메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 2, Issue 3, 2011, Pages 365-411

Spite and reciprocity in auctions

Author keywords

Ascending bid auction; Dominant strategy; English auction; Experiment; Reciprocity; Second price auction; Social preferences; Spite

Indexed keywords


EID: 84865059415     PISSN: None     EISSN: 20734336     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.3390/g2030365     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (20)

References (51)
  • 1
    • 0034407233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Experiments with the pivotal process for providing public goods
    • Attiyeh, G.; Franciosi, R.; Isaac, R.M. Experiments with the pivotal process for providing public goods. Publ. Choice 2000, 102, 95-114.
    • (2000) Publ. Choice , vol.102 , pp. 95-114
    • Attiyeh, G.1    Franciosi, R.2    Isaac, R.M.3
  • 2
    • 0035616158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Can the pivotal mechanism induce truth-telling? An experimental study
    • Kawagoe, T.; Mori, T. Can the pivotal mechanism induce truth-telling? An experimental study. Publ. Choice 2001, 108, 331-354.
    • (2001) Publ. Choice , vol.108 , pp. 331-354
    • Kawagoe, T.1    Mori, T.2
  • 3
    • 33749626315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Secure implementation experiments: Do strategyproof mechanisms really work? Game
    • Cason, T.N.; Saijo, T.; Sjöström, T.; Yamato, T. Secure implementation experiments: Do strategyproof mechanisms really work? Game. Econ. Behav. 2006, 57, 206-235.
    • (2006) Econ. Behav. , vol.57 , pp. 206-235
    • Cason, T.N.1    Saijo, T.2    Sjöström, T.3    Yamato, T.4
  • 4
    • 0000856236 scopus 로고
    • Independent private value auctions: Bidder behavior in first-second-and third-price auctions with varying number of bidders
    • Kagel, J.H.; Levin, D. Independent private value auctions: bidder behavior in first-second-and third-price auctions with varying number of bidders. Econ. J. 1993, 103, 868-879.
    • (1993) Econ. J. , vol.103 , pp. 868-879
    • Kagel, J.H.1    Levin, D.2
  • 5
    • 3843119347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dominant strategy adoption and bidders' experience with pricing rules
    • Harstad, R.M. Dominant strategy adoption and bidders' experience with pricing rules. Exp. Econ. 2000, 3, 261-280.
    • (2000) Exp. Econ. , vol.3 , pp. 261-280
    • Harstad, R.M.1
  • 6
    • 85005224285 scopus 로고
    • Incentives and behavior in English, Dutch, and Sealed-Bid Auctions
    • Coppinger, V.; Smith, V.; Titus, J. Incentives and behavior in English, Dutch, and Sealed-Bid Auctions. Econ. Inq. 1980, 18, 1-22.
    • (1980) Econ. Inq. , vol.18 , pp. 1-22
    • Coppinger, V.1    Smith, V.2    Titus, J.3
  • 8
    • 0001411880 scopus 로고
    • Information impact and allocation rules in auctions with affiliated private values: A laboratory study
    • Kagel, J.H.; Harstad, R.M.; Levin, D. Information impact and allocation rules in auctions with affiliated private values: A laboratory study. Econometrica 1987, 55, 1275-1304.
    • (1987) Econometrica , vol.55 , pp. 1275-1304
    • Kagel, J.H.1    Harstad, R.M.2    Levin, D.3
  • 9
    • 0038354027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revenue Non-Equivalence between the English and the Second-Price Auctions: Experimental Evidence
    • Chew, S.H.; Nishimura, N. Revenue Non-Equivalence between the English and the Second-Price Auctions: Experimental Evidence. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2003, 51, 443-458.
    • (2003) J. Econ. Behav. Organ. , vol.51 , pp. 443-458
    • Chew, S.H.1    Nishimura, N.2
  • 10
    • 84893078969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "Japanese" version of English auction is the type of ascending-bid auction we employed in our theoretical and experimental analyses, where all the bidders are active from the start by pushing their buttons as default and they leave the auction by releasing their buttons
    • The "Japanese" version of English auction is the type of ascending-bid auction we employed in our theoretical and experimental analyses, where all the bidders are active from the start by pushing their buttons as default and they leave the auction by releasing their buttons. Thus, they are not allowed to leave the auction and reenter at the later stage. It is well known that the value-revealing bidding strategy generates the unique dominant strategy equilibrium and there is no room for any asymmetric equilibrium such as jump-bidding strategy (see Milgrom and Weber [11] for example.)
