메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 66, Issue 3, 2014, Pages 545-610

The no-reading problem in consumer contract law

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84897523182     PISSN: 00389765     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (156)

References (278)
  • 2
    • 84897479849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Apple Scraps Controversial Terms in iBook Author EULA Agreement
    • note
    • John P. Mello Jr., Apple Scraps Controversial Terms in iBook Author EULA Agreement, TechHive (Feb. 3, 2012, 5:29 PM), http://www.pcworld.com/article/ 249303/apple_scraps_controversial_terms_in_ibook_author_eula_agreement.html. Apple responded to the controversy surrounding its EULA with a modified version only requiring users to sell books created in the iBooks file format through Apple-a meager concession since this is the only format in which a book may be sold through Apple's iBooks Store.
    • (2012) TechHive
    • Mello Jr., J.P.1
  • 3
    • 84897545777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Google on Chrome EULA Controversy: Our Bad, We'll Change It
    • note
    • Nate Anderson, Google on Chrome EULA Controversy: Our Bad, We'll Change It, Ars Technica (Sept. 3, 2008, 12:56 PM PDT), http://arstechnica.com/tech-policy/2008/ 09/google-on-chrome-eula-controversy-our-bad-well-change-it (internal quotation mark omitted).
    • (2008) Ars Technica
    • Anderson, N.1
  • 4
    • 84897521856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It Pays to Read License Agreements
    • note
    • Larry Magid, It Pays to Read License Agreements, PC Pitstop, http://www.pcpitstop.com/spycheck/eula.asp (last visited Feb. 22, 2014).
    • PC Pitstop
    • Magid, L.1
  • 5
    • 84897521856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It Pays to Read License Agreements
    • note
    • Larry Magid, It Pays to Read License Agreements, PC Pitstop, http://www.pcpitstop.com/spycheck/eula.asp (last visited Feb. 22, 2014).
    • PC Pitstop
    • Magid, L.1
  • 6
    • 84897480902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pointless Conditions Should Not Apply: The Sopoforic Legalese of Online Transactions
    • note
    • Lucy Kellaway, Pointless Conditions Should Not Apply: The Sopoforic Legalese of Online Transactions, Fin. Times (Jan. 23, 2011, 8:24 PM), http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/7158c690-2596-11e0-8258-00144feab49a.html# axzz1zPmBwtYm (internal quotation marks omitted). Over 7000 consumers made a purchase from the site that day, all checking a box saying they understood the conditions, and "no one noticed a thing."
    • (2011) Fin. Times
    • Kellaway, L.1
  • 7
    • 79952130559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Will Increased Disclosure Help? Evaluating the Recommendations of the ALI's Principles of the Law of Software Contracts
    • See, e.g., Florencia Marotta-Wurgler, Will Increased Disclosure Help? Evaluating the Recommendations of the ALI's "Principles of the Law of Software Contracts, " 78 U. Chi. L. Rev. 165, 179-81 (2011).
    • (2011) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.78
    • Marotta-Wurgler, F.1
  • 8
    • 84876405205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does Anyone Read the Fine Print?
    • note
    • Yannis Bakos et al., Does Anyone Read the Fine Print? Testing a Law and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts 1 (N.Y.U. Sch. of Law Ctr. for Law, Econ. & Org., Working Paper No. 09-40, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1443256.
    • (2009) Testing a Law and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts , vol.1
    • Bakos, Y.1
  • 9
    • 84876405205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does Anyone Read the Fine Print?
    • note
    • Yannis Bakos et al., Does Anyone Read the Fine Print? Testing a Law and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts 1 (N.Y.U. Sch. of Law Ctr. for Law, Econ. & Org., Working Paper No. 09-40, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1443256.
    • (2009) Testing a Law and Economics Approach to Standard Form Contracts , vol.1
    • Bakos, Y.1
  • 10
    • 79952130559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Will Increased Disclosure Help? Evaluating the Recommendations of the ALI's "Principles of the Law of Software Contracts, "
    • See, e.g., Florencia Marotta-Wurgler, Will Increased Disclosure Help? Evaluating the Recommendations of the ALI's "Principles of the Law of Software Contracts, " 78 U. Chi. L. Rev. 165, 179-81 (2011).
    • (2011) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.78
    • Marotta-Wurgler, F.1
  • 11
    • 84925886334 scopus 로고
    • Duty to Read-A Changing Concept
    • note
    • For an exposition of the duty to read doctrine, see John D. Calamari, Duty to Read-A Changing Concept, 43 Fordham L. Rev. 341 (1974).
    • (1974) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.43 , pp. 341
    • Calamari, J.D.1
  • 12
    • 84897474151 scopus 로고
    • Upton v. Tribilcock
    • note
    • See, e.g., Upton v. Tribilcock, 91 U.S. 45, 50 (1875) ("It will not do for a man to enter into a contract, and, when called upon to respond to its obligations, to say that he did not read it when he signed it, or did not know what it contained.... A contractor must stand by the words of his contract.
    • (1875) U.S. , vol.91
  • 13
    • 84897493238 scopus 로고
    • John Hancock Mut. Life Ins. Co. v. Yates
    • note
    • John Hancock Mut. Life Ins. Co. v. Yates, 299 U.S. 178, 180 (1936) ("[W]hen the insured receives a policy, it is his duty to read it or have it read.... ").
    • (1936) U.S. , vol.299
  • 14
    • 84897519864 scopus 로고
    • Brown v. E.F. Hutton Grp., Inc
    • note
    • Brown v. E.F. Hutton Grp., Inc., 991 F.2d 1020, 1033 (2d Cir. 1993) (holding that allegedly unsophisticated investors' failure to read securities disclosures was "reckless" and precluded them from bringing fraud claim).
    • (1993) F.2d , vol.991
  • 15
    • 84897503975 scopus 로고
    • Rossi v. Douglas
    • note
    • Rossi v. Douglas, 100 A.2d 3, 7 (Md. 1953) ("[O]ne having the capacity to understand a written document who reads it, or, without reading it or having it read to him, signs it, is bound by his signature. "). This obligation applies even to illiterate buyers.
    • (1953) A.2d , vol.100
  • 16
    • 84897511409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Johnnie's Homes, Inc. v. Holt
    • note
    • See, e.g., Johnnie's Homes, Inc. v. Holt, 790 So. 2d 956, 960 (Ala. 2001).
    • (2001) So. 2d , vol.790
  • 17
    • 84897512571 scopus 로고
    • Secoulsky v. Oceanic Steam Nav. Co
    • note
    • Secoulsky v. Oceanic Steam Nav. Co., 112 N.E. 151, 152 (Mass. 1916).
    • (1916) N.E. , vol.112
  • 18
    • 0042237500 scopus 로고
    • Rules, Standards, and the Battle of the Forms: A Reassessment of § 2-207
    • note
    • For additional scholarship on the duty to read, see Douglas G. Baird & Robert Weisberg, Rules, Standards, and the Battle of the Forms: A Reassessment of § 2-207, 68 Va. L. Rev. 1217 (1982).
    • (1982) Va. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 1217
    • Baird, D.G.1    Weisberg, R.2
  • 19
    • 0742271634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability
    • Russell Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1203 (2003).
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1203
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 20
    • 19844369695 scopus 로고
    • Private Legislation and the Duty to Read-Business Run by IBM Machine, the Law of Contracts and Credit Cards
    • Stewart Macaulay, Private Legislation and the Duty to Read-Business Run by IBM Machine, the Law of Contracts and Credit Cards, 19 Vand. L. Rev. 1051 (1966).
    • (1966) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 1051
    • McAulay, S.1
  • 21
    • 84897496077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • McKenna v. Metropolitan Life Insurance Co
    • note
    • For examples of the duty to read applied in the modern consumer contract context, see McKenna v. Metropolitan Life Insurance Co., 126 F. App'x 571, 574 (3d Cir. 2005) (holding that it was "unreasonable" for an insured consumer not to read his insurance policy).
    • (2005) F. App'x , vol.126
  • 22
    • 84897503102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Trade Commission v. IFC Credit Corp
    • note
    • and Federal Trade Commission v. IFC Credit Corp., 543 F. Supp. 2d 925, 947 (N.D. Ill. 2008) (holding that consumers were responsible for reading telecommunications equipment leases).
    • (2008) F. Supp. 2d , vol.543
  • 23
    • 84897482954 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fivey v. Pa. R., 52 A. 472, 473 (N.J. 1902) (emphasis added).
    • (1902) Fivey v. Pa. R. , vol.52
  • 24
    • 84897528953 scopus 로고
    • Lewis v. Great W. Ry
    • note
    • Lewis v. Great W. Ry., (1860) 157 Eng. Rep. 1427 (L.R. Exch.) 1430 (Bramwell B.).
    • (1860) Eng. Rep. , vol.157 , pp. 1427
  • 25
    • 84897510979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5 H. & N. 867, 874.
    • H. & N. , vol.5
  • 26
    • 84897545845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harris v. Green Tree Fin. Corp
    • note
    • See, e.g., Harris v. Green Tree Fin. Corp., 183 F.3d 173, 181 (3d Cir. 1999) (internal quotation mark omitted) ("Procedural unconscionability pertains to the process by which an agreement is reached and the form of an agreement, including the use therein of fine print and convoluted or unclear language. ")
    • (1999) F.3d , vol.183
  • 27
    • 84897494035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Finding Common Ground in the World of Electronic Contracts: The Consistency of Legal Reasoning in Clickwrap Cases
    • note
    • "Clickwrap" generally refers to electronic agreements that automatically present contractual terms to a user and require the user to accept by affirmatively clicking an "I agree" icon. See generally Robert Lee Dickens, Finding Common Ground in the World of Electronic Contracts: The Consistency of Legal Reasoning in Clickwrap Cases, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 379 (2007) (providing a background on "clickwrap").
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , pp. 379
    • Dickens, R.L.1
  • 28
    • 84897474425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specht v. Netscape Commc'ns Corp
    • note
    • See, e.g., Specht v. Netscape Commc'ns Corp., 150 F. Supp. 2d 585, 596 (S.D.N.Y. 2001).
    • (2001) F. Supp. 2d , vol.150
  • 29
    • 84897501619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grosvenor v. Qwest Commc'ns Int'l, Inc
    • note
    • Grosvenor v. Qwest Commc'ns Int'l, Inc., No. 09-cv-2848-WDM-KMT, 2010 WL 3906253, at *2 (D. Colo. Sept. 30, 2010) ("As a rule, a clickwrap is valid where the terms of the agreement appear on the same screen with the button the user must click to accept the terms and proceed with the installation of the product.").
