메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 59, Issue 3, 2007, Pages 370-403

The Achille's heel of liberal IR theory?: Globalization and conflict in the pre-world war I era

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

ECONOMIC HISTORY; ECONOMIC INTEGRATION; GLOBALIZATION; HISTORICAL GEOGRAPHY; LIBERALISM; NINETEENTH CENTURY; POLITICAL CONFLICT; THEORETICAL STUDY;

EID: 35948974010     PISSN: 00438871     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0043887100020864     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (25)

References (154)
  • 5
    • 84974173391 scopus 로고
    • Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal Case
    • Autumn
    • Barry Buzan, "Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal Case," International Organization 38 (Autumn 1984);
    • (1984) International Organization , vol.38
    • Buzan, B.1
  • 6
    • 21344459739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Interdependence and War: A Theory of Trade Expectations
    • Summer
    • Dale C. Copeland, "Economic Interdependence and War: A Theory of Trade Expectations," International Security 20 (Summer 1996);
    • (1996) International Security , vol.20
    • Copeland, D.C.1
  • 7
    • 0002739028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commercial Liberalism Under Fire: Evidence from 1914 and 1936
    • Winter
    • Norrin M. Ripsman and Jean-Marc F. Blanchard, "Commercial Liberalism Under Fire: Evidence from 1914 and 1936," Security Studies 6 (Winter 1996-97);
    • (1996) Security Studies , vol.6
    • Ripsman, N.M.1    Blanchard, J.F.2
  • 8
    • 0012287759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre-World War I Europe
    • Spring
    • David M. Rowe, "World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre-World War I Europe," International Organization 53 (Spring 1999);
    • (1999) International Organization , vol.53
    • Rowe, D.M.1
  • 9
    • 29244458366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Tragedy of Liberalism: How Globalization Caused the First World War
    • Spring
    • idem, "The Tragedy of Liberalism: How Globalization Caused the First World War," Security Studies 14 (Spring 2005);
    • (2005) Security Studies , vol.14
    • Rowe, D.M.1
  • 11
    • 35948979683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theories of War in an Era of Leading Power Peace
    • March
    • and Robert Jervis, "Theories of War in an Era of Leading Power Peace," American Political Science Review 96 (March 2002).
    • (2002) American Political Science Review , vol.96
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 12
    • 84898349582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edward D. Mansfield and Brian M. Pollins write, Instead, large-N studies have focused almost exclusively on the past half century and have largely ignored whether and how the effects of inter-dependence have changed over time; Mansfield and Pollins, Interdependence and Conflict: An Introduction, in Mansfield and Pollins, eds., Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: New Perspectives on an Enduring Debate (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2003), 8.
    • Edward D. Mansfield and Brian M. Pollins write, "Instead, large-N studies have focused almost exclusively on the past half century and have largely ignored whether and how the effects of inter-dependence have changed over time"; Mansfield and Pollins, "Interdependence and Conflict: An Introduction," in Mansfield and Pollins, eds., Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: New Perspectives on an Enduring Debate (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2003), 8.
  • 13
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In separate studies Oneal and Russett, Russett and Oneal, and Barbieri examine samples between 1870 and 1939. However, all three studies aggregate data before and after World War I into a single sample. John R. Oneal and Bruce Russett, The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1885-1992, World Politics 52 (October 1999);
    • In separate studies Oneal and Russett, Russett and Oneal, and Barbieri examine samples between 1870 and 1939. However, all three studies aggregate data before and after World War I into a single sample. John R. Oneal and Bruce Russett, "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1885-1992," World Politics 52 (October 1999);
  • 16
    • 85036975276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • O'Rourke and Williamson (fn. 1).
    • O'Rourke and Williamson (fn. 1).
  • 17
    • 85036968067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We define the level of free trade in an economy as inversely related to the extent of government regulation of international commerce. As aggregate tariff levels rise, the quantity of imports entering the country duty free should decline
    • We define the level of free trade in an economy as inversely related to the extent of government regulation of international commerce. As aggregate tariff levels rise, the quantity of imports entering the country duty free should decline.
  • 18
    • 8744279199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alliances, Imperfect Markets, and Major Power Trade
    • For empirical evidence supporting this claim, see, October
    • For empirical evidence supporting this claim, see Joanne Gowa and Edward D. Mansfield, "Alliances, Imperfect Markets, and Major Power Trade," International Organization 58 (October 2004);
    • (2004) International Organization , vol.58
    • Gowa, J.1    Mansfield, E.D.2
  • 19
    • 8744269750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Still Follows the Flag: The Primacy of Politics in a Simultaneous Model of Interdependence and Armed Conflict
    • November
    • and Omar M. G. Keshk, Brian M. Pollins, and Rafael Reuveny, "Trade Still Follows the Flag: The Primacy of Politics in a Simultaneous Model of Interdependence and Armed Conflict," Journal of Politics 66 (November 2004).
    • (2004) Journal of Politics , vol.66
    • Keshk, O.M.G.1    Pollins, B.M.2    Reuveny, R.3
  • 23
    • 0031291185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950-1985
    • June
    • John R. Oneal and Bruce Russett, "The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950-1985," International Studies Quarterly 41 (June 1997);
    • (1997) International Studies Quarterly , vol.41
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 24
    • 85036979229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 4);
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 4);
  • 25
    • 85036996028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Russett and Oneal (fn. 4).
