-
1
-
-
78149309443
-
-
See, e.g, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, The Long and Winding Road: Convergence in the Application of Antitrust to Intellectual Property, in 13 GEO. MASON L. REV
-
See, e.g., Makan Delrahim, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, The Long and Winding Road: Convergence in the Application of Antitrust to Intellectual Property, Remarks to the George Mason Law Review Symposium (Oct. 6, 2004), in 13 GEO. MASON L. REV. 259 (2005)
-
(2005)
Remarks to the George Mason Law Review Symposium (Oct. 6, 2004)
, pp. 259
-
-
Delrahim, M.1
-
3
-
-
78149319437
-
-
Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, International An-titrust in the 21st Century: Cooperation and Convergence, Address Before the OECD Global Forum on Competition (Oct. 17, 2001), available at
-
Charles A. James, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, International An-titrust in the 21st Century: Cooperation and Convergence, Address Before the OECD Global Forum on Competition (Oct. 17, 2001), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/9330.pdf
-
-
-
James, C.A.1
-
4
-
-
78149297844
-
European Comm'r for Competition Policy, EU & US Antitrust Policies-Our Shared Belief in Competitive Markets
-
(Mar. 28), available at, (fol-low "en" hyperlink listed next to speech date and title; then follow "EN" hyperlink for PDF)
-
Neelie Kroes, European Comm'r for Competition Policy, EU & US Antitrust Policies-Our Shared Belief in Competitive Markets, Opening Remarks at 56th Annual Spring Meeting of the ABA Section of Antitrust Law, (Mar. 28, 2008), available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/speeches/index_theme_22.html (fol-low "en" hyperlink listed next to speech date and title; then follow "EN" hyperlink for PDF)
-
(2008)
Opening Remarks at 56th Annual Spring Meeting of the ABA Section of Antitrust Law
-
-
Kroes, N.1
-
5
-
-
78149335192
-
Chairman, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n, Convergence, Conflict, and Comity: The Search for Coherence in International Competition Policy
-
(Sept. 27), available at
-
Deborah Platt Majoras, Chairman, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n, Convergence, Conflict, and Comity: The Search for Coherence in International Competition Policy, Remarks at the 34th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law & Policy, (Sept. 27, 2007), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/majoras/070927fordham.pdf
-
(2007)
Remarks at the 34th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law & Policy
-
-
Majoras, D.P.1
-
7
-
-
21644459637
-
-
See, e.g, 72 ANTITRUST L.J
-
See, e.g., Daniel J. Gifford & Robert T. Kudrle, Rhetoric and Reality in the Merger Standards of the United States, Canada, and the European Union, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 423 (2005)
-
(2005)
Rhetoric and Reality in the Merger Standards of the United States, Canada, and the European Union
, pp. 423
-
-
Gifford Daniel, J.1
Kudrle Robert, T.2
-
11
-
-
78149305135
-
-
Press Release, As-sistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Statement on European Microsoft Decision (Sept. 17), available at
-
Press Release, Thomas O. Barnett, As-sistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Statement on European Microsoft Decision (Sept. 17, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2007/226070.pdf.
-
(2007)
-
-
Barnett, T.O.1
-
12
-
-
78149338271
-
-
See, e.g., L.A. TIMES, Sept. 24
-
See, e.g., Jim Puzzanghera, Europe Does Antitrust Its Way, L.A. TIMES, Sept. 24, 2007, at C1.
-
(2007)
Europe Does Antitrust Its Way
-
-
Puzzanghera, J.1
-
13
-
-
78149297093
-
-
note
-
See Case T-201/04 R, Microsoft Corp. v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, 36 (holding that Micro-soft's refusal to share proprietary information necessary to allow rivals to interoperate with its operating system constituted an abuse of a dominant position); cf. Stephen Labaton, Microsoft Finds Legal De-fender in Justice Dept., N.Y. TIMES, June 10, 2007, at A1 (describing the Justice Department's defense of Microsoft both at home and abroad).
-
-
-
-
14
-
-
78149344213
-
-
See, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Antitrust in a Trans-atlantic Context-From the Cicada's Perspective, Remarks at the Antitrust in a Transatlantic Context Conference (June 7, 2004), available, (explor-ing U.S./EC divergence and noting that "unilateral conduct remains the area of greatest separation")
-
See R. Hewitt Pate, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Antitrust in a Trans-atlantic Context-From the Cicada's Perspective, Remarks at the Antitrust in a Transatlantic Context Conference (June 7, 2004), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/203973.pdf (explor-ing U.S./EC divergence and noting that "unilateral conduct remains the area of greatest separation").
-
-
-
Hewitt Pate, R.1
-
15
-
-
78149296328
-
-
note
-
See infra note 9.
-
-
-
-
16
-
-
78149308377
-
-
("We are concerned that the standard applied to unilateral conduct by the [Court of First Instance], rather than helping consumers, may have the unfortunate consequence of harming consumers by chilling innovation and discouraging competition."); see also infra note 115 (providing additional examples)
-
See Barnett, supra note 2 ("We are concerned that the standard applied to unilateral conduct by the [Court of First Instance], rather than helping consumers, may have the unfortunate consequence of harming consumers by chilling innovation and discouraging competition."); see also infra note 115 (providing additional examples).
-
(2005)
Rhetoric and Reality in the Merger Standards of the United States, Canada, and the European Union
, pp. 423
-
-
Barnett1
-
17
-
-
79959186974
-
-
See, TIME, July 8, availa-ble at, (quoting Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill as criticizing the EC's decision regarding the GE-Honeywell merger as "off the wall")
-
See Michael Elliott, The Anatomy of the GE-Honeywell Disaster, TIME, July 8, 2001, at 5, availa-ble at http://www.time.com/time/business/article/0,8599,166732-2,00.html (quoting Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill as criticizing the EC's decision regarding the GE-Honeywell merger as "off the wall")
-
(2001)
The Anatomy of the GE-Honeywell Disaster
, pp. 5
-
-
Elliott, M.1
-
18
-
-
78149342421
-
-
Barnett, supra note 2 (criticizing the EC decision against Microsoft as potentially damaging to consum-ers).
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
78149338268
-
-
See, e.g., WALL ST. J. L. BLOG (Sept. 19, 2007, 2:28 PM ET)
-
See, e.g., Peter Lattman, Antitrust Armageddon: Thomas Barnett v. Neelie Kroes, WALL ST. J. L. BLOG (Sept. 19, 2007, 2:28 PM ET), http://blogs.wsj.com/law/2007/09/19/antitrust-law-armageddon-thomas-barn ett-v-neelie-kroes/
-
Antitrust Armageddon: Thomas Barnett V. Neelie Kroes
-
-
Lattman, P.1
-
21
-
-
78149318333
-
-
note
-
EC Commissioner Neelie Kroes reportedly said:"It is totally unacceptable that a representative of the U.S. administration criticized an independent court of law outside its jurisdiction. The European Com-mission does not pass judgment on rulings by U.S. courts, and we expect the same degree of respect." Id.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
78149331276
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See Neelie Kroes, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, 2005), available at http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/05/537 (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
(2005)
-
-
Kroes, N.1
-
23
-
-
78149302124
-
-
see also, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF
-
see also ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 107-15 (1978).
-
(1978)
, pp. 107-115
-
-
Bork, R.H.1
-
24
-
-
78149343159
-
-
note
-
See Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 224 (1993) ("It is axiomatic that the antitrust laws were passed for the protection of competition, not competitors.'" (quot-ing Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962)))
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
78149320576
-
Editorial
-
WALL ST. J. EUROPE, Sept. 26, ("U.S. and EU antitrust laws agree on most things, not least the objective of benefiting consumers.")
-
Neelie Kroes, Editorial, Why Micro-soft Was Wrong, WALL ST. J. EUROPE, Sept. 26, 2007, at 13 ("U.S. and EU antitrust laws agree on most things, not least the objective of benefiting consumers.")
-
(2007)
Why Micro-soft Was Wrong
, pp. 13
-
-
Kroes, N.1
-
26
-
-
78149331651
-
-
SUBSTANTIAL ANTITRUST CONVERGENCE: DEVELOPED COUNTRY ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT IS CONVERGING ON A CONSUMER WELFARE BASIS
-
MARGARET BLOOM, SUBSTANTIAL ANTITRUST CONVERGENCE: DEVELOPED COUNTRY ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT IS CONVERGING ON A CONSUMER WELFARE BASIS (2005), http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/at-committees/at-ic/pdf/spring/05/aba-co nvergence-final.pdf.
-
(2005)
-
-
Bloom, M.1
-
27
-
-
78149302866
-
-
See, Antitrust Division Organization Chart
-
See Antitrust Division Organization Chart (2002), http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/org.htm
-
(2002)
-
-
-
28
-
-
78149342423
-
-
European Comm'n Directorate Gen. for Competition, (last visited Feb. 12)
-
European Comm'n Directorate Gen. for Competition, http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/competition/economist/role_en.html (last visited Feb. 12, 2010)
-
(2010)
-
-
-
29
-
-
78149319832
-
-
Economic Advisory Group, (last visited Feb. 12)
-
Economic Advisory Group, http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/competition/economist/eagcp.html (last visited Feb. 12, 2010).
