메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 105, Issue 4, 2011, Pages 1581-1633

Regulatory change and optimal transition relief

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84858233405     PISSN: 00293571     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (12)

References (413)
  • 1
    • 84858263593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.S.C. § 7411(a)(1)-(2), (b)(1)(B) (2006) (providing that stringent federal performance standards only apply to "new sources" of air pollution)
    • (2006)
  • 2
    • 37749039804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grandfathering and environmental regulation: The law and economics of new source review
    • note
    • see also, e.g., Jonathan Remy Nash & Richard L. Revesz, Grandfathering and Environmental Regulation: The Law and Economics of New Source Review, 101 NW. U. L. REV. 1677, 1717-18 (2007) ("The early Clean Air Act legislative history reflects a compromise to accept an extension of existing plants' lives in exchange for the application of very strict standards to the new plants that would replace them in the future. More than a third of a century after that compromise was struck, many of the plants that were in existence then remain in service now-far beyond the retirement date that most initially expected, even taking into account the introduction of life-extending differential regulatory standards." (footnote omitted)).
    • (2007) NW. U. L. REV. , vol.101
    • Nash, J.R.1    Revesz, R.L.2
  • 4
    • 0344269063 scopus 로고
    • Legal Transitions: The case of retroactivity in income tax revision
    • Michael J. Graetz, Legal Transitions: The Case of Retroactivity in Income Tax Revision, 126 U. PA. L. REV. 47 (1977)
    • (1977) U. PA. L. REV. , vol.126 , pp. 47
    • Graetz, M.J.1
  • 5
    • 84934564251 scopus 로고
    • An Economic analysis of legal transitions
    • Louis Kaplow, An Economic Analysis of Legal Transitions, 99 HARV. L. REV. 509 (1986)
    • (1986) HARV. L. REV. , vol.99 , pp. 509
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 6
    • 47749108284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Optimal legal change, past behavior, and grandfathering
    • Steven Shavell, On Optimal Legal Change, Past Behavior, and Grandfathering, 37 J. LEGAL STUD. 37 (2008).
    • (2008) J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.37 , pp. 37
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 7
    • 0010192922 scopus 로고
    • Rule Change and transitional equity
    • note
    • See, e.g., Harold M. Hochman, Rule Change and Transitional Equity, in REDISTRIBUTION THROUGH PUBLIC CHOICE 320, 324 (H. Hochman & G. Peterson eds., 1974)
    • (1974) REDISTRIBUTION THROUGH PUBLIC CHOICE
    • Hochman, H.M.1
  • 8
    • 0001656306 scopus 로고
    • Property, utility, and fairness: Comments on the ethical foundations of "just compensation" law
    • note
    • Frank I. Michelman, Property, Utility, and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations of "Just Compensation" Law, 80 HARV. L. REV. 1165, 1219, 1224 (1967). This argument has also been made in the tax context.
    • (1967) HARV. L. REV. , vol.80
    • Michelman, F.I.1
  • 11
    • 25644445389 scopus 로고
    • Retroactivity of tax legislation
    • Retroactivity of Tax Legislation, 29 TAX LAW. 21, 23, 27-28 (1975)
    • (1975) TAX LAW , vol.29
  • 12
    • 25644437207 scopus 로고
    • Setting Effective dates for tax legislation: A rule of prospectivity
    • note
    • Note, Setting Effective Dates for Tax Legislation: A Rule of Prospectivity, 84 HARV. L. REV. 436, 439 (1970).
    • (1970) HARV. L. REV. , vol.84
  • 13
    • 84858251896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 2-3
    • Shaviro1
  • 14
    • 84858246875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow, supra note 2, at 531
    • Kaplow1
  • 15
    • 84858238978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Grandfathering and environmental regulation: The law and economics of new source review
    • note
    • Graetz, supra note 2, at 64-66, 85.
    • (2007) NW. U. L. REV. , vol.101
    • Graetz1
  • 16
    • 84858233951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Graetz, supra note 2.
    • Graetz1
  • 17
    • 84858246877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow, supra note 2.
    • Kaplow1
  • 18
    • 84858204767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2.
    • Shavell1
  • 22
    • 67649383131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Analysis of law
    • note
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Economic Analysis of Law, in 4 HANDBOOK OF PUBLIC ECONOMICS 1661 (Alan J. Auerbach & Martin Feldstein eds., 2002)
    • (2002) HANDBOOK of PUBLIC ECONOMICS , vol.4 , pp. 1661
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 23
    • 0042671102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fairness Versus welfare: Notes on the pareto principle, preferences, and distributive justice
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Fairness Versus Welfare: Notes on the Pareto Principle, Preferences, and Distributive Justice, 32 J. LEGAL STUD. 331 (2003)
    • (2003) J. LEGAL STUD. , vol.32 , pp. 331
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 24
    • 34548020275 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moral Rules, the moral sentiments, and behavior: Toward a theory of an optimal moral system
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Moral Rules, the Moral Sentiments, and Behavior: Toward a Theory of an Optimal Moral System, 115 J. POL. ECON. 494 (2007)
    • (2007) J. POL. ECON. , vol.115 , pp. 494
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 25
    • 0041386048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notions of fairness versus the pareto principle: On the role of logical consistency
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Notions of Fairness Versus the Pareto Principle: On the Role of Logical Consistency, 110 YALE L.J. 237 (2000)
    • (2000) YALE L.J. , vol.110 , pp. 237
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 26
    • 0346581482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property Rules versus liability rules: An economic analysis
    • Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Property Rules Versus Liability Rules: An Economic Analysis, 109 HARV. L. REV. 713 (1996).
    • (1996) HARV. L. REV. , vol.109 , pp. 713
    • Kaplow, L.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 27
    • 84858204770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow, supra note 2, at 615-16.
    • Kaplow1
  • 28
    • 84858204766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 38-39.
    • Shavell1
  • 29
    • 84858267386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This Article focuses on command-and-control regulation and thus does not discuss market-based regimes. We also generally assume regulations that are enforced by injunction as opposed to a system of monetary damages. For an argument that liability-based transition relief is preferable to propertybased relief in the context of environmental regulation, see Jonathan R. Nash, The Cathedral of Transition Relief in Environmental Law 2 (Nov. 11, 2010) (unpublished manuscript) (on file with authors). For a discussion of which institutional actor is best suited to provide transition relief.
  • 30
    • 77954693439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Institutional dynamics of transition relief
    • note
    • see Jonathan S. Masur & Jonathan Remy Nash, The Institutional Dynamics of Transition Relief, 85 N.Y.U. L. REV. 391, 436-55 (2010).
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. REV. , vol.85
    • Masur, J.S.1    Nash, J.R.2
  • 31
    • 84858267387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 2-3 (referring to the position that favors transition relief to protect reliance interests as the "old view").
    • Shaviro1
  • 32
    • 84858204769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This argument has often been advanced in the tax context.
  • 34
    • 84858243244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Comm. on Tax Policy, N.Y. State Bar Ass'n, supra note 3, at 23, 27-28
    • Comm. on Tax Policy
  • 35
    • 84858204771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note, supra note 3, at 439.
  • 36
    • 84858243247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fairness arguments have also been made in favor of transition relief in a more general context.
  • 37
    • 84858243245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Hochman, supra note 3, at 324
    • Hochman1
  • 38
    • 84858267388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Michelman, supra note 3, at 1219, 1223-24.
    • Michelman1
  • 39
    • 84858251897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Jill Fisch has argued that "legal changes must be evaluated individually" and that "[i]n analyzing the effect of a particular new rule, it is necessary to consider the change in context": [I]n the context of an unstable equilibrium our intuitions about the legitimacy of retroactivity are justified, and retroactive lawmaking is an appropriate and efficient means of clarifying, correcting, and incrementally adjusting the regulatory climate. In a stable equilibrium, however, legal change imposes considerable costs on individuals subject to the change and on the legal system as a whole.
  • 40
    • 84925042474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Retroactivity and legal change: An equilibrium approach
    • Jill E. Fisch, Retroactivity and Legal Change: An Equilibrium Approach, 110 HARV. L. REV. 1055, 1100, 1123 (1997).
    • (1997) HARV. L. REV. , vol.110
    • Fisch, J.E.1
  • 41
    • 84858233952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While old-view scholarship is not as common as it was in the 1960s and 1970s, some recent work continues to support the old view.
  • 42
    • 79959254401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beware of legal transitions: A presumptive vote for the reliance interest
    • note
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Beware of Legal Transitions: A Presumptive Vote for the Reliance Interest, 13 J. CONTEMP. LEGAL ISSUES 69, 70 (2003) ("The proper approach starts with a strong presumption and not a categorical denial: beware of legal transitions. Wherever possible try to keep the legal framework constant, and allow the response to societal changes to take place through private adjustments.")
    • (2003) J. CONTEMP. LEGAL ISSUES , vol.13
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 43
    • 47749134278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward a definition and critique of retroactivity
    • note
    • Daniel E. Troy, Toward a Definition and Critique of Retroactivity, 51 ALA. L. REV. 1329, 1341-42 (2000) (arguing that retroactive legislation should be avoided because individuals base their behavior on the existing law and providing fair notice of legal changes is "fundamental to the rule of law"). David Hasen has also recently attacked new-view scholarship as being "analytically deficient.".
    • (2000) ALA. L. REV. , vol.51
    • Troy, D.E.1
  • 44
    • 84858246513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Transitions and the problem of reliance
    • note
    • David M. Hasen, Legal Transitions and the Problem of Reliance, 1 COLUM. J. TAX L. 120, 123-24 (2010) (arguing that new-view literature has failed to both "develop consistent definitions of such key concepts as 'transition,' 'legal transition,' and 'transition norm'. [and] demonstrate that a reliance-based view is unable to reach correct results on the question of the proper default norms for changes to positive law and for judicial decisions that adopt new rules"). The topic of retroactivity in the tax context was also recently debated at the 2010 European Association of Tax Law Professors Congress in Leuven, Belgium. Daniel Shaviro argued against the provision of transition relief when disadvantageous tax changes are implemented, while Charlotte Crane argued in favor of transition relief.
    • (2010) COLUM. J. TAX L. , vol.1
    • Hasen, D.M.1
  • 46
    • 84858240095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see DANIEL SHAVIRO & CHARLOTTE CRANE, Retroactivity in Law & Economics, available at http://www.law.nyu.edu/ecm_dlv3/groups/public/@nyu_law_website__faculty__faculty_profiles__dshaviro/documents/documents/ecm_pro_065857.pdf.
    • Retroactivity in Law & Economics
    • Daniel, S.1    Charlotte, C.2
  • 47
    • 84858246878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Michelman, supra note 3, at 1219-21 (discussing transition relief in the context of the Takings Clause). For a detailed discussion of optimal compensation under the Takings Clause
    • Michelman1
  • 48
    • 0021576415 scopus 로고
    • The Taking of land: When should compensation be paid?
    • note
    • see Lawrence Blume, Daniel L. Rubinfeld & Perry Shapiro, The Taking of Land: When Should Compensation Be Paid?, 99 Q.J. ECON. 71 (1984).