    • and Russett and Oneal (fn. 4).
  • 26
    • 85036984335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For recent edited exploring the links between globalization and military conflict, see Mansfield and Pollins, eds. (fn 3);
    • For recent edited volumes exploring the links between globalization and military conflict, see Mansfield and Pollins, eds. (fn 3);
  • 27
    • 85036986920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Gerald Schneider, Katherine Barbieri, and Nils-Petter Gleditsch, eds., Glohalization and Armed Conflict (Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield, 2003).
    • and Gerald Schneider, Katherine Barbieri, and Nils-Petter Gleditsch, eds., Glohalization and Armed Conflict (Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield, 2003).
  • 28
    • 85036990491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For important criticisms of these claims, see, fn. 4
    • For important criticisms of these claims, see Barbieri (fn. 4)
    • Barbieri1
  • 30
    • 0033415640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Could Trade Affect Conflict?
    • July
    • James D. Morrow, "How Could Trade Affect Conflict?" Journal of Peace Research 36 (July 1999);
    • (1999) Journal of Peace Research , vol.36
    • Morrow, J.D.1
  • 33
    • 0035632134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict
    • Spring
    • Erik Gartzke, Quan Li, and Charles Boehmer, "Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict," International Organization 55 (Spring 2001);
    • (2001) International Organization , vol.55
    • Gartzke, E.1    Li, Q.2    Boehmer, C.3
  • 34
    • 0037284505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Information and Economic Interdependence
    • February
    • and William Reed, "Information and Economic Interdependence," Journal of Conflict Resolution 47 (February 2003).
    • (2003) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.47
    • Reed, W.1
  • 35
    • 84972159336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A critical paper examining the integration of bargaining models into the study of war is James D. Fearon, Rationalist Explanations for War, International Organization (Summer 1995).
    • A critical paper examining the integration of bargaining models into the study of war is James D. Fearon, "Rationalist Explanations for War," International Organization (Summer 1995).
  • 36
    • 85036969899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For similar critiques, see, fn
    • For similar critiques, see Rowe (fn. 2, 1999, 2005);
    • (2005) , vol.2 , pp. 1999
    • Rowe1
  • 37
    • 85036986870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Domestic Roots of Commercial Liberalism: A Sector-specific Approach
    • fn. 8
    • Gerald Schneider and Gunther G. Schulze, "The Domestic Roots of Commercial Liberalism: A Sector-specific Approach," in Schneider, Barbieri, and Gleditsch (fn. 8);
    • Schneider, Barbieri, and Gleditsch
    • Schneider, G.1    Schulze, G.G.2
  • 39
    • 85036972065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1821; London: Dent, 1973).
    • David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1821; London: Dent, 1973).
  • 41
    • 0003258615 scopus 로고
    • A Three Factor Model in Theory, Trade, and History
    • Jagdish Bhagwati, Ronald Jones, Ronald A. Mundell, and Jaroslav Vanek, eds, Amsterdam: North-Holland
    • Ronald Jones, "A Three Factor Model in Theory, Trade, and History," in Jagdish Bhagwati, Ronald Jones, Ronald A. Mundell, and Jaroslav Vanek, eds., Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1971).
    • (1971) Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth
    • Jones, R.1
  • 42
    • 0002749772 scopus 로고
    • Governments, Economic Interdependence, and International Cooperation
    • Philip E. Tetlock, Jo L. Husbands, Robert Jervis, Paul C. Stern, and Charles Tilly, eds, New York: Oxford University Press
    • Arthur A. Stein, "Governments, Economic Interdependence, and International Cooperation," in Philip E. Tetlock, Jo L. Husbands, Robert Jervis, Paul C. Stern, and Charles Tilly, eds., Behavior, Society, and Nuclear War, vol. 3 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993);
    • (1993) Behavior, Society, and Nuclear War , vol.3
    • Stein, A.A.1
  • 45
    • 0033430837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Globalization and Peace: Assessing New Directions in the Study of Trade and Conflict
    • July
    • Katherine Barbieri and Gerald Schneider, "Globalization and Peace: Assessing New Directions in the Study of Trade and Conflict," Journal of Peace Research 36 (July 1999);
    • (1999) Journal of Peace Research , vol.36
    • Barbieri, K.1    Schneider, G.2
  • 46
    • 85036991239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mansfield and Pollins in Mansfield and Pollins, eds. (fn. 3);
    • Mansfield and Pollins in Mansfield and Pollins, eds. (fn. 3);
  • 50
    • 85036958795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rowe (fn. 2 1999,2005);
    • Rowe (fn. 2 1999,2005);
  • 52
    • 85036967148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Schneider and Schulze (fn. 11).
    • and Schneider and Schulze (fn. 11).
  • 53
    • 85036960543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See for example Fearon (fn. 10);
    • See for example Fearon (fn. 10);
  • 56
    • 85037005132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fearon fn. 10
    • Fearon (fn. 10).
  • 57
    • 0009275049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Liberal Theory of International Politics
    • Autumn
    • Andrew Moravscik, "A Liberal Theory of International Politics," International Organization 51 (Autumn 1997), 544.
