메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 107, Issue 6, 2007, Pages 1321-1403

Abolition of the corporate duty to creditors

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 36549090576     PISSN: 00101958     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (57)

References (564)
  • 1
    • 36549080932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For succinctness, we discuss primarily the most important duty shifting doctrine, although much of our discussion also applies to other doctrines. Specifically, we focus on the doctrine associated with the traditional trust fund analysis and its modern extensions. We do not discuss, for instance, deepening insolvency, wherein recovery is sought from officers, directors, and others for prolonging the life of an insolvent corporation. See, e.g, Official Comm. of Unsecured Creditors v. R.F. Lafferty & Co, 267 F.3d 340, 349 3d Cir. 2001, stating that 'deepening insolvency' may give rise to a cognizable injury under Pennsylvania law, The deepening insolvency doctrine appears to be falling of its own weight. In a characteristically thoughtful and witty decision, Vice Chancellor Leo Strine held in August 2006 that Delaware law does not recognize [deepening insolvency] as a cause of action, because catchy though the term may be, it does not ex
    • For succinctness, we discuss primarily the most important duty shifting doctrine, although much of our discussion also applies to other doctrines. Specifically, we focus on the doctrine associated with the traditional "trust fund" analysis and its modern extensions. We do not discuss, for instance, "deepening insolvency," wherein recovery is sought from officers, directors, and others for prolonging the life of an insolvent corporation. See, e.g., Official Comm. of Unsecured Creditors v. R.F. Lafferty & Co., 267 F.3d 340, 349 (3d Cir. 2001) (stating that "'deepening insolvency' may give rise to a cognizable injury" under Pennsylvania law). The deepening insolvency doctrine appears to be falling of its own weight. In a characteristically thoughtful and witty decision, Vice Chancellor Leo Strine held in August 2006 that "Delaware law does not recognize [deepening insolvency] as a cause of action, because catchy though the term may be, it does not express a coherent concept."
  • 2
    • 36549053634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trenwick Am. Litig. Trust v. Ernst & Young, L.L.P., 906 A.2d 168, 174 (Del. Ch. 2006). Other judges are skeptical as well.
    • Trenwick Am. Litig. Trust v. Ernst & Young, L.L.P., 906 A.2d 168, 174 (Del. Ch. 2006). Other judges are skeptical as well.
  • 3
    • 36549082447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Seitz v. Detweiler, Hershey & Assocs. (In re CitX Corp.), 448 F.3d 672, 678 (3d Cir. 2006) (holding that deepening insolvency is not an independent cause of action) ;
    • See, e.g., Seitz v. Detweiler, Hershey & Assocs. (In re CitX Corp.), 448 F.3d 672, 678 (3d Cir. 2006) (holding that deepening insolvency is not an independent cause of action) ;
  • 4
    • 36549057810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Official Comm. of Unsecured Creditors v. Rural Tel. Fin. Coop. (In re VarTec Telecom, Inc.), 335 B.R. 631, 646 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 2005) (holding that Texas does not recognize tort of deepening insolvency).
    • Official Comm. of Unsecured Creditors v. Rural Tel. Fin. Coop. (In re VarTec Telecom, Inc.), 335 B.R. 631, 646 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 2005) (holding that Texas does not recognize tort of "deepening insolvency").
  • 5
    • 84858463589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to related doctrines (and statutes) in other common law jurisdictions, see generally Caron Bélanger Ernst & Young Inc. v. Wise (In re Peoples Dep't Stores Inc.), [2004] 3 S.C.R. 461, 481-86 (Can.) (discussing best interests of the corporation under Canadian law);
    • As to related doctrines (and statutes) in other common law jurisdictions, see generally Caron Bélanger Ernst & Young Inc. v. Wise (In re Peoples Dep't Stores Inc.), [2004] 3 S.C.R. 461, 481-86 (Can.) (discussing "best interests of the corporation" under Canadian law);
  • 6
    • 84901153978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew Keay & Michael Murray, Making Company Directors Liable: A Comparative Analysis of Wrongful Trading in the United Kingdom and Insolvent Trading in Australia, 14 Int'l Insolvency Rev. 27 (2005) (comparing United Kingdom's wrongful trading statute to Australia's insolvent trading statute);
    • Andrew Keay & Michael Murray, Making Company Directors Liable: A Comparative Analysis of Wrongful Trading in the United Kingdom and Insolvent Trading in Australia, 14 Int'l Insolvency Rev. 27 (2005) (comparing United Kingdom's wrongful trading statute to Australia's insolvent trading statute);
  • 7
    • 36549001743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark Cheng Wai Yuen, Corporate Director's Common Law Duty to Creditors? - A Revelation of the Present State of the Law, 22 Sing. L. Rev. 104 (2002) (comparing corporate duty doctrines adopted by courts in Australia, New Zealand, and United Kingdom to Singapore approach). For a pertinent nineteen-country survey,
    • Mark Cheng Wai Yuen, Corporate Director's Common Law Duty to Creditors? - A Revelation of the Present State of the Law, 22 Sing. L. Rev. 104 (2002) (comparing corporate duty doctrines adopted by courts in Australia, New Zealand, and United Kingdom to Singapore approach). For a pertinent nineteen-country survey,
  • 8
    • 36549073219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see INSOL Int'l, Directors in the Twilight Zone II (2005) (comparing countries' approaches to powers and duties of directors of financially troubled corporations).
    • see INSOL Int'l, Directors in the Twilight Zone II (2005) (comparing countries' approaches to powers and duties of directors of financially troubled corporations).
  • 9
    • 36549030368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.B.3
    • See infra Part I.B.3.
  • 10
    • 36549084124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 15-16 (Del. May 18, 2007) (stating that court had never directly addressed the zone of insolvency issue involving directors' purported fiduciary duties to creditors).
    • No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 15-16 (Del. May 18, 2007) (stating that court had "never directly addressed the zone of insolvency issue involving directors' purported fiduciary duties to creditors").
  • 11
    • 36549016161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We thus exclude discussion of fraudulent behavior, inter alia. Cf. id. at 24 (distinguishing fiduciary duty claims from claims rooted in contract or tort).
    • We thus exclude discussion of fraudulent behavior, inter alia. Cf. id. at 24 (distinguishing fiduciary duty claims from claims rooted in contract or tort).
  • 12
    • 36549003180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We keep an open mind regarding one prebankruptcy duty directors might have to creditors: the duty to file for bankruptcy. Often directors may best serve shareholders as well as creditors by an early filing, but we do not attempt to find die answer here. Indeed, we suggest that, in our framework, the key item on the research agenda is to determine when such filings should be mandated. See infra Part V
    • We keep an open mind regarding one prebankruptcy duty directors might have to creditors: the duty to file for bankruptcy. Often directors may best serve shareholders as well as creditors by an early filing, but we do not attempt to find die answer here. Indeed, we suggest that, in our framework, the key item on the research agenda is to determine when such filings should be mandated. See infra Part V.
  • 13
    • 36549067292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For one pessimistic view, see Steven Rattner, The Coming Credit Meltdown, Wall St. J., June 18, 2007, at A17 (stating that money is available today in quantities, at prices and on terms never before seen in the 100-plus years since U.S. financial markets reached full flower). Similar deterioration in corporate creditworthiness may be occurring in Europe.
    • For one pessimistic view, see Steven Rattner, The Coming Credit Meltdown, Wall St. J., June 18, 2007, at A17 (stating that "money is available today in quantities, at prices and on terms never before seen in the 100-plus years since U.S. financial markets reached full flower"). Similar deterioration in corporate creditworthiness may be occurring in Europe.
  • 14
    • 36549079576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Floyd Norris, Are High Credit Ratings Just a Thing of the Past?, N.Y. Times, Nov. 11, 2006, at C3 (asserting that European credit ratings are trending downward, but that trend is less advanced than in United States). In August 2007, the Federal Reserve Board and European Central Bank felt compelled to intervene in ways not seen since 9/11 to stem near panic in world financial markets.
    • See Floyd Norris, Are High Credit Ratings Just a Thing of the Past?, N.Y. Times, Nov. 11, 2006, at C3 (asserting that European credit ratings are trending downward, but that trend is less advanced than in United States). In August 2007, the Federal Reserve Board and European Central Bank felt compelled to intervene in ways not seen since 9/11 to stem near panic in world financial markets.
  • 16
    • 36549029293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ben Steverman, Markets: Keeping the Bears at Bay, Bus. Wk. Online, Aug. 13, 2007, at http://www.businessweek.com/investor/content/aug2007/ pi20070810_184123.htm (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (noting reasons for Federal Reserve's injections of liquidity in August 2007 and immediately after September 11 terrorist attacks).
    • Ben Steverman, Markets: Keeping the Bears at Bay, Bus. Wk. Online, Aug. 13, 2007, at http://www.businessweek.com/investor/content/aug2007/ pi20070810_184123.htm (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (noting reasons for Federal Reserve's injections of liquidity in August 2007 and immediately after September 11 terrorist attacks).
  • 17
    • 33747074656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For analysis of these changes, which have been driven in part by the growth of hedge funds (and hedge fund decoupling of shareholder voting rights from the accompanying economic interest), see Henry T. C. Hu & Bernard Black, The New Vote Buying: Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership, 79 S. Cal. L. Rev. 811, 815 (2006) [hereinafter Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying] (analyzing decoupling of economic ownership from voting power and corporate governance implications, including role of hedge fund activism) ;
    • For analysis of these changes, which have been driven in part by the growth of hedge funds (and hedge fund "decoupling" of shareholder voting rights from the accompanying economic interest), see Henry T. C. Hu & Bernard Black, The New Vote Buying: Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership, 79 S. Cal. L. Rev. 811, 815 (2006) [hereinafter Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying] (analyzing decoupling of economic ownership from voting power and corporate governance implications, including role of hedge fund activism) ;
  • 18
    • 36549052207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David A. Katz & Laura A McIntosh, Corporate Governance: Advice on Coping with Hedge Fund Activism, N.Y.L.J., May 25, 2006, at 5 (stating that [e]very decade needs a villain and that in 2000s, it appears to be activist hedge funds);
    • David A. Katz & Laura A McIntosh, Corporate Governance: Advice on Coping with Hedge Fund Activism, N.Y.L.J., May 25, 2006, at 5 (stating that "[e]very decade needs a villain" and that in 2000s, "it appears to be activist hedge funds");
  • 19
    • 36549086554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kara Scannell, Outside Influence: How Borrowed Shares Swing Company Votes, Wall St. J., Jan. 26, 2007, at Al (discussing decoupling via share lending and foregoing analysis);
    • Kara Scannell, Outside Influence: How Borrowed Shares Swing Company Votes, Wall St. J., Jan. 26, 2007, at Al (discussing decoupling via share lending and foregoing analysis);
  • 20
    • 36549001735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ben White, Thesis on Hedge Fund Tactics Gives Investors a Shock, Fin. Times, Oct. 6, 2006, at 29 (discussing institutional investors and the New Vote Buying-based speech). Similar changes appear to be occurring worldwide.
    • Ben White, Thesis on Hedge Fund Tactics Gives Investors a Shock, Fin. Times, Oct. 6, 2006, at 29 (discussing institutional investors and the New Vote Buying-based speech). Similar changes appear to be occurring worldwide.
  • 21
    • 36549084114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Andrew Morse, Hostile Bid Breaks Japanese Mold, Wall St. J., July 25, 2006, at C4 (discussing unprecedented takeover attempt in Japan) ;
    • See, e.g., Andrew Morse, Hostile Bid Breaks Japanese Mold, Wall St. J., July 25, 2006, at C4 (discussing unprecedented takeover attempt in Japan) ;
  • 22
    • 36549023087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David Reilly, Deutsche Boerse's New Tune on Mergers Gives Investors Hope a New Deal Will Come, Wall St. J., Oct. 26, 2005, at Cl (describing implications for German shareholders of developments involving Deutsche Boerse);
    • David Reilly, Deutsche Boerse's New Tune on Mergers Gives Investors Hope a New Deal Will Come, Wall St. J., Oct. 26, 2005, at Cl (describing implications for German shareholders of developments involving Deutsche Boerse);
  • 23
    • 36549016155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laura Santini, A Firm Activist, Lichtenstein Wins Big in South Korea, Wall St. J., Aug. 10, 2006, at C1 (describing implications of hedge fund's purchase of shares of underperforming South Korean corporation); Julia Werdigier, At More Companies, Shareholders are Challenging the Boss, and Winning, Int'l Herald Trib., May 24, 2007, at 14 (discussing fight over ABN AMRO and other shareholder-related developments in Europe).
    • Laura Santini, A Firm Activist, Lichtenstein Wins Big in South Korea, Wall St. J., Aug. 10, 2006, at C1 (describing implications of hedge fund's purchase of shares of underperforming South Korean corporation); Julia Werdigier, At More Companies, Shareholders are Challenging the Boss, and Winning, Int'l Herald Trib., May 24, 2007, at 14 (discussing fight over ABN AMRO and other shareholder-related developments in Europe).
  • 24
    • 36549000303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We are aware of only one other article that has called for a bankruptcy filing to trigger managerial duties to creditors, just published by Professors Rutherford Campbell and Christopher Frost. See Rutherford B. Campbell, Jr. & Christopher W. Frost, Managers' Fiduciary Duties in Financially Distressed Corporations: Chaos in Delaware (and Elsewhere, 32 J. Corp. L. 491, 522-25 2007, It offers a helpful analysis and deploys some of the same points we make in this article. Campbell and Frost, however, ground their prescription largely on arguments rooted in the concept that clear and efficient default rules are of the utmost importance
    • We are aware of only one other article that has called for a bankruptcy filing to trigger managerial duties to creditors, just published by Professors Rutherford Campbell and Christopher Frost. See Rutherford B. Campbell, Jr. & Christopher W. Frost, Managers' Fiduciary Duties in Financially Distressed Corporations: Chaos in Delaware (and Elsewhere), 32 J. Corp. L. 491, 522-25 (2007). It offers a helpful analysis and deploys some of the same points we make in this article. Campbell and Frost, however, ground their prescription largely on arguments rooted in the concept that "clear and efficient default rules are of the utmost importance."
  • 25
    • 36549037217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 494. Our analysis instead centers on the structure of shareholder ownership rights and of governance systems. Campbell and Frost do not consider the structure of shareholder ownership rights, do not address key congruence issues (such as the imposition of conflict resolution responsibilities on the corporate governance system), and do not consider the research necessitated by abolition of duty shifting.
    • Id. at 494. Our analysis instead centers on the structure of shareholder ownership rights and of governance systems. Campbell and Frost do not consider the structure of shareholder ownership rights, do not address key congruence issues (such as the imposition of conflict resolution responsibilities on the corporate governance system), and do not consider the research necessitated by abolition of duty shifting.
  • 26
    • 36549052628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Financial Characteristics of Businesses in Bankruptcy, 73 Am. Bankr. L.J. 499, 523 (1999).
    • Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Financial Characteristics of Businesses in Bankruptcy, 73 Am. Bankr. L.J. 499, 523 (1999).
  • 27
    • 36549049872 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The interests of shareholders and those of other constituencies do not always conflict, of course. Thus, from an instrumental standpoint, a corporation may further the interests of shareholders by making large (and visible) charitable donations to host communities. In this Article, we are focusing on harder cases, where decisions do turn on which constituency matters. In addition, when we talk of the corporate objective, we generally mean the core (i.e, primary) objective of the corporation. For a corporation to have as its core objective the furtherance of its shareholders' welfare is not necessarily inconsistent with a corporation adopting as some lesser objective the promotion of the interests of nonshareholder constituencies. This Article does not expressly analyze the general desirability of a multiple constituency philosophy or other corporate social responsibility matters. See infra note 16 discussing how views we express in this Article are
    • The interests of shareholders and those of other constituencies do not always conflict, of course. Thus, from an instrumental standpoint, a corporation may further the interests of shareholders by making large (and visible) charitable donations to host communities. In this Article, we are focusing on harder cases, where decisions do turn on which constituency matters. In addition, when we talk of the "corporate objective," we generally mean the core (i.e., primary) objective of the corporation. For a corporation to have as its core objective the furtherance of its shareholders' welfare is not necessarily inconsistent with a corporation adopting as some lesser objective the promotion of the interests of nonshareholder constituencies. This Article does not expressly analyze the general desirability of a "multiple constituency" philosophy or other corporate "social responsibility" matters. See infra note 16 (discussing how views we express in this Article are largely independent of multiple constituency issue). We believe this is appropriate for three reasons. First, the sole exception to the core duty to shareholders recognized in Delaware and most other states is that flowing from duty shifting. Irrespective of how one stands on corporate "social responsibility" generally, this exception exists as a matter of law and must be addressed. Second, Delaware and most other states have long rejected the "multiple constituency" approach and, if anything, have become more focused on the interests of shareholders in the past few years. Third, and perhaps most important, it is the rare public corporation that takes seriously the concept of a core duty to multiple constituencies; this is especially unlikely in today's environment of hedge funds, private equity funds, and shareholder activism. Professor Robert Charles Clark recently noted that it does not appear that directors and officers ever consider a "multiple constituency" approach and, instead, "simply assume or state that the main effort is to maximize shareholder value."
  • 29
    • 36549058279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a classic critique of a multiple constituency philosophy, see Comm. on Corporate Laws, Other Constituencies Statutes: Potential for Confusion, 45 Bus. Law. 2253 (1990);
    • For a classic critique of a "multiple constituency" philosophy, see Comm. on Corporate Laws, Other Constituencies Statutes: Potential for Confusion, 45 Bus. Law. 2253 (1990);
  • 30
    • 33646751726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also David A. Skeel, Jr., Icarus and American Corporate Regulation, 61 Bus. Law. 155, 175-76 (2005) (opposing multiple constituency approach to corporate law).
    • see also David A. Skeel, Jr., Icarus and American Corporate Regulation, 61 Bus. Law. 155, 175-76 (2005) (opposing multiple constituency approach to corporate law).
  • 31
    • 0346934193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Margaret M. Blair & Lynn A. Stout, A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law, 85 Va. L. Rev. 247, 248-57 (1999) (advocating team production approach to understanding public corporations);
    • But see Margaret M. Blair & Lynn A. Stout, A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law, 85 Va. L. Rev. 247, 248-57 (1999) (advocating "team production" approach to understanding public corporations);
  • 32
    • 36549034852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Janis Sana, Creditor Rights and the Public Interest: Restructuring Insolvent Corporations 101-02 (2003) (stating that, in Canada, directors act for all stakeholders).
    • see also Janis Sana, Creditor Rights and the Public Interest: Restructuring Insolvent Corporations 101-02 (2003) (stating that, in Canada, directors act for all stakeholders).
  • 33
    • 36549041909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At least as a starting point, in most cases, management concerned about shareholders need not consider the individual risk and time preferences of its shareholders. See Henry T. C. Hu, Risk, Time, and Fiduciary Principles in Corporate Investment, 38 UCLA L. Rev. 277, 287-95 1990, hereinafter Hu, Risk & Time, arguing that using conventional capital budgeting technique generally leads to investment decisions that benefit all shareholders regardless of individual time and risk preferences
    • At least as a starting point, in most cases, management concerned about shareholders need not consider the individual risk and time preferences of its shareholders. See Henry T. C. Hu, Risk, Time, and Fiduciary Principles in Corporate Investment, 38 UCLA L. Rev. 277, 287-95 (1990) [hereinafter Hu, Risk & Time] (arguing that using conventional capital budgeting technique generally leads to investment decisions that benefit all shareholders regardless of individual time and risk preferences) ;
  • 34
    • 36549006054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra Parts H.B.1-2 (discussing corporate governance system and largely unitary interests of shareholders). In this Article, we focus primarily on the usual publicly held corporation. The special considerations associated with closely held corporations (such as those flowing from ill-diversified shareholders) are beyond the scope of this Article. We also assume, among other things, only one class of equity holders, all of whom are fully diversified and are concerned solely with their own material well-being.
    • infra Parts H.B.1-2 (discussing corporate governance system and largely unitary interests of shareholders). In this Article, we focus primarily on the usual publicly held corporation. The special considerations associated with closely held corporations (such as those flowing from ill-diversified shareholders) are beyond the scope of this Article. We also assume, among other things, only one class of equity holders, all of whom are fully diversified and are concerned solely with their own material well-being.
  • 35
    • 36549081408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B.2 (discussing stylized fact pattern involving only one class of equityholders). For a discussion of limitations to the unitary nature of the interests of shareholders,
    • See infra Part II.B.2 (discussing stylized fact pattern involving only one class of equityholders). For a discussion of limitations to the unitary nature of the interests of shareholders,
  • 36
    • 36549003174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see infra note 155 and accompanying text.
    • see infra note 155 and accompanying text.
  • 37
    • 36549017181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this Article, we leave aside attempts by one group of shareholders (e.g, controlling shareholders) to deprive another group of shareholders (e.g, minority shareholders) of their formal or informal ownership rights
    • In this Article, we leave aside attempts by one group of shareholders (e.g., controlling shareholders) to deprive another group of shareholders (e.g., minority shareholders) of their formal or informal ownership rights.
  • 38
    • 36549078672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For more details about the core nature of investment decisions and a discussion of the difficulties they pose, see Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279-80, 287-306
    • For more details about the core nature of investment decisions and a discussion of the difficulties they pose, see Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279-80, 287-306.
  • 39
    • 84858474470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Micheline Maynard, Ford Posts Loss of $5.8 Billion, Worst Since 1992, N.Y. Times, Oct. 24, 2006, at Al (reporting Ford CEO Alan Mulally's description of two choices);
    • See Micheline Maynard, Ford Posts Loss of $5.8 Billion, Worst Since 1992, N.Y. Times, Oct. 24, 2006, at Al (reporting Ford CEO Alan Mulally's description of two choices);
  • 40
    • 36549028363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Standard & Poor's, Stock Report: Ford Motor Co. (Oct. 14, 2006) (analyzing Ford creditworthiness as of Sept. 11, 2006);
    • cf. Standard & Poor's, Stock Report: Ford Motor Co. (Oct. 14, 2006) (analyzing Ford creditworthiness as of Sept. 11, 2006);
  • 41
    • 36549077727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antony Currie & Jonathan Ford, For Ford, It Doesn't Add Up: Investors' Valuation of Stock Is off When Considering Firm's Liabilities, Assets, Wall St. J., Feb. 12, 2007, at C12 (claiming that intrinsic value of Ford shares is zero);
    • Antony Currie & Jonathan Ford, For Ford, It Doesn't Add Up: Investors' Valuation of Stock Is off When Considering Firm's Liabilities, Assets, Wall St. J., Feb. 12, 2007, at C12 (claiming that intrinsic value of Ford shares is zero);
  • 42
    • 36549022623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shikha Dalmia, The UAW's Health-Care Dreams, Wall St. J., July 27, 2007, at A13 (claiming that Ford, among others, was teetering on the brink of bankruptcy, notwithstanding second quarter profit in 2007).
    • Shikha Dalmia, The UAW's Health-Care Dreams, Wall St. J., July 27, 2007, at A13 (claiming that Ford, among others, was "teetering on the brink of bankruptcy," notwithstanding second quarter profit in 2007).
  • 43
    • 36549022624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maynard, supra note 14
    • Maynard, supra note 14.
  • 44
    • 36549086799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We do not argue that the existing bundle of rights allocated to shareholders is the only possible one, but rather that the longstanding foundational structure of shareholder ownership rights should not be abandoned without compelling reasons. We also suggest that whatever rights are in the bundle at a given time should not be abrogated without transparency and due process. See infra Part III.C. We should also make it clear that we are not addressing larger questions of the social responsibility of corporations. Such questions involve social and political policies outside the scope of this Article. Comments from readers and our conversations with each other confirm to us that one does not have to be politically liberal or conservative to adopt the views we express in this Article
    • We do not argue that the existing bundle of rights allocated to shareholders is the only possible one, but rather that the longstanding foundational structure of shareholder ownership rights should not be abandoned without compelling reasons. We also suggest that whatever rights are in the bundle at a given time should not be abrogated without transparency and due process. See infra Part III.C. We should also make it clear that we are not addressing larger questions of the social responsibility of corporations. Such questions involve social and political policies outside the scope of this Article. Comments from readers and our conversations with each other confirm to us that one does not have to be politically liberal or conservative to adopt the views we express in this Article.
  • 45
    • 36548999818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also supra note 11 discussing interests of multiple constituencies
    • See also supra note 11 (discussing interests of multiple constituencies).
  • 46
    • 36549020043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Henry T. C. Hu, Shareholder and Creditor Decoupling: Separating Embedded Rights and Contractual Rights from Economic Interests 4 (contribution to 10th Singapore Conference on International Business Law, Aug. 22-23, 2007, and associated conference draft of Aug. 17, 2007, on file with the Columbia Law Review) [hereinafter Hu, Shareholder and Creditor Decoupling] (introducing concept of embedded rights, of which voting rights, inspection rights, and rights to sue directors for violations of fiduciary duty are examples).
    • See Henry T. C. Hu, Shareholder and Creditor Decoupling: Separating "Embedded Rights" and Contractual Rights from Economic Interests 4 (contribution to 10th Singapore Conference on International Business Law, Aug. 22-23, 2007, and associated conference volume) (draft of Aug. 17, 2007, on file with the Columbia Law Review) [hereinafter Hu, Shareholder and Creditor Decoupling] (introducing concept of "embedded rights," of which voting rights, inspection rights, and rights to sue directors for violations of fiduciary duty are examples).
  • 47
    • 36549075606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The maximization right-the right to require that management run the corporation in a way intended to maximize benefits to shareholders-is probably the most important of these embedded rights. This maximization right concept was introduced in Henry T. C. Hu, New Financial Products, the Modern Process of Financial Innovation, and the Puzzle of Shareholder Welfare, 69 Tex. L. Rev. 1273, 1288-1300 (1991) [hereinafter Hu, Shareholder Welfare]. However, to avoid the possibility of infinite regress, this Article's ownership-based analysis is not dependent on the existence of this particular embedded right. It is sufficient for our purposes to rely instead on other, more structural rights, such as voting rights.
    • The "maximization right"-the right to require that management run the corporation in a way intended to maximize benefits to shareholders-is probably the most important of these embedded rights. This "maximization right" concept was introduced in Henry T. C. Hu, New Financial Products, the Modern Process of Financial Innovation, and the Puzzle of Shareholder Welfare, 69 Tex. L. Rev. 1273, 1288-1300 (1991) [hereinafter Hu, Shareholder Welfare]. However, to avoid the possibility of infinite regress, this Article's ownership-based analysis is not dependent on the existence of this particular embedded right. It is sufficient for our purposes to rely instead on other, more structural rights, such as voting rights.