    • (1984) Q.J. ECON. , vol.99 , pp. 71
    • Blume, L.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2    Shapiro, P.3
  • 49
    • 84858267385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Michelman, supra note 3, at 1223.
    • Michelman1
  • 50
    • 84858246884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Settlement costs" are measured by the dollar value of the time, effort, and resources which would be required in order to reach compensation settlements adequate to avoid demoralization costs. Included are the costs of settling not only the particular compensation claims presented, but also those of all persons so affected by the measure in question or similar measures as to have claims not obviously distinguishable by the available settlement apparatus.
  • 51
    • 84858246883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1214.
  • 52
    • 84858246874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Michelman also discusses what he terms "demoralization costs": "Demoralization costs" are defined as the total of (1) the dollar value necessary to offset disutilities which accrue to losers and their sympathizers specifically from the realization that no compensation is offered, and (2) the present capitalized dollar value of lost future production (reflecting either impaired incentives or social unrest) caused by demoralization of uncompensated losers, their sympathizers, and other observers disturbed by the thought that they themselves may be subjected to similar treatment on some other occasion.
  • 53
    • 84858186414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1223.
  • 54
    • 84858233953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Louis Kaplow agrees that the failure to compensate will somewhat discourage certain investments but argues that "this 'disincentive' [is] necessary to eliminate the overinvestment that would result from compensation.".
  • 55
    • 84858251899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kaplow, supra note 2, at 561.
    • Kaplow1
  • 56
    • 84858246882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While Michelman does discuss efficiency concerns and maximizing total utility, he stresses that the compensation decision should ultimately be based on justice "without regard to the effect of the decision on the net social product." Michelman, supra note 3, at 1219. Martin Feldstein, writing in the tax context, suggests that transition relief is important to avoid "inefficient precautionary behavior.".
  • 57
    • 0001853805 scopus 로고
    • On the theory of tax reform
    • Martin Feldstein, On the Theory of Tax Reform, 6 J. PUB. ECON. 77, 93 (1976).
    • (1976) J. PUB. ECON. , vol.6
    • Feldstein, M.1
  • 58
    • 84858246885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, he argues that proposals to nullify the "oil depletion allowance" have inefficiently decreased investment in oil. Id. He contends that the way to prevent this inefficient behavior is to consistently provide transition relief because then "investors know that they will be fully compensated for any losses that result from reform.".
  • 59
    • 84858251901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 98.
  • 60
    • 84858251900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Michael J. Graetz criticizes Feldstein for providing no explanation as to why anticipating legal changes leads to inefficient behavior and argues that market principles suggest that the opposite is true.
    • Graetz, M.J.1
  • 61
    • 84858251902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Graetz, supra note 2, at 64-65.
    • Graetz1
  • 62
    • 84858233958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Graetz, supra note 2.
    • Graetz1
  • 63
    • 84858186415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 65.
  • 64
    • 84858233956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 65-66.
  • 65
    • 84858204768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 71.
  • 66
    • 84858233954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 74.
  • 67
    • 84858186413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 75-76 (noting that reliance may no longer be reasonable once the President publicly endorses a change or one or both houses of Congress pass a bill).
  • 68
    • 84858246879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 71 ("[G]randfathered effective dates will often reduce whatever benefits are expected to be realized from the change in the law. The social gains to be realized from the change will often be delayed with a grandfathered effective date.").
  • 69
    • 84858233955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 2-3, 7, 10-11, 62-63, 81-86.
    • Shaviro1
  • 70
    • 84858186416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8; accord id. at 7-8, 13, 53 (discussing "policy change" retroactive taxes).
  • 71
    • 84858246886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 8.
  • 72
    • 84858251903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To use Shaviro's example, consider the municipal bond preference which exempts from taxation interest earned on municipal bonds. Id. The policy-relevant feature is to prefer municipal bonds to other investment types. There are also various accounting features which were adopted in order to accomplish the policy goal.
  • 73
    • 84858233960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 8-9.
  • 74
    • 84858233961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, this tax benefit is provided to bondholders rather than issuers, even though providing the tax preference to issuers would have the same intended economic effect.
  • 75
    • 84858246887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 9.
  • 76
    • 84858267367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In the case of a policy change, a general norm of not providing transition relief serves the purpose of that policy change by producing desirable ex ante incentive effects.
  • 77
    • 84858204745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 7, 60.
  • 78
    • 84858267366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, banning a hazardous product constitutes a "policy change" because not providing transition relief in the event of the ban advances the purpose of the legal change-product safety-by giving manufacturers an ex ante incentive to only invest in safe products. However, with an accounting change, a general norm of not providing transition relief does not advance the purpose of the legal change.
  • 79
    • 84858204763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 62.
  • 80
    • 84858263589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To use Shaviro's example, suppose the prevailing currency, which has a green color, is abandoned in favor of a red currency because the green currency is easily forged.
  • 81
    • 84858263580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 10.
  • 82
    • 84858204748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In this case, providing no transition relief-and thus not permitting individuals holding green currency to trade in their green currency for new red currency-would be undesirable because it would not advance the purpose of the new law.
  • 83
    • 84858243234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our discussion in the text concerns only policy changes.
  • 84
    • 84858267368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While Shaviro's conclusion regarding policy changes is in line with Graetz's, his reasoning is somewhat different. While Graetz suggests that "change[s] in tastes or societal conditions [are] reflected through the political process,".
  • 85
    • 84858243235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Graetz, supra note 2, at 65, Shaviro questions the extent to which "public political choice" (which is reflected in the laws that are passed) is actually similar to "private consumer choice" (which is reflected by market demand).
    • Graetz1
  • 86
    • 84858204765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 64. It is desirable to "let[] the owners of an ice cream parlor absorb the loss from a decline in the public's taste for ice cream [because] it may induce them to try harder to determine what the public wants." Id. Shaviro, however, suggests that making investors bear the risk of a legal change may not make as much sense as making them bear the risk of a market change because, while the demand for a particular product tends to be a good indicator of consumer choice, the laws that are passed are not necessarily good indicators of overall public opinion, partly for public choice reasons.
    • Shaviro1
  • 87
    • 84858263581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 67-71.
  • 88
    • 84858204749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shaviro argues that this is the case for three reasons: problems of aggregation, problems of organization, and problems of information: [C]ollective choice requires aggregating people's preferences rather than giving each one the result he wants. Hence, the point that 49 percent of the people can buy their own ice cream but not pass their own law. Amongst other implications, aggregation is likely to reduce the level of voter investment in attempting to make good decisions.
  • 89
    • 84858263582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 67. Other aggregation problems also arise because people may choose not to vote because "[t]he value of a single vote is so low" and because "voting, unlike the use of money to buy consumer goods, is ordinal rather than cardinal" and thus does not reveal the intensity of voter preferences.
  • 90
    • 84858267371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 67, 69-72 (discussing how interest group theory suggests that "democratic politics tends to produce transfers from the many to the few" and noting that information problems are even worse "in the realm of public political choice" than in the market context).
  • 91
    • 84858267370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 89-90.
    • Shaviro1
  • 92
    • 84858267369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 89 (explaining that, in the tax context, "the political impetus to compensate transition losses exceeds that to deny transition gains").
  • 93
    • 84858204750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 229 (noting that a norm of not providing transition relief for policy changes "would tend to reduce the prevailing asymmetry in favor of providing greater transitional adjustment when income tax preferences that worsen resource allocation are curtailed than when they are expanded").
  • 94
    • 84858263584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Kaplow, supra note 2.
    • Kaplow1
  • 95
    • 84858267373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 513-14.
  • 96
    • 84858267372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In making his argument, Kaplow primarily discusses the transition policy of compensation; however, he explains that his argument generally applies to other forms of transition relief as well.
  • 97
    • 84858263583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 556 n.133.
    • , Issue.133 , pp. 556
  • 98
    • 84858204751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 513, 519.
  • 99
    • 84858243236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 529.
  • 100
    • 84858267376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 527-28.
  • 101
    • 84858267384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 548.
  • 102
    • 84858267375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 549.
  • 103
    • 0346703088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Changes, anticipations, and reparations
    • note
    • See Saul Levmore, Changes, Anticipations, and Reparations, 99 COLUM. L. REV. 1657 (1999).
    • (1999) COLUM. L. REV. , vol.99 , pp. 1657
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 104
    • 84858204754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 1663 ("[R]egulated firms know or could know more than the government about likely subjects of regulatory concern and, therefore, might be in the best position to forecast the coming, good law. [but] if the law is such that these firms know that they will be compensated for the cost of legal change, then they have little incentive to anticipate new law.").
  • 105
    • 84858243237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1658-59.
  • 106
    • 84858204753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1663 ("The more aggressive the expected application of these new rules, the more it seems likely that well-informed firms will choose to substitute other, less harmful inputs before the government. devises the new controls.").
  • 107
    • 84858204752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In the tax context, a few scholars have attacked or at least qualified the view that transition relief is generally inappropriate.
  • 108
    • 0345562962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax Transitions, opportunistic retroactivity, and the benefits of government precommitment
    • note
    • See Kyle D. Logue, Tax Transitions, Opportunistic Retroactivity, and the Benefits of Government Precommitment, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1129, 1138-40 (1996) (arguing that it is economically efficient to provide transition relief in the context of incentive subsidies)
    • (1996) MICH. L. REV. , vol.94
    • Logue, K.D.1
  • 109
    • 25644448978 scopus 로고
    • Tax Transitions and the protection racket: A reply to professors graetz and kaplow
    • note
    • J. Mark Ramseyer & Minoru Nakazato, Tax Transitions and the Protection Racket: A Reply to Professors Graetz and Kaplow, 75 VA. L. REV. 1155, 1163-65 (1989) (arguing that transition relief can be desirable because it minimizes wasteful postenactment lobbying costs). Like Shaviro, Ramseyer and Nakazato criticize the assumption that most tax legislation is efficient and thus desirable.
    • (1989) VA. L. REV. , vol.75
    • Mark Ramseyer, J.1    Nakazato, M.2
  • 110
    • 84858267374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ramseyer & Nakazato, supra, at 1163. Ramseyer and Nakazato also suggest that, even if new tax legislation is generally desirable, providing transition relief is more efficient than not providing it because transition relief minimizes wasteful postenactment lobbying costs.
    • Ramseyer1    Nakazato2
  • 111
    • 84858204756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1173.
  • 112
    • 84858243240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kyle Logue argues that it is economically efficient to provide transition relief in the context of incentive subsidies, which he defines as "provisions whose primary purpose is to alter taxpayers' decisions regarding how they will invest their resources.".
  • 113
    • 84858263585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Logue, supra, at 1138 (emphasis omitted). He argues that if transition relief is not provided for incentive subsidies, then "future incentive credits would have to be more generous. to achieve the same amount of increased investment in the targeted asset or activity.".
    • Logue1
  • 114
    • 84858267377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1139.
  • 115
    • 84858243239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To use Logue's example, suppose there was a dearth of low-income housing.