    • (1997) International Organization , vol.51 , pp. 544
    • Moravscik, A.1
  • 58
    • 0041339206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a brief overview of the many gains from trade including economics of scale, expanded consumer choice, more competitive prices in domestic markets, and real income growth, see, Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • For a brief overview of the many gains from trade including economics of scale, expanded consumer choice, more competitive prices in domestic markets, and real income growth, see Douglas Irwin, Free Trade under Fire (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2002), 29-39.
    • (2002) Free Trade under Fire , pp. 29-39
    • Irwin, D.1
  • 59
    • 0027739432 scopus 로고
    • Testing the Imports-As-Market-Discipline Hypothesis
    • August
    • James Levinsohn, "Testing the Imports-As-Market-Discipline Hypothesis," Journal of International Economics 35 (August 1993).
    • (1993) Journal of International Economics , vol.35
    • Levinsohn, J.1
  • 60
    • 85036970323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Different predictions about the distributional effects of globalization between the Heckscher-Ohlin and Specific Factors model of trade derive largely from the different assumptions about the costs of moving a factor from one sector to another. The Heckscher-Ohlin model assumes zero costs and has been used to predict that societal cleavages created by globalization depend on class. Owners of abundant factors favor globalization, while owners of scarce factors oppose it. However, the specific factors model becomes more appropriate as these costs become positive. Under these circumstances, societal cleavages are more likely to be based on industry differences. For an example of class-based analysis, see Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989
    • Different predictions about the distributional effects of globalization between the Heckscher-Ohlin and Specific Factors model of trade derive largely from the different assumptions about the costs of moving a factor from one sector to another. The Heckscher-Ohlin model assumes zero costs and has been used to predict that societal cleavages created by globalization depend on class. Owners of abundant factors favor globalization, while owners of scarce factors oppose it. However, the specific factors model becomes more appropriate as these costs become positive. Under these circumstances, societal cleavages are more likely to be based on industry differences. For an example of class-based analysis, see Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989).
  • 61
    • 0036734003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a test of these distinctions between class and industry, see Michael Hiscox, Commerce, Coalitions, and Factor Mobility: Evidence from Congressional Votes on Trade Legislation, American Political Science Review 96 (September 2002). We will not explore these distinctions any further here. Rather we wish to exploit the simple insight that globalization produces societal conflict and not all domestic groups will necessarily support the further integration of national markets into the global economy. Our analysis is similar to that of Solingen (fn. 15) who focuses on the domestic struggle between internationalist and statist-nationalist-confessional coalitions.
    • For a test of these distinctions between class and industry, see Michael Hiscox, "Commerce, Coalitions, and Factor Mobility: Evidence from Congressional Votes on Trade Legislation," American Political Science Review 96 (September 2002). We will not explore these distinctions any further here. Rather we wish to exploit the simple insight that globalization produces societal conflict and not all domestic groups will necessarily support the further integration of national markets into the global economy. Our analysis is similar to that of Solingen (fn. 15) who focuses on the domestic struggle between internationalist and statist-nationalist-confessional coalitions.
  • 62
    • 85036982915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Again, this depends on the assumptions made about the costs of moving across industries. As costs approach zero, owners of abundant factors employed in the exporting industry will see income rise. As the costs of redeployment increase, the income of factors specific to the exporting industry will rise
    • Again, this depends on the assumptions made about the costs of moving across industries. As costs approach zero, owners of abundant factors employed in the exporting industry will see income rise. As the costs of redeployment increase, the income of factors specific to the exporting industry will rise.
  • 63
    • 85036985177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We distinguish between export-oriented firms and firms that are competitive in international markets without state assistance for the following reason: Firms or industries may orient their sales to international markets but rely on state assistance to be competitive there. For reasons discussed elsewhere in this article, such firms have been captured by the state and are less likely to support restrained national interests and peace. Prussian landowners prior to World War I are an example of this dynamic. This group relied on subsidies to export grain to western Russia and supported an aggressive stance against Russia during the press war in the six months prior to July 1914
    • We distinguish between export-oriented firms and firms that are competitive in international markets without state assistance for the following reason: Firms or industries may orient their sales to international markets but rely on state assistance to be competitive there. For reasons discussed elsewhere in this article, such firms have been captured by the state and are less likely to support restrained national interests and peace. Prussian landowners prior to World War I are an example of this dynamic. This group relied on subsidies to export grain to western Russia and supported an aggressive stance against Russia during the press war in the six months prior to July 1914.
  • 65
    • 85036993808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Solingen (fn. 15);
    • Solingen (fn. 15);
  • 68
    • 85036993313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trubowitz fn. 24, 68-75
    • Trubowitz (fn. 24), 68-75.
  • 69
    • 85037000717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Walter LaFeber, The New Empire: An Interpretation of American Expansion 1860-1898 (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1998), 275. Wheat interests lobbied President Cleveland for a peaceful resolution with Great Britain over the Venezuelan boundary dispute in 1895.
    • Walter LaFeber, The New Empire: An Interpretation of American Expansion 1860-1898 (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1998), 275. Wheat interests lobbied President Cleveland for a peaceful resolution with Great Britain over the Venezuelan boundary dispute in 1895.
  • 70
    • 85036970735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephen Rock, Why Peace Breaks Out: Great Power Rapprochement in Historical Perspective (Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press, 1989), 44-45.
    • Stephen Rock, Why Peace Breaks Out: Great Power Rapprochement in Historical Perspective (Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press, 1989), 44-45.