-
(2010)
-
-
-
30
-
-
78149301610
-
-
See, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Section 2 Reme-dies: A Necessary Challenge, Presentation at the Fordham Competition Law Institute (Sept. 28), available at, (opining that"there seems to be con-sensus that we should prohibit unilateral conduct only where it is demonstrated through rigorous eco-nomic analysis to harm competition and thereby to harm consumer welfare")
-
See Thomas Barnett, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Section 2 Reme-dies: A Necessary Challenge, Presentation at the Fordham Competition Law Institute (Sept. 28, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/226537.pdf (opining that"there seems to be con-sensus that we should prohibit unilateral conduct only where it is demonstrated through rigorous eco-nomic analysis to harm competition and thereby to harm consumer welfare").
-
(2007)
-
-
Barnett, T.1
-
31
-
-
78149341327
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See BORK, supra note 10, at 122.
-
(2005)
, pp. 122
-
-
Bork1
-
32
-
-
78149353350
-
-
note
-
For sure, many aspects of antitrust law are capable of being accurately analyzed under the lens of economics.
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
78149338947
-
-
See, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition)
-
See DENNIS W. CARLTON & JEFFREY M. PERLOFF, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 57-58, 69-73 (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition).
-
-
-
Carlton, D.W.1
Perloff, J.M.2
-
35
-
-
78149304787
-
-
See generally, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW, (focusing on evaluating the economic efficiency of intellectual property law)
-
See generally WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW (2003) (focusing on evaluating the economic efficiency of intellectual property law)
-
(2003)
-
-
Landes, W.M.1
Posner, R.A.2
-
36
-
-
78149320934
-
-
INNOVATION AND INCENTIVES, (discussing incentive sys-tems and their ability to encourage technological or scientific advances)
-
SUZANNE SCOTCHMER, INNOVATION AND INCENTIVES (2004) (discussing incentive sys-tems and their ability to encourage technological or scientific advances).
-
(2004)
-
-
Scotchmer, S.1
-
37
-
-
78149310716
-
-
See, Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP (Trinko), 540 U.S. 398, 414, (reasoning that courts should avoid over-interference in the workings of the free market)
-
See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP (Trinko), 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004) (reasoning that courts should avoid over-interference in the workings of the free market).
-
(2004)
-
-
-
38
-
-
78149312209
-
-
See
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 352-57.
-
-
-
Carlton1
-
39
-
-
78149288679
-
-
note
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
78149322245
-
-
note
-
As explored below, there are good reasons to be skeptical of long-run harm in predatory pricing scenarios. See infra Part III.B. Nevertheless, for the purposes of the current illustration, we take this potential harm as a given.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
78149296329
-
-
note
-
Compare Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 224 (1992) (requiring that a plaintiff alleging predatory pricing demonstrate"that the competitor had a reasonable prospect, or. a dangerous probability, of recouping its investment in below-cost prices"), with Case C-62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v. Comm'n, 1991 E.C.R. I-3359, 3372-74 (condemning below-cost pricing without consideration to the dominant undertaking's ability to recoup its losses).
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
78149333107
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See BORK, supra note 10, at 299-309, 365-81
-
(2005)
-
-
Bork1
-
43
-
-
78149327140
-
-
ANTITRUST LAW, (2d ed. 2001)
-
RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 197-207 (2d ed. 2001).
-
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
44
-
-
78149329093
-
-
note
-
Europe's recent decision to forbid the bundling of Internet Explorer with Windows was based on just this logic.
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
78149344945
-
-
See Press Release, European Comm'n, Antitrust: Commission Confirms Sending a Statement of Objections to Microsoft on the Tying of Internet Explorer to Windows (Jan. 17), available at, (follow"EN" hyperlink for PDF). The bundling of Internet browsing software with Microsoft's operating system car-ries axiomatic and significant consumer benefits by providing them with goods most of them will con-sume, thereby allowing them to avoid the transaction and negotiation costs of acquiring them separately
-
See Press Release, European Comm'n, Antitrust: Commission Confirms Sending a Statement of Objections to Microsoft on the Tying of Internet Explorer to Windows (Jan. 17, 2009), available at http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/09/15 (follow"EN" hyperlink for PDF). The bundling of Internet browsing software with Microsoft's operating system car-ries axiomatic and significant consumer benefits by providing them with goods most of them will con-sume, thereby allowing them to avoid the transaction and negotiation costs of acquiring them separately.
-
(2009)
-
-
-
46
-
-
78149327895
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See BORK, supra note 10, at 365-81.
-
(2005)
, pp. 365-381
-
-
Bork1
-
47
-
-
78149335191
-
-
note
-
Meanwhile, the economics of complementary effects strongly suggest that the purveyor of such goods will charge a smaller price in combination than it would sepa-rately.
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
78149322597
-
-
See, MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition)
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 638.
-
-
-
Carlton1
Perloff2
-
49
-
-
78149355563
-
-
note
-
The European Commission surely found that these undeniable short-run benefits were outweighed by what it perceived to be the long-run danger to a competitive market structure. In particular, it considered that Microsoft's dominant market share created an impediment to free entry.
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
78149326785
-
-
note
-
See Press Release, European Comm'n, supra (opining that"the tying of Internet Explorer with Windows, which makes Internet Explorer available on 90% of the world's PCs, distorts competition on the merits between competing web browsers insofar as it provides Internet Explorer with an artificial distribution advantage which other web browsers are unable to match"). In short, present efficiency arguments notwithstanding, the possibility that free entry may be frustrated in the future was sufficient to condemn the behavior under review. This decision, which placed long-run considerations ahead of short-run efficiencies, would never have been reached across the Atlantic. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 84 (D.C. Cir. 2001). This is a particu-larly acute example of a broader phenomenon. As a general matter, Europe displays a greater predispo-sition toward regulatory intervention, driven in no small way by its relative skepticism toward the free market's long-run ability to remedy immediate harm.
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
78149330182
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See BORK, supra note 10, at 225-45.
-
(2005)
, pp. 225-245
-
-
Bork1
-
53
-
-
78149310359
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See id. at 241; POSNER, supra note 24, at 226.
-
(2005)
, pp. 226
-
-
Posner1
-
54
-
-
78149304708
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See BORK, supra note 10, at 241
-
(2005)
, pp. 241
-
-
Bork1
-
55
-
-
78149302501
-
-
RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 197-207 (2d ed. 2001)
-
POSNER, supra note 24, at 226.
-
-
-
Posner1
-
56
-
-
78149343860
-
-
RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 197-207 (2d ed. 2001)
-
See POSNER, supra note 24, at 225-26.
-
-
-
Posner1
-
57
-
-
78149289530
-
-
See MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 57-58, 69-73 (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition)
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 429-30.
-
-
-
Carlton1
Perloff2
-
58
-
-
78149311848
-
-
See, Chairman, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n, Vertical Restraints and Vertical As-pects of Mergers-A U.S. Perspective, Remarks Before the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Oct. 16-17), available at
-
See Robert Pitofsky, Chairman, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n, Vertical Restraints and Vertical As-pects of Mergers-A U.S. Perspective, Remarks Before the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Oct. 16-17, 1997), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/pitofsky/fordham7.shtm.
-
(1997)
-
-
Pitofsky, R.1
-
59
-
-
78149314588
-
-
See MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 57-58, 69-73 (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition)
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 638.
-
-
-
Carlton1
Perloff2
-
60
-
-
78149301238
-
-
See, e.g., Commission Decision COMP/M.2220, General Electric/Honeywell, 2004 O.J. (L48) 1 (EC), available at, (ruling that the proposed General Electric and Honeywell merger would result in excessive concentration)
-
See, e.g., Commission Decision COMP/M.2220, General Electric/Honeywell, 2004 O.J. (L48) 1 (EC), available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/cases/decisions/m2220_en.pdf (ruling that the proposed General Electric and Honeywell merger would result in excessive concentration).
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
78149295072
-
-
See, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, GE-Honeywell: The U.S. Decision, Remarks Before the Antitrust Law Section, State Bar of Georgia (Nov. 29), available at, ("Crucial to the EU's theories of competitive harm are the predictions-fueled by Honeywell's rivals-that rivals would be forced to exit in the face of a strengthened Honeywell.")
-
See Deborah Platt Majoras, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, GE-Honeywell: The U.S. Decision, Remarks Before the Antitrust Law Section, State Bar of Georgia (Nov. 29, 2001), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/9893.pdf ("Crucial to the EU's theories of competitive harm are the predictions-fueled by Honeywell's rivals-that rivals would be forced to exit in the face of a strengthened Honeywell.").
