메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 20, Issue 4, 1996, Pages 5-40

Economic interdependence and war a theory of trade expectations

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 21344459739     PISSN: 01622889     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/2539041     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (302)

References (140)
  • 1
    • 84880654215 scopus 로고
    • Back to the Future: Instability in Europe after the Cold War
    • Summer
    • For a summary of the causal variables in the two schools, see John J. Mearsheimer, "Back to the Future: Instability in Europe After the Cold War/' International Security, Vol. 15, No. 1 (Summer 1990), pp. 5-56;
    • (1990) International Security , vol.15 , Issue.1 , pp. 5-56
    • Mearsheimer, J.J.1
  • 2
    • 0003209793 scopus 로고
    • International Liberalism Reconsidered
    • John Dünn, ed., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Robert O. Keohane, "International Liberalism Reconsidered," in John Dünn, ed., Tlte Economic Limits to Modem Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 165-194.
    • (1990) Tlte Economic Limits to Modem Politics , pp. 165-194
    • Keohane, R.O.1
  • 3
    • 33750954456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Four other subsidiary liberal arguments, employing intervening variables, are not sufficiently compelling to discuss here. The first suggests that high trade levels promote domestic prosperity, thereby lessening the internal problems that push leaders into war. The second argues that interdependence helps to foster increased understanding between peoples, which reduces the misunderstandings that lead to war. The third asserts that trade alters the domestic structure of states, heightening the influence of groups with a vested interest in peaceful trade. The final argument contends that trade has the "spill-over" effect of increasing political ties between trading partners, thus improving the prospects for long-term cooperation. For an critical analysis of these views, see Dale Copeland, "Economic Interdependence and the Outbreak of War," paper presented to University of Virginia Department of Government's faculty workshop, March 1995.
  • 5
    • 33750937658 scopus 로고
    • New York: G.P. Putnam's Sons
    • Norman Angell, Tlie Great Illusion, 2d ed. (New York: G.P. Putnam's Sons, 1933), pp. 33, 59-60, 87-89.
    • (1933) Tlie Great Illusion, 2d Ed. , pp. 33
    • Angell, N.1
  • 8
    • 84896555269 scopus 로고
    • War, Trade and Interdependence
    • James N. Rosenau and Hylke Tromp, eds., Aldershot, U.K.: Avebury
    • see also Rosecrance, "War, Trade and Interdependence," in James N. Rosenau and Hylke Tromp, eds., Interdependence and Conflict in World Politics (Aldershot, U.K.: Avebury, 1989), pp. 48-57;
    • (1989) Interdependence and Conflict in World Politics , pp. 48-57
  • 9
    • 84923759502 scopus 로고
    • A New Concert of Powers
    • Spring
    • Rosecrance, "A New Concert of Powers," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 71, No. 2 (Spring 1992), pp. 64-82.
    • (1992) Foreign Affairs , vol.71 , Issue.2 , pp. 64-82
  • 10
    • 0004264908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boston: Little, Brown, 1977-actually contains no such causal argument. For Keohane and Nye, "complex interdependence" is more peaceful by definition: it is "a valuable concept for analyzing the political process" only when military force is "unthinkable"
    • A book often seen as a statement on the peace-inducing effects of interdependence-Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye, Power and Interdependence (Boston: Little, Brown, 1977)-actually contains no such causal argument. For Keohane and Nye, "complex interdependence" is more peaceful by definition: it is "a valuable concept for analyzing the political process" only when military force is "unthinkable" (pp. 29, 24).
    • Power and Interdependence , pp. 29
    • Keohane, R.O.1    Nye, J.S.2
  • 11
    • 33750956505 scopus 로고
    • Glenview, 111.: Scott, Foresman
    • In the second edition: "since we define complex interdependence in terms of [policy] goals and instruments," arguments "about how goals and instruments are affected by the degree to which a situation approximates complex interdependence or realism will be tautological." Thus, "we are left essentially with two dependent variables: changes in agendas and changes in the roles of international organizations." Keohane and Nye, PoiL'er and Interdependence, 2d ed. (Glenview, 111.: Scott, Foresman, 1989), p. 255;
    • (1989) PoiL'er and Interdependence, 2d Ed. , pp. 255
  • 12
    • 33750932281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • emphasis in original. The dependent variable of this article-the likelihood of war-is nowhere to be found, which is not surprising, since it is assumed away. Other works on interdependence from the 1970s, which largely examined dependent variables other than war, are discussed in Copeland, "Economic Interdependence and the Outbreak of War."