  • 72
    • 85037001461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lenin (fn. 2);
    • Lenin (fn. 2);
  • 73
    • 85036997637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Joseph Schumpeter, The Sociology of Imperialisms, in Paul M. Sweezy, ed., and Heinz Norden, trans., Imperialism and Social Classes (1919: New York: Augustus M. Kelley, Inc., 1951).
    • and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Sociology of Imperialisms," in Paul M. Sweezy, ed., and Heinz Norden, trans., Imperialism and Social Classes (1919: New York: Augustus M. Kelley, Inc., 1951).
  • 74
    • 85036990755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LaFeber fn. 27
    • LaFeber (fn. 27).
  • 80
    • 85036998259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following section draws on the arguments of Fischer and Berghahn. Fritz Fischer, War of Illusions: German Policies from 1911 to 1914, trans. Marian Jackson (New York: Norton, 1975);
    • The following section draws on the arguments of Fischer and Berghahn. Fritz Fischer, War of Illusions: German Policies from 1911 to 1914, trans. Marian Jackson (New York: Norton, 1975);
  • 82
    • 85036976528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good discussion of the relative breakdown of economic and political interests within Germany and England during this period, see chap. 17 in Paul Kennedy, The Rise of the Anglo-German Antagonism, 1860-1914 London: The Ashfield Press, 1980
    • For a good discussion of the relative breakdown of economic and political interests within Germany and England during this period, see chap. 17 in Paul Kennedy, The Rise of the Anglo-German Antagonism, 1860-1914 (London: The Ashfield Press, 1980).
  • 83
    • 85036964789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kennedy (fn. 36);
    • Kennedy (fn. 36);
  • 85
    • 0007760331 scopus 로고
    • Russia and the Coming of War
    • R. J. W. Evans and Hartmut Pogge von Strandmann, eds, Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • D. W. Spring, "Russia and the Coming of War," in R. J. W. Evans and Hartmut Pogge von Strandmann, eds., The Coming of the First World War (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1988).
    • (1988) The Coming of the First World War
    • Spring, D.W.1
  • 86
    • 85036994594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See for example Fearon (fn. 10);
    • See for example Fearon (fn. 10);
  • 88
    • 85036989101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While it is true that governments, by and large, relied heavily on tariffs for revenue during the nineteenth century, debate over public finance and the distribution of taxation generated struggles and domestic cleavages similar to those surrounding globalization. The political choice to rely on tariffs for revenue disproportionately placed the burden of public finance on the segments of society (namely the left) that spent large portions of their income on consumption, i.e, food. Thus the constituents lobbying for free trade saw the removal of tariffs as a device for making the burden of public finance more democratic. Not only would the elimination of tariffs reduce the costs of consumer goods and thus increase the political lefts real income, it would also force the state to replace this lost revenue via property and income taxes, the burdens of which would fall on wealthier segments of the electorate. For discussions of these domestic dynamics and their implications for foreign
    • While it is true that governments, by and large, relied heavily on tariffs for revenue during the nineteenth century, debate over public finance and the distribution of taxation generated struggles and domestic cleavages similar to those surrounding globalization. The political choice to rely on tariffs for revenue disproportionately placed the burden of public finance on the segments of society (namely the left) that spent large portions of their income on consumption, i.e., food. Thus the constituents lobbying for free trade saw the removal of tariffs as a device for making the burden of public finance more democratic. Not only would the elimination of tariffs reduce the costs of consumer goods (and thus increase the political lefts real income), it would also force the state to replace this lost revenue via property and income taxes, the burdens of which would fall on wealthier segments of the electorate. For discussions of these domestic dynamics and their implications for foreign policy, see Bruce Kent, The Spoils of War: The Politics, Economics, and Diplomacy of Reparations, 1919-1932 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989);
  • 91
    • 85036972471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a study that tests these arguments during the second, or post-World War II era of globalization, see, fn. 11
    • For a study that tests these arguments during the second, or post-World War II era of globalization, see McDonald (fn. 11).
    • McDonald1
  • 93
    • 2442678992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade?
    • For a recent debate exploring the role of the GATT and the WTO in promoting trade, see, March
    • For a recent debate exploring the role of the GATT and the WTO in promoting trade, see Andrew K. Rose, "Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade?" American Economic Review 94 (March 2004);
    • (2004) American Economic Review , vol.94
    • Rose, A.K.1
  • 94
    • 27144480931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Working Paper, no. 10024 Cambridge, Mass, National Bureau for Economic Research
    • and Arvind Subramanian and Shang-Jin Wei, "The WTO Promotes Trade, Strongly but Unevenly," Working Paper, no. 10024 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau for Economic Research, 2003).
    • (2003) The WTO Promotes Trade, Strongly but Unevenly
    • Subramanian, A.1    Wei, S.2
  • 95
    • 85036984385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul Bairoch, European Trade Policy, 1815-1914, Susan Burke, trans., in Peter Mathias and Sidney Pollard, eds., The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 8 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989). Referring to the differences between these two periods, O'Rourke and Williamson (fn. 1), 29, write, all (source italics) of the commodity market integration in the Atlantic economy after the 1860s was due to the fall in transport costs between markets, and none was due to a more liberal trade policy, In contrast, most of the commodity market integration after the 1950s was (we suspect) due to more liberal trade policy.