-
(2001)
-
-
Majoras, D.P.1
-
62
-
-
78149322241
-
-
note
-
See id
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
78149292464
-
-
See Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Department of Justice Antitrust Division Issues State-ment on the European Commission's Decision Regarding the Proposed Transaction Between Oracle and Sun (Nov. 9), available at
-
See Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Department of Justice Antitrust Division Issues State-ment on the European Commission's Decision Regarding the Proposed Transaction Between Oracle and Sun (Nov. 9, 2009), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2009/251782.htm.
-
(2009)
-
-
-
66
-
-
78149325305
-
-
See Press Release, Mergers: Commission Clear Oracle's Proposed Acquisition of Sun Microsys-tems (Jan. 21), available at
-
See Press Release, Mergers: Commission Clear Oracle's Proposed Acquisition of Sun Microsys-tems (Jan. 21, 2010), available at http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/10/40.
-
(2010)
-
-
-
68
-
-
78149326784
-
-
See, U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT 1, [hereinafter SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT], available at, (describing innovation as"the most important source of economic growth")
-
See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT 1 (2008) [hereinafter SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT], available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/reports/236681.pdf (describing innovation as"the most important source of economic growth").
-
(2008)
-
-
-
69
-
-
78149323015
-
-
note
-
This conclusion doubtless finds its foundation in Frank Easterbrook's famous 1984 article in the Texas Law Review.
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
84934453628
-
-
See, 63 TEX. L. REV., (noting that courts act with imperfect information and their actions can ultimately harm efficiency)
-
See Frank Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1 (1984) (noting that courts act with imperfect information and their actions can ultimately harm efficiency).
-
(1984)
The Limits of Antitrust
, pp. 1
-
-
Easterbrook, F.1
-
71
-
-
78149309446
-
-
See Press Release, FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report,"Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act" (Sept. 8), available at
-
See Press Release, FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report,"Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act" (Sept. 8, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2008/09/section2.shtm.
-
(2008)
-
-
-
72
-
-
78149338946
-
-
See Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Justice Department Withdraws Report on Antitrust Mo-nopoly Law (May 11), available at
-
See Press Release, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Justice Department Withdraws Report on Antitrust Mo-nopoly Law (May 11, 2009), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/2009/May/09-at-459.html.
-
(2009)
-
-
-
73
-
-
78149341674
-
-
note
-
This is because each jurisdiction is likely to have a distinct sociopolitical view on the merits of short-run gains vis-à-vis facilitating long-run investment.
-
-
-
-
74
-
-
78149326418
-
-
Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, GE-Honeywell: The U.S. Decision, Remarks Before the Antitrust Law Section, State Bar of Georgia (Nov. 29, 2001), available at See, (referring to an explosion in the number of countries enacting antitrust statutes). The latest and most prominent example is provided by China, which enacted its"An-ti-monopoly Law" in 2007
-
See Platt Majoras, supra note 34 (referring to an explosion in the number of countries enacting antitrust statutes). The latest and most prominent example is provided by China, which enacted its"An-ti-monopoly Law" in 2007.
-
-
-
Majoras, P.1
-
76
-
-
78149353710
-
-
note
-
The history of competition law enforcement is replete with examples of this phenomenon. Illu-stratively, in the United States the Sherman Act-a notoriously flexible piece of legislation-has been employed to a variety of ends, from trust-busting in the early twentieth century to protectionism by the Warren Court to consumer welfare in modern times.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
0742288973
-
-
See generally The Modern Evolution of U.S. Competition Policy Enforcement Norms 71 ANTITRUST L.J
-
See generally William E. Kovacic, The Modern Evolution of U.S. Competition Policy Enforcement Norms 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 377 (2003)
-
(2003)
, pp. 377
-
-
Kovacic, W.E.1
-
79
-
-
78149352581
-
-
note
-
The Sherman Act, in particular, is a conspicuously vague statute, purporting to condemn con-tracts, combinations, and conspiracies in restraint of trade, in addition to prohibiting the willful acquisi-tion or maintenance of monopoly power. 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-2 (2006). The Act is a classic"common law statute," and Congress left to the courts the task of giving meaning to its broad commands. 21 Cong. Rec. 2456 (1890) (statement of Sen. John Sherman). Given the malleability of the statutory rules, anti-trust law is eminently capable of becoming a conduit for enforcers'political predispositions.
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
30344432939
-
-
See, 53 AM. J. COMP. L. 1, 1, (noting that the basic ambiguity in market rhetoric"enables competition authorities to invoke the spirit of the market no matter what they do")
-
See Aditi Bagchi, The Political Economy of Merger Regulation, 53 AM. J. COMP. L. 1, 1 (2005) (noting that the basic ambiguity in market rhetoric"enables competition authorities to invoke the spirit of the market no matter what they do").
-
(2005)
The Political Economy of Merger Regulation
-
-
Bagchi, A.1
-
81
-
-
46049113694
-
-
See, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 439, (noting that"[a]ntitrust law and bankruptcy law go hand in hand")
-
See Frank Easterbrook, The Chicago School and Exclusionary Conduct, 31 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 439, 440 (2008) (noting that"[a]ntitrust law and bankruptcy law go hand in hand")
-
(2008)
The Chicago School and Exclusionary Conduct
, pp. 440
-
-
Easterbrook, F.1
-
82
-
-
78149333106
-
-
U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n Chairman, National Champions: I Don't Even Think It Sounds Good, Remarks Before the International Competition Conference/EU Competition Day (Mar. 26), available at
-
Deborah Platt Majoras, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n Chairman, National Champions: I Don't Even Think It Sounds Good, Remarks Before the International Competition Conference/EU Competition Day (Mar. 26, 2007), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/majoras/070326munich.pdf.
-
(2007)
-
-
Majoras, D.P.1
-
83
-
-
78149323409
-
-
See, (explaining how monopoly leads to artificially high prices caused by restrictions in output)
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 95-99 (explaining how monopoly leads to artificially high prices caused by restrictions in output).
-
-
-
-
84
-
-
78149354056
-
-
note
-
European antitrust law has been clearly influenced by the Freiburg School of ordoliberalism, which arose in the aftermath of the failed Weimar Republic. This school of thought saw an open com-petitive process as essential to both a robust economy and effective government. Excessive concentra-tion and monopoly were seen as harbingers of economic ruin and governmental instability.
-
-
-
-
85
-
-
78149340947
-
-
See generally, COMPETITION LAW 19-20 (LexisNexis UK 5th ed, (explaining the ordoliberal influence on the development of EU competition policy)
-
See generally RICHARD WHISH, COMPETITION LAW 19-20 (LexisNexis UK 5th ed. 2003) (explaining the ordoliberal influence on the development of EU competition policy).
-
(2003)
-
-
Whish, R.1
-
87
-
-
78149332028
-
-
See generally, (discussing the historical contradictions in U.S. an-titrust law)
-
See generally BORK, supra note 10, at 15-19 (discussing the historical contradictions in U.S. an-titrust law).
-
-
-
-
89
-
-
78149298641
-
-
See, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294
-
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962).
-
(1962)
, pp. 325
-
-
-
90
-
-
78149306416
-
-
See Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Comm'n, E.C.R. 207
-
See Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Comm'n, 1978 E.C.R. 207, 211-21.
-
(1978)
, pp. 211-221
-
-
-
91
-
-
78149348087
-
-
note
-
See Treaty Establishing the European Community art. 82(d), Nov. 10, 1997, 1997 O.J. (C 340); Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 12 (1984).
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
78149289529
-
-
See, (deriding the state of antitrust law in the United States in 1976)
-
See POSNER, supra note 24, at viii (deriding the state of antitrust law in the United States in 1976).
-
-
-
Posner1
-
95
-
-
0041647697
-
-
See, 62 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1020
-
See Joseph F. Brodley, The Economic Goals of Antitrust: Efficiency, Consumer Welfare, and Technological Progress, 62 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1020, 1021 (1987).
-
(1987)
The Economic Goals of Antitrust: Efficiency, Consumer Welfare, and Technological Progress
, pp. 1021
-
-
Brodley Joseph, F.1
-
96
-
-
0347756908
-
-
See, 466 U.S
-
See Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12.
-
Jefferson Parish
, pp. 12
-
-
-
97
-
-
78149291416
-
-
See, Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S., (overruling the Court's 1911 decision in Dr. Miles, which held that vertical minimum price fixing is illegal per se)
-
See Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 882 (2007) (overruling the Court's 1911 decision in Dr. Miles, which held that vertical minimum price fixing is illegal per se)
-
(2007)
, vol.877
, pp. 882
-
-
-
98
-
-
78149298220
-
-
State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, (overruling its 1968 Albrecht decision, which held that vertical maximum price fixing was a per se antitrust violation)
-
State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10-22 (1997) (overruling its 1968 Albrecht decision, which held that vertical maximum price fixing was a per se antitrust violation).
-
(1997)
, pp. 10-22
-
-
-
99
-
-
78149286868
-
-
See, e.g., Weyerhaeuser Co. v Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U.S. 312
-
See, e.g., Weyerhaeuser Co. v Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U.S. 312, 314-20 (2007)
-
(2007)
, pp. 314-320
-
-
-
100
-
-
78149309060
-
-
Brooke Group Ltd. v Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209
-
Brooke Group Ltd. v Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 219-27 (1993).
