메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 74, Issue 3, 2007, Pages 537-574

Merger analysis and the treatment of uncertainty: Should we expect better?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 39449135584     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (20)

References (105)
  • 1
    • 39449137453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From 1996 to 2005 the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice conducted an average of 210 merger investigations each year, which is more than all of the Division's other civil and criminal investigations combined. U.S. Dep't. of Justice, Antitrust Division, Workload Statistics 1996-2005 (2006). Merger investigations constitute a similarly important part of the Federal Trade Commission's work. FED. TRADE COMM'N, CHAIRMAN'S REPORT 2007 at 5-10, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2007/04/Chairmans Report2007.pdf.
    • From 1996 to 2005 the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice conducted an average of 210 merger investigations each year, which is more than all of the Division's other civil and criminal investigations combined. U.S. Dep't. of Justice, Antitrust Division, Workload Statistics 1996-2005 (2006). Merger investigations constitute a similarly important part of the Federal Trade Commission's work. FED. TRADE COMM'N, CHAIRMAN'S REPORT 2007 at 5-10, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2007/04/Chairmans Report2007.pdf.
  • 2
    • 39449133882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For purposes of this article, we are taking as given that the statutory objective of competition policy is to promote consumer welfare, .see, e.g., FTC v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1222-23 (11th Cir. 1991);
    • For purposes of this article, we are taking as given that the statutory objective of competition policy is to promote consumer welfare, .see, e.g., FTC v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1222-23 (11th Cir. 1991);
  • 3
    • 39449085771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. United Tote, Inc., 768 F. Supp. 1064, 1084-85 (D. Del. 1991), notwithstanding strong economic arguments for the use of a total surplus standard.
    • United States v. United Tote, Inc., 768 F. Supp. 1064, 1084-85 (D. Del. 1991), notwithstanding strong economic arguments for the use of a total surplus standard.
  • 4
    • 0001652957 scopus 로고
    • Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs, 58
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Oliver E. Williamson Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs, 58 AM. ECON. REV. 1372 (1968).
    • (1968) AM. ECON. REV , vol.1372
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 5
    • 39449123490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a survey and assessment of economic arguments in favor of applying a consumer welfare standard in antitrust analysis, see Joseph Farrell & Michael L. Katz, The Economics of Welfare Standards in Antitrust, 2 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 3 2006
    • For a survey and assessment of economic arguments in favor of applying a consumer welfare standard in antitrust analysis, see Joseph Farrell & Michael L. Katz, The Economics of Welfare Standards in Antitrust, 2 COMPETITION POL'Y INT'L 3 (2006).
  • 6
    • 39449109095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An obvious problem with this view is that something has to happen in the future, so not all probabilities can be zero. Thus, by assigning zero probabilities to the lowprobability events, the agencies and courts either implicitly assume the alternative will happen with certainty or are forming irrational beliefs
    • An obvious problem with this view is that something has to happen in the future, so not all probabilities can be zero. Thus, by assigning zero probabilities to the lowprobability events, the agencies and courts either implicitly assume the alternative will happen with certainty or are forming irrational beliefs.
  • 7
    • 33947654442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of recent enforcement actions involving innovative industries, see Michael L. Katz & Howard A. Shelanksi, Mergers and Innovation, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 1 (2007).
    • For a discussion of recent enforcement actions involving innovative industries, see Michael L. Katz & Howard A. Shelanksi, Mergers and Innovation, 74 ANTITRUST L.J. 1 (2007).
  • 8
    • 21644488588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In his analysis of how different responses to uncertainty can help to explain international differences in enforcement decisions (notably differences between the United States and European Union, Ken Heyer also advocates the application of decision theory to merger analysis and other antitrust actions. Because we address only the application of decision theory to merger analysis, we share his perspective but not his focus and emphases. Ken Heyer, A World of Uncertainty: Economics and the Globalization of Antitrust, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 375 2005
    • In his analysis of how different responses to uncertainty can help to explain international differences in enforcement decisions (notably differences between the United States and European Union), Ken Heyer also advocates the application of decision theory to merger analysis and other antitrust actions. Because we address only the application of decision theory to merger analysis, we share his perspective but not his focus and emphases. Ken Heyer, A World of Uncertainty: Economics and the Globalization of Antitrust, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 375 (2005).