    • Paul Bairoch, "European Trade Policy, 1815-1914," Susan Burke, trans., in Peter Mathias and Sidney Pollard, eds., The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol. 8 (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1989). Referring to the differences between these two periods, O'Rourke and Williamson (fn. 1), 29, write, "all (source italics) of the commodity market integration in the Atlantic economy after the 1860s was due to the fall in transport costs between markets, and none was due to a more liberal trade policy, In contrast, most of the commodity market integration after the 1950s was (we suspect) due to more liberal trade policy."
  • 96
    • 85036972971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bairoch fn. 44, 57
    • Bairoch (fn. 44), 57.
  • 98
    • 4344700218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The MID 3 Data Set, 1993-2001: Procedures, Coding Rules, and Description
    • Faten Ghosn, Glenn Palmer, and Stuart Bremer, "The MID 3 Data Set, 1993-2001: Procedures, Coding Rules, and Description," Conflict Management and Peace Science 21 (2004).
    • (2004) Conflict Management and Peace Science , vol.21
    • Ghosn, F.1    Palmer, G.2    Bremer, S.3
  • 100
    • 0030327035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel M. Jones, Stuart A. Bremer, and J. David Singer, Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816-1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns, Conflict Management and Peace Science 15 (1996).
    • Daniel M. Jones, Stuart A. Bremer, and J. David Singer, "Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816-1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns," Conflict Management and Peace Science 15 (1996).
  • 101
    • 0038831393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Research Design and Estimator Choices in the Analysis of Interstate Dyads: When Decisions Matter
    • October
    • D. Scott Bennett and Allan C. Stam, "Research Design and Estimator Choices in the Analysis of Interstate Dyads: When Decisions Matter," Journal of Conflict Resolution 44 (October 2000), 658.
    • (2000) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.44 , pp. 658
    • Scott Bennett, D.1    Stam, A.C.2
  • 102
    • 85037000194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a description of the MID data set, Jones, Bremer, and Singer fn. 47, 178, write, We, based our indicator of what constitutes a revisionist state on the prevailing status quo ante prior to the onset of any militarized action and recorded as revisionist the state or states that sought to overturn the status quo ante. This explicit coding criterion raises our confidence that the definition of national interests occurs prior to the onset of a dispute. Consequently, this variable is particularly appropriate to our theoretical framework that focuses on the first stage of a war-generating process in which a domestic struggle over the costs and benefits of globalization shapes the definition of national interests over which states are willing to employ military force to defend
    • In a description of the MID data set, Jones, Bremer, and Singer (fn. 47), 178, write, "We...based our indicator of what constitutes a revisionist state on the prevailing status quo ante prior to the onset of any militarized action and recorded as revisionist the state or states that sought to overturn the status quo ante." This explicit coding criterion raises our confidence that the definition of national interests occurs prior to the onset of a dispute. Consequently, this variable is particularly appropriate to our theoretical framework that focuses on the first stage of a war-generating process in which a domestic struggle over the costs and benefits of globalization shapes the definition of national interests over which states are willing to employ military force to defend.
  • 104
    • 85036988833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The eight deleted colonies from the Williamson data set are: Australia, Burma, Canada, Ceylon, India, Indonesia, New Zealand, and the Philippines
    • The eight deleted colonies from the Williamson data set are: Australia, Burma, Canada, Ceylon, India, Indonesia, New Zealand, and the Philippines.
  • 105
    • 85036978924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitchell's data allowed us to add Belgium, Bulgaria, the Netherlands, Romania, and Switzerland to the sample. These cases account for 168 cases in the baseline model sample of 1,293. Additionally, data from both Williamson and Mitchell is available for 519 of these 1,293 cases. The bivariate correlation between these two data sources is 0.9851. Brian Mitchell, International Historical Statistics (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, various years).
    • Mitchell's data allowed us to add Belgium, Bulgaria, the Netherlands, Romania, and Switzerland to the sample. These cases account for 168 cases in the baseline model sample of 1,293. Additionally, data from both Williamson and Mitchell is available for 519 of these 1,293 cases. The bivariate correlation between these two data sources is 0.9851. Brian Mitchell, International Historical Statistics (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, various years).
  • 106
    • 85036999071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While annual counts ranged between thirty-three and forty-four states in the international system during this period, there were on average thirty-nine. The following thirty-two states are included in our sample: Argentina, Austria-Hungary, Belgium, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Cuba, Denmark, Egypt, France, Germany, Great Britain, Greece, Italy, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, Peru, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Serbia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Thailand, Turkey, the United States, and Uruguay
    • While annual counts ranged between thirty-three and forty-four states in the international system during this period, there were on average thirty-nine. The following thirty-two states are included in our sample: Argentina, Austria-Hungary, Belgium, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China, Colombia, Cuba, Denmark, Egypt, France, Germany, Great Britain, Greece, Italy, Japan, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, Peru, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Serbia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Thailand, Turkey, the United States, and Uruguay.