    • (2010) , pp. 2
  • 30
    • 84897529763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TradeComet. com LLC v. Google, Inc
    • note
    • TradeComet. com LLC v. Google, Inc., 693 F. Supp. 2d 370, 377-78 (S.D.N.Y. 2010) (holding that a Google AdWords clickwrap agreement was reasonably communicated where the user had to "click through" the text of the agreement).
    • (2010) F. Supp. 2d , vol.693
  • 31
    • 79951623877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Principles of the Law: Software Contracts § 2.02(c)(1) (2010) (noting that a software contract is enforceable if, inter alia, "the standard form is reasonably accessible electronically prior to initiation of the transfer").
    • (2010) Principles of the Law: Software Contracts
  • 32
    • 84861862408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulating Opt-Out: An Economic Theory of Altering Rules
    • note
    • See, e.g., Ian Ayres, Regulating Opt-Out: An Economic Theory of Altering Rules, 121 Yale L.J. 2032, 2079-80 (2012) (analyzing the Higher Education Opportunity Act of 2008, which employs an altering rule to ensure students are more informed about their loans). Our proposal might be conceived as a kind of altering rule. To write enforceable terms that are in derogation of the expectations of a majority of buyers, mass-market sellers must abide by the enhanced disclosure obligations set out below.
    • (2012) Yale L.J. , vol.121
    • Ayres, I.1
  • 33
    • 77954730433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In North Dakota, for example, a mortgagee may only waive her homestead exemption rights if the mortgage contains a specific statement "printed in a conspicuous manner" and "immediately followed by the date and the signature of the person to indicate that the person is specifically and knowingly waiving the exemption. " N.D. Cent. Code § 47-18-05.1 (2013).
    • (2013) N.D. Cent. Code
  • 34
    • 84897462013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hagwood v. Newton
    • note
    • Hagwood v. Newton, 282 F.3d 285, 291 (4th Cir. 2002).
    • (2002) F.3d , vol.282
  • 35
    • 79952175130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Failure of Mandated Disclosure
    • note
    • See generally Omri Ben-Shahar & Carl E. Schneider, The Failure of Mandated Disclosure, 159 U. Pa. L. Rev. 647, 649 (2011) (providing a survey of mandatory disclosures across different fields).
    • (2011) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.159
    • Ben-Shahar, O.1    Schneider, C.E.2
  • 36
    • 0036327974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age
    • For a general discussion of consumers' failure to read contracts, see Robert A. Hillman & Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age, 77 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 429 (2002).
    • (2002) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 429
    • Hillman, R.A.1    Rachlinski, J.J.2
  • 37
    • 84864795030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Do Consumers Make Choices? A Survey of Evidence
    • note
    • See, e.g., Zakaria Babutsidze, How Do Consumers Make Choices? A Survey of Evidence, 26 J. Econ. Survs. 752, 756 (2012) ("[C]onsumer reports and dealer visits [are] the most widely used source[s] of information. Next come experts' and friends' opinions. Advertising and mass media score considerably lower.... More recent studies find that interpersonal relations are so important that consumers exhibit more faith in information obtained through their friends than the reasonable level. " (citation omitted).
    • (2012) J. Econ. Survs. , vol.26
    • Babutsidze, Z.1
  • 38
    • 0003921180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Google Inc., ZMOT Handbook: Ways to Win Shoppers at the Zero Moment of Truth 46 (2012), available at http://ssl.gstatic.com/think/docs/2012-zmot-handbook_research-studies.pdf ("68% of consumers report using YouTube to browse and research retail companies." (italics omitted).
    • (2012) ZMOT Handbook: Ways to Win Shoppers at the Zero Moment of Truth , pp. 46
  • 39
    • 84860553484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Searching in Choice Mode: Consumer Decision Processes in Product Search with Recommendations
    • note
    • Benedict G.C. Dellaert & Gerald Häubl, Searching in Choice Mode: Consumer Decision Processes in Product Search with Recommendations, 49 J. Marketing Res. 277, 277 (2012) ("[Outside the contracts context, a]n effective means of assisting consumer search is to provide them with recommendations.... Such assistance may be provided by human advisors (e.g., sales assistants, financial advisors, real estate agents), but it is increasingly available in the form of recommendations that are generated automatically by information systems. ").
    • (2012) J. Marketing Res. , vol.49 , pp. 277
    • Dellaert, B.G.C.1    Häubl, G.2
  • 40
    • 84865121471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Observational Learning and Demand for Search Goods
    • note
    • Kenneth Hendricks et al., Observational Learning and Demand for Search Goods, Am. Econ. J.: Microeconomics, Feb. 2012, at 1, 1 ("A consumer's decision to learn about a product can be influenced by the choices of other consumers.... ").
    • (2012) Am. Econ. J.: Microeconomics , pp. 1
    • Hendricks, K.1
  • 41
    • 84872171020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shopping Cost and Brand Exploration in Online Grocery
    • note
    • Andrea Pozzi, Shopping Cost and Brand Exploration in Online Grocery, Am. Econ. J.: Microeconomics, Aug. 2012, at 96, 97 ("E-retailers provide recommendations based on customer[] profiling.... These features can affect product exploration.... [T]hese practices are becoming ubiquitous.... ").
    • (2012) Am. Econ. J.: Microeconomics
    • Pozzi, A.1
  • 42
    • 79952671152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation
    • note
    • There is a separate concern where consumers expect the inclusion of inefficiently unfavorable terms (for example, in the form of supracompetitive back-end fees) that can result when sellers cannot credibly commit to exclude these terms and instead compete by lowering the (front-end) price. Michael S. Barr et al., The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives on Regulation 25, 47 (David Moss & John Cisternino eds., 2009). If consumers expect the terms, they will be correctly priced. Thus, these authors claim that the problem is cognitive error. Our empirical results, reported in Part IV, suggest, however, the possibility of term optimism, which would yield incorrect pricing.
    • (2009) New Perspectives on Regulation
    • Barr, M.S.1
  • 43
    • 84897552146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Part II defines term optimism more precisely. An optimistic term has two features: (i) the consumer is unaware of the term's content.
  • 44
    • 84897475392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • and (ii) the consumer assigns more positive utility or less negative utility to the term than he would have assigned had he known what the term actually does. The text above illustrates the mistakenly high-utility case: the consumer who is unaware of his insurance policy's exclusion clause incorrectly assumes that he is covered for more categories of harm than he is in fact, so he attributes more utility to the insurance contract than the contract actually generates for him.
  • 45
    • 84897514610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As explained below in Part III, the regulatory scheme we propose would encourage sellers to bury expected terms and instruct courts to enforce those terms even though consumers may have lacked a ready means of reading the terms prior to purchase. Our approach, that is, would discourage consumers from reading terms whose substance the consumers expect in favor of reading terms whose presence in the contract would otherwise be regrettably surprising.
  • 46
    • 84871191192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sound Disclosures: Assessing When a Disclosure Is Worthwhile
    • note
    • Recent studies suggest that the appropriate choice of format can materially influence consumer choice. John Kozup et al., Sound Disclosures: Assessing When a Disclosure Is Worthwhile, 31 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 313, 315-16 (2012) ("[R]ecent research suggests that message format has profound effects on different attitudinal, belief, and knowledge variables.... [M]essage characteristics, such as the format of the label, can make a difference... [although] additional research on format specificity is necessary. ").
    • (2012) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.31
    • Kozup, J.1
  • 47
    • 84871191192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sound Disclosures: Assessing When a Disclosure Is Worthwhile
    • note
    • Recent studies suggest that the appropriate choice of format can materially influence consumer choice. John Kozup et al., Sound Disclosures: Assessing When a Disclosure Is Worthwhile, 31 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 313, 315-16 (2012) ("[R]ecent research suggests that message format has profound effects on different attitudinal, belief, and knowledge variables.... [M]essage characteristics, such as the format of the label, can make a difference... [although] additional research on format specificity is necessary. ").
    • (2012) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.31
    • Kozup, J.1
  • 48
    • 84871216822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the Fine Print: The Need for Effective Testing of Mandatory Mortgage Loan Disclosures
    • note
    • Vanessa G. Perry & Pamela M. Blumenthal, Understanding the Fine Print: The Need for Effective Testing of Mandatory Mortgage Loan Disclosures, 31 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 305, 307 (2012) ("[Prior] findings imply that disclosure information, in a clear and simple format, may have a positive effect on decisions.... ").
    • (2012) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.31
    • Perry, V.G.1    Blumenthal, P.M.2
  • 49
    • 84871216822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the Fine Print: The Need for Effective Testing of Mandatory Mortgage Loan Disclosures
    • note
    • Vanessa G. Perry & Pamela M. Blumenthal, Understanding the Fine Print: The Need for Effective Testing of Mandatory Mortgage Loan Disclosures, 31 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 305, 307 (2012) ("[Prior] findings imply that disclosure information, in a clear and simple format, may have a positive effect on decisions.... ").
    • (2012) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.31
    • Perry, V.G.1    Blumenthal, P.M.2
  • 50
    • 84871216822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the Fine Print: The Need for Effective Testing of Mandatory Mortgage Loan Disclosures
    • note
    • Vanessa G. Perry & Pamela M. Blumenthal, Understanding the Fine Print: The Need for Effective Testing of Mandatory Mortgage Loan Disclosures, 31 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 305, 307 (2012) ("[Prior] findings imply that disclosure information, in a clear and simple format, may have a positive effect on decisions.... ").
    • (2012) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.31
    • Perry, V.G.1    Blumenthal, P.M.2
  • 52
    • 0036970577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consenting to Form Contracts
    • Randy E. Barnett, Consenting to Form Contracts, 71 Fordham L. Rev. 627 (2002).
    • (2002) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 627
    • Barnett, R.E.1
  • 54
    • 84923634012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Myth of the "Opportunity to Read" in Contract Law
    • Omri Ben-Shahar, The Myth of the "Opportunity to Read" in Contract Law, 5 Eur. Rev. Cont. L. 1 (2009).
    • (2009) Eur. Rev. Cont. L. , vol.5 , pp. 1
    • Ben-Shahar, O.1
  • 55
    • 84925886334 scopus 로고
    • Duty to Read-A Changing Concept
    • note
    • For an exposition of the duty to read doctrine, see John D. Calamari, Duty to Read-A Changing Concept, 43 Fordham L. Rev. 341 (1974).
