메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 21, Issue 1, 1996, Pages 112-146

Current gains and future outcomes: When cumulative relative gains matter

(1)  Matthews III, John C a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0030521901     PISSN: 01622889     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1162/isec.21.1.112     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (35)

References (153)
  • 1
    • 0004205937 scopus 로고
    • New York: McGraw-Hill, esp.
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1979) Theory of International Politics , pp. 105
    • Waltz, K.1
  • 2
    • 84972468435 scopus 로고
    • Anarchy and the limits of cooperation: A realist critique of the Newest Liberal institutionalism
    • Summer
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1988) International Organization , vol.42 , Issue.3
    • Grieco, J.1
  • 3
    • 0003993070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1990) Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-tariff Barriers to Trade
    • Grieco, J.1
  • 4
    • 34248247318 scopus 로고
    • The relative gains problem for international cooperation
    • September
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1993) American Political Science Review , vol.87 , Issue.3
    • Grieco, J.1
  • 5
    • 0002349233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the problem of international cooperation: The limits of neoliberal institutionalism and the future of realist theory
    • David Baldwin, ed., New York: Columbia University Press
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1993) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate
    • Grieco, J.1
  • 6
    • 0004130918 scopus 로고
    • Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1989) International Institutions and State Power
    • Keohane, R.1
  • 7
    • 0001794187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutional theory and the realist challenge after the Cold War
    • David Baldwin, ed., New York: Columbia University Press
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1993) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate
    • Keohane, R.1
  • 8
    • 84971736578 scopus 로고
    • Relative gains and the pattern of international cooperation
    • September
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85 , Issue.3
    • Snidal, D.1
  • 9
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고
    • Absolute and relative gains in international relations theory
    • December
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85 , Issue.4
    • Powell, R.1
  • 10
    • 84928438245 scopus 로고
    • Do relative gains matter? America's response to Japanese industrial policy
    • Summer
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1991) International Security , vol.16 , Issue.1
    • Mastanduno, M.1
  • 11
    • 84934453533 scopus 로고
    • Global communications and national power: Life on the Pareto Frontier
    • April
    • See, for instance, Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), esp. pp. 105, 175; Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988); Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990); Joseph Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993); Joseph Grieco, "Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Robert Keohane, International Institutions and State Power (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1989); Robert Keohane, "Institutional Theory and the Realist Challenge after the Cold War," in David Baldwin, ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993); Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 3 (September 1991); Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 4, (December 1991); Michael Mastanduno, "Do Relative Gains Matter? America's Response to Japanese Industrial Policy," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Summer 1991); Stephen Krasner, "Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier," World Politics, Vol. 43, No. 3 (April 1991).
    • (1991) World Politics , vol.43 , Issue.3
    • Krasner, S.1
  • 12
    • 84899666610 scopus 로고
    • Realists as optimists: Cooperation as self-help
    • Winter
    • This article uses the terms "IPE" or "international political economy" to denote the issue area of international economic affairs and "security" for state security affairs. The first deals with issues of trade, monetary policy, investment, and other economic activities that generally have wealth as their principal goal. Security deals with issues of military capacity and the ability to wage war and physically defend a state against attackers. These distinctions are not clear-cut, as economic interactions can have security implications and vice versa. Nevertheless, much of the literature in international relations makes the strong argument that the two issue areas are sufficiently different to be analytically dissimilar in terms of prospects for cooperation. For a somewhat contrasting usage of the term "security," see Charles L. Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help," International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/95), pp. 53, fn. 6, and pp. 70-73.
    • (1994) International Security , vol.19 , Issue.3 , pp. 53
    • Glaser, C.L.1
  • 13
    • 85033754915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I define "gain" as a benefit derived from cooperation. In economic cooperation this will generally take the form of monetary benefits. In security cooperation the primary benefit is a decrease in the capability of a potential adversary to inflict damage to one's own state or its physical assets. A "relative gain" is a disproportionate benefit which changes the balance between two states. An absolute gain is the total award received by a state for a transaction; the comparative measure of absolute gains is the same state relative to itself at different times. Relative gains create "advantages" when they allow the state that benefits more to secure additional gains not directly linked to the terms of the original agreement or outcome. Advantages result when relative gains can be used to influence other outcomes.
  • 14
    • 85033751115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I use "round" to mean a period of limited duration during which a state attempts to alter significantly the status quo existing between itself and partners or rivals. Bilateral and multilateral negotiations are rounds, as are unilateral actions and counter-actions. Rounds begin when a state initiates serious efforts to create a new status quo. They end when the states involved agree to accept or are forced to accept new rules for action or new payoffs, or when the states abandon, temporarily or permanently, the attempt at revision and revert to the status quo ante.
  • 15
    • 85033745722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grieco also used the term "cumulative" to describe increasing returns to early relative gains. His usage is brief and undeveloped, however, and refers essentially to the potential for relative losses to restrict independent action of states at a later date in their political decisions. See Grieco, "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," p. 734.
    • The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation , pp. 734
    • Grieco1
  • 16
    • 0002440763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Security regimes
    • Stephen Krasner, ed., Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, esp.
    • See for instance Robert Jervis, "Security Regimes," in Stephen Krasner, ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983), esp. pp. 174-176. Jervis argues that because security differs so fundamentally from other issues in international relations, cooperation and regime formation are exceedingly difficult.
    • (1983) International Regimes , pp. 174-176
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 18
    • 0003993070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I define cooperation as a joint decision by two or more states to limit or regulate conflict over a contentious issue. This generally will bring mutual benefit, though it may be unequal. See, for example, Grieco, Cooperation among Nations, p. 22.
    • Cooperation among Nations , pp. 22
    • Grieco1
  • 20
    • 84874353575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Waltz provides the theoretical underpinning for this argument in his analysis of anarchy. See particularly Waltz, Theory of International Politics, pp. 114.
    • Theory of International Politics , pp. 114
    • Waltz1
  • 24
    • 0040559435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is essentially the nature of Grieco's "K Factor," as well as Snidal's relative gains variable. They express the same idea, that relative gains concerns vary according to some set of factors. See Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation," p. 501; Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation."
    • Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation , pp. 501
    • Grieco1
  • 25
    • 0040855985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is essentially the nature of Grieco's "K Factor," as well as Snidal's relative gains variable. They express the same idea, that relative gains concerns vary according to some set of factors. See Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation," p. 501; Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation."
    • Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation
    • Snidal1
  • 26
    • 0003993070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grieco, Cooperation among Nations, pp. 45-47. This argument suggests that in some instances IPE and security do overlap and economic interactions produce security results. When this happens, relative gains become more problematic. While this argument links the two issue areas, it also reinforces the conventional distinction, which sees economic interactions as being more cooperative by nature and security interactions as being necessarily conflictual. The implication of the security linkage argument is that cooperation is more likely and relative gains are less problematic in economic affairs that have small security implications. I do not contend that this framework is never useful; for a variety of reasons discussed in the literature, security is a more difficult area for cooperation. I do suggest that the distinction has become too strongly drawn, however, and that explanations of variance in relative gains based on it have difficulty accounting for many important cases within and across the issue areas.
    • Cooperation among Nations , pp. 45-47
    • Grieco1
  • 27
    • 85033762710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the argument that relative gains concerns decline as the number of partners increases, see Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of Cooperation"; and Snidal's contribution to "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993), esp. pp. 738-739. For the argument regarding the translation of gains into military instruments, see Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," pp. 1311-1314.
    • Relative Gains and the Pattern of Cooperation
    • Snidal1
  • 28
    • 34248247318 scopus 로고
    • The relative gains problem for international cooperation
    • September esp.
    • For the argument that relative gains concerns decline as the number of partners increases, see Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of Cooperation"; and Snidal's contribution to "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993), esp. pp. 738-739. For the argument regarding the translation of gains into military instruments, see Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," pp. 1311-1314.
    • (1993) American Political Science Review , vol.87 , Issue.3 , pp. 738-739
    • Snidal1
  • 29
    • 0006131485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the argument that relative gains concerns decline as the number of partners increases, see Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of Cooperation"; and Snidal's contribution to "The Relative Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review, Vol. 87, No. 3 (September 1993), esp. pp. 738-739. For the argument regarding the translation of gains into military instruments, see Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," pp. 1311-1314.
    • Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory , pp. 1311-1314
    • Powell1
  • 31
    • 85033757576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In large part, these arguments are not contested. Most analysts seem to concur that insofar as these conditions obtain, relative gains will vary. More of the dispute centers on which conditions, threatening or benign, most frequently characterize attempts at cooperation.
  • 32
    • 0004151660 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basil Blackwell, esp.
    • A good collection of essays on the nature of power in international relations is David Baldwin, Paradoxes of Power (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1989), esp. p. 3.
    • (1989) Paradoxes of Power , pp. 3
    • Baldwin, D.1
  • 33
    • 0003330502 scopus 로고
    • The richness of the tradition of political realism
    • Robert Keohane, ed., New York: Columbia University Press
    • Robert Gilpin, "The Richness of the Tradition of Political Realism," in Robert Keohane, ed., Neorealism and Its Critics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1986), p. 305.
    • (1986) Neorealism and Its Critics , pp. 305
    • Gilpin, R.1
  • 34
    • 0039315517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a critique of this perspective on security and relative gains, see Glaser, "Realists as Optimists," pp. 74-75, in which he argues that while it is true that states care about how much the other is gaining or losing in military assets, this is best seen as a concern over levels of absolute security. Glaser's analyses on this point, however, and on how security can be viewed as an absolute measure, remain vague, and much of his logic continues to suggest that states will still act in the same way as indicated by relative gains theorists.
    • Realists As Optimists , pp. 74-75
    • Glaser1
  • 37
    • 0006131485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," pp. 1309-1310. This type of analysis is in many ways similar to my thesis of cumulation effects. However, while these works focus on cumulation across issue areas, from IPE to security, my focus is on cumulation within issue areas. However, a broader notion of cumulation could include both types of analysis.
    • Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory , pp. 1309-1310
    • Powell1
  • 38
    • 0039173716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mearsheimer, for example, rejects the distinction between IPE and security for this reason, arguing that in any agreement on economics there will be concerns over relative security gains that may inhibit cooperation. It is notable that Mearsheimer acknowledges that there may be other reasons for relative gains concerns that are not security based, but declares that they are not realist in nature because they are "non-military." Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," pp. 20-21, fn. 62.
    • The False Promise of International Institutions , pp. 20-21
    • Mearsheimer1
  • 42
    • 84881781568 scopus 로고
    • Competitiveness: A dangerous obsession
    • March/April
    • See for example, Paul Krugman, "Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 73, No. 2 (March/April 1994). It may be the case, however, that economists are the only ones to believe this. See Robert Reich, "Do We Want U.S. Rich or Japan Poor?" Wall Street Journal, June 18, 1990.
    • (1994) Foreign Affairs , vol.73 , Issue.2
    • Krugman, P.1
  • 43
    • 25544453675 scopus 로고
    • Do we want U.S. Rich or Japan poor?
    • June
    • See for example, Paul Krugman, "Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 73, No. 2 (March/April 1994). It may be the case, however, that economists are the only ones to believe this. See Robert Reich, "Do We Want U.S. Rich or Japan Poor?" Wall Street Journal, June 18, 1990.
    • (1990) Wall Street Journal , vol.18
    • Reich, R.1
  • 45
    • 85033759157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A "pareto-superior" arrangement is one which some or all of the partners to the arrangement realize greater gains than they presently receive, and no parties realize lower ones. A pareto-optimal arrangement is one in which it is impossible for this to happen because the total gains to be realized are bounded and any alteration in the existing arrangements would increase the share one party receives at the expense of others' share. When states or firms are at the pareto frontier, that is, when they have reached this boundary of total gains, the only way to increase their own absolute gains is by taking some from a partner or rival.
  • 48
    • 84959626707 scopus 로고
    • International cooperation in security and economic affairs
    • October
    • See, for example, Charles Lipson, "International Cooperation in Security and Economic Affairs," World Politics, Vol. 37, No. 1 (October 1984).
    • (1984) World Politics , vol.37 , Issue.1
    • Lipson, C.1
  • 49
    • 85033751848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cumulation is measured by examining whether the issue displays characteristics that allow a state to demand or acquire additional benefits later. When an issue displays many such characteristics, the cumulation effect is high; when it displays few, cumulation is low.