  • 107
    • 85036973996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We utilize version 2 of the Polity IV, which converts regime scores previously classified as interregnum or transition to the twenty-one-point scale. For a discussion of these coding rules, see http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity /convert.htm;
    • We utilize version 2 of the Polity IV, which converts regime scores previously classified as "interregnum" or "transition" to the twenty-one-point scale. For a discussion of these coding rules, see http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity /convert.htm;
  • 109
    • 33846018188 scopus 로고
    • Libertarianism and International Violence
    • March
    • R. J. Rummel, "Libertarianism and International Violence," Journal of Conflict Resolution 27 (March 1983);
    • (1983) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.27
    • Rummel, R.J.1
  • 110
    • 85036970133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Lee Ray, Democracy and International Conflict: An Evaluation of the Democratic Peace Proposition (Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina Press, 1995);
    • James Lee Ray, Democracy and International Conflict: An Evaluation of the Democratic Peace Proposition (Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina Press, 1995);
  • 111
    • 0030369526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democracies Really Are More Pacific (in General)
    • December
    • Kenneth Benoit, "Democracies Really Are More Pacific (in General)," Journal of Conflict Resolution 40 (December 1996);
    • (1996) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.40
    • Benoit, K.1
  • 112
    • 33744991313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Liberal Peace Revisited: The Role of Democracy, Dependence, and Development in Militarized Interstate Dispute Initiation, 1950-1999
    • April-June
    • and Mark Souva and Brandon Prins, "The Liberal Peace Revisited: The Role of Democracy, Dependence, and Development in Militarized Interstate Dispute Initiation, 1950-1999," International Interactions 32 (April-June 2006).
    • (2006) International Interactions , vol.32
    • Souva, M.1    Prins, B.2
  • 113
    • 0001792116 scopus 로고
    • Capability Distribution, Uncertainty, and Major Power War
    • Bruce Russett, ed, Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1972
    • J. David Singer, Stuart Bremer, and John Stuckey, "Capability Distribution, Uncertainty, and Major Power War, 1820-1965," in Bruce Russett, ed., Peace, War, and Numbers (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1972).
    • (1820) Peace, War, and Numbers
    • David Singer, J.1    Bremer, S.2    Stuckey, J.3
  • 116
    • 85036992028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While we do not include these coefficient estimates in our tables for reasons of space, this technique includes one counter and three cubic splines in each of the models. Nathaniel Beck, Jonathan N. Katz, and Richard Tucker, Taking Time Seriously in Binary Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis, American Journal of Political Science 42 October 1998, To counter within-panel heteroskedasticity we employ Huber-White standard errors, which are reported in parentheses below the parameter estimates
    • While we do not include these coefficient estimates in our tables for reasons of space, this technique includes one counter and three cubic splines in each of the models. Nathaniel Beck, Jonathan N. Katz, and Richard Tucker, "Taking Time Seriously in Binary Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis," American Journal of Political Science 42 (October 1998). To counter within-panel heteroskedasticity we employ Huber-White standard errors, which are reported in parentheses below the parameter estimates.
  • 120
    • 0035532335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Back to Kant: Reinterpreting the Democratic Peace as a Macrohistorical Learning Process
    • March
    • Lars-Erik Cederman, "Back to Kant: Reinterpreting the Democratic Peace as a Macrohistorical Learning Process," American Political Science Review 95 (March 2001), 22-23.
    • (2001) American Political Science Review , vol.95 , pp. 22-23
    • Cederman, L.1
  • 121
    • 85036978487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • fn. 4, 114
    • Russett and Oneal (fn. 4), 114.
    • Russett1    Oneal2
  • 122
    • 85036996800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 4), 24. In a series of regressions where the sample was restricted to the observations in a given year, our tests show a positive coefficient on democracy until 1905. In the years 1906 to 1914, the coefficient is negative in 1906, 1907, 1912, and 1914.
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 4), 24. In a series of regressions where the sample was restricted to the observations in a given year, our tests show a positive coefficient on democracy until 1905. In the years 1906 to 1914, the coefficient is negative in 1906, 1907, 1912, and 1914.
  • 123
    • 85036986997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These suggestions about the foreign-policy implications of limited political participation in nineteenth-century democracies are consistent with the arguments of the selectorate model found in Bueno de Mesquita et al, fn. 34, They argue that the proportion of society responsible for selecting political leaders is the crucial component of democracy that shapes decisions for war and peace. The need to cultivate political support from a majority of the population leads democratic officials to be concerned about public-policy failures. They avoid entering war when the probability of victory is low. However, when entering war, they devote more resources to the effort to ensure victory than do autocratic regimes. Peace thus emerges from democratic hesitation to wage war against powerful adversaries and the unwillingness of many states to attack democracies because of the latter's tendency to contribute more resources to victory
    • These suggestions about the foreign-policy implications of limited political participation in nineteenth-century democracies are consistent with the arguments of the selectorate model found in Bueno de Mesquita et al. (fn. 34). They argue that the proportion of society responsible for selecting political leaders is the crucial component of democracy that shapes decisions for war and peace. The need to cultivate political support from a majority of the population leads democratic officials to be concerned about public-policy failures. They avoid entering war when the probability of victory is low. However, when entering war, they devote more resources to the effort to ensure victory than do autocratic regimes. Peace thus emerges from democratic hesitation to wage war against powerful adversaries and the unwillingness of many states to attack democracies because of the latter's tendency to contribute more resources to victory.
  • 124
    • 0034409890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The median value for Protect is 0.105. Its 90th percentile value is 0.313. In these simulations we hold all other variables constant at their medians. Gary King, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg, Making the Most of Statistical Analysis: Improving Interpretation and Presentation, American Journal of Political Science 44 (April 2000).
    • The median value for Protect is 0.105. Its 90th percentile value is 0.313. In these simulations we hold all other variables constant at their medians. Gary King, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg, "Making the Most of Statistical Analysis: Improving Interpretation and Presentation," American Journal of Political Science 44 (April 2000).
