메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 24, Issue 1, 1999, Pages 42-62

Realism, neoliberalism, and cooperation: Understanding the debate

(1)  Jervis, Robert a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0033413897     PISSN: 01622889     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1162/016228899560040     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (259)

References (144)
  • 1
    • 21844491800 scopus 로고
    • The false promise of international institutions
    • Winter
    • John J. Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 5-49; Robert O. Keohane and Lisa L. Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 39-51; Mearsheimer "A Realist Reply," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 82-93. See also Martin and Beth Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 729-758; and Keohane and Martin "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," paper prepared for meeting on "Progress in International Relations Theory," January 15-16, 1999, Scottsdale, Arizona, which says that "institutional theory" is a more descriptive title than "neoliberal institutionalism."
    • (1994) International Security , vol.19 , Issue.3 , pp. 5-49
    • Mearsheimer, J.J.1
  • 2
    • 84937282714 scopus 로고
    • The promise of institutional theory
    • Summer
    • John J. Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 5-49; Robert O. Keohane and Lisa L. Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 39-51; Mearsheimer "A Realist Reply," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 82-93. See also Martin and Beth Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 729-758; and Keohane and Martin "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," paper prepared for meeting on "Progress in International Relations Theory," January 15-16, 1999, Scottsdale, Arizona, which says that "institutional theory" is a more descriptive title than "neoliberal institutionalism."
    • (1995) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.1 , pp. 39-51
    • Keohane, R.O.1    Martin, L.L.2
  • 3
    • 21844481434 scopus 로고
    • A realist reply
    • Summer
    • John J. Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 5-49; Robert O. Keohane and Lisa L. Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 39-51; Mearsheimer "A Realist Reply," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 82-93. See also Martin and Beth Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 729-758; and Keohane and Martin "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," paper prepared for meeting on "Progress in International Relations Theory," January 15-16, 1999, Scottsdale, Arizona, which says that "institutional theory" is a more descriptive title than "neoliberal institutionalism."
    • (1995) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.1 , pp. 82-93
    • Mearsheimer1
  • 4
    • 85008779563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Theories and empirical studies of international institutions
    • Autumn
    • John J. Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 5-49; Robert O. Keohane and Lisa L. Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 39-51; Mearsheimer "A Realist Reply," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 82-93. See also Martin and Beth Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 729-758; and Keohane and Martin "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," paper prepared for meeting on "Progress in International Relations Theory," January 15-16, 1999, Scottsdale, Arizona, which says that "institutional theory" is a more descriptive title than "neoliberal institutionalism."
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.4 , pp. 729-758
    • Martin1    Simmons, B.2
  • 5
    • 0141971668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutional theory, endogeneity, and delegation
    • January 15-16, Scottsdale, Arizona
    • John J. Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 5-49; Robert O. Keohane and Lisa L. Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 39-51; Mearsheimer "A Realist Reply," International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1 (Summer 1995), pp. 82-93. See also Martin and Beth Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 729-758; and Keohane and Martin "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," paper prepared for meeting on "Progress in International Relations Theory," January 15-16, 1999, Scottsdale, Arizona, which says that "institutional theory" is a more descriptive title than "neoliberal institutionalism."
    • (1999) Progress in International Relations Theory
    • Keohane1    Martin2
  • 6
    • 85058004291 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1991) Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition
    • Snyder, J.L.1
  • 7
    • 84897821836 scopus 로고
    • Realism and domestic politics
    • Summer
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1992) International Security , vol.17 , Issue.1 , pp. 177-198
    • Zakaria, F.1
  • 8
    • 80052780189 scopus 로고
    • Realists as optimists: Cooperation as self-help
    • Winter
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1994) International Security , vol.19 , Issue.3 , pp. 50-90
    • Glaser, C.L.1
  • 9
    • 0003134512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neorealism's status-quo bias: What security dilemma?
    • Spring
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1996) Security Studies , vol.5 , Issue.3 , pp. 90-121
    • Schweller, R.L.1
  • 10
    • 0031524620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dueling realisms
    • Summer
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1997) International Organization , vol.51 , Issue.3 , pp. 445-478
    • Brooks, S.1
  • 11
    • 0009944670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond victory: Offensive realism and the expansion of war aims
    • Summer
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1997) Security Studies , vol.6 , Issue.4 , pp. 1-49
    • Labs, E.J.1
  • 12
    • 0039907879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sheep in sheep's clothing: Why security seekers do not fight each other
    • Autumn
    • My definition of the distinction between offensive and defensive realism can be found below, pp. 48-50. For other discussions, see Jack L. Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991); Fareed Zakaria, "Realism and Domestic Politics," International Security, Vol. 17, No. 1 (Summer 1992), pp. 177-198; Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 50-90; Randall L. Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?" Security Studies, Vol. 5, No. 3 (Spring 1996), pp. 90-121; Stephen Brooks, "Dueling Realisms," International Organization, Vol. 51, No. 3 (Summer 1997), pp. 445-478; Eric J. Labs, "Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and the Expansion of War Aims," Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1997), pp. 1-49; and Andrew Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing: Why Security Seekers Do Not Fight Each Other," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Autumn 1997), pp. 114-155. Glaser uses the term "contingent realism," which I think is more descriptive than "defensive realism," but I use the latter term because it has gained greater currency.
    • (1997) Security Studies , vol.7 , Issue.1 , pp. 114-155
    • Kydd, A.1
  • 13
    • 0033442950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is anybody still a realist?
    • Fall
    • I use this term because I do not think realism and neoliberal institutionalism can be sharply defined. Indeed, they are better labeled schools of thought or approaches than theories. Although this vagueness contributes to confusion as scholars talk past one another, a precise definition would be necessary only if either of these approaches really were a tight theory. In that case, falsification of propositions derived from the theory would cast doubt on the entire enterprise. But, for better and for worse, neither of these approaches has the sort of integrity that would permit the use of that logic. For an attempt to formulate a rigorous, but I think excessively narrow, definition of realism, see Jeffrey W. Legro and Andrew Moravcsik, "Is Anybody Still a Realist?" International Security, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Fall 1999). See also Kenneth N. Waltz, "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory," in Robert L. Rothstein, ed., The Evolution of Theory in International Relations (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1991), pp. 21-38; and the exchange between Colin Elman and Waltz in Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 1 (Autumn 1996), pp. 7-61.
    • (1999) International Security , vol.24 , Issue.2
    • Legro, J.W.1    Moravcsik, A.2
  • 14
    • 0040098489 scopus 로고
    • Realist thought and neorealist theory
    • Robert L. Rothstein, ed., Columbia: University of South Carolina Press
    • I use this term because I do not think realism and neoliberal institutionalism can be sharply defined. Indeed, they are better labeled schools of thought or approaches than theories. Although this vagueness contributes to confusion as scholars talk past one another, a precise definition would be necessary only if either of these approaches really were a tight theory. In that case, falsification of propositions derived from the theory would cast doubt on the entire enterprise. But, for better and for worse, neither of these approaches has the sort of integrity that would permit the use of that logic. For an attempt to formulate a rigorous, but I think excessively narrow, definition of realism, see Jeffrey W. Legro and Andrew Moravcsik, "Is Anybody Still a Realist?" International Security, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Fall 1999). See also Kenneth N. Waltz, "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory," in Robert L. Rothstein, ed., The Evolution of Theory in International Relations (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1991), pp. 21-38; and the exchange between Colin Elman and Waltz in Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 1 (Autumn 1996), pp. 7-61.
    • (1991) The Evolution of Theory in International Relations , pp. 21-38
    • Waltz, K.N.1
  • 15
    • 0001873679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Autumn
    • I use this term because I do not think realism and neoliberal institutionalism can be sharply defined. Indeed, they are better labeled schools of thought or approaches than theories. Although this vagueness contributes to confusion as scholars talk past one another, a precise definition would be necessary only if either of these approaches really were a tight theory. In that case, falsification of propositions derived from the theory would cast doubt on the entire enterprise. But, for better and for worse, neither of these approaches has the sort of integrity that would permit the use of that logic. For an attempt to formulate a rigorous, but I think excessively narrow, definition of realism, see Jeffrey W. Legro and Andrew Moravcsik, "Is Anybody Still a Realist?" International Security, Vol. 24, No. 2 (Fall 1999). See also Kenneth N. Waltz, "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory," in Robert L. Rothstein, ed., The Evolution of Theory in International Relations (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1991), pp. 21-38; and the exchange between Colin Elman and Waltz in Security Studies, Vol. 6, No. 1 (Autumn 1996), pp. 7-61.
    • (1996) Security Studies , vol.6 , Issue.1 , pp. 7-61
    • Elman, C.1    Waltz2
  • 16
    • 0007509476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," p. 3; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 9, 29, 67; Robert O. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1989), pp. 7-9. See also Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85; Randall L. Schweller and David Priess, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, Supplement 1 (May 1997), pp. 1-32; and Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 739-740. In the statement quoted, Keohane and Martin refer to neorealism, not realism. For the purposes of this article, I do not need to distinguish between the two, as Waltz does very well in "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory."
    • Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation , pp. 3
    • Keohane1    Martin2
  • 17
    • 84883967565 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," p. 3; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 9, 29, 67; Robert O. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1989), pp. 7-9. See also Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85; Randall L. Schweller and David Priess, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, Supplement 1 (May 1997), pp. 1-32; and Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 739-740. In the statement quoted, Keohane and Martin refer to neorealism, not realism. For the purposes of this article, I do not need to distinguish between the two, as Waltz does very well in "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory."
    • (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy , pp. 9
    • Keohane, R.O.1
  • 18
    • 0004130918 scopus 로고
    • Boulder, Colo.: Westview
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," p. 3; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 9, 29, 67; Robert O. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1989), pp. 7-9. See also Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85; Randall L. Schweller and David Priess, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, Supplement 1 (May 1997), pp. 1-32; and Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 739-740. In the statement quoted, Keohane and Martin refer to neorealism, not realism. For the purposes of this article, I do not need to distinguish between the two, as Waltz does very well in "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory."
    • (1989) International Institutions and State Power , pp. 7-9
    • Keohane, R.O.1
  • 19
    • 0039832371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," p. 3; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 9, 29, 67; Robert O. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1989), pp. 7-9. See also Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85; Randall L. Schweller and David Priess, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, Supplement 1 (May 1997), pp. 1-32; and Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 739-740. In the statement quoted, Keohane and Martin refer to neorealism, not realism. For the purposes of this article, I do not need to distinguish between the two, as Waltz does very well in "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory."
    • Realists As Optimists , pp. 85
    • Glaser1
  • 20
    • 0031400090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A tale of two realisms: Expanding the institutions debate
    • May
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," p. 3; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 9, 29, 67; Robert O. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1989), pp. 7-9. See also Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85; Randall L. Schweller and David Priess, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, Supplement 1 (May 1997), pp. 1-32; and Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 739-740. In the statement quoted, Keohane and Martin refer to neorealism, not realism. For the purposes of this article, I do not need to distinguish between the two, as Waltz does very well in "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory."
    • (1997) Mershon International Studies Review , vol.41 , Issue.1 SUPPL. , pp. 1-32
    • Schweller, R.L.1    Priess, D.2
  • 21
    • 0040691881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," p. 3; Robert O. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 9, 29, 67; Robert O. Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1989), pp. 7-9. See also Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85; Randall L. Schweller and David Priess, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review, Vol. 41, Supplement 1 (May 1997), pp. 1-32; and Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 739-740. In the statement quoted, Keohane and Martin refer to neorealism, not realism. For the purposes of this article, I do not need to distinguish between the two, as Waltz does very well in "Realist Thought and Neorealist Theory."
    • Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions , pp. 739-740
    • Martin1    Simmons2
  • 22
    • 84990935518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rationalizing politics: The emerging synthesis among international politics and American and comparative politics
    • Autumn
    • The realization that commitment is difficult within states as well has led to enormous progress in understanding domestic politics and arrangements among private actors, thus making recent analyses in American and comparative politics appear quite familiar to students of international politics. See Helen V. Milner, "Rationalizing Politics: The Emerging Synthesis among International Politics and American and Comparative Politics," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 759-786. It is often assumed that anarchy and the possibility of the use of force are the same, but this is not correct, as shown by Milner, "The Assumption of Anarchy in International Relations Theory: A Critique," Review of International Studies, Vol. 17, No. 1 (January 1991), pp. 71-74; and Robert Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate," International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 2 (Spring 1994), pp. 330-334.
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.4 , pp. 759-786
    • Milner, H.V.1
  • 23
    • 84974186329 scopus 로고
    • The assumption of anarchy in international relations theory: A critique
    • January
    • The realization that commitment is difficult within states as well has led to enormous progress in understanding domestic politics and arrangements among private actors, thus making recent analyses in American and comparative politics appear quite familiar to students of international politics. See Helen V. Milner, "Rationalizing Politics: The Emerging Synthesis among International Politics and American and Comparative Politics," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 759-786. It is often assumed that anarchy and the possibility of the use of force are the same, but this is not correct, as shown by Milner, "The Assumption of Anarchy in International Relations Theory: A Critique," Review of International Studies, Vol. 17, No. 1 (January 1991), pp. 71-74; and Robert Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate," International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 2 (Spring 1994), pp. 330-334.
    • (1991) Review of International Studies , vol.17 , Issue.1 , pp. 71-74
    • Milner1
  • 24
    • 84971881632 scopus 로고
    • Anarchy in international relations theory: The neorealist-neoliberal debate
    • Spring
    • The realization that commitment is difficult within states as well has led to enormous progress in understanding domestic politics and arrangements among private actors, thus making recent analyses in American and comparative politics appear quite familiar to students of international politics. See Helen V. Milner, "Rationalizing Politics: The Emerging Synthesis among International Politics and American and Comparative Politics," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 759-786. It is often assumed that anarchy and the possibility of the use of force are the same, but this is not correct, as shown by Milner, "The Assumption of Anarchy in International Relations Theory: A Critique," Review of International Studies, Vol. 17, No. 1 (January 1991), pp. 71-74; and Robert Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate," International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 2 (Spring 1994), pp. 330-334.
    • (1994) International Organization , vol.48 , Issue.2 , pp. 330-334
    • Powell, R.1
  • 25
    • 0039506693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The differences may be sharper in some central issues I am putting aside here: the efficacy and fungibility of various forms of power, especially military power; the differences in state behavior when force, coercion, or unilateral solutions are available; and the frequency of such situations.
  • 26
    • 0038914089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This view is hard even to conceptualize in a multipolar world. Any gain of territory or power by state A would have to come at the expense of some other state, but if it diminishes state B or state C, this might aid state D, at least in the short run, if D is the rival of B or C. Here the situation is zero-sum (or, more technically, constant sum) overall, but not all actors are hurt, and some may be advantaged, by another's gain.
  • 28
    • 84972029004 scopus 로고
    • Security regimes
    • Spring
    • The differences between the issue areas are not inherent, but it is generally believed that the factors that are conducive to cooperation, such as vulnerability, offensive advantage, and lack of transparency, are more prevalent in IPE than in the security arena. See Robert Jervis, "Security Regimes," International Organization, Vol. 36, No. 2 (Spring 1982), pp. 358-360; and Charles H. Lipson, "International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs," World Politics, Vol. 37, No. 1 (October 1984), pp. 1-23.
    • (1982) International Organization , vol.36 , Issue.2 , pp. 358-360
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 29
    • 84959626707 scopus 로고
    • International cooperation in economic and security affairs
    • October
    • The differences between the issue areas are not inherent, but it is generally believed that the factors that are conducive to cooperation, such as vulnerability, offensive advantage, and lack of transparency, are more prevalent in IPE than in the security arena. See Robert Jervis, "Security Regimes," International Organization, Vol. 36, No. 2 (Spring 1982), pp. 358-360; and Charles H. Lipson, "International Cooperation in Economic and Security Affairs," World Politics, Vol. 37, No. 1 (October 1984), pp. 1-23.
    • (1984) World Politics , vol.37 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-23
    • Lipson, C.H.1
  • 30
    • 0004224103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • Nonetheless, I think neoliberals were enlightened by Jack Knight's argument that institutions can affect not only the level of cooperation, but who gains more. See Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Similarly, while neoliberals have drawn heavily on the literature on organizations, they pay little attention to power-laden analyses such as Charles Perrow, Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d ed. (New York: Random House, 1986). Robert O. Keohane acknowledges that he initially underestimated the significance of distributive issues. See Keohane "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 446-447. See also Keohane and Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," pp. 45-46. For a good discussion of distribution and institutions, see Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 338-343. For an argument that the shape of domestic institutions affects both the chance of international agreement and the distribution of the benefits, see Helen V. Milner, Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1992) Institutions and Social Conflict
    • Knight1
  • 31
    • 0003526791 scopus 로고
    • New York: Random House
    • Nonetheless, I think neoliberals were enlightened by Jack Knight's argument that institutions can affect not only the level of cooperation, but who gains more. See Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Similarly, while neoliberals have drawn heavily on the literature on organizations, they pay little attention to power-laden analyses such as Charles Perrow, Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d ed. (New York: Random House, 1986). Robert O. Keohane acknowledges that he initially underestimated the significance of distributive issues. See Keohane "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 446-447. See also Keohane and Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," pp. 45-46. For a good discussion of distribution and institutions, see Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 338-343. For an argument that the shape of domestic institutions affects both the chance of international agreement and the distribution of the benefits, see Helen V. Milner, Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1986) Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d Ed.