  • 52
    • 85033745313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This article focuses on the way in which this argument works within a given issue area, but the concept of cumulation need not be analytically confined to a single issue. In many instances, relative gains in one issue area can cumulate into advantages in related areas as well; gains sometimes are fungible. This more expansive application of the idea of a cumulation effect is clearly similar to the existing arguments in the literature described above which highlight the importance for security of relative gains acquired in economic interactions.
  • 53
    • 84971881632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This relatively narrow focus differs in obvious ways from many attempts to explain variance in relative gains, which point to broader conditions such as the number of actors (roughly equivalent to polarity) or the differences between economics and security. Current explanations for variation in relative gains point most often to the strategic setting in ways which have led some to conclude that these conditions rarely change and, as a consequence, relative gains concerns are generally quite high. See, e.g., Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," p. 23. Powell also argues that relative gains concerns either vary by their strategic setting, or do not vary at all. Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate," International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 2 (Spring 1994), p. 335.
    • The False Promise of International Institutions , pp. 23
    • Mearsheimer1
  • 54
    • 84971881632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anarchy in international relations theory: The neorealist-neoliberal debate
    • Spring
    • This relatively narrow focus differs in obvious ways from many attempts to explain variance in relative gains, which point to broader conditions such as the number of actors (roughly equivalent to polarity) or the differences between economics and security. Current explanations for variation in relative gains point most often to the strategic setting in ways which have led some to conclude that these conditions rarely change and, as a consequence, relative gains concerns are generally quite high. See, e.g., Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," p. 23. Powell also argues that relative gains concerns either vary by their strategic setting, or do not vary at all. Powell, "Anarchy in International Relations Theory: The Neorealist-Neoliberal Debate," International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 2 (Spring 1994), p. 335.
    • (1994) International Organization , vol.48 , Issue.2 , pp. 335
    • Powell1
  • 55
    • 85033747362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cumulation in this article is about advantages. In any trade agreement, for example, both partners will, over time, accumulate absolute gains. However, in some instances one partner will be able not only to accumulate more gains, but to use disproportionate gains to increase its advantage. The relative gap in distribution will grow, leaving the "losing" state worse off than it could have been had the initial conditions not been unbalanced. Even when states are both anticipating absolute gains from an arrangement with few security implications, relative gains can be very significant due to the potentially massive long-term absolute-gains consequences of initial conditions.
  • 56
    • 85033754392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This article does not contend that relative gains are only important for their cumulation effects. Rather, it argues that concerns over relative gains limited to a single current interaction present more tractable problems for cooperation. The more likely cumulation effects are to exist, however, the more likely relative gains are to be major barriers to cooperation rather than manageable ones. Thus, while cumulation is not the sole cause for concern over relative gains, it is the one most likely to preclude cooperation.
  • 57
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • The Prisoner's Dilemma is the most common game theory model used in international relations. Two players each have two choices, to cooperate or to, defect, C or D. The payoffs for each depend on the choice of the other, so that the order of preferences for an individual is DC, CC, DD, CD, where the first letter indicates the player's own choice and the second the choice of its partner or opponent. Because of the incentives in this game, any player on a single round should defect, resulting in a DD outcome. However, if the game is extended to multiple rounds, the players can establish a pattern of CC in order to reap the greatest long-term gains. Achieving cooperation under the incentives of a Prisoner's Dilemma is the subject of much of the cooperation literature. The classic work on this subject is Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984). For a discussion of the effect of the shadow of the future on cooperation generally, see Kenneth Oye, "Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies," in Kenneth Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986), pp. 12-18 . Also see Robert Axelrod and Robert Keohane, "Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions," in ibid., pp. 232-234.
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 58
    • 0002565924 scopus 로고
    • Explaining cooperation under anarchy: Hypotheses and strategies
    • Kenneth Oye, ed., Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • The Prisoner's Dilemma is the most common game theory model used in international relations. Two players each have two choices, to cooperate or to, defect, C or D. The payoffs for each depend on the choice of the other, so that the order of preferences for an individual is DC, CC, DD, CD, where the first letter indicates the player's own choice and the second the choice of its partner or opponent. Because of the incentives in this game, any player on a single round should defect, resulting in a DD outcome. However, if the game is extended to multiple rounds, the players can establish a pattern of CC in order to reap the greatest long-term gains. Achieving cooperation under the incentives of a Prisoner's Dilemma is the subject of much of the cooperation literature. The classic work on this subject is Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984). For a discussion of the effect of the shadow of the future on cooperation generally, see Kenneth Oye, "Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies," in Kenneth Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986), pp. 12-18 . Also see Robert Axelrod and Robert Keohane, "Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions," in ibid., pp. 232-234.
    • (1986) Cooperation under Anarchy , pp. 12-18
    • Kenneth, O.1
  • 59
    • 0002745347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Achieving cooperation under anarchy: Strategies and institutions
    • Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • The Prisoner's Dilemma is the most common game theory model used in international relations. Two players each have two choices, to cooperate or to, defect, C or D. The payoffs for each depend on the choice of the other, so that the order of preferences for an individual is DC, CC, DD, CD, where the first letter indicates the player's own choice and the second the choice of its partner or opponent. Because of the incentives in this game, any player on a single round should defect, resulting in a DD outcome. However, if the game is extended to multiple rounds, the players can establish a pattern of CC in order to reap the greatest long-term gains. Achieving cooperation under the incentives of a Prisoner's Dilemma is the subject of much of the cooperation literature. The classic work on this subject is Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984). For a discussion of the effect of the shadow of the future on cooperation generally, see Kenneth Oye, "Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies," in Kenneth Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986), pp. 12-18 . Also see Robert Axelrod and Robert Keohane, "Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions," in ibid., pp. 232-234.
    • Cooperation under Anarchy , pp. 232-234
    • Axelrod, R.1    Keohane, R.2
  • 61
    • 85033752496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The traditional extended play Prisoner's Dilemma keeps the payoffs for an outcome constant. If in the first round a DC has a 4:1 payoff, it will have the same payoff in later rounds. The cumulation argument suggests that by winning the 4:1 payoff now, states can construct different payoffs in the future so that the ratio may grow beyond 4:1. This may also influence the payoffs for all other outcomes as well so that unequal payoffs can be built into later rounds by current victors. This reduces the effectiveness of the loser's retaliation.
  • 62
    • 0039240707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In effect, this is an extended version of Krasner's argument. He suggests that relative gains concerns are important for distributional reasons, and in fact the issue is made even more difficult by the temporal aspect considered in this article. Krasner, "Global Communications and National power."