-
(1993)
, pp. 219-227
-
-
-
102
-
-
78149352155
-
-
The Merger Guidelines of the U.S. Department of Justice-In Perspective, Remarks at 20th Anniversary of the 1982 Merger Guidelines (June 10), available at
-
Oliver E. Wil-liamson, The Merger Guidelines of the U.S. Department of Justice-In Perspective, Remarks at 20th Anniversary of the 1982 Merger Guidelines (June 10, 2002), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/hmerger/11257.pdf.
-
(2002)
-
-
Wil-Liamson Oliver, E.1
-
104
-
-
78149292465
-
-
See, Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Link Line Commc'ns, Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1109
-
See Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Link Line Commc'ns, Inc., 129 S. Ct. 1109, 1114-15 (2009)
-
(2009)
, pp. 1114-1115
-
-
-
106
-
-
78149314202
-
-
See, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 353, ("[I]t needs to be remembered that the goal is efficiency, not competition. The ultimate goal is that there be efficiency.")
-
See Lawrence H. Summers, Competition Policy in the New Economy, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 353, 358 (2001) ("[I]t needs to be remembered that the goal is efficiency, not competition. The ultimate goal is that there be efficiency.").
-
(2001)
Competition Policy in the New Economy
, pp. 358
-
-
Summers Lawrence, H.1
-
107
-
-
78149316153
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See BORK, supra note 10, at 122.
-
(2005)
, pp. 122
-
-
Bork1
-
108
-
-
13444276477
-
-
See, COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 257 (reviewing the development and nature of post-Chicago antitrust doctrine); see also Posner, supra note 64 (describing the growing consensus of an economic approach to antitrust doctrine)
-
See Hovenkamp, supra note 65 (reviewing the development and nature of post-Chicago antitrust doctrine); see also Posner, supra note 64 (describing the growing consensus of an economic approach to antitrust doctrine).
-
(2001)
Post-Chicago Antitrust: A Review and Critique
-
-
Hovenkamp1
-
109
-
-
78149291413
-
-
See, EC COMPETITION LAW
-
See GIORGIO MONTI, EC COMPETITION LAW 79-80 (2007).
-
(2007)
, pp. 79-80
-
-
Monti, G.1
-
112
-
-
78149355562
-
-
See, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See Kroes, supra note 10.
-
(2005)
-
-
Kroes1
-
116
-
-
78149354055
-
-
Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, U.S. and EU Competition Poli-cy: Cartels, Mergers, and Beyond, Address Before the Council for the United States and Italy Bi-Annual Conference (Jan. 25), available at
-
William J. Ko-lasky, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, U.S. and EU Competition Poli-cy: Cartels, Mergers, and Beyond, Address Before the Council for the United States and Italy Bi-Annual Conference (Jan. 25, 2002), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/9848.pdf.
-
(2002)
-
-
Ko-Lasky William, J.1
-
117
-
-
84856653508
-
-
See, in THE EVOLUTION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW: WHOSE REGULATION, WHICH COMPETITION? 53, (Hanns Ullrich ed., ("It is generally believed that Eu-ropean competition law is becoming both more similar to US antitrust law and more based on econom-ics.")
-
See Mark R. Patterson, Revision of the New Technology Transfer Block Exemption Regulation: Convergence or Capitulation?, in THE EVOLUTION OF EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW: WHOSE REGULATION, WHICH COMPETITION? 53, 53 (Hanns Ullrich ed., 2006) ("It is generally believed that Eu-ropean competition law is becoming both more similar to US antitrust law and more based on econom-ics.")
-
(2006)
Revision of the New Technology Transfer Block Exemption Regulation: Convergence Or Capitulation?
, pp. 53
-
-
Patterson Mark, R.1
-
118
-
-
78149347317
-
-
Dialogue and Consultation Facilitates Convergence in the Analyses of Mergers in the US and EU, (last visited Feb. 16)
-
David Scheffman & Mary Coleman, Dialogue and Consultation Facilitates Convergence in the Analyses of Mergers in the US and EU, http://www.ftc.gov/be/convergence.pdf (last visited Feb. 16, 2010).
-
(2010)
-
-
Scheffman, D.1
Coleman, M.2
-
120
-
-
78149340580
-
-
See, Commission Decision COMP/C-3/37.792, Microsoft, 2007 OJ (L 32) 23 (Mar. 24), available at
-
See Commission Decision COMP/C-3/37.792, Microsoft, 2007 OJ (L 32) 23 (Mar. 24, 2004), available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/decisions/37792/en.pdf
-
(2004)
-
-
-
121
-
-
78149355920
-
-
THE MICROSOFT CASE: ANTITRUST, HIGH TECHNOLOGY, AND CONSUMER WELFARE 80-83
-
WILLIAM H. PAGE & JOHN E. LOPATKA, THE MICROSOFT CASE: ANTITRUST, HIGH TECHNOLOGY, AND CONSUMER WELFARE 80-83 (2007)
-
(2007)
-
-
Page, W.H.1
Lopatka, J.E.2
-
122
-
-
31344453512
-
-
see also, United States v. Microsoft, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON, (discussing the controversial nature of the action taken by the Eu-ropean Commission against Microsoft)
-
see also David S. Evans et al., United States v. Microsoft: Did Consumers Win?, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 497 (2005) (discussing the controversial nature of the action taken by the Eu-ropean Commission against Microsoft)
-
(2005)
Did Consumers Win?
, pp. 497
-
-
Evans David, S.1
-
123
-
-
78149356680
-
-
Op-Ed, WASH. TIMES, Oct. 5, available at, (criticizing the EC's decision in the Mi-crosoft case)
-
Stephen H. Haber, F. Scott Kieff & Troy A. Paredes, Op-Ed. EU Antitrust Nonsense, WASH. TIMES, Oct. 5, 2007, at A19, available at http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2007/oct/05/eu-antitrust-nonsense/(c riticizing the EC's decision in the Mi-crosoft case).
-
(2007)
EU Antitrust Nonsense
-
-
Haber Stephen, H.1
Scott Kieff, F.2
Paredes Troy, A.3
-
126
-
-
78149335570
-
-
On February 27, 2008, the European Commission fined Microsoft $1.3 billion-then the largest fine in the history of antitrust enforcement-for charging rivals"unreasonable prices" for gaining access to interface information for work group servers that would facilitate interoperability. See Press Release, European Comm'n, Antitrust: Commission Imposes € 899 Million Penalty on Microsoft for Noncom-pliance with March 2004 Decision (Feb. 27, available at, (follow"Antitrust: Commission imposes." hyperlink; then fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF). The offending prices were initial royalty rates of 3.87% of licensees'product revenues for patented information and 2.98% for confidential interoperability information. Id
-
On February 27, 2008, the European Commission fined Microsoft $1.3 billion-then the largest fine in the history of antitrust enforcement-for charging rivals"unreasonable prices" for gaining access to interface information for work group servers that would facilitate interoperability. See Press Release, European Comm'n, Antitrust: Commission Imposes € 899 Million Penalty on Microsoft for Noncom-pliance with March 2004 Decision (Feb. 27, 2008), available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/index/by_nr_75.html#i37_ 792 (follow"Antitrust: Commission imposes." hyperlink; then fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF). The offending prices were initial royalty rates of 3.87% of licensees'product revenues for patented information and 2.98% for confidential interoperability information. Id.
-
(2008)
-
-
-
127
-
-
78149328725
-
-
See Press Release, Microsoft Statement on European Commission Statement of Objections (Jan. 16), available at
-
See Press Release, Microsoft Statement on European Commission Statement of Objections (Jan. 16, 2009), available at http://www.microsoft.com/presspass/press/2009/jan09/01-16statement.mspx.
-
(2009)
-
-
-
129
-
-
78149351042
-
-
See, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, United States and European Competition Policy: Are There More Differences than We Care to Admit?, Address Before the European Policy Center (Apr. 10), available at, "In the U.S., we believe [calculating negative long-run effects caused by short-run efficiency gains] will generally exceed our limited predictive abilities. We therefore will generally not intervene in these circumstances. We prefer to let markets sort it out.")
-
See William J. Kolasky, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, United States and European Competition Policy: Are There More Differences than We Care to Admit?, Address Before the European Policy Center (Apr. 10, 2002), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/10999.pdf ("In the U.S., we believe [calculating negative long-run effects caused by short-run efficiency gains] will generally exceed our limited predictive abilities. We therefore will generally not intervene in these circumstances. We prefer to let markets sort it out.").
-
(2002)
-
-
Kolasky William, J.1
-
130
-
-
78149327515
-
-
See, COOPERATION BETWEEN ANTITRUST AGENCIES AT THE INTERNATIONAL LEVEL, ("[T]he definition of market power is much broader under EC law, and dominance is more likely to be found in the European Communities than in the United States.")