    • (1974) Fordham L. Rev. , vol.43 , pp. 341
    • Calamari, J.D.1
  • 56
    • 84937295025 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Cognition and the Limits of Contract
    • Melvin Aron Eisenberg, The Limits of Cognition and the Limits of Contract, 47 Stan. L. Rev. 211 (1995).
    • (1995) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 211
    • Eisenberg, M.A.1
  • 57
    • 0036327974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age
    • For a general discussion of consumers' failure to read contracts, see Robert A. Hillman & Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age, 77 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 429 (2002).
    • (2002) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 429
    • Hillman, R.A.1    Rachlinski, J.J.2
  • 58
    • 0040152237 scopus 로고
    • The Standardizing of Contracts
    • Nathan Isaacs, The Standardizing of Contracts, 27 Yale L.J. 34 (1917).
    • (1917) Yale L.J. , vol.27 , pp. 34
    • Isaacs, N.1
  • 59
    • 0038968074 scopus 로고
    • Contracts of Adhesion-Some Thoughts About Freedom of Contract
    • Friedrich Kessler, Contracts of Adhesion-Some Thoughts About Freedom of Contract, 43 Colum. L. Rev. 629 (1943).
    • (1943) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.43 , pp. 629
    • Kessler, F.1
  • 60
    • 0742271634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability
    • Russell Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1203 (2003).
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1203
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 61
    • 0348209844 scopus 로고
    • Unconscionability and the Code-The Emperor's New Clause
    • Arthur Allen Leff, Unconscionability and the Code-The Emperor's New Clause, 115 U. Pa. L. Rev. 485 (1967).
    • (1967) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.115 , pp. 485
    • Leff, A.A.1
  • 62
    • 79951892871 scopus 로고
    • The Reunification of Contract Law: The Objective Theory of Consumer Form Contracts
    • Michael I. Meyerson, The Reunification of Contract Law: The Objective Theory of Consumer Form Contracts, 47 U. Miami L. Rev. 1263 (1993).
    • (1993) U. Miami L. Rev. , vol.47 , pp. 1263
    • Meyerson, M.I.1
  • 63
    • 0348063225 scopus 로고
    • The Parol Evidence Process and Standardized Agreements Under the Restatement (Second) of Contracts
    • John E. Murray, Jr., The Parol Evidence Process and Standardized Agreements Under the Restatement (Second) of Contracts, 123 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1342 (1975).
    • (1975) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.123 , pp. 1342
    • Murray Jr., J.E.1
  • 64
    • 0042237491 scopus 로고
    • The Standardized Agreement Phenomena in the Restatement (Second) of Contracts
    • John E. Murray, Jr., The Standardized Agreement Phenomena in the Restatement (Second) of Contracts, 67 Cornell L. Rev. 735 (1982).
    • (1982) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.67 , pp. 735
    • Murray Jr., J.E.1
  • 65
    • 77957710787 scopus 로고
    • Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction
    • Todd D. Rakoff, Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction, 96 Harv. L. Rev. 1174 (1983).
    • (1983) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1174
    • Rakoff, T.D.1
  • 66
    • 0040152218 scopus 로고
    • Standard Form Contracts and Democratic Control of Lawmaking Power
    • note
    • W. David Slawson, Standard Form Contracts and Democratic Control of Lawmaking Power, 84 Harv. L. Rev. 529 (1971) [hereinafter Slawson, Standard Form Contracts].
    • (1971) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 529
    • Slawson, W.D.1
  • 67
    • 84883907837 scopus 로고
    • The New Meaning of Contract: The Transformation of Contracts Law by Standard Forms
    • W. David Slawson, The New Meaning of Contract: The Transformation of Contracts Law by Standard Forms, 46 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 21 (1984).
    • (1984) U. Pitt. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 21
    • Slawson, W.D.1
  • 68
    • 84881922375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2
    • James J. White, Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2, 75 Wash. U. L.Q. 315 (1997).
    • (1997) Wash. U. L.Q. , vol.75 , pp. 315
    • White, J.J.1
  • 71
    • 77957710787 scopus 로고
    • Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction
    • Todd D. Rakoff, Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction, 96 Harv. L. Rev. 1174 (1983).
    • (1983) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1174
    • Rakoff, T.D.1
  • 72
    • 77957710787 scopus 로고
    • Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction
    • Todd D. Rakoff, Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction, 96 Harv. L. Rev. 1174 (1983).
    • (1983) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1174
    • Rakoff, T.D.1
  • 73
    • 84897544466 scopus 로고
    • Steven v. Fid. & Cas. Co. of N. Y
    • note
    • See, e.g., Steven v. Fid. & Cas. Co. of N.Y., 377 P.2d 284, 295-98 (Cal. 1962) (providing a canonical example of California's unconscionability doctrine).
    • (1962) P.2d , vol.377
  • 74
    • 0348209844 scopus 로고
    • Unconscionability and the Code-The Emperor's New Clause
    • Arthur Allen Leff, Unconscionability and the Code-The Emperor's New Clause, 115 U. Pa. L. Rev. 485 (1967).
    • (1967) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.115 , pp. 485
    • Leff, A.A.1
  • 75
    • 84883907837 scopus 로고
    • The New Meaning of Contract: The Transformation of Contracts Law by Standard Forms
    • W. David Slawson, The New Meaning of Contract: The Transformation of Contracts Law by Standard Forms, 46 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 21 (1984).
    • (1984) U. Pitt. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 21
    • Slawson, W.D.1
  • 76
    • 84897538925 scopus 로고
    • Lundgren v. Nat'l Bank of Alaska
    • note
    • Such clauses, also known as "dragnet clauses, " typically "state[] that the mortgage will secure not only the debt incurred in the instant mortgage transaction, but in addition all other debts or obligations that are presently owed or may in the future be owed to the mortgagee by the mortgagor. " Restatement (Third) of Prop.: Mortgs. § 2.4 cmt. (1997). While many states enforce these clauses, see, e.g., Lundgren v. Nat'l Bank of Alaska, 756 P.2d 270, 277-78 (Alaska 1987) (surveying the case law of state dragnet enforcement, though ruling against the dragnet clause in the specific case).
    • (1987) P.2d , vol.756
  • 77
    • 84897505644 scopus 로고
    • Citizens & S. DeKalb Bank v. Hicks
    • note
    • Citizens & S. DeKalb Bank v. Hicks, 206 S.E.2d 22, 24 (Ga. 1974).
    • (1974) S.E.2d , vol.206
  • 78
    • 84897499258 scopus 로고
    • Capocasa v. First Nat'l Bank of Stevens Point
    • Capocasa v. First Nat'l Bank of Stevens Point, 154 N.W.2d 271, 274 (Wis. 1967), courts in other states have expressed skepticism over such clauses and, in some circumstances, have refused to enforce them.
    • (1967) N.W.2d , vol.154
  • 79
    • 84897560730 scopus 로고
    • Nat'l Bank of E. Ark. v. Blankenship
    • note
    • Nat'l Bank of E. Ark. v. Blankenship, 177 F. Supp. 667, 673-74 (E.D. Ark. 1959), aff'd, 283 F.2d 574 (8th Cir. 1960).
    • (1959) F. Supp. , vol.177
  • 80
    • 84897528850 scopus 로고
    • Wood v. Parker Square State Bank
    • note
    • Wood v. Parker Square State Bank, 400 S.W.2d 898, 902 (Tex. 1966).
    • (1966) S.W.2d , vol.400
  • 81
    • 84897528329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act of 1994 (HOEPA), Congress restricted the use of mortgage prepayment penalties under federal law. Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act of 1994
    • note
    • In passing the Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act of 1994 (HOEPA), Congress restricted the use of mortgage prepayment penalties under federal law. Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act of 1994, Pub. L. No. 103-325, § 129(c), 108 Stat. 2160, 2192-93 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 1639(c) (2012). According to one recent study, twenty-five states and the District of Columbia have adopted versions of HOEPA. Lei Ding et al., Ctr. for Cmty. Capital, State Anti-Predatory Lending Laws: Impact and Federal Preemption Phase I Descriptive Analysis 12 & n.5 (2009), available at http://ccc.unc.edu/contentitems/558 (listing states with mini-HOEPA statutes).
    • (2012) Stat. , vol.108
  • 82
    • 84897515913 scopus 로고
    • Standard Contracts Law, 5743-1982
    • note
    • Standard Contracts Law, 5743-1982, 37 LSI 6 (1982-1983) (Isr.). The Israeli statute grants a special tribunal, the Standard Contracts Tribunal, the power to review potentially unfair contract terms ex ante, outside the litigation context and often at the request of a seller seeking certification of his contract. Id. at 6. The statute further lists presumptively unfair contract terms, including waiver of all liability, unilateral ability to change or set price terms, and restrictions on a customer's legal remedies (e.g., mandatory arbitration). Id. at 6-7. For further discussion of Israeli contract law.
    • (1982) LSI , vol.37 , pp. 6
  • 83
    • 84881929221 scopus 로고
    • Controlling Standard Contracts-The Israeli Version
    • Sinai Deutch, Controlling Standard Contracts-The Israeli Version, 30 McGill L.J. 458 (1985).
    • (1985) McGill L.J. , vol.30 , pp. 458
    • Deutch, S.1
  • 84
    • 84897556750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Israel
    • note
    • and Jonathan Yovel & Yoseph M. Edrey, Israel, in 3 International Contract Manual 60-1 (Albert H. Kritzer et al. eds., 2008). Thailand has enacted similar legislation outlining certain presumptively unfair, unenforceable terms.
    • (2008) International Contract Manual , vol.3 , pp. 60-61
    • Yovel, J.1    Edrey, Y.M.2
  • 85
    • 84897482048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Unfair Contract Terms Act, B.E. 2540 (1997), ThaiLaws. com, http://thailaws.com/law/t_laws/tlaw0319.pdf (last visited Feb. 22, 2014).
    • (1997) Unfair Contract Terms Act, B.E. , pp. 2540
  • 86
    • 84897505803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, Interactive Brokers has an innovative contract with its retail investor customers under which customers who buy on margin contractually waive the right to receive a telephonic margin call. Interactive Brokers LLC, Interactive Brokers LLC Agreements and Disclosure Documents 194, available at http://www.interactivebrokers.com/download/IB_LLC_Agreements_and_Disclosure_Packag e.pdf ("IB Will Not Issue Margin Calls: IB does not have to notify Customer of any failure to meet Margin Requirements prior to IB exercising its rights under this Agreement. Customer acknowledges that IB generally will not issue margin calls.
    • Interactive Brokers LLC Agreements and Disclosure Documents , pp. 194
  • 87
    • 84897517823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Generally will not credit Customer's account to meet intraday or overnight margin deficiencies.