    • Perrow, C.1
  • 32
    • 0001794187 scopus 로고
    • Institutional theory and the realist challenge after the cold war
    • David A. Baldwin, ed., New York: Columbia University Press
    • Nonetheless, I think neoliberals were enlightened by Jack Knight's argument that institutions can affect not only the level of cooperation, but who gains more. See Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Similarly, while neoliberals have drawn heavily on the literature on organizations, they pay little attention to power-laden analyses such as Charles Perrow, Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d ed. (New York: Random House, 1986). Robert O. Keohane acknowledges that he initially underestimated the significance of distributive issues. See Keohane "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 446-447. See also Keohane and Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," pp. 45-46. For a good discussion of distribution and institutions, see Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 338-343. For an argument that the shape of domestic institutions affects both the chance of international agreement and the distribution of the benefits, see Helen V. Milner, Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1993) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate , pp. 446-447
    • Keohane1
  • 33
    • 0039506690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nonetheless, I think neoliberals were enlightened by Jack Knight's argument that institutions can affect not only the level of cooperation, but who gains more. See Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Similarly, while neoliberals have drawn heavily on the literature on organizations, they pay little attention to power-laden analyses such as Charles Perrow, Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d ed. (New York: Random House, 1986). Robert O. Keohane acknowledges that he initially underestimated the significance of distributive issues. See Keohane "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 446-447. See also Keohane and Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," pp. 45-46. For a good discussion of distribution and institutions, see Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 338-343. For an argument that the shape of domestic institutions affects both the chance of international agreement and the distribution of the benefits, see Helen V. Milner, Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • The Promise of Institutional Theory , pp. 45-46
    • Keohane1    Martin2
  • 34
    • 0039831231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nonetheless, I think neoliberals were enlightened by Jack Knight's argument that institutions can affect not only the level of cooperation, but who gains more. See Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Similarly, while neoliberals have drawn heavily on the literature on organizations, they pay little attention to power-laden analyses such as Charles Perrow, Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d ed. (New York: Random House, 1986). Robert O. Keohane acknowledges that he initially underestimated the significance of distributive issues. See Keohane "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 446-447. See also Keohane and Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," pp. 45-46. For a good discussion of distribution and institutions, see Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 338-343. For an argument that the shape of domestic institutions affects both the chance of international agreement and the distribution of the benefits, see Helen V. Milner, Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • Anarchy in International Relations Theory , pp. 338-343
    • Powell1
  • 35
    • 0003519166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Nonetheless, I think neoliberals were enlightened by Jack Knight's argument that institutions can affect not only the level of cooperation, but who gains more. See Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Similarly, while neoliberals have drawn heavily on the literature on organizations, they pay little attention to power-laden analyses such as Charles Perrow, Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay, 3d ed. (New York: Random House, 1986). Robert O. Keohane acknowledges that he initially underestimated the significance of distributive issues. See Keohane "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David A. Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993), pp. 446-447. See also Keohane and Martin, "The Promise of Institutional Theory," pp. 45-46. For a good discussion of distribution and institutions, see Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 338-343. For an argument that the shape of domestic institutions affects both the chance of international agreement and the distribution of the benefits, see Helen V. Milner, Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1997) Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations
    • Milner, H.V.1
  • 36
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Absolute and relative gains in international relations theory
    • December
    • Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4 (December 1991), pp. 701-726; Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 334-338; Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 74-75; and Arthur A. Stein, Why Nations Cooperate (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), chap. 5. Issues of relative versus absolute gains are not the same as distribution versus efficiency because an actor can care about distribution even in the absence of concerns about relative gains. It should also be noted that although the main reason for seeking relative gains today is to improve one's absolute situation tomorrow, some goods are inherently positional. See the classic and yet underappreciated analysis of Fred Hirsch, Social Limits to Growth (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976).
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85 , Issue.4 , pp. 701-726
    • Powell, R.1
  • 37
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4 (December 1991), pp. 701-726; Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 334-338; Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 74-75; and Arthur A. Stein, Why Nations Cooperate (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), chap. 5. Issues of relative versus absolute gains are not the same as distribution versus efficiency because an actor can care about distribution even in the absence of concerns about relative gains. It should also be noted that although the main reason for seeking relative gains today is to improve one's absolute situation tomorrow, some goods are inherently positional. See the classic and yet underappreciated analysis of Fred Hirsch, Social Limits to Growth (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976).
    • Anarchy in International Relations Theory , pp. 334-338
    • Powell1
  • 38
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4 (December 1991), pp. 701-726; Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 334-338; Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 74-75; and Arthur A. Stein, Why Nations Cooperate (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), chap. 5. Issues of relative versus absolute gains are not the same as distribution versus efficiency because an actor can care about distribution even in the absence of concerns about relative gains. It should also be noted that although the main reason for seeking relative gains today is to improve one's absolute situation tomorrow, some goods are inherently positional. See the classic and yet underappreciated analysis of Fred Hirsch, Social Limits to Growth (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976).
    • Realists As Optimists , pp. 74-75
    • Glaser1
  • 39
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, chap. 5
    • Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4 (December 1991), pp. 701-726; Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 334-338; Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 74-75; and Arthur A. Stein, Why Nations Cooperate (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), chap. 5. Issues of relative versus absolute gains are not the same as distribution versus efficiency because an actor can care about distribution even in the absence of concerns about relative gains. It should also be noted that although the main reason for seeking relative gains today is to improve one's absolute situation tomorrow, some goods are inherently positional. See the classic and yet underappreciated analysis of Fred Hirsch, Social Limits to Growth (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976).
    • (1990) Why Nations Cooperate
    • Stein, A.A.1
  • 40
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
    • Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4 (December 1991), pp. 701-726; Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory," pp. 334-338; Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 74-75; and Arthur A. Stein, Why Nations Cooperate (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), chap. 5. Issues of relative versus absolute gains are not the same as distribution versus efficiency because an actor can care about distribution even in the absence of concerns about relative gains. It should also be noted that although the main reason for seeking relative gains today is to improve one's absolute situation tomorrow, some goods are inherently positional. See the classic and yet underappreciated analysis of Fred Hirsch, Social Limits to Growth (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976).
    • (1976) Social Limits to Growth
    • Hirsch, F.1
  • 41
  • 42
    • 0004012778 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, chap. 3
    • When states are allied - and expect to remain so in the future - each may gain "security externalities" from the others' economic gains. See Joanne Gowa, Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994), chap. 3. But relative economic gains can redistribute power within an alliance (as shown by Arthur A. Stein, "The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order," International Organization, Vol. 38, No. 2 [Spring 1984], pp. 355-386), and will be of concern if actors believe that they will influence future wealth. See Robert Jervis, "International Primacy: Is the Game Worth the Candle?" International Security, Vol. 17, No. 4 (Spring 1993), pp. 54-59; and John C. Matthews III, "Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter," International Security, Vol. 21, No. 1 (Summer 1996), pp. 112-146. Furthermore, despite the existence of nuclear weapons, an extreme gap in the economic health of the United States and Western Europe on the one hand, and the Soviet Union on the other, undermined the latter's security, largely by sapping its self-confidence.
    • (1994) Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade
    • Gowa, J.1
  • 43
    • 84974110696 scopus 로고
    • The Hegemon's dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the international economic order
    • Spring
    • When states are allied - and expect to remain so in the future - each may gain "security externalities" from the others' economic gains. See Joanne Gowa, Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994), chap. 3. But relative economic gains can redistribute power within an alliance (as shown by Arthur A. Stein, "The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order," International Organization, Vol. 38, No. 2 [Spring 1984], pp. 355-386), and will be of concern if actors believe that they will influence future wealth. See Robert Jervis, "International Primacy: Is the Game Worth the Candle?" International Security, Vol. 17, No. 4 (Spring 1993), pp. 54-59; and John C. Matthews III, "Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter," International Security, Vol. 21, No. 1 (Summer 1996), pp. 112-146. Furthermore, despite the existence of nuclear weapons, an extreme gap in the economic health of the United States and Western Europe on the one hand, and the Soviet Union on the other, undermined the latter's security, largely by sapping its self-confidence.
    • (1984) International Organization , vol.38 , Issue.2 , pp. 355-386
    • Stein, A.A.1
  • 44
    • 0346089398 scopus 로고
    • International primacy: Is the game worth the candle?
    • Spring
    • When states are allied - and expect to remain so in the future - each may gain "security externalities" from the others' economic gains. See Joanne Gowa, Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994), chap. 3. But relative economic gains can redistribute power within an alliance (as shown by Arthur A. Stein, "The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order," International Organization, Vol. 38, No. 2 [Spring 1984], pp. 355-386), and will be of concern if actors believe that they will influence future wealth. See Robert Jervis, "International Primacy: Is the Game Worth the Candle?" International Security, Vol. 17, No. 4 (Spring 1993), pp. 54-59; and John C. Matthews III, "Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter," International Security, Vol. 21, No. 1 (Summer 1996), pp. 112-146. Furthermore, despite the existence of nuclear weapons, an extreme gap in the economic health of the United States and Western Europe on the one hand, and the Soviet Union on the other, undermined the latter's security, largely by sapping its self-confidence.
    • (1993) International Security , vol.17 , Issue.4 , pp. 54-59
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 45
    • 0030521901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Current gains and future outcomes: When cumulative relative gains matter
    • Summer
    • When states are allied - and expect to remain so in the future - each may gain "security externalities" from the others' economic gains. See Joanne Gowa, Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994), chap. 3. But relative economic gains can redistribute power within an alliance (as shown by Arthur A. Stein, "The Hegemon's Dilemma: Great Britain, the United States, and the International Economic Order," International Organization, Vol. 38, No. 2 [Spring 1984], pp. 355-386), and will be of concern if actors believe that they will influence future wealth. See Robert Jervis, "International Primacy: Is the Game Worth the Candle?" International Security, Vol. 17, No. 4 (Spring 1993), pp. 54-59; and John C. Matthews III, "Current Gains and Future Outcomes: When Cumulative Relative Gains Matter," International Security, Vol. 21, No. 1 (Summer 1996), pp. 112-146. Furthermore, despite the existence of nuclear weapons, an extreme gap in the economic health of the United States and Western Europe on the one hand, and the Soviet Union on the other, undermined the latter's security, largely by sapping its self-confidence.