    • Thus, they are not allowed to leave the auction and reenter at the later stage
  • 11
    • 0001757115 scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding
    • Milgrom, P.; Weber, R. A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding, Econometrica 1982, 50, 1089-1122.
    • (1982) Econometrica , vol.50 , pp. 1089-1122
    • Milgrom, P.1    Weber, R.2
  • 12
    • 84970331973 scopus 로고
    • The "spite" dilemma in voluntary contribution mechanism experiments
    • Saijo, T.; Nakamura, H. The "spite" dilemma in voluntary contribution mechanism experiments. J. Confl. Resolut. 1995, 39, 535-560.
    • (1995) J. Confl. Resolut. , vol.39 , pp. 535-560
    • Saijo, T.1    Nakamura, H.2
  • 13
    • 0000832255 scopus 로고
    • Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics
    • Rabin, M. Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. Am. Econ. Rev. 1993, 83, 1281-1302.
    • (1993) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 1281-1302
    • Rabin, M.1
  • 14
    • 34548052459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tit for tat: Foundations of preferences for reciprocity in strategic settings
    • Segal, U.; Sobel, J. Tit for tat: Foundations of preferences for reciprocity in strategic settings. J. Econ. Theor. 2007, 136, 197-216.
    • (2007) J. Econ. Theor. , vol.136 , pp. 197-216
    • Segal, U.1    Sobel, J.2
  • 17
    • 0344705995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The spite motive and equilibrium behavior in auctions
    • Morgan, J.; Steiglitz, K.; Reis, G. The spite motive and equilibrium behavior in auctions. Contrib. Econ. Anal. Pol. 2003, 2, 5:1-5:27.
    • (2003) Contrib. Econ. Anal. Pol. , vol.2 , pp. 51-527
    • Morgan, J.1    Steiglitz, K.2    Reis, G.3
  • 18
    • 52749086161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding overbidding in second price auctions: An experimental study
    • Cooper, D.; Fang, H. Understanding overbidding in second price auctions: An experimental study. Econ. J. 2008, 118, 1572-1595.
    • (2008) Econ. J. , vol.118 , pp. 1572-1595
    • Cooper, D.1    Fang, H.2
  • 19
    • 34248549851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Asymmetric information about rivals' types in standard auctions: An experiment
    • Andreoni, J.; Che, Y.-K.; Kim, J. Asymmetric information about rivals' types in standard auctions: An experiment. Game. Econ. Behav. 2007, 59, 240-259.
    • (2007) Game. Econ. Behav. , vol.59 , pp. 240-259
    • Andreoni, J.1    Che, Y.-K.2    Kim, J.3
  • 21
    • 38549123971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Effects of information-revelation policies under market-structure uncertainty
    • Arora, A.; Greenwald, A.; Kannan, K.; Krishnan, R. Effects of information-revelation policies under market-structure uncertainty. Manag. Sci. 2007, 53, 1234-1248.
    • (2007) Manag. Sci. , vol.53 , pp. 1234-1248
    • Arora, A.1    Greenwald, A.2    Kannan, K.3    Krishnan, R.4
  • 22
    • 79954461351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An experimental study of information revelation policies in sequential auctions
    • Cason, T.N.; Kannan, K.; Siebert, R. An experimental study of information revelation policies in sequential auctions. Manag. Sci. 2011, 57, 667-688.
    • (2011) Manag. Sci. , vol.57 , pp. 667-688
    • Cason, T.N.1    Kannan, K.2    Siebert, R.3
  • 23
    • 35448949581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Internet advertising and the generalized second-price auction: Selling billions of dollars worth of keywords
    • Edelman, B.; Ostrovsky, M.; Schwarz, M. Internet advertising and the generalized second-price auction: Selling billions of dollars worth of keywords. Am. Econ. Rev., 2007, 97, 242-259.
    • (2007) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 242-259
    • Edelman, B.1    Ostrovsky, M.2    Schwarz, M.3
  • 24
    • 84893152862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [3], subjects fail to choose dominant strategies when other, non-dominant strategy Nash equilibria exist. This led Saijo et al. [25] to introduce secure implementation, where the goal is achieved by both dominant and Nash equilibria
    • As highlighted in Cason et al. [3], subjects fail to choose dominant strategies when other, non-dominant strategy Nash equilibria exist. This led Saijo et al. [25] to introduce secure implementation, where the goal is achieved by both dominant and Nash equilibria.