  • 13
    • 0003684530 scopus 로고
    • Powell, Snidal, and Keohane in David A. Baldwin, ed., New York: Columbia University Press
    • One might contend that realists doubt the causal importance of economic interdependence, since relative gains concerns convince great powers to avoid becoming dependent in the first place. Aside from arguments showing why states may cooperate despite concerns for relative gains (see essays by Powell, Snidal, and Keohane in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate [New York: Columbia University Press, 1993];
    • (1993) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: the Contemporary Debate
  • 14
    • 33750937048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Dale Copeland, "Why Relative Gams Concerns May Promote Economic Cooperation: A Realist Explanation for Great Power Interdependence," presented at the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, San Diego, April 1996), the argument is empirically false. Periods of high interdependence have arisen even when the security competition between great powers was particularly intense, such as from 1880 to 1914, as Waltz acknowledges. Kenneth Waltz, "The Myth of Interdependence," in Ray Maghoori and Bennett Ramberg, Globalism versus Realism (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1982), p. 83. Since the reality of high interdependence cannot be argued or assumed away, I focus here on the core realist claim that whenever high levels of interdependence are reached, for whatever reason, war is more likely.
  • 16
    • 0002786364 scopus 로고
    • Disorder Restored
    • Graham Allison and Gregory F. Treverton, eds., New York: W.W. Norton
    • John J. Mearsheimer, "Disorder Restored," in Graham Allison and Gregory F. Treverton, eds., Rethinking America's Security (New York: W.W. Norton, 1992), p. 223;
    • (1992) Rethinking America's Security , pp. 223
    • Mearsheimer, J.J.1
  • 18
    • 0038946242 scopus 로고
    • Economic Interdependence and National Security in Historical Perspective
    • Klaus Knorr and Frank N. Trager, eds., Lawrence, Kan.: Alien
    • See also Robert Gilpin, "Economic Interdependence and National Security in Historical Perspective," in Klaus Knorr and Frank N. Trager, eds., Economic Issues and National Security (Lawrence, Kan.: Alien, 1977), p. 29.
    • (1977) Economic Issues and National Security , pp. 29
    • Gilpin, R.1
  • 19
    • 5944248200 scopus 로고
    • Interdepend-ence and Instability
    • Jack Snyder and Robert Jervis, eds., Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press
    • Adopting the realist argument, but emphasizing how dependence leads states to adopt destabilizing offensive strategies, is Anne Uchitel, "Interdepend-ence and Instability," in Jack Snyder and Robert Jervis, eds., Coping with Complexity in the International System (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1993), pp. 243-264.
    • (1993) Coping with Complexity in the International System , pp. 243-264
  • 20
    • 84974173391 scopus 로고
    • Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal Case
    • Autumn esp.
    • For Barry Buzan, since liberal free-trading systems are dependent on a Hegemon which invariably declines, such systems are destined to fall into "malevolent" mercantilist practices, as states scramble to control access to goods formerly safeguarded by the hegemon. Avoiding the liberal system altogether, through a "benign" mercantilist system of self-sufficient trading blocs, will be therefore preferred. Buzan, "Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal Case," International Organization, Vol. 38, No. 4 (Autumn 1984), esp. pp. 597, 609-623.
    • (1984) International Organization , vol.38 , Issue.4 , pp. 597
  • 22
    • 33750945040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • trans. Mendel Shapiro (London: George Alien, 1931)
    • See Eli F. Heckscher, Mercantilism, vol. 2, trans. Mendel Shapiro (London: George Alien, 1931), p. 15;
    • Mercantilism , vol.2 , pp. 15
    • Heckscher, E.F.1
  • 23
    • 84971169641 scopus 로고
    • Power Versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries
    • October
    • Jacob Vmer, "Power Versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries," World Politics, Vol. 1, No. 1 (October 1948), p. 10;
    • (1948) World Politics , vol.1 , Issue.1 , pp. 10
    • Vmer, J.1
  • 24
    • 0004193947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, chap. 5.
    • David A. Baldwin, Economic Statecraft (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1985), chap. 5.
    • (1985) Economic Statecraft
    • Baldwin, D.A.1
  • 25
    • 33750966394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heckscher, Mercantilism, vol. 2, p. 40.
    • Mercantilism , vol.2 , pp. 40
  • 26
    • 33750937307 scopus 로고
    • World Politics and the International Economic System
    • C. Fred Bergsten, ed.
    • See Keohane and Nye, "World Politics and the International Economic System," in C. Fred Bergsten, ed., Tlie Future of the International Economic Order (Lexington: D.C. Heath, 1973), pp. 121122;
    • (1973) Tlie Future of the International Economic Order Lexington: D.C. Heath , pp. 121122
  • 27
    • 84912837779 scopus 로고
    • Trade Dependence and Foreign Policy Compliance
    • June
    • Neil R. Richardson and Charles W. Kegley, "Trade Dependence and Foreign Policy Compliance," International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 24, No. 2 (June 1980), pp. 191-222.