    • (1996) International Security , vol.21 , Issue.1 , pp. 112-146
    • Matthews J.C. III1
  • 46
    • 0039832371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The greatest deficiency in the relative/absolute gains literature is that it has remained largely at the level of theory and prescription, with much less attention to when decisionmakers do in fact exhibit relative-gains concerns. Thus as noteworthy as the fact that leading academics employed impeccable logic to demonstrate the irrelevance of relative advantage in a world of mutual second-strike capabilities was the fact that each side's decisionmakers remained unpersuaded, continued to fear that the other sought nuclear superiority, and sought advantage, if not superiority, for itself. For a related argument, see Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 86-88. For a good empirical study in the trade area, see Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991), pp. 73-113.
    • Realists As Optimists , pp. 86-88
    • Glaser1
  • 47
    • 84928438245 scopus 로고
    • Do relative gains matter? America's response to Japanese industrial policy
    • Summer
    • The greatest deficiency in the relative/absolute gains literature is that it has remained largely at the level of theory and prescription, with much less attention to when decisionmakers do in fact exhibit relative-gains concerns. Thus as noteworthy as the fact that leading academics employed impeccable logic to demonstrate the irrelevance of relative advantage in a world of mutual second-strike capabilities was the fact that each side's decisionmakers remained unpersuaded, continued to fear that the other sought nuclear superiority, and sought advantage, if not superiority, for itself. For a related argument, see Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 86-88. For a good empirical study in the trade area, see Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991), pp. 73-113.
    • (1991) International Security , vol.16 , Issue.1 , pp. 73-113
    • Mastanduno, M.1
  • 48
    • 0000478178 scopus 로고
    • National images and international systems
    • June
    • For a parallel discussion of "real" and "illusory" incompatibility, see Kenneth E. Boulding, "National Images and International Systems," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 3, No. 2 (June 1959), p. 130. This distinction and the one I am making are not without their difficulties, as I discuss below. The move from conflicting preferences to conflictful behavior is not entirely direct because if information is complete and outcomes are infinitely divisible, the actors should be able to find a way of reaching the outcome that is cheaper than engaging in costly conflict. This is known as the Hicks paradox in economics and was introduced into the international relations literature by James D. Fearon in "Rationalist Explanations for War," International Organization, Vol. 49, No. 3 (Summer 1995), pp. 379-414. The subject is important but not central to the issues of concern here.
    • (1959) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.3 , Issue.2 , pp. 130
    • Boulding, K.E.1
  • 49
    • 84972159336 scopus 로고
    • Rationalist explanations for war
    • Summer
    • For a parallel discussion of "real" and "illusory" incompatibility, see Kenneth E. Boulding, "National Images and International Systems," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 3, No. 2 (June 1959), p. 130. This distinction and the one I am making are not without their difficulties, as I discuss below. The move from conflicting preferences to conflictful behavior is not entirely direct because if information is complete and outcomes are infinitely divisible, the actors should be able to find a way of reaching the outcome that is cheaper than engaging in costly conflict. This is known as the Hicks paradox in economics and was introduced into the international relations literature by James D. Fearon in "Rationalist Explanations for War," International Organization, Vol. 49, No. 3 (Summer 1995), pp. 379-414. The subject is important but not central to the issues of concern here.
    • (1995) International Organization , vol.49 , Issue.3 , pp. 379-414
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 50
    • 84959578392 scopus 로고
    • Global communication and national power: Life on the pareto frontier
    • April
    • Stephen D. Krasner, "Global Communication and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991), pp. 336-366.
    • (1991) World Politics , vol.43 , Issue.3 , pp. 336-366
    • Krasner, S.D.1
  • 51
    • 0003928173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • This is not to say that all arguments that actors are below the Pareto frontier share neoliberalism's stress on the importance of institutions. Thus Deborah W. Larson's analysis of missed opportunities during the Cold War seeks to demonstrate that, at a number of points, lack of trust and related psychological impediments prevented the United States and the Soviet Union from relaxing tensions and reaching agreements that would have made both of them both better off. See Larson, Anatomy of Mistrust: U.S.-Soviet Relations during the Cold War (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1997).
    • (1997) Anatomy of Mistrust: U.S.-soviet Relations during the Cold War
    • Larson1
  • 52
    • 0040691881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For discussion, see Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 744-747; and James K. Sebenius, "Challenging Conventional Explanations of International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Winter 1992), pp. 334-339.
    • Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions , pp. 744-747
    • Martin1    Simmons2
  • 53
    • 84972344702 scopus 로고
    • Challenging conventional explanations of international cooperation
    • Winter
    • For discussion, see Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," pp. 744-747; and James K. Sebenius, "Challenging Conventional Explanations of International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Winter 1992), pp. 334-339.
    • (1992) International Organization , vol.46 , Issue.1 , pp. 334-339
    • Sebenius, J.K.1
  • 55
    • 0003795537 scopus 로고
    • Lawrence: University Press of Kansas
    • Of Gray's voluminous writings, see, for example, Colin Gray, Weapons Don't Make War: Policy, Strategy, and Military Technology (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1993); and Gray, House of Cards': Wliy Arms Control Must Fail (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992).
    • (1993) Weapons Don't Make War: Policy, Strategy, and Military Technology
    • Gray, C.1
  • 56
    • 0006757095 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • Of Gray's voluminous writings, see, for example, Colin Gray, Weapons Don't Make War: Policy, Strategy, and Military Technology (Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1993); and Gray, House of Cards': Wliy Arms Control Must Fail (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992).
    • (1992) House of Cards': Wliy Arms Control Must Fail
    • Gray1
  • 57
    • 84905629884 scopus 로고
    • Bandwagoning for profit: Bringing the revisionist state back in
    • Summer
    • Randall L. Schweller, "Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994), pp. 72-107; and Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias." See also Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing." This is why Charles Glaser sees "realists as optimists": in most circumstances, states that seek security can develop a military posture that signals their benign intentions, thereby minimizing unnecessary conflict. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 67-70.
    • (1994) International Security , vol.19 , Issue.1 , pp. 72-107
    • Schweller, R.L.1
  • 58
    • 0040098487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randall L. Schweller, "Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994), pp. 72-107; and Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias." See also Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing." This is why Charles Glaser sees "realists as optimists": in most circumstances, states that seek security can develop a military posture that signals their benign intentions, thereby minimizing unnecessary conflict. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 67-70.
    • Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias
    • Schweller1
  • 59
    • 0038914087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randall L. Schweller, "Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994), pp. 72-107; and Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias." See also Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing." This is why Charles Glaser sees "realists as optimists": in most circumstances, states that seek security can develop a military posture that signals their benign intentions, thereby minimizing unnecessary conflict. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 67-70.
    • Sheep in Sheep's Clothing
    • Kydd1
  • 60
    • 0039832371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randall L. Schweller, "Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994), pp. 72-107; and Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias." See also Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing." This is why Charles Glaser sees "realists as optimists": in most circumstances, states that seek security can develop a military posture that signals their benign intentions, thereby minimizing unnecessary conflict. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 67-70.
    • Realists As Optimists
    • Glaser, C.1
  • 61
    • 0039832371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Randall L. Schweller, "Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994), pp. 72-107; and Schweller, "Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias." See also Kydd, "Sheep in Sheep's Clothing." This is why Charles Glaser sees "realists as optimists": in most circumstances, states that seek security can develop a military posture that signals their benign intentions, thereby minimizing unnecessary conflict. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 67-70.
    • Realists As Optimists , pp. 67-70
    • Glaser1
  • 63
    • 0038914085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Embedded counterfactuals and the case for World War I as an 'unavoidable' war
    • Richard Ned Lebow, Philip E. Tetlock, and Geoffrey Parker, eds., unpublished book manuscript, Ohio State University
    • A particularly insightful use of counterfactuals to explore changes that could have avoided a major war is Paul W. Schroeder, "Embedded Counterfactuals and the Case for World War I as an 'Unavoidable' War," in Richard Ned Lebow, Philip E. Tetlock, and Geoffrey Parker, eds., "Unmaking the West: Exploring Alternative Histories of Counterfactual Worlds," unpublished book manuscript, Ohio State University. I am concerned here with short-run changes that could reduce a current conflict, not with changes such as instituting a world government, making all states democratic, or using future DNA technology to alter human nature.
    • Unmaking the West: Exploring Alternative Histories of Counterfactual Worlds
    • Schroeder, P.W.1
  • 65
    • 0003671778 scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • Thus reputation plays a central role in neoliberalism parallel to its role in deterrence theory. But what little empirical research we have casts grave doubt on the standard deductive claims for how reputations form and operate. See Ted Hopf, Peripheral Visions: Deterrence Theory and American Foreign Policy in the Third World, 1965-1990 (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994); and Jonathan Mercer, Reputation and International Politics (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1996). See also Robert Jervis, "Signaling and Perception," in Kristen Monroe, ed., "Political Psychology," unpublished book manuscript, University of California at Irvine.