  • 9
    • 39449094188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Several other authors have recommended the use of decision theory to assess the burden of proof and antitrust policy rules targeted at particular types of conduct (e.g, whether to have a high or low standard of proof for finding tying to be anticompetitive, That work tends to focus on the relative likelihood of false positives and false negatives for a given rule, rather than estimating the consumer welfare effects of a particular conduct in a specific case. Although the fundamental tools are similar, the divergent applications raise different considerations. See, e.g, Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1973);
    • Several other authors have recommended the use of decision theory to assess the burden of proof and antitrust policy rules targeted at particular types of conduct (e.g., whether to have a high or low standard of proof for finding tying to be anticompetitive). That work tends to focus on the relative likelihood of false positives and false negatives for a given rule, rather than estimating the consumer welfare effects of a particular conduct in a specific case. Although the fundamental tools are similar, the divergent applications raise different considerations. See, e.g., Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1973);
  • 10
    • 0033410755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frederick Beckner III & Steven C. Salop, Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 41 (1999) ;
    • Frederick Beckner III & Steven C. Salop, Decision Theory and Antitrust Rules, 67 ANTITRUST L.J. 41 (1999) ;
  • 11
    • 39449086340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A NeoChicago Approach (AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Related Publication 04-20 (2004));
    • David S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practices: A NeoChicago Approach (AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Related Publication 04-20 (2004));
  • 13
    • 39449084018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger analysis is also used to assess alternative remedies, such as partial divestitures. Ultimately, the questions asked are the same: would the proposed transaction-in its originally proposed form or subject to modification-harm consumers?
    • Merger analysis is also used to assess alternative remedies, such as partial divestitures. Ultimately, the questions asked are the same: would the proposed transaction-in its originally proposed form or subject to modification-harm consumers?
  • 14
    • 39449117903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 18. Mergers can also be challenged under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, which bars [e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations. In addition, mergers can be challenged by state enforcers under state antitrust laws or by private parties, the latter of which often face antitrust-injury and standing hurdles and which may be motivated by very different considerations than government enforcers. Our focus here is on federal enforcement.
    • 15 U.S.C. § 18. Mergers can also be challenged under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, which bars "[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations." In addition, mergers can be challenged by state enforcers under state antitrust laws or by private parties, the latter of which often face antitrust-injury and standing hurdles and which may be motivated by very different considerations than government enforcers. Our focus here is on federal enforcement.
  • 15
    • 39449123755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FTC v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1211 n.12 (11th Cir. 1991); FTC v. PPG Industries, Inc., 798 F.2d 1500, 1503 (D.C.Cir. 1986);
    • See FTC v. University Health, Inc., 938 F.2d 1206, 1211 n.12 (11th Cir. 1991); FTC v. PPG Industries, Inc., 798 F.2d 1500, 1503 (D.C.Cir. 1986);
  • 16
    • 39449119975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1081-82 (D.D.C.1997).
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1081-82 (D.D.C.1997).
  • 17
    • 39449085479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992, revised 1997), available at http://www.ftc.gov/bc/docs/ horizmer.htm [hereinafter Merger Guidelines].
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992, revised 1997), available at http://www.ftc.gov/bc/docs/ horizmer.htm [hereinafter Merger Guidelines].
  • 18
    • 39449135792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962). For a discussion of whether this stage of the analysis is helpful or necessary to the determination of the welfare effects of a merger, see infra Part III.B.
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962). For a discussion of whether this stage of the analysis is helpful or necessary to the determination of the welfare effects of a merger, see infra Part III.B.
  • 19
    • 39449131033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 4. See, e.g., Staples, 970 F. Supp. at 1088;
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 4. See, e.g., Staples, 970 F. Supp. at 1088;
  • 20
    • 39449137730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1288-92 (N.D. 111. 1989).
    • United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1288-92 (N.D. 111. 1989).
  • 21
    • 39449138337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The concentration thresholds set out in the Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 1.5, provide a highly incomplete description.
    • The concentration thresholds set out in the Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 1.5, provide a highly incomplete description.
  • 22
    • 39449102912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTICIPATING THE 21ST CENTURY: COMPETITION POLICY IN THE NEW HIGH-T ECH, GLOBAL MARKETPLACE 27 (1996), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/ global/report/gc_v1.pdf, [hereinafter 1996 FTC Report].
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTICIPATING THE 21ST CENTURY: COMPETITION POLICY IN THE NEW HIGH-T ECH, GLOBAL MARKETPLACE 27 (1996), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/ global/report/gc_v1.pdf, [hereinafter 1996 FTC Report].
  • 23
    • 39449109094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 4.
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 4.
  • 24
    • 39449138656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, emphasis added
    • Id. (emphasis added).