  • 48
    • 41649095862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The above static versus dynamic economic rights assertion does not depend in any way on contingent claims analysis (CCA, a branch of finance theory made possible by option pricing models, on any of the related finance theoretic scholarship, or on the validity of any related finance scholarship. Some finance theorists have used CCA analysis to analyze certain creditor-shareholder conflicts and, in doing so, viewed shareholders as call holders of some sort. See, e.g, Marc Chesney & Rajna Gibson-Asner, Reducing Asset Substitution with Warrant and Convertible Debt Issues, J. Derivatives, Fall 2001, at 39, 51 stating that, under posited capital structure, equity can be priced as a combination of down-and-out European calls that is similar to a vertical call spread, For an introduction to call options and option pricing models
    • The above static versus dynamic economic rights assertion does not depend in any way on "contingent claims analysis" (CCA - a branch of finance theory made possible by option pricing models), on any of the related finance theoretic scholarship, or on the validity of any related finance scholarship. Some finance theorists have used CCA analysis to analyze certain creditor-shareholder conflicts and, in doing so, viewed shareholders as call holders of some sort. See, e.g., Marc Chesney & Rajna Gibson-Asner, Reducing Asset Substitution with Warrant and Convertible Debt Issues, J. Derivatives, Fall 2001, at 39, 51 (stating that, under posited capital structure, equity "can be priced as a combination of down-and-out European calls that is similar to a vertical call spread"). For an introduction to call options and option pricing models,
  • 49
    • 36549003175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Henry T. C. Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives: The Causes of Informational Failure and the Promise of Regulatory Incrementalism, 102 Yale L.J. 1457, 1464-76 (1993) [hereinafter Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives].
    • see Henry T. C. Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives: The Causes of Informational Failure and the Promise of Regulatory Incrementalism, 102 Yale L.J. 1457, 1464-76 (1993) [hereinafter Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives].
  • 50
    • 36549033835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to the matter of options always having value, see infra note 221 and accompanying text
    • As to the matter of options always having value, see infra note 221 and accompanying text.
  • 51
    • 36549046092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-19 (discussing recent emergence of this phenomenon and independent significance of shareholder voting and economic rights)
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-19 (discussing recent emergence of this phenomenon and independent significance of shareholder voting and economic rights). This Article does not purport to address all of the implications of such decoupling.
    • This Article does not purport to address all of the implications of such decoupling
    • Hu1    Black2
  • 52
    • 36549068257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part V
    • See infra Part V.
  • 53
    • 36549065242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B; cf. supra note 11 noting distinction between core and secondary corporate objectives and discussing multiple constituency issue
    • See infra Part II.B; cf. supra note 11 (noting distinction between "core" and secondary corporate objectives and discussing multiple constituency issue).
  • 54
    • 36549068769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C
    • See infra Part I.C.
  • 55
    • 36549069757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Civ. A. No. 12150, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 Del. Ch. Dec. 30, 1991
    • Civ. A. No. 12150, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 (Del. Ch. Dec. 30, 1991).
  • 56
    • 36549007506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 19, 22 (Del. May 18, 2007).
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 19, 22 (Del. May 18, 2007).
  • 57
    • 36549017182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I.C
    • See infra Part I.C.
  • 58
    • 36549014659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 30 F. Cas. 435 (C.C.D. Me. 1824) (No. 17, 994).
    • 30 F. Cas. 435 (C.C.D. Me. 1824) (No. 17, 994).
  • 59
    • 36549015708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1 E. Merrick Dodd, Jr. & Ralph J. Baker, Cases on Business Associations-Corporations 895 (1940);
    • 1 E. Merrick Dodd, Jr. & Ralph J. Baker, Cases on Business Associations-Corporations 895 (1940);
  • 61
    • 36549077008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wood, 30 F. Cas. at 436.
    • Wood, 30 F. Cas. at 436.
  • 62
    • 36549077719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Joseph Jude Norton, Relationship of Shareholders to Corporate Creditors upon Dissolution: Nature and Implications of the Trust Fund Doctrine of Corporate Assets, 30 Bus. Law. 1061, 1064 (1975). Note that the United States is like many other countries in excluding banks from the operation of the ordinary bankruptcy laws.
    • See, e.g., Joseph Jude Norton, Relationship of Shareholders to Corporate Creditors upon Dissolution: Nature and Implications of the "Trust Fund" Doctrine of Corporate Assets, 30 Bus. Law. 1061, 1064 (1975). Note that the United States is like many other countries in excluding banks from the operation of the ordinary bankruptcy laws.
  • 63
    • 84858473255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 11 U.S.C. § 109(b)(2) (2000). More broadly, governments tend to subject banks and other financial institutions to special regulation, including limiting the risk taking they may engage in.
    • See 11 U.S.C. § 109(b)(2) (2000). More broadly, governments tend to subject banks and other financial institutions to special regulation, including limiting the risk taking they may engage in.
  • 64
    • 36549030367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Robert Charles Clark, The Soundness of Financial Intermediaries, 86 Yale L.J. 1, 3 (1976). As with the state law duty shifting doctrines, bank regulatory regimes seek to limit shareholder-optimal risk taking.
    • See, e.g., Robert Charles Clark, The Soundness of Financial Intermediaries, 86 Yale L.J. 1, 3 (1976). As with the state law duty shifting doctrines, bank regulatory regimes seek to limit shareholder-optimal risk taking.
  • 65
    • 36549016642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry T. C. Hu, Swaps, the Modern Process of Financial Innovation and the Vulnerability of a Regulatory Paradigm, 138 U. Pa. L. Rev. 333, 366-70 (1989). But, in contrast to those doctrines' failure to consider mechanisms to guide managerial behavior, bank regulatory regimes rely on a wide variety of finely-tuned legal, administrative, and market mechanisms to do so.
    • Henry T. C. Hu, Swaps, the Modern Process of Financial Innovation and the Vulnerability of a Regulatory Paradigm, 138 U. Pa. L. Rev. 333, 366-70 (1989). But, in contrast to those doctrines' failure to consider mechanisms to guide managerial behavior, bank regulatory regimes rely on a wide variety of finely-tuned legal, administrative, and market mechanisms to do so.
  • 66
    • 36549063004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts II.C.2-II.D.
    • See infra Parts II.C.2-II.D.
  • 67
    • 36549051663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Joseph W. Bishop, Jr., Sitting Ducks and Decoy Ducks: New Trends in the Indemnification of Corporate Directors and Officers, 77 Yale L.J. 1078, 1099 (1968) (discussing uniqueness of bank director exposure).
    • See Joseph W. Bishop, Jr., Sitting Ducks and Decoy Ducks: New Trends in the Indemnification of Corporate Directors and Officers, 77 Yale L.J. 1078, 1099 (1968) (discussing uniqueness of bank director exposure).
  • 68
    • 36549037222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Writing in 1940, Professors Merrick Dodd and Ralph Baker belitded the significance of the trust fund doctrine; all that Story meant was that corporate property must be first appropriated to the payment of the debts of the company before there can be any distribution of it among stockholders - a proposition that is sound upon the plainest principles of common honesty. Dodd & Baker, supra note 26, at 895.
    • Writing in 1940, Professors Merrick Dodd and Ralph Baker belitded the significance of the "trust fund doctrine"; all that Story meant "was that corporate property must be first appropriated to the payment of the debts of the company before there can be any distribution of it among stockholders - a proposition that is sound upon the plainest principles of common honesty." Dodd & Baker, supra note 26, at 895.
  • 69
    • 36549033840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Bankruptcy Act of 1800 was repealed in 1803, and the next federal bankruptcy statute would not be adopted until 1841. It was 1898 before the United States began to have a continuous federal bankruptcy system. Theodore Eisenberg, Bankruptcy and Debtor-Creditor Law 216 (3d ed. 2004);
    • The Bankruptcy Act of 1800 was repealed in 1803, and the next federal bankruptcy statute would not be adopted until 1841. It was 1898 before the United States began to have a continuous federal bankruptcy system. Theodore Eisenberg, Bankruptcy and Debtor-Creditor Law 216 (3d ed. 2004);
  • 70
    • 36549074182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of Debtors and Creditors 108 (5th ed. 2005) [hereinafter Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems]. Not coincidentally, Justice Story, in the years after Wood, was a leading advocate of adoption of a federal bankruptcy law. According to his son, he actually drafted the bill that became the 1841 Act. 2 Life and Letters of Joseph Story 407 (William W. Story ed., 1851).
    • Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of Debtors and Creditors 108 (5th ed. 2005) [hereinafter Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems]. Not coincidentally, Justice Story, in the years after Wood, was a leading advocate of adoption of a federal bankruptcy law. According to his son, he actually drafted the bill that became the 1841 Act. 2 Life and Letters of Joseph Story 407 (William W. Story ed., 1851).
  • 71
    • 36549067768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This response was also understandable as a way of reaching the right result in the face of poorly drafted pleadings. See Bayless Manning & James J. Hanks, Jr, Legal Capital 31 (3d ed. 1990, deeming Justice Story's Wood opinion simple, clear and wholly adequate for the particular problem with which he was confronted);
    • This response was also understandable as a way of reaching the right result in the face of poorly drafted pleadings. See Bayless Manning & James J. Hanks, Jr., Legal Capital 31 (3d ed. 1990) (deeming Justice Story's Wood opinion "simple, clear and wholly adequate for the particular problem with which he was confronted");
  • 72
    • 36549002265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norton, supra note 28, at 1062-63 describing bill in equity as poorly written
    • Norton, supra note 28, at 1062-63 (describing bill in equity as "poorly written").
  • 73
    • 36549003640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an amusing discussion of this historical context, see Manning & Hanks, supra note 31, at 20-43
    • For an amusing discussion of this historical context, see Manning & Hanks, supra note 31, at 20-43.
  • 75
    • 36549086555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One of the leading English cases was Trevor v. Whitworth, (1887) 12 App. Cas. 409, 411 (H.L.) (appeal taken from CA.) ([N]o reduction of capital otherwise than as allowed by statute is legitimate.).
    • One of the leading English cases was Trevor v. Whitworth, (1887) 12 App. Cas. 409, 411 (H.L.) (appeal taken from CA.) ("[N]o reduction of capital otherwise than as allowed by statute is legitimate.").
  • 76
    • 36549012764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dewing, supra note 33, at 25-26 arguing that aggregate par value representations are suspect
    • See Dewing, supra note 33, at 25-26 (arguing that aggregate par value representations are suspect).
  • 77
    • 84858472861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Act of Apr. 15, 1912, eh. 351, 1912 N.Y. Laws 687 (codified at N.Y. Stock Corp. Law §19);
    • Act of Apr. 15, 1912, eh. 351, 1912 N.Y. Laws 687 (codified at N.Y. Stock Corp. Law §19);
  • 78
    • 36549071143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Dewing, supra note 33, at 23 (noting first statute permitting no-par stock); Dodd & Baker, supra note 26, at 1001 (discussing New York statute and comparing with those of other states). It may not be entirely coincidental that these developments followed shortly after the adoption of our first viable bankruptcy law in 1898. In England, a leading case left directors largely free to ignore creditor interests.
    • see Dewing, supra note 33, at 23 (noting first statute permitting no-par stock); Dodd & Baker, supra note 26, at 1001 (discussing New York statute and comparing with those of other states). It may not be entirely coincidental that these developments followed shortly after the adoption of our first viable bankruptcy law in 1898. In England, a leading case left directors largely free to ignore creditor interests.
  • 79
    • 36549070676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Salomon v. Salomon & Co., [1897] A.C. 22, 27 (H.L.) (appeal taken from C.A.) (holding that director need not indemnify company against creditors' claims).
    • See Salomon v. Salomon & Co., [1897] A.C. 22, 27 (H.L.) (appeal taken from C.A.) (holding that director need not indemnify company against creditors' claims).
  • 80
    • 36549016643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dewing, supra note 33, at 23
    • Dewing, supra note 33, at 23.
  • 81
    • 84858474466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 James D. Cox, Thomas Lee Hazen & F. Hodge O'Neal, Corporations § 16.15 n.2 (1995).
    • 2 James D. Cox, Thomas Lee Hazen & F. Hodge O'Neal, Corporations § 16.15 n.2 (1995).
  • 83
    • 36549011290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Am. Nat'l Bank of Austin v. MortgageAmerica Corp. (In re MortgageAmerica Corp.), 714 F.2d 1266, 1269 (5th Cir. 1983)
    • Am. Nat'l Bank of Austin v. MortgageAmerica Corp. (In re MortgageAmerica Corp.), 714 F.2d 1266, 1269 (5th Cir. 1983)
  • 84
    • 84858453470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting 15A William Meade Fletcher et al., Fletcher Cyclopedia of the Law of Private Corporations § 7369, at 42 (perm, ed., rev. 1981)).
    • (quoting 15A William Meade Fletcher et al., Fletcher Cyclopedia of the Law of Private Corporations § 7369, at 42 (perm, ed., rev. vol. 1981)).
  • 85
    • 36549037218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For excellent discussions of the trust fund cases, see Decker v. Mitchell (In re JTS Corp.), 305 B.R. 529, 535-36 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. 2003);
    • For excellent discussions of the trust fund cases, see Decker v. Mitchell (In re JTS Corp.), 305 B.R. 529, 535-36 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. 2003);
  • 86
    • 36549067291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gregory V. Varallo & Jesse A. Finkelstein, Fiduciary Obligations of Directors of the Financially Troubled Company, 48 Bus. Law. 239, 245-48 (1992).
    • Gregory V. Varallo & Jesse A. Finkelstein, Fiduciary Obligations of Directors of the Financially Troubled Company, 48 Bus. Law. 239, 245-48 (1992).
  • 87
    • 36549060143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 38 A.2d 808, 809 (Del. 1944).
    • 38 A.2d 808, 809 (Del. 1944).
  • 88
    • 36549042027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 811-12, 814
    • Id. at 811-12, 814.
  • 89
    • 36549044975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 813 citations omitted
    • Id. at 813 (citations omitted).
  • 90
    • 36549052208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 91
    • 84858453468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Today this common law doctrine has been displaced with respect to the termination of corporations by state statutory law relating to the winding up of corporations and by federal bankruptcy law. If shareholders wish to terminate a corporation outside of bankruptcy, the directors must follow specific statutory rules about notifying creditors, paying creditors, and distributing remaining property to shareholders. See, e.g, Rev. Model Bus. Corp. Act §§ 14.02, 14.06, 14.09(a, 2005);
    • Today this common law doctrine has been displaced with respect to the termination of corporations by state statutory law relating to the "winding up" of corporations and by federal bankruptcy law. If shareholders wish to terminate a corporation outside of bankruptcy, the directors must follow specific statutory rules about notifying creditors, paying creditors, and distributing remaining property to shareholders. See, e.g., Rev. Model Bus. Corp. Act §§ 14.02, 14.06, 14.09(a) (2005);
  • 92
    • 36549072517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Pac. Scene, Inc. v. Penasquitos, Inc., 758 P.2d 1182, 1183 (Cal. 1988) (stating that Legislature has generally occupied the field with respect to the remedies available against the former shareholders of dissolved corporations, thus preempting antecedent common law causes of action) ;
    • cf. Pac. Scene, Inc. v. Penasquitos, Inc., 758 P.2d 1182, 1183 (Cal. 1988) (stating that "Legislature has generally occupied the field with respect to the remedies available against the former shareholders of dissolved corporations, thus preempting antecedent common law causes of action") ;
  • 93
    • 84858469531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rev. Model Bus. Corp. Act §14.05 official cmt. (stating that winding up process under Revised Model Business Corporations Act does not have any of the characteristics of common law dissolution). However, because of the ubiquity of bankruptcy law in the United States in the last century, use of winding up for insolvent corporations has been less important. In the United Kingdom, where business bankruptcy law is treated as part of corporate law, winding up is the customary bankruptcy process for insolvent corporations.
    • Rev. Model Bus. Corp. Act §14.05 official cmt. (stating that winding up process under Revised Model Business Corporations Act "does not have any of the characteristics of common law dissolution"). However, because of the ubiquity of bankruptcy law in the United States in the last century, use of winding up for insolvent corporations has been less important. In the United Kingdom, where business bankruptcy law is treated as part of corporate law, winding up is the customary "bankruptcy" process for insolvent corporations.
  • 94
    • 36549009581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Roy M. Goode, Principles of Corporate Insolvency Law 19 (3d ed. 2005) (noting that usual method of insolvency proceedings in United Kingdom is winding up); Harry Rajak, Company Liquidations, at vii (1988) (remarking that winding up is usual course for insolvent corporations in United Kingdom).
    • See Roy M. Goode, Principles of Corporate Insolvency Law 19 (3d ed. 2005) (noting that usual method of insolvency proceedings in United Kingdom is winding up); Harry Rajak, Company Liquidations, at vii (1988) (remarking that winding up is usual course for insolvent corporations in United Kingdom).
  • 95
    • 84858453871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 324 A.2d 215 (Del. Ch. 1974), rev'd on other grounds, 347 A.2d 133 (Del. 1975). The single corporate act challenged was the declaration of a dividend of $1.75 a share by Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer the previous year. The plaintiffs, holders of convertible subordinate debt, did not allege fraud or that the dividends violated either the governing indenture or any Delaware statute. Instead, the plaintiffs argued that defendants breached their fiduciary duty to the plaintiffs since defendants were the controlling stockholders and such dividends on the common stock hurt the market value of their debentures and the conversion feature.
    • 324 A.2d 215 (Del. Ch. 1974), rev'd on other grounds, 347 A.2d 133 (Del. 1975). The single corporate act challenged was the declaration of a dividend of $1.75 a share by Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer the previous year. The plaintiffs, holders of convertible subordinate debt, did not allege fraud or that the dividends violated either the governing indenture or any Delaware statute. Instead, the plaintiffs argued that defendants breached their fiduciary duty to the plaintiffs since defendants were the controlling stockholders and such dividends on the common stock hurt the market value of their debentures and the conversion feature.
  • 96
    • 36549062024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 221. Without citing Bovay, the trust fund doctrine, or offering much by way of analysis, the court suggested the possibility of debenture holders having extracontractual rights when there were special circumstances such as fraud, insolvency, or a violation of a statute.
    • Id. at 221. Without citing Bovay, the trust fund doctrine, or offering much by way of analysis, the court suggested the possibility of debenture holders having extracontractual rights when there were "special circumstances" such as "fraud, insolvency, or a violation of a statute."
  • 97
    • 36549077009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 221-22. Nowhere did the Harff court suggest that these extracontractual rights involved a fiduciary duty to creditors.
    • Id. at 221-22. Nowhere did the Harff court suggest that these extracontractual rights involved a fiduciary duty to creditors.
  • 98
    • 36549072516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Simons v. Cogans, 542 A.2d 785, 788 (Del. Ch. 1987) (quoting with approval 1987 chancery court opinion that '(i) a debenture holder has no independent right to maintain a claim for breach of fiduciary duty and (ii) in the absence of fraud, insolvency or a statutory violation, a debenture holder's rights are defined by the terms of the indenture'
    • See, e.g., Simons v. Cogans, 542 A.2d 785, 788 (Del. Ch. 1987) (quoting with approval 1987 chancery court opinion that "'(i) a debenture holder has no independent right to maintain a claim for breach of fiduciary duty and (ii) in the absence of fraud, insolvency or a statutory violation, a debenture holder's rights are defined by the terms of the indenture'"
  • 99
    • 36549032208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Cont'l Ill. Nat'l Bank & Trust Co. v. Hunt Int'l Res. Corp., No. 7888, 1987 WL 55826, at *4 (Del. Ch. Feb. 27, 1987))), aff'd, 549 A.2d 300 (Del. 1988). The Delaware Supreme Court expressly predicated the existence of any fiduciary duty owed by management on an existing property right or equitable interest supporting such a duty; until a debenture is converted into stock, the holder has no equitable interest and remains a creditor whose interests are protected by the contractual terms of the indenture. 549 A.2d at 304. The court also noted that an equitable interest in the issuing corporation [is] necessary for the imposition of a trust relationship with concomitant fiduciary duties.
    • (quoting Cont'l Ill. Nat'l Bank & Trust Co. v. Hunt Int'l Res. Corp., No. 7888, 1987 WL 55826, at *4 (Del. Ch. Feb. 27, 1987))), aff'd, 549 A.2d 300 (Del. 1988). The Delaware Supreme Court expressly predicated the existence of any fiduciary duty owed by management on an "existing property right or equitable interest supporting such a duty"; until a debenture is converted into stock, the holder has no equitable interest and remains a creditor "whose interests are protected by the contractual terms of the indenture." 549 A.2d at 304. The court also noted that "an equitable interest in the issuing corporation [is] necessary for the imposition of a trust relationship with concomitant fiduciary duties."
  • 100
    • 36549086807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 303
    • Id. at 303.
  • 101
    • 36549000767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With perhaps one major exception, all of the decisions in which courts have allowed recovery on such grounds involved directors of an insolvent corporation diverting corporate assets for the benefit of insiders or preferred creditors. Professor Laura Lin groups the cases as follows: (1) withdrawing assets from the insolvent corporation as alleged payment of claims that the directors had against the corporation, such as loans to the company or unpaid commissions; (2) using corporate funds to pay off the company's loans that the directors had personally guaranteed; (3) engaging in transactions, usually without fair consideration to the company, for the benefit of its parent corporation or related entities; (4) pocketing the proceeds of a sale of all corporate assets to a third party or otherwise transferring property to a related entity, leaving the former corporation insolvent; and (5) other forms of self-dealing in which die directors use assets of the insolvent firm for their own bene
    • With perhaps one major exception, all of the decisions in which courts have allowed recovery on such grounds involved directors of an insolvent corporation diverting corporate assets for the benefit of insiders or preferred creditors. Professor Laura Lin groups the cases as follows: (1) withdrawing assets from the insolvent corporation as alleged payment of claims that the directors had against the corporation, such as loans to the company or unpaid commissions; (2) using corporate funds to pay off the company's loans that the directors had personally guaranteed; (3) engaging in transactions, usually without fair consideration to the company, for the benefit of its parent corporation or related entities; (4) pocketing the proceeds of a sale of all corporate assets to a third party or otherwise transferring property to a related entity, leaving the former corporation insolvent; and (5) other forms of self-dealing in which die directors use assets of the insolvent firm for their own benefit, such as pledging stock owned by the corporation as collateral to finance the directors' personal stock purchases. Laura Lin, Shift of Fiduciary Duty upon Corporate Insolvency: Proper Scope of Directors' Duty to Creditors, 46 Vand. L. Rev. 1485, 1513-14 (1993) (citations omitted).
  • 102
    • 36549005554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The exception is N.Y. Credit Men's Adjustment Bureau v. Weiss, 110 N.E.2d 397 (N.Y. 1953). For a discussion of this case,
    • The exception is N.Y. Credit Men's Adjustment Bureau v. Weiss, 110 N.E.2d 397 (N.Y. 1953). For a discussion of this case,
  • 103
    • 0242680328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Jonathan C. Lipson, Directors' Duties to Creditors: Power Imbalance and die Financially Distressed Corporation, 50 UCLA L. Rev. 1189, 1205-06 (2003);
    • see Jonathan C. Lipson, Directors' Duties to Creditors: Power Imbalance and die Financially Distressed Corporation, 50 UCLA L. Rev. 1189, 1205-06 (2003);
  • 104
    • 36549018150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Varallo & Finkelstein, supra note 41, at 247-48
    • Varallo & Finkelstein, supra note 41, at 247-48.
  • 105
    • 36549076052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is nonetheless noteworthy that the example used in Credit Lyonnais assumes a dead corporation, just like the carcasses in Wood and Bovay.
    • It is nonetheless noteworthy that the example used in Credit Lyonnais assumes a "dead" corporation, just like the carcasses in Wood and Bovay.
  • 106
    • 36549071600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of corporate investment decisions and their importance, see Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279-81
    • For a discussion of corporate "investment decisions" and their importance, see Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279-81.
  • 107
    • 36549026919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fact, Credit Lyonnais not only intervenes as to investment decisions, but also as to the other major class of managerial decisions - financing decisions. For the distinction between investment decisions and financing decisions, see, for example, Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279 & n.1 (characterizing investment decisions as any use of current resources to achieve a future return and financing decisions as, roughly speaking, how the corporation obtains the money).
    • In fact, Credit Lyonnais not only intervenes as to investment decisions, but also as to the other major class of managerial decisions - financing decisions. For the distinction between investment decisions and financing decisions, see, for example, Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279 & n.1 (characterizing investment decisions as "any use of current resources to achieve a future return" and financing decisions as, roughly speaking, "how the corporation obtains the money").
  • 108
    • 36549016637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of this control versus economic rights theme in both the corporate governance system (i.e, voting rights versus economic rights) and the bankruptcy governance system i.e, control versus priority, see infra Parts II.C-D, III.B. We have also independentiy considered this theme previously in our respective fields. In the context of die bankruptcy governance system
    • For a discussion of this control versus economic rights theme in both the corporate governance system (i.e., voting rights versus economic rights) and the bankruptcy governance system (i.e., control versus priority), see infra Parts II.C-D, III.B. We have also independentiy considered this theme previously in our respective fields. In the context of die bankruptcy governance system,
  • 109
    • 2442585666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Control of Wealth in Bankruptcy, 82 Tex. L. Rev. 795, 797 nn.3-4 (2004) [hereinafter Westbrook, Control] ;
    • see Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Control of Wealth in Bankruptcy, 82 Tex. L. Rev. 795, 797 nn.3-4 (2004) [hereinafter Westbrook, Control] ;
  • 110
    • 84858453462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Goode, supra note 46, ¶¶2-02 to -08. In the context of the corporate governance system,
    • see also Goode, supra note 46, ¶¶2-02 to -08. In the context of the corporate governance system,
  • 111
    • 33749668495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Henry T. C. Hu & Bernard Black, Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership: Taxonomy, Implications, and Reforms, 61 Bus. Law. 1011, 1013-14 (2006) [hereinafter Hu & Black, Taxonomy];
    • see Henry T. C. Hu & Bernard Black, Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership: Taxonomy, Implications, and Reforms, 61 Bus. Law. 1011, 1013-14 (2006) [hereinafter Hu & Black, Taxonomy];
  • 112
    • 34249699743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry T. C. Hu & Bernard Black, Hedge Funds, Insiders, and the Decoupling of Economic and Voting Ownership: Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership, 13 J. Corp. Fin. 343, 353-55 (2007) [hereinafter Hu & Black, Decoupling].
    • Henry T. C. Hu & Bernard Black, Hedge Funds, Insiders, and the Decoupling of Economic and Voting Ownership: Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership, 13 J. Corp. Fin. 343, 353-55 (2007) [hereinafter Hu & Black, Decoupling].
  • 113
    • 36549065722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland, N.V. v. Pathe Commc'ns Corp, Civ. A. No. 12150, 1991 WL 277613, at *33-*34 Del. Ch. Dec. 30, 1991
    • Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland, N.V. v. Pathe Commc'ns Corp., Civ. A. No. 12150, 1991 WL 277613, at *33-*34 (Del. Ch. Dec. 30, 1991).
  • 114
    • 36549068258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at *34
    • Id. at *34.
  • 115
    • 36549016156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. It seemed clear that Credit Lyonnais created a shield for directors, not a sword to be used against them. Indeed, several years after Credit Lyonnais, shortly before resigning from the bench, Chancellor Allen offered dicta that appeared to exclude duty shifting as a sword in the hands of creditors. See Equity-Linked Investors, L.P. v. Adams, 705 A.2d 1040, 1041 (Del. Ch. 1997). This is not the law in Delaware today.