    • (1994) Peripheral Visions: Deterrence Theory and American Foreign Policy in the Third World, 1965-1990
    • Hopf, T.1
  • 66
    • 0003458968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • Thus reputation plays a central role in neoliberalism parallel to its role in deterrence theory. But what little empirical research we have casts grave doubt on the standard deductive claims for how reputations form and operate. See Ted Hopf, Peripheral Visions: Deterrence Theory and American Foreign Policy in the Third World, 1965-1990 (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994); and Jonathan Mercer, Reputation and International Politics (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1996). See also Robert Jervis, "Signaling and Perception," in Kristen Monroe, ed., "Political Psychology," unpublished book manuscript, University of California at Irvine.
    • (1996) Reputation and International Politics
    • Mercer, J.1
  • 67
    • 14544285390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Signaling and perception
    • Kristen Monroe, ed., unpublished book manuscript, University of California at Irvine
    • Thus reputation plays a central role in neoliberalism parallel to its role in deterrence theory. But what little empirical research we have casts grave doubt on the standard deductive claims for how reputations form and operate. See Ted Hopf, Peripheral Visions: Deterrence Theory and American Foreign Policy in the Third World, 1965-1990 (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994); and Jonathan Mercer, Reputation and International Politics (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1996). See also Robert Jervis, "Signaling and Perception," in Kristen Monroe, ed., "Political Psychology," unpublished book manuscript, University of California at Irvine.
    • Political Psychology
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 68
    • 0004027370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane, After Hegemony. See also Celeste A. Wallander, Mortal Friends, Best Enemies: German-Russian Cooperation after the Cold War (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1998), pp. 19-34.
    • After Hegemony
    • Keohane1
  • 70
    • 0004179313 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986), which includes essays by defensive realists and neoliberals. These arguments were developed in works that formed the basis for the Oye volume: Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Robert Jervis, "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January 1978), pp. 167-214; and Keohane, After Hegemony. It is not true, however, that a long "shadow of the future" by itself increases cooperation. When an agreement is expected to last for a long time, the incentives to bargain harder are greater. See James D. Fearon, "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 2 (Spring 1998), pp. 269-305. Similarly, when what is at stake are actors' reputations for standing firm, as was true in many Cold War interactions, then issues of little intrinsic importance produce very high conflict. Much of the relative gains problem turns
    • (1986) Cooperation under Anarchy
    • Oye, K.A.1
  • 71
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986), which includes essays by defensive realists and neoliberals. These arguments were developed in works that formed the basis for the Oye volume: Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Robert Jervis, "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January 1978), pp. 167-214; and Keohane, After Hegemony. It is not true, however, that a long "shadow of the future" by itself increases cooperation. When an agreement is expected to last for a long time, the incentives to bargain harder are greater. See James D. Fearon, "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 2 (Spring 1998), pp. 269-305. Similarly, when what is at stake are actors' reputations for standing firm, as was true in many Cold War interactions, then issues of little intrinsic importance produce very high conflict. Much of the relative gains problem turns on the expectation that the outcome of the current interaction will strongly affect the actors' future well-being; states often fight at one time because they fear that otherwise they will be at a greater disadvantage in the future. Neoliberals argue that institutions can curb these effects.
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 72
    • 84974380232 scopus 로고
    • Cooperation under the security dilemma
    • January
    • Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986), which includes essays by defensive realists and neoliberals. These arguments were developed in works that formed the basis for the Oye volume: Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Robert Jervis, "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January 1978), pp. 167-214; and Keohane, After Hegemony. It is not true, however, that a long "shadow of the future" by itself increases cooperation. When an agreement is expected to last for a long time, the incentives to bargain harder are greater. See James D. Fearon, "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 2 (Spring 1998), pp. 269-305. Similarly, when what is at stake are actors' reputations for standing firm, as was true in many Cold War interactions, then issues of little intrinsic importance produce very high conflict. Much of the relative gains problem turns on the expectation that the outcome of the current interaction will strongly affect the actors' future well-being; states often fight at one time because they fear that otherwise they will be at a greater disadvantage in the future. Neoliberals argue that institutions can curb these effects.
    • (1978) World Politics , vol.30 , Issue.2 , pp. 167-214
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 73
    • 84889096526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986), which includes essays by defensive realists and neoliberals. These arguments were developed in works that formed the basis for the Oye volume: Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Robert Jervis, "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January 1978), pp. 167-214; and Keohane, After Hegemony. It is not true, however, that a long "shadow of the future" by itself increases cooperation. When an agreement is expected to last for a long time, the incentives to bargain harder are greater. See James D. Fearon, "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 2 (Spring 1998), pp. 269-305. Similarly, when what is at stake are actors' reputations for standing firm, as was true in many Cold War interactions, then issues of little intrinsic importance produce very high conflict. Much of the relative gains problem turns on the expectation that the outcome of the current interaction will strongly affect the actors' future well-being; states often fight at one time because they fear that otherwise they will be at a greater disadvantage in the future. Neoliberals argue that institutions can curb these effects.
    • After Hegemony
  • 74
    • 0032355311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining, enforcement, and international cooperation
    • Spring
    • Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986), which includes essays by defensive realists and neoliberals. These arguments were developed in works that formed the basis for the Oye volume: Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Robert Jervis, "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January 1978), pp. 167-214; and Keohane, After Hegemony. It is not true, however, that a long "shadow of the future" by itself increases cooperation. When an agreement is expected to last for a long time, the incentives to bargain harder are greater. See James D. Fearon, "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 2 (Spring 1998), pp. 269-305. Similarly, when what is at stake are actors' reputations for standing firm, as was true in many Cold War interactions, then issues of little intrinsic importance produce very high conflict. Much of the relative gains problem turns on the expectation that the outcome of the current interaction will strongly affect the actors' future well-being; states often fight at one time because they fear that otherwise they will be at a greater disadvantage in the future. Neoliberals argue that institutions can curb these effects.
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.2 , pp. 269-305
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 75
    • 0004026691 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace
    • For the importance of diagnosis, see Alexander L. George, Bridging the Gap: Theory and Practice in Foreign Policy (Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace, 1993). See also Robert Jervis, Perception and Misperception in International Politics (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1976), chap. 3. In many cases, contemporary policymakers or later analysts may not be clear as to whether they are disagreeing about the nature of the situation the state is in or the policies that are appropriate for that situation.
    • (1993) Bridging the Gap: Theory and Practice in Foreign Policy
    • George, A.L.1
  • 76
    • 0003393578 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, chap. 3
    • For the importance of diagnosis, see Alexander L. George, Bridging the Gap: Theory and Practice in Foreign Policy (Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace, 1993). See also Robert Jervis, Perception and Misperception in International Politics (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1976), chap. 3. In many cases, contemporary policymakers or later analysts may not be clear as to whether they are disagreeing about the nature of the situation the state is in or the policies that are appropriate for that situation.
    • (1976) Perception and Misperception in International Politics
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 78
    • 0004224103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Similar definitions are found in Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict, pp. 2-4; Douglass C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (New York: W.W. Norton, 1990), pp. 4-5; and Celeste A. Wallander, Helga Haftendorn, and Robert O. Keohane, "Introduction," in Haftendorn, Keohane, and Wallander, eds., Imperfect Unions: Security Institutions over Time and Space (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), pp. 1-2. Despite its roots in economics, neoliberalism's treatment of institutions pays scant attention to principal-agent problems and the ways in which institutions and their leaders can maximize their own self-interest at the expense of those of the principals.
    • Institutions and Social Conflict , pp. 2-4
    • Knight1
  • 79
    • 0003540038 scopus 로고
    • New York: W.W. Norton
    • Similar definitions are found in Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict, pp. 2-4; Douglass C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (New York: W.W. Norton, 1990), pp. 4-5; and Celeste A. Wallander, Helga Haftendorn, and Robert O. Keohane, "Introduction," in Haftendorn, Keohane, and Wallander, eds., Imperfect Unions: Security Institutions over Time and Space (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), pp. 1-2. Despite its roots in economics, neoliberalism's treatment of institutions pays scant attention to principal-agent problems and the ways in which institutions and their leaders can maximize their own self-interest at the expense of those of the principals.
    • (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance , pp. 4-5
    • North, D.C.1
  • 80
    • 0039506660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Introduction
    • Haftendorn, Keohane, and Wallander, eds., New York: Oxford University Press
    • Similar definitions are found in Knight, Institutions and Social Conflict, pp. 2-4; Douglass C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (New York: W.W. Norton, 1990), pp. 4-5; and Celeste A. Wallander, Helga Haftendorn, and Robert O. Keohane, "Introduction," in Haftendorn, Keohane, and Wallander, eds., Imperfect Unions: Security Institutions over Time and Space (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), pp. 1-2. Despite its roots in economics, neoliberalism's treatment of institutions pays scant attention to principal-agent problems and the ways in which institutions and their leaders can maximize their own self-interest at the expense of those of the principals.
    • (1999) Imperfect Unions: Security Institutions over Time and Space , pp. 1-2
    • Wallander, C.A.1    Haftendorn, H.2    Keohane, R.O.3
  • 81
    • 0007509476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," agree that the question is posed correctly, although answered incorrectly, in Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions." See also Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions." For the finding that joint membership in international organizations is negatively correlated with conflict, see Bruce M. Russett, John R. Oneal, and David R. Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 441-168. The recent literature on the role of institutions in domestic politics is very large: recent surveys are Peter A. Hall and Rosemary C.R. Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Political Studies, Vol. 44, No. 5 (April 1996), pp. 936-957; and Ira Katznelson, "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?" American Political Science Review, Vol. 92, No. 1 (March 1998), pp. 191-197.
    • Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation
    • Keohane1    Martin2
  • 82
    • 0039173716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," agree that the question is posed correctly, although answered incorrectly, in Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions." See also Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions." For the finding that joint membership in international organizations is negatively correlated with conflict, see Bruce M. Russett, John R. Oneal, and David R. Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 441-168. The recent literature on the role of institutions in domestic politics is very large: recent surveys are Peter A. Hall and Rosemary C.R. Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Political Studies, Vol. 44, No. 5 (April 1996), pp. 936-957; and Ira Katznelson, "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?" American Political Science Review, Vol. 92, No. 1 (March 1998), pp. 191-197.
    • The False Promise of International Institutions
    • Mearsheimer1
  • 83
    • 0040691881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," agree that the question is posed correctly, although answered incorrectly, in Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions." See also Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions." For the finding that joint membership in international organizations is negatively correlated with conflict, see Bruce M. Russett, John R. Oneal, and David R. Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 441-168. The recent literature on the role of institutions in domestic politics is very large: recent surveys are Peter A. Hall and Rosemary C.R. Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Political Studies, Vol. 44, No. 5 (April 1996), pp. 936-957; and Ira Katznelson, "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?" American Political Science Review, Vol. 92, No. 1 (March 1998), pp. 191-197.
    • Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions
    • Martin1    Simmons2
  • 84
    • 0040676472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The third leg of the kantian tripod for peace: International organizations and militarized disputes, 1950-1985
    • Summer
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," agree that the question is posed correctly, although answered incorrectly, in Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions." See also Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions." For the finding that joint membership in international organizations is negatively correlated with conflict, see Bruce M. Russett, John R. Oneal, and David R. Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 441-168. The recent literature on the role of institutions in domestic politics is very large: recent surveys are Peter A. Hall and Rosemary C.R. Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Political Studies, Vol. 44, No. 5 (April 1996), pp. 936-957; and Ira Katznelson, "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?" American Political Science Review, Vol. 92, No. 1 (March 1998), pp. 191-197.
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.3 , pp. 441-1168
    • Russett, B.M.1    Oneal, J.R.2    Davis, D.R.3
  • 85
    • 0009978678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political science and the three new institutionalisms
    • April
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," agree that the question is posed correctly, although answered incorrectly, in Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions." See also Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions." For the finding that joint membership in international organizations is negatively correlated with conflict, see Bruce M. Russett, John R. Oneal, and David R. Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 441-168. The recent literature on the role of institutions in domestic politics is very large: recent surveys are Peter A. Hall and Rosemary C.R. Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Political Studies, Vol. 44, No. 5 (April 1996), pp. 936-957; and Ira Katznelson, "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?" American Political Science Review, Vol. 92, No. 1 (March 1998), pp. 191-197.
    • (1996) Political Studies , vol.44 , Issue.5 , pp. 936-957
    • Hall, P.A.1    Taylor, R.C.R.2
  • 86
    • 0011349026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The doleful dance of politics and policy: Can historical institutionalism make a difference?
    • March
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation," agree that the question is posed correctly, although answered incorrectly, in Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions." See also Martin and Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions." For the finding that joint membership in international organizations is negatively correlated with conflict, see Bruce M. Russett, John R. Oneal, and David R. Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 441-168. The recent literature on the role of institutions in domestic politics is very large: recent surveys are Peter A. Hall and Rosemary C.R. Taylor, "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Political Studies, Vol. 44, No. 5 (April 1996), pp. 936-957; and Ira Katznelson, "The Doleful Dance of Politics and Policy: Can Historical Institutionalism Make a Difference?" American Political Science Review, Vol. 92, No. 1 (March 1998), pp. 191-197.
    • (1998) American Political Science Review , vol.92 , Issue.1 , pp. 191-197
    • Katznelson, I.1
  • 88
    • 0038914067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Functional theory regimes
    • chap. 6
    • Keohane and Martin, "Institutional Theory, Endogeneity, and Delegation." This is consistent with Keohane's "functional theory regimes" in After Hegemony, chap. 6.
    • After Hegemony
    • Keohane's1
  • 89
    • 0039832371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85. See also Kenneth N. Waltz, "Realism after the Cold War," paper delivered at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, Massachusetts, September 3-6, 1998, pp. 23-29.
    • Realists As Optimists , pp. 85
    • Glaser1
  • 90
    • 0039506654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Realism after the cold war
    • Boston, Massachusetts, September 3-6
    • Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," p. 85. See also Kenneth N. Waltz, "Realism after the Cold War," paper delivered at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, Massachusetts, September 3-6, 1998, pp. 23-29.
    • (1998) Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association , pp. 23-29
    • Waltz, K.N.1
  • 91
    • 0038417804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Government, Harvard University
    • Page V. Fortna, "A Peace That Lasts," Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Government, Harvard University, 1998. See also Caroline A. Hartzell, "Explaining the Stability of Negotiated Settlements to Intrastate Wars," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 43, No. 1 (February 1999), pp. 3-22; and Barbara F. Walter, "Designing Transitions from Civil War: Demobilization, Democratization, and Commitments to Peace," International Security, Vol. 24, No. 1 (Summer 1999), pp. 127-155.
    • (1998) A Peace That Lasts
    • Fortna, P.V.1
  • 92
    • 22444454840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining the stability of negotiated settlements to intrastate wars
    • February
    • Page V. Fortna, "A Peace That Lasts," Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Government, Harvard University, 1998. See also Caroline A. Hartzell, "Explaining the Stability of Negotiated Settlements to Intrastate Wars," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 43, No. 1 (February 1999), pp. 3-22; and Barbara F. Walter, "Designing Transitions from Civil War: Demobilization, Democratization, and Commitments to Peace," International Security, Vol. 24, No. 1 (Summer 1999), pp. 127-155.
    • (1999) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.43 , Issue.1 , pp. 3-22
    • Hartzell, C.A.1
  • 93
    • 0033459172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing transitions from civil war: Demobilization, democratization, and commitments to peace
    • Summer
    • Page V. Fortna, "A Peace That Lasts," Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Government, Harvard University, 1998. See also Caroline A. Hartzell, "Explaining the Stability of Negotiated Settlements to Intrastate Wars," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 43, No. 1 (February 1999), pp. 3-22; and Barbara F. Walter, "Designing Transitions from Civil War: Demobilization, Democratization, and Commitments to Peace," International Security, Vol. 24, No. 1 (Summer 1999), pp. 127-155.
    • (1999) International Security , vol.24 , Issue.1 , pp. 127-155
    • Walter, B.F.1
  • 94
    • 0003701880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • For further discussion of the methodological issues involved, see Robert Jervis, System Effects: Complexity in Political and Social Life (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997), pp. 81-87.
    • (1997) System Effects: Complexity in Political and Social Life , pp. 81-87
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 95
    • 1642616239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union
    • Grieco, J.M.1
  • 96
    • 0004264732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • Neorealism and Neoliberalism , pp. 116-169
    • Baldwin1
  • 97
    • 0003921720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • (1998) The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht
    • Moravcsik, A.1
  • 98
    • 0012997402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions, strategic restraint, and the persistence of American postwar order
    • Winter
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • (1998) International Security , vol.23 , Issue.3 , pp. 44-45
    • Ikenberry, G.J.1
  • 99
    • 0031987392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why states act through formal organizations
    • February
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • (1998) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.42 , Issue.1 , pp. 3-32
    • Abbott, K.W.1    Snidal, D.2
  • 100
    • 0003459520 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • (1973) The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History
    • North, D.C.1    Thomas, R.D.2
  • 101
    • 0002336395 scopus 로고
    • Trust as a commodity
    • Diego Gambetta, ed., New York: Basil Blackwell
    • Compare, for example, Joseph M. Grieco, "State Interest and Institutional Rule Trajectories: A Neorealist Interpretation of the Maastricht Treaty and European Economic and Monetary Union," in Baldwin, Neorealism and Neoliberalism, pp. 116-169, and Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press, 1998). See also G. John Ikenberry, "Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Persistence of American Postwar Order," International Security, Vol. 23, No. 3 (Winter 1998/99), pp. 44-45, 55. For the role of institutions in self-binding, see Kenneth W. Abbott and Duncan Snidal, "Why States Act through Formal Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 42, No. 1 (February 1998), pp. 3-32. This emphasis on commitment is consistent with the past generation of research that has argued that the crucial role of governments in economic development is their willingness and ability to maintain domestic order while guaranteeing that they will not confiscate property and wealth, and the work on intertemporal games explaining why and how individuals might bind themselves to do what they would otherwise not do in the future. For the former, the classic study is Douglass C. North and Robert D. Thomas, The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973). For a brief summary of the literature in the latter area, see Partha Dasgupta, "Trust as a Commodity," in Diego Gambetta, ed., Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988), pp. 54-55.
    • (1988) Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations , pp. 54-55
    • Dasgupta, P.1
  • 102
    • 85047494104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blunt reasoning for enlarging NATO: Curbs on Germany
    • December 7
    • Quoted in Jane Perlez, "Blunt Reasoning for Enlarging NATO: Curbs on Germany," New York Times, December 7, 1997, p. 18.