    • Global Communications and National Power
    • Krasner1
  • 63
    • 84974380232 scopus 로고
    • Cooperation under the security Dilemma
    • January
    • The classic work on the offense-defense balance and the effects on cooperation between states is Robert Jervis, "Cooperation under the Security Dilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January 1978).
    • (1978) World Politics , vol.30 , Issue.2
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 64
    • 0006131485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a similar argument regarding the effects of offensive advantage on relative gains concerns, see Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," pp. 1311-1314. Powell does not use the term offense-defense balance, but that logic is the foundation of his argument about when relative gains will matter most.
    • Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory , pp. 1311-1314
    • Powell1
  • 65
    • 0000059858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Offense-defense theory and its critics
    • Summer
    • For an excellent overview of the literature on the offense-defense balance and its critics, and a defense of the concept, see Sean Lynn-Jones, "Offense-Defense Theory and Its Critics," Security Studies, Vol. 4, No. 4 (Summer 1995). Of particular relevance here is Lynn-Jones's argument that while any particular weapon has both offensive and defensive potential, some weapons and constellations of weapons make offensive maneuvers less costly and make defense more costly. Tanks can be used for defense, but, as Lynn-Jones notes, their advent made offensive operations less costly and thus shifted the offense-defense balance to make offense more attractive than it had been. Ibid., pp. 674-677. This article diverges from Lynn-Jones on offense-defense advantages in that it examines them not as only as technological properties of the system, but as balances that apply to particular relationships. In the cases examined in this article, these are the nuclear and conventional relationships between the United States and the Soviet Union during the 1970s and 1980s. For Lynn-Jones' specification of the offense-defense balance as a systemic property, see ibid., p. 668.
    • (1995) Security Studies , vol.4 , Issue.4
    • Lynn-Jones, S.1
  • 66
    • 0000059858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes
    • For an excellent overview of the literature on the offense-defense balance and its critics, and a defense of the concept, see Sean Lynn-Jones, "Offense-Defense Theory and Its Critics," Security Studies, Vol. 4, No. 4 (Summer 1995). Of particular relevance here is Lynn-Jones's argument that while any particular weapon has both offensive and defensive potential, some weapons and constellations of weapons make offensive maneuvers less costly and make defense more costly. Tanks can be used for defense, but, as Lynn-Jones notes, their advent made offensive operations less costly and thus shifted the offense-defense balance to make offense more attractive than it had been. Ibid., pp. 674-677. This article diverges from Lynn-Jones on offense-defense advantages in that it examines them not as only as technological properties of the system, but as balances that apply to particular relationships. In the cases examined in this article, these are the nuclear and conventional relationships between the United States and the Soviet Union during the 1970s and 1980s. For Lynn-Jones' specification of the offense-defense balance as a systemic property, see ibid., p. 668.
    • Security Studies , pp. 674-677
    • Lynn-Jones1
  • 67
    • 0000059858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an excellent overview of the literature on the offense-defense balance and its critics, and a defense of the concept, see Sean Lynn-Jones, "Offense-Defense Theory and Its Critics," Security Studies, Vol. 4, No. 4 (Summer 1995). Of particular relevance here is Lynn-Jones's argument that while any particular weapon has both offensive and defensive potential, some weapons and constellations of weapons make offensive maneuvers less costly and make defense more costly. Tanks can be used for defense, but, as Lynn-Jones notes, their advent made offensive operations less costly and thus shifted the offense-defense balance to make offense more attractive than it had been. Ibid., pp. 674-677. This article diverges from Lynn-Jones on offense-defense advantages in that it examines them not as only as technological properties of the system, but as balances that apply to particular relationships. In the cases examined in this article, these are the nuclear and conventional relationships between the United States and the Soviet Union during the 1970s and 1980s. For Lynn-Jones' specification of the offense-defense balance as a systemic property, see ibid., p. 668.
    • (1970) Security Studies , pp. 668
    • Lynn-Jones1
  • 68
    • 0003758853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • For a good general overview of these issues and models, see David M. Kreps, A Course in Microeconomic Theory (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990), pp. 325-330.
    • (1990) A Course in Microeconomic Theory , pp. 325-330
    • Kreps, D.M.1
  • 70
    • 0000618950 scopus 로고
    • First mover and second mover advantages
    • Esther Gal-Or, "First Mover and Second Mover Advantages," International Economic Review, Vol. 26, No. 3 (1985), p. 651.
    • (1985) International Economic Review , vol.26 , Issue.3 , pp. 651
    • Gal-Or, E.1
  • 71
    • 84935842016 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: MIT Press
    • This argument draws upon and to some extent parallels some of the strategic trade literature. See Paul Krugman, ed., Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986). The underlying concern of both strategic trade and the notion of cumulation as related to IPE in this essay is very similar, namely that a state may be disadvantaged in particular types of markets if it does not compete for relative share at early stages. Notably, both arguments see barriers to entry increasing as the market matures, making late entry quite expensive if not impossible. However, the notion of cumulation is a more expansive category and could be applied to IPE areas outside of trade such as monetary policy. Furthermore, unlike strategic trade theory, the theory of cumulation in this essay is not limited necessarily to so-called "sunrise" industries, or even to high-value-added industries per se. That is, whereas strategic trade suggests that certain types of industries may be worth fighting for, and may also exhibit the characteristics described above, this essay simply suggests that certain markets do not easily admit late-comers and therefore will elicit stronger competitive responses from states.
    • (1986) Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics
    • Krugman, P.1
  • 72
    • 0002642594 scopus 로고
    • Standardization, compatibility, and innovation
    • Spring
    • J. Farrell and G. Saloner, "Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation," Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Spring 1985), p. 71; Paul David, "CLIO and the Economics of QWERTY," American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 2 (May 1985), pp. 332-337.
    • (1985) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.16 , Issue.1 , pp. 71
    • Farrell, J.1    Saloner, G.2
  • 73
    • 85024536192 scopus 로고
    • CLIO and the economics of QWERTY
    • May
    • J. Farrell and G. Saloner, "Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation," Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Spring 1985), p. 71; Paul David, "CLIO and the Economics of QWERTY," American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 2 (May 1985), pp. 332-337.
