr., Coping with the Time Dimension in Products Liability, 69 CAL. L. REV. 919 (1981).
  • 427
    • 41249092427 scopus 로고
    • Products Liability - Inadequacy of Information, 48
    • advocating a move away from negligence to strict liability for fairness reasons, See also
    • See also W. Page Keeton, Products Liability - Inadequacy of Information, 48 TEX. L. REV. 398 (1970) (advocating a move away from negligence to strict liability for fairness reasons).
    • (1970) TEX. L. REV , vol.398
    • Page Keeton, W.1
  • 428
    • 84868958912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • KEETON ET AL., supra note 103, § 96, at 685 ([I]t is the state of the art in the sense of the scientific knowledge and technological information regarding danger that was available to a seller at the time such seller surrendered possession that is relevant and admissible as regards what he should have known.).
    • KEETON ET AL., supra note 103, § 96, at 685 ("[I]t is the state of the art in the sense of the scientific knowledge and technological information regarding danger that was available to a seller at the time such seller surrendered possession that is relevant and admissible as regards what he should have known.").
  • 429
    • 0032219101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Omri Ben-Shahar, Should Products Liability Be Based on Hindsight?, 14 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 325 (1998) (observing how the use of ex post information often distorts the ex ante incentive to take care, but that it often results in a new ex post incentive after the sale and distribution of the product).
    • See Omri Ben-Shahar, Should Products Liability Be Based on Hindsight?, 14 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 325 (1998) (observing how the use of ex post information often distorts the ex ante incentive to take care, but that it often results in a new ex post incentive after the sale and distribution of the product).
  • 430
    • 66049089640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For opinions emphasizing the importance of relating the inquiry back in time to the point of invention, see In re Kotzab, 217 F.3d 1365, 1369 (Fed. Cir. 2000);
    • For opinions emphasizing the importance of relating the inquiry back in time to the point of invention, see In re Kotzab, 217 F.3d 1365, 1369 (Fed. Cir. 2000);
  • 431
    • 66049151774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and In re Dembiczak, 175 F.3d 994, 999 (Fed. Cir. 1999).
    • and In re Dembiczak, 175 F.3d 994, 999 (Fed. Cir. 1999).
  • 432
    • 66049113713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard A. Posner, Misappropriation: A Dirge, 40 HOUS. L. REV. 621, 622-26 (2003) (rejecting misappropriation as a unifying principle).
    • See Richard A. Posner, Misappropriation: A Dirge, 40 HOUS. L. REV. 621, 622-26 (2003) (rejecting misappropriation as a unifying principle).
  • 433
    • 0347333595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Positive Psychological Theory of Judging in Hindsight, 65
    • For a general overview of the hindsight bias and its influence on judicial decisionmaking, see
    • For a general overview of the hindsight bias and its influence on judicial decisionmaking, see Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, A Positive Psychological Theory of Judging in Hindsight, 65 U. CHI. L. REV. 571 (1998).
    • (1998) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.571
    • Rachlinski, J.J.1
  • 434
    • 0001525505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Jay J.J. Christensen-Szalanski & Cynthia Fobian Willham, The Hindsight Bias: A Meta-Analysis, 48 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 147 (1991).
    • See also Jay J.J. Christensen-Szalanski & Cynthia Fobian Willham, The Hindsight Bias: A Meta-Analysis, 48 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAV. & HUM. DECISION PROCESSES 147 (1991).
  • 435
    • 33747927436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hindsight ≠ Foresight: The Effect of Outcome Knowledge on Judgment Under Uncertainty
    • 197s, Professor Baruch Fischhoff's work is credited with identifying the bias
    • Baruch Fischhoff, Hindsight ≠ Foresight: The Effect of Outcome Knowledge on Judgment Under Uncertainty, I J. EXP. PSYCH. 288, 288 (197s). Professor Baruch Fischhoff's work is credited with identifying the bias.
    • I J. EXP. PSYCH , vol.288 , pp. 288
    • Fischhoff, B.1
  • 436
    • 66049095289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Baruch Fischhoff, For Those Condemned To Study the Past: Heuristics and Biases in Hindsight, in JUDGMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY: HEURISTICS AND BIASES 335 (Daniel Kahneman et al. eds., 1982).
    • See also Baruch Fischhoff, For Those Condemned To Study the Past: Heuristics and Biases in Hindsight, in JUDGMENT UNDER UNCERTAINTY: HEURISTICS AND BIASES 335 (Daniel Kahneman et al. eds., 1982).
  • 437
    • 34547156257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hindsight Bias in Legal Decision Making, 25
    • For studies verifying the existence of hindsight bias, see
    • For studies verifying the existence of hindsight bias, see Erin M. Harley, Hindsight Bias in Legal Decision Making, 25 SOC. COGNITION 48 (2007);
    • (2007) SOC. COGNITION , vol.48
    • Harley, E.M.1
  • 438
    • 0028955104 scopus 로고
    • Ex Post ≠ Ex Ante: Determining Liability in Hindsight, 19
    • Kim A. Kamin & Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Ex Post ≠ Ex Ante: Determining Liability in Hindsight, 19 LAW & HUM. BEHAV. 89 (1995);
    • (1995) LAW & HUM. BEHAV , vol.89
    • Kamin, K.A.1    Rachlinski, J.J.2
  • 439
    • 0041724477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decomposing Hindsight Bias, 16
    • Mark Kelman et al., Decomposing Hindsight Bias, 16 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 251 (1998);
    • (1998) J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY , vol.251
    • Kelman, M.1
  • 440
    • 0029838363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Determinations of Negligence and the Hindsight Bias, 20
    • and Susan J. LaBine & Gary LaBine, Determinations of Negligence and the Hindsight Bias, 20 LAW & HUM. BEHAV. 501 (1996).
    • (1996) LAW & HUM. BEHAV , vol.501
    • LaBine, S.J.1    LaBine, G.2
  • 441
    • 34948831530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 103a, 2006, denying patent protection to inventions that would have been obvious at the time the invention was made
    • See 35 U.S.C. § 103(a) (2006) (denying patent protection to inventions that "would have been obvious at the time the invention was made").
    • 35 U.S.C
  • 442
    • 66049104752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, Patently Non-Obvious: Empirical Demonstration that the Hindsight Bias Renders Patent Decisions Irrational, 67 OHIO ST. L.J. 1391, 1391 2006
    • See Gregory N. Mandel, Patently Non-Obvious: Empirical Demonstration that the Hindsight Bias Renders Patent Decisions Irrational, 67 OHIO ST. L.J. 1391, 1391 (2006).
    • Mandel, G.N.1
  • 443
    • 66049108091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Univ. of London Press, Ltd. v. Univ. Tutorial Press, Ltd., (1916) 2 Ch. 601, 610. While U.S. copyright law has since moved away from this model, it is in many ways representative of the general ex post structural framework on which copyright is premised.
    • Univ. of London Press, Ltd. v. Univ. Tutorial Press, Ltd., (1916) 2 Ch. 601, 610. While U.S. copyright law has since moved away from this model, it is in many ways representative of the general ex post structural framework on which copyright is premised.
  • 444
    • 66049124349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rachlinski, supra note 232, at 571
    • See Rachlinski, supra note 232, at 571.
  • 445
    • 66049159835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 573, 586-88.
    • See id. at 573, 586-88.
  • 446
    • 66049103893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 587, 607-24.
    • See id. at 587, 607-24.
  • 447
    • 66049093967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 607-24
    • Id. at 607-24.
  • 448
    • 66049142719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 624
    • Id. at 624.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.