-
See BRUNO ZANETTIN, COOPERATION BETWEEN ANTITRUST AGENCIES AT THE INTERNATIONAL LEVEL 221 (2002) ("[T]he definition of market power is much broader under EC law, and dominance is more likely to be found in the European Communities than in the United States.").
-
(2002)
, pp. 221
-
-
Zanettin, B.1
-
131
-
-
78149309673
-
-
See generally, (discussing the EC's governing tests for deter-mining dominant positions in antitrust) European antitrust law has been clearly influenced by the Freiburg School of ordoliberalism, which arose in the aftermath of the failed Weimar Republic. This school of thought saw an open com-petitive process as essential to both a robust economy and effective government. Excessive concentra-tion and monopoly were seen as harbingers of economic ruin and governmental instability
-
See generally WHISH, supra note 56, at 178-90 (discussing the EC's governing tests for deter-mining dominant positions in antitrust).
-
-
-
-
132
-
-
78149313452
-
-
note
-
See Case T-219/99, British Airways PLC v. Comm'n, 2003 E.C.R. II-5917 (finding British Air-ways to be dominant in the UK air travel agency market with a share of 39.7%).
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
78149349169
-
-
See United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 424 (2d Cir)
-
See United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 424 (2d Cir. 1945).
-
(1945)
-
-
-
134
-
-
78149335187
-
-
See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs. Inc., 504 U.S. 451
-
See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs. Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 481 (1992).
-
(1992)
, pp. 481
-
-
-
135
-
-
78149293982
-
-
note
-
See United States v. Syufy Enters., 903 F.2d 659, 665-66 (9th Cir. 1990) (asserting that a firm's market share is a less important consideration than its ability to maintain that market share)
-
-
-
-
136
-
-
78149332378
-
-
note
-
see also L.A. Land Co. v. Brunswick Corp., 6 F.3d 1422, 1425-29 (9th Cir. 1993), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 1197 (1994) (explaining that 100% market share does not necessarily demonstrate power to control prices or exclude competition).
-
-
-
-
137
-
-
78149349556
-
-
note
-
See Joined Cases C-395/96 P & C-396/96 P, Compagnie Maritime Belge Transps. SA v. Comm'n, 2000 E.C.R. I-1365, 119, 137.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
78149291415
-
-
See COOPERATION BETWEEN ANTITRUST AGENCIES AT THE INTERNATIONAL LEVEL 221 ("[T]he definition of market power is much broader under EC law, and dominance is more likely to be found in the European Communities than in the United States.")
-
See ZANETTIN, supra note 92, at 221.
-
(2002)
, pp. 221
-
-
Zanettin1
-
139
-
-
78149348086
-
-
note
-
Compare Brooke Group Ltd v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 224 (1993) (requiring that a plaintiff alleging predatory pricing demonstrate"that the competitor had a reasonable prospect" or"a dangerous probability of recouping its investment in below-cost prices"), with Case C-62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v. Comm'n, 1991 E.C.R. I-3359, 3372-74 (condemning below-cost pricing without considering the dominant undertaking's ability to recoup its losses).
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
78149334455
-
-
note
-
See Comm'n Notice, Commission Guidelines on Vertical Restraints, 2003 E.C.R. II-5917, 141.
-
-
-
-
143
-
-
78149312591
-
-
note
-
Compare Case T-201/04 R, Microsoft Corp. v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601 (finding Micro-soft's tying arrangements as problematic and anticompetitive), with United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 84 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (holding that Microsoft's tying arrangements are not per se illegal but should judged by the rule of reason).
-
-
-
-
144
-
-
78149290636
-
-
note
-
Compare Joined Cases 56 & 58/64, Établissements Consten, S.A.R.L. v. Comm'n, 1966 E.C.R. 299, 339 (finding geographical and price restrictions on car dealerships to violate antitrust law), with State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10-22 (1997) (holding that requiring distributors to sell at certain price restrictions was not anticompetitive) and Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 882 (2007) (overruling the Court's 1911 decision in Dr. Miles, which held that vertical mini-mum price fixing is illegal per se).
-
-
-
-
145
-
-
78149322243
-
-
Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, U.S. and EU Competition Poli-cy: Cartels, Mergers, and Beyond, Address Before the Council for the United States and Italy Bi-Annual Conference (Jan. 25), available at
-
See Kolasky, supra note 91.
-
(2002)
-
-
Kolasky1
-
146
-
-
78149320193
-
-
See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004); In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d 1322, 1327-28 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
-
-
-
-
148
-
-
78149323408
-
-
note
-
See Case C-418/01, IMS Health GmbH & Co. v. NDC Health GmbH & Co. (IMS Health), 2004 E.C.R. I-5039, 5081-88; Case T-201/04 R, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601; Case C-241/91 P, Radio Telefis Eireann v. Comm'n, 1995 E.C.R. I-743, 815-25.
-
-
-
-
150
-
-
78149333858
-
-
RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 197-207 (2d ed. 2001)
-
See POSNER, supra note 24, at 207-23.
-
-
-
Posner1
-
151
-
-
78149337542
-
-
See, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Remarks, Intero-perability Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property (Sept. 13, 2006), in 14 GEO. MASON L. REV. 859
-
See Thomas Barnett, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Remarks, Intero-perability Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property (Sept. 13, 2006), in 14 GEO. MASON L. REV. 859, 865-66 (2007).
-
(2007)
, pp. 865-866
-
-
Barnett, T.1
-
152
-
-
78149306414
-
-
See MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 57-58, 69-73 (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition)
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 638.
-
-
-
-
153
-
-
78149293224
-
-
See, e.g, N.Y. TIMES, June 28, 2001, at C2 ("When evaluating a merger, United States antitrust officials tend to focus on the benefits to consumers, while European regulators give substantial weight to the impact on competitors, especially if they are national champions.'")
-
See, e.g., Hal R. Varian, Economic Scene; in Europe, G.E. and Honeywell Ran Afoul of 19th-Century Thinking, N.Y. TIMES, June 28, 2001, at C2 ("When evaluating a merger, United States antitrust officials tend to focus on the benefits to consumers, while European regulators give substantial weight to the impact on competitors, especially if they are national champions.'")
-
Economic Scene; in Europe, G.E. and Honeywell Ran Afoul of 19th-Century Thinking
-
-
Varian, H.R.1
-
154
-
-
78149294693
-
-
note
-
Editorial, Europe to GE: Go Home, WALL ST. J., June 15, 2001, at A14 ("In the Honeywell case, novel antitrust theories have been dreamed up simply because it would be unthinkable to let a large U.S. company go about its business unmolested.").
-
-
-
-
155
-
-
78149329815
-
-
See, e.g, WALL ST. J., July 5, at A3 ("Clear and longstanding U.S. antitrust policy holds that the antitrust laws protect competition, not competitors'. The EU decision reflects a significant point of divergence." (internal quotation marks omitted))
-
See, e.g., John R. Wilke, U.S. Antitrust Chief Criticizes EU Decision to Reject Merger of GE and Honeywell, WALL ST. J., July 5, 2001, at A3 ("Clear and longstanding U.S. antitrust policy holds that the antitrust laws protect competition, not competitors'. The EU decision reflects a significant point of divergence." (internal quotation marks omitted)).
-
(2001)
U.S. Antitrust Chief Criticizes EU Decision to Reject Merger of GE and Honeywell
-
-
Wilke, J.R.1
-
157
-
-
78149293225
-
-
See generally, (asserting that the United States'deference to market forces diverges from the European approach)
-
See generally Kolasky, supra note 91 (asserting that the United States'deference to market forces diverges from the European approach).
-
(2002)
-
-
Kolasky1
-
158
-
-
78149353709
-
-
Part of this tendency can be explained by the ordoliberal tradition that pervaded parts of Europe at the incipiency of the then European Economic Community (EEC), and the resulting policies that may be traced to the so-called Freiburg School
-
Part of this tendency can be explained by the ordoliberal tradition that pervaded parts of Europe at the incipiency of the then European Economic Community (EEC), and the resulting policies that may be traced to the so-called Freiburg School.
-
-
-
-
160
-
-
78149318331
-
-
See Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, 697-98, available at, (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link) (placing the burden on the defendant to prove with specificity that interoperability would reduce incentives to innovate)
-
See Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, 697-98, available at http://curia.europa.eu/jurisp/cgi-bin/form.pl?lang=EN&Submit=recherc her&numaff=T-201/04 (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link) (placing the burden on the defendant to prove with specificity that interoperability would reduce incentives to innovate).
-
-
-
-
161
-
-
78149306413
-
-
note
-
JOHN MAYNARD KEYNES, A TRACT ON MONETARY REFORM 80 (1923) (italics omitted).
-
-
-
-
162
-
-
78149344212
-
-
See generally, U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, 1992 HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552 (Sept. 10, 1992), revised, 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 13,104 (Apr. 8, 1997); Council Regulation 139/2004, 2004 O.J. (L 24) 1-22 (EC), available at, (EC merger regulations)
-
See generally U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, 1992 HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552 (Sept. 10, 1992), revised, 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) 13,104 (Apr. 8, 1997); Council Regulation 139/2004, 2004 O.J. (L 24) 1-22 (EC), available at http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/legislation/regulations.html#mer ger_reg (EC merger regulations).