    • (1980) International Studies Quarterly , vol.24 , Issue.2 , pp. 191-222
    • Richardson, N.R.1    Kegley, C.W.2
  • 28
    • 84972277757 scopus 로고
    • Interdependence and Power: A Conceptual Analysis
    • Autumn
    • David A. Baldwin, "Interdependence and Power: A Conceptual Analysis," International Organization, Vol. 34, No. 4 (Autumn 1980), pp. 478, 482-484, 489;
    • (1980) International Organization , vol.34 , Issue.4 , pp. 478
    • Baldwin, D.A.1
  • 29
    • 0002344527 scopus 로고
    • The Power of Positive Sanctions
    • October
    • Baldwin, "The Power of Positive Sanctions," World Politics, Vol. 24, No. 1 (October 1971), pp. 19-38;
    • (1971) World Politics , vol.24 , Issue.1 , pp. 19-38
  • 32
    • 33750938595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Costs of adjusting" as an integral part of "vulnerability" interdependence
    • Keohane and Nye examine the "costs of adjusting" as an integral part of "vulnerability" interdependence (Power and Interdependence, p. 13).
    • Power and Interdependence , pp. 13
  • 33
    • 0004262417 scopus 로고
    • New York: McGraw Hill
    • Yet they do not establish the original autarchic position as a baseline for examining these costs independently from the benefits of trade forgone; this baseline is incorporated later in building the new theory. Liberals also consider "costs" in terms of losses in "autonomy" due to trade ties; see Richard N. Cooper, The Economics of Interdependence (New York: McGraw Hill, 1968), pp. 4-12;
    • (1968) The Economics of Interdependence , pp. 4-12
    • Cooper, R.N.1
  • 35
    • 0010083467 scopus 로고
    • International Interdependence and Integration
    • Fred I. Greenstein and Nelson W. Polsby, eds., Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley
    • Note, however, that these are costs that go hand in hand with high trade, not costs that are experienced if trade is cut off. Hence, these losses in autonomy are more accurately considered as a form of sensitivity interdependencecosts incurred when trade is ongoing-rather than as a form of "vulnerability" interdependence so worrying to realists. On this, see Keohane and Nye, "International Interdependence and Integration," hi Fred I. Greenstein and Nelson W. Polsby, eds., Handbook of Political Science, vol. 8 (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1975), pp. 368-370.
    • (1975) Handbook of Political Science , vol.8 , pp. 368-370
  • 37
    • 33750958431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the appendix, an iterated prisoner's dilemma is used to show the "concrete benefits" from trade cooperation. If states decide not to cooperate, they simply "[do] not benefit"; pp. 233-236.
    • In the appendix, an iterated prisoner's dilemma is used to show the "concrete benefits" from trade cooperation. If states decide not to cooperate, they simply "[do] not benefit"; pp. 233-236.
  • 38
    • 33750946693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rosecrance occasionally seems to accept that some goods are more vital than others, but even here he reiterates the liberal argument: "Countries dependent on the world economy for markets, assistance, and critical raw materials are doubly hesitant to embark on military adventures"; ibid., p. 133, emphasis added. -j '
  • 39
    • 33750962099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Plato's Phaedrus in Pliaedrus and Letters VII and VIII, trans. Walter Hamilton (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1973), sections 246-256. The historical roots of this view are explicated in Albert O. Hirschman, The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977). He quotes Montesquieu (ibid., p. 73): "It is fortunate for men to be in a situation in which, though their passions may prompt them to be wicked, they have nevertheless an interest in not being so."
  • 40
    • 33749634230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (see also p. 111). Rosecrance does point out that Germany and Japan apparently went to war also to gain raw materials (ibid., p. 108). He does not argue, however, that these two states were more dependent than other states for such materials; to have done so would suggest the validity of the realist logic.
    • Rosecrance, Rise of the Trading State, pp. 102-103 (see also p. 111). Rosecrance does point out that Germany and Japan apparently went to war also to gain raw materials (ibid., p. 108). He does not argue, however, that these two states were more dependent than other states for such materials; to have done so would suggest the validity of the realist logic.
    • Rise of the Trading State , pp. 102-103
  • 41
    • 33750948720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ibid., pp. 106, 123,150, 162.
    • See ibid., pp. 106, 123,150, 162.
  • 42
    • 33750957416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ibid., pp. 18-19, 88, 96-97, 99,150.