    • Id. It seemed clear that Credit Lyonnais created a shield for directors, not a sword to be used against them. Indeed, several years after Credit Lyonnais, shortly before resigning from the bench, Chancellor Allen offered dicta that appeared to exclude duty shifting as a sword in the hands of creditors. See Equity-Linked Investors, L.P. v. Adams, 705 A.2d 1040, 1041 (Del. Ch. 1997). This is not the law in Delaware today.
  • 116
    • 36549078186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV
    • See infra Part IV.
  • 117
    • 84858453463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The famous footnote follows: The possibility of insolvency can do curious things to incentives, exposing creditors to risks of opportunistic behavior and creating complexities for directors. Consider, for example, a solvent corporation having a single asset, a judgment for $51 million against a solvent debtor. The judgment is on appeal and thus subject to modification or reversal. Assume that the only liabilities of the company are to bondholders in the amount of $12 million. Assume that the array of probable outcomes of the appeal is as follows: Expected Value 25% chance of affirmance ($51mm) $12.75 70% chance of modification ($4mm) 2.8 5% chance of reversal ($0) 0 Expected Value of Judgment on Appeal Thus, the best evaluation is that the current value of the equity is $3.55 million, $15.55 million expected value of judgment on appeal, $12 million liability to bondholders, Now assume an offer to settle at $12.5 m
    • The famous footnote follows: The possibility of insolvency can do curious things to incentives, exposing creditors to risks of opportunistic behavior and creating complexities for directors. Consider, for example, a solvent corporation having a single asset, a judgment for $51 million against a solvent debtor. The judgment is on appeal and thus subject to modification or reversal. Assume that the only liabilities of the company are to bondholders in the amount of $12 million. Assume that the array of probable outcomes of the appeal is as follows: Expected Value 25% chance of affirmance ($51mm) $12.75 70% chance of modification ($4mm) 2.8 5% chance of reversal ($0) 0 Expected Value of Judgment on Appeal Thus, the best evaluation is that the current value of the equity is $3.55 million. ($15.55 million expected value of judgment on appeal - $12 million liability to bondholders). Now assume an offer to settle at $12.5 million (also consider one at $17.5 million). By what standard do the directors of the company evaluate the fairness of these offers? The creditors of this solvent company would be in favor of accepting either a $12.5 million offer or a $17.5 million offer. In either event they will avoid the 75% risk of insolvency and default. The stockholders, however, will plainly be opposed to acceptance of a $12.5 million setdement (under which they get practically nothing). More importantly, they very well may be opposed to acceptance of the $17.5 million offer under which the residual value of the corporation would increase from $3.5 to $5.5 million. This is so because the litigation alternative, with its 25% probability of a $39 million outcome to them ($51 milIon - $12 million = $39 million) has an expected value to the residual risk bearer of $9.75 million ($39 million × 25% chance of affirmance), substantially greater than the $5.5 million available to them in the settlement. While in fact the stockholders' preference would reflect their appetite for risk, it is possible (and with diversified shareholders likely) that shareholders would prefer rejection of both settlement offers. But if we consider the community of interests that the corporation represents it seems apparent that one should in this hypothetical accept die best settlement offer available providing it is greater than $15.55 million, and one below that amount should be rejected. But that result will not be reached by a director who thinks he owes duties directly to shareholders only. It will be reached by directors who are capable of conceiving of the corporation as a legal and economic entity. Such directors will recognize that in managing the business affairs of a solvent corporation in the vicinity of insolvency, circumstances may arise when the right (both the efficient and the fair) course to follow for the corporation may diverge from the choice that the stockholders (or the creditors, or the employees, or any single group interested in the corporation) would make if given the opportunity to act. Credit Lyonnais, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 n.55.
  • 118
    • 36549075607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Chancellor Allen's litigation example implicitly weighs conflicting interests, there is no reason to believe that those weights were meant to (or even can) be used in nonlitigation contexts. See infra Part II.C.2
    • Although Chancellor Allen's litigation example implicitly weighs conflicting interests, there is no reason to believe that those weights were meant to (or even can) be used in nonlitigation contexts. See infra Part II.C.2.
  • 119
    • 36549025924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 863 A.2d 772, 790-91 (Del. Ch. 2004). In this case, Production Resources had obtained a judgment against NCT Group, Inc., but had been unsuccessful in collecting the judgment Production Resources claimed NCT was insolvent and sought to protect its interests by the appointment of a receiver for NCT under Delaware law. Production Resources also alleged that NCT's board and one of its officers had breached their fiduciary duties. Credit Lyonnais and the trust fund doctrine came up in a procedural context: NCT claimed that this fiduciary breach count raised derivative claims that Production Resources had not properly pled. If die nature of the claim was direct, rather than derivative, the count would not be barred.
    • 863 A.2d 772, 790-91 (Del. Ch. 2004). In this case, Production Resources had obtained a judgment against NCT Group, Inc., but had been unsuccessful in collecting the judgment Production Resources claimed NCT was insolvent and sought to protect its interests by the appointment of a receiver for NCT under Delaware law. Production Resources also alleged that NCT's board and one of its officers had breached their fiduciary duties. Credit Lyonnais and the trust fund doctrine came up in a procedural context: NCT claimed that this fiduciary breach count raised derivative claims that Production Resources had not properly pled. If die nature of the claim was direct, rather than derivative, the count would not be barred.
  • 120
    • 36549072040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also U.S. Bank Nat'l Ass'n v. U.S. Timberlands Klamath Falls, L.L.C., 864 A.2d 930, 947-48 (Del. Ch. 2004) ( [Directors' or managers' fiduciary duties may extend to the interests of the company's creditors when the company is in the 'zone of insolvency.'), vacated, 875 A.2d 632 (Del. 2005);
    • See also U.S. Bank Nat'l Ass'n v. U.S. Timberlands Klamath Falls, L.L.C., 864 A.2d 930, 947-48 (Del. Ch. 2004) (" [Directors' or managers' fiduciary duties may extend to the interests of the company's creditors when the company is in the 'zone of insolvency.'"), vacated, 875 A.2d 632 (Del. 2005);
  • 121
    • 36549004109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Odyssey Partners, L.P. v. Fleming Cos., 735 A.2d 386, 417 (Del. Ch. 1999) [W]hile directors normally do not owe creditors fiduciary duties, an exception exists in the case of insolvency _
    • Odyssey Partners, L.P. v. Fleming Cos., 735 A.2d 386, 417 (Del. Ch. 1999) ("[W]hile directors normally do not owe creditors fiduciary duties, an exception exists in the case of insolvency _"
  • 122
    • 36549024460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (citing Geyer v. Ingersoll Publ'ns, 621 A.2d 784, 787 (Del. Ch. 1992)));
    • (citing Geyer v. Ingersoll Publ'ns, 621 A.2d 784, 787 (Del. Ch. 1992)));
  • 123
    • 36549030833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Equity-Linked Investors, L.P. v. Adams, 705 A.2d 1040, 1042 (Del. Ch. 1997) (discussing interests of common stockholders relative to those of preferred stockholders);
    • Equity-Linked Investors, L.P. v. Adams, 705 A.2d 1040, 1042 (Del. Ch. 1997) (discussing interests of common stockholders relative to those of preferred stockholders);
  • 124
    • 36549026410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Haft v. Haft, 671 A.2d 413, 422 (Del. Ch. 1995) (discussing inefficiencies of proxy voting);
    • Haft v. Haft, 671 A.2d 413, 422 (Del. Ch. 1995) (discussing inefficiencies of proxy voting);
  • 125
    • 36549001256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geyer, 621 A.2d at 787 ([N] either party seriously disputes that when the insolvency exception does arise, it creates fiduciary duties for the benefit of creditors.).
    • Geyer, 621 A.2d at 787 ("[N] either party seriously disputes that when the insolvency exception does arise, it creates fiduciary duties for the benefit of creditors.").
  • 126
    • 36549064265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 17-24 (Del. May 18, 2007) (discussing court of chancery's opinion in Production Resources).
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 17-24 (Del. May 18, 2007) (discussing court of chancery's opinion in Production Resources).
  • 127
    • 36549020614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prod. Res. Group, 863 A.2d at 790 n.57. Vice Chancellor Strine said, elegantly and accurately, that he did not need to explore the metaphysical boundaries of the zone of insolvency because the company was insolvent.
    • Prod. Res. Group, 863 A.2d at 790 n.57. Vice Chancellor Strine said, elegantly and accurately, that he did not need to "explore the metaphysical boundaries of the zone of insolvency" because the company was insolvent.
  • 128
    • 36549056590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 790
    • Id. at 790.
  • 129
    • 36549088156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 790-91
    • Id. at 790-91.
  • 130
    • 36549002264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brandt v. Hicks, Muse & Co. (In re Healthco Int'l, Inc.), 208 B.R. 288, 302 (Bankr. D. Mass. 1997) (involving suit brought by trustee in bankruptcy on behalf of corporation but in interest of creditors).
    • Brandt v. Hicks, Muse & Co. (In re Healthco Int'l, Inc.), 208 B.R. 288, 302 (Bankr. D. Mass. 1997) (involving suit brought by trustee in bankruptcy on behalf of corporation but in interest of creditors).
  • 131
    • 36549090540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.E (warning that worthwhile bet the company risk taking may be precluded if Healthco is followed). It is worth noting that the corporation in Chancellor Allen's example in Credit Lyonnais was solvent, albeit comatose and with no business to operate.
    • See infra Part II.E (warning that worthwhile "bet the company" risk taking may be precluded if Healthco is followed). It is worth noting that the corporation in Chancellor Allen's example in Credit Lyonnais was solvent, albeit comatose and with no business to operate.
  • 132
    • 36549061513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is based on a search of the U.S. Law Reviews and Journals, Combined database on Lexis on August 4, 2006. Using the phrase credit lyonnais /10 pathe generated 160 items
    • This is based on a search of the "U.S. Law Reviews and Journals, Combined" database on Lexis on August 4, 2006. Using the phrase "credit lyonnais /10 pathe" generated 160 items.
  • 133
    • 36549056589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark J. Roe, Bankruptcy and Debt: A New Model for Corporate Reorganizations, 83 Colum. L. Rev. 527, 583 (1983).
    • Mark J. Roe, Bankruptcy and Debt: A New Model for Corporate Reorganizations, 83 Colum. L. Rev. 527, 583 (1983).
  • 134
    • 36549079606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporation Law and Economics
    • Stephen M. Bainbridge, Corporation Law and Economics 431 (2002);
    • (2002) Bainbridge , pp. 431
    • Stephen, M.1
  • 135
    • 18844441259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Sabin Willed, The Shallows of Deepening Insolvency, 60 Bus. Law. 549, 561 (2005) (viewing insolvent company as dea[d] and its owners as having no real interest in it);
    • see also Sabin Willed, The Shallows of Deepening Insolvency, 60 Bus. Law. 549, 561 (2005) (viewing insolvent company as "dea[d]" and its owners as having no real interest in it);
  • 136
    • 84909007200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Janis Sarra, Taking the Corporation past the 'Plimsoll Line'-Director and Officer Liability When the Corporation Founders, 10 Int'l Insolvency Rev. 229, 233-34 (2001) (asserting residual claimant justification for duty shifting in context of Canadian doctrine). The statements set out in the text represent the classic conflating of insolvency, an economic state, and bankruptcy, a legal proceeding. In a recent essay, Professor Bainbridge appears to have modified his views on duty shifting somewhat, but continues to subscribe to duty shifting's vision that shareholders are nothing more than as-if liquidation residual claimants.
    • cf. Janis Sarra, Taking the Corporation past the 'Plimsoll Line'-Director and Officer Liability When the Corporation Founders, 10 Int'l Insolvency Rev. 229, 233-34 (2001) (asserting residual claimant justification for duty shifting in context of Canadian doctrine). The statements set out in the text represent the classic conflating of insolvency, an economic state, and bankruptcy, a legal proceeding. In a recent essay, Professor Bainbridge appears to have modified his views on duty shifting somewhat, but continues to subscribe to duty shifting's vision that shareholders are nothing more than as-if liquidation residual claimants.
  • 137
    • 36549084641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, Much Ado About Little? Directors' Fiduciary Duties in the Vicinity of Insolvency, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 335 passim (2007).
    • See Stephen M. Bainbridge, Much Ado About Little? Directors' Fiduciary Duties in the Vicinity of Insolvency, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 335 passim (2007).
  • 138
    • 0036879761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Alon Chaver & Jesse M. Fried, Managers' Fiduciary Duty upon the Firm's Insolvency: Accounting for Performance Creditors, 55 Vand. L. Rev. 1813, 1815-16 (2002) (discussing rationales for duty shifting with respect to performance creditors);
    • See, e.g., Alon Chaver & Jesse M. Fried, Managers' Fiduciary Duty upon the Firm's Insolvency: Accounting for Performance Creditors, 55 Vand. L. Rev. 1813, 1815-16 (2002) (discussing rationales for duty shifting with respect to performance creditors);
  • 139
    • 36549006527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew Keay, Directors' Duties to Creditors: Contractarian Concerns Relating to Efficiency and Over-Protection of Creditors, 66 Mod. L. Rev. 665, 693-98 (2003) (discussing rationales for duty shifting with respect to employees, customers, involuntary creditors, and many trade creditors);
    • Andrew Keay, Directors' Duties to Creditors: Contractarian Concerns Relating to Efficiency and Over-Protection of Creditors, 66 Mod. L. Rev. 665, 693-98 (2003) (discussing rationales for duty shifting with respect to employees, customers, involuntary creditors, and many trade creditors);
  • 140
    • 36549083444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lipson, supra note 49, at 1245-48 discussing rationales for duty shifting with respect to tort and wage claimants
    • Lipson, supra note 49, at 1245-48 (discussing rationales for duty shifting with respect to tort and wage claimants).
  • 141
    • 36549018619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We are sympathetic to the special needs of constituencies such as involuntary creditors but feel that any accommodation for those needs must be based on approaches far more finely tuned than duty shifting. See infra note 268 elaborating on this and discussing pertinent bankruptcy statute provisions
    • We are sympathetic to the special needs of constituencies such as involuntary creditors but feel that any accommodation for those needs must be based on approaches far more finely tuned than duty shifting. See infra note 268 (elaborating on this and discussing pertinent bankruptcy statute provisions).
  • 142
    • 36549003179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lipson, supra note 49, at 1211 (stating that chief criticism of Credit Lyonnais is that it creates uncertainty);
    • See, e.g., Lipson, supra note 49, at 1211 (stating that "chief criticism" of Credit Lyonnais is that it "creates uncertainty");
  • 143
    • 36549073713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frederick Tung, Gap Filling in the Zone of Insolvency, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 1201, 1204 (2007) (arguing that fiduciary duties to creditors are unnecessary and may be counterproductive).
    • Frederick Tung, Gap Filling in the Zone of Insolvency, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 1201, 1204 (2007) (arguing that fiduciary duties to creditors "are unnecessary and may be counterproductive").
  • 144
    • 36549043477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a recent essay criticizing duty shifting resting in large part on the desirability of general directorial insulation from challenge, see Richard A. Booth, The Duty to Creditors Reconsidered-Filling a Much Needed Gap in Corporation Law, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 415, 425 2007
    • For a recent essay criticizing duty shifting resting in large part on the desirability of general directorial insulation from challenge, see Richard A. Booth, The Duty to Creditors Reconsidered-Filling a Much Needed Gap in Corporation Law, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 415, 425 (2007).
  • 145
    • 36549027909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For very thoughtful discussions of the effect of these doctrines on the capacity of the corporation's legal advisors to advise management, see Royce de Rohan Barondes, Fiduciary Duties in Distressed Corporations: Second Generation Issues, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 371, 378-87 (2007);
    • For very thoughtful discussions of the effect of these doctrines on the capacity of the corporation's legal advisors to advise management, see Royce de Rohan Barondes, Fiduciary Duties in Distressed Corporations: Second Generation Issues, 1 J. Bus. & Tech. L. 371, 378-87 (2007);
  • 146
    • 36549067773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bruce A. Markell, The Folly of Representing Insolvent Corporations: Examining Lawyer Liability and Ethical Issues Involved in Extending Fiduciary Duties to Creditors, 6 J. Bankr. L. & Prac 403, 413-27 (1997).
    • Bruce A. Markell, The Folly of Representing Insolvent Corporations: Examining Lawyer Liability and Ethical Issues Involved in Extending Fiduciary Duties to Creditors, 6 J. Bankr. L. & Prac 403, 413-27 (1997).
  • 147
    • 36549043483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of Campbell and Frost's helpful article, see supra note 9
    • For a discussion of Campbell and Frost's helpful article, see supra note 9.
  • 148
    • 36549002263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One recent article claims that a corporation's use of net present value in deciding on investments would [serve] the interests of all corporate constituencies. See Remus D. Valsan & Moin A. Yahya, Shareholders, Creditors, and Directors' Fiduciary Duties: A Law and Finance Approach, 2 Va. L. & Bus. Rev. 1, 4 (2007). As to their critical claim that maximizing the value of the firm is functionally equivalent with maximizing shareholder value, Valsan and Yahya note that one of the authors of this Article has a different opinion and outlines that opinion.
    • One recent article claims that a corporation's use of net present value in deciding on investments would "[serve] the interests of all corporate constituencies." See Remus D. Valsan & Moin A. Yahya, Shareholders, Creditors, and Directors' Fiduciary Duties: A Law and Finance Approach, 2 Va. L. & Bus. Rev. 1, 4 (2007). As to their critical claim that "maximizing the value of the firm is functionally equivalent with maximizing shareholder value," Valsan and Yahya note that one of the authors of this Article has "a different opinion" and outlines that opinion.
  • 149
    • 36549049871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 40 & n.108
    • Id. at 40 & n.108
  • 150
    • 36549018161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (referring to Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12). On there being a difference in opinion, we agree. Valsan and Yahya fail to address a number of crucial matters, including differences between diversifiable and nondiversifiable risk, die impact of shareholder diversification on how net present value calculations should be adjusted for risk, and corporate decisions that are not translatable into net present value terms. The closest Valsan and Yahya come to addressing the issue of diversifiable versus nondiversifable risk appears at the end of footnote 157, wherein they appear to assume away conflicts between diversified shareholders and creditors on the ground that shareholders in a corporation would also hold bonds in the corporation-and in just the right amounts.
    • (referring to Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12). On there being a difference in opinion, we agree. Valsan and Yahya fail to address a number of crucial matters, including differences between diversifiable and nondiversifiable risk, die impact of shareholder diversification on how net present value calculations should be adjusted for risk, and corporate decisions that are not translatable into net present value terms. The closest Valsan and Yahya come to addressing the issue of diversifiable versus nondiversifable risk appears at the end of footnote 157, wherein they appear to assume away conflicts between diversified shareholders and creditors on the ground that shareholders in a corporation would also hold bonds in the corporation-and in just the right amounts.
  • 151
    • 36549018630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 49 n.157
    • Id. at 49 n.157.
  • 152
    • 36549014164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, its 2003 opinion in Omnicare, Inc. v. NCS Healthcare, Inc. could be read to reject duty shifting, although it did not cite Credit Lyonnais. In Omnicare, the majority noted: Notwithstanding the corporation's insolvent condition, the NCS board had no authority to execute a merger agreement that subsequendy prevented it from effectively discharging its ongoing fiduciary responsibilities. The stockholders of a Delaware corporation are entitled to rely upon the board to discharge its fiduciary duties at all times. The fiduciary duties of a director are unremitting and must be effectively discharged in the specific context of the actions that are required with regard to the corporation or its stockholders as circumstances change. 818 A.2d. 914, 938 Del. 2003, citations omitted
    • Indeed, its 2003 opinion in Omnicare, Inc. v. NCS Healthcare, Inc. could be read to reject duty shifting, although it did not cite Credit Lyonnais. In Omnicare, the majority noted: Notwithstanding the corporation's insolvent condition, the NCS board had no authority to execute a merger agreement that subsequendy prevented it from effectively discharging its ongoing fiduciary responsibilities. The stockholders of a Delaware corporation are entitled to rely upon the board to discharge its fiduciary duties at all times. The fiduciary duties of a director are unremitting and must be effectively discharged in the specific context of the actions that are required with regard to the corporation or its stockholders as circumstances change. 818 A.2d. 914, 938 (Del. 2003) (citations omitted).
  • 153
    • 36549016160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a June 2006 bankruptcy opinion indicates that, notwithstanding the critical nature of the issue, none of the parties even tried to dispute that Delaware law imposed fiduciary duties to creditors once a corporation was operating in the vicinity of insolvency. Official Comm. of Unsecured Creditors of Verestar, Inc. v. Am. Tower Corp. (In re Verestar, Inc.), 343 B.R. 444, 471 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2006). In a July 2005 opinion, the chief judge of the District of Delaware's Bankruptcy Court adopted the Credit Lyonnais insolvency or vicinity of insolvency as the trigger for duty shifting; she neither referenced Omnicare on this issue nor gave any indication that any litigant disputed her characterization.
    • For example, a June 2006 bankruptcy opinion indicates that, notwithstanding the critical nature of the issue, none of the parties even tried to dispute that Delaware law imposed fiduciary duties to creditors once a corporation was operating in the "vicinity of insolvency." Official Comm. of Unsecured Creditors of Verestar, Inc. v. Am. Tower Corp. (In re Verestar, Inc.), 343 B.R. 444, 471 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2006). In a July 2005 opinion, the chief judge of the District of Delaware's Bankruptcy Court adopted the Credit Lyonnais insolvency or "vicinity of insolvency" as the trigger for duty shifting; she neither referenced Omnicare on this issue nor gave any indication that any litigant disputed her characterization.
  • 154
    • 36549056598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Liquidation Trust of Hechinger Inv. Co. of Del. v. Fleet Retail Fin. Group (In re Hechinger Inv. Co. of Del.), 327 B.R. 537, 548 (Bankr. D. Del. 2005).
    • Liquidation Trust of Hechinger Inv. Co. of Del. v. Fleet Retail Fin. Group (In re Hechinger Inv. Co. of Del.), 327 B.R. 537, 548 (Bankr. D. Del. 2005).
  • 155
    • 36549080098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007) (When a corporation is insolvent, however, its creditors take the place of the shareholders as the residual beneficiaries of any increase in value.).
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007) ("When a corporation is insolvent, however, its creditors take the place of the shareholders as the residual beneficiaries of any increase in value.").
  • 156
    • 36549004606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 3. Importantly, the lower court held it did not have to determine if Clearwire was insolvent or in the vicinity of insolvency, so the holding in the case must stand independent of that factual question. See N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. Civ. A. 1456-N, 2006 WL 2588971, at *6 n.65 Del. Ch. Sept. 1, 2006
    • Id. at 3. Importantly, the lower court held it did not have to determine if Clearwire was insolvent or in the vicinity of insolvency, so the holding in the case must stand independent of that factual question. See N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. Civ. A. 1456-N, 2006 WL 2588971, at *6 n.65 (Del. Ch. Sept. 1, 2006).
  • 157
    • 36549054718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • slip op. at
    • North American, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 24.
    • (2006) North American , Issue.521 , pp. 24
  • 158
    • 36549047999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 17-19
    • Id. at 17-19.
  • 159
    • 36549028359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19 (referring to need for providing directors with definitive guidance). We believe, however, that in actual litigation, the distinction between whether a corporation is insolvent or merely in the zone of insolvency can also be far from clear. Even in the Delaware duty shifting cases themselves, there is no agreement as to what insolvency means. Compare Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A2d 772, 782 (Del. Ch. 2004) (holding that insolvency means either (1) an asset shortfall in face of which no reasonable prospect of successful continuation exists, or (2) 'an inability to meet maturing obligations as they fall due'
    • Id. at 19 (referring to "need for providing directors with definitive guidance"). We believe, however, that in actual litigation, the distinction between whether a corporation is "insolvent" or merely in the "zone of insolvency" can also be far from clear. Even in the Delaware duty shifting cases themselves, there is no agreement as to what "insolvency" means. Compare Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A2d 772, 782 (Del. Ch. 2004) (holding that insolvency means either (1) an asset shortfall in face of which no reasonable prospect of successful continuation exists, or (2) "'an inability to meet maturing obligations as they fall due'"
  • 160
    • 36549017654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Siple v. S & K Plumbing & Heating, Inc., No. 6731, 1982 WL 8769, at *2 (Del. Ch. Apr. 13, 1982))),
    • (quoting Siple v. S & K Plumbing & Heating, Inc., No. 6731, 1982 WL 8769, at *2 (Del. Ch. Apr. 13, 1982))),
  • 161
    • 36549064747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • with Geyer v. Ingersoll Publ'ns Co., 621 A.2d 784, 787-90 (defining insolvency as when value of assets is less than amount of debts).
    • with Geyer v. Ingersoll Publ'ns Co., 621 A.2d 784, 787-90 (defining insolvency as when value of assets is less than amount of debts).
  • 162
    • 36549077726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A 2005 Delaware bankruptcy court, purporting to apply Delaware duty shifting doctrines, looked at neither Production Resources nor Geyer for guidance as to the meaning of insolvency, but instead at the Bankruptcy Code. In re Hechinger Inv. Co., 327 B.R. at 548.
    • A 2005 Delaware bankruptcy court, purporting to apply Delaware duty shifting doctrines, looked at neither Production Resources nor Geyer for guidance as to the meaning of "insolvency," but instead at the Bankruptcy Code. In re Hechinger Inv. Co., 327 B.R. at 548.
  • 163
    • 36549075149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, slip op. at
    • See North American, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20-21.
    • (2006) North American , Issue.521 , pp. 20-21
  • 164
    • 36549043941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 165
    • 36549062997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Prod. Res. Group, 863 A.2d at 792).
    • (quoting Prod. Res. Group, 863 A.2d at 792).
  • 166
    • 36549013196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part IV
    • See infra Part IV.
  • 167
    • 84858453856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Const, art. I, § 8, c1.4.
    • U.S. Const, art. I, § 8, c1.4.
  • 168
    • 36549006528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bankruptcy Act of 1898, ch. 541, 30 Stat. 544, repealed by Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-598, 92 Stat. 2549, 2682.
    • Bankruptcy Act of 1898, ch. 541, 30 Stat. 544, repealed by Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-598, 92 Stat. 2549, 2682.
  • 169
    • 36549009126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 107-08;
    • Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 107-08;
  • 170
    • 36549010490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also David A. Skeel, Jr., Debt's Dominion: A History of Bankruptcy Law in America 24-28 (2001) [hereinafter Skeel, Debt's Dominion] (describing various bankruptcy laws enacted during nineteenth century);
    • see also David A. Skeel, Jr., Debt's Dominion: A History of Bankruptcy Law in America 24-28 (2001) [hereinafter Skeel, Debt's Dominion] (describing various bankruptcy laws enacted during nineteenth century);
  • 171
    • 36549088629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles Warren, Bankruptcy in United States History 3-141 (1935) (describing attempts at bankrupcty legislation in United States up to 1898).
    • Charles Warren, Bankruptcy in United States History 3-141 (1935) (describing attempts at bankrupcty legislation in United States up to 1898).
  • 172
    • 36549023992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bankruptcy Act of 1867, ch. 176, 14 Stat. 517 (repealed 1878). In the 1898 Bankruptcy Act, corporations were not permitted to use die composition provisions that were that Act's closest approach to reorganization.