-
-
-
-
163
-
-
78149337893
-
-
See generally SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT, (analyzing various forms of single firm conduct, such as exclusionary conduct, price predation, and tying in terms of both the anticompetitive and pro-competitive effects) U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, COMPETITION AND MONOPOLY: SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT UNDER SECTION 2 OF THE SHERMAN ACT 1 [hereinafter SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT], available at
-
See generally SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT, supra note 43 (analyzing various forms of single firm conduct, such as exclusionary conduct, price predation, and tying in terms of both the anticompetitive and pro-competitive effects).
-
(2008)
-
-
-
164
-
-
78149298640
-
-
note
-
See In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d 1322, 1327-28 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
-
-
-
-
165
-
-
78149327896
-
-
See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION, [herei-nafter PROMOTING INNOVATION], available at
-
See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION 27-28 (2007) [herei-nafter PROMOTING INNOVATION], available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf.
-
(2007)
, pp. 27-28
-
-
-
166
-
-
78149310715
-
-
Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, available at, (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link)
-
Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, available at http://curia.europa.eu/jurisp/cgi-bin/form.pl?lang=EN&Submit=recherc her&numaff=T-201/04 (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link).
-
-
-
-
167
-
-
78149313833
-
-
note
-
See Commission Decision 89/205/EEC, Magill TV Guide/ITP, BBC & RTE, 1989 O.J. (L 78) 43.
-
-
-
-
168
-
-
78149333486
-
-
note
-
Microsoft, 2007 E.C.R. 367, 643.
-
-
-
-
169
-
-
0442310752
-
-
See, 69 ANTITRUST L.J., (describing European intellectual property law on licensing for the benefit of American readers)
-
See Valentine Korah, The Interface Between Intellectual Property and Antitrust: The European Experience, 69 ANTITRUST L.J. 801 (2001) (describing European intellectual property law on licensing for the benefit of American readers).
-
(2001)
The Interface Between Intellectual Property and Antitrust: The European Experience
, pp. 801
-
-
Korah, V.1
-
170
-
-
78149304351
-
-
See, e.g., Press Release, Assistant Att'y Gen. for Antitrust, R. Hewitt Pate, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Issues Statement on the EC's Decision in its Microsoft Investigation (Mar. 24), available at, (noting the Justice Department's criticism of the European Commission's decision against Microsoft, suggesting that the Commission's action"may produce unintended consequences" and that"[s]ound antitrust policy must avoid chilling innovation and competition even by dominant'companies")
-
See, e.g., Press Release, Assistant Att'y Gen. for Antitrust, R. Hewitt Pate, U.S. Dep't of Justice, Issues Statement on the EC's Decision in its Microsoft Investigation (Mar. 24, 2004), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/2004/March/04_at_184.htm (noting the Justice Department's criticism of the European Commission's decision against
-
(2004)
-
-
-
171
-
-
78149340945
-
-
Compare, e.g., SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT, supra note 43, (noting the United States generally re-laxes the restrictions on dominant firms), with Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report,"Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Sec-tion 2 of the Sherman Act" (Sept. 8), available at, (criticizing the Department of Justice's Single-Firm Conduct report for weakening antitrust laws and promoting the interests of dominant companies)
-
Compare, e.g., SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT, supra note 43, (noting the United States generally re-laxes the restrictions on dominant firms), with Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report,"Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Sec-tion 2 of the Sherman Act" (Sept. 8, 2008), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2008/09/section2.shtm (criticizing the Department of Justice's Single-Firm Conduct report for weakening antitrust laws and promoting the interests of dominant companies).
-
(2008)
-
-
-
172
-
-
78149329466
-
-
Compare, e.g., SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT, supra note 43, (noting the United States generally re-laxes the restrictions on dominant firms), with Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, FTC Commissioners React to Department of Justice Report,"Competition and Monopoly: Single-Firm Conduct Under Sec-tion 2 of the Sherman Act" (Sept. 8), available at, (criticizing the Department of Justice's Single-Firm Conduct report for weakening antitrust laws and promoting the interests of dominant companies)
-
See supra note 131.
-
(2008)
-
-
-
173
-
-
78149316151
-
-
See, e.g., Austin Modine, Microsoft to EC: Define 'Unreasonable', REGISTER, Apr. 23
-
See, e.g., Austin Modine, Microsoft to EC: Define 'Unreasonable', REGISTER, Apr. 23, 2007, http://www.theregister.co.uk/2007/04/23/microsoft_responds_to_ec_complai nt/.
-
(2007)
-
-
-
174
-
-
78149355193
-
-
See, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Remarks, Intero-perability Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property (Sept. 13, 2006), in 14 GEO. MASON L. REV. 859 Note
-
See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004) ("The mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant charging of monopoly prices, is not only not unlawful; it is an important element of the free-market system. The opportunity to charge mo-nopoly prices-at least for a short period-is what attracts business acumen'in the first place; it induc-es risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth. To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly power will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct."); Barnett, supra note 113, at 865-66.
-
(2007)
, pp. 865-866
-
-
Barnett, T.1
-
175
-
-
78149309444
-
-
note
-
See United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416, 430 (2d Cir. 1945) ("The successful competitor, having been urged to compete, must not be turned upon when he wins.").
-
-
-
-
176
-
-
78149341325
-
-
See, Assistant Att'y Gen. Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Remarks, Intero-perability Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property (Sept. 13, 2006), in 14 GEO. MASON L. REV. 859
-
See Barnett, supra note 113, at 860-61.
-
(2007)
, pp. 860-861
-
-
Barnett, T.1
-
177
-
-
0035579072
-
-
See, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925, (explaining the Schumpeterian nature of competition in high technology markets, whereby the prospect of monopoly returns drives valuable ex ante competition in innovation)
-
See Richard A. Posner, Antitrust in the New Economy, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925, 929-30 (2001) (explaining the Schumpeterian nature of competition in high technology markets, whereby the prospect of monopoly returns drives valuable ex ante competition in innovation).
-
(2001)
Antitrust in the New Economy
, pp. 929-930
-
-
Posner Richard, A.1
-
178
-
-
0035579072
-
-
See, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925, (explaining the Schumpeterian nature of competition in high technology markets, whereby the prospect of monopoly returns drives valuable ex ante competition in innovation) Part II.B
-
See infra Part II.B.
-
(2001)
Antitrust in the New Economy
, pp. 929-930
-
-
Posner Richard, A.1
-
179
-
-
0035579072
-
-
See, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 925, (explaining the Schumpeterian nature of competition in high technology markets, whereby the prospect of monopoly returns drives valuable ex ante competition in innovation) Part II.B
-
See infra Part II.B.
-
(2001)
Antitrust in the New Economy
, pp. 929-930
-
-
Posner Richard, A.1
-
180
-
-
78149346070
-
-
See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION, [herei-nafter PROMOTING INNOVATION], available at See, PROMOTING INNOVATION
-
See PROMOTING INNOVATION, supra note 125, at 15-32.
-
(2007)
, pp. 15-32
-
-
-
181
-
-
78149323014
-
-
note
-
See Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP (Trinko), 540 U.S. 398, 411 (2004) (refusing to recognize the essential facility doctrine or another exception to the principle that there is no duty to aid competitors) Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp. (Aspen), 472 U.S. 585, 600 (1984) (stating that a firm with monopoly power has no general duty to cooperate with a competitor)
-
-
-
-
182
-
-
78149343158
-
-
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, (affirming, despite the Sherman Act,"the long recognized right of trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to parties with whom he will deal")
-
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307 (1919) (affirming, despite the Sherman Act,"the long recognized right of trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to parties with whom he will deal").
-
(1919)
, pp. 307
-
-
-
183
-
-
78149317244
-
-
note
-
Trinko, 540 U.S. 398.
-
-
-
-
184
-
-
78149305134
-
-
See, e.g, ANTITRUST LAW: ECONOMIC THEORY & COMMON LAW EVOLUTION, (reading Aspen to"imply[] a duty to cooperate with rivals")
-
See, e.g., KEITH N. HYLTON, ANTITRUST LAW: ECONOMIC THEORY & COMMON LAW EVOLUTION 203-05 (2003) (reading Aspen to"imply[] a duty to cooperate with rivals").
-
(2003)
, pp. 203-205
-
-
Hylton, K.N.1
-
185
-
-
78149352973
-
-
note
-
Aspen, 472 U.S. 585.
-
-
-
-
186
-
-
78149327139
-
-
note
-
Id. at 593.
-
-
-
-
187
-
-
78149319081
-
-
Id. at 603.
-
-
-
-
188
-
-
78149330570
-
-
note
-
Id. at 606-07.
-
-
-
-
189
-
-
78149335188
-
-
note
-
Id. at 608.