  • 25
    • 39449091232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States, v. Country Lake Foods, 754 F. Supp. 669, 680 n.13 (D. Minn. 1990);
    • See, e.g., United States, v. Country Lake Foods, 754 F. Supp. 669, 680 n.13 (D. Minn. 1990);
  • 26
    • 39449122436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1289 (N.D. 111. 1989).
    • United States v. Rockford Mem'l Corp., 717 F. Supp. 1251, 1289 (N.D. 111. 1989).
  • 28
    • 39449090908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1089 (D.D.C. 1997).
    • 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1089 (D.D.C. 1997).
  • 29
    • 39449129475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 30
    • 39449115317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 246 F.3d 708, 721 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
    • 246 F.3d 708, 721 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
  • 31
    • 39449123756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 720
    • Id. at 720.
  • 32
    • 39449122099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 33
    • 39449139244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 721
    • Id. at 721.
  • 35
    • 39449133575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Balto, supra note 17
    • See Balto, supra note 17.
  • 36
    • 39449125513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The following nonmerger hypothetical illustrates our fundamental objection to the use of probability thresholds. Suppose you were diagnosed as having a disease that, absent treatment, would prove fatal within six months. Moreover, suppose that the only known course of treatment cost $1,000 and had no side effects but, through years of experience, was known to work in only one in ten patients. We would be very surprised if any reader would refuse to undertake the treatment on the grounds that the chance of success was so low that any benefits of being cured were too speculative to count
    • The following nonmerger hypothetical illustrates our fundamental objection to the use of probability thresholds. Suppose you were diagnosed as having a disease that, absent treatment, would prove fatal within six months. Moreover, suppose that the only known course of treatment cost $1,000 and had no side effects but, through years of experience, was known to work in only one in ten patients. We would be very surprised if any reader would refuse to undertake the treatment on the grounds that the chance of success was so low that any benefits of being cured were too speculative to count.
  • 37
    • 39449089984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moreover, as discussed below, it is well known that a consumer who is risk-neutral with respect to income will be risk-loving with respect to prices
    • Moreover, as discussed below, it is well known that a consumer who is risk-neutral with respect to income will be risk-loving with respect to prices.
  • 38
    • 39449100485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Balto, supra note 17
    • Balto, supra note 17.
  • 39
    • 39449115606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael L. Katz, The Role of Efficiency Considerations in Merger Control: What WeDo in the U.S., in EC MERGER CONTROL: A MAJOR REFORM IN PROGRESS (Götz Drauz & Michael Reynolds eds., 2003). This assumption has been called a standard deduction for merger efficiencies. Michael Salinger, Director, FTC Bureau of Economics, Presentation to ABA Antitrust Section Economics Committee Brown Bag: Four Questions About Horizontal Merger Enforcement 3 (Sept. 14, 2005), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/ salinger.htm.
    • Michael L. Katz, The Role of Efficiency Considerations in Merger Control: What WeDo in the U.S., in EC MERGER CONTROL: A MAJOR REFORM IN PROGRESS (Götz Drauz & Michael Reynolds eds., 2003). This assumption has been called a "standard deduction" for merger efficiencies. Michael Salinger, Director, FTC Bureau of Economics, Presentation to ABA Antitrust Section Economics Committee Brown Bag: Four Questions About Horizontal Merger Enforcement 3 (Sept. 14, 2005), available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/ salinger.htm.
  • 40
    • 39449136392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/ atr/public/guidelines/215247.htm [hereinafter Merger Guidelines Commentary].
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/ atr/public/guidelines/215247.htm [hereinafter Merger Guidelines Commentary].
  • 41
    • 39449084318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (citing recent cases involving the analysis of entry). This approach is sometimes rationalized on the grounds that there is little credible evidence regarding entry, but-as we discuss below-the lack of credible evidence is typically better handled by adjusting the probabilities to account for the lack of evidence rather than applying an arbitrary threshold for rounding probabilities to zero.
    • See id. (citing recent cases involving the analysis of entry). This approach is sometimes rationalized on the grounds that there is little credible evidence regarding entry, but-as we discuss below-the lack of credible evidence is typically better handled by adjusting the probabilities to account for the lack of evidence rather than applying an arbitrary threshold for rounding probabilities to zero.
  • 42
    • 39449112636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specifically, for non-durable goods the agencies tend to look only two years forward, although the Merger Guidelines provide no rationale for this cutoff. Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 3.2. The agencies sometimes take a more sophisticated view, at least when deciding whether to file a case against a proposed merger, if not in court.