  • 88
    • 84897505803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, Interactive Brokers has an innovative contract with its retail investor customers under which customers who buy on margin contractually waive the right to receive a telephonic margin call. Interactive Brokers LLC, Interactive Brokers LLC Agreements and Disclosure Documents 194, available at http://www.interactivebrokers.com/download/IB_LLC_Agreements_and_Disclosure_Packag e.pdf ("IB Will Not Issue Margin Calls: IB does not have to notify Customer of any failure to meet Margin Requirements prior to IB exercising its rights under this Agreement. Customer acknowledges that IB generally will not issue margin calls.
    • Interactive Brokers LLC Agreements and Disclosure Documents , pp. 194
  • 89
    • 84897549984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Notwithstanding these concerns, one of the authors believes that both ex ante and ex post substantive protections, if properly crafted, can usefully complement the reforms suggested in this Article.
  • 94
    • 34547380292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a Fairer Model of Consumer Assent to Standard Form Contracts: In Defense of Restatement Subsection 211(3)
    • note
    • Wayne R. Barnes, Toward a Fairer Model of Consumer Assent to Standard Form Contracts: In Defense of Restatement Subsection 211(3), 82 Wash. L. Rev. 227, 249 (2007) ("In this subsection, the 'other party' is almost invariably the business that drafted the standard form, and the party which appears to manifest assent is the consumer entering into the transaction with the business. ").
    • (2007) Wash. L. Rev. , vol.82
    • Barnes, W.R.1
  • 97
    • 79551479617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Interdisciplinary Critique of the Reasonable Expectations Doctrine
    • E.g., Jeffrey E. Thomas, An Interdisciplinary Critique of the Reasonable Expectations Doctrine, 5 Conn. Ins. L.J. 295, 303 (1998).
    • (1998) Conn. Ins. L.J. , vol.5
    • Thomas, J.E.1
  • 98
    • 84881922375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2
    • James J. White, Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2, 75 Wash. U. L.Q. 315 (1997).
    • (1997) Wash. U. L.Q. , vol.75 , pp. 315
    • White, J.J.1
  • 99
    • 34547380292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a Fairer Model of Consumer Assent to Standard Form Contracts: In Defense of Restatement Subsection 211(3)
    • note
    • Wayne R. Barnes, Toward a Fairer Model of Consumer Assent to Standard Form Contracts: In Defense of Restatement Subsection 211(3), 82 Wash. L. Rev. 227, 249 (2007) ("In this subsection, the 'other party' is almost invariably the business that drafted the standard form, and the party which appears to manifest assent is the consumer entering into the transaction with the business. ").
    • (2007) Wash. L. Rev. , vol.82
    • Barnes, W.R.1
  • 101
    • 84881922375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2
    • James J. White, Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2, 75 Wash. U. L.Q. 315 (1997).
    • (1997) Wash. U. L.Q. , vol.75 , pp. 315
    • White, J.J.1
  • 102
    • 84897505243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unidroit Principles of Int'l Commercial Contracts art. 2.1.20
    • Unidroit Principles of Int'l Commercial Contracts art. 2.1.20 (Int'l Inst. for the Unification of Private Law 2010).
    • (2010) Int'l Inst. for the Unification of Private Law
  • 103
    • 84881922375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2
    • James J. White, Form Contracts Under Revised Article 2, 75 Wash. U. L.Q. 315 (1997).
    • (1997) Wash. U. L.Q. , vol.75 , pp. 315
    • White, J.J.1
  • 104
    • 84897568769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principles of the Law: Software Contracts ch. 2, topic 2
    • note
    • Principles of the Law: Software Contracts ch. 2, topic 2, summary overview (2010) (footnote omitted).
    • (2010) Summary overview
  • 105
    • 84897568769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principles of the Law: Software Contracts ch. 2, topic 2
    • note
    • Principles of the Law: Software Contracts ch. 2, topic 2, summary overview (2010) (footnote omitted).
    • (2010) Summary overview
  • 106
    • 84897491852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The goals of promoting autonomy and efficiency may at times diverge. While we emphasize the efficiency-enhancing effects of our proposal, autonomy advocates might embrace our proposal because it is less likely to bind consumers to unfavorable terms that they did not expect.
  • 107
    • 77957710787 scopus 로고
    • Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction
    • Todd D. Rakoff, Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction, 96 Harv. L. Rev. 1174 (1983).
    • (1983) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1174
    • Rakoff, T.D.1
  • 108
    • 84897473776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • But a term does not become invisible merely because it was presented by the drafting party on a take-it-or-leave-it basis. If we follow the dynamics of the practice we have investigated, we must also include within the set of visible terms those for which a large proportion of adherents (although not necessarily all) may be expected to have shopped.
  • 109
    • 77957710787 scopus 로고
    • Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction
    • Todd D. Rakoff, Contracts of Adhesion: An Essay in Reconstruction, 96 Harv. L. Rev. 1174 (1983).
    • (1983) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.96 , pp. 1174
    • Rakoff, T.D.1
  • 110
    • 84867512212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit Card Pricing: The Card Act and Beyond
    • Myopia is asserted to cause state-of-the-world mistakes in connection with credit card contracts in Oren Bar-Gill & Ryan Bubb, Credit Card Pricing: The Card Act and Beyond, 97 Cornell L. Rev. 967, 976 (2012).
    • (2012) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.97
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Bubb, R.2
  • 111
    • 78650481543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exploiting Naïvete About Self-Control in the Credit Market
    • note
    • Present bias is said to cause consumer mistakes in connection with credit card contracts in Paul Heidhues & Botond Ko{double acute}szegi, Exploiting Naïvete About Self-Control in the Credit Market, 100 Am. Econ. Rev. 2279 (2010). Heidhues & Ko{double acute}szegi and Bar-Gill & Bubb implicitly assume that consumers know what their contracts say.
    • (2010) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.100 , pp. 2279
    • Heidhues, P.1    Koszegi, B.2
  • 112
    • 84921546652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • State-of-the-world inefficiency may present itself broadly. For example, a consumer fails to understand a transaction's consequences if she underestimates her cell phone use, the likelihood of her defaulting on a loan, or the probability that a product is defective. Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Contract: Law, Economics, and Psychology in Consumer Markets 7 (2012) (noting that one of the main "tenets" of "behavioraleconomics theory" assumes that "[c]onsumers' purchasing and use decisions are affected by systematic misperceptions").
    • (2012) Seduction by Contract: Law, Economics, and Psychology in Consumer Markets , pp. 7
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 113
    • 84897542634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How to Rematch: Share Your Best Practices
    • note
    • One might, however, imagine extending our proposal to require enhanced warning to correct state-of-the-world optimism. Thus, for example, au pair providers might inquire into whether clients have systematically optimistic views about the probability of having to "rematch" (i.e., send away an initial au pair from your family and seek a replacement). CV Harquail, How to Rematch: Share Your Best Practices, AuPairMom (Apr. 16, 2013), http://aupairmom.com/how-to-rematch-share-your-best-practices/2013/04/16/celiaharquail. Indeed, one might imagine using seller substantiation and disclosure to respond to other forms of optimism-including attribute optimism (e.g., consumers mistakenly believe their iPhone screen will not scratch) and competition optimism (e.g., consumers mistakenly believe their cell phone contract is less expensive than those offered by competitors).
    • (2013) AuPairMom
    • Harquail, C.V.1
  • 114
    • 84872844230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When Does a Firm Disclose Product Information?
    • Frédéric Koessler & Régis Renault, When Does a Firm Disclose Product Information?, 43 RAND J. Econ. 630, 631-32 (2012).
    • (2012) RAND J. Econ. , vol.43
    • Koessler, F.1    Renault, R.2
  • 115
    • 84897540701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Regarding this notation, a partly informed consumer knows ti terms where i ε [1, T-1]. In the example above, i = 2.
  • 116
    • 84866312639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Diagnosing Consumer Confusion and Sub-Optimal Shopping Effort: Theory and Mortgage-Market Evidence
    • note
    • A consumer's total cost of search comprises the cost of comparing the contracts of competing firms and the cost of learning about the associated contracts. When search costs, so defined, are zero, competition compels firms to offer efficient contracts. Search costs are often positive, however, and can disadvantage consumers. As an example, one recent study found that borrowers sacrifice at least $1000 by not shopping around enough for mortgage brokers. Susan E. Woodward & Robert E. Hall, Diagnosing Consumer Confusion and Sub-Optimal Shopping Effort: Theory and Mortgage-Market Evidence, 102 Am. Econ. Rev. 3249, 3249 (2012).
    • (2012) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.102 , pp. 3249
    • Woodward, S.E.1    Hall, R.E.2
  • 117
    • 84897522200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We constrain the seller to offer the same contract to everyone because we are interested in how heterogeneous buyer expectations affect contract content. This assumption rules out price discrimination. We note that consumers in the model differ in two dimensions: as said above, they hold different beliefs about contract content, and some care more about contract quality than others do.
  • 118
    • 84897524409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As an example of what these inequalities represent, consumers get more utility from a broader warranty than from a narrower warranty, but a broader warranty is more costly for the seller to offer.
  • 119
    • 84897492535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We assume for convenience that consumers value the product equally but have different preferences over the associated contract.
  • 120
    • 84897476647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We omit subscripts for convenience.
  • 121
    • 84873321089 scopus 로고
    • Monopoly, Quality, and Regulation
    • note
    • This proposition parallels an analogous result of A. Michael Spence, Monopoly, Quality, and Regulation, 6 Bell J. Econ. 417 (1975), which demonstrates that monopolists maximize profits by attending to quality preferences of the marginal, and not the average, purchaser.
    • (1975) Bell J. Econ. , vol.6 , pp. 417
    • Spence, A.M.1
  • 122
    • 47749109068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Much Irrationality Does the Market Permit?
    • Alan Schwartz, How Much Irrationality Does the Market Permit?, 37 J. Legal Stud. 131, 149 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Legal Stud. , vol.37
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 123
    • 84897479287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The consumer derives positive utility from the terms she knows because, we assume, people do not knowingly purchase negative utility contracts.
  • 124
    • 84897522591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • When the seller has market power, excess (net optimistic) demand may at times counteract the deadweight loss of supracompetitive pricing.
  • 125
    • 84897520384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As an example, the seller inserts an inconvenient forum selection clause.
  • 126
    • 84897507572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As said above, the argument in the text is a game-theoretic way to derive the result in the benchmark case that contract quality is inefficiently low because inframarginal/average consumers value contract quality more than marginal consumers.