  • 125
    • 85036958862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The numbers in parentheses immediately below the shift in the likelihood of conflict are a 95 percent confidence interval on that substantive result
    • The numbers in parentheses immediately below the shift in the likelihood of conflict are a 95 percent confidence interval on that substantive result.
  • 126
    • 85036975547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In these 939 cases, the bivariate correlation between openness and protection is -0.155. We relied on three sources to construct this openness indicator. First, we used Oneal and Russett's (fn. 4) bilateral-trade to GDP ratios that measure interdependence between two states in a dyad. This trade series begins in 1885. To construct a monadic openness measure, we totaled up these bilateral openness measures for all potential trading partners for each state in the international system. For example, imagine there were four states in the international system in 1890: the United States, France, Great Britain, and Spain. Then imagine that the bilateral trade ratios between the United States and these three trading partners were 0.05, 0.03, and 0.02. We would create a total openness score for the United States in 1890 by totaling these three scores and getting a value of 0.10. This strategy created fairly good data coverage for the period from 1885 to 1914
    • In these 939 cases, the bivariate correlation between openness and protection is -0.155. We relied on three sources to construct this openness indicator. First, we used Oneal and Russett's (fn. 4) bilateral-trade to GDP ratios that measure interdependence between two states in a dyad. This trade series begins in 1885. To construct a monadic openness measure, we totaled up these bilateral openness measures for all potential trading partners for each state in the international system. For example, imagine there were four states in the international system in 1890: the United States, France, Great Britain, and Spain. Then imagine that the bilateral trade ratios between the United States and these three trading partners were 0.05, 0.03, and 0.02. We would create a total openness score for the United States in 1890 by totaling these three scores and getting a value of 0.10. This strategy created fairly good data coverage for the period from 1885 to 1914.
  • 127
    • 85036965653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second, we relied on Mitchell (fn. 53) to add pre-1885 data for nine countries to the analysis: Brazil, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Spain, Sweden, Great Britain, and the United States. While Mitchell has strong data coverage on imports and exports for most countries during the pre-1885 period, national income data that matches in terms of currency and price indexing (current prices) is available only for the above nine countries. Third, we relied on Maddison for GDP indices that were matched with trade data from Mitchell to construct openness indicators for the following states in the pre-1885 period: Argentina, Austria-Hungary, Belgium, Chile, Japan, the Netherlands, and Spain. Angus Maddison, Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992 Paris: Development Center for Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1995
    • Second, we relied on Mitchell (fn. 53) to add pre-1885 data for nine countries to the analysis: Brazil, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Spain, Sweden, Great Britain, and the United States. While Mitchell has strong data coverage on imports and exports for most countries during the pre-1885 period, national income data that matches in terms of currency and price indexing (current prices) is available only for the above nine countries. Third, we relied on Maddison for GDP indices that were matched with trade data from Mitchell to construct openness indicators for the following states in the pre-1885 period: Argentina, Austria-Hungary, Belgium, Chile, Japan, the Netherlands, and Spain. Angus Maddison, Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992 (Paris: Development Center for Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1995).
  • 129
    • 85036988807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Maddala fn. 60
    • and Maddala (fn. 60).
  • 130
    • 85036974604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This estimation technique is called two-stage probit least squares (2SPLS, 2SPLS estimates the coefficients very similarly to two-stage least squares. All of the right-hand variables are used to estimate predicted values of both conflict and protection levels. These predicted values are then utilized as the instrumental variables in the final estimations of the respective regressions that use MILCONFLICT and Protect as the dependent variables. We estimated the 2SPLS model using the STATA command cdsimeq. The program was written by Keshk Omar M. G. Keshk, CDSIMEQ; A Program to Implement Two-Stage Probit Least Squares, The STATA Journal 3 2003
    • This estimation technique is called two-stage probit least squares (2SPLS). 2SPLS estimates the coefficients very similarly to two-stage least squares. All of the right-hand variables are used to estimate predicted values of both conflict and protection levels. These predicted values are then utilized as the instrumental variables in the final estimations of the respective regressions that use MILCONFLICT and Protect as the dependent variables. We estimated the 2SPLS model using the STATA command "cdsimeq." The program was written by Keshk Omar M. G. Keshk, "CDSIMEQ; A Program to Implement Two-Stage Probit Least Squares," The STATA Journal 3 (2003).
  • 131
    • 85036983531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mansfield, Milner, and Rosendorff (fn. 46) find that democratic regimes trade more with each other. These findings point to the inclusion of a control for regime type in the protection equation, with the expectation that democracies have lower tariffs.
    • Mansfield, Milner, and Rosendorff (fn. 46) find that democratic regimes trade more with each other. These findings point to the inclusion of a control for regime type in the protection equation, with the expectation that democracies have lower tariffs.