  • 116
    • 84858243238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1144. To remedy this situation, the government might decide to pass an incentive subsidy and grant a tax credit to individuals who invest in low-income housing.
  • 117
    • 84858204758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By granting this credit, people who otherwise would not invest in low-income housing would be encouraged to do so. If this incentive subsidy was later repealed and transition relief was not provided, those investors would suffer a transition loss.
  • 118
    • 84858204755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 1133, 1139.
  • 119
    • 84858263586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This would cause future investors to be more cautious when making investments based on promised tax credits because there is a possibility that the government would repeal the tax credit, making their investments unprofitable.
  • 120
    • 84858263587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1140. Thus, in order to ensure that the proper level of investment is achieved, the government would have to increase future incentive subsidies or, to use Logue's terminology, increase the "default premium.".
  • 121
    • 84858204759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1139.
  • 122
    • 84858204757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 38-39.
    • Shavell1
  • 123
    • 84858267379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra text accompanying notes 56-59.
  • 124
    • 84858267378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 38-39.
    • Shavell1
  • 125
    • 84858243242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 41.
  • 126
    • 84858267381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 56-57.
  • 127
    • 84858204760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell acknowledges that grandfathering may actually increase participation in certain activities and that "because such enhanced participation would tend to be socially undesirable, grandfathering would be socially desirable less often than [he] found it to be.".
  • 128
    • 84858267380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 57.
  • 129
    • 84858204761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 42.
  • 130
    • 84858243241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 42-43.
  • 131
    • 84858243243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 41-42.
  • 132
    • 84858263590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 46-47.
  • 133
    • 84858204762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 44.
  • 134
    • 84858263588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 46-47.
  • 135
    • 84858267383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 79.
  • 136
    • 84858267382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Perhaps the reason Kaplow does not address this argument is that his article is primarily concerned with a strict liability regime, and grandfathering is always undesirable in strict liability regimes where "parties will automatically be induced to take past behavior into account in a socially appropriate manner.".
  • 137
    • 84858186418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 39.
  • 138
    • 84858246888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow, supra note 2, at 531-32.
    • Kaplow1
  • 139
    • 84858186417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell argues that "[t]he key to understanding the difference in conclusions is to note that the transitions literature does not distinguish between legal rules based on legal standards and legal rules based on strict liability.".
  • 140
    • 84858251904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 78. However, as we demonstrate, actors can also be expected to anticipate legal changes when those changes are based on legal standards.
    • Shavell1
  • 141
    • 84858246890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra Part II.
  • 142
    • 84858186420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Shavell, supra note 2, at 79.
    • Shavell1
  • 143
    • 84858243233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 42-43, 80 (assuming that "present regulated behavior. appropriately reflect[s] all possible future changes in the world").
  • 144
    • 84858186421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 80 ("[T]he legal standard in period 1 impounds correctly all possible future changes in harm in period 2.").
  • 145
    • 33751251369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Centralized Oversight of the regulatory state
    • note
    • See, e.g., Nicholas Bagley & Richard L. Revesz, Centralized Oversight of the Regulatory State, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 1260, 1268 (2006) (noting that the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) primarily focuses on Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) regulations due to their economic significance).
    • (2006) COLUM. L. REV. , vol.106
    • Bagley, N.1    Revesz, R.L.2
  • 146
    • 84858186419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Shavell, supra note 2, at 38 ("Consider a firm that installed a type of smoke scrubber that satisfied pollution-control rules 5 years ago when the firm built a factory.").
    • Shavell1
  • 147
    • 84858251906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 79.
  • 148
    • 84858251905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 78-83 and accompanying text.
  • 149
    • 84858251907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 78-79 and accompanying text.
  • 150
    • 84858246889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 49-50, 61-62.
    • Shavell1
  • 151
    • 84858251908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 68-69 (discussing general stability of the law).
  • 152
    • 84858233963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 42-43 (noting that the uncertainty about the level of harm is resolved by the beginning of period 2 and that, at this time, the law will change "in the light of the new information and circumstances")
  • 153
    • 84858251909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also id. at 80 (assuming that present regulations reflect "all possible future changes in the world").
  • 154
    • 84858188495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 80 (assuming that "present regulated behavior. appropriately reflect[s] all possible future changes in the world" and that "the legal standard in period 1 impounds correctly all possible future changes in harm in period 2").
  • 155
    • 84858246892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell does, however, acknowledge that imperfect information of the state may change the analysis.
  • 156
    • 84858240629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 54-55.
  • 157
    • 77954754014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See RICHARD L. REVESZ, ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND POLICY 168 (2008) (noting that performance standards are set "by reference to what the best available technology can accomplish, but. each source [may] choose the actual technology that it intends to use in order to meet the standard")
    • (2008) ENVIRONMENTAL LAW and POLICY , pp. 168
    • Richard, L.R.1
  • 158
    • 0347776234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Choice of regulatory instruments in environmental policy
    • note
    • Nathaniel O. Keohane, Richard L. Revesz & Robert N. Stavins, The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy, 22 HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. 313, 313 (1998) (noting that although design standards "requir[e] a particular technology's usage. performance standards prescrib[e] the maximum amount of pollution that a source can emit")
    • (1998) HARV. ENVTL. L. REV. , vol.22
    • Keohane, N.O.1    Revesz, R.L.2    Stavins, R.N.3
  • 159
    • 1542650802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goals, instruments, and environmental policy choice
    • note
    • Sydney A. Shapiro & Robert L. Glicksman, Goals, Instruments, and Environmental Policy Choice, 10 DUKE ENVTL. L. & POL'Y F. 297, 308 (2000) ("Performance standards rely on particular technologies to formulate pollution reduction goals, but do not dictate that those same technologies be used as policy instruments to achieve those goals.").
    • (2000) DUKE ENVTL. L. & POL'Y F. , vol.10
    • Shapiro, S.A.1    Glicksman, R.L.2
  • 160
    • 84937276351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress, constitutional moments, and the cost-benefit state
    • note
    • See, e.g., Cass R. Sunstein, Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State, 48 STAN. L. REV. 247, 268 (1996) ("[I]f an industry can comply with a sulfur dioxide emission standard by either using clean coal or implementing energy conservation methods, government should not command a particular method of compliance.")
    • (1996) STAN. L. REV. , vol.48
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 161
    • 21344494659 scopus 로고
    • More Good than harm": A first principle for environmental agencies and reviewing courts
    • note
    • Edward W. Warren & Gary E. Marchant, "More Good Than Harm": A First Principle for Environmental Agencies and Reviewing Courts, 20 ECOLOGY L.Q. 379, 425-26 (1993) ("'[P]erformance standards,' which allow regulated companies to choose their own methods of compliance, are more cost effective than 'design standards,' which impose specific compliance methods.").
    • (1993) ECOLOGY L.Q , vol.20
    • Warren, E.W.1    Marchant, G.E.2
  • 162
    • 84858268171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See REVESZ, supra note 78, at 168
    • Revesz1
  • 163
    • 84858162939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shapiro & Glicksman, supra note 78, at 305 ("In theory at least, regulated entities subject to a performance standard have an incentive to develop such alternative means if they provide a more efficient means of achieving the regulatory goal.").
    • Shapiro1    Glicksman2
  • 164
    • 84858246894 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra text accompanying notes 101-05 (discussing Adamo Wrecking Co. v. United States, 434 U.S. 275, 289 (1978)).
    • (1978)
  • 165
    • 0041728483 scopus 로고
    • Beyond the _ew deal: Coal and the clean air act
    • note
    • See Bruce A. Ackerman & William T. Hassler, Beyond the _ew Deal: Coal and the Clean Air Act, 89 YALE L.J. 1466, 1485 & n.71 (1980)
    • (1980) YALE L.J. , vol.89 , Issue.71
    • Ackerman, B.A.1    Hassler, W.T.2
  • 166
    • 84858251911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • REVESZ, supra note 78, at 216-17
    • Revesz1
  • 167
    • 0003951050 scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also BRUCE A. ACKERMAN & WILLIAM T. HASSLER, CLEAN COAL/DIRTY AIR 31-54 (1981) (discussing political considerations that motivate alternate methods for complying with the applicable standard).
    • (1981) CLEAN COAL/DIRTY AIR , pp. 31-54
    • Bruce, A.A.1    William, T.H.2
  • 168
  • 169
    • 0348080690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Triumph of technology-based standards
    • note
    • Wendy E. Wagner, The Triumph of Technology-Based Standards, 2000 U. ILL. L. REV. 83, 90 ("[A]lmost all technology-based standards. take the form of quantitative pollution limits and thus allow industry to choose how to best meet the standards-a choice that includes developing new pollution control technologies that run more cheaply or effectively.").
    • U. ILL. L. REV. , vol.2000
    • Wagner, W.E.1
  • 170
    • 84858162943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a detailed discussion of what constitutes a modification.
  • 172
    • 84858240620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See also infra notes 232-34 and accompanying text (discussing how certain modifications trigger new source review under the Clean Air Act).
  • 173
    • 84858183362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(a)(1)-(2), (b)(1)(B), (b)(4) (2006) (providing that stringent federal performance standards apply to "new sources" of air pollution and including modified sources within the definition of "new source").
    • (2006)
  • 174
    • 77952787384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Balancing Mandate and discretion in the institutional design of federal climate change policy
    • note
    • See, e.g., Robert L. Glicksman, Balancing Mandate and Discretion in the Institutional Design of Federal Climate Change Policy, 102 NW. U. L. REV. COLLOQUY 196, 205 (2008) ("The EPA must identify the best available technology for a particular industry and calculate the performance-based results that the identified technology is capable of achieving. Industry is then free to comply by using the identified technology or any other means it prefers that allow more efficient compliance." (footnote omitted)).
    • (2008) NW. U. L. REV. COLLOQUY , vol.102
    • Glicksman, R.L.1
  • 175
    • 84858268164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • § 7411(a)(1).
  • 176
    • 84858183361 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments created two new programs-the Prevention of Significant Deterioration (PSD) Program and the Nonattainment Program. PSD was aimed at preserving the air quality in regions where air quality was superior to the quality required by the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS). Clean Air Act Amendments of 1977, Pub. L. No. 95-95, 91 Stat. 685 (1977).
  • 177
    • 84858240623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • REVESZ, supra note 78, at 373, 384-85.
    • Revesz1
  • 178
    • 84858240621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Nonattainment Program provisions are aimed at those areas that have not achieved compliance with the primary NAAQS.
  • 179
    • 84858240622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • REVESZ, supra note 78, at 384-85.
    • Revesz1
  • 180
    • 84858240624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The term "major emitting facility" is defined by the source's "potential to emit." § 7479(1). The term "stationary source," as opposed to mobile source, is defined in § 7602(z).
  • 181
    • 84858268163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 7479(3).
    • , Issue.3 , pp. 7479
  • 182
    • 84858183363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The relevant statutory language reads: Each State shall. adopt and submit to the Administrator. a plan which provides for implementation, maintenance, and enforcement of such primary standard in each air quality control region. within such State. In addition, such State shall adopt and submit to the Administrator. a plan which provides for implementation, maintenance, and enforcement of such secondary standard in each air quality control region. within such State. Id. § 7410(a)(1).