  • 127
    • 84897558770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The model's results continue to hold when contracts are disaggregated given a severability assumption. The assumption holds that the consumer's demand for a particular term is independent of her demand for other terms. To illustrate, let a contract have two terms: a price and a warranty, which we denote w. Accordingly, k = w and the analysis proceeds as above: the contract is degraded if the warranty is narrowed. Severability apparently is a plausible assumption in many contexts. Regarding the warranty example, the consumer's demand for a warranty should not be affected by how she finances the purchase or whether she would be penalized for prepaying the loan. As an example of how general the severability assumption is, let term y in the Facebook EULA permit Facebook to collect information from a consumer's posts but permit the consumer to delete those posts. Facebook then adds term z, which permits it to share widely the information in any undeleted post. Though there now are two terms, severability would not be violated: the addition of term z makes term y less desirable, so term z is just the method for degrading term y. In the language above, the consumer's demand for term y is partly a function of her belief that she has control over term y. Therefore, her demand falls-the contract is relevantly degraded-when her control is reduced.
  • 128
    • 84872248693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Salience in Quality Disclosure: Evidence from the U.S. News College Rankings
    • note
    • Michael Luca & Jonathan Smith, Salience in Quality Disclosure: Evidence from the U.S. News College Rankings, 22 J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy 58, 58 (2013).
    • (2013) J. Econ. & Mgmt. Strategy , vol.22 , pp. 58
    • Luca, M.1    Smith, J.2
  • 129
    • 84897540899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As said above, consumers seldom actually read contracts. Consumers can ask friends or consult Internet rankings to see if a product or service they like comes with favored or disfavored terms. Firms, we assume, can affect these extracontractual channels to create salience. For convenience, the text sometimes refers to the first or the second page of a contract or the like. These references may be taken as metaphor. The key assumption is that salience is partly within a seller's control.
  • 130
    • 79955025759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Procedural Analysis of Choice Rules with Applications to Bounded Rationality
    • note
    • The analysis here follows Yuval Salant, Procedural Analysis of Choice Rules with Applications to Bounded Rationality, 101 Am. Econ. Rev. 724, 737 (2011).
    • (2011) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.101
    • Salant, Y.1
  • 131
    • 84897498005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We note that stopping short can be rational when it is costly to search. Part III. A introduces costly search into the consumer's learning problem when discussing the efficacy of our warning box proposal.
  • 132
    • 84897559059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For convenience, we ignore indifference and assume transitivity.
  • 133
    • 84897514499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We use the word "important" in two senses. A term is "important" if consumers care about the term and sellers know they care. The warranty and the price usually are important in this sense. A term also is "important" if the term is not salient to consumers, but likely would affect their behavior if the term were made salient. Our proposal focuses on terms that are important in this second sense.
  • 134
    • 84897533771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This logic applies regardless of the size of the consumer's search set. We ignore the case in which the consumer observes two terms she likes and one that has negative utility, but buys because the good outweighs the bad. This consumer is informed and better off on net by buying.
  • 135
    • 84879963522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Static Versus Dynamic Disclosures, and How Not to Judge Their Success or Failure
    • note
    • Disclosure probably should ignore the consumers who prefer terms tc and td because disclosure would make these terms salient and thus possibly decrease the salience of the terms that a substantial number of consumers prefer. This could worsen the information environment overall. For an analysis of this heterogeneity concern, see Richard Craswell, Static Versus Dynamic Disclosures, and How Not to Judge Their Success or Failure, 88 Wash. L. Rev. 333, 345-54 (2013). As the text above suggests, increasing competition is a better response.
    • (2013) Wash. L. Rev. , vol.88
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 136
    • 79952208502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standardization as a Solution to the Reading Costs of Form Contracts
    • note
    • Abraham Wickelgren has an analysis that is similar to ours. Abraham L. Wickelgren, Standardization as a Solution to the Reading Costs of Form Contracts, 167 J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. 30 (2011). He argues that if firms offer the efficient contract, consumers need not read it to deter deviations.
    • (2011) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.167 , pp. 30
    • Wickelgren, A.L.1
  • 137
    • 79952208502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standardization as a Solution to the Reading Costs of Form Contracts
    • note
    • Abraham Wickelgren has an analysis that is similar to ours. Abraham L. Wickelgren, Standardization as a Solution to the Reading Costs of Form Contracts, 167 J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. 30 (2011). He argues that if firms offer the efficient contract, consumers need not read it to deter deviations.
    • (2011) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.167 , pp. 30
    • Wickelgren, A.L.1
  • 138
    • 84897545263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We argue that sellers should warn about unfavorable terms that fifty percent or more of consumers do not anticipate. Sellers also should warn about terms that fewer than fifty percent of consumers mistake if the mistake imposes large losses on the consumers who make it. Terms that induce such mistakes likely reduce welfare as much as less grave terms that half or more of consumers mistake.
  • 140
    • 79551479617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Interdisciplinary Critique of the Reasonable Expectations Doctrine
    • E.g., Jeffrey E. Thomas, An Interdisciplinary Critique of the Reasonable Expectations Doctrine, 5 Conn. Ins. L.J. 295, 303 (1998).
    • (1998) Conn. Ins. L.J. , vol.5
    • Thomas, J.E.1
  • 141
    • 51249120894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do Borrowers Know Their Mortgage Terms?
    • note
    • Brian Bucks & Karen Pence, Do Borrowers Know Their Mortgage Terms?, 64 J. Urb. Econ. 218 (2008) (comparing mortgage borrowers' perceptions of loan terms as reflected in the 2001 Survey of Consumer Finances with lenders' reports of mortgage terms in the 2001 Residential Finance Survey).
    • (2008) J. Urb. Econ. , vol.64 , pp. 218
    • Bucks, B.1    Pence, K.2
  • 145
    • 77956098018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Failure and Promise of Mandated Consumer Mortgage Disclosures: Evidence from Qualitative Interviews and a Controlled Experiment with Mortgage Borrowers
    • James M. Lacko & Janis K. Pappalardo, The Failure and Promise of Mandated Consumer Mortgage Disclosures: Evidence from Qualitative Interviews and a Controlled Experiment with Mortgage Borrowers, 100 Am. Econ. Rev. (Papers & Proc.) 516, 518-19 (2010).
    • (2010) Am. Econ. Rev. (Papers & Proc.) , vol.100
    • Lacko, J.M.1    Pappalardo, J.K.2
  • 146
    • 79551483813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Helping Law Catch Up to Markets: Applying Broker-Dealer Law to Subprime Mortgages
    • note
    • Jonathan Macey et al., Helping Law Catch Up to Markets: Applying Broker-Dealer Law to Subprime Mortgages, 34 J. Corp. L. 789, 816 (2009) (discussing the New York Stock Exchange's "Know Thy Customer Rule").
    • (2009) J. Corp. L. , vol.34
    • Macey, J.1
  • 148
    • 84859750873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Product-Use Information and the Limits of Voluntary Disclosure
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Oliver Board, Product-Use Information and the Limits of Voluntary Disclosure, 14 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 235, 236-37 (2012).
    • (2012) Am. L. & Econ. Rev. , vol.14
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Board, O.2
  • 149
    • 84887364220 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Restatement (Second) of Contracts §§ 153, 211 (1981) (articulating, respectively, the doctrine of unilateral mistake and the standardized agreement rule, which holds that if another party has reason to believe that the party manifesting assent would not do so if he knew that the writing contained a particular term, then the term is not part of the agreement).
    • (1981) Restatement (Second) of Contracts , pp. 211
  • 150
    • 0031321542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining with Imperfect Information: A Study of Worker Perceptions of Legal Protection in an At-Will World
    • note
    • The concept of term substantiation might in some contexts be extended to the idea of substantiating that consumers do not hold optimistic views about the content of legal default rules. For example, Pauline Kim has argued that employees hold systematically optimistic beliefs about the default terms of at-will employment contracts. Pauline T. Kim, Bargaining with Imperfect Information: A Study of Worker Perceptions of Legal Protection in an At-Will World, 83 Cornell L. Rev. 105, 147 (1997).
    • (1997) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.83
    • Kim, P.T.1
  • 151
    • 0031321542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining with Imperfect Information: A Study of Worker Perceptions of Legal Protection in an At-Will World
    • note
    • The concept of term substantiation might in some contexts be extended to the idea of substantiating that consumers do not hold optimistic views about the content of legal default rules. For example, Pauline Kim has argued that employees hold systematically optimistic beliefs about the default terms of at-will employment contracts. Pauline T. Kim, Bargaining with Imperfect Information: A Study of Worker Perceptions of Legal Protection in an At-Will World, 83 Cornell L. Rev. 105, 147 (1997).
    • (1997) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.83
    • Kim, P.T.1
  • 152
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 163
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 155
    • 84891388238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Failed Promise of the UCITA Mass-Market Concept and Its Lessons for Policing of Standard-Form Contracts
    • note
    • See generally Jean Braucher, The Failed Promise of the UCITA Mass-Market Concept and Its Lessons for Policing of Standard-Form Contracts, 7 J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. 393 (2003) (arguing that UCITA's definition of "mass-market" is too narrow).
    • (2003) J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. , vol.7 , pp. 393
    • Braucher, J.1
  • 156
    • 84897562784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 13 C.F.R. § 121.101 (2013).
    • (2013) C.F.R. , vol.13
  • 157
    • 84855412830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.S. Small Bus. Admin., SBA Size Standards Methodology 7 (2009), available at http://www.sba.gov/sites/default/files/ size_standards_methodology.pdf.
    • (2009) SBA Size Standards Methodology , pp. 7
  • 159
    • 84897506341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., 13 C.F.R. § 123.403. There are, of course, many other ways in which businesses are distinguished based on size: the census employs a model (also using NAICS data) based on number of employees
    • C.F.R. , vol.13
  • 161
    • 84897545447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revised Jurisdictional Thresholds for Section 7A of the Clayton Act
    • note
    • the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act requires merger registration only for transactions above a certain dollar-value threshold (currently $75.9 million), see Revised Jurisdictional Thresholds for Section 7A of the Clayton Act, 79 Fed. Reg. 3814 (Jan. 23, 2014).
    • (2014) Fed. Reg. , vol.79 , pp. 3814
  • 162
    • 84897559712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A mass-market contractor who failed to conduct an adequate substantiation study would be subject to an enforcement action by either a state or federal consumer protection agency, and regulators might create a presumption that willfully unsubstantiated terms are voidable at the consumers' option unless the mass-market contractor can bring forth sufficient evidence to establish that the term in question met or exceeded the median consumer's expectation.