    • (1985) American Economic Review , vol.75 , Issue.2 , pp. 332-337
    • David, P.1
  • 74
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Axelrod suggests, for example, that a reason for defection has little to do with rationality and a good deal to do with a psychological need to measure performance against peers. Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation, pp. 110-113.
    • The Evolution of Cooperation , pp. 110-113
    • Axelrod1
  • 75
    • 0040424965 scopus 로고
    • Supercomputers and national policy: Maintaining U.S. Predominance in an emerging industry
    • J.R. Kirkland and J.H. Pierce, New York: Praeger Press
    • George Kozmetsky, "Supercomputers and National Policy: Maintaining U.S. Predominance in an Emerging Industry," in J.R. Kirkland and J.H. Pierce, Supercomputers: A Key to U.S. Scientific, Technological, and Industrial Preeminence (New York: Praeger Press, 1987), pp. 10-11.
    • (1987) Supercomputers: A Key to U.S. Scientific, Technological, and Industrial Preeminence , pp. 10-11
    • Kozmetsky, G.1
  • 76
    • 0040424957 scopus 로고
    • The genius: Seymour cray, father of the supercomputer
    • April
    • U.S. firms retain 90 percent market share. "The Genius: Seymour Cray, Father of the Supercomputer," Business Week, April 30, 1990, pp. 81-83.
    • (1990) Business Week , vol.30 , pp. 81-83
  • 77
    • 4243986738 scopus 로고
    • Office of technology assessment, before legislation and national security subcommittee of the committee on government operations
    • July
    • Testimony of Julie Fox Gorte, Office of Technology Assessment, before Legislation and National Security Subcommittee of the Committee on Government Operations, House of Representatives, 102nd Congress, July 1 and 8, 1992, p. 23.
    • (1992) House of Representatives, 102nd Congress , vol.1-8 , pp. 23
    • Gorte, J.F.1
  • 78
    • 0003487681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics
    • For a good, brief overview of the U.S.-Japanese relation over supercomputers, see Laura D'Andrea Tyson, Who's Bashing Whom: Trade Conflict in High-Technology Industries (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics), 1992, pp. 76-82.
    • (1992) Who's Bashing Whom: Trade Conflict in High-technology Industries , pp. 76-82
    • Tyson, L.D.1
  • 80
    • 24244446016 scopus 로고
    • Legislation and national security subcommittee of the committee on government operations
    • July
    • Testimony of Representative Martin Sabo at hearings before Legislation and National Security Subcommittee of the Committee on Government Operations, House of Representatives, 102nd Congress, July 1 and 8, 1992, p. 13.
    • (1992) House of Representatives, 102nd Congress , vol.1-8 , pp. 13
    • Sabo, M.1
  • 82
    • 0039240667 scopus 로고
    • Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon Press
    • Christopher Lazou, Supercomputers and Their Use (Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon Press, 1988), p. 197. For a general review of current U.S. efforts to aid the supercomputer industry, see Congressional Budget Office, Promoting High-Performance Computing and Communications (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office [U.S. GPO], 1993).
    • (1988) Supercomputers and Their Use , pp. 197
    • Lazou, C.1
  • 83
    • 0040424954 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office [U.S. GPO]
    • Christopher Lazou, Supercomputers and Their Use (Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon Press, 1988), p. 197. For a general review of current U.S. efforts to aid the supercomputer industry, see Congressional Budget Office, Promoting High-Performance Computing and Communications (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office [U.S. GPO], 1993).
    • (1993) Promoting High-performance Computing and Communications
  • 84
    • 1842472339 scopus 로고
    • Friends like these: U.S. Gets tough with its trading partners
    • May
    • Susumu Awanohara, "Friends Like These: U.S. Gets Tough with Its Trading Partners," Far Eastern Economic Review, May 13, 1993, p. 74; "The Japanese Public Sector: Problems and Prospects for U.S. Supercomputing Vendors," Cray Report, May 1990, p. 55.
    • (1993) Far Eastern Economic Review , vol.13 , pp. 74
    • Awanohara, S.1
  • 85
    • 0040424956 scopus 로고
    • The japanese public sector: Problems and prospects for U.S. Supercomputing vendors
    • May
    • Susumu Awanohara, "Friends Like These: U.S. Gets Tough with Its Trading Partners," Far Eastern Economic Review, May 13, 1993, p. 74; "The Japanese Public Sector: Problems and Prospects for U.S. Supercomputing Vendors," Cray Report, May 1990, p. 55.
    • (1990) Cray Report , pp. 55
  • 86
    • 0041017940 scopus 로고
    • Japanese procurement of supercomputers an issue of concern to United States
    • "Japanese Procurement of Supercomputers an Issue of Concern to United States," Business America, Vol. 114, No. 7 (1993), p. 15.
    • (1993) Business America , vol.114 , Issue.7 , pp. 15
  • 87
    • 0011405467 scopus 로고
    • Japan: A competitive assessment
    • September
    • David Kahaner and Ulrich Wattenberg, "Japan: A Competitive Assessment," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 42-43; Jack Worlton, "Existing Conditions," in National Academy of Sciences, Supercomputers: Directions in Technology and Applications (Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1989), pp. 42-43.
    • (1992) IEEE Spectrum , vol.29 , Issue.9 , pp. 42-43
    • Kahaner, D.1    Wattenberg, U.2
  • 88
    • 0011405467 scopus 로고
    • Existing conditions
    • Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press
    • David Kahaner and Ulrich Wattenberg, "Japan: A Competitive Assessment," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 42-43; Jack Worlton, "Existing Conditions," in National Academy of Sciences, Supercomputers: Directions in Technology and Applications (Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1989), pp. 42-43.
    • (1989) National Academy of Sciences, Supercomputers: Directions in Technology and Applications , pp. 42-43
    • Worlton, J.1
  • 89
    • 24244435342 scopus 로고
    • Vice president of iEEE, in hearings before legislation and national security subcommittee of the committee on government operations
    • July
    • Testimony of Arvid Larson, Vice President of IEEE, in hearings before Legislation and National Security Subcommittee of the Committee on Government Operations, House of Representatives, 102nd Congress, July 1 and 8, 1992, pp. 118-119.