  • 183
    • 84858268165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 7501(3)(A)-(B).
  • 184
    • 84858183364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. §§ 7479(3), 7501(3)
  • 185
    • 84858162934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see REVESZ, supra note 78, at 374, 387.
    • Revesz1
  • 186
    • 84858188490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • § 7410(a)(1).
  • 187
    • 84858268168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Clean Air Act requires states to adopt enforceable emission limitations.
  • 188
    • 84858188491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See § 7410(a)(2)(A)
  • 189
    • 84858270765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Location, location, location: Did north carolina go far enough?
    • note
    • see also D. R. van der Vaart & John C. Evans, Location, Location, Location: Did North Carolina Go Far Enough?, 10 VT. J. ENVTL. L. 267, 269 (2009) ("The strategy that states develop to satisfy their obligation as the primary implementing agency-typically a mixture of emission standards and regulations-is collectively referred to as the [State Implementation Plan].").
    • (2009) VT. J. ENVTL. L. , vol.10
    • van der Vaart, D.R.1    Evans, J.C.2
  • 190
    • 84858183365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990, Pub. L. No. 101-549, § 172(c)(1), 104 Stat. 2412, 2414 (1990).
  • 191
    • 77950495498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Air Quality protection using state implementation plans-thirty-seven years of increasing complexity
    • note
    • see Arnold W. Reitze Jr., Air Quality Protection Using State Implementation Plans-Thirty-Seven Years of Increasing Complexity, 15 VILL. ENVTL. L.J. 209, 227 (2004).
    • (2004) VILL. ENVTL. L.J. , vol.15
    • Reitze, A.W.1
  • 192
    • 84858268167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Adamo Wrecking Co. v. United States, 434 U.S. 275, 289 (1978) (quoting S. REP. NO. 95-127, at 44 (1977)).
  • 193
    • 84858268166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7412(h)(1).
  • 194
    • 84858183368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Adamo, 434 U.S. at 286 (quoting Clean Air Act Amendments of 1977 § 110).
  • 195
    • 84858240625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Adamo, 434 U.S. at 287.
    • Adamo1
  • 196
    • 84858240627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. (quoting 38 Fed. Reg. 8820, 8821 (Apr. 6, 1973)) (internal quotation mark omitted).
  • 197
    • 84858188492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Clean Water Act defines point source as "any discernible, confined and discrete conveyance, including but not limited to any pipe, ditch, channel, tunnel, conduit, well, discrete fissure, container, rolling stock, concentrated animal feeding operation, or vessel or other floating craft, from which pollutants are or may be discharged." 33 U.S.C. § 1362(14) (2006).
    • (2006) , Issue.14 , pp. 1362
  • 198
    • 84858268172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • § 1316(a)(1).
  • 199
    • 84858268169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See CPC Int'l Inc. v. Train, 515 F.2d 1032, 1045 n.25 (8th Cir. 1975) (citing S. REP. NO. 92-414, at 1477 (1971)).
  • 200
    • 84858240628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • § 1311(b)(1)(A)(i).
  • 201
    • 84858233965 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 1311(b)(2)(A)(i).
  • 202
    • 84858233966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • REVESZ, supra note 78, at 535 ("The three main types of variances are § 301(c) variances (allowing modifications of BAT standards on the basis of economic capability), § 301(g) variances (allowing modification to BAT standards on water quality grounds), and fundamentally different factor (FDF) variances (allowing modifications to individual point sources that demonstrate characteristics that are fundamentally different from those which define the category in which the source is placed).").
    • Revesz1
  • 203
    • 84858251910 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In the case of "point sources" the pollution comes out of a "discernible, confined and discrete conveyance," § 1362(14). Typically, the pollution comes out of a pipe. Nonpoint sources, in contrast, are typically agricultural or urban runoff.
  • 204
    • 84858246893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See REVESZ, supra note 78, at 545-46.
    • Revesz1
  • 205
    • 84858168494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 546.
  • 206
    • 84858246947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 515, 546.
  • 207
    • 84858186468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 546.
  • 209
    • 84858168493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 136-37.
  • 210
    • 84858269037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Due diligence-counting carbon
    • note
    • See, e.g., Jeff Civins, Mary Mendoza & Adam Sencenbaugh, Environmental Due Diligence-Counting Carbon, 24 NAT. RESOURCES & ENV'T 37, 38 (2009) ("Driven by a variety of stakeholders, and perhaps in anticipation of upcoming regulation, many sources of GHG emissions have undertaken voluntary measures to reduce CO2 and other GHGs attributable to their operations.")
    • (2009) NAT. RESOURCES & ENV'T , vol.24
    • Civins, J.1    Mendoza, M.2    Sencenbaugh, A.3
  • 211
    • 84858175994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Commission Guidance Regarding Disclosure Related to Climate Change, 75 Fed. Reg. 6290, 6291 (Feb. 8, 2010) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 211, 231, 241) (discussing potential for future climate change regulation and noting "increasing calls for climate-related disclosures by shareholders of public companies").
  • 212
    • 84858168492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Civins et al., supra note 118, at 38-39 (noting that in addition to reducing emissions from stationary sources, which are most likely to be regulated, companies are also voluntarily taking efforts to reduce their overall carbon footprint).
    • Civins1
  • 213
    • 34249323329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate Social responsibility: Hard choices on soft issues
    • note
    • See Jeffery Marshall, Corporate Social Responsibility: Hard Choices on Soft Issues, FIN. EXECUTIVE, July/Aug. 2005, at 44, 45-46
    • (2005) FIN. EXECUTIVE
    • Marshall, J.1
  • 214
    • 84858175995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Greening of general electric: A lean, clean electric machine
    • note
    • The Greening of General Electric: A Lean, Clean Electric Machine, ECONOMIST, Dec. 10, 2005, at 77
    • (2005) ECONOMIST , pp. 77
  • 215
    • 34250896205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ECOMAGINATION, http://www.ecomagination.com (last visited Nov. 23, 2011) (describing the program and its success so far).
    • ECOMAGINATION
  • 216
    • 84858228811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wal-mart to double solar initiative
    • note
    • See Paul Davidson, Wal-Mart to Double Solar Initiative, USA TODAY, Apr. 22, 2009, at 3B.
    • (2009) USA TODAY
    • Davidson, P.1
  • 217
    • 84858174492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Citigroup Tries banking on the natural kind of green
    • note
    • Jim Carlton, Citigroup Tries Banking on the Natural Kind of Green, WALL ST. J., Sept. 5, 2007, at B1.
    • (2007) WALL ST. J.
    • Carlton, J.1
  • 218
    • 84858168496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Greening of Google, SOLARIPEDIA, http://www.solaripedia.com/13/63/greening_of_google.html (last visited Aug. 11, 2011).
    • Greening of Google
  • 220
    • 84858168495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • CHI. CLIMATE EXCH., OVERVIEW BROCHURE 3 (2008) (on file with authors) (listing one of the benefits of joining the exchange as the opportunity to "demonstrate unique commitment through a legally binding goal, to shareholders").
    • (2008) CHI. CLIMATE EXCH., OVERVIEW BROCHURE , pp. 3
  • 221
    • 84858176000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 2.
  • 222
    • 84858186470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If a special event requires a member to emit more than its allotted amount of emissions, the member can purchase a Carbon Financial Instrument contract (CFI) to offset the extra emissions released.
  • 223
    • 84858182214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 4.
  • 224
    • 84858175997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cap-and-trade exchange calls it quits
    • note
    • John Collins Rudolf, Cap-and-Trade Exchange Calls It Quits, N.Y. TIMES GREEN BLOG (Nov. 17, 2010, 8:22 AM), http://green.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/11/17/climate-futures-exchange-calls-it-quits ("With climate legislation in the United States dead in the water for the foreseeable future, participants in the exchange have lost interest.").
    • N.Y. TIMES GREEN BLOG
    • Rudolf, J.C.1
  • 225
    • 84858186469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Pet. for Interpretive Guidance on Climate Risk Disclosures at 8 (2007) (No. 4-547), available at http://www.sec.gov/rules/petitions/2007/petn4-547.pdf ("Investors of all types are aware that climate change, and greenhouse gas regulation, will have enormous implications for long-term capital investments that are being made right now by corporations. They want to know how fully (if at all) companies are taking climate change into account in making those decisions. They want to identify, and invest in, companies that are 'out front' in responding to climate risks and opportunities, and to avoid firms that are behind the curve.")
  • 226
    • 84858240200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulating Greenhouse gases by mandatory information disclosure
    • note
    • see also Andrew Schatz, Note, Regulating Greenhouse Gases by Mandatory Information Disclosure, 26 VA. ENVTL. L.J. 335, 371 (2008) (discussing how investors are increasingly putting pressure on companies to disclose greenhouse gas emissions).
    • (2008) VA. ENVTL. L.J. , vol.26
    • Schatz, A.1
  • 227
    • 84858168497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 76 and accompanying text.
  • 228
    • 50049097708 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emerging Science, adaptive regulation, and the problem of rulemaking ruts
    • note
    • See Lynn E. Blais & Wendy E. Wagner, Emerging Science, Adaptive Regulation, and the Problem of Rulemaking Ruts, 86 TEX. L. REV. 1701, 1701 (2008) ("[W]hen new information threatens to unsettle existing regulatory requirements governing powerful stakeholders in the rulemaking process, using it to develop stricter environmental standards is unlikely to be a simple or straightforward matter.").
    • (2008) TEX. L. REV. , vol.86
    • Blais, L.E.1    Wagner, W.E.2
  • 229
    • 70049111786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Super Wicked problems and climate change: Restraining the present to liberate the future
    • note
    • See Richard J. Lazarus, Super Wicked Problems and Climate Change: Restraining the Present to Liberate the Future, 94 CORNELL L. REV. 1153, 1180 (2009) ("The essentially conservative, fragmented, and deliberately cumbersome process for lawmaking in the United States does not readily lend itself to such responsive, iterative lawmaking initiatives.")
    • (2009) CORNELL L. REV. , vol.94
    • Lazarus, R.J.1
  • 230
    • 84858175999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Air Pollution standards for stationary sources: Next moves (oct. 6, 2009)
    • note
    • Donald Stever et al., Air Pollution Standards for Stationary Sources: Next Moves (Oct. 6, 2009), in 40 ENVTL. L. REP. 10012, 10013 (2010) ("[W]e don't want to go through a period like the 1980s again, when we waited around for Congress to pass what eventually became the 1990 [Clean Air Act] Amendments."). Delay may be particularly problematic in the environmental context given its "inherently dynamic nature."
    • (2010) ENVTL. L. REP. , vol.40
    • Stever, D.1
  • 231
    • 84858182216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Lazarus, supra, at 1180, 1227 ("Environmental law's inherently dynamic nature creates further obstacles in that multiple statutes, statutory amendments, and regulatory revisions are likely to be necessary over time.").