  • 132
    • 85036996780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because large economies have large internal markets that reduce integration with the global economy, we also control for economic size with a variable measuring a country's population and expect it to be positively correlated with protection levels. Together the lagged protect variable and the population variable satisfy the exclusion restriction for this two-stage approach. The population variable carries the extra virtue of offering an operationalization of economic size that is not correlated with our key dependent variable of interest, military conflict. In bivariate regressions with conflict as the dependent variable (not shown, the coefficient on population was not significant. For a study that examines the relationship between economic openness and economic size (as measured by population, see Alberto Alesina and Enrico Spolaore, The Size of Nations Cambridge, Mass, MIT Press, 2003
    • Because large economies have large internal markets that reduce integration with the global economy, we also control for economic size with a variable measuring a country's population and expect it to be positively correlated with protection levels. Together the lagged protect variable and the population variable satisfy the exclusion restriction for this two-stage approach. The population variable carries the extra virtue of offering an operationalization of economic size that is not correlated with our key dependent variable of interest - military conflict. In bivariate regressions with conflict as the dependent variable (not shown), the coefficient on population was not significant. For a study that examines the relationship between economic openness and economic size (as measured by population), see Alberto Alesina and Enrico Spolaore, The Size of Nations (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2003).
  • 133
    • 85036980654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Much of the identification of the protection effect comes from the lagged Protect variable. Because Protect is highly autocorrelated, endogeneity bias may not be completely purged from the analysis. Future research could usefully identify other exogenous variation in trade protection
    • Much of the identification of the protection effect comes from the lagged Protect variable. Because Protect is highly autocorrelated, endogeneity bias may not be completely purged from the analysis. Future research could usefully identify other exogenous variation in trade protection.
  • 134
    • 85036961720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While not described in any more detail, we also checked whether an assumption of unit homogeneity across countries was valid for our sample by incorporating fixed and random effects models. Hausman tests on both of these models revealed that the probit specification without country-specific coefficients or country-specific error terms was appropriate
    • While not described in any more detail, we also checked whether an assumption of unit homogeneity across countries was valid for our sample by incorporating fixed and random effects models. Hausman tests on both of these models revealed that the probit specification without country-specific coefficients or country-specific error terms was appropriate.
  • 137
    • 85036963415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These regressions suppress a regional dummy for North America and thus make it the reference category for the other regional variables
    • These regressions suppress a regional dummy for North America and thus make it the reference category for the other regional variables.
  • 138
    • 85036960086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We obtained similar results in the single equation framework. The coefficient on Protect was still positive and significant
    • We obtained similar results in the single equation framework. The coefficient on Protect was still positive and significant.
  • 139
    • 85036986041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A single equation framework using probit produced the same primary conclusions
    • A single equation framework using probit produced the same primary conclusions.
  • 140
    • 85036982243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mansfield fn. 8
    • Mansfield (fn. 8).
  • 141
    • 85036972307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The purpose of this section is not to identify a new explanation for the origins of World War I. Given this conffict's status as perhaps the most heavily studied war ever, a huge of research identifying multiple causes for war suggests that the conflict was in many ways overdetermined. In part, the multicausal nature of this single event underscores the importance of assessing the links between free trade and peace over this entire fifty-year period of globalization with techniques, like statistical analysis, suitable to examining a large number of cases. At the same time, the centrality of this single case to realist critiques of commercial liberalism creates a need to examine it within the context of the theoretical framework presented here.
    • The purpose of this section is not to identify a new explanation for the origins of World War I. Given this conffict's status as perhaps the most heavily studied war ever, a huge volume of research identifying multiple causes for war suggests that the conflict was in many ways overdetermined. In part, the multicausal nature of this single event underscores the importance of assessing the links between free trade and peace over this entire fifty-year period of globalization with techniques, like statistical analysis, suitable to examining a large number of cases. At the same time, the centrality of this single case to realist critiques of commercial liberalism creates a need to examine it within the context of the theoretical framework presented here.
  • 142
    • 85036986939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Russett and Oneal (fn. 4).
    • Russett and Oneal (fn. 4).
  • 143
    • 85036964216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.;
  • 145
    • 85036989504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Writing about the transition in Russian foreign policy as the Three Emperors' League expired and Russia moved closer to France in the late 1880's, Geyer notes, Protectionism was clearly the Achilles' heel of the Russo-German Entente .... There was an inevitability in the mounting economic antagonism because neither Germany nor Russia could renounce protectionism. Dietrich Geyer, Russian Imperialism: The Interaction of Domestic and Foreign Policy, 1860-1914, trans. Bruce Little (Leamington Spa, U.K.: Berg, 1997), 152.
    • Writing about the transition in Russian foreign policy as the Three Emperors' League expired and Russia moved closer to France in the late 1880's, Geyer notes, "Protectionism was clearly the Achilles' heel of the Russo-German Entente .... There was an inevitability in the mounting economic antagonism because neither Germany nor Russia could renounce protectionism." Dietrich Geyer, Russian Imperialism: The Interaction of Domestic and Foreign Policy, 1860-1914, trans. Bruce Little (Leamington Spa, U.K.: Berg, 1997), 152.
  • 146
    • 85036982921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good summary of this press war and its implications for great power diplomacy, see, fn. 35, 370-88
    • For a good summary of this press war and its implications for great power diplomacy, see Fischer (fn. 35), 370-88.
    • Fischer1
  • 149
    • 85036972294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David McLaren McDonald, United Government and Foreign Policy in Russia 1900-1914 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992).
    • David McLaren McDonald, United Government and Foreign Policy in Russia 1900-1914 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992).
  • 153
    • 85036980712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spring fn. 38, 68
    • Spring (fn. 38), 68.
  • 154
    • 85036985712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischer fn. 35, 367
    • Fischer (fn. 35), 367.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.