    • (1992) House of Representatives, 102nd Congress , vol.1-8 , pp. 118-119
    • Larson, A.1
  • 90
    • 0039831280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kozmetsky, "Supercomputers and National Policy," pp. 29, 36-37; Kenneth Wilson, "Science, Industry and the New Japanese Challenge," Proceedings of the IEEE, Vol. 72, No. 1 (January 1984), p. 12; "The Genius," Business Week, pp. 81-83; George Cybenko and David Kuck, "Revolution or Evolution," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 39-40.
    • Supercomputers and National Policy , pp. 29
    • Kozmetsky1
  • 91
    • 0021166524 scopus 로고
    • Science, industry and the new Japanese challenge
    • January
    • Kozmetsky, "Supercomputers and National Policy," pp. 29, 36-37; Kenneth Wilson, "Science, Industry and the New Japanese Challenge," Proceedings of the IEEE, Vol. 72, No. 1 (January 1984), p. 12; "The Genius," Business Week, pp. 81-83; George Cybenko and David Kuck, "Revolution or Evolution," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 39-40.
    • (1984) Proceedings of the IEEE , vol.72 , Issue.1 , pp. 12
    • Wilson, K.1
  • 92
    • 0039831280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The genius
    • Kozmetsky, "Supercomputers and National Policy," pp. 29, 36-37; Kenneth Wilson, "Science, Industry and the New Japanese Challenge," Proceedings of the IEEE, Vol. 72, No. 1 (January 1984), p. 12; "The Genius," Business Week, pp. 81-83; George Cybenko and David Kuck, "Revolution or Evolution," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 39-40.
    • Business Week , pp. 81-83
  • 93
    • 0039831280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revolution or evolution
    • September
    • Kozmetsky, "Supercomputers and National Policy," pp. 29, 36-37; Kenneth Wilson, "Science, Industry and the New Japanese Challenge," Proceedings of the IEEE, Vol. 72, No. 1 (January 1984), p. 12; "The Genius," Business Week, pp. 81-83; George Cybenko and David Kuck, "Revolution or Evolution," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 39-40.
    • (1992) IEEE Spectrum , vol.29 , Issue.9 , pp. 39-40
    • Cybenko, G.1    Kuck, D.2
  • 94
    • 0039831284 scopus 로고
    • Japanese supercomputers: An overview
    • Raul Mendez, ed., West Sussex, U.K.: John Wiley and Sons
    • Raul Mendez, "Japanese Supercomputers: An Overview," in Raul Mendez, ed., High Performance Computing: Research and Practice in Japan (West Sussex, U.K.: John Wiley and Sons, 1992), p. 4.
    • (1992) High Performance Computing: Research and Practice in Japan , pp. 4
    • Mendez, R.1
  • 97
    • 85033736262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mendez, "Japanese Supercomputers," p. 5; Kahaner and Wattenberg, "Japan: A Competitive Assessment," p. 43.
    • Japanese Supercomputers , pp. 5
    • Mendez1
  • 100
    • 85033733532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kahaner and Wattenberg, "Japan: A Competitive Assessment," p. 46; Chen, "Toward the Future," pp. 64-65.
    • Toward the Future , pp. 64-65
    • Chen1
  • 101
    • 84942393230 scopus 로고
    • The power of parallelism
    • September
    • Glen Zorpette, "The Power of Parallelism," IEEE Spectrum, Vol. 29, No. 9 (September 1992), pp. 32-33.
    • (1992) IEEE Spectrum , vol.29 , Issue.9 , pp. 32-33
    • Zorpette, G.1
  • 102
    • 85033732809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Supercomputer systems markets
    • Kirkland and Pierce
    • Lloyd Thorndyke, "Supercomputer Systems Markets," in Kirkland and Pierce, Supercomputers, p. 54.
    • Supercomputers , pp. 54
    • Thorndyke, L.1
  • 103
    • 85033764403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The japanese public sector
    • "The Japanese Public Sector," Cray Report, p. 53.
    • Cray Report , pp. 53
  • 104
    • 85033764403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The japanese public sector
    • "The Japanese Public Sector," Cray Report, p. 53.
    • Cray Report , pp. 53
  • 105
    • 0041017958 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, esp.
    • An obvious question that this argument raises is how to account for the success of the 1989 Treaty on Conventional Armed Forces in Europe (CFE). I argue that the causes of CFE success are the radical domestic changes in, and collapse of, the Soviet Union and WTO. As Richard Falkenrath argues, the Soviet Union under Gorbachev was desperate to shift resources to its failing civilian economy and could not afford to maintain its then-current levels of conventional forces. In essence, the Soviet Union was driven to disregard relative gains because it no longer had the resources to support continued competition with NATO. This led to large-scale unilateral Soviet cuts prior to the beginning to CFE, and capitulation to NATO's demands on CFE. Successful post-MBFR arms control is thus due to the fundamental changes that occurred domestically in the Soviet Union. Had the massive alteration in Soviet domestic politics not taken place, conventional arms control would not have been successful. This event was clearly unique and is outside the scope of this thesis. For an excellent account of CFE, see Richard A. Falkenrath, Shaping Europe's Military Order: The Origins and Consequences of the CFE Treaty (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1995), esp. pp. 22-44.
    • (1995) Shaping Europe's Military Order: The Origins and Consequences of the CFE Treaty , pp. 22-44
    • Falkenrath, R.A.1
  • 106
    • 85033755180 scopus 로고
    • Introduction
    • Robert Blackwill and F. Stephen Larrabee, eds., Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press
    • Robert Blackwill and F. Stephen Larrabee, "Introduction," in Robert Blackwill and F. Stephen Larrabee, eds., Conventional Arms Control and East-West Security (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1989), p. xxiii. It may be true that one implicit aim of MBFR was to keep the United States in Europe and avoid the terms of the Mansfield amendment, but this cannot be seen as a successful case of arms control. On Soviet motives for entering MBFR, see John G. Keliher, The Negotiations on Mutual and Balanced Force Reductions: The Search for Arms Control in Central Europe (New York: Pergamon Press, 1980), p. 145.
    • (1989) Conventional Arms Control and East-West Security
    • Blackwill, R.1    Larrabee, F.S.2
  • 108
  • 109
    • 84928505178 scopus 로고
    • Conceptual problems of conventional arms control
    • Spring
    • Robert Blackwill, "Conceptual Problems of Conventional Arms Control," International Security, Vol. 12, No. 4 (Spring 1988), pp. 40-41.