    • Bankruptcy Act of 1867, ch. 176, 14 Stat. 517 (repealed 1878). In the 1898 Bankruptcy Act, corporations were not permitted to use die composition provisions that were that Act's closest approach to reorganization.
  • 173
    • 7544241604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Stephen J. Lubben, Railroad Receiverships and Modern Bankruptcy Theory, 89 Cornell L. Rev. 1420, 1440 (2004) (noting that the [1898] Bankruptcy Act did not permit the reorganization of large corporations and expressly excepted railroads from its scope).
    • See Stephen J. Lubben, Railroad Receiverships and Modern Bankruptcy Theory, 89 Cornell L. Rev. 1420, 1440 (2004) (noting that "the [1898] Bankruptcy Act did not permit the reorganization of large corporations and expressly excepted railroads from its scope").
  • 174
    • 36549020044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Novica Petrovski, The Bankruptcy Code, Section 1121: Exclusivity Reloaded, 11 Am. Bankr. Inst. L. Rev. 451, 455 n.12 (2003).
    • Novica Petrovski, The Bankruptcy Code, Section 1121: Exclusivity Reloaded, 11 Am. Bankr. Inst. L. Rev. 451, 455 n.12 (2003).
  • 175
    • 84858453452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The same thing was true of insolvency statutes around the world. Most of them, like the United States law, contained a composition provision, but those provisions were notoriously ill-designed and nearly useless. See generally 1 J.H. Dalhuisen, Dalhuisen on International Insolvency and Bankruptcy, pt. I, § 2.01 (1986) (describing development of corporate reorganization law and composition provisions in United States and western Europe).
    • The same thing was true of insolvency statutes around the world. Most of them, like the United States law, contained a "composition" provision, but those provisions were notoriously ill-designed and nearly useless. See generally 1 J.H. Dalhuisen, Dalhuisen on International Insolvency and Bankruptcy, pt. I, § 2.01 (1986) (describing development of corporate reorganization law and composition provisions in United States and western Europe).
  • 176
    • 36549003177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lubben, supra note 82, at 1426-52 (discussing history of railroad industry receiverships in late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries);
    • See Lubben, supra note 82, at 1426-52 (discussing history of railroad industry receiverships in late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries);
  • 178
    • 36549003636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Skeel, Debt's Dominion, supra note 81, at 48-70 discussing railroad receiverships in general
    • See generally Skeel, Debt's Dominion, supra note 81, at 48-70 (discussing railroad receiverships in general).
  • 179
    • 36549045102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Act of June 22, 1938, Pub. L. No. 75-696, 52 Stat. 840 (repealed 1978);
    • Act of June 22, 1938, Pub. L. No. 75-696, 52 Stat. 840 (repealed 1978);
  • 180
    • 26844543257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harvey R. Miller & Shai Y. Waisman, Does Chapter 11 Reorganization Remain a Viable Option for Distressed Businesses for the Twenty-First Century?, 78 Am. Bankr. L.J. 153, 167 (2004) (The so-called 'Great Depression' of the 1930s was the catalyst for the codification of principles that had evolved in the Railroad Equity Receiverships.);
    • Harvey R. Miller & Shai Y. Waisman, Does Chapter 11 Reorganization Remain a Viable Option for Distressed Businesses for the Twenty-First Century?, 78 Am. Bankr. L.J. 153, 167 (2004) ("The so-called 'Great Depression' of the 1930s was the catalyst for the codification of principles that had evolved in the Railroad Equity Receiverships.");
  • 181
    • 36549022121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles J. Tabb, The Future of Chapter 11, 44 S.C. L. Rev. 791, 806 (1993) (Chapter 11 is the product of experience. Equity receiverships were used because voluntary deals could not be made. Section 77B and then Chapters X and XI, which were designed to replace equity receiverships, were enacted for the same reason. So too with Chapter 11 in 1978.).
    • Charles J. Tabb, The Future of Chapter 11, 44 S.C. L. Rev. 791, 806 (1993) ("Chapter 11 is the product of experience. Equity receiverships were used because voluntary deals could not be made. Section 77B and then Chapters X and XI, which were designed to replace equity receiverships, were enacted for the same reason. So too with Chapter 11 in 1978.").
  • 182
    • 84858453852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-598, 92 Stat. 2549 (codified as amended at 11 U.S.C. §§ 101-1300 2000
    • Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-598, 92 Stat. 2549 (codified as amended at 11 U.S.C. §§ 101-1300 (2000)).
  • 183
    • 36549004108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Miller & Waisman, supra note 87, at 199-200 (noting that European countries are mov[ing] towards a reorganization model similar to . . . chapter 11).
    • See, e.g., Miller & Waisman, supra note 87, at 199-200 (noting that European countries are "mov[ing] towards a reorganization model similar to . . . chapter 11").
  • 184
    • 84858469511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 U.S.C. § 701 (a) (1) (Promptly after the order for relief under this chapter, the United States trustee shall appoint one disinterested person ... to serve as interim trustee in the case.); § 702(b) (At the meeting of creditors held under section 341 of this title, creditors may elect one person to serve as trustee in the case . . . .).
    • 11 U.S.C. § 701 (a) (1) ("Promptly after the order for relief under this chapter, the United States trustee shall appoint one disinterested person ... to serve as interim trustee in the case."); § 702(b) ("At the meeting of creditors held under section 341 of this title, creditors may elect one person to serve as trustee in the case . . . .").
  • 185
    • 84858453449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 704 (requiring trustee to collect and reduce to money the property of the estate for which such trustee serves, and close such estate as expeditiously as is compatible with the best interests of parties in interest).
    • § 704 (requiring trustee to "collect and reduce to money the property of the estate for which such trustee serves, and close such estate as expeditiously as is compatible with the best interests of parties in interest").
  • 186
    • 84858463693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 704(a) (listing trustee's duties in administering Chapter 7 estate);
    • § 704(a) (listing trustee's duties in administering Chapter 7 estate);
  • 187
    • 84858453447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C.A. § 1106(a) (West 2004 & Supp. 2007) (giving Chapter 11 trustee most of duties of Chapter 7 trustee);
    • U.S.C.A. § 1106(a) (West 2004 & Supp. 2007) (giving Chapter 11 trustee most of duties of Chapter 7 trustee);
  • 188
    • 84858463695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C. § 1107(a) (giving Debtor in Possession most of powers and duties of Chapter 11 trustee); § 1108 (giving Chapter 11 trustee power to operate debtor's business).
    • U.S.C. § 1107(a) (giving Debtor in Possession most of powers and duties of Chapter 11 trustee); § 1108 (giving Chapter 11 trustee power to operate debtor's business).
  • 189
    • 84858453846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1109(b) (A party in interest... may raise and may appear and be heard on any issue in a case under this chapter.). In large cases, there is often a creditors' committee that acts for creditors generally. § 1102 ([T] he United States trustee shall appoint a committee of creditors holding unsecured claims and may appoint additional committees of creditors or of equity security holders ....).
    • § 1109(b) ("A party in interest... may raise and may appear and be heard on any issue in a case under this chapter."). In large cases, there is often a creditors' committee that acts for creditors generally. § 1102 ("[T] he United States trustee shall appoint a committee of creditors holding unsecured claims and may appoint additional committees of creditors or of equity security holders ....").
  • 190
    • 36549089535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lynn M. LoPucki & William C. Whitford, Patterns in the Reorganization of Large, Publicly Held Companies, 78 Cornell L. Rev. 597, 610-11 (1993) (discussing changes in share ownership in Chapter 11 reorganizations).
    • See, e.g., Lynn M. LoPucki & William C. Whitford, Patterns in the Reorganization of Large, Publicly Held Companies, 78 Cornell L. Rev. 597, 610-11 (1993) (discussing changes in share ownership in Chapter 11 reorganizations).
  • 191
    • 84858474111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 105c
    • 11 U.S.C. § 105(c);
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 192
    • 84858469507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S.C.A. § 157(b) (West 2006); 2 Collier on Bankruptcy 1 105.07 (rev. 15th ed. 2007).
    • U.S.C.A. § 157(b) (West 2006); 2 Collier on Bankruptcy 1 105.07 (rev. 15th ed. 2007).
  • 193
    • 36549087736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynn M. LoPucki, The Demographics of Bankruptcy Practice, 63 Am. Bankr. L.J. 289, 311 (1989) (Bankruptcy is probably among the most highly specialized areas of practice.).
    • Lynn M. LoPucki, The Demographics of Bankruptcy Practice, 63 Am. Bankr. L.J. 289, 311 (1989) ("Bankruptcy is probably among the most highly specialized areas of practice.").
  • 195
    • 36549081410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.D.2.
    • See infra Part II.D.2.
  • 196
    • 36549039098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.A
    • See infra Part II.A.
  • 197
    • 36549043478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B.1.
    • See infra Part II.B.1.
  • 198
    • 36549009118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B.2.
    • See infra Part II.B.2.
  • 199
    • 36549036222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C
    • See infra Part II.C.
  • 200
    • 36549022117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C.1.
    • See infra Part II.C.1.
  • 201
    • 36549076055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.C.2.
    • See infra Part II.C.2.
  • 202
    • 36549004601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.D
    • See infra Part II.D.
  • 203
    • 36549033336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.E
    • See infra Part II.E.
  • 204
    • 36549069759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 279.
  • 205
    • 36549033836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 206
    • 36549057068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These interconstituency and intraconstituency conflicts are discussed in greater detail in, for example, Henry T. C. Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge: Information and the Limits of Shareholder Wealth Maximization, J. Applied Corp. Fin., Fall 1996, at 39, 40-43 [hereinafter Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge];
    • These interconstituency and intraconstituency conflicts are discussed in greater detail in, for example, Henry T. C. Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge: Information and the Limits of "Shareholder Wealth Maximization," J. Applied Corp. Fin., Fall 1996, at 39, 40-43 [hereinafter Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge];
  • 207
    • 36549003178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry T. C. Hu, Buffett, Corporate Objectives, and the Nature of Sheep, 19 Cardozo L. Rev. 379, 392-95, 397-406 (1997)
    • Henry T. C. Hu, Buffett, Corporate Objectives, and the Nature of Sheep, 19 Cardozo L. Rev. 379, 392-95, 397-406 (1997)
  • 208
    • 36549073214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter Hu, Nature of Sheep]; Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1286-1309;
    • [hereinafter Hu, Nature of Sheep]; Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1286-1309;
  • 209
    • 36549066202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-306, 318-66;
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-306, 318-66;
  • 210
    • 36549063779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 53, at
    • Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1019 n.23.
    • Taxonomy, supra , Issue.23 , pp. 1019
    • Hu1    Black2
  • 211
    • 36549027428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to how modern financial science has helped us understand the divergence of interests, see, for example, Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 43-48;
    • As to how modern financial science has helped us understand the divergence of interests, see, for example, Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 43-48;
  • 212
    • 36549011296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-306, 318-47
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-306, 318-47.
  • 213
    • 36549012765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Robert Charles Clark, Corporate Law 33-34 (1986) (stating that major problem dealt with by corporate law is how to keep managers accountable while allowing them great discretionary power).
    • Cf. Robert Charles Clark, Corporate Law 33-34 (1986) (stating that "major problem dealt with by corporate law" is how to keep managers accountable while allowing them great discretionary power).
  • 214
    • 36549028360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adolph A. Berle, Jr. & Gardiner C. Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property 5 (1932).
    • Adolph A. Berle, Jr. & Gardiner C. Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property 5 (1932).
  • 215
    • 36549006055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Henry T. C. Hu, Hedging Expectations: Derivative Reality and the Law and Finance of the Corporate Objective, 73 Tex. L. Rev. 985, 1016-17 (1995)
    • See Henry T. C. Hu, Hedging Expectations: "Derivative Reality" and the Law and Finance of the Corporate Objective, 73 Tex. L. Rev. 985, 1016-17 (1995)
  • 216
    • 36549026918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • hereinafter Hu, Derivative Reality, Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 318-32
    • [hereinafter Hu, Derivative Reality]; Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 318-32.
  • 217
    • 36548999820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For discussions of when managers may want to take more risk than would be optimal for diversified shareholders, see Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives, supra note 18, at 1492-95;
    • For discussions of when managers may want to take more risk than would be optimal for diversified shareholders, see Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives, supra note 18, at 1492-95;
  • 218
    • 36549076060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 325-26, 328-32
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 325-26, 328-32.
  • 219
    • 36549014664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brian J. Hall, The Challenge of Turning Managers into Owners, NBER Rep., Summer 2004, at 9, 10-11 (finding that insufficient diversification is important part of establishing strong ownership incentives);
    • See Brian J. Hall, The Challenge of Turning Managers into Owners, NBER Rep., Summer 2004, at 9, 10-11 (finding that insufficient diversification is important part of establishing strong ownership incentives);
  • 220
    • 0036186952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brian J. Hall & Kevin J. Murphy, Stock Options for Undiversified Executives, 33 J. Acct. & Econ. 3, 8-21 (2002) (showing that stock options result in high costs to companies and lower values for managers).
    • Brian J. Hall & Kevin J. Murphy, Stock Options for Undiversified Executives, 33 J. Acct. & Econ. 3, 8-21 (2002) (showing that stock options result in high costs to companies and lower values for managers).
  • 221
    • 33751011019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For new evidence on how options holdings can sometimes substantially decrease executives' willingness to take risk, see Katharina Lewellen, Financing Decisions When Managers Are Risk Averse, 82 J. Fin. Econ. 551, 556-69 (2006).
    • For new evidence on how options holdings can sometimes substantially decrease executives' willingness to take risk, see Katharina Lewellen, Financing Decisions When Managers Are Risk Averse, 82 J. Fin. Econ. 551, 556-69 (2006).
  • 222
    • 36549047992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B
    • See infra Part II.B.
  • 223
    • 84866063049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a helpful survey and analysis of the literature on bank and bond covenants, see William W. Bratton, Bond Covenants and Creditor Protection: Economics and Law, Theory and Practice, Substance and Process, 7 Eur. Bus. Org. L. Rev. 39 (2006).
    • For a helpful survey and analysis of the literature on bank and bond covenants, see William W. Bratton, Bond Covenants and Creditor Protection: Economics and Law, Theory and Practice, Substance and Process, 7 Eur. Bus. Org. L. Rev. 39 (2006).
  • 224
    • 0041949150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Different legal systems around the world have made quite different decisions about legal priorities among creditors and other stakeholders, including employees. See generally Ulrik Rammeskow Bang-Pedersen, Asset Distribution in Transnational Insolvency: Combining Predictability and Protection of Local Interests, 73 Am. Bankr. L.J. 385 (1999, discussing possible distribution rules for transnational bankruptcies, Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Universal Participation in Transnational Bankruptcies, in Making Commercial Law: Essays in Honour of Roy Goode 419 (Ross Cranston ed, 1997, discussing priorities for distribution in transnational bankruptcies under European Union system);
    • Different legal systems around the world have made quite different decisions about legal priorities among creditors and other stakeholders, including employees. See generally Ulrik Rammeskow Bang-Pedersen, Asset Distribution in Transnational Insolvency: Combining Predictability and Protection of Local Interests, 73 Am. Bankr. L.J. 385 (1999) (discussing possible distribution rules for transnational bankruptcies); Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Universal Participation in Transnational Bankruptcies, in Making Commercial Law: Essays in Honour of Roy Goode 419 (Ross Cranston ed., 1997) (discussing priorities for distribution in transnational bankruptcies under European Union system);
  • 225
    • 36549013671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Universal Priorities, 33 Tex. Int'l L.J. 27, 30-31, 34 (1998) (discussing transnational insolvency problems raised by existence of different priority systems in different countries and policy reasons underlying United States priority system).
    • Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Universal Priorities, 33 Tex. Int'l L.J. 27, 30-31, 34 (1998) (discussing transnational insolvency problems raised by existence of different priority systems in different countries and policy reasons underlying United States priority system).
  • 226
    • 0039964962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a finance theory-oriented analysis, see Cheol Park, Monitoring and Structure of Debt Contracts, 55 J. Fin. 2157, 2172-85 (2000).
    • For a finance theory-oriented analysis, see Cheol Park, Monitoring and Structure of Debt Contracts, 55 J. Fin. 2157, 2172-85 (2000).
  • 227
    • 36549050812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are intercreditor agreements but they are almost always within alliances of lenders or other homogeneous subsets of creditors. See, e.g, Mark N. Berman &Jo Ann J. Brighton, Second-Lien Financings: Enforcement of Intercreditor Agreements in Bankruptcy, Am. Bankr. Inst. J, Feb. 2006, at 38, 39 (listing issues that might be presented to bankruptcy courts about the enforceability of provisions commonly found in intercreditor agreements used in second-lien financing transactions);
    • There are intercreditor agreements but they are almost always within alliances of lenders or other homogeneous subsets of creditors. See, e.g., Mark N. Berman &Jo Ann J. Brighton, Second-Lien Financings: Enforcement of Intercreditor Agreements in Bankruptcy, Am. Bankr. Inst. J., Feb. 2006, at 38, 39 (listing "issues that might be presented to bankruptcy courts about the enforceability of provisions commonly found in intercreditor agreements used in second-lien financing transactions");
  • 229
    • 36549032841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James C. Schulwolf, Controlling Your Destiny: Key Issues in Subordination and Intercreditor Agreements, Secured Lender, Nov.-Dec. 1995, at 22, 22 (discussing motivations for intercreditor agreements and common negotiation issues).
    • James C. Schulwolf, Controlling Your Destiny: Key Issues in Subordination and Intercreditor Agreements, Secured Lender, Nov.-Dec. 1995, at 22, 22 (discussing motivations for intercreditor agreements and common negotiation issues).
  • 230
    • 36549029295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to the concept of shareholders holding maximization rights, see supra note 17
    • As to the concept of shareholders holding "maximization rights," see supra note 17.
  • 231
    • 36549055167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 223-27 (outlining difference between secured and unsecured claims);
    • See Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 223-27 (outlining difference between secured and unsecured claims);
  • 232
    • 36549014162 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael J. Herbert & Domenic E. Pacitti, Down and Out in Richmond, Virginia: The Distribution of Assets in Chapter 7 Bankruptcy Proceedings Closed During 1984-1987, 22 U. Rich. L. Rev. 303, 310-11 (1988) (noting that, during period of study, over 95% of Chapter 7 cases did not pay distributions);
    • Michael J. Herbert & Domenic E. Pacitti, Down and Out in Richmond, Virginia: The Distribution of Assets in Chapter 7 Bankruptcy Proceedings Closed During 1984-1987, 22 U. Rich. L. Rev. 303, 310-11 (1988) (noting that, during period of study, over 95% of Chapter 7 cases did not pay distributions);
  • 233
    • 36549042034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynn M. LoPucki, Contract Bankruptcy: A Reply to Alan Schwartz, 109 Yale L.J. 317, 328 (1999) (noting that junior creditors prefer reorganization because it results in larger recovery than liquidation);
    • Lynn M. LoPucki, Contract Bankruptcy: A Reply to Alan Schwartz, 109 Yale L.J. 317, 328 (1999) (noting that junior creditors prefer reorganization because it results in larger recovery than liquidation);
  • 234
    • 36549061050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephen J. Lubben, Some Realism About Reorganization: Explaining the Failure of Chapter 11 Theory, 106 Dick. L. Rev. 267, 278 (2001) (discussing conflicting creditor preferences between liquidation and reorganization);
    • Stephen J. Lubben, Some Realism About Reorganization: Explaining the Failure of Chapter 11 Theory, 106 Dick. L. Rev. 267, 278 (2001) (discussing "conflicting creditor preferences between liquidation and reorganization");
  • 235
    • 80054815356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. John D. Ayer, Debt Abides: A Prolegomena for Any Future Chapter 11, 78 Am. Bankr. L.J. 427, 447-48 (2004) (illustrating differences in potential payoffs from equity and debt standpoints).
    • cf. John D. Ayer, Debt Abides: A Prolegomena for Any Future Chapter 11, 78 Am. Bankr. L.J. 427, 447-48 (2004) (illustrating differences in potential payoffs from equity and debt standpoints).
  • 236
    • 36549031719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Plender, Markets Versus the Conventional Wisdom in 2007, Fin. Times, Jan. 2, 2007, at 16. A credit derivative has been defined as a derivative whose payoff depends on die creditworthiness of one or more companies or countries.
    • John Plender, Markets Versus the Conventional Wisdom in 2007, Fin. Times, Jan. 2, 2007, at 16. A credit derivative has been defined as a "derivative whose payoff depends on die creditworthiness of one or more companies or countries."
  • 237
    • 36549088157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 6th ed., As to some questions for duty shifting posed by credit derivatives, see infra Part V
    • John C. Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 746 (6th ed. 2006). As to some questions for duty shifting posed by credit derivatives, see infra Part V
    • (2006) Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives , vol.746
    • Hull, J.C.1
  • 238
    • 36549079124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Debt Buyers vs. The Indebted
    • Oct. 17, at
    • Henry Sender, Debt Buyers vs. The Indebted, Wall St. J., Oct. 17, 2006, at C1.
    • (2006) Wall St. J
    • Sender, H.1
  • 239
    • 36549039589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Company's Road to Restructuring May Teem with Hedge-Fund Potholes
    • Mar. 30, at
    • Henry Sender, A Company's Road to Restructuring May Teem with Hedge-Fund Potholes, Wall St. J., Mar. 30, 2006, at Cl.
    • (2006) Wall St. J
    • Henry Sender, A.1
  • 240
    • 0347494187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, Lucian Ayre Bebchuk & Jesse M. Fried, The Uneasy Case for the Priority of Secured Claims in Bankruptcy, 105 Yale L.J. 857 (1996) (discussing secured creditors versus unsecured creditors, especially those unable to adjust their terms to varying bankruptcy provisions);
    • See generally, Lucian Ayre Bebchuk & Jesse M. Fried, The Uneasy Case for the Priority of Secured Claims in Bankruptcy, 105 Yale L.J. 857 (1996) (discussing secured creditors versus unsecured creditors, especially those unable to adjust their terms to varying bankruptcy provisions);
  • 241
    • 14544297334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth Warren &Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Contracting Out of Bankruptcy: An Empirical Intervention, 118 Harv. L. Rev. 1197, 1237 (2005) (providing empirical data showing substantial number of maladjusting creditors).
    • Elizabeth Warren &Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Contracting Out of Bankruptcy: An Empirical Intervention, 118 Harv. L. Rev. 1197, 1237 (2005) (providing empirical data showing substantial number of maladjusting creditors).
  • 242
    • 36549087737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts II.C, II.E
    • See infra Parts II.C, II.E.
  • 243
    • 36549060606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, the identity of the owners may change
    • Of course, the identity of the owners may change.
  • 244
    • 36549029840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 57 and accompanying text (analyzing Credit Lyonnais's famous footnote 55).
    • See supra note 57 and accompanying text (analyzing Credit Lyonnais's famous footnote 55).
  • 245
    • 36549020045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The discussion in this Part draws on an evolving framework set out in Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 40-50 (addressing corporate hedgingrelated distinctions between shareholder wealth maximization and shareholder welfare maximization from finance perspective);
    • The discussion in this Part draws on an evolving framework set out in Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 40-50 (addressing corporate hedgingrelated distinctions between "shareholder wealth maximization" and "shareholder welfare maximization" from finance perspective);
  • 246
    • 36549042030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 392-95, 397-407 (analyzing one prominent corporation essentially run on hybrid of actual and blissful shareholder wealth maximization);
    • Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 392-95, 397-407 (analyzing one prominent corporation essentially run on hybrid of "actual" and "blissful" shareholder wealth maximization);
  • 247
    • 36549013197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 996-1040 (discussing incompleteness of shareholder wealth maximization); Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1278-1309 (discussing financial innovation and the corporate objective, including new types of corporate securities and certain short-termism issues);
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 996-1040 (discussing incompleteness of "shareholder wealth maximization"); Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1278-1309 (discussing financial innovation and the corporate objective, including new types of corporate securities and certain "short-termism" issues);
  • 248
    • 36549023994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-366 (discussing three basic conceptions of shareholder fidelity);
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-366 (discussing three basic conceptions of shareholder fidelity);
  • 249
    • 36549060609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1019 n.23 (discussing hedge fund activism and short-termism);
    • Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1019 n.23 (discussing hedge fund activism and "short-termism");
  • 250
    • 36549023472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-63 (discussing shareholder ownership rights, shareholders that are empty voters, and how decoupling of economic ownership and voting ownership undermines existing legal and economic dieories of corporate governance).
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-63 (discussing shareholder ownership rights, shareholders that are "empty voters," and how decoupling of economic ownership and voting ownership undermines existing legal and economic dieories of corporate governance).
  • 251
    • 36549070684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Brealey & Stewart C. Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance 23-24 (7th ed. 2003) (arguing that managers should maximize market value of each stockholder's share).
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Brealey & Stewart C. Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance 23-24 (7th ed. 2003) (arguing that managers should maximize market value of each stockholder's share).
  • 252
    • 84858453431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I Am. Law Inst., Principles of Corporate Governance § 2.01 (1994).
    • I Am. Law Inst., Principles of Corporate Governance § 2.01 (1994).
  • 253
    • 84858453432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 2.01 reporter's note 1 (quoting Dodge v. Ford Motor Co., 170 N.W. 668, 684 (Mich. 1919)).
    • Id. § 2.01 reporter's note 1 (quoting Dodge v. Ford Motor Co., 170 N.W. 668, 684 (Mich. 1919)).
  • 254
    • 84858463683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rev. Model Bus. Corp. Act § 8.30(a) (2005).
    • Rev. Model Bus. Corp. Act § 8.30(a) (2005).
  • 255
    • 84858463684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 8.30(a) official cmt. 2
    • Id. § 8.30(a) official cmt. 2.
  • 256
    • 36549059198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v. QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 43 (Del. 1994)
    • Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v. QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 43 (Del. 1994)
  • 257
    • 36549027913 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Macmillan, Inc., 559
    • Del. 1989, quoting Mills Acquisition Co. v
    • (quoting Mills Acquisition Co. v. Macmillan, Inc., 559 A.2d 1261, 1280 (Del. 1989)).
    • A.2d , vol.1261 , pp. 1280
  • 258
    • 36549040525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007) (emphasis added).
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007) (emphasis added).
  • 259
    • 36549074181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 15, 19 (emphasis added);
    • Id. at 15, 19 (emphasis added);
  • 260
    • 36549005077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see infra Part II.E
    • see infra Part II.E.
  • 261
    • 36549026414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II.B.2.
    • See infra Part II.B.2.
  • 262
    • 36549042508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For discussions on the transition to actual shareholder wealth maximization, see Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1000-07;
    • For discussions on the transition to actual shareholder wealth maximization, see Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1000-07;
  • 263
    • 36549044979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1279-83;
    • Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1279-83;
  • 264
    • 36549077014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-306, 355-66;
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 295-306, 355-66;
  • 265
    • 34547162340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Rise of Independent Directors in the United States, 1950-2005: Of Shareholder Value and Stock Market Prices, 59 Stan. L. Rev. 1465, 1527-35 (2007) (discussing independent board and shareholder value).
    • cf. Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Rise of Independent Directors in the United States, 1950-2005: Of Shareholder Value and Stock Market Prices, 59 Stan. L. Rev. 1465, 1527-35 (2007) (discussing independent board and shareholder value).