    • (1997) New York Times , pp. 18
    • Perlez, J.1
  • 103
    • 0004075967 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • There is some overlap here with the arguments for the potential role of greater knowledge. See, for example, Ernst B. Haas, When Knowledge Is Power (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); and the special issue of International Organization on epistemic communities, edited by Peter J. Haas, "Knowledge, Power, and International Policy Coordination," International Organization, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Winter 1992).
    • (1990) When Knowledge Is Power
    • Haas, E.B.1
  • 104
    • 0002348552 scopus 로고
    • Knowledge, power, and international policy coordination
    • Winter
    • There is some overlap here with the arguments for the potential role of greater knowledge. See, for example, Ernst B. Haas, When Knowledge Is Power (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990); and the special issue of International Organization on epistemic communities, edited by Peter J. Haas, "Knowledge, Power, and International Policy Coordination," International Organization, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Winter 1992).
    • (1992) International Organization , vol.46 , Issue.1
    • Haas, P.J.1
  • 105
    • 0004165120 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, chap. 9
    • Thomas C. Schelling, The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1960), chap. 9; Schelling and Morton H. Halperin, Strategy and Arms Control (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1961); and Robert Jervis, "Arms Control, Stability, and Causes of War," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 108, No. 2 (Summer 1993), pp. 239-253.
    • (1960) The Strategy of Conflict
    • Schelling, T.C.1
  • 106
    • 0004199322 scopus 로고
    • New York: Twentieth Century Fund
    • Thomas C. Schelling, The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1960), chap. 9; Schelling and Morton H. Halperin, Strategy and Arms Control (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1961); and Robert Jervis, "Arms Control, Stability, and Causes of War," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 108, No. 2 (Summer 1993), pp. 239-253.
    • (1961) Strategy and Arms Control
    • Schelling1    Halperin, M.H.2
  • 107
    • 85055297135 scopus 로고
    • Arms control, stability, and causes of war
    • Summer
    • Thomas C. Schelling, The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1960), chap. 9; Schelling and Morton H. Halperin, Strategy and Arms Control (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1961); and Robert Jervis, "Arms Control, Stability, and Causes of War," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 108, No. 2 (Summer 1993), pp. 239-253.
    • (1993) Political Science Quarterly , vol.108 , Issue.2 , pp. 239-253
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 108
    • 84922412965 scopus 로고
    • Hans Morgenthau, realism, and the scientific study of international politics
    • Winter
    • For a discussion of problems with realism on this score, see Robert Jervis, "Hans Morgenthau, Realism, and the Scientific Study of International Politics," Social Research, Vol. 61, No. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 859-860.
    • (1994) Social Research , vol.61 , Issue.4 , pp. 859-860
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 109
    • 24544470760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peru, Ecuador sign border dispute
    • October 27
    • Anthony Faiola, "Peru, Ecuador Sign Border Dispute," Washington Post, October 27, 1998, p. 20; and "Peru and Ecuador Sign Treaty to End Longstanding Conflict," New York Times, October 27, 1998, p. 3.
    • (1998) Washington Post , pp. 20
    • Faiola, A.1
  • 110
    • 0040098467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peru and Ecuador sign treaty to end longstanding conflict
    • October 27
    • Anthony Faiola, "Peru, Ecuador Sign Border Dispute," Washington Post, October 27, 1998, p. 20; and "Peru and Ecuador Sign Treaty to End Longstanding Conflict," New York Times, October 27, 1998, p. 3.
    • (1998) New York Times , pp. 3
  • 111
    • 0004248550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, part 1
    • Gary S. Becker, Accounting for Tastes (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1996), part 1. For more subtle treatments, see Amartya Sen, "Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory," Philosophy and Public Affairs, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1977), pp. 317-344; and Albert O. Hirschman, "Against Parsimony: Three Easy Ways of Complicating Some Categories of Economic Discourse," in Hirschman, Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays (New York: Viking, 1986), chap. 6.
    • (1996) Accounting for Tastes
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 112
    • 79959682688 scopus 로고
    • Rational fools: A critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory
    • Summer
    • Gary S. Becker, Accounting for Tastes (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1996), part 1. For more subtle treatments, see Amartya Sen, "Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory," Philosophy and Public Affairs, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1977), pp. 317-344; and Albert O. Hirschman, "Against Parsimony: Three Easy Ways of Complicating Some Categories of Economic Discourse," in Hirschman, Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays (New York: Viking, 1986), chap. 6.
    • (1977) Philosophy and Public Affairs , vol.6 , Issue.4 , pp. 317-344
    • Sen, A.1
  • 113
    • 4143058308 scopus 로고
    • Against parsimony: Three easy ways of complicating some categories of economic discourse
    • Hirschman, New York: Viking, chap. 6
    • Gary S. Becker, Accounting for Tastes (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1996), part 1. For more subtle treatments, see Amartya Sen, "Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory," Philosophy and Public Affairs, Vol. 6, No. 4 (Summer 1977), pp. 317-344; and Albert O. Hirschman, "Against Parsimony: Three Easy Ways of Complicating Some Categories of Economic Discourse," in Hirschman, Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays (New York: Viking, 1986), chap. 6.
    • (1986) Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays
    • Hirschman, A.O.1
  • 114
    • 0040294285 scopus 로고
    • Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1954) Political Community at the International Level
    • Deutsch, K.W.1
  • 115
    • 0003817545 scopus 로고
    • Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1958) The Uniting of Europe
    • Haas, E.B.1
  • 116
    • 0040098468 scopus 로고
    • Autumn
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1970) International Organization , vol.24 , Issue.4
  • 117
    • 0003969006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • Regional Integration
    • Lindberg, L.N.1    Scheingold, S.A.2
  • 118
    • 0003477231 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1975) The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory
    • Haas1
  • 119
    • 85196595828 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1992) High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation
    • Sandholtz, W.1
  • 120
    • 0000933198 scopus 로고
    • Obstinate or obsolete? The fate of the nation-state and the case of Western Europe
    • Summer
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1966) Daedalus , vol.95 , Issue.3 , pp. 862-915
    • Hoffmann, S.1
  • 121
    • 0003456576 scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1992) The European Rescue of the Nation-State
    • Milward, A.S.1
  • 122
    • 0004143218 scopus 로고
    • London: Routledge
    • The literature on regional integration is enormous. See, for example, Karl W. Deutsch, Political Community at the International Level (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1954); Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1958); the special issue of International Organization, Vol. 24, No. 4 (Autumn 1970), entitled "Regional Integration," Leon N. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold, eds.; Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1975); and Wayne Sandholtz, High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). For objections and rebuttals, see Stanley Hoffmann, "Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of Western Europe," Daedalus, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Summer 1966), pp. 862-915; Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992); and Milward, Ruggero Ranieri, Frances Lynch, F. Romero, and Vibeke Sorensen, The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992 (London: Routledge, 1993). The most thorough liberal account is Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe.
    • (1993) The Frontier of National Sovereignty: History and Theory, 1945-1992
    • Milward1    Ranieri, R.2    Lynch, F.3    Romero, F.4    Sorensen, V.5
  • 123
    • 84937268168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The institutional dynamics of international political orders
    • Autumn
    • For a brief discussion of both the intended and the unintended creation of identities, see James G. March and Johan P. Olsen, "The Institutional Dynamics of International Political Orders," International Organization, Vol. 52, No. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 960-964.
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.4 , pp. 960-964
    • March, J.G.1    Olsen, J.P.2
  • 124
    • 79952431656 scopus 로고
    • Institutions and cooperation: Sanctions during the Falkland Islands conflict
    • Spring
    • Lisa L. Martin, "Institutions and Cooperation: Sanctions during the Falkland Islands Conflict," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 4 (Spring 1992), pp. 143-178. Martin and Simmons, "International Institutions," pp. 750-751, see unanticipated consequences (which they correctly note may not be the same as unintended ones) as a puzzle for institutional theory rather than as its strength.
    • (1992) International Security , vol.16 , Issue.4 , pp. 143-178
    • Martin, L.L.1
  • 125
    • 2942695943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lisa L. Martin, "Institutions and Cooperation: Sanctions during the Falkland Islands Conflict," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 4 (Spring 1992), pp. 143-178. Martin and Simmons, "International Institutions," pp. 750-751, see unanticipated consequences (which they correctly note may not be the same as unintended ones) as a puzzle for institutional theory rather than as its strength.
    • International Institutions , pp. 750-751
    • Martin1    Simmons2
  • 127
    • 0001935418 scopus 로고
    • Not yet a wing
    • October
    • Stephen Jay Gould, "Not Yet a Wing," Natural History, Vol. 94, No. 10 (October 1985), pp. 12-25. Institutions, like evolution, can also "lock in" arrangements that are suboptimal or advantage one party. There is also a parallel in the argument that "social capital" in the form of dense networks of groups and voluntary associations have the unintended effect of facilitating a wide range of political and economic activities. The best known work is perhaps Robert D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993). See also Putnam, "Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America," PS: Political Science & Politics, Vol. 28, No. 4 (December 1995), pp. 664-683. For critical reviews of the literature, see Robert W. Jackman, "Social Capital and Politics," Annual Review of Political Science (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 1, pp. 47-74; and Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 24, pp. 1-24.