    • See ibid., pp. 18-19, 88, 96-97, 99,150.
  • 43
    • 33750957396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., p. 141 (see also p. 150). The argument here borders on being non-falsifiable: disconfirming cases where war occurs despite high interdependence can be sidestepped by saying simply that states did not "accept" being peaceful traders. Note as well that if states have already decided to be peaceful, then interdependence is not needed as a restraint.
    • Ibid., p. 141 (see also p. 150). The argument here borders on being non-falsifiable: disconfirming cases where war occurs despite high interdependence can be sidestepped by saying simply that states did not "accept" being peaceful traders. Note as well that if states have already decided to be peaceful, then interdependence is not needed as a restraint.
  • 44
    • 0004335489 scopus 로고
    • Liberalism and International Relations Theory
    • Center for International Affairs, Harvard University
    • On liberalism's inherently unit-level orientation to conflict, see Andrew Moravcsik, "Liberalism and International Relations Theory," Working Paper, Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, 1992;
    • (1992) Working Paper
    • Moravcsik, A.1
  • 45
    • 0003832294 scopus 로고
    • New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press, On the democratic peace argument
    • Michael Howard, War and the Liberal Conscience (New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press, 1978). On the democratic peace argument,
    • (1978) War and the Liberal Conscience
    • Howard, M.1
  • 48
    • 33750953721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: McGraw-Hill, 1990, chaps. 1, 12, and 18.
    • On the differences between comparative statics and dynamic analyses that incorporate the future, see Eugene Silberberg, Tlie Structure of Economics, 2d ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1990), chaps. 1, 12, and 18.
    • Tlie Structure of Economics, 2d Ed.
    • Silberberg, E.1
  • 49
    • 84959610525 scopus 로고
    • Political Consequences of Military Strategy: Expanding and Refining the Spiral and Deterrence Models
    • July
    • That is, war is rational if it has either a higher net positive value or a lower net negative value. The theory thus works regardless of whether states are innately "greedy"-seeking positive gains from war-or simply security-seekers desiring to minimize long-term threats. See Charles L. Glaser, "Political Consequences of Military Strategy: Expanding and Refining the Spiral and Deterrence Models," World Politics, Vol. 44, No. 4 (July 1992), pp. 497-538.
    • (1992) World Politics , vol.44 , Issue.4 , pp. 497-538
    • Glaser, C.L.1
  • 50
    • 28344440878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neorealism and the Myth of Bipolar Stability: Toward a New Dynamic Realist Theory of Major War
    • Spring
    • By connecting the trading environment to fears about relative decline, I draw upon the notion that declining states launch preventive wars to uphold their waning security. Elsewhere, I build a solely power-driven theory showing why states faced with deep and inevitable decline initiate major wars. Dale Copeland, "Neorealism and the Myth of Bipolar Stability: Toward a New Dynamic Realist Theory of Major War," Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996).
    • (1996) Security Studies , vol.5 , Issue.3
  • 52
    • 33750932090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I thank Andrew Moravcsik for discussions on the potential benefits of trade.
    • I thank Andrew Moravcsik for discussions on the potential benefits of trade.
  • 53
    • 33750949501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The capital investments represent "sunk costs" not easily recouped. See Arad, Hirsch, and Tovias, The Economics of Peacemaking, pp. 26-28.
    • The Economics of Peacemaking , pp. 26-28
  • 56
    • 33750932478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is worth remembering that alternative suppliers and markets are only valuable in reducing A's dependence if A can get access to them. If B is able not only to sever bilateral trade, but also to blockade A to prevent third-party trading, then A effectively has no alternatives and is therefore dependent. This was the situation for Japan vis-à-vis the United States before 1941 regarding oil imports. 31.
  • 57
    • 33750940499 scopus 로고
    • Modelling Economic Interdependence and War: A Theory of Trade Expectations
    • Chicago, September
    • This Une of reasoning is developed formally in Dale Copeland, "Modelling Economic Interdependence and War: A Theory of Trade Expectations," paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, September 1995.
    • (1995) Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association
  • 58
    • 33750930972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "probability of transaction" as a determinant of expected national income in Arad, Hirsch, and Tovias
    • although they do not employ expectations of future trade as a theoretical variable affecting the likelihood of war.
    • It is consistent with consideration of the "probability of transaction" as a determinant of expected national income in Arad, Hirsch, and Tovias, The Economic of Peacemaking, pp. 37-43, although they do not employ expectations of future trade as a theoretical variable affecting the likelihood of war.
    • The Economic of Peacemaking , pp. 37-43
  • 63
    • 0004319381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • trans. Rex Warner (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1954), Book 1, lines 80-88.