    • Specifically, for non-durable goods the agencies tend to look only two years forward, although the Merger Guidelines provide no rationale for this cutoff. Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 3.2. The agencies sometimes take a more sophisticated view, at least when deciding whether to file a case against a proposed merger, if not in court.
  • 43
    • 39449093880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at n.37
    • Id. at n.37.
  • 44
    • 39449119976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We present a somewhat stylized depiction of current practice as a probability-threshold-oriented approach. We recognize that enforcement is not based exclusively on probabilities, but we think it fair to say that the current approach emphasizes likely events over unlikely ones and, thus, for purposes of our comparison present it as a probabilitythreshold-based framework
    • We present a somewhat stylized depiction of current practice as a probability-threshold-oriented approach. We recognize that enforcement is not based exclusively on probabilities, but we think it fair to say that the current approach emphasizes likely events over unlikely ones and, thus, for purposes of our comparison present it as a probabilitythreshold-based framework.
  • 45
    • 39449094189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 4 (emphasis added).
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 4 (emphasis added).
  • 46
    • 39449107360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at n.37. To the extent that future efficiencies are discounted to account for the time value of money, this approach is sound. Our concern is with the use of discounting to account for uncertainty.
    • Id. at n.37. To the extent that future efficiencies are discounted to account for the time value of money, this approach is sound. Our concern is with the use of discounting to account for uncertainty.
  • 47
    • 39449129039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In our example, either there are no efficiencies or efficiencies are fully realized. In practice, there may be several different levels of efficiencies that might be attained with positive probability. The expected-payoff readily generalizes to any number of possibilities
    • In our example, either there are no efficiencies or efficiencies are fully realized. In practice, there may be several different levels of efficiencies that might be attained with positive probability. The expected-payoff readily generalizes to any number of possibilities.
  • 48
    • 39449092410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As we will discuss below, payoffs can be measured in ways that incorporate the decision maker's attitudes towards risks and process errors. We are taking the payoffs to be dollar consumer benefits in this example solely for expositional convenience
    • As we will discuss below, payoffs can be measured in ways that incorporate the decision maker's attitudes towards risks and process errors. We are taking the payoffs to be dollar consumer benefits in this example solely for expositional convenience.
  • 49
    • 39449129783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We note that the use of econometric studies and formal simulation models can contribute to this problem if they are not properly interpreted. Specifically, there is sometimes a tendency to focus on the point estimates that come out of models, rather than to consider the full distributions of the predicted values
    • We note that the use of econometric studies and formal simulation models can contribute to this problem if they are not properly interpreted. Specifically, there is sometimes a tendency to focus on the "point estimates" that come out of models, rather than to consider the full distributions of the predicted values.
  • 50
    • 39449114699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although it is counter-intuitive to many people, if one is making a prediction about a binary outcome e.g, whether a coin toss results in heads or tails, each of the two probabilities tends to 50 percent, not zero, as uncertainty grows
    • Although it is counter-intuitive to many people, if one is making a prediction about a binary outcome (e.g., whether a coin toss results in heads or tails), each of the two probabilities tends to 50 percent, not zero, as uncertainty grows.
  • 51
    • 39449120679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We discuss below why temporal cutoffs are not an appropriate way to incorporate uncertainty that increases over time
    • We discuss below why temporal cutoffs are not an appropriate way to incorporate uncertainty that increases over time.
  • 52
    • 39449110018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because this approach considers strategic interaction with other parties, it can be viewed as crossing over from decision theory to game theory. For a brief survey of formal models of the interaction between antitrust enforcement and the population of proposed mergers, see Farrell & Katz, supra note 2
    • Because this approach considers strategic interaction with other parties, it can be viewed as crossing over from decision theory to game theory. For a brief survey of formal models of the interaction between antitrust enforcement and the population of proposed mergers, see Farrell & Katz, supra note 2.
  • 53
    • 39449089003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We also want to be clear that we do not consider current policy to be an example of this practice. We have in mind thresholds somewhere below 5 percent
    • We also want to be clear that we do not consider current policy to be an example of this practice. We have in mind thresholds somewhere below 5 percent.
  • 54
    • 39449136393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • p.
    • p.
  • 56
    • 39449104714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 32, 34
    • Id. at 32, 34.
  • 57
    • 39449123491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 58
    • 39449103837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DAVID M. KREPS, A COURSE IN MICROECONOMIC THEORY 82 (1990).
    • See, e.g., DAVID M. KREPS, A COURSE IN MICROECONOMIC THEORY 82 (1990).