    • As highlighted in Cason et al
  • 27
    • 84893053188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Their model has the simplest form among various reciprocity models proposed, yet general enough to include such models as Rabin [13] and Charness and Rabin [28]. They provide axiomatic foundation for reciprocity models and obtain utility representation theorem which prescribes utility function Ui(σi, σ*j) of the form (3) except that σi is player i's mixed strategy and σ*j is player i's belief about player j's mixed strategy. Also the constant term Rj =0 in the Segal and Sobel's model, whereas Rj =0 in other reciprocity models. Like other reciprocity models, they consider the framework of the psychological game developed by Geanakoplos, Pearce, and Stacchetti [29] in which beliefs play an important role. Segal and Sobel [14] showed that the concept of Nash equilibrium directly applicable in their framework in the sense that each player i considers her best response for a given belief σ*j, and in equilibrium the belief must coincide with the actual strategy choice, i.e., σ*j = σj. As long as we restrict our attentions to the analysis of equilibrium behavior, not off-equilibrium, we can avoid discussions of beliefs. Thus, we conduct our analysis based on a degenerate form of (3) treating beliefs implicitly, although we include an analysis that incorporates beliefs in our working paper Nishimura et al. [30]. For more detail discussions of beliefs, see Sobel [31].
  • 28
    • 0036704136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding social preferences with simple tests
    • Charness, G.; Rabin, M. Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Q. J. Econ. 2002, 117, 817-869.
    • (2002) Q. J. Econ. , vol.117 , pp. 817-869
    • Charness, G.1    Rabin, M.2
  • 30
    • 84893050775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Working paper; Shinshu University: Matsumoto, Nagano, Japan; Purdue University: West Lafayette, IN, USA
    • Nishimura, N.; Cason, T.; Saijo, T.; Ikeda, Y. Spite and Counter-Spite in Auctions; Working paper; Shinshu University: Matsumoto, Nagano, Japan; Purdue University: West Lafayette, IN, USA, 2007.
    • (2007) Spite and Counter-Spite in Auctions
    • Nishimura, N.1    Cason, T.2    Saijo, T.3    Ikeda, Y.4
  • 31
    • 25844433130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interdependent preferences and reciprocity
    • Sobel, J. Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. J. Econ. Lit. 2005, 43, 392-436.
    • (2005) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.43 , pp. 392-436
    • Sobel, J.1
  • 32
    • 84893093339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We set reference losing payoff to be zero for both buyers. Note that buyer i's psychological payoff in the event of winning is zero and omitted in (3), since both her rival's payoff and reference losing payoff in that event are zero
    • We set reference losing payoff to be zero for both buyers. The reciprocity model prescribes utility as a sum of own monetary payoff and psychological payoff. Note that buyer i's psychological payoff in the event of winning is zero and omitted in (3), since both her rival's payoff and reference losing payoff in that event are zero.
    • The reciprocity model prescribes utility as a sum of own monetary payoff and psychological payoff
  • 33
    • 84893130307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To be precise, the negative weight means spite motivation
    • To be precise, the negative weight means spite motivation.
  • 34
    • 84893027001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is common in reciprocity models to normalize the deviation from some reference by the payoff range defined by the maximum and the minimum payoff available under the relevant consideration. Such need arises due to the requirement of a discrete bid strategy space
    • It is common in reciprocity models to normalize the deviation from some reference by the payoff range defined by the maximum and the minimum payoff available under the relevant consideration. Here, we add ccto the denominator to be consistent with the case of ascending-bid auction, without loss of generality. Such need arises due to the requirement of a discrete bid strategy space.
    • Here, we add ccto the denominator to be consistent with the case of ascending-bid auction, without loss of generality
  • 35
    • 84893121105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • equating buyer I s winning and losing payoff when fej =b2 = x. We then find the nearest 0, e B satisfying xe It is easy to check that exists and A For more detail, see Appendix A-1
    • In order to identify B, we first solve for a real number xe [0,6] that satisfies i.e. equating buyer I s winning and losing payoff when fej =b2 = x. We then find the nearest 0, e B satisfying xe It is easy to check that exists and A For more detail, see Appendix A-1.
    • In order to identify B, we first solve for a real number xe [0,6] that satisfies i.e.
  • 38
    • 84893035581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allowing reciprocity eliminates the proposer's strategy of choosing the most self-advantageous offer expecting the receiver to accept it that is sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium under the standard model, but keeps other Nash equilibria that would have failed the sub-game perfect refinement
    • This is not the only case where allowing for the possibility of reciprocity leads to eliminating some of Nash equilibria generated by the standard model. The well-known example is an ultimatum game which has multiple Nash equilibria under the standard model. Allowing reciprocity eliminates the proposer's strategy of choosing the most self-advantageous offer expecting the receiver to accept it that is sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium under the standard model, but keeps other Nash equilibria that would have failed the sub-game perfect refinement.