    • Thucydides, The Peloponnesian War, trans. Rex Warner (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1954), Book 1, lines 80-88.
    • The Peloponnesian War
  • 64
    • 33750959524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • When one state is very large and the other very small, it is harder to sort out the effects of interdependence from the effects of relative power, at least hi actual cases of war. The expected value of war for the superior state is likely to be quite positive anyway, and thus will tend to overshadow the expected value of trade even when the state has positive expectations of future trade. Here, the superior state simply chooses war as the "greater of two goods." This choice would not be altered by any diminution of trade expectations; indeed, war would simply be even more rational as the expected value of trade (and therefore peace) falls. War in such a situation of marked power imbalance and low expectations of future trade is thus overdetermined; it would be difficult to tell whether war occurred because of the positive expected value of war, the negative expected value of trade, or both. Thus, in my empirical analysis, I examine cases where great powers attacked great powers in long and costly total wars. While these cases do not cover the universe of wars, they do isolate the role of economic interdependence and changing expectations of future trade in the outbreak of war.
  • 65
    • 0004193947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 6
    • Given space constraints, my case studies in this article do not provide a full analysis of the bargaining dynamic. For an analysis of interstate economic bargaining, see Baldwin, Economic Statecraft, chap. 6;
    • Economic Statecraft
    • Baldwin1
  • 66
    • 84972168015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Interdependence, Bargaining Power, and Political Influence
    • Summer 1988
    • R. Harrison Wagner, "Economic Interdependence, Bargaining Power, and Political Influence," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988), pp. 461183.
    • International Organization , vol.42 , Issue.3 , pp. 461183
    • Harrison Wagner, R.1
  • 67
    • 33750936506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note also that there may be a causal feedback loop, whereby increasing fears of war lead others to reduce trade, which in turn heightens the incentive of dependent states to initiate war. These and other issues involving the endogeneity of trade expectations are addressed more fully in my book manuscript, "Economic Interdependence and War."
  • 68
    • 33750959508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that state A, the decision-making unit in the theory, can still be treated as a rational unitary actor responding to the observed domestic forces on the other side.
    • Note that state A, the decision-making unit in the theory, can still be treated as a rational unitary actor responding to the observed domestic forces on the other side.
  • 70
    • 33750931516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • International trade institutions such as the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), by lowering transaction costs and facilitating the punishment of cheaters, may be an additional means to build positive expectations for future trade. Indeed, for some liberals, peace may only be likely when both interdependence and effective global institutions co-exist and reinforce one another; Keohane, "International Liberalism Reconsidered," p. 183. While such institutions may indeed affect trade expectations, they are unlikely to be as significant in history as the systemic and domestic factors just discussed, for the simple reason that these institutions are a creation of the post-World War II era. Moreover, since concerns for war and peace revolve mostly around the great powers, and powers like Soviet Union and China have been historically excluded from trade institutions like GATT, such institutions cannot account for fluctuations in the levels of tension between the United States and these powers since 1945. Finally, the institutional approach overlooks bilateral diplomacy as the principal mechanism through which expectations of trade change; consider the United States and Japan up to December 1941, or the United States and Japan today. Accordingly, while my argument recognizes the contribution institutions can make to the improvement of future trade expectations, the focus both theoretically and empirically remains fundamentally non-institutional.
  • 71
    • 0004205937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One might also argue that domestic and individual level factors within a state can distort expectations, but I simply assume that such misperceptions are minimal for purposes of building a deductive theory; this assumption can be later relaxed if so desired.
    • Trade expectations theory, like realism, is a systemic theory; it assumes no unit-level drives towards aggression. While expectations may seem like a unit-level factor, remember that these are expectations of an external phenomenon, namely, the other's propensity to trade into the future; the causal source of behavior comes from outside, not from within, the actor. See Waltz, Theory of International Politics, p. 60. One might also argue that domestic and individual level factors within a state can distort expectations, but I simply assume that such misperceptions are minimal for purposes of building a deductive theory; this assumption can be later relaxed if so desired.