    • (1988) International Security , vol.12 , Issue.4 , pp. 40-41
    • Blackwill, R.1
  • 110
    • 0039831277 scopus 로고
    • Conventional strategy: New critics, old choices
    • Spring
    • Richard Betts, "Conventional Strategy: New Critics, Old Choices,26quot; International Security, Vol. 7, No. 4 (Spring 1983), p. 141.
    • (1983) International Security , vol.7 , Issue.4 , pp. 141
    • Betts, R.1
  • 112
    • 84926270684 scopus 로고
    • Conventional deterrence and conventional retaliation in Europe
    • Winter
    • Samuel P. Huntington, "Conventional Deterrence and Conventional Retaliation in Europe," International Security, Vol. 8, No. 3 (Winter 1983/84).
    • (1983) International Security , vol.8 , Issue.3
    • Huntington, S.P.1
  • 113
    • 85033741886 scopus 로고
    • Report Mosbach, Germany: AFES-Press
    • See, for example, Malcolm Chalmers and Lutz Unterseher, Is There a Tank Gap? A Comparative Assessment of the Tank Fleets of NATO and the Warsaw Pact, Report No. 20 (Mosbach, Germany: AFES-Press, 1988), p. 57; Andreas von Bulow, "Defensive Entanglement: An Alternative Strategy for NATO," in Andrew J. Pierre, ed., The Conventional Defense of Europe: New Technologies and New Strategies (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1986), pp. 127-128, 141-144.
    • (1988) Is There a Tank Gap? A Comparative Assessment of the Tank Fleets of NATO and the Warsaw Pact , vol.20 , pp. 57
    • Chalmers, M.1    Unterseher, L.2
  • 114
    • 0039239530 scopus 로고
    • Defensive entanglement: An alternative strategy for NATO
    • Andrew J. Pierre, ed., New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press
    • See, for example, Malcolm Chalmers and Lutz Unterseher, Is There a Tank Gap? A Comparative Assessment of the Tank Fleets of NATO and the Warsaw Pact, Report No. 20 (Mosbach, Germany: AFES-Press, 1988), p. 57; Andreas von Bulow, "Defensive Entanglement: An Alternative Strategy for NATO," in Andrew J. Pierre, ed., The Conventional Defense of Europe: New Technologies and New Strategies (New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 1986), pp. 127-128, 141-144.
    • (1986) The Conventional Defense of Europe: New Technologies and New Strategies , pp. 127-128
    • Von Bulow, A.1
  • 115
    • 85033749071 scopus 로고
    • Alliance requirements and the need for conventional force improvements
    • Uwe Nerlich and James A. Thomson, eds., Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press
    • Anthony Cordesman, "Alliance Requirements and the Need for Conventional Force Improvements," in Uwe Nerlich and James A. Thomson, eds., Conventional Arms Control and the Security of Europe (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1988), p. 90.
    • (1988) Conventional Arms Control and the Security of Europe , pp. 90
    • Cordesman, A.1
  • 118
    • 85033743439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conventional arms control revisited: Objectives in the new phase
    • Nerlich and Thomson, eds.
    • James A. Thomson and Nanette C. Gantz, "Conventional Arms Control Revisited: Objectives in the New Phase," in Nerlich and Thomson, eds., Conventional Arms Control, pp. 116-119.
    • Conventional Arms Control , pp. 116-119
    • Thomson, J.A.1    Gantz, N.C.2
  • 119
    • 0039239538 scopus 로고
    • Conventional forces and the NATO strategy of flexible response: Issues and approaches
    • Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND, January
    • Roger L.L. Facer, "Conventional Forces and the NATO Strategy of Flexible Response: Issues and Approaches," RAND Report R-3209-FF (Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND, January 1985), p. 24.
    • (1985) RAND Report R-3209-FF , pp. 24
    • Facer, R.L.L.1
  • 120
    • 85033765185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The military objectives of conventional arms control
    • Blackwill and Larrabee, eds.
    • K.-Peter Stratman, "The Military Objectives of Conventional Arms Control," in Blackwill and Larrabee, eds., Conventional Arms Control, p. 146.
    • Conventional Arms Control , pp. 146
    • Stratman, K.-P.1
  • 121
    • 85033763281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The military balance in Europe
    • Blackwill and Larrabee, eds.
    • Richard Kugler, "The Military Balance in Europe," in Blackwill and Larrabee, eds., Conventional Arms Control, p. 60.
    • Conventional Arms Control , pp. 60
    • Kugler, R.1
  • 123
    • 0041017960 scopus 로고
    • Soviet conventional offensive in Europe
    • For good discussions of Soviet land and air operations in Europe, see Philip Peterson and John Hines, "Soviet Conventional Offensive in Europe," Department of Defense manuscript, 1983; David Glantz, "Future Directions in Soviet Military Strategy," manuscript, 1990.
    • (1983) Department of Defense Manuscript
    • Peterson, P.1    Hines, J.2
  • 124
    • 0039239531 scopus 로고
    • manuscript
    • For good discussions of Soviet land and air operations in Europe, see Philip Peterson and John Hines, "Soviet Conventional Offensive in Europe," Department of Defense manuscript, 1983; David Glantz, "Future Directions in Soviet Military Strategy," manuscript, 1990.
    • (1990) Future Directions in Soviet Military Strategy
    • Glantz, D.1
  • 125
    • 84925979747 scopus 로고
    • Why the soviets can't win quickly in central Europe
    • Summer
    • John Mearsheimer, "Why the Soviets Can't Win Quickly in Central Europe," International Security, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Summer 1982), pp. 27-28; Kim Holmes, "Measuring the Conventional Balance in Europe," International Security, Vol. 12, No. 4 (Spring 1988), pp. 171-172. It was thought by some analysts that NATO forces were at a good force-to-space ratio, and that cuts might jeopardize the ability of the NATO divisions to hold.
    • (1982) International Security , vol.7 , Issue.1 , pp. 27-28
    • Mearsheimer, J.1
  • 126
    • 0040423861 scopus 로고
    • Measuring the conventional balance in Europe
    • Spring
    • John Mearsheimer, "Why the Soviets Can't Win Quickly in Central Europe," International Security, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Summer 1982), pp. 27-28; Kim Holmes, "Measuring the Conventional Balance in Europe," International Security, Vol. 12, No. 4 (Spring 1988), pp. 171-172. It was thought by some analysts that NATO forces were at a good force-to-space ratio, and that cuts might jeopardize the ability of the NATO divisions to hold.