-
-
-
-
190
-
-
78149318332
-
-
note
-
Id. at 608-09.
-
-
-
-
191
-
-
78149309674
-
-
See, e.g, ANTITRUST LAW: ECONOMIC THEORY & COMMON LAW EVOLUTION, (reading Aspen to"imply[] a duty to cooperate with rivals")
-
See, e.g., HYLTON, supra note 143, at 203-05.
-
(2003)
, pp. 203-205
-
-
Hylton, K.N.1
-
192
-
-
78149300494
-
-
note
-
Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP (Trinko), 540 U.S. 398, 409-10 (2004).
-
-
-
-
193
-
-
78149296682
-
-
note
-
Id. at 410.
-
-
-
-
194
-
-
78149336308
-
-
See U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION, [herei-nafter PROMOTING INNOVATION], available at See, e.g, PROMOTING INNOVATION
-
See, e.g., PROMOTING INNOVATION, supra note 125, at 15-32.
-
(2007)
, pp. 15-32
-
-
-
195
-
-
78149348425
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d 1322 (Fed. Cir. 2000); Image Tech-nical Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak, Co., 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997); Miller Insituform, Inc. v. Insi-tuform of N. Am. Inc., 830 F.2d 606 (6th Cir. 1987).
-
-
-
-
196
-
-
78149295459
-
-
note
-
see also Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411 (finding no duty for telephone company to aid competi-tors under antitrust law by allowing access to its computer system).
-
-
-
-
197
-
-
78149325676
-
-
Kodak, 125 F.3d
-
Kodak, 125 F.3d at 1216.
-
-
-
-
199
-
-
78149352580
-
-
note
-
SCM Corp. v. Xerox Corp., 645 F.2d 1195, 1197 (2d Cir. 1981).
-
-
-
-
200
-
-
78149350503
-
-
note
-
Id. at 1209.
-
-
-
-
201
-
-
78149310005
-
-
note
-
F.3d 1195, 1201 (9th Cir. 1997).
-
-
-
-
202
-
-
78149348800
-
-
(quoting Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147, 1187 (1st Cir. 1994)) (internal quotation marks omitted)
-
Id. at 1218 (quoting Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147, 1187 (1st Cir. 1994)) (internal quotation marks omitted).
-
-
-
-
203
-
-
78149355919
-
-
note
-
Id. at 1212.
-
-
-
-
204
-
-
78149335189
-
-
note
-
In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d 1322, 1324 (Fed. Cir. 2000).
-
-
-
-
205
-
-
78149312590
-
-
note
-
Id. at 1327.
-
-
-
-
206
-
-
78149349168
-
-
See, Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem. Corp., 382 U.S. 172
-
See Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem. Corp., 382 U.S. 172, 177 (1965).
-
(1965)
, pp. 177
-
-
-
207
-
-
78149306549
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Prof'l Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Indus., 508 U.S. 49, 56 (1993); Asahi Glass Co. v. Pentech Pharm., Inc., 289 F. Supp. 2d 986, 993 (N.D. Ill. 2003).
-
-
-
-
209
-
-
84869636232
-
-
See, e.g., 9 SUP. CT. ECON. REV, (arguing that the differences between the Xerox and In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. An-titrust Litig. cases did not warrant resolution by the Supreme Court)
-
See, e.g., Michelle M. Burtis & Bruce H. Kobayashi, Why an Original Can be Better than a Copy: Intellectual Property, the Antitrust Refusal to Deal, and ISO Antitrust Litigation, 9 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 143 (2001) (arguing that the differences between the Xerox and In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. An-titrust Litig. cases did not warrant resolution by the Supreme Court).
-
(2001)
Why An Original Can be Better Than a Copy: Intellectual Property, the Antitrust Refusal to Deal, and ISO Antitrust Litigation
, pp. 143
-
-
Burtis Michelle, M.1
Kobayashi Bruce, H.2
-
210
-
-
78149303593
-
-
note
-
Compare In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d at 1325-26 (recognizing a patent holder's right to exclude so long as the patent is not fraudulently obtained or used for sham litigantion), with Image Technical Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak, Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1215-19 (9th Cir. 1997) (si-milarly recognizing a patent holder's right to exclude within limits).
-
-
-
-
211
-
-
78149295073
-
-
note
-
In re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d at 1329; Kodak, Inc., 125 F.3d at 1218.
-
-
-
-
212
-
-
78149302500
-
-
note
-
Cf. PROMOTING INNOVATION, supra note 125, at 17 (criticizing the Kodak decision on the basis that it is difficult to advise clients with respect to refusals to deal that are"pretextual").
-
-
-
-
213
-
-
78149352150
-
-
See, e.g, 13 GEO. MASON L. REV. 1197, (noting that"antitrust authorities on both sides of the Atlantic recognize that it is only in the rarest cases that refusing to cooperate with a rival should be prohibited by antitrust law")
-
See, e.g., Kenneth Glazer, The IMS Health Case: A U.S. Perspective, 13 GEO. MASON L. REV. 1197, 1205 (2006) (noting that"antitrust authorities on both sides of the Atlantic recognize that it is only in the rarest cases that refusing to cooperate with a rival should be prohibited by antitrust law").
-
(2006)
The IMS Health Case: A U.S. Perspective
, pp. 1205
-
-
Glazer, K.1
-
214
-
-
78149292836
-
-
See Case 238/87, AB Volvo v. Erik Veng (UK) Ltd., 1988 E.C.R. 6232, 8, available at
-
See Case 238/87, AB Volvo v. Erik Veng (UK) Ltd., 1988 E.C.R. 6232, 8, available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:61987J0238:E N:HTML.
-
-
-
-
215
-
-
78149332735
-
-
See Case C-7/97, Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. KG v. Mediaprint Zeitungs-und Zeitschriftenver-lag GmbH&Co. KG, 1998 E.C.R. 7791, 38, available at, (emphasis added)
-
See Case C-7/97, Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. KG v. Mediaprint Zeitungs-und Zeitschriftenver-lag GmbH&Co. KG, 1998 E.C.R. 7791, 38, available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:61997J0007:E N:HTML (emphasis added).
-
-
-
-
216
-
-
78149294342
-
-
note
-
See AB Volvo, 1988 E.C.R. 39.
-
-
-
-
217
-
-
78149313834
-
-
note
-
Joined Cases C-241/91 P & C-242/91 P, Radio Telefis Eireann & Indep. Television Publ'ns. Ltd v. Comm'n, 1995 E.C.R. I-743, 2.
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
78149307625
-
-
note
-
Id.at 822-25.
-
-
-
-
219
-
-
78149314587
-
-
note
-
See Case C-418/01, IMS Health GmbH & Co. OHG v. NDC Health GmbH & Co. KG, 2004 E.C.R. I-5039.
-
-
-
-
220
-
-
78149305500
-
-
(emphasis added)
-
Id. 49, 52 (emphasis added).
-
-
-
-
221
-
-
78149352151
-
-
note
-
For the authors'view on this decision, see Alan Devlin & Michael Jacobs, Microsoft's Five Fat-al Flaws, 2009 COLUM. BUS. L. REV 67.
-
-
-
-
222
-
-
78149347318
-
-
Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, 690 at 3831, available at, (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link)
-
Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, 690 at 3831, available at http:// curia.europa.eu/jurisp/cgi-bin/form.pl?lang=EN&Submit=rechercher& ;numaff=T-201/04 (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link).
-
-
-
-
223
-
-
78149301237
-
-
note
-
Id. 697-98.
-
-
-
-
224
-
-
78149351804
-
-
note
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
225
-
-
78149298219
-
-
note
-
Id. 330, 332.
-
-
-
-
226
-
-
78149314964
-
-
note
-
Indeed, we have argued elsewhere that this agnosticism constitutes a major weakness to Euro-pean competition policy.
-
-
-
-
228
-
-
78149289528
-
-
See generally, (arguing the importance of dynamic efficiency and innovation in the field of intellectual property and the related societal benefits of realizing these features)
-
See generally Barnett, supra note 113, at 859-61, 865-66 (arguing the importance of dynamic efficiency and innovation in the field of intellectual property and the related societal benefits of realizing these features).
-
-
-
-
229
-
-
78149308722
-
-
See, (stating that a firm that knows it will have to share its intellectual property will be deterred from investing in its development altogether or in its further advancement after hitting the market)
-
See id. at 865-66 (stating that a firm that knows it will have to share its intellectual property will be deterred from investing in its development altogether or in its further advancement after hitting the market).
-
-
-
-
230
-
-
0036961271
-
-
See, e.g, 90 CAL. L. REV. 1889, 1892, ("People innovate for many reasons, and in many industries the exis-tence of IP rights doesn't appear to be chief among them.")
-
See, e.g., Mark A. Lemley, Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations, 90 CAL. L. REV. 1889, 1892 (2002) ("People innovate for many reasons, and in many industries the exis-tence of IP rights doesn't appear to be chief among them.").
-
(2002)
Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organizations
-
-
Lemley, M.A.1
-
231
-
-
78149306030
-
-
See
-
See WHISH, supra note 56, at 20-21.