    • Theory of International Politics , pp. 60
    • Waltz1
  • 72
    • 33750955361 scopus 로고
    • Nobutaka Ike, Irans, and ed., Stanford: Stanford University Press
    • Given space limitations, my "best case" among the major wars of this century, Japan and World War II, is covered elsewhere; Copeland, "Modelling Economic Interdependence and War." I show that Japanese leaders-military, civilian, and the emperor himself-reluctantly moved towards a consensus for war with the United States and Britain due to progressively more devastating U.S.-British trade sanctions. Japan, due to its small size, was almost completely dependent on outside sources for the raw materials and oil that supported its industrial structure. As American and British trade restrictions began to increase after 1930, and especially after a series of embargoes starting in 1939, Japan shifted from a primary concern with the Soviet threat to the need for control of raw materials in South East Asia. After the U.S., British, and Dutch severed all oil trade to Japan in July-August 1941, Japanese leaders agreed that unless oil imports were restored, economic decline would imperil long-term security. Hence, following the failure of desperate diplomatic initiatives in November 1941 to secure renewed trade, the plan for all-out war was accepted by the emperor. In short, Japan's extreme dependence, coupled with very negative expectations for future trade, pushed the country into a war that almost all recognized would have great costs and a low probability of success. See Nobutaka Ike, Irans, and ed., Japan's Decision for War: Records of the 1941 Policy Conferences (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1967).
    • (1967) Japan's Decision for War: Records of the 1941 Policy Conferences
  • 73
    • 33750950044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See note 37, above. To minimize the selection bias of focusing just on the wars themselves, I also look at the periods before the wars began, to see how incentives for aggression changed as independent variables did.
  • 74
    • 84924700157 scopus 로고
    • Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: Some Cross-national Evidence
    • March
    • Empirical analyses so far have been primarily correlational studies, finding that high trade tends to be associated with lower conflict. Mark J. Gasiorowski, "Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: Some Cross-national Evidence," International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 30, No. 1 (March 1986), pp. 22-38;
    • (1986) International Studies Quarterly , vol.30 , Issue.1 , pp. 22-38
    • Gasiorowski, M.J.1
  • 75
    • 84965573387 scopus 로고
    • Conflict and Interdependence: East-West Trade and Linkages in the Era of Detente
    • December
    • Mark J. Gasiorowski and Solomon W. Polachek, "Conflict and Interdependence: East-West Trade and Linkages in the Era of Detente," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 26, No. 4 (December 1982), pp. 709-729;
    • (1982) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.26 , Issue.4 , pp. 709-729
    • Gasiorowski, M.J.1    Polachek, S.W.2
  • 76
    • 84970205822 scopus 로고
    • Conflict and Trade
    • March
    • Polachek, "Conflict and Trade," Journal of Conflict Research, Vol. 24, No. 1 (March 1980), pp. 55-78;
    • (1980) Journal of Conflict Research , vol.24 , Issue.1 , pp. 55-78
  • 78
    • 0003844532 scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton University Press, chap 4.
    • Edward D. Mansfield, Power, Trade, and War (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994), chap 4.
    • (1994) Power, Trade, and War
    • Mansfield, E.D.1
  • 79
    • 84972091498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State Power and the Structure of International Trade
    • April 1976
    • These studies, however, provide no documentary evidence that leaders considered trade levels in deciding between war and peace. It is thus hard to know whether the correlation is spurious or illuminating. While the result seems to support liberalism over realism, it is also consistent with trade expectations theory: high trade should be associated with lower conflict in those instances where expectations for future trade are also positive. Given their suspect methodologies, one should also be cautious about quickly dismissing realism. The correlation of trade with less conflict in the first three studies is not surprising, since dyads of small states are included to build the sample. Such states tend to have very high trade/GNP ratios. See Stephen D. Krasner, "State Power and the Structure of International Trade," World Politics, Vol. 28, No. 3 (April 1976),-p. 328. However, they are deterred from war by their very size. Note as well that all of these tests simply assume that the trade/GNP ratio alone is an adequate measure of the core concept, dependence. Given the concern of realism and trade expectations theory for the costs of severed trade, a proper test must also include such factors as dependence on others for vital goods and availability of alternative sources of supply.
    • World Politics , vol.28 , Issue.3 , pp. 328
    • Krasner, S.D.1
  • 81
    • 33750934263 scopus 로고
    • trans. E.T.S. Dugsdale New York: Harper and Brothers
    • Quoted from German Diplomatic Documents, 1871-1914, vol. II, trans. E.T.S. Dugsdale (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1930), pp. 486-487.
    • (1930) Quoted from German Diplomatic Documents, 1871-1914 , vol.2 , pp. 486-487
  • 84
    • 0003897649 scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • It was at this time that German leaders implemented the concepts of Weltpolitik and Mitteleuropa as responses to growing foreign protectionism. Weltpolitik sought "the attainment of secure external supplies of raw materials at regulated prices," while Mitteleuropa, its continental counterpart, envisioned the development of "an organized and protected system of economic exchanges between an industrial Germany and an agricultural periphery in central and eastern Europe." See Woodruff D. Smith, The Ideological Origins of Nazi Imperialism (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), pp. 65, 78.