    • The well-known example is an ultimatum game which has multiple Nash equilibria under the standard model
  • 39
    • 84893109606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A change in the weight j i iiiias r increases can lead to a different bid decision. In this sense our model maintains consistency. The related issue can be found in the context of sequential decision making through partial resolution of risk particularly via non-expected utility preferences
    • A change in the weight j iiiias r increases can lead to a different bid decision. As shown in Proposition 2 below and related discussion to follow, each equilibrium bid decision at the every decision point reached in the ascending-bid auction is also equilibrium in the previous decision point (not vice versa), and all the way back to the very start of auction. In this sense our model maintains consistency. The related issue can be found in the context of sequential decision making through partial resolution of risk particularly via non-expected utility preferences. If we want to maintain the dynamic consistency in preferences, it is known that preferences must satisfy consequentialism (Hammond [40]). It seems, however, inappropriate to impose consequentialism on preferences especially when we deal with players' intentions explicitly.
    • As shown in Proposition 2 below and related discussion to follow, each equilibrium bid decision at the every decision point reached in the ascending-bid auction is also equilibrium in the previous decision point (not vice versa), and all the way back to the very start of auction
  • 40
    • 0001784671 scopus 로고
    • Consequentialist foundations of expected utility
    • Hammond, P. Consequentialist foundations of expected utility. Theor. Decis. 1988, 25, 25-78.
    • (1988) Theor. Decis. , vol.25 , pp. 25-78
    • Hammond, P.1
  • 41
    • 84893111019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the same manner as described in [35], p-Lr is derived from the solution i.e. equating buyer l's winning and losing payoff when Then, find the smallest number e Br satisfying It can be shown that. For more details, see Appendix A-4
    • In the same manner as described in [35], p-Lr is derived from the solution i.e. equating buyer l's winning and losing payoff when Then, find the smallest number e Br satisfying It can be shown that. For more details, see Appendix A-4.
  • 42
    • 84893093259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Though we omit the argument regarding beliefs in our analysis, it may be worthwhile to point out the following; First, it is clear from Definition 3 that every equilibrium bidding strategy profile (&, b'2)
    • Though we omit the argument regarding beliefs in our analysis, it may be worthwhile to point out the following; First, it is clear from Definition 3 that every equilibrium bidding strategy profile (&, b'2) belongs to interim equilibrium Er for all >-Second, since £f has the lowest upper bound, there would not arise any need to revise a belief that is consistent with equilibrium bid on the equilibrium path. With these two properties, our Definition 3 is consistent with the definition of Sequential Reciprocity Equilibrium by Dufwenberg and Kirschteiger [15].
  • 43
    • 84893126717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The psychological dynamics are different in nature from the comparison of Nash equilibrium versus subgame perfect Nash equilibrium The subgame perfect equilibrium set in the conventional self-interested preferences ascending-bid auction is equivalent to the Nash equilibrium set in the second price auction without its inefficient elements. However, with the spite motivation the maximum equilibrium price in the ascending bid auction is f. Thus, the ascending-bid auction price predicted for buyers of spite-with-reciprocity is bounded by the maximum price predicted in the conventional model.
  • 44
    • 84893109272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The corresponding tie bid xr defined in [41] is 748.3 for r = 720, 746.3 for r = 730, and 744.2 for r = 740. It follows that t= 740.
  • 45
    • 84893038072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is well known that the symmetric equilibrium bidding strategy must be strictly increasing in the buyer type (value in this model) in the auction where the highest bidder wins; for example, see Milgrom [46].
  • 47
    • 0002564950 scopus 로고
    • Auctions: A survey of experimental research
    • Kagel, J., Roth, A., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA
    • Kagel, J. Auctions: A survey of experimental research. In The Handbook of Experimental Economics; Kagel, J., Roth, A., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1995.
    • (1995) The Handbook of Experimental Economics
    • Kagel, J.1
  • 51
    • 84893128038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As in Table 1, we only employ the sealed bid auction data in these regressions because the high-value bidders' bids are rarely observed in the ascending price auction
    • As in Table 1, we only employ the sealed bid auction data in these regressions because the high-value bidders' bids are rarely observed in the ascending price auction.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.