    • (1988) International Security , vol.12 , Issue.4 , pp. 171-172
    • Holmes, K.1
  • 128
    • 0039239540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Killebrew, Conventional Defense and Total Deterrence: Assessing NATO's Strategic Options (Wilmington, Del.: Scholarly Resources, 1986), p. 14; Mearsheimer, "Why the Soviets Can't Win Quickly," pp. 13-14; Mearsheimer, "Numbers, Strategy and the European Balance," p. 175.
    • Why the Soviets Can't Win Quickly , pp. 13-14
    • Mearsheimer1
  • 129
    • 0039063339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Killebrew, Conventional Defense and Total Deterrence: Assessing NATO's Strategic Options (Wilmington, Del.: Scholarly Resources, 1986), p. 14; Mearsheimer, "Why the Soviets Can't Win Quickly," pp. 13-14; Mearsheimer, "Numbers, Strategy and the European Balance," p. 175.
    • Numbers, Strategy and the European Balance , pp. 175
    • Mearsheimer1
  • 130
    • 0041017946 scopus 로고
    • The U.S. Steel trigger price mechanism: Import impact and strategic response
    • For instance, while in 1947 U.S. steel manufacturers held 57 percent of world market share, by 1984 it had dropped to 11.8 percent. Aspy P. Palia, "The U.S. Steel Trigger Price Mechanism: Import Impact and Strategic Response," Akron Business Review, Vol. 21, No. 2 (1990), p. 46.
    • (1990) Akron Business Review , vol.21 , Issue.2 , pp. 46
    • Palia, A.P.1
  • 135
    • 84970486674 scopus 로고
    • State Autonomy and societal pressure: The steel industry and U.S. Import policy
    • Andrew Stritch, "State Autonomy and Societal Pressure: The Steel Industry and U.S. Import Policy," Administration and Society, 56ol. 23, No. 3 (1991), p. 299.
    • (1991) Administration and Society , vol.23 , Issue.3 , pp. 299
    • Stritch, A.1
  • 139
    • 85033735638 scopus 로고
    • Producers of steel press for renewal of steel import quotas: Steelmakers praise effects of trade restraints, but users say the price is too high
    • March 25
    • Elizabeth Wehr, "Producers of Steel Press for Renewal of Steel Import Quotas: Steelmakers Praise Effects of Trade Restraints, But Users Say the Price Is Too High," Congressional Quarterly Weekly Report, Vol. 47, No. 12 (March 25, 1989), p. 630.
    • (1989) Congressional Quarterly Weekly Report , vol.47 , Issue.12 , pp. 630
    • Wehr, E.1
  • 140
    • 0040423872 scopus 로고
    • Protection's stepchild
    • May
    • Foreign imports accounted for only 18 percent of the U.S. market at that time. "Protection's Stepchild," Economist, May 16, 1992, p. 98.
    • (1992) Economist , vol.16 , pp. 98
  • 144
    • 0040423870 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press
    • Steel Panel Committee on Technology and International Economic and Trade Issues of the Foreign Secretary of the National Academy of Engineering, The Competitive Status of the U.S. Steel Industry (Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1985), p. 5.
    • (1985) The Competitive Status of the U.S. Steel Industry , pp. 5
  • 146
    • 0027718443 scopus 로고
    • The diffusion of process innovations in industrialized and developing countries: A case study of the world textile and steel industries
    • Matthias Lucke, "The Diffusion of Process Innovations in Industrialized and Developing Countries: A Case Study of the World Textile and Steel Industries," World Development, Vol. 21, No. 7 (1993), pp. 1228-1229.
    • (1993) World Development , vol.21 , Issue.7 , pp. 1228-1229
    • Lucke, M.1
  • 147
    • 0039239527 scopus 로고
    • Big steel's big opportunity
    • January
    • Stephen Baker, "Big Steel's Big Opportunity," Business Week, January 10, 1994, p. 74; "Protection's Stepchild," p. 98.
    • (1994) Business Week , vol.10 , pp. 74
    • Baker, S.1
  • 148
    • 85033746107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephen Baker, "Big Steel's Big Opportunity," Business Week, January 10, 1994, p. 74; "Protection's Stepchild," p. 98.
    • Rotection's Stepchild , pp. 98
  • 149
    • 0039239528 scopus 로고
    • Strategic arms control, 1967-1987
    • Alexander George, Philip Farley, and Alexander Dallin, eds., New York: Oxford University Press
    • Reviews of U.S.-Soviet nuclear arms control abound. This discussion uses primarily Philip Farley, "Strategic Arms Control, 1967-1987," in Alexander George, Philip Farley, and Alexander Dallin, eds., U.S.-Soviet Security Cooperation: Achievements, Failures, Lessons (New York: Oxford University Press, 1988), pp. 215-253.
    • (1988) U.S.-Soviet Security Cooperation: Achievements, Failures, Lessons , pp. 215-253
    • Farley, P.1
  • 150
    • 84925927540 scopus 로고
    • Do negotiated arms limitations have a future?
    • See, for example, Barry Blechman, "Do Negotiated Arms Limitations Have a Future?" Foreign Affairs, Vol. 59, No. 1 (1980), pp. 108-109.
    • (1980) Foreign Affairs , vol.59 , Issue.1 , pp. 108-109
    • Blechman, B.1
  • 151
    • 85033749180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is true that both the United States and the Soviet Union indicated a desire for some sort of offensive capability. For the Soviets, this essentially took the form of a war-fighting strategy with counter-value targeting by heavy ICBMs. For the Americans, war-fighting was offered as an option, and the possibility of fielding a ballistic missile defense system was urged.
  • 152
    • 85033752389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SALT and the search for a security regime
    • George, Farley, and Dallin, eds.
    • As Condoleezza Rice argues, mutual deterrence and the inability to win a nuclear war were key elements to the success of arms control. Condoleezza Rice, "SALT and the Search for a Security Regime," in George, Farley, and Dallin, eds., U.S.-Soviet Security Cooperation, pp. 295-296.
    • U.S.-Soviet Security Cooperation , pp. 295-296
    • Rice, C.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.