    • (1986) The Ideological Origins of Nazi Imperialism , pp. 65
    • Smith, W.D.1
  • 91
  • 92
    • 33750930973 scopus 로고
    • Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press
    • see also Hans W. Gatzke, Germany's Drive to the West (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1950), pp. 30-38.
    • (1950) Germany's Drive to the West , pp. 30-38
    • Gatzke, H.W.1
  • 93
    • 33750939538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also pp. 322-326.
    • Quoted in Fischer, War of Illusion, p. 326; see also pp. 322-326.
    • War of Illusion , pp. 326
  • 94
    • 33750943575 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Oxford University Press, chaps. 15-21; pp. 325-326, 335. By 1906, Germany was importing about 20 per cent of its annual grain consumption (p. 230).
    • Avner Offer, The First World War: An Agrarian Interpretation (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989), p. 322; chaps. 15-21; pp. 325-326, 335. By 1906, Germany was importing about 20 per cent of its annual grain consumption (p. 230).
    • (1989) The First World War: An Agrarian Interpretation , pp. 322
    • Offer, A.1
  • 95
    • 33750932077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While Fischer's goal is to show that domestic causes for the war were predominant, much of his evidence actually indicates that German leaders were driven by systemic concerns, namely the safeguarding of German economic security. Fischer, War of Illusions, pp. viii-ix.
  • 96
    • 33750963179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quoted in ibid., p. 35.
    • Quoted in ibid., p. 35.
  • 97
    • 33750942948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischer's words, ibid., p. 10.
    • Fischer's words, ibid., p. 10.
  • 98
    • 33750955552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quotations in ibid., pp. 234, 250-253.
    • Quotations in ibid., pp. 234, 250-253.
  • 99
    • 33750947957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quoted in ibid., pp. 238, 450.
    • Quoted in ibid., pp. 238, 450.
  • 100
    • 8344246663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1993, chaps. 3 and 4.
    • For a summary, see Dale Copeland, "Realism and the Origins of Major War" (Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1993), chaps. 3 and 4.
    • Realism and the Origins of Major War
    • Copeland, D.1
  • 102
    • 33750963578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., pp. 101 and 11. The first part of the quote is Fischer's paraphrase from the document; the words "essential objective" Fischer takes from the document itself. Bethmann was clearly impressed by the memo; he circulated it throughout the department. Ibid., p. 101.
    • Ibid., pp. 101 and 11. The first part of the quote is Fischer's paraphrase from the document; the words "essential objective" Fischer takes from the document itself. Bethmann was clearly impressed by the memo; he circulated it throughout the department. Ibid., p. 101.
  • 103
    • 0004723467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quoted in Fischer, War of Illusions, p. 533;
    • War of Illusions , pp. 533
  • 104
  • 105
    • 33750957197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischer's words summarizing the document
    • Fischer's words summarizing the document, War of Illusions, p. 538.
    • War of Illusions , pp. 538
  • 106
    • 33750962611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quoted in ibid., p. 540. _ .
    • Quoted in ibid., p. 540. _ .
  • 107
    • 33750938767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quoted in ibid., p. 539.
    • Quoted in ibid., p. 539.
  • 108
  • 110
    • 33750949849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In showing this continuity, I do not mean to minimize the atrocities committed by the Nazi regime. Rather, while Hitler's means were far more evil than Wilhelmine Germany's, many of his ends in terms of economic and territorial security were essentially the same. The most important contribution to the "continuity" argument in modern historiography is Fritz Fischer's work and the work of his followers in the "Hamburg School." See also Smith, Ideological Origins.
  • 111
    • 33750964443 scopus 로고
    • trans. Ralph Manheim Boston: Houghton Mifflin, For the pre-1914 origins of the idea of Lebensraum, see Smith, Ideological Origins, chap. 5.
    • Hitler, Mein Kampf, trans. Ralph Manheim (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1925), pp. 131-140. For the pre-1914 origins of the idea of Lebensraum, see Smith, Ideological Origins, chap. 5.
    • (1925) Mein Kampf , pp. 131-140
    • Hitler1
  • 112
    • 33750957397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Hitler's fears of the rise of Russia
    • see Hitler, chap. 24.
    • On Hitler's fears of the rise of Russia, see Hitler, Mein Kampf, chap. 24.
    • Mein Kampf
  • 113
    • 33750947423 scopus 로고
    • summary notes, Exeter, U.K.: University of Exeter
    • From J. Noakes and G. Pridham's summary notes, Nazism 1919-1945: A Documentary Reader, vols. 2 and 3 (Exeter, U.K.: University of Exeter, 1988), pp. 259-260.