  • 163
    • 0005369389 scopus 로고
    • The Irrelevance of Information Overload: An Analysis of Search and Disclosure
    • note
    • The analysis that follows extends the analysis in Part II. D by making explicit the search cost aspect of the consumer's optimization problem. For an early showing that information overload does not occur when disclosure increases the net gain from searching, see David M. Grether et al., The Irrelevance of Information Overload: An Analysis of Search and Disclosure, 59 S. Cal. L. Rev. 277 (1986).
    • (1986) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 277
    • Grether, D.M.1
  • 164
    • 84897557704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Studies, including ours, show that consumers are aware of many terms in common contracts and have pessimistic expectations about a subset of the rest. Joshua Mitts, An Experimental Evaluation of Term Substantiation 1 (Oct. 13, 2013) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors).
    • (2013) An Experimental Evaluation of Term Substantiation , pp. 1
    • Mitts, J.1
  • 165
    • 84864795030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Do Consumers Make Choices? A Survey of Evidence
    • note
    • See, e.g., Zakaria Babutsidze, How Do Consumers Make Choices? A Survey of Evidence, 26 J. Econ. Survs. 752, 756 (2012) ("[C]onsumer reports and dealer visits [are] the most widely used source[s] of information. Next come experts' and friends' opinions. Advertising and mass media score considerably lower.... More recent studies find that interpersonal relations are so important that consumers exhibit more faith in information obtained through their friends than the reasonable level. " (citation omitted).
    • (2012) J. Econ. Survs. , vol.26
    • Babutsidze, Z.1
  • 166
    • 84897545446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are serious difficulties in eliciting information about term importance. Consumers who hold inaccurate views about term content may not be able to say how important a term is until they know how their beliefs are wrong. Accordingly, it might be appropriate to iteratively elicit information on term importance from mistaken consumers only after they are informed about the actual content of the contract.
  • 167
    • 84897527490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As indicated below, validation has a dynamic aspect: warnings should change with changes in consumer knowledge and contract content.
  • 168
    • 0012102814 scopus 로고
    • Regulating Deceptive Advertising: The Role of Cost-Benefit Analysis
    • Regulators should be concerned about the possibility that warnings overshoot and cause optimistic consumers to be overly pessimistic about the terms of the contract. Similar concerns have arisen with regard to "corrective advertising. " Richard Craswell, Regulating Deceptive Advertising: The Role of Cost-Benefit Analysis, 64 S. Cal. L. Rev. 549, 567 (1991) (discussing cost-benefit concerns of corrective advertising).
    • (1991) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.64
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 169
    • 84859048517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blind Consent? A Social Psychological Investigation of Non-Readership of Click-Through Agreements
    • Victoria C. Plaut & Robert P. Bartlett, III, Blind Consent? A Social Psychological Investigation of Non-Readership of Click-Through Agreements, 36 Law & Hum. Behav. 293, 300 (2012).
    • (2012) Law & Hum. Behav. , vol.36
    • Plaut, V.C.1    Bartlett III, R.P.2
  • 170
    • 84897557704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Studies, including ours, show that consumers are aware of many terms in common contracts and have pessimistic expectations about a subset of the rest. Joshua Mitts, An Experimental Evaluation of Term Substantiation 1 (Oct. 13, 2013) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors).
    • (2013) An Experimental Evaluation of Term Substantiation , pp. 1
    • Mitts, J.1
  • 171
    • 84897557704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Studies, including ours, show that consumers are aware of many terms in common contracts and have pessimistic expectations about a subset of the rest. Joshua Mitts, An Experimental Evaluation of Term Substantiation 1 (Oct. 13, 2013) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors).
    • (2013) An Experimental Evaluation of Term Substantiation , pp. 1
    • Mitts, J.1
  • 172
    • 84897567895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The seller can treat this kind of term as "expected, " making it enforceable even if buried. The warning waiver concept is implied by our focus on the disclosure of terms that may have affected consumer choice if correctly perceived. Consumers who eschew notice of particular terms would not have changed their purchase behavior were those terms brought to their attention.
  • 173
    • 0036327974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age
    • Robert A. Hillman & Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age, 77 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 429 (2002).
    • (2002) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 429
    • Hillman, R.A.1    Rachlinski, J.J.2
  • 174
    • 0036327974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age
    • For a general discussion of consumers' failure to read contracts, see Robert A. Hillman & Jeffrey J. Rachlinski, Standard-Form Contracting in the Electronic Age, 77 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 429 (2002).
    • (2002) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 429
    • Hillman, R.A.1    Rachlinski, J.J.2
  • 175
    • 84928847393 scopus 로고
    • A Critique of the Reasonable Expectations Doctrine
    • note
    • Stephen J. Ware, Comment, A Critique of the Reasonable Expectations Doctrine, 56 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1461, 1482 (1989) (arguing that, in certain circumstances, consumers may expect that sellers "will not risk a bad reputation in the market by sticking to the fine print").
    • (1989) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.56
    • Ware, S.J.1
  • 176
    • 84935413249 scopus 로고
    • On the Currency of Egalitarian Justice
    • note
    • G.A. Cohen, On the Currency of Egalitarian Justice, 99 Ethics 906, 922-23, 930-31 (1989).
    • (1989) Ethics , vol.99
    • Cohen, G.A.1
  • 177
    • 84857615260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Experimental Evidence of the Relationship Between Reading the Fine Print and Performance of Form-Contract Terms
    • note
    • Zev Eigen has found that contractors may be more likely to pay attention to disclosed terms when there is less background noise. Zev J. Eigen, Experimental Evidence of the Relationship Between Reading the Fine Print and Performance of Form-Contract Terms, 168 J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. 124, 124, 134-37 (2012) ("Results suggest that individuals spend almost three times more time reviewing form contracts when less information is provided outside the contract.... ").
    • (2012) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.168
    • Eigen, Z.J.1
  • 178
    • 0346226006 scopus 로고
    • Imperfect Information in Markets for Contract Terms: The Examples of Warranties and Security Interests
    • Alan Schwartz & Louis L. Wilde, Imperfect Information in Markets for Contract Terms: The Examples of Warranties and Security Interests, 69 Va. L. Rev. 1387, 1415 (1983).
    • (1983) Va. L. Rev. , vol.69
    • Schwartz, A.1    Wilde, L.L.2
  • 179
    • 77951965074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Shadow Terms: Contract Procedure and Unilateral Amendments
    • note
    • David Horton, The Shadow Terms: Contract Procedure and Unilateral Amendments, 57 UCLA L. Rev. 605, 623-36 (2010) (charting the historical rise of unilateral modifications).
    • (2010) UCLA L. Rev. , vol.57
    • Horton, D.1
  • 180
    • 84883178568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Set in Stone? Change and Innovation in Consumer Standard-Form Contracts
    • Florencia Marotta-Wurgler & Robert Taylor, Set in Stone? Change and Innovation in Consumer Standard-Form Contracts, 88 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 240, 252-53 (2013).
    • (2013) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.88
    • Marotta-Wurgler, F.1    Taylor, R.2
  • 181
    • 0346319120 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 69 (1981) (delineating circumstances in which silence may constitute acceptance).
    • (1981) Restatement (Second) of Contracts
  • 182
    • 84899135780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 111-24, sec. 101
    • note
    • Pub. L. No. 111-24, sec. 101, §§ 127, 148, 171-172, 123 Stat. 1734, 1735-38.
    • Stat. , vol.123
  • 183
    • 84891510429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Badie v. Bank of Am
    • note
    • See, e.g., Badie v. Bank of Am., 79 Cal. Rptr. 2d 273, 289 (Ct. App. 1998).
    • (1998) Cal. Rptr. 2d , vol.79
  • 184
    • 79951967887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empty Promises
    • note
    • Our approach is conceptually analogous to a proposal of Oren Bar-Gill and Kevin Davis that unilateral modifications only be enforced if approved by "Change Approval Boards. " Oren Bar-Gill & Kevin Davis, Empty Promises, 84 S. Cal. L. Rev. 1, 37-39 (2010). Our approach enlists the sellers' efforts to more directly elicit the preferences of consumers. Our approach may thus be less susceptible to a kind of autonomy-defeating paternalism, whereby consumer protection advocates block substantive terms or require separate assent to warnings that a majority of consumers dislike.
    • (2010) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.84
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Davis, K.2
  • 185
    • 84897505946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • False and misleading advertising is governed by section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act
    • False and misleading advertising is governed by section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. § 45 (2012).
    • (2012) U.S.C. , vol.15
  • 186
    • 84882405113 scopus 로고
    • Kraft, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n
    • note
    • Kraft, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n, 970 F.2d 311, 314 (7th Cir. 1992).
    • (1992) F.2d , vol.970
  • 187
    • 84866292258 scopus 로고
    • Thompson Med. Co
    • note
    • In re Thompson Med. Co., 104 F.T.C. 648, 839 (1984), aff'd, 791 F.2d 189 (D.C. Cir. 1986).
    • (1984) F.T.C. , vol.104
  • 188
    • 84897520999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kraft
    • note
    • Kraft, 970 F.2d at 318.
    • F.2d , vol.970 , pp. 318
  • 189
    • 84897532344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Thompson Med. Co
    • note
    • In re Thompson Med. Co., 104 F.T.C. at 789.
    • F.T.C. , vol.104 , pp. 789
  • 190
    • 84897532344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Thompson Med. Co
    • note
    • In re Thompson Med. Co., 104 F.T.C. at 789.
    • F.T.C. , vol.104 , pp. 789
  • 191
    • 84897474736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 97 F. Supp. 2d 502, 529-30 (S.D.N.Y. 2000).
    • (2000) F. Supp. 2d , vol.97
  • 192
    • 84897550842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Thompson Med. Co
    • note
    • In re Thompson Med. Co, 104 F.T.C. at 839. Courts evaluate the level of substantiation required on a case-by-case basis, looking to a number of factors including "(1) the type of claim.
    • F.T.C. , vol.104 , pp. 839
  • 193
    • 84897532346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (2) the product.
  • 194
    • 84897478629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (3) the consequences of a false claim.
  • 195
    • 84897515116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (4) the benefits of a truthful claim.
  • 196
    • 84897529408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (5) the cost of developing substantiation for the claim.
  • 197
    • 84897514729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fed. Trade Comm'n v. QT, Inc
    • note
    • Fed. Trade Comm'n v. QT, Inc., 448 F. Supp. 2d 908, 959 (N.D. Ill. 2006).