    • Lazarus1
  • 232
    • 0347802046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress, science, and environmental policy
    • note
    • See, e.g., Wendy E. Wagner, Congress, Science, and Environmental Policy, 1999 U. ILL. L. REV. 181, 222 ("The oldest model of congressional behavior, the popular democracy model, depicts a federal legislator as the direct representative or agent of the people."). We will consider a less representative model of Congress when we discuss interest group theory and public choice pathologies in Part V.
    • U. ILL. L. REV. , vol.1999
    • Wagner, W.E.1
  • 233
    • 70449126089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See FRANK R. BAUMGARTNER et al., LOBBYING AND POLICY CHANGE: WHO WINS, WHO LOSES, AND WHY 22 (2009) ("The information environment in Washington is overwhelmingly complex, with thousands of bills being considered each year in Congress, hundreds of hearings occurring in more than a hundred different subcommittees, and public concerns moving from issue to issue at a rapid pace.")
    • (2009) LOBBYING and POLICY CHANGE: WHO WINS, WHO LOSES, and WHY , pp. 22
    • Frank, R.B.1
  • 234
    • 84858186471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • RICHARD L. HALL, PARTICIPATION IN CONGRESS 24 (1996) ("Congressmen in committees simply have too much to do legislatively and too little time, energy, and other legislative resources to do it. They cannot take on every issue; they must choose.").
    • (1996) PARTICIPATION IN CONGRESS , vol.24
    • Richard, L.H.1
  • 235
    • 84858168500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See REVESZ & LIVERMORE, supra note 116, at 108 ("[T]he benefits of mitigating climate change will occur in the future. ").
    • Revesz1    Livermore2
  • 236
    • 84858168499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, some environmental issues-such as hazardous waste disposal-are highly salient.
  • 237
    • 0025260463 scopus 로고
    • Legislative Incapacity: The congressional role in environmental policymaking and the case of superfund
    • note
    • See, e.g., Barry G. Rabe, Legislative Incapacity: The Congressional Role in Environmental Policymaking and the Case of Superfund, 15 J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L. 571, 576 (1990) (describing hazardous waste disposal as a "high-salience" issue, leading to the enactment of both the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA) and the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (CERCLA)).
    • (1990) J. HEALTH POL. POL'Y & L. , vol.15
    • Rabe, B.G.1
  • 238
    • 0039869782 scopus 로고
    • Congress as reluctant regulator: Hazardous waste policy in the 1980's
    • note
    • See James J. Florio, Congress as Reluctant Regulator: Hazardous Waste Policy in the 1980's, 3 YALE J. ON REG. 351, 380 (1986) (noting that because of Congress's "limited attention span," regulatory programs may be subject to "long periods of stagnation")
    • (1986) YALE J. ON REG. , vol.3
    • Florio, J.J.1
  • 239
    • 84858168498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also BAUMGARTNER et al., supra note 135, at 22 (noting "scarcity of space on the public agenda").
    • Baumgartner1
  • 240
    • 84858176002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Global Warming
    • note
    • Andrew C. Revkin, Global Warming, ASOCIACIÓN DE VOLUNTARIOS PARA EL SERVICIO EN AREAS PROTEGIDAS DE COSTA RICA, http://www.asvocr.org/english/noticias/index.php?subaction=showfull&id=1268024383&archive=&start_from=&ucat=57&(last visited Aug. 11, 2011) ("[A] national preoccupation with the slow economy and competing issues, led by health care, threaten to delay or weaken [climate change] legislation.").
    • ASOCIACIÓN DE VOLUNTARIOS PARA EL SERVICIO EN AREAS PROTEGIDAS DE COSTA RICA
    • Revkin, A.C.1
  • 241
    • 84858176001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Stever et al., supra note 133, at 10013 (suggesting that congressional delay caused amendments to the Clean Air Act discussed in the 1980s to not actually be adopted until 1990).
    • Stever1
  • 242
    • 84858164521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taking the pit bull off the leash: Siccing the endangered species act on climate change
    • note
    • Ari N. Sommer, Note, Taking the Pit Bull off the Leash: Siccing the Endangered Species Act on Climate Change, 36 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 273, 283 n.80 (2009) ("The Clean Water Act (CWA) was passed in its modern form in 1972, with significant amendments in 1977 and 1987.").
    • (2009) B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. , vol.36 , Issue.80
    • Sommer, A.N.1
  • 243
    • 84858186472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rabe, supra note 137, at 573 ("This transformation [from committee to subcommittee governance] enabled multiple House subcommittees to explore the same policy area, compounding the historical problems of overlapping committee jurisdiction.")
    • Rabe1
  • 244
    • 84858176004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Lazarus, supra note 133, at 1181 ("Fragmentation of congressional committee jurisdiction over environmental issues is inevitable given the ways in which ecological cause and effect span so many diverse human activities.").
    • Lazarus1
  • 245
    • 84858186473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Rabe, supra note 137, at 573 ("Multiple hearings and bill referrals became commonplace, resulting. in the enactment of fewer laws and the submission of fewer reports to the full House. However, those laws that were passed were longer and more complex.").
    • Rabe1
  • 246
    • 84858182220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Lazarus, supra note 133, at 1180 ("Securing passage of environmental law. requires multiple debates.").
    • Lazarus1
  • 247
    • 84858168501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rabe, supra note 137, at 576.
    • Rabe1
  • 248
    • 84858256774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Climate Change and backlash
    • note
    • See, e.g., Eric Biber, Climate Change and Backlash, 17 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 1295, 1319 (noting that socially desirable environmental regulations often impose concentrated costs on particular industries, thus giving them an incentive to resist the regulation)
    • N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. , vol.17
    • Biber, E.1
  • 249
    • 84858204088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Period of consequences": Global warming legislation, cooperative federalism, and the fight between the epa and the state of california
    • note
    • Krista Yee, "A Period of Consequences": Global Warming Legislation, Cooperative Federalism, and the Fight Between the EPA and the State of California, 32 ENVIRONS: ENVTL. L. & POL'Y J. 183, 200 (2008) ("Global warming legislation often impacts the automobile industry, forcing manufacturers to create new cars in compliance with recently enacted environmental standards, sometimes at great cost. Thus, from a business perspective, it is natural for the automobile industry to resist new environmental legislation." (footnote omitted)).
    • (2008) ENVIRONS: ENVTL. L. & POL'Y J. , vol.32
    • Yee, K.1
  • 250
    • 84858182219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even if environmental legislation has numerous benefits, members of Congress tend "to weigh the prospect of potential losses more heavily than the possibility of gains" and thus may be wary about passing legislation "that may generate unintended and deleterious consequences" even when the legislation is also likely to produce beneficial results.
  • 251
    • 84858182218 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • BAUMGARTNER et al., supra note 135, at 114.
    • Baumgartner1
  • 252
    • 77955097418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Administrative Law, filter failure, and information capture
    • note
    • See Wendy E. Wagner, Administrative Law, Filter Failure, and Information Capture, 59 DUKE L.J. 1321, 1325-26, 1329 (2010) (discussing the problem of information capture, noting that because "[a]dministrative law. imposes almost no filtering requirements. on any of the participants who engage in the rulemaking," well-financed interest groups can "gain[] control over regulatory decisionmaking in informal rulemakings" through "the excessive use of information. [and a] continuous barrage of letters, telephone calls, meetings, follow-up memoranda, formal comments, postrule comments, petitions for reconsideration, and notices of appeal").
    • (2010) DUKE L.J. , vol.59
    • Wagner, W.E.1
  • 253
    • 70349234825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Iterative Federalism and climate change
    • Ann E. Carlson, Iterative Federalism and Climate Change, 103 NW. U. L. REV. 1097, 1117 (2009).
    • (2009) NW. U. L. REV. , vol.103
    • Carlson, A.E.1
  • 254
    • 77958410286 scopus 로고
    • Toward a theory of statutory evolution: The federalization of environmental law
    • note
    • See E. Donald Elliott, Bruce A. Ackerman & John C. Millian, Toward a Theory of Statutory Evolution: The Federalization of Environmental Law, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 313, 329 (1985)
    • (1985) J.L. ECON. & ORG. , vol.1
    • Donald Elliott, E.1    Ackerman, B.A.2    Millian, J.C.3
  • 255
    • 84858176005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Carlson, supra note 148, at 1111 ("Elliott, Ackerman, and Millian theorize that this federal legislation [regulating automobile emissions] came about largely because automobile manufacturers, along with the coal industry, feared inconsistent and potentially more stringent regulations from state and local governments.").
    • Carlson1
  • 256
    • 84858182217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., ACKERMAN & HASSLER, supra note 82, at 11 n.*, 31
    • , vol.11 , pp. 31
    • Ackerman1    Hassler2
  • 257
    • 84858192671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law and economics of environmental federalism: Europe and the united states compared
    • note
    • Michael G. Faure & Jason Scott Johnston, The Law and Economics of Environmental Federalism: Europe and the United States Compared, 27 VA. ENVTL. L.J. 205, 273 (2009) ("[I]ndustry in countries with a high demand for environmental protection would lobby to impose tough standards on competitors in other jurisdictions, thus benefiting from their higher levels of environmental regulation by effectively creating barriers to entry.").
    • (2009) VA. ENVTL. L.J. , vol.27
    • Faure, M.G.1    Johnston, J.S.2
  • 258
    • 0347293362 scopus 로고
    • Goals Statutes or rules statutes: The case of the clean air act
    • note
    • See David Schoenbrod, Goals Statutes or Rules Statutes: The Case of the Clean Air Act, 30 UCLA L. REV. 740, 812-13 (1983) ("A supposed advantage of delegation is that delegated authorities can respond more quickly than Congress to significant new information. Practice under the Clean Air Act, however, has proved far different than theory.").
    • (1983) UCLA L. REV. , vol.30
    • Schoenbrod, D.1
  • 259
    • 21144470858 scopus 로고
    • Some Thoughts on "deossifying" the rulemaking process
    • note
    • See Thomas O. McGarity, Some Thoughts on "Deossifying" the Rulemaking Process, 41 DUKE L.J. 1385 (1992)
    • (1992) DUKE L.J. , vol.41 , pp. 1385
    • McGarity, T.O.1
  • 260
    • 0039689847 scopus 로고
    • Seven Ways to deossify agency rulemaking
    • note
    • Richard J. Pierce, Jr., Seven Ways to Deossify Agency Rulemaking, 47 ADMIN. L. REV. 59 (1995). For examples in more general works
    • (1995) ADMIN. L. REV. , vol.47 , pp. 59
    • Pierce, R.J.1
  • 262
    • 84858168502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Blais & Wagner, supra note 132, at 1704-06
    • Blais1    Wagner2
  • 263
    • 77956721373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deregulation Through nonenforcement
    • note
    • Daniel T. Deacon, Note, Deregulation Through Nonenforcement, 85 N.Y.U. L. REV. 795, 825-26 (2010).
    • (2010) N.Y.U. L. REV. , vol.85
    • Deacon, D.T.1
  • 264
    • 84858182221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Pierce, supra note 152, at 62.
    • Pierce1
  • 265
    • 84858186475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 64.
  • 266
    • 84858168505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 65.