  • 266
    • 36549065248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1282-83 (stating that [m]ost academics now believe that shareholder wealth maximization is the basic pecuniary objective of the modern publicly held corporations);
    • Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1282-83 (stating that "[m]ost academics now believe that shareholder wealth maximization is the basic pecuniary objective of the modern publicly held corporations");
  • 267
    • 36549082946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra Parts I.B.2, I.B.4 (discussing Credit Lyonnais, North American, and whether there exists duty to maximize shareholder wealth); infra Part IV (discussing North American and whether there exists duty to maximize shareholder wealth).
    • see also supra Parts I.B.2, I.B.4 (discussing Credit Lyonnais, North American, and whether there exists duty to maximize shareholder wealth); infra Part IV (discussing North American and whether there exists duty to maximize shareholder wealth).
  • 268
    • 36549002256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v. QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 44 (Del. 1994).
    • Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v. QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 44 (Del. 1994).
  • 269
    • 36549006999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 48;
    • Id. at 48;
  • 270
    • 36549005553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 182-83 (Del. 1986) (detailing duty of board after authorization of management to negotiate sale of company).
    • see also Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 182-83 (Del. 1986) (detailing duty of board after authorization of management to negotiate sale of company).
  • 271
    • 36549018160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Paramount Commc'ns, Inc. v. Time, Inc., 571 A.2d 1140, 1154 (Del. 1990) (stating that fiduciary duty to manage a corporate enterprise includes the selection of a time frame for achievement of corporate goals);
    • See Paramount Commc'ns, Inc. v. Time, Inc., 571 A.2d 1140, 1154 (Del. 1990) (stating that "fiduciary duty to manage a corporate enterprise includes the selection of a time frame for achievement of corporate goals");
  • 272
    • 36549043005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geller v. Tabas, 462 A.2d 1078, 1082 (Del. 1983) (relying on business judgment rule to strike plaintiff shareholders' claims of breach of fiduciary duty from company making speculative investments in silver and United States Treasury bond futures contracts);
    • Geller v. Tabas, 462 A.2d 1078, 1082 (Del. 1983) (relying on business judgment rule to strike plaintiff shareholders' claims of breach of fiduciary duty from company making speculative investments in silver and United States Treasury bond futures contracts);
  • 273
    • 36549076058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Penn v. Pemberton & Penn, 53 S.E.2d 823, 829 (Va. 1949) (They simply decided to do business in a very conservative way until there were reasonably good prospects of making substantial profits.);
    • Penn v. Pemberton & Penn, 53 S.E.2d 823, 829 (Va. 1949) ("They simply decided to do business in a very conservative way until there were reasonably good prospects of making substantial profits.");
  • 274
    • 36549008664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 301-02 (discussing effect of business judgment rule and other cases).
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 301-02 (discussing effect of business judgment rule and other cases).
  • 275
    • 36549039596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This was introduced in Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 357-62, and developed further in subsequent literature
    • This was introduced in Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 357-62, and developed further in subsequent literature.
  • 276
    • 36549000770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 46-51 (examining how such shareholder wealth maximization concepts need to incorporate shareholder expectations in order to properly guide decisions on whether to hedge);
    • See, e.g., Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 46-51 (examining how such shareholder wealth maximization concepts need to incorporate shareholder expectations in order to properly guide decisions on whether to hedge);
  • 277
    • 36549077724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 398-408 (illustrating blissful versus actual shareholder weidth maximization with selected case studies);
    • Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 398-408 (illustrating blissful versus actual shareholder weidth maximization with selected case studies);
  • 278
    • 36549027911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1007-09 (comparing blissful shareholder wealth maximization with actual shareholder wealth maximization);
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1007-09 (comparing blissful shareholder wealth maximization with actual shareholder wealth maximization);
  • 279
    • 36549083665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1285-86 exploring how blissful shareholder wealth maximization might influence corporate investment decisions
    • Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1285-86 (exploring how blissful shareholder wealth maximization might influence corporate investment decisions).
  • 280
    • 36549062514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blissful shareholder value maximization effectively assumes that information costs, agency costs, and other factors can cause stock prices to deviate from their intrinsic or fair value; and, in such cases, managers' task is to maximize not the actual stock price, but the intrinsic value of the shares thus defined. Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 357-62.
    • "Blissful" shareholder value maximization effectively assumes that information costs, agency costs, and other factors can cause stock prices to deviate from their "intrinsic" or "fair value"; and, in such cases, managers' task is to maximize not the actual stock price, but the intrinsic value of the shares thus defined. Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 357-62.
  • 281
    • 36549024000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 42-43; Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 397-406.
    • See Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 42-43; Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 397-406.
  • 282
    • 36549033338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For ways in which Buffett and Munger's intrinsic value maximization differs from blissful shareholder wealth maximization, see, note 109, at, In the wake of the Enron, WorldCom, and other recent debacles, Michael Jensen, the former President of the American Finance Association, called for adoption of a notion of shareholder wealth maximization very similar to blissful shareholder wealth maximization
    • For ways in which Buffett and Munger's "intrinsic value" maximization differs from "blissful shareholder wealth maximization," see Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 402. In the wake of the Enron, WorldCom, and other recent debacles, Michael Jensen, the former President of the American Finance Association, called for adoption of a notion of shareholder wealth maximization very similar to blissful shareholder wealth maximization.
    • Nature of Sheep, supra , pp. 402
    • Hu1
  • 283
    • 36549047051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dare to Keep Your Stock Price Low
    • See, Dec. 31, at
    • See Joseph Fuller & Michael C. Jensen, Dare to Keep Your Stock Price Low, Wall St. J., Dec. 31, 2001, at A8.
    • (2001) Wall St. J
    • Fuller, J.1    Jensen, M.C.2
  • 284
    • 36549033339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For detailed discussions of the balance between corporate welfare and shareholder welfare, see Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1004-05, 1010-30;
    • For detailed discussions of the balance between corporate welfare and shareholder welfare, see Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1004-05, 1010-30;
  • 285
    • 36549047993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 299-300, 318-32
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 299-300, 318-32.
  • 286
    • 36549070195 scopus 로고
    • For an introduction to the capital asset pricing model, see, 5th ed
    • For an introduction to the capital asset pricing model, see William F. Sharpe, Gordon J. Alexander & Jeffery V. Bailey, Investments 261-92 (5th ed. 1995).
    • (1995) Investments , pp. 261-292
    • Sharpe, W.F.1    Alexander, G.J.2    Bailey, J.V.3
  • 287
    • 84858469490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Factually, the substantial majority of shares are now held by institutional investors; for instance, at year-end 2004, institutional investors owned 69.4% of the shares of the largest 1,000 companies in the United States. Institutional Equity Ownership up in 2003, Pensions & Investments, Oct. 17, 2005, at 32. Moreover, the individual investors who hold such minority stakes tend to be more sophisticated and well-off than, say, individual investors who only own mutual funds. Thus, one recent survey indicated that 59 percent of equity investors with household financial assets of $500,000 or more own both stock mutual funds and individual stock, compared with 20 percent of those with household assets below $50,000. Seventy percent of equity investors in this low-asset category solely own stock mutual funds. Inv. Co. Inst & Sec. Indus. Ass'n, Equity Ownership in America, 2005, at 14 2005, In addition, most individual equity investors hold a broader range
    • Factually, the substantial majority of shares are now held by institutional investors; for instance, at year-end 2004, institutional investors owned 69.4% of the shares of the largest 1,000 companies in the United States. Institutional Equity Ownership up in 2003, Pensions & Investments, Oct. 17, 2005, at 32. Moreover, the individual investors who hold such minority stakes tend to be more sophisticated and well-off than, say, individual investors who only own mutual funds. Thus, one recent survey indicated that "59 percent of equity investors with household financial assets of $500,000 or more own both stock mutual funds and individual stock, compared with 20 percent of those with household assets below $50,000. Seventy percent of equity investors in this low-asset category solely own stock mutual funds." Inv. Co. Inst & Sec. Indus. Ass'n, Equity Ownership in America, 2005, at 14 (2005). In addition, most individual equity investors hold a broader range of investments, such as bond funds, money market funds, annuities, and investment real estate. Id. at 24. Normatively, it is not reasonable to manage a company for a small minority of shareholders who-by choice or ignorance-are not diversified, when the result is to prevent maximization of shareholder wealth using modern portfolio theory. For discussions of the general viability of running a corporation with well-diversified shareholder diversification in mind and some exceptions, see Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 392-94 (discussing Berkshire Hathaway); Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1306-09 (discussing why diversified shareholders do not benefit from corporate reduction of unsystematic risk);
  • 288
    • 36549046098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 361-66 (discussing wealth maximization problems associated with closely held corporations and inadequately diversified shareholders);
    • Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 361-66 (discussing wealth maximization problems associated with closely held corporations and inadequately diversified shareholders);
  • 289
    • 36549038167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Joy v. North, 692 F.2d 880, 886 (2d Cir. 1982) ([C]ourts need not bend over backwards to give special protection to shareholders who refuse to reduce the volatility of risk by not diversifying.).
    • cf. Joy v. North, 692 F.2d 880, 886 (2d Cir. 1982) ("[C]ourts need not bend over backwards to give special protection to shareholders who refuse to reduce the volatility of risk by not diversifying.").
  • 290
    • 36549080926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more precise and detailed exposition of the ideas in this paragraph, see Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 287-95, 355-66
    • For a more precise and detailed exposition of the ideas in this paragraph, see Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 287-95, 355-66.
  • 291
    • 36549070678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For contrary examples where the particular risk preferences of shareholders do matter, see Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 48-50;
    • For contrary examples where the particular risk preferences of shareholders do matter, see Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 48-50;
  • 292
    • 36548998859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1031-40
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1031-40.
  • 293
    • 84858453821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That is, the discount rate would be equal to: rf, β, rm, rf, where: rf is the time discount rate, βis the beta of the project, and rm is the rate of return applicable to that beta
    • m is the rate of return applicable to that beta.
  • 294
    • 36549004104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III A
    • See infra Part III A
  • 295
    • 36549036748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brealey & Myers, supra note 131, at 21
    • Brealey & Myers, supra note 131, at 21.
  • 296
    • 36549087268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For examples of this counterintuitive situation and the associated distinctions between shareholder wealth maximization and shareholder welfare maximization, see Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 48-50;
    • For examples of this counterintuitive situation and the associated distinctions between shareholder wealth maximization and shareholder welfare maximization, see Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 48-50;
  • 297
    • 36549063490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1033-36
    • Hu, Derivative Reality, supra note 113, at 1033-36.
  • 298
    • 36549049399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-204, 116 Stat. 745 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 11, 15, 18, 28, 29 U.S.C).
    • Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-204, 116 Stat. 745 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 11, 15, 18, 28, 29 U.S.C).
  • 299
    • 36549054712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This theme, the need for an entity's objective to correspond to the mechanisms of the host governance system, has been previously raised in the context of the governance of stock exchanges. See Means and Ends: NYSE Regulation, NYSE Group, and the Matter of Togetherness: Hearing on a Review of Self-Regulatory Organizations in the Securities Markets Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, 109th Cong, passim 2006, statement of Henry T. C. Hu, Allan Shivers Chair in the Law of Banking and Finance, University of Texas School of Law
    • This theme, the need for an entity's objective to correspond to the mechanisms of the host governance system, has been previously raised in the context of the governance of stock exchanges. See Means and Ends: NYSE Regulation, NYSE Group, and the Matter of Togetherness: Hearing on a Review of Self-Regulatory Organizations in the Securities Markets Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, 109th Cong, passim (2006) (statement of Henry T. C. Hu, Allan Shivers Chair in the Law of Banking and Finance, University of Texas School of Law).
  • 300
    • 36549002257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to the core nature of shareholder exclusivity in voting power, see Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1013-14;
    • As to the core nature of shareholder exclusivity in voting power, see Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1013-14;
  • 301
    • 36549007511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decoupling, supra note 53, at
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 344, 353-55;
    • Hu1    Black2
  • 302
    • 36549034848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-15;
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-15;
  • 303
    • 36549015211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra Part ILB;
    • supra Part ILB;
  • 304
    • 36549053632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • infra Part II.D.1
    • infra Part II.D.1.
  • 305
    • 36549039594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., William A. Klein & John C. Coffee, Jr., Business Organization and Finance: Legal and Economic Principles 124 (10th ed. 2007) (stating that, by statute, shareholders have right to vote in director elections and fundamental matters such as certain mergers, amendments of articles, and liquidation).
    • See, e.g., William A. Klein & John C. Coffee, Jr., Business Organization and Finance: Legal and Economic Principles 124 (10th ed. 2007) (stating that, by statute, shareholders have right to vote in director elections and "fundamental matters" such as certain mergers, amendments of articles, and liquidation).
  • 307
    • 0007043402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Sanford Grossman & Oliver Hart, One Share-One Vote and the Market for Corporate Control, 20 J. Fin. Econ. 175, 175-80 (1988) (arguing that one share-one vote rule encourages selection of best management team);
    • See, e.g., Sanford Grossman & Oliver Hart, One Share-One Vote and the Market for Corporate Control, 20 J. Fin. Econ. 175, 175-80 (1988) (arguing that one share-one vote rule encourages selection of best management team);
  • 308
    • 45549118731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Milton Harris & Artur Raviv, Corporate Governance: Voting Rights and Majority Rules, 20 J. Fin. Econ. 203, 226-28 (1988) (concluding that one share-one vote rule in conjunction with simple majority rule results in election of best management);
    • Milton Harris & Artur Raviv, Corporate Governance: Voting Rights and Majority Rules, 20 J. Fin. Econ. 203, 226-28 (1988) (concluding that one share-one vote rule in conjunction with simple majority rule results in election of best management);
  • 309
    • 36549076057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 353-57 (discussing theoretical and empirical support for idea that linking voting rights to shares results in efficient market for corporate control) ;
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 353-57 (discussing theoretical and empirical support for idea that linking voting rights to shares results in efficient market for corporate control) ;
  • 310
    • 36549073718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 850-57 same
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 850-57 (same).
  • 311
    • 36549072045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The creditor remedy of involuntary bankruptcy is often not terribly useful. See Susan Block-Lieb, Why Creditors File So Few Involuntary Petitions and Why the Number Is Not Too Small, 57 Brook. L. Rev. 803, 835-52 (1991) (explaining why creditors often disfavor involuntary bankruptcy). One question for further research is whether it should be easier for creditors to initiate a bankruptcy proceeding under some circumstances.
    • The creditor remedy of involuntary bankruptcy is often not terribly useful. See Susan Block-Lieb, Why Creditors File So Few Involuntary Petitions and Why the Number Is Not Too Small, 57 Brook. L. Rev. 803, 835-52 (1991) (explaining why creditors often disfavor involuntary bankruptcy). One question for further research is whether it should be easier for creditors to initiate a bankruptcy proceeding under some circumstances.
  • 312
    • 36549079127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland, N.V. v. Pathe Commc'ns Corp, Civ. A. No. 12150, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 n.55 (Del. Ch. Dec 30, 1991);
    • Credit Lyonnais Bank Nederland, N.V. v. Pathe Commc'ns Corp., Civ. A. No. 12150, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 n.55 (Del. Ch. Dec 30, 1991);
  • 313
    • 36549062023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see supra note 57 and accompanying text.
    • see supra note 57 and accompanying text.
  • 314
    • 36549085577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit Lyonnais, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 n.55.
    • Credit Lyonnais, 1991 WL 277613, at *34 n.55.
  • 315
    • 36549083668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Parts III.A-B.1.
    • See infra Parts III.A-B.1.
  • 316
    • 36549011786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By contrast, business bankruptcy law, under the rubric insolvency, is largely embedded in corporate law in the United Kingdom and most other common law countries. See Am. Law Inst., Principles of Cooperation Among the NAFTA Countries 1 n.2 (2003).
    • By contrast, business bankruptcy law, under the rubric "insolvency," is largely embedded in corporate law in the United Kingdom and most other common law countries. See Am. Law Inst., Principles of Cooperation Among the NAFTA Countries 1 n.2 (2003).
  • 317
    • 36549080929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some commentators have suggested that bankruptcy law must be limited to procedure, with all substantive policies to be found in other law. See Douglas G. Baird & Thomas H. Jackson, Corporate Reorganizations and the Treatment of Diverse Ownership Interests: A Comment on Adequate Protection of Secured Creditors in Bankruptcy, 51 U. Chi. L. Rev. 97, 100-01 (1984) (arguing that bankruptcy law should only include substantive rules that preserve assets for collective good of investors as group) ;
    • Some commentators have suggested that bankruptcy law must be limited to procedure, with all substantive policies to be found in other law. See Douglas G. Baird & Thomas H. Jackson, Corporate Reorganizations and the Treatment of Diverse Ownership Interests: A Comment on Adequate Protection of Secured Creditors in Bankruptcy, 51 U. Chi. L. Rev. 97, 100-01 (1984) (arguing that bankruptcy law should only include substantive rules that preserve assets for collective good of investors as group) ;
  • 318
    • 36549047054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James W. Bowers, Whither What Hits the Fan?: Murphy's Law, Bankruptcy Theory, and the Elementary Economics of Loss Distribution, 26 Ga. L. Rev. 27, 76-80 (1991) (arguing that efficient bankruptcy law would look like just another specialized form of civil procedure). There is no compelling reason for this dichotomy, given that the circumstance of general default may well create reasons for the application of different policies than would be appropriate in other contexts.
    • James W. Bowers, Whither What Hits the Fan?: Murphy's Law, Bankruptcy Theory, and the Elementary Economics of Loss Distribution, 26 Ga. L. Rev. 27, 76-80 (1991) (arguing that efficient bankruptcy law would look like "just another specialized form of civil procedure"). There is no compelling reason for this dichotomy, given that the circumstance of general default may well create reasons for the application of different policies than would be appropriate in other contexts.
  • 319
    • 36549056593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Bankruptcy Control of the Recovery Process, 12 Am. Bankr. Inst. L. Rev. 245, 252 & n.40, 254 n.51 (2004) [hereinafter Westbrook, Process];
    • Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Bankruptcy Control of the Recovery Process, 12 Am. Bankr. Inst. L. Rev. 245, 252 & n.40, 254 n.51 (2004) [hereinafter Westbrook, Process];
  • 320
    • 36549011292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Westbrook, Control, supra note 53, at 855-56. Indeed, one of the key themes that we emphasize in this Article is the presence of two alternative governance systems; the principal-agent problems in the bankruptcy governance system are no less worthy of consideration than those that arise in the corporate governance system. The principal-agent problems associated with the two systems are different, stemming in part from differences in the principal and differences in the homogeneity of stakeholder interests. Finally, because of the somewhat diminished role of market discipline when a corporation is in bankruptcy, the need for legal mechanisms to address agency issues becomes manifest.
    • Westbrook, Control, supra note 53, at 855-56. Indeed, one of the key themes that we emphasize in this Article is the presence of two alternative governance systems; the principal-agent problems in the bankruptcy governance system are no less worthy of consideration than those that arise in the corporate governance system. The principal-agent problems associated with the two systems are different, stemming in part from differences in the "principal" and differences in the homogeneity of stakeholder interests. Finally, because of the somewhat diminished role of market discipline when a corporation is in bankruptcy, the need for legal mechanisms to address agency issues becomes manifest.
  • 321
    • 36549027426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 395-99 (discussing history and mechanisms of reorganization under Chapter 11).
    • See generally Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 395-99 (discussing history and mechanisms of reorganization under Chapter 11).
  • 322
    • 84858462997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1107a, 2000
    • 11 U.S.C. § 1107(a) (2000).
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 323
    • 84858453422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 1126(c), 1129(a)(7)(A)(i).
    • §§ 1126(c), 1129(a)(7)(A)(i).
  • 324
    • 36549066827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. In re Channel Master Holdings, Inc., 309 B.R. 855, 860-61 (Bankr. D. Del. 2004) (noting that court is free to allocate secured party collateral to fund creditor committee professionals).
    • Cf. In re Channel Master Holdings, Inc., 309 B.R. 855, 860-61 (Bankr. D. Del. 2004) (noting that court is free to allocate secured party collateral to fund creditor committee professionals).
  • 325
    • 36549013198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Concerning corporate control, see generally Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1013-14 (discussing how voting power is central to concept of share ownership);
    • Concerning corporate control, see generally Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1013-14 (discussing how voting power is central to concept of share ownership);
  • 326
    • 36549041480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 344, 353-55 (discussing roles of shareholder vote and one share-one vote paradigm in theory of corporate governance and capital structure);
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 344, 353-55 (discussing roles of shareholder vote and one share-one vote paradigm in theory of corporate governance and capital structure);
  • 327
    • 36549009120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-15 discussing vote as core source of shareholder power that serves instrumental and legitimizing purposes
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-15 (discussing vote as "core source of shareholder power" that serves instrumental and legitimizing purposes).
  • 328
    • 36549068770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to control of bankruptcy proceedings, see Westbrook, Process, supra note 167, at 253 (noting that bankruptcy regimes universally give control of debtor's assets to publicly designated official or entity).
    • As to control of bankruptcy proceedings, see Westbrook, Process, supra note 167, at 253 (noting that bankruptcy regimes universally give control of debtor's assets to publicly designated official or entity).
  • 329
    • 36549055170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As explained below, the public control may fall into the hands of private interests, but in principle it is always public
    • As explained below, the public control may fall into the hands of private interests, but in principle it is always public.
  • 330
    • 36548998857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The ends sought through application of bankruptcy laws vary gready in theory and in practice around the world. Among the objectives might be the lowest possible cost for debt capital, a solution to the collective action problem faced by creditors, and the achievement of pari passu distributional fairness, among others
    • The ends sought through application of bankruptcy laws vary gready in theory and in practice around the world. Among the objectives might be the lowest possible cost for debt capital, a solution to the "collective action" problem faced by creditors, and the achievement of pari passu distributional fairness, among others.
  • 331
    • 36549081412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 167, at, Central to the necessary control is a stay or moratorium on creditor actions. Virtually all bankruptcy systems provide for such a stay. In the United States, the stay is very broad and automatic, while in many jurisdictions the stay is granted only after a request to a court and may be limited in scope
    • Westbrook, Process, supra note 167, at 247. Central to the necessary control is a stay or moratorium on creditor actions. Virtually all bankruptcy systems provide for such a stay. In the United States, the stay is very broad and automatic, while in many jurisdictions the stay is granted only after a request to a court and may be limited in scope.
    • Process, supra , pp. 247
    • Westbrook1
  • 333
    • 84858453416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, 11 U.S.C. § 362a, 2000
    • See, e.g., 11 U.S.C. § 362(a) (2000);
  • 334
    • 84858469488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, § 8, sched. B1, para. 44 (Eng.)
    • Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, § 8, sched. B1, para. 44 (Eng.)
  • 335
    • 84858469487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (as amended by Enterprise Act, 2002, c. 40, § 248, sched. 16 (Eng.)). Japan is one of the countries in which a stay must be sought in each case.
    • (as amended by Enterprise Act, 2002, c. 40, § 248, sched. 16 (Eng.)). Japan is one of the countries in which a stay must be sought in each case.
  • 336
    • 36549014662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shinichiro Abe, Recent Developments of Insolvency Laws and Cross-Border Practices in the United States and Japan, 10 Am. Bankr. Inst L. Rev. 47, 53 (2002) (noting that Japanese law provides no automatic stay and discussing alternative temporary legal restraints on creditors);
    • See Shinichiro Abe, Recent Developments of Insolvency Laws and Cross-Border Practices in the United States and Japan, 10 Am. Bankr. Inst L. Rev. 47, 53 (2002) (noting that Japanese law provides no automatic stay and discussing alternative temporary legal restraints on creditors);
  • 337
    • 0347053878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kent Anderson, The Cross Border Insolvency Paradigm: A Defense of the Modified Universal Approach Considering the Japanese Experience, 21 U. Pa. J. Int'l Econ. L. 679, 705 (2000) (Notably though, unlike the United States, no automatic stay is issued at commencement. Instead, debtor's assets are only protected upon application for and granting of a 'preservation measure' (hozen shobun) (quoting Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy Act], Law No. 71 of 1922, art. 155));
    • Kent Anderson, The Cross Border Insolvency Paradigm: A Defense of the Modified Universal Approach Considering the Japanese Experience, 21 U. Pa. J. Int'l Econ. L. 679, 705 (2000) ("Notably though, unlike the United States, no automatic stay is issued at commencement. Instead, debtor's assets are only protected upon application for and granting of a 'preservation measure' (hozen shobun)" (quoting Hasan Ho [Bankruptcy Act], Law No. 71 of 1922, art. 155));
  • 338
    • 36549054098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shoichi Tagashira, Intraterritorial Effects of Foreign Insolvency Proceedings: An Analysis of Ancillary Proceedings in the United States and Japan, 29 Tex. Int'l L.J. 1, 12-13 (1994) ('Yet Japan has never accepted the notion of such a comprehensive automatic stay.). Germany is an example of a country in which the stay is limited in scope;
    • Shoichi Tagashira, Intraterritorial Effects of Foreign Insolvency Proceedings: An Analysis of "Ancillary" Proceedings in the United States and Japan, 29 Tex. Int'l L.J. 1, 12-13 (1994) ('Yet Japan has never accepted the notion of such a comprehensive automatic stay."). Germany is an example of a country in which the stay is limited in scope;
  • 339
    • 0006303344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • it cannot reach secured creditors. Klaus Kamlah, The New German Insolvency Act: Insolvenzordnung, 70 Am. Bankr. L.J. 417, 425-28 (1996) (The Insolvenzordnung does not impose an automatic stay on secured creditors' enforcement of their rights against property of the estate. Here, German law takes a more complex approach.).
    • it cannot reach secured creditors. Klaus Kamlah, The New German Insolvency Act: Insolvenzordnung, 70 Am. Bankr. L.J. 417, 425-28 (1996) ("The Insolvenzordnung does not impose an automatic stay on secured creditors' enforcement of their rights against property of the estate. Here, German law takes a more complex approach.").
  • 340
    • 36549086802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Westbrook, Control, supra note 53, at 857-60.
    • See Westbrook, Control, supra note 53, at 857-60.
  • 341
    • 36549069763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Warren & Westbrook, Outcomes, supra note 97, at 3 stating that forty percent of unsuccessful cases are dismissed or converted within six months and three-quarters gone within year of filing
    • Warren & Westbrook, Outcomes, supra note 97, at 3 (stating that forty percent of unsuccessful cases are dismissed or converted within six months and three-quarters gone within year of filing).
  • 342
    • 84858453411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • party in interest
    • Every creditor is a entitled to participate actively in the bankruptcy proceeding. See, e.g, 11 U.S.C. §§ 102, 105, 11242
    • Every creditor is a "party in interest" entitled to participate actively in the bankruptcy proceeding. See, e.g., 11 U.S.C. §§ 102, 105, 1124(2);
  • 343
    • 84858463667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 1109.01.
    • Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 1109.01.
  • 344
    • 36549031722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The DIP system was adopted in large part on the argument that existing management, for all of its faults, would manage the company better than some trustee in bankruptcy having no prior knowledge of the company and often little expertise in the industry. 3 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, 1 365.06(1)(d).
    • The DIP system was adopted in large part on the argument that existing management, for all of its faults, would manage the company better than some trustee in bankruptcy having no prior knowledge of the company and often little expertise in the industry. 3 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, 1 365.06(1)(d).