    • (1985) Natural History , vol.94 , Issue.10 , pp. 12-25
    • Gould, S.J.1
  • 128
    • 0003443840 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Stephen Jay Gould, "Not Yet a Wing," Natural History, Vol. 94, No. 10 (October 1985), pp. 12-25. Institutions, like evolution, can also "lock in" arrangements that are suboptimal or advantage one party. There is also a parallel in the argument that "social capital" in the form of dense networks of groups and voluntary associations have the unintended effect of facilitating a wide range of political and economic activities. The best known work is perhaps Robert D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993). See also Putnam, "Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America," PS: Political Science & Politics, Vol. 28, No. 4 (December 1995), pp. 664-683. For critical reviews of the literature, see Robert W. Jackman, "Social Capital and Politics," Annual Review of Political Science (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 1, pp. 47-74; and Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 24, pp. 1-24.
    • (1993) Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy
    • Putnam, R.D.1
  • 129
    • 84971108567 scopus 로고
    • Tuning in, tuning out: The strange disappearance of social capital in America
    • December
    • Stephen Jay Gould, "Not Yet a Wing," Natural History, Vol. 94, No. 10 (October 1985), pp. 12-25. Institutions, like evolution, can also "lock in" arrangements that are suboptimal or advantage one party. There is also a parallel in the argument that "social capital" in the form of dense networks of groups and voluntary associations have the unintended effect of facilitating a wide range of political and economic activities. The best known work is perhaps Robert D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993). See also Putnam, "Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America," PS: Political Science & Politics, Vol. 28, No. 4 (December 1995), pp. 664-683. For critical reviews of the literature, see Robert W. Jackman, "Social Capital and Politics," Annual Review of Political Science (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 1, pp. 47-74; and Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 24, pp. 1-24.
    • (1995) PS: Political Science & Politics , vol.28 , Issue.4 , pp. 664-683
    • Putnam1
  • 130
    • 0040042003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital and politics
    • Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press
    • Stephen Jay Gould, "Not Yet a Wing," Natural History, Vol. 94, No. 10 (October 1985), pp. 12-25. Institutions, like evolution, can also "lock in" arrangements that are suboptimal or advantage one party. There is also a parallel in the argument that "social capital" in the form of dense networks of groups and voluntary associations have the unintended effect of facilitating a wide range of political and economic activities. The best known work is perhaps Robert D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993). See also Putnam, "Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America," PS: Political Science & Politics, Vol. 28, No. 4 (December 1995), pp. 664-683. For critical reviews of the literature, see Robert W. Jackman, "Social Capital and Politics," Annual Review of Political Science (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 1, pp. 47-74; and Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 24, pp. 1-24.
    • (1998) Annual Review of Political Science , vol.1 , pp. 47-74
    • Jackman, R.W.1
  • 131
    • 0032331809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social capital: Its origins and applications in modern sociology
    • Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press
    • Stephen Jay Gould, "Not Yet a Wing," Natural History, Vol. 94, No. 10 (October 1985), pp. 12-25. Institutions, like evolution, can also "lock in" arrangements that are suboptimal or advantage one party. There is also a parallel in the argument that "social capital" in the form of dense networks of groups and voluntary associations have the unintended effect of facilitating a wide range of political and economic activities. The best known work is perhaps Robert D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1993). See also Putnam, "Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of Social Capital in America," PS: Political Science & Politics, Vol. 28, No. 4 (December 1995), pp. 664-683. For critical reviews of the literature, see Robert W. Jackman, "Social Capital and Politics," Annual Review of Political Science (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 1, pp. 47-74; and Alejandro Portes, "Social Capital: Its Origins and Applications in Modern Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology (Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews Press, 1998), vol. 24, pp. 1-24.
    • (1998) Annual Review of Sociology , vol.24 , pp. 1-24
    • Portes, A.1
  • 132
    • 0030098710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Western Europe needs the United States and NATO
    • Spring
    • Furthermore, post-Cold War developments show the continuing importance of national conflicts and U.S. power. Robert J. Art, "Why Western Europe Needs the United States and NATO," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 111, No. 1 (Spring 1996), pp. 1-39; and Waltz, "Realism after the Cold War."
    • (1996) Political Science Quarterly , vol.111 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-39
    • Art, R.J.1
  • 133
    • 0030098710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Furthermore, post-Cold War developments show the continuing importance of national conflicts and U.S. power. Robert J. Art, "Why Western Europe Needs the United States and NATO," Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 111, No. 1 (Spring 1996), pp. 1-39; and Waltz, "Realism after the Cold War."
    • Realism after the Cold War
    • Waltz1
  • 136
    • 84936192966 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
    • Helen V. Milner, Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988); Scott C. James and David A. Lake, "The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain's Repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846," International Organization, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Winter 1989), pp. 1-29; and Lars S. Skålnes, "From the Inside Out: NATO Expansion and International Relations Theory," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 4 (Summer 1998), pp. 44-87. See also Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," p. 295. I think Martin and Simmons are too harsh when they say that "institutionalists have generally neglected the role of domestic politics"; see "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," p. 747. I am grateful to Robert Keohane for discussion on this subject.
    • (1988) Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade
    • Milner, H.V.1
  • 137
    • 84971957482 scopus 로고
    • The second face of hegemony: Britain's repeal of the corn laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846
    • Winter
    • Helen V. Milner, Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988); Scott C. James and David A. Lake, "The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain's Repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846," International Organization, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Winter 1989), pp. 1-29; and Lars S. Skålnes, "From the Inside Out: NATO Expansion and International Relations Theory," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 4 (Summer 1998), pp. 44-87. See also Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," p. 295. I think Martin and Simmons are too harsh when they say that "institutionalists have generally neglected the role of domestic politics"; see "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," p. 747. I am grateful to Robert Keohane for discussion on this subject.
    • (1989) International Organization , vol.43 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-29
    • James, S.C.1    Lake, D.A.2
  • 138
    • 4243743385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From the inside out: NATO expansion and international relations theory
    • Summer
    • Helen V. Milner, Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988); Scott C. James and David A. Lake, "The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain's Repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846," International Organization, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Winter 1989), pp. 1-29; and Lars S. Skålnes, "From the Inside Out: NATO Expansion and International Relations Theory," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 4 (Summer 1998), pp. 44-87. See also Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," p. 295. I think Martin and Simmons are too harsh when they say that "institutionalists have generally neglected the role of domestic politics"; see "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," p. 747. I am grateful to Robert Keohane for discussion on this subject.
    • (1998) Security Studies , vol.7 , Issue.4 , pp. 44-87
    • Skålnes, L.S.1
  • 139
    • 0039966482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Helen V. Milner, Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988); Scott C. James and David A. Lake, "The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain's Repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846," International Organization, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Winter 1989), pp. 1-29; and Lars S.
    • Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War , pp. 295
    • Keohane1
  • 140
    • 0040691854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Helen V. Milner, Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988); Scott C. James and David A. Lake, "The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain's Repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846," International Organization, Vol. 43, No. 1 (Winter 1989), pp. 1-29; and Lars S. Skålnes, "From the Inside Out: NATO Expansion and International Relations Theory," Security Studies, Vol. 7, No. 4 (Summer 1998), pp. 44-87. See also Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," p. 295. I think Martin and Simmons are too harsh when they say that "institutionalists have generally neglected the role of domestic politics"; see "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions," p. 747. I am grateful to Robert Keohane for discussion on this subject.
    • Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions , pp. 747
  • 141
    • 0037772968 scopus 로고
    • Did the congress of Vienna rest on a balance of power?
    • June
    • Thus my analysis of the Concert of Europe that is based on defensive realism denies or at least ignores the deeper changes that Paul W. Schroeder argues had occurred. See Schroeder, "Did the Congress of Vienna Rest on a Balance of Power?" American Historical Review, Vol. 97, No. 3 (June 1992), pp. 683-706; and Jervis, "A Political Science Perspective on the Balance of Power and the Concert," ibid., pp. 716-724. For a fuller presentation of Schroeder's views, see Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 1763-1848 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996).
    • (1992) American Historical Review , vol.97 , Issue.3 , pp. 683-706
    • Schroeder1
  • 142
    • 0038190562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A political science perspective on the balance of power and the concert
    • Thus my analysis of the Concert of Europe that is based on defensive realism denies or at least ignores the deeper changes that Paul W. Schroeder argues had occurred. See Schroeder, "Did the Congress of Vienna Rest on a Balance of Power?" American Historical Review, Vol. 97, No. 3 (June 1992), pp. 683-706; and Jervis, "A Political Science Perspective on the Balance of Power and the Concert," ibid., pp. 716-724. For a fuller presentation of Schroeder's views, see Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 1763-1848 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996).
    • American Historical Review , pp. 716-724
    • Jervis1
  • 143
    • 0004103242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • Thus my analysis of the Concert of Europe that is based on defensive realism denies or at least ignores the deeper changes that Paul W. Schroeder argues had occurred. See Schroeder, "Did the Congress of Vienna Rest on a Balance of Power?" American Historical Review, Vol. 97, No. 3 (June 1992), pp. 683-706; and Jervis, "A Political Science Perspective on the Balance of Power and the Concert," ibid., pp. 716-724. For a fuller presentation of Schroeder's views, see Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 1763-1848 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996).
    • (1996) The Transformation of European Politics, 1763-1848
    • Schroeder1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.