  • 267
    • 84858186477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 84.
  • 269
    • 84858162931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Blais & Wagner, supra note 132, at 1715-25 ("EPA is not revising standards frequently, and. when it does revise its standards, it is not necessarily because of advances in pollution-control technologies.").
    • Blais1    Wagner2
  • 270
    • 84858268151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Schoenbrod, supra note 151, at 812-13 (footnote omitted).
    • Schoenbrod1
  • 271
    • 0033475286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Waiting to be protected under the endangered species act: The political economy of regulatory delay
    • note
    • See Amy Whritenour Ando, Waiting to be Protected Under the Endangered Species Act: The Political Economy of Regulatory Delay, 42 J.L. & ECON. 29, 30, 45-48, 52 (1999) (using empirical analysis to demonstrate how interest group pressure delays endangered species listings).
    • (1999) J.L. & ECON. , vol.42
    • Ando, A.W.1
  • 272
    • 84858162930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Blais & Wagner, supra note 132, at 1713-15.
    • Blais1    Wagner2
  • 273
    • 84858240613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 79-80 ("[B]y the design of the regulators, present regulated behavior will in principle appropriately reflect all possible future changes in the world. In the model that I examined, for example, the level of precaution chosen by the regulators to be the legal standard in period 1 impounds correctly all possible future changes in harm in period 2.").
    • Shavell1
  • 274
    • 11844287630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commons Ignorance: The failure of environmental law to produce needed information on health and the environment
    • note
    • See Wendy E. Wagner, Commons Ignorance: The Failure of Environmental Law to Produce Needed Information on Health and the Environment, 53 DUKE L.J. 1619, 1641-42 (2004).
    • DUKE L.J. , vol.53
    • Wagner, W.E.1
  • 275
    • 84858183357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Levmore, supra note 44, at 1659.
    • Levmore1
  • 276
    • 84858183356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The standard of review for agency regulations depends on the relevant statute. For example, the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA) has the burden of demonstrating that it developed regulations based upon substantial evidence-a more demanding standard of review than the "arbitrary and capricious" standard. See Indus. Union Dep't, AFL-CIO v. Am. Petroleum Inst., 448 U.S. 607, 705 (1980) (Marshall, J., dissenting) ("This standard represents a legislative judgment that regulatory action should be subject to review more stringent than the traditional 'arbitrary and capricious' standard for informal rulemaking.").
  • 277
    • 84858268160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., United Steelworkers of America, AFL-CIO-CLC v. Marshall, 647 F.2d 1189, 1266 (D.C. Cir. 1980) ("As for technological feasibility, we know that we cannot require of OSHA anything like certainty. Since 'technology-forcing' assumes the agency will make highly speculative projections about future technology, a standard is obviously not infeasible solely because OSHA has no hard evidence to show that the standard has been met.").
  • 278
    • 84858183359 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Indus. Union Dep't, 448 U.S. at 652-53, 662 (holding that OSHA must demonstrate "a significant risk of material health impairment" before issuing standards); Gulf S. Insulation v. U.S. Consumer Prod. Safety Comm'n, 701 F.2d 1137, 1146 (5th Cir. 1983) (overturning formaldehyde regulation because "it is not good science to rely on a single experiment, particularly one involving only 240 subjects, to make precise estimates of cancer risk. To make precise estimates, precise data are required."); Portland Cement Ass'n v. Ruckelshaus, 486 F.2d 375, 391 (D.C. Cir. 1973) ("The Administrator may make a projection based on existing technology, though that projection is subject to the restraints of reasonableness and cannot be based on 'crystal ball' inquiry." (quoting Int'l Harvester Co. v. Ruckelshaus, 478 F.2d 615, 629 (D.C. Cir. 1973)); Int'l Harvester Co., 478 F.2d at 645 (rejecting EPA's assumption used to calculate lead adjustment factor as too speculative).
  • 279
    • 84858268157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Industrial Union Dep't, 448 U.S. at 652-53 (footnote omitted).
  • 280
    • 84858240617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Portland Cement Ass'n, 486 F.2d at 379 ("The action of the Administrator has been challenged on [three] grounds. [including that] [t]he achievability of the standards was not adequately demonstrated.")
  • 281
    • 84858240616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also supra note 87 and accompanying text.
  • 282
    • 84858240615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Portland Cement Ass'n, 486 F.2d at 391 (quoting Int'l Harvester Co., 478 F.2d at 629).
  • 283
    • 84858183358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 392 (quoting Int'l Harvester Co., 478 F.2d at 642).
  • 284
    • 0002700335 scopus 로고
    • Good Science, bad regulation, and toxic risk assessment
    • note
    • See, e.g., Howard Latin, Good Science, Bad Regulation, and Toxic Risk Assessment, 5 YALE J. ON REG. 89, 133 (1988) [hereinafter Latin, Good Science] ("[J]udicial requirements for comprehensive agency assessments of all potentially relevant factors and for a high degree of scientific precision have substantially emasculated environmental control programs in the past decade.")
    • (1988) YALE J. ON REG. , vol.5
    • Latin, H.1
  • 285
    • 0000905294 scopus 로고
    • Regulatory Failure, administrative incentives, and the new clean air act
    • note
    • Howard Latin, Regulatory Failure, Administrative Incentives, and the New Clean Air Act, 21 ENVTL. L. 1647, 1663 (1991) [hereinafter Latin, Regulatory Failure] (noting that judicial review leads agencies to avoid regulating under uncertainty); Wagner, supra note 147, at 1422 ("Rather than focusing its energies on developing public-oriented regulatory policy, the agency finds instead that it must devote most of its analysis to preparing rules that can withstand fierce attack from an aggressive group of affected interests and respond to the flood of information loaded into the system by these same groups.").
    • (1991) ENVTL. L. , vol.21
    • Latin, H.1
  • 286
    • 84858183355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Latin, Regulatory Failure, supra note 172, at 1663 (footnote omitted).
    • Regulatory Failure , pp. 1663
    • Latin1
  • 287
    • 84858268158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The choice would be different, of course, if the old technology could simply be upgraded for the $5000 difference in the cost of the technologies. But just like we cannot upgrade our laptops by paying the difference between the cost of our obsolete three-year-old laptop and the cost of a new one with far greater computing power, typically this type of choice is also not available in the pollution-control context.
  • 288
    • 84858268159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra text accompanying notes 187-91.
  • 289
    • 84858162932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One might argue that the regulator could consider the date when the actor entered the activity in determining whether to grandfather the actor. That is, the regulator could choose to not grandfather entrants who should have adopted newer precautions. In practice, however, this policy would be difficult to implement because the regulator would have to make assumptions about when this information was first known and would have to be able to defend the decision against the inevitable judicial challenges.
  • 290
    • 84858240614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 73 ("[U]nlimited duration of grandfathering of plants raises questions.").
    • Shavell1
  • 291
    • 84858268161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We assume that the harm is $700,000 in each of the periods.
  • 292
    • 84858162933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The transition relief literature does not include detailed discussion about how new legal rules are selected, but it is implicit that new, prospective rules are those rules that would be optimal for new sources. Shavell assumes at the outset that the newly adopted regulation is the one that is optimal for new entrants.
  • 293
    • 84858240619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 48. He then discusses which grandfathering policy would be socially optimal in light of the new rule. Id. Kaplow also implies that the new rule is selected in light of what is optimal for new actors. He suggests that the new rule should be the rule we would want all existing sources to anticipate even in the face of uncertainty.
    • Shavell1
  • 294
    • 84858240618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow, supra note 2, at 521. He also assumes that the substantive policy decision is not affected by the choice of transition policy. Id. ("[T]he discussion assumes that the reforms themselves are desirable at the time they are made. A significant related assumption, implied by the stronger assumption just stated, is that substantive policy decisions are not themselves affected by the choice of transition policy.").
    • Kaplow1
  • 295
    • 84858168504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 53 and accompanying text.
  • 296
    • 84858168506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1708-09.
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 297
    • 84858176006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Several authors have provided an overview of the old-plant effect.
  • 298
    • 84858182222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See ACKERMAN & HASSLER, supra note 82, at 67-68
    • Ackerman1    Hassler2
  • 299
    • 84858186476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Keohane, Revesz & Stavins, supra note 78, at 315 n.10
    • , Issue.10 , pp. 315
    • Keohane, R.1    Stavins2
  • 300
    • 0020388428 scopus 로고
    • Differentiated Regulation: The case of auto emissions standards
    • note
    • see also Howard K. Gruenspecht, Differentiated Regulation: The Case of Auto Emissions Standards, 72 AM. ECON. REV. 328, 328 (1982) ("The adoption of more stringent emissions standards for new vehicles is shown to prolong the retention of old, high-emission-rate vehicles in the fleet.")
    • (1982) AM. ECON. REV. , vol.72
    • Gruenspecht, H.K.1
  • 301
    • 33947546473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vintage-differentiated environmental regulation
    • note
    • Robert N. Stavins, Vintage-Differentiated Environmental Regulation, 25 STAN. ENVTL. L.J. 29, 41-56 (2006) (describing "effects of vintage-differentiated regulation on the lives of durable plant and equipment")
    • (2006) STAN. ENVTL. L.J. , vol.25
    • Stavins, R.N.1
  • 302
    • 84858167670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spotlight on safety at nuclear power plants: The view from oyster creek
    • note
    • Richard Webster & Julia LeMense, Spotlight on Safety at Nuclear Power Plants: The View from Oyster Creek, 26 PACE ENVTL. L. REV. 365, 367 (2009) (describing how NRC regulations which have only "increased the safety requirements for new plants" have produced a "trend. toward relicensing of old plants rather than replacement with new plants").
    • (2009) PACE ENVTL. L. REV. , vol.26
    • Webster, R.1    Lemense, J.2
  • 303
    • 84858176007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Stavins, supra note 183, at 43 (noting that vintage-differentiated regulation "can lead to short-term emissions increases" and that "when the sources subject to regulation have especially low rates of deterioration and technical obsolescence. the 'short term' is very long").
    • Stavins1
  • 304
    • 84858186478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1710.
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 305
    • 84858186480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1711.
  • 306
    • 0000508965 scopus 로고
    • Structure and process, politics and policy: Administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies
    • note
    • See Matthew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll, & Barry R. Weingast, Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies, 75 VA. L. REV. 431, 467 (1989) ("[T]he abatement system can be included in a new plant's original design, but must be fit into an older plant.")
    • (1989) VA. L. REV. , vol.75
    • McCubbins, M.D.1    Noll, R.G.2    Weingast, B.R.3
  • 307
    • 84858168507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Stavins, supra note 183, at 30.
    • Stavins1
  • 308
    • 84926275144 scopus 로고
    • The Old-new division in risk regulation
    • note
    • See Peter Huber, The Old-New Division in Risk Regulation, 69 VA. L. REV. 1025, 1027 (1983) ("[The regulation of old risks] therefore often faces large economic and social obstacles and incurs transition costs.")
    • (1983) VA. L. REV. , vol.69
    • Huber, P.1
  • 309
    • 84858186479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 51-52 (discussing transition costs).