  • 345
    • 36549077013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 7 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, 1 1122.01.
    • 7 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, 1 1122.01.
  • 346
    • 84858463668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 11 U.S.C. § 1126(a) (The holder of a claim or interest . . . may accept or reject a plan.);
    • See 11 U.S.C. § 1126(a) ("The holder of a claim or interest . . . may accept or reject a plan.");
  • 347
    • 84858463670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1141(d)(1)(B) (stating that confirmation of plan terminates all rights and interests of equity security holders and general partners provided for by the plan).
    • § 1141(d)(1)(B) (stating that confirmation of plan "terminates all rights and interests of equity security holders and general partners provided for by the plan").
  • 348
    • 36549041908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth Warren, Bankruptcy Policymaking in an Imperfect World, 92 Mich. L. Rev. 336, 355-57 (1993).
    • Elizabeth Warren, Bankruptcy Policymaking in an Imperfect World, 92 Mich. L. Rev. 336, 355-57 (1993).
  • 349
    • 84858463664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, most jurisdictions with developed insolvency laws recognize that default by certain kinds of debtors-like utilities, nursing homes, and insurance companies-require a primary focus on protection of customers going forward. Banks, insurance companies, and railroads are excluded from Chapter 7 liquidation in the United States. 11 U.S.C. § 109b
    • Indeed, most jurisdictions with developed insolvency laws recognize that default by certain kinds of debtors-like utilities, nursing homes, and insurance companies-require a primary focus on protection of customers going forward. Banks, insurance companies, and railroads are excluded from Chapter 7 liquidation in the United States. 11 U.S.C. § 109(b).
  • 350
    • 36549015210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Railroads must use separate provisions of Chapter 11 designed exclusively for them. Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 875.
    • Railroads must use separate provisions of Chapter 11 designed exclusively for them. Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 875.
  • 351
    • 36549079126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Warren & Westbrook, Outcomes, supra note 97, at 3
    • Warren & Westbrook, Outcomes, supra note 97, at 3.
  • 352
    • 36549061048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Asset recapitalization comprises the financial restructuring of a company or a sale of the company's business to a third party as a going concern. Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Globalisation of Bankruptcy Reform, 1999 N.Z. L. Rev. 401, 410-11.
    • "Asset recapitalization" comprises the financial restructuring of a company or a sale of the company's business to a third party as a going concern. Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Globalisation of Bankruptcy Reform, 1999 N.Z. L. Rev. 401, 410-11.
  • 353
    • 84858469158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 365a
    • 11 U.S.C. § 365(a).
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 354
    • 84858453409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, a creditor who has his contract assumed as part of a confirmed plan of reorganization will be promised full payment, §§ 502(b), 1129(a), whereas a creditor who has his contract rejected will be promised only a pro-rata payment as an unsecured creditor. § 502(g). Critical vendors are those whom the debtor seeks to pay immediately after filing bankruptcy because they are so critical to the debtor's business that the debtor will fail without them. The Seventh Circuit has held that bankruptcy courts do not have the authority to grant critical vendor relief. In re Kmart Corp., 359 F.3d 866, 874 (7th Cir. 2004);
    • For example, a creditor who has his contract assumed as part of a confirmed plan of reorganization will be promised full payment, §§ 502(b), 1129(a), whereas a creditor who has his contract rejected will be promised only a pro-rata payment as an unsecured creditor. § 502(g). "Critical vendors" are those whom the debtor seeks to pay immediately after filing bankruptcy because they are so "critical" to the debtor's business that the debtor will fail without them. The Seventh Circuit has held that bankruptcy courts do not have the authority to grant critical vendor relief. In re Kmart Corp., 359 F.3d 866, 874 (7th Cir. 2004);
  • 355
    • 36549013200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see StevenJ. Lubben, The New and Improved Chapter 11, 93 Ky. L.J. 839, 854 (2005).
    • see StevenJ. Lubben, The "New and Improved" Chapter 11, 93 Ky. L.J. 839, 854 (2005).
  • 356
    • 36549068772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Other courts have expressed caution and hesitance toward critical vendors and at least one court has outlined a three-part test that must be satisfied in order for a creditor to attain such an elevated status over other general unsecured creditors, but many such orders have been approved. See, e.g., In re CoServ, L.L.C., 273 B.R. 487, 498 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 2002).
    • Other courts have expressed caution and hesitance toward "critical vendors" and at least one court has outlined a three-part test that must be satisfied in order for a creditor to attain such an elevated status over other general unsecured creditors, but many such orders have been approved. See, e.g., In re CoServ, L.L.C., 273 B.R. 487, 498 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 2002).
  • 357
    • 36549074179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., David A. Skeel, Jr., The Past, Present and Future of Debtor-InPossession Financing, 25 Cardozo L. Rev. 1905, 1920-29 (2004) [hereinafter Skeel, Past, Present & Future] (describing how debtor's decision to accept DIP financing can transfer control of debtor to lender);
    • See, e.g., David A. Skeel, Jr., The Past, Present and Future of Debtor-InPossession Financing, 25 Cardozo L. Rev. 1905, 1920-29 (2004) [hereinafter Skeel, Past, Present & Future] (describing how debtor's decision to accept DIP financing can transfer control of debtor to lender);
  • 358
    • 36549069237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mary Jo Wiggins, Finance and Factionalism: The Uneasy Present (and Future) of Special Interest Committees in Corporate Reorganization Law, 41 San Diego L. Rev. 1373, 1384 (2004) (The use of debtor-in-possession financing and the willingness of some bankruptcy courts to approve so-called 'first-day orders' potentially leaves many unsecured creditors without adequate notice or protection or both.).
    • Mary Jo Wiggins, Finance and Factionalism: The Uneasy Present (and Future) of Special Interest Committees in Corporate Reorganization Law, 41 San Diego L. Rev. 1373, 1384 (2004) ("The use of debtor-in-possession financing and the willingness of some bankruptcy courts to approve so-called 'first-day orders' potentially leaves many unsecured creditors without adequate notice or protection or both.").
  • 359
    • 36549018627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Office Prod, of Am., Inc., 136 B.R. 983, 984-88 (Bankr. W.D. Tex. 1992).
    • See, e.g., In re Office Prod, of Am., Inc., 136 B.R. 983, 984-88 (Bankr. W.D. Tex. 1992).
  • 360
    • 36549034337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Martin J. Bienenstock, Conflicts Between Management and the Debtor in Possession's Fiduciary Duties, 61 U. Cin. L. Rev. 543 (1992) (discussing whether Bankruptcy Code facilitates enforcement of management's fiduciary duties);
    • See generally Martin J. Bienenstock, Conflicts Between Management and the Debtor in Possession's Fiduciary Duties, 61 U. Cin. L. Rev. 543 (1992) (discussing whether Bankruptcy Code facilitates enforcement of management's fiduciary duties);
  • 361
    • 36549081959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John T. Roache, Note, The Fiduciary Obligations of a Debtor in Possession, 1993 U. 111. L. Rev. 133 (discussing which fiduciary standard should be applied to debtor in possession in Chapter 11 reorganization).
    • John T. Roache, Note, The Fiduciary Obligations of a Debtor in Possession, 1993 U. 111. L. Rev. 133 (discussing which fiduciary standard should be applied to debtor in possession in Chapter 11 reorganization).
  • 362
    • 84858478013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1103(c)2, 3
    • 11 U.S.C. § 1103(c)(2)-(3).
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 363
    • 36549086058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A notable recent instance was the Chapter 11 proceeding filed by a huge power company, Mirant In re Mirant Corp., 334 B.R. 800 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 2005). There was a crucial dispute between shareholders and management as to the value of the company and therefore the amount of value, if any, that should be available to shareholders in a reorganization plan. Id. at 806. The court appointed a shareholder committee to represent the interests of that group and held hearings to resolve the dispute. Id. Following the court's preliminary ruling, the parties settled on a plan. Id. at 811;
    • A notable recent instance was the Chapter 11 proceeding filed by a huge power company, Mirant In re Mirant Corp., 334 B.R. 800 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 2005). There was a crucial dispute between shareholders and management as to the value of the company and therefore the amount of value, if any, that should be available to shareholders in a reorganization plan. Id. at 806. The court appointed a shareholder committee to represent the interests of that group and held hearings to resolve the dispute. Id. Following the court's preliminary ruling, the parties settled on a plan. Id. at 811;
  • 364
    • 36549089537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Rebecca Smith, Court Orders Mirant to Revamp Calculation of Value of Company, Wall St. J. Online, June 30, 2005 (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • see also Rebecca Smith, Court Orders Mirant to Revamp Calculation of Value of Company, Wall St. J. Online, June 30, 2005 (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 365
    • 34848864735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1129(a)5, Another example is the appointment of special committees to represent particular constituencies upon a showing of need
    • 11 U.S.C. § 1129(a)(5). Another example is the appointment of special committees to represent particular constituencies upon a showing of need.
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 366
    • 36549064752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re Loral Space & Commc'ns, Ltd., No. 04 Civ. 8645(RPP), 2004 U.S. Dist LEXIS 25681, at *12-*16 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. Dec. 23, 2004) (appointing shareholder committee).
    • See, e.g., In re Loral Space & Commc'ns, Ltd., No. 04 Civ. 8645(RPP), 2004 U.S. Dist LEXIS 25681, at *12-*16 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. Dec. 23, 2004) (appointing shareholder committee).
  • 367
    • 84858477458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 U.S.C. § 1129(a)(8), (b).
    • 11 U.S.C. § 1129(a)(8), (b).
  • 368
    • 36549026915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A creditor is en tided to sell another person its claim against a bankrupt debtor if disclosure of the sale is made. Fed. R. Bankr. P. 3001(e)2, In large public Chapter 11 cases there may be a substantial market in claims
    • A creditor is en tided to sell another person its claim against a bankrupt debtor if disclosure of the sale is made. Fed. R. Bankr. P. 3001(e)(2). In large public Chapter 11 cases there may be a substantial market in claims.
  • 369
    • 36549065247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an explanation of the practice, see Paul M. Goldschmid, More Phoenix Than Vulture: The Case for Distressed Investor Presence in the Bankruptcy Reorganization Process, 2005 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 191, 206-09.
    • For an explanation of the practice, see Paul M. Goldschmid, More Phoenix Than Vulture: The Case for Distressed Investor Presence in the Bankruptcy Reorganization Process, 2005 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 191, 206-09.
  • 370
    • 36549068263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Claims trading is increasingly important given the emerging role of hedge funds in Chapter 11 proceedings and the roaring controversy over their disclosure obligations under Federal Rule of Bankruptcy Procedure 2019. See, e.g., In re Northwest Airlines, 363 B.R. 701, 704 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2007).
    • Claims trading is increasingly important given the emerging role of hedge funds in Chapter 11 proceedings and the roaring controversy over their disclosure obligations under Federal Rule of Bankruptcy Procedure 2019. See, e.g., In re Northwest Airlines, 363 B.R. 701, 704 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 2007).
  • 371
    • 36549047994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even this bankruptcy system, designed for negotiation and conflict resolution, has been strained by the development of credit derivatives. There is emerging concern that, as a result, creditors sometimes may not have the normal economic incentives to maximize value and save a business because they have bargained away risk. See
    • Even this bankruptcy system, designed for negotiation and conflict resolution, has been strained by the development of credit derivatives. There is emerging concern that, as a result, creditors sometimes may not have the normal economic incentives to maximize value and save a business because they have bargained away risk. See INSOL Int'l, Credit Derivatives in Restructurings 15-16 (2006);
    • (2006) Credit Derivatives in Restructurings , pp. 15-16
    • INSOL Int'l1
  • 372
    • 34547179924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frank Partnoy & David A. Skeel, Jr., The Promise and Perils of Credit Derivatives, 75 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1019, 1035 (2007) (providing example). For a related point, applicable in both the corporate governance context and the bankruptcy context, see infra Part V (referring to analytical framework conceiving decoupling of creditor contractual rights and creditor economic interests).
    • Frank Partnoy & David A. Skeel, Jr., The Promise and Perils of Credit Derivatives, 75 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1019, 1035 (2007) (providing example). For a related point, applicable in both the corporate governance context and the bankruptcy context, see infra Part V (referring to analytical framework conceiving "decoupling" of creditor contractual rights and creditor economic interests).
  • 373
    • 36549016158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 7-Eleven case illustrates the difference between saving the company and saving the business. The old company lost everything, but the business-slimmed down but intact-was sold as a going concern. See Larry Light, Suzanne Woolley & Stephanie Anderson Forest, Quickie Bankruptcies: Speed Isn't Everything, Bus. Wk., Apr. 29, 1991, at 72, 72-73;
    • The 7-Eleven case illustrates the difference between saving the company and saving the business. The old company lost everything, but the business-slimmed down but intact-was sold as a going concern. See Larry Light, Suzanne Woolley & Stephanie Anderson Forest, Quickie Bankruptcies: Speed Isn't Everything, Bus. Wk., Apr. 29, 1991, at 72, 72-73;
  • 374
  • 375
    • 84858455871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kmart successfully emerged from bankruptcy at $15 per share and rose to $109 per share before merging with Sears
    • Joel Groover, A Site Better: Big-name Retailers Sought-for Their Real Estate, Shopping Centers Today, Feb, at, on file with the
    • More recendy, Kmart successfully emerged from bankruptcy at $15 per share and rose to $109 per share before merging with Sears. Joel Groover, A Site Better: Big-name Retailers Sought-for Their Real Estate, Shopping Centers Today, Feb. 2005, at http:// www.icsc.org/srch/sct/sct0205/ (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • (2005) Columbia Law Review
    • recendy, M.1
  • 376
    • 36549067769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephen J. Lubben, The Direct Costs of Corporate Reorganization: An Empirical Examination of Professional Fees in Large Chapter 11 Cases, 74 Am. Bankr. L.J. 509, 550 (2000).
    • Stephen J. Lubben, The Direct Costs of Corporate Reorganization: An Empirical Examination of Professional Fees in Large Chapter 11 Cases, 74 Am. Bankr. L.J. 509, 550 (2000).
  • 377
    • 36549084117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Warren & Westbrook, Outcomes, supra note 97, at 25-26
    • Warren & Westbrook, Outcomes, supra note 97, at 25-26.
  • 378
    • 36549044977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is not to say, of course, that in individual cases the costs associated with lawyers or managers may not be excessive
    • This is not to say, of course, that in individual cases the costs associated with lawyers or managers may not be excessive.
  • 379
    • 45249128199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Stuart C. Gilson, Management Turnover and Financial Distress, 25 J. Fin. Econ. 241, 261 (1989) (concluding that management turnover is much more likely to occur in distressed companies);
    • See, e.g., Stuart C. Gilson, Management Turnover and Financial Distress, 25 J. Fin. Econ. 241, 261 (1989) (concluding that management turnover is much more likely to occur in distressed companies);
  • 380
    • 36549052210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RonaldJ. Gilson, Reflections in a Distant Mirror: Japanese Corporate Governance Through American Eyes, 1998 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 203, 214 (discussing study of management changes in poorly performing companies);
    • RonaldJ. Gilson, Reflections in a Distant Mirror: Japanese Corporate Governance Through American Eyes, 1998 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 203, 214 (discussing study of management changes in poorly performing companies);
  • 381
    • 36549034849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lynn M. LoPucki & William C. Whitford, Corporate Governance in the Bankruptcy Reorganization of Large, Publicly Held Companies, 141 U. Pa. L. Rev. 669, 723-37 (1993) (finding that nearly all distressed companies change CEOs at least once before or after confirmation);
    • Lynn M. LoPucki & William C. Whitford, Corporate Governance in the Bankruptcy Reorganization of Large, Publicly Held Companies, 141 U. Pa. L. Rev. 669, 723-37 (1993) (finding that nearly all distressed companies change CEOs at least once before or after confirmation);
  • 382
    • 36549063491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Elizabeth Warren, The Untenable Case for Repeal of Chapter 11, 102 Yale L.J. 437, 449-52 (1992) (reviewing gloomy prospect for managers of distressed companies).
    • Elizabeth Warren, The Untenable Case for Repeal of Chapter 11, 102 Yale L.J. 437, 449-52 (1992) (reviewing "gloomy prospect for managers of distressed companies").
  • 383
    • 36549018154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Barry E. Adler, Vedran Capkun & Lawrence A. Weiss, Destruction of Value in the New Era of Chapter 11, at 12, 29 (Oct 24, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Columbia Law Review), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=795987 (discussing incentives for managers to delay bankruptcy filing).
    • See Barry E. Adler, Vedran Capkun & Lawrence A. Weiss, Destruction of Value in the New Era of Chapter 11, at 12, 29 (Oct 24, 2006) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the Columbia Law Review), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=795987 (discussing incentives for managers to delay bankruptcy filing).
  • 384
    • 36549043942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 407
    • Hu, Nature of Sheep, supra note 109, at 407
  • 385
    • 36549012766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting letter from Charles T. Munger to Henry T. C. Hu (Jan. 14, 1991)).
    • (quoting letter from Charles T. Munger to Henry T. C. Hu (Jan. 14, 1991)).
  • 386
    • 36549062515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of the notion that the corporation's assets now represent the creditor's money-that is, the idea of the primacy of the residual claimant-see supra note 16 and accompanying text; infra Parts III.A., III.C.2, IV.
    • For a discussion of the notion that the corporation's assets now represent the creditor's money-that is, the idea of the primacy of the residual claimant-see supra note 16 and accompanying text; infra Parts III.A., III.C.2, IV.
  • 387
    • 36549065727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dwyer v. Jones (In re Tri-State Paving, Inc.), 32 B.R. 2, 3 (Bankr. W.D. Pa. 1982), discussed in Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of Debtors and Creditors 632 (3d ed. 1996). The directors claimed the money was owed to them, but the court did not agree and the opinion gives the definite impression that tile directors literally bet the company.
    • Dwyer v. Jones (In re Tri-State Paving, Inc.), 32 B.R. 2, 3 (Bankr. W.D. Pa. 1982), discussed in Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Law of Debtors and Creditors 632 (3d ed. 1996). The directors claimed the money was owed to them, but the court did not agree and the opinion gives the definite impression that tile directors literally "bet the company."
  • 388
    • 36549072043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 790 n.57 (Del. Ch. 2004) ([I]t is easy to posit extreme hypothetical involving directors putting cash in slot machines....).
    • See also Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 790 n.57 (Del. Ch. 2004) ("[I]t is easy to posit extreme hypothetical involving directors putting cash in slot machines....").
  • 389
    • 36549020617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Overnight Success
    • Sept. 20, at
    • Dean Foust, No Overnight Success, Bus. Wk., Sept. 20, 2004, at 18, 18.
    • (2004) Bus. Wk
    • Dean Foust1
  • 390
    • 36549090056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.A.2.
    • See supra Part II.A.2.
  • 391
    • 36549006531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One exception might be where options that are well out of the money (as may be the case with troubled corporations) tempt managers to engage in bet the company behavior-the increase in volatility alone would, under standard option pricing models, increase the value of their options. See, e.g., Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 328-29 (discussing incentive effects of stock options on managerial risk taking).
    • One exception might be where options that are well out of the money (as may be the case with troubled corporations) tempt managers to engage in "bet the company" behavior-the increase in volatility alone would, under standard option pricing models, increase the value of their options. See, e.g., Hu, Risk & Time, supra note 12, at 328-29 (discussing incentive effects of stock options on managerial risk taking).
  • 392
    • 36549035318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Adler et al., supra note 200, at 8-9 (stating that debtors now frequently enter bankruptcy with little or no liquid assets and require an immediate debtor-inpossession ... loan to continue in business, with the pre-bankruptcy secured lender... in a unique position to provide such a loan).
    • See Adler et al., supra note 200, at 8-9 (stating that "debtors now frequently enter bankruptcy with little or no liquid assets and require an immediate debtor-inpossession ... loan to continue in business, with the pre-bankruptcy secured lender... in a unique position to provide such a loan").
  • 393
    • 0012872139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, The Essential Role of Organizational Law, 110 Yale L.J. 387, 399-401 (2000) (describing use of corporate subsidiaries as asset partitioning devices).
    • Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, The Essential Role of Organizational Law, 110 Yale L.J. 387, 399-401 (2000) (describing use of corporate subsidiaries as "asset partitioning" devices).
  • 394
    • 36549018155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Skeel, Past, Present & Future, supra note 187, at 1920-21 describing scenarios in which control has shifted through additional credit
    • See Skeel, Past, Present & Future, supra note 187, at 1920-21 (describing scenarios in which control has shifted through additional credit).
  • 395
    • 36549054099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Vanessa Finch, The Recasting of Insolvency Law, 68 Mod. L. Rev. 713, 735 (2005) (noting that, in era of secured creditor influence, courts must guard against creditors insisting on excessively low risk strategies when more enterprising behavior would . . . benefit unsecured creditors).
    • See, e.g., Vanessa Finch, The Recasting of Insolvency Law, 68 Mod. L. Rev. 713, 735 (2005) (noting that, in era of secured creditor influence, courts must guard against creditors "insisting on excessively low risk strategies when more enterprising behavior would . . . benefit unsecured creditors").
  • 396
    • 30344478243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an empirical exploration of the potential alliance of caution between management and bondholders, from the perspective of the bondholders, see Mark S. Klock, Sattar A. Mansi & William F. Maxwell, Does Corporate Governance Matter to Bondholders, 40 J. Fin. & Quantitative Analysis 693 2005
    • For an empirical exploration of the potential alliance of caution between management and bondholders, from the perspective of the bondholders, see Mark S. Klock, Sattar A. Mansi & William F. Maxwell, Does Corporate Governance Matter to Bondholders?, 40 J. Fin. & Quantitative Analysis 693 (2005).
  • 397
    • 36549039104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Richard M. Cieri & Michael J. Riela, Protecting Directors and Officers of Corporations That Are Insolvent or in the Zone or Vicinity of Insolvency: Important Considerations, Practical Solutions, 2 DePaul Bus. & Com. L.J. 295, 303-06 (2004) (noting lack of clarity about whether business judgment or entire fairness rule applies to duties to creditors).
    • See, e.g., Richard M. Cieri & Michael J. Riela, Protecting Directors and Officers of Corporations That Are Insolvent or in the Zone or Vicinity of Insolvency: Important Considerations, Practical Solutions, 2 DePaul Bus. & Com. L.J. 295, 303-06 (2004) (noting lack of clarity about whether business judgment or entire fairness rule applies to duties to creditors).
  • 398
    • 36549072514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under Delaware's current formulation, the business judgment rule is a presumption that in making a business decision, the directors of a corporation acted on an informed basis, in good faith and in the honest belief that the action taken was in the best interests of the company. Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d 805, 812 (Del. 1984). On similar grounds, some lawyers have urged that directors may have a duty to cause their corporations to hedge against currency, commodity, and other market fluctuations. This reflects, among other things, a failure to distinguish between the welfare of the corporation and the welfare of diversified shareholders.
    • Under Delaware's current formulation, the business judgment rule is "a presumption that in making a business decision, the directors of a corporation acted on an informed basis, in good faith and in the honest belief that the action taken was in the best interests of the company." Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d 805, 812 (Del. 1984). On similar grounds, some lawyers have urged that directors may have a duty to cause their corporations to hedge against currency, commodity, and other market fluctuations. This reflects, among other things, a failure to distinguish between the welfare of the corporation and the welfare of diversified shareholders.
  • 399
    • 36549001260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 49-50 (discussing corporate hedging and varying approaches of gold mining companies);
    • See, e.g., Hu, Behind the Corporate Hedge, supra note 109, at 49-50 (discussing corporate hedging and varying approaches of gold mining companies);
  • 400
    • 36549022627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra Parts II.B.1.a, II.B.2 (discussing conflicts between entity-optimal and shareholder-optimal risk behavior).
    • supra Parts II.B.1.a, II.B.2 (discussing conflicts between entity-optimal and shareholder-optimal risk behavior).
  • 401
    • 36549078677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is increasingly recognized, by gold mining companies and others, that such advice is often contrary to the interests of shareholders. As one example, Barrick, the leading gold miner that had hedged aggressively against drops in the gold price, has recently moved significantly away from hedging as a policy matter. Canadian Press, Barrick Gold Corp. Goes Unhedged, Now Able to Sell Production at Spot Prices, May 2, 2007, available at Westlaw, Canadian Press Wire (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (noting how Barrick's status as unhedged gold producer marks the end of an era).
    • It is increasingly recognized, by gold mining companies and others, that such advice is often contrary to the interests of shareholders. As one example, Barrick, the leading gold miner that had hedged aggressively against drops in the gold price, has recently moved significantly away from hedging as a policy matter. Canadian Press, Barrick Gold Corp. Goes Unhedged, Now Able to Sell Production at Spot Prices, May 2, 2007, available at Westlaw, Canadian Press Wire (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (noting how Barrick's status as unhedged gold producer "marks the end of an era").
  • 402
    • 36549088159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007).
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007).
  • 403
    • 33644807710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to the role of risk taking in economic growth, see, for example, Douglas J. Cumming, The Determinants of Venture Capital Portfolio Size: Empirical Evidence, 79 J. Bus. 1083, 1114 (2006) (noting importance of venture capital and entrepreneurial investing for economic growth);
    • As to the role of risk taking in economic growth, see, for example, Douglas J. Cumming, The Determinants of Venture Capital Portfolio Size: Empirical Evidence, 79 J. Bus. 1083, 1114 (2006) (noting importance of venture capital and entrepreneurial investing for economic growth);
  • 404
    • 36549015208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Greg Ip & Mark Whitehouse, Why Economists Track Firms' R&D, Wall St. J., Sept. 29, 2006, at A2 (discussing research showing domestic economic growth from investment in R&D).
    • Greg Ip & Mark Whitehouse, Why Economists Track Firms' R&D, Wall St. J., Sept. 29, 2006, at A2 (discussing research showing domestic economic growth from investment in R&D).
  • 405
    • 36549032211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Jim Collins, The Wizard, King, and Hobbit of Business, Fast Company, Apr. 2004, at 93, 95 (discussing IBM 360 project);
    • See, e.g., Jim Collins, The Wizard, King, and Hobbit of Business, Fast Company, Apr. 2004, at 93, 95 (discussing IBM 360 project);
  • 406
    • 84858453387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Selling of the 707, Fortune, Oct. 1957, at 129, 129 (stating that prior to first 707, Boeing had invested $185 million - $36 million more than Boeing's net worth in previous year);
    • The Selling of the 707, Fortune, Oct. 1957, at 129, 129 (stating that prior to first 707, Boeing had invested $185 million - $36 million more than Boeing's net worth in previous year);
  • 407
    • 36549020046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jerry Useem, 20 That Made History, Fortune, June 27, 2005, at 58, 60 (implying that 707 was negative net present value project);
    • Jerry Useem, 20 That Made History, Fortune, June 27, 2005, at 58, 60 (implying that 707 was negative net present value project);
  • 408
    • 84858453789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Leslie Wayne, Boeing Bets the House - A Return to No. 1 Rests on Its New Dreamliner, N.Y. Times, May 7, 2006, § 3, at 1 (noting how Boeing is today resting its hopes on 787, its first new commercial airplane in a decade).