    • (1988) Nazism 1919-1945: A Documentary Reader , vol.2-3 , pp. 259-260
    • Noakes, J.1    Pridhams, G.2
  • 117
    • 33750931340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Noakes and Pridham,-Nazism, 2919-1945, p. 277.
    • Noakes and Pridham,-Nazism, 2919-1945, p. 277.
  • 118
    • 33750958423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 185, pp. 283-284.
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 185, pp. 283-284.
  • 119
    • 33750934493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 185, pp. 284-286 (emphasis added).
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 185, pp. 284-286 (emphasis added).
  • 121
    • 33750930974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • raw materials from Noakes and Pridham, Nazism 1919-1945, p. 291.
    • iron ore from Mitchell, European Historical Statistics, pp.J446, 410; raw materials from Noakes and Pridham, Nazism 1919-1945, p. 291.
    • European Historical Statistics
  • 122
    • 0007130996 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press, chaps. 1, 5 and 7
    • On German efforts to reduce dependence through increased trade ties with China and Eastern Europe, and through intervention in the Spanish Civil War, see Gerhard L. Weinberg, Tlie Foreign Policy of Hitler's Germany: Starting World War II (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980), chaps. 1, 5 and 7;
    • (1980) Tlie Foreign Policy of Hitler's Germany: Starting World War II
    • Weinberg, G.L.1
  • 127
    • 33750931871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Noakes and Pridham, Nazism 1919-1945, p. 680.
    • Nazism 1919-1945 , pp. 680
  • 128
    • 33750931871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doc. No. 503
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 503, pp. 681-683.
    • Nazism 1919-1945 , pp. 681-683
  • 129
    • 33750931871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doc. No. 503
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 503, pp. 682-683.
    • Nazism 1919-1945 , pp. 682-683
  • 130
    • 33750931871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doc. No. 503
    • Ibid., Doc. No. 503, pp. 684-685.
    • Nazism 1919-1945 , pp. 684-685
  • 131
    • 0004056065 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • One might discount Hitler's language as mere talk necessary to justify his true driving force, which was his lust to dominate others; see Hans J. Morgenthau,' Scientific Man Versus Power Politics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1946).
    • (1946) Scientific Man Versus Power Politics
    • Morgenthau, H.J.1
  • 132
    • 0039782571 scopus 로고
    • Correlli Barnett, ed., New York: Quill
    • Even if this were true, however, it begs the question of why he felt his four key military leaders would need to hear an elaborate economic rationale for war. We thus return to the point that without the support of his subordinates, Hitler could not have initiated war; calculated aggression, therefore, had to have a logical end. It is also clear that the majority of Hitler's military leaders were not simply brain-washed dupes of Nazi ideology, but accepted the necessity of major war on strategic grounds. See the essays in Correlli Barnett, ed., Hitler's Generals (New York: Quill, 1989);
    • (1989) Hitler's Generals
  • 135
    • 33750931871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Doc. No. 539
    • On May 23,1939, Hitler told his top military officials that while Germany must "aim at a short war," it "must also be prepared for a war of 10-15 years' duration." Noakes and Pridham, Nazism 1919-1945, Doc. No. 539, p. 738.
    • Nazism 1919-1945 , pp. 738
  • 136
    • 84917377124 scopus 로고
    • The Rise of China
    • November/ December
    • See Nicholas D. Kristof, "The Rise of China," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 72, No. 5 (November/ December 1993), p. 64.
    • (1993) Foreign Affairs , vol.72 , Issue.5 , pp. 64
    • Kristof, N.D.1
  • 137
    • 21344457848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • East Asia and the 'Constamment' of China
    • Spring
    • China has already staked a claim to the potentially oil rich and much disputed Spratly Islands in the South China Sea. See Gerald Segal, "East Asia and The 'Constamment' of China," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 4 (Spring 1996), pp. 107-135.
    • (1996) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.4 , pp. 107-135
    • Segal, G.1
  • 139
    • 0003888739 scopus 로고
    • New York: St. Martin's Press
    • For an exaggerated but still insightful analysis of this, see George Friedman and Meredith Lebard, The Coming War with Japan (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1991).
    • (1991) The Coming War with Japan
    • Friedman, G.1    Lebard, M.2
  • 140
    • 85050786472 scopus 로고
    • Ukrainian-Russian Trade: The Economics of Dependency
    • October 29
    • See Erik Whitlock, "Ukrainian-Russian Trade: The Economics of Dependency," Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty Research Report, Vol. 2, No. 43 (October 29,1993), pp. 38-42.
    • (1993) Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty Research Report , vol.2 , Issue.43 , pp. 38-42
    • Whitlock, E.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.