    • Shavell1
  • 310
    • 84858176011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • REVESZ & LIVERMORE, supra note 116, at 135-37.
    • Revesz1    Livermore2
  • 311
    • 84858182223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 136-37.
  • 312
    • 84858176010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 44-45.
    • Shavell1
  • 313
    • 84858176009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Shavell, supra note 2, at 46.
    • Shavell1
  • 314
    • 84858186482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In all three examples, the question is whether the existing source should meet the new source standard or whether, instead, it should be grandfathered. It is possible to design a regulatory scheme under which there is an additional option: the existing source could meet a standard that is less stringent than the one that applies to the new source but that leads to less risk than grandfathering. Analyzing this additional option would complicate the examples but would not change the key argument of this Part: that sequential optimization does not produce the socially beneficial regulatory policy.
  • 315
    • 84858256774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Climate Change and backlash
    • note
    • See Eric Biber, Climate Change and Backlash, 17 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 1295, 1328 (2009) (noting that opposition to climate change legislation can "be bought off with grandfather exemptions and sidepayments")
    • (2009) N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. , vol.17
    • Biber, E.1
  • 316
    • 0347020547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining in the shadow of democracy
    • note
    • David Dana & Susan P. Koniak, Bargaining in the Shadow of Democracy, 148 U. PA. L. REV. 473, 483-84 n.24 (1999) ("Grandfather clauses, in contrast to compensation payments, may well facilitate the passage of reform legislation. When the legislature grandfathers current beneficiaries of a certain regulatory regime from new regulations, it reduces or eliminates the opposition of those beneficiaries without extracting money from some other interest group and entailing associated political costs.")
    • (1999) U. PA. L. REV. , vol.148 , Issue.24
    • Dana, D.1    Koniak, S.P.2
  • 317
    • 0040243794 scopus 로고
    • A Critical reexamination of the takings jurisprudence
    • note
    • Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., A Critical Reexamination of the Takings Jurisprudence, 90 MICH. L. REV. 1892, 1955 (1992) ("Absent the promise of compensation, a concentrated group will too often be able to block even those concentrated-dispersed measures that would benefit society as a whole. By promising compensation, and thereby replacing the concentrated group with a dispersed group, the Court would make enactment of these measures more likely.")
    • (1992) MICH. L. REV. , vol.90
    • Lunney, G.S.1
  • 318
    • 84858182224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Stavins, supra note 183, at 34 ("[G]randfathering is likely to be a politically expedient option for legislators. By limiting the scope of regulation to new capital assets, the burden of regulatory compliance is concentrated on a small subset of the electorate and the cost is transferred to unspecified, future 'new sources.'").
    • Stavins1
  • 319
    • 84858186481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Ramseyer & Nakazato, supra note 48, at 1171-73.
    • Ramseyer1    Nakazato2
  • 320
    • 84858162928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We use the term "public choice expenditures" to refer to expenses aimed at influencing governmental officials to adopt particular positions on policy issues. These include campaign contributions, salaries for lobbyists who meet with government officials, and expenses for informational purposes such as commissioning studies in order to bolster the interest group's position. Sometimes the academic literature uses the term "lobbying" to refer only to the transmission of information to political officials for the purposes of accomplishing a particular policy goal, thus excluding campaign contributions.
  • 321
    • 0030306584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Multiple ambiguities of "counteractive lobbying
    • note
    • See Frank R. Baumgartner & Beth L Leech, The Multiple Ambiguities of "Counteractive Lobbying," 40 AM. J. POL. SCI. 521, 529 (1996). However, some authors define lobbying more broadly to include campaign contributions.
    • (1996) AM. J. POL. SCI. , vol.40
    • Baumgartner, F.R.1    Leech Beth, L.2
  • 322
    • 84858176724 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See JEFFREY M. BERRY, LOBBYING FOR THE PEOPLE: THE POLITICAL BEHAVIOR OF PUBLIC INTEREST GROUPS 263 (1977) (describing four strategies of lobbying: law, confrontation, information, and constituency influence which includes campaign contributions). For a description of case studies measuring the influence of interest groups
    • (1977) LOBBYING FOR the PEOPLE: The POLITICAL BEHAVIOR of PUBLIC INTEREST GROUPS , pp. 263
    • Jeffrey, M.B.1
  • 324
    • 0038514305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Models of interest groups: Four different approaches
    • note
    • see Jan Potters & Frans van Winden, Models of Interest Groups: Four Different Approaches, in COLLECTIVE DECISION-MAKING: SOCIAL CHOICE AND POLITICAL ECONOMY 337-62 (Norman Schofield ed., 1996) (discussing four models of interest groups: models employing an influence function, models employing a vote function, models employing a composite utility function, and models focusing on the transmission of information).
    • COLLECTIVE DECISION-MAKING: SOCIAL CHOICE and POLITICAL ECONOMY , pp. 337-362
    • Potters, J.1    van Winden, F.2
  • 325
    • 84979190207 scopus 로고
    • The Welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft
    • note
    • Gordon Tullock, The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft, 5 W. ECON. J. 224, 228 (1967). There are three types of rent-seeking expenditures that are generally considered socially wasteful: "The efforts and expenditures of the potential recipients of the monopoly[,]. [t]he efforts of the government officials to obtain or to react to the expenditures of the potential recipients[,]. [and] [t]hird-party distortions induced by the monopoly itself or the government as a consequence of the rentseeking activity."
    • (1967) W. ECON. J. , vol.5
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 326
    • 0012595291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • DENNIS C. MUELLER, PUBLIC CHOICE III 334 (2003) (citing James M. Buchanan, Rent Seeking and Profit Seeking, in TOWARD A THEORY OF THE RENT-SEEKING SOCIETY 12-14 (James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, & Gordon Tullock eds., 1980)). Of course, as Ramseyer and Nakazato acknowledge, "resources spent in. lobbying do produce a social good to the extent they create accurate information about the effects of. reform." Ramseyer & Nakazato, supra note 48, at 1171-72 n.44.
    • (2003) PUBLIC CHOICE III , pp. 334
    • Dennis, C.M.1
  • 327
    • 84858162920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 194.
  • 328
    • 84858162921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Levmore, supra note 44, at 1665-66.
    • Levmore1
  • 330
    • 84858183351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 316.
  • 331
    • 84928439040 scopus 로고
    • Emissions Trading to reduce acid deposition
    • note
    • See Brennan Van Dyke, Note, Emissions Trading to Reduce Acid Deposition, 100 YALE L.J. 2707, 2720 (1991) (noting that initially allocating permits through a system of grandfathering "has one great advantage over an auction scheme: its political appeal to influential interest groups").
    • (1991) YALE L.J. , vol.100
    • van Dyke, B.1
  • 333
    • 84858162923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1171-73.
  • 334
    • 84858162922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 1171 ("They will pay honoraria, organize grass-roots political organizations, and contribute to campaigns; to protect their projects from reform, they will coax, cajole, and bribe.").
  • 335
    • 84858162924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1171-73.
  • 336
    • 84858240609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1167-68.
  • 337
    • 84858268149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1172. Congress would essentially agree that, in the event of a repeal, beneficiaries of the tax benefit would receive a "lump sum equal to the net present value of the expected, but as-yetuncollected, tax benefit[]."
  • 338
    • 84858162925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1168.
  • 339
    • 84858240612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 74-75.
    • Shaviro1
  • 340
    • 84858183353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 74-81.
  • 341
    • 84858268150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Ramseyer & Nakazato, supra note 48, at 1171 (defining "tax-guaranteed strategy" as "a promise to grandfather, coupled with a promise to pay damages for breach").
    • Ramseyer1    Nakazato2
  • 342
    • 84858268153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 74-81.
    • Shaviro1
  • 343
    • 84858268148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Ramseyer & Nakazato, supra note 48, at 1171 (defining "tax-contingent strategy" as "Graetz and Kaplow's never-grandfather strategy").
    • Ramseyer1    Nakazato2
  • 344
    • 84858240610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 74-81. However, Ramseyer and Nakazato dismiss the concern that greater enactment-period lobbying expenses might offset the reduced postenactment lobbying costs: When Congress decides to grant tax benefits to promote investment, it could either guarantee the benefits or keep then [sic] contingent. All else equal, however, rational investors will consider only the expected net present value of those benefits when deciding how much to invest. As a result, when comparing the enactment-period lobbying costs generated by the tax-contingent and tax-guaranteed strategies, the correct comparison is between strategies that produce postenactment benefits of equal net present value. Yet between tax-guaranteed and tax-contingent benefits of equal net actuarial value, investors will not care. And because they will not care, the tax-guaranteed strategy will induce the same amount of enactment-period lobbying as the tax-contingent one. If so, then the optimal strategy is the one that minimizes the social loss from post enactment period lobbying. The analysis above suggests the tax-guaranteed strategy does just that.
    • Shaviro1
  • 345
    • 84858268152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ramseyer & Nakazato, supra note 48, at 1173 (footnote omitted). In Ramseyer and Nakazato's view, the actual value of the benefit Congress chooses to adopt will vary depending on whether Congress adopts a tax-guaranteed or tax-contingent benefit.
    • Ramseyer1    Nakazato2
  • 346
    • 84858240611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To borrow an example from Shaviro, if Congress were to adopt a municipal bond tax preference in order encourage investment in municipal bonds, it could "fine-tune the preference upon enactment to take account of the anticipated transition rule in the event that the preference is later repealed. ".
  • 347
    • 84858162927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SHAVIRO, supra note 2, at 74.
    • Shaviro1
  • 348
    • 84858268154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Thus, if Congress intended not to grant transition relief in the event of repeal, it would enact a more generous tax benefit than it would if it promised transition relief, "thus keeping the preference's value from being affected by the transition regime." Id. at 75. Assuming such "scaling" occurs, interest groups standing to benefit from the tax benefit would be indifferent between the two approaches to transition relief in the pre-enactment stage.
  • 349
    • 84858183352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 74-75. Thus, we would expect that enactment lobbying expenditures would not vary according to the transition rule. However, if Congress later decides to repeal the tax benefit, we would expect postenactment expenditures to be greater when investors have not been promised transition relief-making the tax-guaranteed strategy preferable to the tax-contingent strategy.
  • 350
  • 351
    • 77954732688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transition Policy: A conceptual framework
    • Louis Kaplow, Transition Policy: A Conceptual Framework, 13 J. CONTEMP. LEGAL ISSUES 161, 198-99 (2003).
    • (2003) J. CONTEMP. LEGAL ISSUES , vol.13
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 352
    • 84858268156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 198.
  • 353
    • 84858268155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Kaplow levies this same critique against the argument that transition relief may be necessary in order to "reduce[] opposition to desirable reforms.".
  • 354
    • 84858176013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 197.
  • 355
    • 84858186484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • He explains that consistently providing transition relief may merely "buy off. opposition to undesirable reforms"-thus making it easier for policies that have net social costs to prevail.
  • 356
    • 84858176012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 198.
  • 357
    • 84858168508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 198.
  • 358
    • 84858186483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 198-99.