    • (2006) F. Supp. 2d , vol.448
  • 198
    • 84897550842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Thompson Med. Co
    • note
    • In re Thompson Med. Co, 104 F.T.C. at 839
    • F.T.C. , vol.104 , pp. 839
  • 199
    • 84897487456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Trade Commission v. Sabal
    • note
    • Federal Trade Commission v. Sabal, 32 F. Supp. 2d 1004, 1008 (N.D. Ill. 1998)
    • (1998) F. Supp. 2d , vol.32
  • 200
    • 84897512056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Trade Commission v. Garvey
    • note
    • Federal Trade Commission v. Garvey, the Ninth Circuit found that the star of a weight loss infomercial had adequately proved his genuine belief in the claims related to the efficacy of the program that was the subject of the infomercial by demonstrating that he and his wife had lost eight and twenty-seven pounds using the program, respectively, and that he had reviewed two booklets with substantiation materials for the program. 383 F.3d 891, 901-02 (9th Cir. 2004).
    • (2004) F.3d , vol.383
  • 201
    • 79955574465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1125(a)(1). See generally Gregory Klass, Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception, 100 Geo. L.J. 449, 482-88 (2012) (providing background information on false advertising actions under the Lanham Act).
    • U.S.C. , vol.15
  • 202
    • 79955574465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception
    • note
    • See generally Gregory Klass, Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception, 100 Geo. L.J. 449, 482-88 (2012) (providing background information on false advertising actions under the Lanham Act).
    • (2012) Geo. L.J. , vol.100
    • Klass, G.1
  • 203
    • 79955574465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception
    • note
    • See generally Gregory Klass, Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception, 100 Geo. L.J. 449, 482-88 (2012) (providing background information on false advertising actions under the Lanham Act).
    • (2012) Geo. L.J. , vol.100
    • Klass, G.1
  • 204
    • 84897528476 scopus 로고
    • Ames Publ'g Co. v. Walker-Davis Publ'ns, Inc
    • note
    • Ames Publ'g Co. v. Walker-Davis Publ'ns, Inc., 372 F. Supp. 1, 13-14 (E.D. Pa. 1974) ("While unarticulated in the Act itself, an underlying purpose of Section 43(a) appears to be protection of the consuming public from false representations and descriptions in connection with the advertising of goods and services. ").
    • (1974) F. Supp. , vol.372
  • 205
    • 84860109631 scopus 로고
    • 20th Century Wear, Inc. v. Sanmark-Stardust Inc
    • note
    • 20th Century Wear, Inc. v. Sanmark-Stardust Inc., 747 F.2d 81, 91 (2d Cir. 1984) ("[S]ection 43(a) has been broadly construed to provide protection against deceptive marking, packaging, and advertising of goods and services in commerce. "). An advertisement generally violates section 43(a) when it includes: (1) a false or misleading description of fact or representation of fact by the defendant in a commercial advertisement about its own or another's product.
    • (1984) F.2d , vol.747
  • 206
    • 84897525670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (2) the statement actually deceives or has the tendency to deceive a substantial segment of its audience.
  • 207
    • 84897502295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (3) the deception is material, in that it is likely to influence the purchasing decision.
  • 208
    • 84897528991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (4) the defendant placed the false or misleading statement in interstate commerce.
  • 209
    • 84860213127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clorox Co. P.R. v. Proctor & Gamble Commercial Co
    • note
    • and (5) the plaintiff has been or is likely to be injured as a result of the false or misleading statement, either by direct diversion of sales from itself to defendant or by a lessening of goodwill associated with its products. Clorox Co. P.R. v. Proctor & Gamble Commercial Co., 228 F.3d 24, 33 n.6 (1st Cir. 2000).
    • (2000) F.3d , vol.228
  • 210
    • 84897560119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clorox
    • note
    • E.g., Clorox, 228 F.3d at 36 ("An advertisement's propensity to deceive the viewing public is most often proven by consumer survey data. ").
    • F.3d , vol.228 , pp. 36
  • 211
    • 79955574465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception
    • note
    • See generally Gregory Klass, Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception, 100 Geo. L.J. 449, 482-88 (2012) (providing background information on false advertising actions under the Lanham Act).
    • (2012) Geo. L.J. , vol.100
    • Klass, G.1
  • 212
    • 84897508953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 661 F. Supp. 2d 940, 943, 952-56, 958 (N.D. Ill. 2009).
    • (2009) F. Supp. 2d , vol.661
  • 213
    • 84897479869 scopus 로고
    • Stiffel Co. v. Westwood Lighting Grp
    • note
    • Stiffel Co. v. Westwood Lighting Grp., 658 F. Supp. 1103, 1114 (D.N.J. 1987) (noting that the potential that between 22% and 57% of consumers will be misled is "not insubstantial" (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • (1987) F. Supp. , vol.658
  • 214
    • 79955571769 scopus 로고
    • McNeilab, Inc. v. Am. Home Prods. Corp
    • note
    • McNeilab, Inc. v. Am. Home Prods. Corp., 501 F. Supp. 517, 527 (S.D.N.Y. 1980) (holding that 23% of consumers being misled was enough to demonstrate that a commercial "tend[ed] to confuse or mislead" (emphasis omitted) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • (1980) F. Supp. , vol.501
  • 215
    • 67649314109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Full State Funding of Education as a State Constitutional Imperative
    • Laurie Reynolds, Full State Funding of Education as a State Constitutional Imperative, 60 Hastings L.J. 749, 776-80 (2009).
    • (2009) Hastings L.J. , vol.60
    • Reynolds, L.1
  • 216
    • 84897542896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In re Thompson Med. Co
    • note
    • While the general rule is that an advertiser must substantiate its claims before disseminating them, the FTC and the courts may, in their discretion, consider post-claim evidence of substantiation in determining whether advertisements are false or misleading. See In re Thompson Med. Co., 104 F.T.C. at 841 ("[U]sing post-claim evidence to evaluate the truth of a claim, or otherwise using such evidence in deciding whether there is a public interest in continuing an investigation or issuing a complaint, is appropriate policy. ").
    • F.T.C. , vol.104 , pp. 841
  • 217
    • 84897542766 scopus 로고
    • Developing Rational Standards for an Advertising Substantiation Policy
    • note
    • Charles Shafer, Developing Rational Standards for an Advertising Substantiation Policy, 55 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1, 67 (1986) (discussing the history of the FTC's substantiation policy and explaining the four circumstances in which the FTC considers post-claim substantiation: "when (1) evaluating the truth of the claim.
    • (1986) U. Cin. L. Rev. , vol.55
    • Shafer, C.1
  • 218
    • 84897485391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (2) deciding whether there is public interest.
  • 219
    • 84897565428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (3) deciding the appropriate scope of the order.
  • 220
    • 84897510089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (4) assessing the reasonableness of the prior substantiation".
  • 221
    • 84860212356 scopus 로고
    • Johnson & Johnson-Merck Consumer Pharm. Co. v. Rhone-Poulenc Rorer Pharm., Inc
    • note
    • Johnson & Johnson-Merck Consumer Pharm. Co. v. Rhone-Poulenc Rorer Pharm., Inc., 19 F.3d 125, 129 (3d Cir. 1994).
    • (1994) F.3d , vol.19
  • 222
    • 84897508085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Requiring statistically significant (p <.05) results helps resolve whether a competitor survey was sufficiently large to produce credible evidence of an unexpected term. A smaller substantiation survey would only trigger a warning duty if it uncovered a substantial enough disparity to achieve statistical significance. To assure that mass-market sellers surveyed an adequate number of consumers, sellers would also calculate and disclose a "power analysis" indicating that their chosen sample size is sufficient to identify a five percent disparity at least eighty percent of the time. We discuss in Part IV. A how the warning trigger should treat a respondent who reports not having beliefs or "any idea" about particular terms.
  • 223
    • 84897480151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Term substantiation might also elicit information about contractual representation. For example, some users of stickK may not realize that they represent "that the total of all Commitment Stakes authorized by [a] Client is less than 10 percent of [a] Client's annual income. " Terms and Conditions of Commitment Contract, stickK ¶ 6.2, http://www.stickk.com/faq/tac (last visited Feb. 22, 2014).
    • Terms and Conditions of Commitment Contract
  • 227
    • 84897556993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Opening Brief of Plaintiff-Appellant Fed. Trade Comm'n at 19, Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Fin. Freedom Processing, Inc
    • note
    • Opening Brief of Plaintiff-Appellant Fed. Trade Comm'n at 19, Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Fin. Freedom Processing, Inc., 538 Fed. App'x 488 (5th Cir. 2013) (No. 12-10520).
    • (2013) Fed. App'x , vol.538 , pp. 488
  • 229
    • 84897556993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fin. Freedom Processing, Inc
    • note
    • Fin. Freedom Processing, Inc., 538 Fed. App'x 488 (No. 12-10520).
    • Fed. App'x , vol.538 , pp. 488
  • 230
    • 84897556993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fin. Freedom Processing, Inc
    • Fin. Freedom Processing, Inc., 538 Fed. App'x at 489.
    • Fed. App'x , vol.538 , pp. 489
  • 231
    • 84897540071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Tashman
    • note
    • Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Tashman, 318 F.3d 1273, 1283 (11th Cir. 2003) (Vinson, D.J., dissenting) ("[B]oth the advertisements and the disclosure documents must be construed together to evaluate the net impression of the representations to consumers. ").
    • (2003) F.3d , vol.318
  • 232
    • 84897524116 scopus 로고
    • Removatron Int'l Corp. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n
    • note
    • Removatron Int'l Corp. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n, 884 F.2d 1489, 1497 (1st Cir. 1989) (addressing the "common-sense net impression of petitioners' advertising claims").
    • (1989) F.2d , vol.884
  • 233
    • 84874780491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Product Warnings, Debiasing, and Free Speech: The Case of Tobacco Regulation
    • note
    • A second distinction between advertisement and term substantiation concerns causation. Advertisement substantiation tries to uncover the causal impact of particular advertisements on consumer impressions. Sellers are not liable for misperceptions that stem from independent sources. But we favor assessing the net impression of consumers' belief about contractual terms regardless of the source of those impressions. If the seller learns that a majority of its customers have false and overly optimistic impressions about certain terms of an agreement, the seller should warn customers about these unexpected terms (or face the prospect that the terms will not be enforced). This result is consistent with the impetus behind cigarette health warnings, which, as argued by Christine Jolls, can be justified as an attempt to "debias" consumers' overoptimistic perceptions of health risks (regardless of whether those misperceptions were caused by seller advertisements). Christine Jolls, Product Warnings, Debiasing, and Free Speech: The Case of Tobacco Regulation, 169 J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. 53, 54, 56 (2013).