    • cf. Leslie Wayne, Boeing Bets the House - A Return to No. 1 Rests on Its New Dreamliner, N.Y. Times, May 7, 2006, § 3, at 1 (noting how Boeing is today resting its hopes on 787, its first new commercial airplane in a decade).
  • 409
    • 36549033838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Louis R. Dienes, United States: Insolvent Companies Create Boardroom Risks for Venture Capital Firms, Mondaq, Nov. 28, 2006, at http://www. mondaq.com/article.asp?articleid=44466 (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (advising that venture capital representatives on boards may owe fiduciary duties to creditors).
    • See, e.g., Louis R. Dienes, United States: Insolvent Companies Create Boardroom Risks for Venture Capital Firms, Mondaq, Nov. 28, 2006, at http://www. mondaq.com/article.asp?articleid=44466 (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (advising that venture capital representatives on boards may owe fiduciary duties to creditors).
  • 410
    • 11044231189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For introductions to venture capital risks and returns, see generally John H. Cochrane, The Risk and Return of Venture Capital, 75 J. Fin. Econ. 3 (2005) (measuring statistically expected return on venture capital investments);
    • For introductions to venture capital risks and returns, see generally John H. Cochrane, The Risk and Return of Venture Capital, 75 J. Fin. Econ. 3 (2005) (measuring statistically expected return on venture capital investments);
  • 411
    • 36549003639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cumming, supra note 215 (investigating efficient size of venture capital funds) ;
    • Cumming, supra note 215 (investigating efficient size of venture capital funds) ;
  • 412
    • 6344230194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steven N. Kaplan & Per Strõmberg, Characteristics, Contracts, and Actions: Evidence from Venture Capitalist Analyses, 59 J. Fin. 2177 (2004) (testing predictions of financial contracting theories using investments by venture capitalists).
    • Steven N. Kaplan & Per Strõmberg, Characteristics, Contracts, and Actions: Evidence from Venture Capitalist Analyses, 59 J. Fin. 2177 (2004) (testing predictions of financial contracting theories using investments by venture capitalists).
  • 413
    • 36549045601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 63 and accompanying text (discussing In re Healthco Int'l, Inc., 208 B.R. 288 (Bankr. D. Mass. 1997)).
    • See supra note 63 and accompanying text (discussing In re Healthco Int'l, Inc., 208 B.R. 288 (Bankr. D. Mass. 1997)).
  • 415
    • 36549040981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 18 and accompanying text (discussing this analysis and its relationship to contingent claims analysis approach in finance theory). That is, their economic ownership rights, as a legal matter, include a call option in the economic sense. A call option is a form of contract that gives the owner of the contract the right, but not the obligation, to buy an asset at a specified price. This contract has value to the owner that varies with, among other things, the exercise price under the contract, the current price of the asset, and the time remaining until expiration.
    • See supra note 18 and accompanying text (discussing this analysis and its relationship to "contingent claims analysis" approach in finance theory). That is, their economic ownership rights, as a legal matter, include a call option in the economic sense. A call option is a form of contract that gives the owner of the contract the right, but not the obligation, to buy an asset at a specified price. This contract has value to the owner that varies with, among other things, the exercise price under the contract, the current price of the asset, and the time remaining until expiration.
  • 416
    • 36549002706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives, supra note 18, at 1466-67, 1473-76 discussing ability of contracts to insulate exogenous risk and describing independent variables influencing value of option
    • See, e.g., Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives, supra note 18, at 1466-67, 1473-76 (discussing ability of contracts to insulate exogenous risk and describing independent variables influencing value of option).
  • 417
    • 36549082952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is because an option only gives rights and does not impose any obligations on the options holder: In other words, the obligation is one-sided. Consideration of options pricing models also confirms this. See Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives, supra note 18, at 1466-67, 1474-76 discussing nature of obligations as to options and Black-Scholes option pricing model
    • This is because an option only gives rights and does not impose any obligations on the options holder: In other words, the obligation is one-sided. Consideration of options pricing models also confirms this. See Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives, supra note 18, at 1466-67, 1474-76 (discussing nature of obligations as to options and Black-Scholes option pricing model).
  • 418
    • 36549019551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007).
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007).
  • 419
    • 36549086803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 57 and accompanying text.
    • See supra note 57 and accompanying text.
  • 420
    • 36549003638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lipson, supra note 49, at 1231-32 ([A]t the moment it matters most-the 'vicinity of insolvency'-it will usually be difficult, if not impossible, to know whether the corporation will be able to reorganize, or whether it will have to liquidate.).
    • See Lipson, supra note 49, at 1231-32 ("[A]t the moment it matters most-the 'vicinity of insolvency'-it will usually be difficult, if not impossible, to know whether the corporation will be able to reorganize, or whether it will have to liquidate.").
  • 421
    • 36549088160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra
    • See supra Part I.B.2.
    • , vol.2
    • Part, I.B.1
  • 422
    • 84858477438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is instructive to note that even in England the wrongful trading provision penalizing directors for carrying on an insolvent business requires that they know the business has no reasonable prospect apart from liquidation. Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, § 214(3) (Eng.).
    • It is instructive to note that even in England the "wrongful trading" provision penalizing directors for carrying on an insolvent business requires that they know the business has no reasonable prospect apart from liquidation. Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, § 214(3) (Eng.).
  • 423
    • 36549008182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to the core nature of shareholder exclusivity in voting power, see Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1013-14;
    • As to the core nature of shareholder exclusivity in voting power, see Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1013-14;
  • 424
    • 36549023091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decoupling, supra note 53, at
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 344, 353-55;
    • Hu1    Black2
  • 425
    • 36549014661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-15;
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-15;
  • 426
    • 36549026914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also supra Parts II.B, II.C.I, II.D.I.
    • see also supra Parts II.B, II.C.I, II.D.I.
  • 427
    • 36549080928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, as discussed in Part IV infra, shareholders have the exclusive right to sue directiy for breaches of fiduciary duty
    • Indeed, as discussed in Part IV infra, shareholders have the exclusive right to sue directiy for breaches of fiduciary duty.
  • 428
    • 36549047053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007) stating that, upon insolvency, creditors become 'the principal constituency injured by any fiduciary breaches that diminish the firm's value' because shareholders are no longer effectively the residual claimants
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (Del. May 18, 2007) (stating that, upon insolvency, creditors become "'the principal constituency injured by any fiduciary breaches that diminish the firm's value'" because shareholders are no longer effectively the residual claimants
  • 429
    • 36549052213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 794 n.67 (Del. Ch. 2004))).
    • (quoting Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 794 n.67 (Del. Ch. 2004))).
  • 430
    • 36549047996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 564 A.2d 651, 659 (Del. Ch. 1988);
    • 564 A.2d 651, 659 (Del. Ch. 1988);
  • 431
    • 36549064269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also MM Cos. v. Liquid Audio, Inc., 813 A.2d 1118, 1126, 1129 (Del. 2003) (adopting Chancellor Allen's formulation).
    • see also MM Cos. v. Liquid Audio, Inc., 813 A.2d 1118, 1126, 1129 (Del. 2003) (adopting Chancellor Allen's formulation).
  • 432
    • 36549054717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I.B.2. Other mechanisms of the corporate governance system, however, continue to operate in favor of shareholder interests. The market for corporate control is animated in large part by share prices: a low share price flowing from bad management that would attract bidders and a subsequent higher share price after a spell of good management. Incentives force corporate managers to focus on maximizing shareholder wealth. (Indeed, if corporate managers instead managed the company in the interests of creditors as directed by duty shifting, an unwelcome hostile takeover would be all the more likely.)
    • See supra Part I.B.2. Other mechanisms of the corporate governance system, however, continue to operate in favor of shareholder interests. The market for corporate control is animated in large part by share prices: a low share price flowing from "bad" management that would attract bidders and a subsequent higher share price after a spell of "good" management. Incentives force corporate managers to focus on maximizing shareholder wealth. (Indeed, if corporate managers instead managed the company in the interests of creditors as directed by duty shifting, an unwelcome hostile takeover would be all the more likely.)
  • 433
    • 36549045600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another factor aligning managers with shareholders is that managers typically have large securities holdings, including shares and stock options, in their companies. Even when companies are troubled, those securities holdings continue to incentivize managers to focus on the share price. As noted above, these factors may or may not outweigh the influence over management that creditors often enjoy during periods of financial distress. See supra notes 202-211 and accompanying text.
    • Another factor aligning managers with shareholders is that managers typically have large securities holdings, including shares and stock options, in their companies. Even when companies are troubled, those securities holdings continue to incentivize managers to focus on the share price. As noted above, these factors may or may not outweigh the influence over management that creditors often enjoy during periods of financial distress. See supra notes 202-211 and accompanying text.
  • 434
    • 36549060146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 8
    • See supra note 8.
  • 435
    • 36549055169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1014 (Sometimes [hedge funds] hold more votes than shares - a pattern we call 'empty voting' because the votes have been emptied of an accompanying economic interest) ;
    • See, e.g., Hu & Black, Taxonomy, supra note 53, at 1014 ("Sometimes [hedge funds] hold more votes than shares - a pattern we call 'empty voting' because the votes have been emptied of an accompanying economic interest") ;
  • 436
    • 36549027910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 348 (describing practice of empty voting by hedge funds) ;
    • Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 348 (describing practice of "empty voting" by hedge funds) ;
  • 437
    • 36549056115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 815 (analyzing decoupling of economic ownership from voting power and corporate governance implications);
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 815 (analyzing decoupling of economic ownership from voting power and corporate governance implications);
  • 438
    • 36549090543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scannell, supra note 8 (recounting instances of empty voting by hedge funds);
    • Scannell, supra note 8 (recounting instances of "empty voting" by hedge funds);
  • 439
    • 36549081418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • White, supra note 8 (The concern centres on the increasing ability of hedge funds and other sophisticated investors to accumulate large voting positions while having little, or even negative, economic interest in a company.);
    • White, supra note 8 ("The concern centres on the increasing ability of hedge funds and other sophisticated investors to accumulate large voting positions while having little, or even negative, economic interest in a company.");
  • 440
    • 36549087271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also infra Part V discussing implications of decoupling for our analysis
    • see also infra Part V (discussing implications of decoupling for our analysis).
  • 441
    • 36549076540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 817, 834
    • Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 817, 834.
  • 442
    • 36549015209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Those who view this change positively refer to a new corporate governance paradigm while those who look askance speak darkly about opening the floodgates to contested elections. See, e.g., Brooke A. Masters, Shareholders Flex Muscles, Wash. Post, June 17, 2006, at DOl (quoting Patrick McGurn of Institutional Shareholder Services as saying that new corporate governance paradigm [is] emerging with respect to shareholder power);
    • Those who view this change positively refer to a "new corporate governance paradigm" while those who look askance speak darkly about opening the "floodgates to contested elections." See, e.g., Brooke A. Masters, Shareholders Flex Muscles, Wash. Post, June 17, 2006, at DOl (quoting Patrick McGurn of Institutional Shareholder Services as saying that "new corporate governance paradigm [is] emerging" with respect to shareholder power);
  • 443
    • 36549015711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Memorandum from David A. Katz & Laura A. McIntosh, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Corporate Governance: A Seismic Shift in the Mechanics of Electing Directors (July 27, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (stating that [t]his is a dynamic moment in the history of public company shareholder voting and that certain changes in voting mechanics threaten to open the floodgates to contested elections).
    • Memorandum from David A. Katz & Laura A. McIntosh, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Corporate Governance: A Seismic Shift in the Mechanics of Electing Directors (July 27, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (stating that "[t]his is a dynamic moment in the history of public company shareholder voting" and that certain changes in voting mechanics "threaten to open the floodgates to contested elections").
  • 444
    • 36549089536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, infra note 246 and accompanying text discussing impact majority vote system would have had on reelection of Disney chairman
    • See, e.g., infra note 246 and accompanying text (discussing impact majority vote system would have had on reelection of Disney chairman Michael Eisner).
    • Michael Eisner)
  • 445
    • 36549069236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Masters, supra note 235
    • Masters, supra note 235.
  • 446
    • 36549061516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 447
    • 47949116169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Study of Majority Voting in Director Elections
    • See, Feb. 5, available at, on file with the
    • See Claudia H. Allen, Study of Majority Voting in Director Elections i-v (Feb. 5, 2007), available at http://www.ngelaw.com/files/upload/ majority_callen_020707.pdf (on file with the Columbia Law Review);
    • (2007) Columbia Law Review
    • Allen, C.H.1
  • 448
    • 36549081417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Companies Switch to Tougher Majority Voting for Board Directors, Andrews Corp. Officers and Directors Liability Litig. Rep
    • Companies Switch to Tougher Majority Voting for Board Directors, Says Survey, 21 Andrews Corp. Officers and Directors Liability Litig. Rep. 13 (2006);
    • (2006) Says Survey , vol.21 , pp. 13
  • 449
    • 36549023999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Masters, supra note 235. In June 2006, at the end of the proxy season, Wachtell Lipton, a firm long oriented to director primacy, admitted that the majority voting standard will become universal. Memorandum from Martin Lipton, Gregory E. Osding & David M. Adlerstein, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Majority Voting - A Look Back at the 2006 Proxy Season (June 12, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • Masters, supra note 235. In June 2006, at the end of the proxy season, Wachtell Lipton, a firm long oriented to director primacy, admitted that the majority voting standard "will become universal." Memorandum from Martin Lipton, Gregory E. Osding & David M. Adlerstein, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Majority Voting - A Look Back at the 2006 Proxy Season (June 12, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 450
    • 36549011785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On August 1, 2006, amendments to the Delaware General Corporation Law became effective, having the effect of encouraging the adoption of majority voting bylaws. Memorandum from Martin Lipton et al., Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Delaware Adopts Majority Voting Amendments (July 7, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • On August 1, 2006, amendments to the Delaware General Corporation Law became effective, having the effect of encouraging the adoption of majority voting bylaws. Memorandum from Martin Lipton et al., Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Delaware Adopts Majority Voting Amendments (July 7, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 451
    • 36549079610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Masters, supra note 235 citing Institutional Investor Services statistics
    • Masters, supra note 235 (citing Institutional Investor Services statistics).
  • 452
    • 36549046097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Memorandum from David A. Katz & Laura A. McIntosh, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Corporate Governance Update: Poison Pills-Maintain Flexibility in Takeover Defense (Jan. 26, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review). Under shareholder pressure, companies have increasingly eliminated takeover defenses or submitted them to a shareholder vote. In 2004 and 2005, shareholders voted on nearly seventy-five precatory shareholder proposals to rescind poison pills. Each received an average of fifty-seven percent of the votes cast. Lawyers advise corporations that the consequences of ignoring such majority votes can be severe and that they should take care to avoid that situation if possible.
    • Memorandum from David A. Katz & Laura A. McIntosh, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Corporate Governance Update: Poison Pills-Maintain Flexibility in Takeover Defense (Jan. 26, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review). Under shareholder pressure, companies have increasingly eliminated takeover defenses or submitted them to a shareholder vote. In 2004 and 2005, shareholders voted on nearly seventy-five precatory shareholder proposals to rescind poison pills. Each received an average of fifty-seven percent of the votes cast. Lawyers advise corporations that the consequences of ignoring such majority votes "can be severe" and that they "should take care to avoid that situation if possible."
  • 453
    • 36549085131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 3
    • Id. at 3.
  • 454
    • 36549030365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Internet Availability of Proxy Materials, Exchange Act Release No. 52,926, 70 Fed. Reg. 74,598, 74,598-99 (proposed Dec. 15, 2005). By allowing this switch to electronic delivery, the cost to dissident shareholders of launching proxy fights-historically, a major barrier-is lowered dramatically.
    • Internet Availability of Proxy Materials, Exchange Act Release No. 52,926, 70 Fed. Reg. 74,598, 74,598-99 (proposed Dec. 15, 2005). By allowing this switch to electronic delivery, the cost to dissident shareholders of launching proxy fights-historically, a major barrier-is lowered dramatically.
  • 455
    • 36549063001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Shareholder Proposals, Exchange Act Release No. 56,160, 72 Fed. Reg. 43,466, 43,469-72 (proposed Aug. 3, 2007) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt 240);
    • See Shareholder Proposals, Exchange Act Release No. 56,160, 72 Fed. Reg. 43,466, 43,469-72 (proposed Aug. 3, 2007) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt 240);
  • 456
    • 36549010058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shareholder Proposals Relating to the Election of Directors, Exchange Act Release No. 56,161, 72 Fed. Reg. 43,488, 43,493 (proposed Aug. 3, 2007) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) ;
    • Shareholder Proposals Relating to the Election of Directors, Exchange Act Release No. 56,161, 72 Fed. Reg. 43,488, 43,493 (proposed Aug. 3, 2007) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) ;
  • 457
    • 36549084644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Solomon? Cox Splits Vote on Proxy Access
    • July 26, at
    • Kara Scannell, SECs Solomon? Cox Splits Vote on Proxy Access, Wall St. J., July 26, 2007, at Cl.
    • (2007) Wall St. J
    • Kara Scannell, S.E.C.1
  • 458
    • 36549037669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Big Board Moves to Change Rule on Proxy Votes
    • Oct. 25, at
    • Big Board Moves to Change Rule on Proxy Votes, N.Y. Times, Oct. 25, 2006, at C12.
    • (2006) N.Y. Times
  • 459
    • 36549014660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Report and Recommendations of the Proxy Working Group to the New York Stock Exchange 21 (June 5, 2006), at http://www.nyse.com/pdfs/PWG_REPORT.pdf (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
    • Report and Recommendations of the Proxy Working Group to the New York Stock Exchange 21 (June 5, 2006), at http://www.nyse.com/pdfs/PWG_REPORT.pdf (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
  • 460
    • 36549061515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • About seventy to eighty percent of all publicly held companies' shares are held in street name, meaning that the record owner is a broker, bank, or other depository. Id. at 10.
    • About seventy to eighty percent of all publicly held companies' shares are held in "street name," meaning that the record owner is a broker, bank, or other depository. Id. at 10.
  • 461
    • 36549066828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under NYSE's existing Rule 452, brokers who hold shares for their clients and do not receive specific voting instructions prior to the meeting date may use the brokers' own discretion in voting on any matters considered routine. Id. at 8.
    • Under NYSE's existing Rule 452, brokers who hold shares for their clients and do not receive specific voting instructions prior to the meeting date may use the brokers' own discretion in voting on any matters considered "routine." Id. at 8.
  • 462
    • 36549036224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One of the items considered routine was the uncontested election of directors. Id. at 1.
    • One of the items considered "routine" was the uncontested election of directors. Id. at 1.
  • 463
    • 36549012768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Historically, brokers have cast uninstructed shares overwhelmingly in support of the board's recommendations, meaning that the incumbent board has a significant advantage in director elections and other matters. Id. at 14.
    • Historically, brokers have cast uninstructed shares " overwhelmingly" in support of the board's recommendations, meaning that the incumbent board has a significant advantage in director elections and other matters. Id. at 14.
  • 464
    • 36549082444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eisner was reelected with fifty-five percent of the votes cast. Had broker votes not counted, Eisner would have received only forty-five percent of the votes. Id. at 9.
    • Eisner was reelected with fifty-five percent of the votes cast. Had broker votes not counted, Eisner would have received only forty-five percent of the votes. Id. at 9.
  • 465
    • 36549032212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Masters, supra note 235
    • See Masters, supra note 235.
  • 466
    • 36549049865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A 2006 Council of Institutional Investors study found that sixty-one of the ninety-seven companies whose shareholder proposals received a majority vote in 2005 had taken action similar to that requested-more than double the percentage of the previous year. Id.
    • A 2006 Council of Institutional Investors study found that sixty-one of the ninety-seven companies whose shareholder proposals received a majority vote in 2005 had taken action similar to that requested-more than double the percentage of the previous year. Id.
  • 467
    • 36549041484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., John Maggs, CEOs Under Fire, Nat'l J., June 16, 2007, at 42, 45 (discussing saga of man in chicken suit).
    • See, e.g., John Maggs, CEOs Under Fire, Nat'l J., June 16, 2007, at 42, 45 (discussing saga of man in chicken suit).
  • 468
    • 36549037670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Unisuper Ltd. v. News Corp., No. 1699-N, 2005 Del. Ch. LEXIS 205, at *32 (Del. Ch. Dec. 20, 2005).
    • See Unisuper Ltd. v. News Corp., No. 1699-N, 2005 Del. Ch. LEXIS 205, at *32 (Del. Ch. Dec. 20, 2005).
  • 469
    • 36549051660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 470
    • 36549023471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unisuper Ltd. v. News Corp., No. 1699-N, 2006 Del. Ch. LEXIS 11, at *11 (Del. Ch. Jan. 19, 2006). For reactions to these opinions, see David Marcus, News Agents, Daily Deal, Feb. 27, 2006 (arguing that Unisuper cases suggest shareholder primacy is gaining ground in Delaware);
    • Unisuper Ltd. v. News Corp., No. 1699-N, 2006 Del. Ch. LEXIS 11, at *11 (Del. Ch. Jan. 19, 2006). For reactions to these opinions, see David Marcus, News Agents, Daily Deal, Feb. 27, 2006 (arguing that Unisuper cases suggest shareholder primacy is gaining ground in Delaware);
  • 471
    • 36549044450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Memorandum from Theodore N. Mirvis, Paul K. Rowe & William Savitt, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Delaware Supreme Court Is Likely to Hear Quick Appeal from Controversial News Corp. Decision (Jan. 20, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (predicting that Delaware Supreme Court affirmance would allow shareholders to impose binding mandates on directors).
    • Memorandum from Theodore N. Mirvis, Paul K. Rowe & William Savitt, Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, to Clients, Delaware Supreme Court Is Likely to Hear Quick Appeal from Controversial News Corp. Decision (Jan. 20, 2006) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (predicting that Delaware Supreme Court affirmance would allow shareholders to impose binding mandates on directors).
  • 472
    • 36549017657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Credit Bureau of Broken Bow v. Moninger, 284 N.W.2d 855, 856 (Neb. 1979);
    • See, e.g., Credit Bureau of Broken Bow v. Moninger, 284 N.W.2d 855, 856 (Neb. 1979);
  • 473
    • 36549001741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gerdes v. Kennamer, 155 S.W.3d 541, 544 (Tex. App. 2004);
    • Gerdes v. Kennamer, 155 S.W.3d 541, 544 (Tex. App. 2004);
  • 474
    • 36549018157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judge Approves Sale of Simpson Assets to Help Pay Judgment, CNN, at http://www.cnn.com/US/9811/03/ simpson.estate/index.html (last visited Sept. 7, 2007) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (describing seizure of O.J. Simpson's assets, including Heisman trophy, to pay judgments).
    • Judge Approves Sale of Simpson Assets to Help Pay Judgment, CNN, at http://www.cnn.com/US/9811/03/ simpson.estate/index.html (last visited Sept. 7, 2007) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (describing seizure of O.J. Simpson's assets, including Heisman trophy, to pay judgments).
  • 475
    • 84858453779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, §§ 238, 423(3) (Eng.);
    • Insolvency Act, 1986, c. 45, §§ 238, 423(3) (Eng.);
  • 476
    • 36549023090 scopus 로고
    • Insolvency Focus, L. Soc'y
    • Feb. 19, at
    • Hamish Anderson, Insolvency Focus, L. Soc'y Gazette, Feb. 19, 1992, at 26.
    • (1992) Gazette , pp. 26
    • Anderson, H.1
  • 477
    • 84858453370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • transactions at an undervalue
    • In United States law the concept correlative to is the constructive fraudulent conveyance. 11 U.S.C. § 548a, 2000
    • In United States law the concept correlative to "transactions at an undervalue" is the constructive fraudulent conveyance. 11 U.S.C. § 548(a) (2000).
  • 478
    • 84858453778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Each permits the undoing of a transaction without a showing of actual intent to defraud. 11 U.S.C. §548a, 1, B
    • "Each permits the undoing of a transaction without a showing of actual intent to defraud." 11 U.S.C. §548(a) (1) (B) ;
  • 479
    • 84858453366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unif. Fraudulent Transfer Act §§ 4(a) (2), 5, 7A U.L.A. pt. 2, at 58, 129 (2006);
    • Unif. Fraudulent Transfer Act §§ 4(a) (2), 5, 7A U.L.A. pt. 2, at 58, 129 (2006);
  • 480
    • 84858477427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see 5 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 548.01[1, 2
    • see 5 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 548.01[1]-[2].
  • 481
    • 38349047820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 7. The Act does permit injunctive relief and receivership remedies against the debtor, but not monetary liability
    • Unif. Fraudulent Transfer Act § 7. The Act does permit injunctive relief and receivership remedies against the debtor, but not monetary liability.
    • Fraudulent Transfer Act
    • Unif1
  • 482
    • 84858465356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 523(a)6
    • 11 U.S.C. § 523(a)(6);
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 483
    • 36549073717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles Jordan Tabb, The Scope of the Fresh Start in Bankruptcy: Collateral Conversions and the Dischargeability Debate, 59 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 56, 59 (1990).
    • Charles Jordan Tabb, The Scope of the Fresh Start in Bankruptcy: Collateral Conversions and the Dischargeability Debate, 59 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 56, 59 (1990).
  • 484
    • 84858453362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An example of criminal penalties for secreting or carrying off collateral is Hindering Secured Creditors, Tex. Penal Code Ann. § 32.33 Vernon 2006
    • An example of criminal penalties for secreting or carrying off collateral is Hindering Secured Creditors, Tex. Penal Code Ann. § 32.33 (Vernon 2006).
  • 485
    • 36549018625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By an individual debtor, we refer throughout to a debtor who is a natural person rather than a legal entity
    • By an "individual" debtor, we refer throughout to a debtor who is a natural person rather than a legal entity.
  • 486
    • 36549021103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As with personal property, there is an action for conversion or waste if the debtor puts the collateral beyond a secured party's reach, but that remains a property-based remedy, not an independent duty owed to the creditor qua creditor. It is also an ordinary, tort-like duty, not a fiduciary obligation.
    • As with personal property, there is an action for conversion or waste if the debtor puts the collateral beyond a secured party's reach, but that remains a property-based remedy, not an independent duty owed to the creditor qua creditor. It is also an ordinary, tort-like duty, not a fiduciary obligation.
  • 487
    • 36549019549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even after default, debtors do not owe their creditors fiduciary or other special duties. Instead, creditors are expected to include in their contracts such restraints on debtor behavior as they diink necessary and appropriate. Both individual and corporate debtors are subject to receivership remedies in cases of fraud or similar conduct. Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 154-55. However, these remedies are conservatory, protecting the value of the debtor's property for the benefit of creditors, rather than imposing a liability duty on the debtor.
    • Even after default, debtors do not owe their creditors fiduciary or other special duties. Instead, creditors are expected to include in their contracts such restraints on debtor behavior as they diink necessary and appropriate. Both individual and corporate debtors are subject to receivership remedies in cases of fraud or similar conduct. Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 154-55. However, these remedies are conservatory, protecting the value of the debtor's property for the benefit of creditors, rather than imposing a liability duty on the debtor.