  • 359
    • 84858168511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 183-86 and accompanying text.
  • 360
    • 84858168509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., ACKERMAN & HASSLER, supra note 82, at 26-54, 117-18 (describing how producers of high-sulfur coal lobbied for more stringent regulation of new sources and for standards favoring coal scrubbing over low-sulfur coal to secure a competitive advantage over producers of low-sulfur coal).
    • Ackerman1    Hassler2
  • 361
  • 362
    • 84858182227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1169, 1172.
  • 363
    • 84858182228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1729.
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 364
    • 84858182225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a useful overview of "vintage-differentiated regulations" in environmental law.
  • 365
    • 84858182226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see Stavins, supra note 183, at 30, 36.
    • Stavins1
  • 366
    • 84858168513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Clean Water Act employs this approach.
  • 367
    • 84858182230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See 33 U.S.C. § 1311(b) (2006) (establishing timetable for achievement of effluent limitation standards).
  • 368
    • 84858186485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also REVESZ, supra note 78, at 507 ("[T]he [Clean Water Act] adopted a phased approach to the setting of federal standards for existing sources, such that EPA was directed to set increasingly stringent effluent limitations for point sources over time.").
    • Revesz1
  • 369
    • 84858182233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Clean Air Act adopts this approach.
  • 370
    • 84858176014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra notes 231-32 and accompanying text. Some land use regulations also provide for initial grandfathering, but require grandfathered buildings to comply with the new regulations once major modifications are made.
  • 371
    • 84858182232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Shavell, supra note 2, at 75 & n.55.
    • , Issue.55 , pp. 75
    • Shavell1
  • 372
    • 84858182229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally Nash & Revesz, supra note 1 (presenting an economic analysis of transition relief through a case study of the Clean Air Act).
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 373
    • 84858168515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 42 U.S.C. § 7411(a)(2) (2006) (stating that federal performance standards apply to stationary sources, "the construction or modification of which is commenced after the publication of regulations").
  • 374
    • 84858168514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Modification" is defined in the statute as "any physical change in, or change in the method of operation of, a stationary source which increases the amount of any air pollutant emitted by such source or which results in the emission of any air pollutant not previously emitted.".
  • 375
    • 84858176017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. § 7411(a)(4). The EPA, however, has promulgated rules exempting from the definition of "modification" certain plant changes, including "routine maintenance, repair, and replacement; an increase in production rate, if the increase did not exceed the 'operating design capacity of the affected facility'; an increase in hours of operation; and use of alternative fuel or raw material if the affected facility could accommodate such use." Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1684-85.
  • 376
    • 84858168512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1681 ("Commentators regularly note that Congress expected most existing sources to gradually phase out over the course of their ordinary economic lives or to upgrade and trigger the new source performance standards, leaving most major stationary sources subject to federal control.")
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 377
    • 27944497159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coal-fired power in a restructured electricity market
    • note
    • David B. Spence, Coal-Fired Power in a Restructured Electricity Market, 15 DUKE ENVTL. L. & POL'Y F. 187, 195 (2005) ("Congress does not seem to have intended for grandfathered plants to be grandfathered indefinitely, since the [Clean Air] Act calls for application of a 'new source' permitting standards to 'stationary source[s] the construction or modification of which is commenced after' the effective date of the Act's new source permitting requirements." (second alteration in original) (emphasis added) (citing § 7411(a)(2))).
    • (2005) DUKE ENVTL. L. & POL'Y F , vol.15
    • Spence, D.B.1
  • 378
    • 84858176019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1708-09 ("[D]ifferential environmental regulations delay plant retirement."); Spence, supra note 233, at 195 ("[O]lder coal-fired power plants, many of them in the Midwest, continued to pollute at essentially unregulated rates long after the passage of the [Clean Air] Act, depositing acid rain and other pollution on downwind states."). Although the acid rain program has dramatically reduced total sulfur dioxide emissions from coal-fired power plants, by imposing a nationwide cap on emissions, and permitting individual sources to buy and sell emissions allowances (tradable permits). [it] does little to solve other pollution problems posed by unregulated coal-fired power plants, including those associated with emissions of particulates, nitrogen oxides, carbon dioxide and mercury.
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 379
    • 84858182234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 197 (footnotes omitted).
  • 380
    • 84858176018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, U.S. Sues Electric Utilities in Unprecedented Action to Enforce the Clean Air Act (Nov. 3, 1999), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/1999/November/524enr.htm.
    • (1999)
  • 381
    • 84858186486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See PUB. CITIZEN, EPA'S SMOKE SCREEN: HOW CONGRESS WAS GIVEN FALSE INFORMATION WHILE CAMPAIGN CONTRIBUTIONS AND POLITICAL CONNECTIONS GUTTED A KEY CLEAN AIR RULE 6 (2003), available at http://www.cleanupwashington.org/documents/epasmokescreen.pdf. The Department of Justice sued nine utility companies: American Electric Power, Cinergy, Duke Energy Corp., Illinois Power Co. (Dynegy), FirstEnergy Corp., Southern Co., Southern Indiana Gas & Electric Co. (SIGECO), Tampa Electric Co., and the Tennessee Valley Authority. Id. at 7. Three other companies-Virginia Power (VEPCO), PSEG, and Wisconsin Electric-were threatened with a lawsuit but settled.
    • (2003) PUB. CITIZEN, EPA'S SMOKE SCREEN: HOW CONGRESS WAS GIVEN FALSE INFORMATION WHILE CAMPAIGN CONTRIBUTIONS and POLITICAL CONNECTIONS GUTTED a KEY CLEAN AIR RULE , pp. 6
  • 382
    • 84858268147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 6.
  • 384
    • 79956087233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • PUB. CITIZEN, supra note 236, at 3.
    • PUB. CITIZEN , pp. 3
  • 385
    • 84858186488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 3, 20.
  • 387
    • 84858168519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While the industry did give money to the Democrats as well, the lion's share of the campaign contributions went to the Republican Party.
  • 388
    • 84858182236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 101-02 ("The top five electric utility contributors to the political parties in the 2000 and 2002 election cycles-Dominion Resources, Inc., Southern Company, Exelon Corporation, Texas Utilities Company, and the National Rural Electric Cooperative Association-gave nearly threequarters (74 percent) of their party donations, $5.1 million, to the Republican national committees and just $1.8 million to the Democrats.").
  • 389
    • 79956087233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • PUB. CITIZEN, supra note 236, at 4.
    • PUB. CITIZEN , pp. 4
  • 390
    • 84858176022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The three officials were Anthony Alexander, president of FirstEnergy, Stephen Wakefield, a vice president at Southern Co., and Thomas Farrell, a vice president at Dominion.
  • 391
    • 84858268144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 21.
  • 392
    • 84858183350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 4.
  • 393
    • 84858162915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The OAR is the arm of the EPA directly responsible for drafting NSR rules, whereas a different arm, the Office of Enforcement and Compliance Assurance, primarily serves an enforcement role.
  • 394
    • 84858183349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 10-11.
  • 395
    • 34247130598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Treading Water": A preliminary assessment of epa enforcement during the bush ii administration
    • Joel A. Mintz, "Treading Water": A Preliminary Assessment of EPA Enforcement During the Bush II Administration, 34 ENVTL. L. REP. 10912, 10918 (2004).
    • (2004) ENVTL. L. REP. , vol.34
    • Mintz, J.A.1
  • 397
    • 84858240603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The ERCC filed its first lobbying report with the Senate Office of Public Records (SOPR) for the second half of 2000.
  • 398
    • 84858162916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See LDA Reports, U.S. SENATE, http://www.senate.gov/legislative/Public_Disclosure/LDA_reports.htm (last visited Nov. 23, 2011).
    • See LDA Reports, U.S. SENATE
  • 399
    • 84858240601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • WU, supra note 239, at 14.
    • Wu1
  • 400
    • 84858268145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • All data taken from LDA Reports, supra note 247 (follow "Search the Lobbying Database (LD-1, LD-2)," click the box next to "client name" in the new window that opens and click "submit," type "Electric Reliability Coordinating Council" in the field for client name and click "submit," filter results by year by clicking on "Filing Year" in the chart, and add the amounts in the column "Amt Reported" to get a total of over $10 million).
  • 401
    • 84858240606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • (follow "Search the Lobbying Database (LD-1, LD-2)," click the box next to "client name" in the new window that opens and click "submit," type "Edison Electric Institute" in the field for client name and click "submit," filter results by year by clicking on "Filing Year" in the chart, then add the amounts in the "Amt Reported" column to reach a total of $74,655,466,000 spent between 1999 and 2002).
  • 402
    • 84858168517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1697-98.
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 403
    • 84858240605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra note 232 and accompanying text.
  • 404
    • 84858240602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nash & Revesz, supra note 1, at 1698.
    • Nash1    Revesz2
  • 405
    • 84858240604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1699.
  • 406
    • 84858240607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 1702-03. Under this rule, three out of the nine utilities sued by the DOJ claimed that they were no longer in violation of the Clean Air Act and that the actions should be dropped.
  • 409
    • 84858218100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Clean air act's new source review program: Beneficial to public health or merely a smoke-and-mirrors scheme?
    • William S. Eubanks II, The Clean Air Act's New Source Review Program: Beneficial to Public Health or Merely a Smoke-and-Mirrors Scheme?, 29 J. LAND RESOURCES & ENVTL. L. 361, 370 (2009).
    • (2009) J. LAND RESOURCES & ENVTL. L. , vol.29
    • Eubanks II, W.S.1
  • 410
    • 25144518800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Prevention of Significant Deterioration (PSD) and Non-Attainment New Source Review (NSR): Equipment Replacement Provision of the Routine Maintenance, Repair, and Replacement Exclusion: Reconsideration, 70 Fed. Reg. 33,838 (June 10, 2005) (to be codified at 40 C.F.R. pts. 51-52).
  • 411
    • 84858162918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See New York v. Envtl. Prot. Agency, 443 F.3d 880, 890 (D.C. Cir. 2006).
  • 412
    • 84935618810 scopus 로고
    • Reforming Environmental law
    • note
    • See, e.g., Bruce A. Ackerman & Richard B. Stewart, Reforming Environmental Law, 37 STAN. L. REV. 1333, 1341-42 (1985) ("A system of tradeable rights will tend to bring about a least-cost allocation of control burdens, saving many billions of dollars annually.")
    • (1985) STAN. L. REV. , vol.37
    • Ackerman, B.A.1    Stewart, R.B.2
  • 413
    • 0002212026 scopus 로고
    • Incentive-based environmental regulation: A new era from an old idea?
    • note
    • Robert W. Hahn & Robert N. Stavins, Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation: A New Era from an Old Idea?, 18 ECOLOGY L.Q. 1, 7-8 (1991) ("In contrast to traditional command-and-control approaches, policy mechanisms based on economic incentive systems ensure that firms 'automatically' undertake pollution control efforts in precisely the manner and degree which will result in the cost-effective allocation of the overall control burden." (footnote omitted)).
    • (1991) ECOLOGY L.Q. , vol.18
    • Hahn, R.W.1    Stavins, R.N.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.