    • (2013) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.169
    • Jolls, C.1
  • 234
    • 79955574465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception
    • note
    • See generally Gregory Klass, Meaning, Purpose, and Cause in the Law of Deception, 100 Geo. L.J. 449, 482-88 (2012) (providing background information on false advertising actions under the Lanham Act).
    • (2012) Geo. L.J. , vol.100
    • Klass, G.1
  • 236
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 237
    • 84900841073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Data Use Policy
    • note
    • See Data Use Policy, Facebook, https://www.facebook.com/about/privacy (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Our survey instrument can be found in Ian Ayres et al., A Randomized Survey Assessing User Knowledge of Facebook Terms of Service 11-20 (Oct. 22, 2013) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors).
    • Facebook
  • 238
    • 84897543200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The surveys were collected by a second-year Yale Law School student, Patrick Hayden.
  • 239
    • 84897525838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Yale campus locations included the law school dining hall, the foyer of the Payne Whitney Gymnasium, and the Memorial Rotunda.
  • 240
    • 84897558106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These surveys were administered at the entrance of the Super Stop & Shop, which is located in the Whalley Avenue Special Service District in New Haven. The demographics of this neighborhood are quite different from those of the Yale students who participated in our survey. The median household income in this neighborhood was $28,894 in 2008, see AMS Consulting & MJB Retail Consulting, Retail Assessment & Strategy: Whalley Avenue Special Service District 46 (drft. 2009), available at http://www.cityofnewhaven.com/uploads/WSSD%20Retail%20Assessment-Strategy% 20Reportv1.pdf, which is 24% below New Haven's 2008 median income, see id., and 44% below the 2008 national median income.
    • (2009) AMS Consulting & MJB Retail Consulting, Retail Assessment & Strategy: Whalley Avenue Special Service District , pp. 46
  • 242
    • 84897531411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Given the empiricism reported in notes 6 and 7 above and the accompanying text, it is unlikely that 23% of our subjects actually had read the Facebook EULA.
  • 243
    • 84897512957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States Facebook Statistics by Country
    • note
    • See United States Facebook Statistics by Country, Socialbakers, http://www.socialbakers.com/facebook-statistics/united-states (last visited Feb. 22, 2014). Note that this disparity can be partly explained by the fact that six percent of Facebook's users are under the age of eighteen, and that we were only authorized to survey participants aged eighteen or older in this study.
    • Socialbakers
  • 244
    • 84897512957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States Facebook Statistics by Country
    • note
    • See United States Facebook Statistics by Country, Socialbakers, http://www.socialbakers.com/facebook-statistics/united-states (last visited Feb. 22, 2014). Note that this disparity can be partly explained by the fact that six percent of Facebook's users are under the age of eighteen, and that we were only authorized to survey participants aged eighteen or older in this study.
    • Socialbakers
  • 245
    • 77954227912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Based on 2012 census data, the U.S. population is 63% white and not of Hispanic descent, 17% Hispanic, 13% black or African American, and 5% Asian. See State & County QuickFacts, U.S. Census Bureau (Dec. 17, 2013, 2:44 PM EST), http://quickfacts.census.gov/qfd/states/00000.html.
    • (2013) State & County QuickFacts
  • 246
    • 84861556198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How Diverse Is Facebook?
    • note
    • Cameron Marlow, How Diverse Is Facebook?, Facebook (Dec. 16, 2009, 6:54 PM), http://www.facebook.com/note.php? note_id=205925658858 (estimating that Facebook's U.S. user base was approximately ten percent black in 2009).
    • (2009) Facebook
    • Marlow, C.1
  • 248
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 250
    • 84897539249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What's Facebook's Philosophy on Personal Information and Ads?
    • note
    • The correct answer is c. See What's Facebook's Philosophy on Personal Information and Ads?, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/help/?faq=207216349317757# What's-Facebook's-philosophy-on-personal-information-and-ads? (last visited Feb. 22, 2014) ("Facebook Ads are sometimes paired with news about social actions (e.g., liking a Page) that your friends have taken. You only appear in Facebook Ads to your confirmed friends. If a photo is used, it is your profile photo and not from your photo albums.").
    • Facebook
  • 251
    • 84897539249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What's Facebook's Philosophy on Personal Information and Ads?
    • note
    • The correct answer is c. See What's Facebook's Philosophy on Personal Information and Ads?, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/help/?faq=207216349317757# What's-Facebook's-philosophy-on-personal-information-and-ads? (last visited Feb. 22, 2014) ("Facebook Ads are sometimes paired with news about social actions (e.g., liking a Page) that your friends have taken. You only appear in Facebook Ads to your confirmed friends. If a photo is used, it is your profile photo and not from your photo albums.").
    • Facebook
  • 253
    • 84897512145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The two dimensions (forward/backward and no idea/best guess) of randomization produced a total of four survey versions. If we expand our analysis to include "no idea" group respondents, and count "no idea" responses as problematic, the number of required warnings would increase from five to eleven terms.
  • 254
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 256
    • 84897566955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another 8.7% of respondents believed that the contract was less favorable than the actual contract by answering, "Facebook may use your photo and name for any advertisement. "
  • 257
    • 84897562921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sharing and Finding You on Facebook
    • note
    • The four warnings are derived from the corresponding sections of Facebook's EULA. See Sharing and Finding You on Facebook, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ about/privacy/your-info-on-fb (last visited Feb. 22, 2014) ("When you select an audience for your friend list, you are only controlling who can see the entire list of your friends on your timeline. We call this a timeline visibility control. This is because your friend list is always available to the games, applications and websites you use, and your friendships may be visible elsewhere (such as on your friends' timelines or in searches). For example, if you select 'Only Me' as the audience for your friend list, but your friend sets her friend list to 'Public,' anyone will be able to see your connection on your friend's timeline.").
    • Facebook
  • 258
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 259
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 260
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 261
    • 84897501908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For our ranking of importance we limited the sample to respondents who had pessimistic or uninformed responses.
  • 262
    • 84897490527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We found no significant difference in the number of terms triggering warnings for salient subgroups (i.e., black or African Americans, Hispanics, and women).
  • 263
    • 84897477798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Warn" was also triggered if a participant selected an incorrect response that could not properly be classified as either optimistic or pessimistic (e.g., selecting New York rather than California in a question related to Facebook's choice-of-law provision).
  • 264
    • 84897562625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Backward" refers to the effect of reversing the question.
  • 265
    • 84897511668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "No Idea" refers to the inclusion of the "I have no idea" answer option.
  • 266
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 267
    • 84897543416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Importance" refers to the respondent's subjective rating of the importance of a given term on a scale from one to five.
  • 268
    • 80051876759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities
    • note
    • Statement of Rights and Responsibilities, Facebook, http://www.facebook.com/ legal/terms (last modified Nov. 15, 2013). Facebook's Statement of Rights and Responsibilities incorporates several of its other policies, which are detailed on separate webpages. Most importantly, many of Facebook's most essential privacy policies appear in its Data Use Policy.
    • Facebook
  • 269
    • 84897564014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Importance" refers to the respondent's subjective rating of the importance of a given term on a scale from one to five.
  • 270
    • 84897509607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • and "Law School Education" refers to whether the participant is currently or has ever been enrolled in law school. We selected obvious defaults for gender (male) and race (white), and we used the median reported household income of our respondents ($60,000 to $99,999) as the income default. These defaults are omitted from Table 1.
  • 271
    • 84897484681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The level of specificity in the framing of consumer knowledge might importantly affect the results of term-substantiation studies such as this one. But as discussed in Part III. A above, our proposal's embrace of third-party contestability is likely to limit the importance of particular specificity frames as being outcome determinative.
  • 272
    • 84893356825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Personalizing Default Rules and Disclosure with Big Data
    • note
    • Ariel Porat & Lior Jacob Strahilevitz, Personalizing Default Rules and Disclosure with Big Data, 112 Mich. L. Rev. (forthcoming 2014).
    • Mich. L. Rev. , vol.112
    • Porat, A.1    Strahilevitz, L.J.2
  • 273
    • 84893356825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Personalizing Default Rules and Disclosure with Big Data
    • note
    • Ariel Porat & Lior Jacob Strahilevitz, Personalizing Default Rules and Disclosure with Big Data, 112 Mich. L. Rev. (forthcoming 2014).
    • Mich. L. Rev. , vol.112
    • Porat, A.1    Strahilevitz, L.J.2
  • 274
    • 0642277195 scopus 로고
    • Back to Basics: Regulating How Corporations Speak to the Market
    • note
    • Ian Ayres, Back to Basics: Regulating How Corporations Speak to the Market, 77 Va. L. Rev. 945, 945-46, 966 (1991).
    • (1991) Va. L. Rev. , vol.77
    • Ayres, I.1
  • 275
    • 84930558935 scopus 로고
    • Good Finance, Bad Economics: An Analysis of the Fraud-on-the-Market Theory
    • note
    • Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Good Finance, Bad Economics: An Analysis of the Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 1059, 1066 (1990) (arguing that, if they could, shareholders would allow, and even contract for, management misrepresentations because they would benefit from the resulting long-term increase in share price).
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42
    • Macey, J.R.1    Miller, G.P.2
  • 276
    • 84897511396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A competitive market, for example, is unlikely to place risk on the inefficient loss avoider. Therefore, consumers might infer that grossly inefficient terms that merely engross seller profits would not persist in a market with sufficient reputational checks on sellers.
  • 277
    • 84871191192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sound Disclosures: Assessing When a Disclosure Is Worthwhile
    • note
    • Recent studies suggest that the appropriate choice of format can materially influence consumer choice. John Kozup et al., Sound Disclosures: Assessing When a Disclosure Is Worthwhile, 31 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 313, 315-16 (2012) ("[R]ecent research suggests that message format has profound effects on different attitudinal, belief, and knowledge variables.... [M]essage characteristics, such as the format of the label, can make a difference... [although] additional research on format specificity is necessary. ").
    • (2012) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.31
    • Kozup, J.1
  • 278
    • 84897494720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Alex Plunkett, Disclosures: A New Avenue for Improvement, Consumer Fin. Protection Bureau Blog (Oct. 3, 2013), http://www.consumerfinance.gov/blog/disclosures-a-newavenue-for-improvement ("[The CFPB's] new trial disclosure policy... allows companies to apply for a waiver to test potential disclosure improvements on a trial basis.").
    • (2013) Disclosures: A New Avenue for Improvement
    • Plunkett, A.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.