-
-
-
Whish1
-
232
-
-
79951753982
-
-
See, NAT'L AFF., Fall, available at
-
See Luigi Zingales, Capitalism After the Crisis, NAT'L AFF., Fall 2009, available at http://www.nationalaffairs.com/publications/detail/capitalism-after-the- crisis.
-
(2009)
Capitalism After the Crisis
-
-
Zingales, L.1
-
234
-
-
78149317956
-
-
See, ECONOMIST, Oct. 13
-
See The Age of Mass Innovation, ECONOMIST, Oct. 13, 2007, at 89.
-
(2007)
The Age of Mass Innovation
, pp. 89
-
-
-
235
-
-
78149338602
-
-
Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP (Trinko), 540 U.S. 398
-
Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP (Trinko), 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004).
-
(2004)
, pp. 407
-
-
-
236
-
-
78149334839
-
-
See, ("[The United States has] more confidence in the self-correcting nature of markets [than the European Union]. This confidence is especially strong when the markets are populated by strong rivals and strong buyers, who will usually find ways to protect them-selves from an aspiring monopolist. Our strong belief in markets and our humility in our own predictive abilities lead us to be skeptical of claims by rivals that a merger will lead to their ultimate demise and to demand strong empirical proof before we will accept such claims.")
-
See Kolasky, supra note 25, at 537 ("[The United States has] more confidence in the self-correcting nature of markets [than the European Union]. This confidence is especially strong when the markets are populated by strong rivals and strong buyers, who will usually find ways to protect them-selves from an aspiring monopolist. Our strong belief in markets and our humility in our own predictive abilities lead us to be skeptical of claims by rivals that a merger will lead to their ultimate demise and to demand strong empirical proof before we will accept such claims.").
-
-
-
-
237
-
-
78149295599
-
-
See, CAPITALISM, SOCIALISM AND DEMOCRACY, (arguing the importance of new technologies, commodities, sources of sources of supply, and types of organizations in driv-ing economic evolution)
-
See JOSEPH SCHUMPETER, CAPITALISM, SOCIALISM AND DEMOCRACY 82-85 (1975) (arguing the importance of new technologies, commodities, sources of supply, and types of organizations in driv-ing economic evolution).
-
(1975)
, pp. 82-85
-
-
Schumpeter, J.1
-
238
-
-
78149326059
-
-
note
-
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407.
-
-
-
-
239
-
-
78149297451
-
-
See, (explaining that the United States has"more confidence in the self-correcting nature of markets" than the European Union)
-
See Kolasky, supra note 25, at 537 (explaining that the United States has"more confidence in the self-correcting nature of markets" than the European Union).
-
-
-
-
241
-
-
78149333485
-
-
note
-
See supra Part II.B.2.
-
-
-
-
242
-
-
78149330932
-
-
note
-
See supra Part II.B.1.
-
-
-
-
243
-
-
78149343157
-
-
note
-
Bendix Autolite Corp. v. Midwesco Enters., 486 U.S. 888, 897 (1988) (Scalia, J., concurring).
-
-
-
-
245
-
-
78149295458
-
-
See, e.g, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See, e.g., BORK, supra note 10, at ix-xiv.
-
(2005)
-
-
Bork1
-
246
-
-
78149295974
-
-
See, e.g, Member of the European Comm'n in Charge of Competition Policy, Prelimi-nary Thoughts on Policy Review of Article 82, Speech at the Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 23, available at, (fol-low"EN" hyperlink for PDF) ("I think that competition policy evolves as our understanding of econom-ics evolves. In days gone by, fairness'played a prominent role in [U.S.] enforcement in a way that is no longer the case. I don't see why a similar development could not take place in Europe.")
-
See POSNER, supra note 24, at 207-23.
-
(2005)
, pp. 207-223
-
-
-
247
-
-
78149319436
-
-
note
-
See id. at 207-10.
-
-
-
-
248
-
-
78149349167
-
-
note
-
A Type I error occurs when a hypothesis is found to be false when it is actually true.
-
-
-
-
250
-
-
78149292835
-
-
see, ANTITRUST ERROR, 52 WM. & MARY L. REV. (forthcoming)
-
see Alan Devlin & Michael Jacobs, ANTITRUST ERROR, 52 WM. & MARY L. REV. (forthcoming 2010).
-
(2010)
-
-
Devlin, A.1
Jacobs, M.2
-
251
-
-
78149316152
-
-
See ANTITRUST LAW: ECONOMIC THEORY & COMMON LAW EVOLUTION 203-05 (reading Aspen to "imply[] a duty to cooperate with rivals.")
-
See HYLTON, supra note 143, at 279-80.
-
(2003)
, pp. 279-280
-
-
Hylton1
-
252
-
-
78149342422
-
-
See Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, available at, (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link)
-
See Case T-201/04, Microsoft v. Comm'n, 2007 E.C.R. II-3601, available at http://curia.europa.eu/jurisp/cgi-bin/form.pl?lang=EN&Submit=recherc her&numaff=T-201/04 (under the"Cases" column and in the row with"Judgment," follow the"T-201/04" link)
-
-
-
-
253
-
-
78149291414
-
-
see also John Lo-patka, Leverage in the CFI's Microsoft Decision, ANTITRUST & COMPETITION POL'Y BLOG, (Sept. 21) (describing the Court of First Instance's reliance on the concepts of tying and monopoly leverage in the Microsoft case)
-
see also John Lo-patka, Leverage in the CFI's Microsoft Decision, ANTITRUST & COMPETITION POL'Y BLOG, (Sept. 21, 2007), http://lawprofessors.typepad.com/antitrustprof_blog/2007/09/leverage-in- the.html (describing the Court of First Instance's reliance on the concepts of tying and monopoly leverage in the Microsoft case).
-
-
-
-
254
-
-
78149323013
-
-
See Scheiber v. Dolby Labs., Inc., 293 F.3d 1014, 1020 (7th Cir., ("The naive objection [to tying arrangements] is that they extend monopoly; the sophisticated objection is that they facilitate price discrimination.")
-
See Scheiber v. Dolby Labs., Inc., 293 F.3d 1014, 1020 (7th Cir. 2002) ("The naive objection [to tying arrangements] is that they extend monopoly; the sophisticated objection is that they facilitate price discrimination.").
-
(2002)
-
-
-
255
-
-
78149324830
-
-
See MODERN INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION 57-58, 69-73 (4th ed. 2005) (explaining the static efficiency benefits of competition)
-
See CARLTON & PERLOFF, supra note 16, at 306-08.
-
-
-
Carlton1
Perloff2
-
256
-
-
78149316864
-
-
note
-
Id. at 299-300, 308.
-
-
-
-
257
-
-
34547652299
-
-
One of the authors has explained this view in greater detail elsewhere., See, 44 AM. BUS. L.J. 521
-
One of the authors has explained this view in greater detail elsewhere. See Alan Devlin, A Neo-Chicago Perspective on the Law of Product Tying, 44 AM. BUS. L.J. 521, 543-45 (2007).
-
(2007)
A Neo-Chicago Perspective on the Law of Product Tying
, pp. 543-545
-
-
Devlin, A.1
-
258
-
-
33745032836
-
-
See, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 311
-
See Steven C. Salop, Exclusionary Conduct, Effect on Consumers, and the Flawed Profit-Sacrifice Standard, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 311, 343-44 (2006).
-
(2006)
Exclusionary Conduct, Effect on Consumers, and the Flawed Profit-Sacrifice Standard
, pp. 343-344
-
-
Salop Steven, C.1
-
259
-
-
78149351041
-
-
See This conclusion doubtless finds its foundation in Frank Easterbrook's famous 1984 article in the Texas Law Review
-
See Easterbrook, supra note 45, at 2-3.
-
-
-
Easterbrook1
-
263
-
-
70349150501
-
-
See generally, 84 IND. L.J
-
See generally Alan Devlin, Michael Jacobs & Bruno Peixoto, Success, Dominance, and Intero-perability, 84 IND. L.J. 1157 (2009).
-
(2009)
Success, Dominance, and Intero-perability
, pp. 1157
-
-
Devlin, A.1
Jacobs, M.2
Peixoto, B.3
-
264
-
-
78149338945
-
-
See, e.g, 52 IND. L.J. 735, (describing one decisionmaking theory approach and the general obstacles that such theories face in being adopted in the antitrust field, and ultimately concluding that decisionmaking theory should be employed in antitrust law)
-
See, e.g., Joseph F. Brodley, The Possibilities and Limits of Decision Theory in Antitrust: A Re-sponse to Professor Horowitz, 52 IND. L.J. 735 (1977) (describing one decisionmaking theory approach and the general obstacles that such theories face in being adopted in the antitrust field, and ultimately concluding that decisionmaking theory should be employed in antitrust law).
-
(1977)
The Possibilities and Limits of Decision Theory in Antitrust: A Re-sponse to Professor Horowitz
-
-
Brodley, J.F.1
|