  • 488
    • 36549071145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sometimes these contractual duties are supported by the restraints imposed by property law with regard to collateral given as security, but those restraints are themselves quite narrow. There is a rich literature concerning the costs and benefits of expanding contract liability, but most of it in recent years has been focused on tort liability along the lines of tortious inducement of breach of contract. See, e.g, Mark P. Gergen, Tortious Interference: How It Is Engulfing Commercial Law, Why This is not Entirely Bad, and a Prudential Response, 38 Ariz. L. Rev. 1175, 1182-83 (1996, exploring different prayers of damage under tortious interference that can create an enormous potential scope in contract);
    • Sometimes these contractual duties are supported by the restraints imposed by property law with regard to collateral given as security, but those restraints are themselves quite narrow. There is a rich literature concerning the costs and benefits of expanding contract liability, but most of it in recent years has been focused on tort liability along the lines of tortious inducement of breach of contract. See, e.g., Mark P. Gergen, Tortious Interference: How It Is Engulfing Commercial Law, Why This is not Entirely Bad, and a Prudential Response, 38 Ariz. L. Rev. 1175, 1182-83 (1996) (exploring different prayers of damage under tortious interference that can create "an enormous potential scope in contract");
  • 489
    • 36549075609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harvey S. Perlman, Interference with Contract and Other Economic Expectancies: A Clash of Tort and Contract Doctrine, 49 U. Chi. L. Rev. 61, 70-72 (1982) (assessing costs of economic loss with respect to determining proper limits of liability for tortious act);
    • Harvey S. Perlman, Interference with Contract and Other Economic Expectancies: A Clash of Tort and Contract Doctrine, 49 U. Chi. L. Rev. 61, 70-72 (1982) (assessing costs of economic loss with respect to determining proper limits of liability for tortious act);
  • 490
    • 36549062517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James B. Sales, The Tort of Interference with Contract: An Argument for Requiring a Valid Existing Contract to Restrain the Use of Tort Law in Circumventing Contract Remedies, 22 Tex. Tech. L. Rev. 123, 127 (1991) (Generally, contract remedies promote efficiency and predictability, whereas the intervention of tortious interference with contract introduces inefficiency and unpredictability.).
    • James B. Sales, The Tort of Interference with Contract: An Argument for Requiring a "Valid Existing Contract" to Restrain the Use of Tort Law in Circumventing Contract Remedies, 22 Tex. Tech. L. Rev. 123, 127 (1991) ("Generally, contract remedies promote efficiency and predictability, whereas the intervention of tortious interference with contract introduces inefficiency and unpredictability.").
  • 491
    • 36549008181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a list of critiques of tortious interference's ambiguities, see Gary Myers, The Differing Treatment of Efficiency and Competition in Antitrust and Tortious Interference Law, 77 Minn. L. Rev. 1097, 1109-10 (1993).
    • For a list of critiques of tortious interference's ambiguities, see Gary Myers, The Differing Treatment of Efficiency and Competition in Antitrust and Tortious Interference Law, 77 Minn. L. Rev. 1097, 1109-10 (1993).
  • 492
    • 36549034336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interestingly enough, that sentiment is expressed in a recent Delaware case discussing the duty shifting doctrines. See Trenwick Am. Litig. Trust v. Ernst & Young, L.L.P., 906 A.2d 168, 173, 199 (Del. Ch. 2006) (noting that Delaware law leaves protection of creditors largely to contracts they negotiate).
    • Interestingly enough, that sentiment is expressed in a recent Delaware case discussing the duty shifting doctrines. See Trenwick Am. Litig. Trust v. Ernst & Young, L.L.P., 906 A.2d 168, 173, 199 (Del. Ch. 2006) (noting that Delaware law leaves protection of creditors largely to contracts they negotiate).
  • 493
    • 36549059672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The court makes a similar statement in North American, despite its adoption of duty shifting. N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 15 (Del. May 18, 2007).
    • The court makes a similar statement in North American, despite its adoption of duty shifting. N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 15 (Del. May 18, 2007).
  • 494
    • 36549017184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Apparendy, lenders and other creditors do not often bargain for directors' duties to protect creditor interests. One reason may be that they are not regarded as important or efficacious for creditors. Another possible reason is the risk of liability to a creditor found to have been in control of a corporation. See, e.g., Bergquist v. First Nat'l Bank of St. Paul (In re Am. Lumber Co.), 5 B.R. 470, 477-78 (Bankr. D. Minn. 1980). In addition, depending on the nature of the agreement, there may be questions as to its enforceability under Delaware law.
    • Apparendy, lenders and other creditors do not often bargain for directors' duties to protect creditor interests. One reason may be that they are not regarded as important or efficacious for creditors. Another possible reason is the risk of liability to a creditor found to have been in control of a corporation. See, e.g., Bergquist v. First Nat'l Bank of St. Paul (In re Am. Lumber Co.), 5 B.R. 470, 477-78 (Bankr. D. Minn. 1980). In addition, depending on the nature of the agreement, there may be questions as to its enforceability under Delaware law.
  • 496
    • 36549085576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Hertig and Kanda assert that limited liability is a good reason for imposing on corporations an additional duty to creditors, but provide little concrete justification. Gerard Hertig & Hideki Kanda, Creditor Protection, in The Anatomy of Corporate Law: A Comparative and Functional Approach 71, 71-73 2004
    • Professors Hertig and Kanda assert that limited liability is a good reason for imposing on corporations an additional duty to creditors, but provide little concrete justification. Gerard Hertig & Hideki Kanda, Creditor Protection, in The Anatomy of Corporate Law: A Comparative and Functional Approach 71, 71-73 (2004).
  • 498
    • 36549034850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joseph McKnight, Protection of the Family Home from Seizure by Creditors: The Sources and Evolution of a Legal Principle, 86 Sw. Hist. Q. 369, 388-90 (1983) (comparing provisions of 1829 act of Mexican state of Coahuila y Texas, which followed Spanish tradition of protecting debtor's land, with eighteenth century English law allowing debtors to protect certain movables but subjected all land and slaves to enforcement of debt).
    • Joseph McKnight, Protection of the Family Home from Seizure by Creditors: The Sources and Evolution of a Legal Principle, 86 Sw. Hist. Q. 369, 388-90 (1983) (comparing provisions of 1829 act of Mexican state of Coahuila y Texas, which followed Spanish tradition of protecting debtor's land, with eighteenth century English law allowing debtors to protect certain movables but subjected all land and slaves to enforcement of debt).
  • 499
    • 36549071597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Imprisonment for debt retreated, but unevenly. Balleisen, supra note 263, at 12 (From the 1820s onward, a growing number of states dramatically curtailed the use of imprisonment for debt, essentially restricting the institution to instances in which a debtor was guilty of gross fraud.);
    • Imprisonment for debt retreated, but unevenly. Balleisen, supra note 263, at 12 ("From the 1820s onward, a growing number of states dramatically curtailed the use of imprisonment for debt, essentially restricting the institution to instances in which a debtor was guilty of gross fraud.");
  • 500
    • 36549073216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bruce H. Mann, Republic of Debtors 106 (2002) (commenting that argument against imprisoning debtors-that old insolvency laws were based on fiction that debtors were criminal-resulted in New York abolishing imprisonment for most debt in 1831, while Pennsylvania waited eleven more years to abolish imprisonment for most debt).
    • Bruce H. Mann, Republic of Debtors 106 (2002) (commenting that argument against imprisoning debtors-that old insolvency laws were based on fiction that debtors were criminal-resulted in New York abolishing imprisonment for most debt in 1831, while Pennsylvania waited eleven more years to abolish imprisonment for most debt).
  • 501
    • 36549087270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Balleisen, supra note 263, passim discussing bankruptcy discharge of personal liability for business debts
    • Balleisen, supra note 263, passim (discussing bankruptcy discharge of personal liability for business debts).
  • 502
    • 36549075150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Trevor v. Whitworth, (1887) 12 App. Cas. 409, 411 (H.L.) (appeal taken from C.A.) (The surrender of shares . . . may be lawfully made without reducing the real capital, but no reduction of capital otherwise than as allowed by statute is legitimate ....);
    • See Trevor v. Whitworth, (1887) 12 App. Cas. 409, 411 (H.L.) (appeal taken from C.A.) ("The surrender of shares . . . may be lawfully made without reducing the real capital, but no reduction of capital otherwise than as allowed by statute is legitimate ....");
  • 503
    • 36549040065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Craig A. Peterson & Norman W. Hawker, Does Corporate Law Matter? Legal Capital Restrictions on Stock Distributions, 31 Akron L. Rev. 175, 180-83 (1997) (discussing historical move away from par value legal capital doctrine);
    • Craig A. Peterson & Norman W. Hawker, Does Corporate Law Matter? Legal Capital Restrictions on Stock Distributions, 31 Akron L. Rev. 175, 180-83 (1997) (discussing historical move away from par value legal capital doctrine);
  • 504
    • 36549048411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 32-38 and accompanying text. For a description of the view from Europe, where some of the same sorts of rules are now being reviewed, see Bratton, supra note 117, at 41-44.
    • supra notes 32-38 and accompanying text. For a description of the view from Europe, where some of the same sorts of rules are now being reviewed, see Bratton, supra note 117, at 41-44.
  • 505
    • 0002469635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lynn M. LoPucki, The Death of Liability, 106 Yale L.J. 1, 6 (1996) ([T] his Article concludes that currendy effective judgment-proofing strategies are fully capable of defeating the liability system.).
    • See, e.g., Lynn M. LoPucki, The Death of Liability, 106 Yale L.J. 1, 6 (1996) ("[T] his Article concludes that currendy effective judgment-proofing strategies are fully capable of defeating the liability system.").
  • 506
    • 84858453360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of course, those rules are critically important with regard to tort victims and other involuntary creditors. We do not address the problems presented by involuntary creditors of financially distressed debtors in this Article, beyond noting that its solution should probably be sought in bankruptcy law and policy. We note, however, that until now no special priority has been given to most of these creditors under most state laws or the Bankruptcy Code. Indeed, until 1978 tort creditors generally could not present their claims in bankruptcy, but had to be content with an undischarged claim that often had little postbankruptcy value. 2 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 101.05
    • Of course, those rules are critically important with regard to tort victims and other involuntary creditors. We do not address the problems presented by involuntary creditors of financially distressed debtors in this Article, beyond noting that its solution should probably be sought in bankruptcy law and policy. We note, however, that until now no special priority has been given to most of these creditors under most state laws or the Bankruptcy Code. Indeed, until 1978 tort creditors generally could not present their claims in bankruptcy, but had to be content with an undischarged claim that often had little postbankruptcy value. 2 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 101.05.
  • 507
    • 36549009122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Marshall v. McCaffrey (In re McCaffrey), 216 B.R. 196, 202 (Bankr. E.D. Mich. 1997) (dismissing plaintiff's arguments against dischargeability of debt on grounds of breach of fiduciary duty, conversion, and failure to keep adequate records when portion of corporate loan was used for gambling).
    • Cf. Marshall v. McCaffrey (In re McCaffrey), 216 B.R. 196, 202 (Bankr. E.D. Mich. 1997) (dismissing plaintiff's arguments against dischargeability of debt on grounds of breach of fiduciary duty, conversion, and failure to keep adequate records when portion of corporate loan was used for gambling).
  • 508
    • 36549047995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.E.
    • See supra Part II.E.
  • 509
    • 36549089086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part III.C.2.
    • See infra Part III.C.2.
  • 510
    • 36549010056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 790-91 (Del. Ch. 2004) ;
    • Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 790-91 (Del. Ch. 2004) ;
  • 511
    • 36549056113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see supra note 62 and accompanying text.
    • see supra note 62 and accompanying text.
  • 512
    • 84858453352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Regulation S-K, 17 C.F.R. §§ 229.303, 229.402 (2007). Other, more specific, SEC disclosure requirements, such as those relating to limitations on the payment of dividends, may apply in certain narrow circumstances.
    • See Regulation S-K, 17 C.F.R. §§ 229.303, 229.402 (2007). Other, more specific, SEC disclosure requirements, such as those relating to limitations on the payment of dividends, may apply in certain narrow circumstances.
  • 513
    • 36549004107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On a related point, Professor Lipson has made an effective attack on Credit Lyonnais by recognizing that the duty shifting doctrines rest upon a confusion between priority and duty. See Lipson, supra note 49, at 1192.
    • On a related point, Professor Lipson has made an effective attack on Credit Lyonnais by recognizing that the duty shifting doctrines rest upon a confusion between priority and duty. See Lipson, supra note 49, at 1192.
  • 514
    • 84858453354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 2 Michael T. Madison et al., The Law of Real Estate Financing § 12:34 (rev. ed. 2007) (describing typical steps required for judicial foreclosure).
    • See 2 Michael T. Madison et al., The Law of Real Estate Financing § 12:34 (rev. ed. 2007) (describing typical steps required for judicial foreclosure).
  • 515
    • 84858453349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Restatement (Third) of Prop.: Mortgages § 4.1 (1997) (A mortgage creates only a security interest in real estate and confers no right to possession of that real estate on the mortgagee.) ;
    • See Restatement (Third) of Prop.: Mortgages § 4.1 (1997) ("A mortgage creates only a security interest in real estate and confers no right to possession of that real estate on the mortgagee.") ;
  • 516
    • 84858477417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 4.6 (outlining elements of waste and remedies for breach of duty by mortgagor).
    • id. § 4.6 (outlining elements of waste and remedies for breach of duty by mortgagor).
  • 517
    • 36549037667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Nissan Motor Acceptance Corp. v. Baker, 239 B.R. 484, 488-89 (N.D. Tex. 1999) (mem.) (holding creditor in violation of bankruptcy stay for failure to return car that was lawfully seized before bankruptcy but was not sold before bankruptcy was filed).
    • See, e.g., Nissan Motor Acceptance Corp. v. Baker, 239 B.R. 484, 488-89 (N.D. Tex. 1999) (mem.) (holding creditor in violation of bankruptcy stay for failure to return car that was lawfully seized before bankruptcy but was not sold before bankruptcy was filed).
  • 518
    • 84858453764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The stay does not have effect if the foreclosure is complete before filing. See generally, 2 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 105.02 (discussing procedures for applying for bankruptcy stays);
    • The stay does not have effect if the foreclosure is complete before filing. See generally, 2 Collier on Bankruptcy, supra note 95, ¶ 105.02 (discussing procedures for applying for bankruptcy stays);
  • 519
    • 84858453765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. ¶ 362.05 (discussing exceptions to bankruptcy stays).
    • id. ¶ 362.05 (discussing exceptions to bankruptcy stays).
  • 520
    • 36549046095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. JP Morgan Chase Bank v. Altos Hornos de Mex., S.A. de C.V., 412 F.3d 418, 426-27 (2d Cir. 2005) (finding that funds deposited in collection account from which creditor could withdraw for purposes of debt repayment were not property of creditor).
    • Cf. JP Morgan Chase Bank v. Altos Hornos de Mex., S.A. de C.V., 412 F.3d 418, 426-27 (2d Cir. 2005) (finding that funds deposited in collection account from which creditor could withdraw for purposes of debt repayment were not property of creditor).
  • 521
    • 84858453762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to personal property, the rights to seizure, sale, and payment from proceeds are found in U.C.C. §§ 9-601 to 9-607 (2004).
    • As to personal property, the rights to seizure, sale, and payment from proceeds are found in U.C.C. §§ 9-601 to 9-607 (2004).
  • 522
    • 36549007001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some courts have tried to expand the rights of secured parties after default, but recent cases have insisted on the traditional bundle. See, e.g., In re Mitchell v. Bankillinois, 316 B.R. 891, 897 (S.D. Tex. 2004) (highlighting differences between lienholder and owner).
    • Some courts have tried to expand the rights of secured parties after default, but recent cases have insisted on the traditional bundle. See, e.g., In re Mitchell v. Bankillinois, 316 B.R. 891, 897 (S.D. Tex. 2004) (highlighting differences between lienholder and owner).
  • 523
    • 84858457777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 1104 2000
    • 11 U.S.C. § 1104 (2000).
    • 11 U.S.C
  • 524
    • 36549042505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. N. Pac Ry. Co. v. Boyd, 228 U.S. 482, 505-06 (1913) (emphasizing that foreclosure proceedings take into account interests of botfi shareholders and creditors, even if creditors have prior rights);
    • Cf. N. Pac Ry. Co. v. Boyd, 228 U.S. 482, 505-06 (1913) (emphasizing that foreclosure proceedings take into account interests of botfi shareholders and creditors, even if creditors have "prior rights");
  • 525
    • 36549082443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Louisville Trust Co. v. Louisville, New Albany & Chi. Ry. Co., 174 U.S. 674, 688 (1899) (discussing need to protect unsecured creditors from collusion between bondholders and stockholders);
    • Louisville Trust Co. v. Louisville, New Albany & Chi. Ry. Co., 174 U.S. 674, 688 (1899) (discussing need to protect unsecured creditors from collusion between bondholders and stockholders);
  • 526
    • 36549060145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bezanson v. Fleet Bank-NH, 29 F.3d 16, 20 (1st Cir. 1994) (holding that creditor for loan in default cannot walk away with the collateral if it is worth more than the debt).
    • Bezanson v. Fleet Bank-NH, 29 F.3d 16, 20 (1st Cir. 1994) (holding that creditor for "loan in default cannot walk away with the collateral if it is worth more than the debt").
  • 527
    • 36549083445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts II.B, II.C, III.B.
    • See supra Parts II.B, II.C, III.B.
  • 528
    • 36549001740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MM Cos. v. Liquid Audio, Inc., 813 A.2d 1118, 1126 (Del. 2003).
    • MM Cos. v. Liquid Audio, Inc., 813 A.2d 1118, 1126 (Del. 2003).
  • 529
    • 36549045599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., In re KDI Holdings, Inc., 277 B.R. 493, 515-16 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 1999) (listing elements to establish lender liability);
    • See, e.g., In re KDI Holdings, Inc., 277 B.R. 493, 515-16 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 1999) (listing elements to establish lender liability);
  • 530
    • 36549085575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Bratton, supra note 117, at 50-51 noting that managing creditor can be held liable to stockholders
    • see also Bratton, supra note 117, at 50-51 (noting that managing creditor can be held liable to stockholders).
  • 532
    • 36549002705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Hernando de Soto, The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else 61-62 (2000) (describing closely tracked Western property system).
    • See generally Hernando de Soto, The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else 61-62 (2000) (describing closely tracked Western property system).
  • 533
    • 36549059671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. (Del. May 18, 2007);
    • N. Am. Catholic Educ. Programming Found, v. Gheewalla, No. 521, 2006, slip op. (Del. May 18, 2007);
  • 534
    • 36549039591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also discussion supra
    • see also discussion supra Part I.B.4.
    • , vol.4
    • Part, I.B.1
  • 535
    • 36549020618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • slip op. at
    • North American, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 23-24.
    • (2006) North American , Issue.521 , pp. 23-24
  • 536
    • 36549082442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19
    • Id. at 19.
  • 537
    • 84900012704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Canadian Supreme Court has adopted a somewhat similar approach, through the oppression remedy. See Janis Sarra, Canada's Supreme Court Rules No Fiduciary Obligation Towards Creditors on Insolvency-People's Department Stores v. Wise, 15 Int'l. Insolvency Rev. 1 passim (2006) (discussing oppression remedy). That court also imposed a duty of care owed to creditors. Id. at 9.
    • The Canadian Supreme Court has adopted a somewhat similar approach, through the "oppression" remedy. See Janis Sarra, Canada's Supreme Court Rules No Fiduciary Obligation Towards Creditors on Insolvency-People's Department Stores v. Wise, 15 Int'l. Insolvency Rev. 1 passim (2006) (discussing oppression remedy). That court also imposed a duty of care owed to creditors. Id. at 9.
  • 538
    • 36549037219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • slip op. at, emphasis in original
    • North American, No. 521, 2006, slip op. at 20 (emphasis in original)
    • (2006) North American , Issue.521 , pp. 20
  • 539
    • 36549039100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 794 n.67 (Del. Ch. 2004)).
    • (quoting Prod. Res. Group, L.L.C. v. NCT Group, Inc., 863 A.2d 772, 794 n.67 (Del. Ch. 2004)).
  • 540
    • 36549048410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 15, 20, 23 emphasis added
    • Id. at 15, 20, 23 (emphasis added).
  • 541
    • 36549070194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 23 emphasis added
    • Id. at 23 (emphasis added).
  • 542
    • 36549088626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts II.A.1, II.B.
    • See supra Parts II.A.1, II.B.
  • 543
    • 36549026411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Parts II.A.1, II.B.
    • See supra Parts II.A.1, II.B.
  • 544
    • 36549086556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As to the need to consider the timing issue, see Legal Dep't, Int'l Monetary Fund
    • As to the need to consider the timing issue, see Legal Dep't, Int'l Monetary Fund, Orderly & Effective Insolvency Procedural Principles: Key Issues 53-55 (1999);
    • (1999) Orderly & Effective Insolvency Procedural Principles: Key Issues , pp. 53-55
  • 545
    • 36549066688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cf. Hertig & Kanda, supra note 262, at 73 (stating that all jurisdictions have devised ways to induce insolvent firms to file for bankruptcy with reasonable promptness). In the United States, a key question for future research is determining whether the corporate governance system or the bankruptcy system should be the locus of the transition decision.
    • cf. Hertig & Kanda, supra note 262, at 73 (stating that "all jurisdictions have devised ways to induce insolvent firms to file for bankruptcy with reasonable promptness"). In the United States, a key question for future research is determining whether the corporate governance system or the bankruptcy system should be the locus of the transition decision.
  • 546
    • 36549068262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Legal Dep't, Int'l Monetary Fund, supra note 296, at 59;
    • See Legal Dep't, Int'l Monetary Fund, supra note 296, at 59;
  • 547
    • 36549036223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 397
    • Warren & Westbrook, Text, Cases & Problems, supra note 31, at 397.
  • 549
    • 36549055624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Hertig and Kanda say that most countries require directors to file an insolvency proceeding upon insolvency, but they seem to be focused primarily upon European countries. Hertig & Kanda, supra note 262, at 73
    • Professors Hertig and Kanda say that most countries require directors to file an insolvency proceeding upon insolvency, but they seem to be focused primarily upon European countries. Hertig & Kanda, supra note 262, at 73.
  • 550
    • 36549070679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One example is Germany, where a failure to file for insolvency once a corporation is insolvent may subject directors to both criminal penalties and civil liability. Sandy Shandro, Germany: Failed to File? Go Directly to Jail!, Am. Bankr. Inst. J., Jan. 24, 2006, at 18 (including survey of European rules of this type).
    • One example is Germany, where a failure to file for insolvency once a corporation is insolvent may subject directors to both criminal penalties and civil liability. Sandy Shandro, Germany: Failed to File? Go Directly to Jail!, Am. Bankr. Inst. J., Jan. 24, 2006, at 18 (including survey of European rules of this type).
  • 551
    • 36549042998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such a filing by the directors of a German subsidiary of the Singer Group precipitated its worldwide bankruptcy in over one hundred countries. See Evan D. Flaschen, AnthonyJ. Smits & Leo Plank, Foreign Representatives in U.S. Chapter 11 Cases: Filling the Void in the Law of Multinational Insolvencies, 17 Conn. J. Int'l L. 3, 20 2001
    • Such a filing by the directors of a German subsidiary of the Singer Group precipitated its worldwide bankruptcy in over one hundred countries. See Evan D. Flaschen, AnthonyJ. Smits & Leo Plank, Foreign Representatives in U.S. Chapter 11 Cases: Filling the Void in the Law of Multinational Insolvencies, 17 Conn. J. Int'l L. 3, 20 (2001).
  • 552
    • 36549002704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Other common law countries have penalties for wrongful trading, which means roughly continuing the business after it has become insolvent. See, e.g, Keay & Murray, supra note 2, at 34
    • Other common law countries have penalties for "wrongful trading," which means roughly continuing the business after it has become insolvent. See, e.g., Keay & Murray, supra note 2, at 34.
  • 553
    • 36549005551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Block-Lieb, supra note 162, at 805 noting that a surprisingly small number of involuntary petitions are filed each year
    • See Block-Lieb, supra note 162, at 805 (noting that "a surprisingly small number of involuntary petitions are filed each year").
  • 554
    • 36549060144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see In re Liberate Techs., 314 B.R. 206, 218 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. 2004) (finding debtor's bankruptcy petition premature because [d]ebtor is very solvent, very liquid, and can sell its assets as a going concern outside of bankruptcy).
    • But see In re Liberate Techs., 314 B.R. 206, 218 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. 2004) (finding debtor's bankruptcy petition premature because "[d]ebtor is very solvent, very liquid, and can sell its assets as a going concern outside of bankruptcy").
  • 555
    • 36549087738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III.A.
    • See supra Part III.A.
  • 556
    • 36549042999 scopus 로고
    • Commodity Futures Trading Comm'n v
    • The corporation's attorney-client privilege can be waived by a trustee in bankruptcy, U.S. 343
    • The corporation's attorney-client privilege can be waived by a trustee in bankruptcy. Commodity Futures Trading Comm'n v. Weintraub, 471 U.S. 343, 358 (1985).
    • (1985) Weintraub , vol.471 , pp. 358
  • 557
    • 36549033837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 12
    • See supra note 12.
  • 558
    • 36549054713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1292-1317 discussing impact of financial innovation on capital structure and related matters
    • See, e.g., Hu, Shareholder Welfare, supra note 17, at 1292-1317 (discussing impact of financial innovation on capital structure and related matters).
  • 559
    • 36549044978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 150 discussing exceptions to presumption of well-diversified shareholders
    • See supra note 150 (discussing exceptions to presumption of well-diversified shareholders).
  • 560
    • 36549052211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-23, 844-47
    • See, e.g., Hu & Black, The New Vote Buying, supra note 8, at 814-23, 844-47.
  • 561
    • 36549082441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 814-27 (coining term empty voting and setting forth analytical framework for decoupling, in shareholder context, of voting rights and economic interest). The term empty voter does not refer only to those without any economic interest in a company. This term involves looking at the extent of voting power relative to the economic interest, not the absolute level of economic interest.
    • Id. at 814-27 (coining term "empty voting" and setting forth analytical framework for decoupling, in shareholder context, of voting rights and economic interest). The term "empty voter" does not refer only to those without any economic interest in a company. This term involves looking at the extent of voting power relative to the economic interest, not the absolute level of economic interest.
  • 562
    • 36549081416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 825
    • Id. at 825.
  • 563
    • 36549039590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 346-53 discussing evidence regarding extent of decoupling
    • See, e.g., Hu & Black, Decoupling, supra note 53, at 346-53 (discussing evidence regarding extent of decoupling).
  • 564
    • 36549063492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This discussion of extending this shareholder decoupling analytical framework to decoupling in the creditor context is based on Hu, Shareholder and Creditor Decoupling, supra note 17, at 20-21 coining terms empty creditor and empty covenant-holder, relating functional elements of creditor decoupling to those of shareholder decoupling, and discussing parallel policy concerns
    • This discussion of extending this shareholder decoupling analytical framework to decoupling in the creditor context is based on Hu, Shareholder and Creditor Decoupling, supra note 17, at 20-21 (coining terms "empty creditor" and "empty covenant-holder," relating functional elements of creditor decoupling to those of shareholder decoupling, and discussing parallel policy concerns).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.