  • 59
    • 39449120680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This fact is what underlies consumers' preference for risk with respect to price changes discussed supra note 27
    • This fact is what underlies consumers' preference for risk with respect to price changes discussed supra note 27.
  • 60
    • 0030494662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another implication of this phenomenon is that merger review should integrate the efficiencies analysis and competitive effects analysis. Simply summing up separate, expected price changes might be an improvement over the probability-threshold approach of current merger enforcement. But calculation of an integrated expected-consumer-welfare effect would clearly be better than either. Gregory Werden offers a clever methodology that integrates the market power and efficiencies analyses and, in effect, allows one to determine if the price effects of the most likely efficiencies will outweigh the price effects of the most likely increase in market power. However, because Werden's computations are based on the most likely values of relevant variables, rather than computing the expected change in consumer welfare, it is subject to die criticisms of Part H.B above. Gregory J. Werden, A Robust Test for Consumer Welfare Enhancing Mergers Among Sellers of Differentiated Products, 44 J. I
    • Another implication of this phenomenon is that merger review should integrate the efficiencies analysis and competitive effects analysis. Simply summing up separate, expected price changes might be an improvement over the probability-threshold approach of current merger enforcement. But calculation of an integrated expected-consumer-welfare effect would clearly be better than either. Gregory Werden offers a clever methodology that integrates the market power and efficiencies analyses and, in effect, allows one to determine if the price effects of the most likely efficiencies will outweigh the price effects of the most likely increase in market power. However, because Werden's computations are based on the most likely values of relevant variables, rather than computing the expected change in consumer welfare, it is subject to die criticisms of Part H.B above. Gregory J. Werden, A Robust Test for Consumer Welfare Enhancing Mergers Among Sellers of Differentiated Products, 44 J. INDUS. ECON. 409 (1996).
  • 61
    • 39449108798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This issue arose in the dispute over Oracle's merger with PeopleSoft. United States, v. Oracle Corp, 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098, 1129-30 N.D. Cal. 2004
    • This issue arose in the dispute over Oracle's merger with PeopleSoft. United States, v. Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098, 1129-30 (N.D. Cal. 2004).
  • 62
    • 39449093577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 =p(0.1×α-0.095×p).
    • 2 =p(0.1×α-0.095×p).
  • 64
    • 39449109702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Philippe Choné & Laurent Linnemer, Assessing Horizontal Mergers Under Uncertain Efficiency Gains (unpublished manuscript, CREST-LEI Oct. 2006) (manuscripts on file with authors).
    • Philippe Choné & Laurent Linnemer, Assessing Horizontal Mergers Under Uncertain Efficiency Gains (unpublished manuscript, CREST-LEI Oct. 2006) (manuscripts on file with authors).
  • 65
    • 39449104713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rabah Amir, Effronsyni Diamantoudi, & Licun Xue, Merger Performance Under Uncertain Efficiency Gains (Working Paper, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, May 2004) (on file with authors).
    • Rabah Amir, Effronsyni Diamantoudi, & Licun Xue, Merger Performance Under Uncertain Efficiency Gains (Working Paper, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, May 2004) (on file with authors).
  • 66
    • 39449111774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 18
    • 15 U.S.C. § 18.
  • 67
    • 39449087805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Guidelines Commentary, supra note 30
    • Merger Guidelines Commentary, supra note 30.
  • 68
    • 39449137731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, this statement can also be read as excluding efficiencies from consideration unless they clear thresholds for likelihood and magnitude
    • However, this statement can also be read as excluding efficiencies from consideration unless they clear thresholds for likelihood and magnitude.
  • 69
    • 39449095631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1089 (D.D.C. 1997).
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1089 (D.D.C. 1997).
  • 70
    • 39449105309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098 (N.D. Cal. 2004).
    • United States v. Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098 (N.D. Cal. 2004).
  • 71
    • 39449093881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1175
    • Id. at 1175.
  • 72
    • 39449125204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We are not offering an opinion on whether (a) is, in fact, a correct statement in this particular case
    • We are not offering an opinion on whether (a) is, in fact, a correct statement in this particular case.
  • 73
    • 0008551104 scopus 로고
    • The Cellophane Case and the New Competition, 45
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., George W. Stocking & Willard F. Mueller, The Cellophane Case and the New Competition, 45 AM. ECON. REV. 29, 44-48 (1955).
    • (1955) AM. ECON. REV , vol.29 , pp. 44-48
    • Stocking, G.W.1    Mueller, W.F.2
  • 74
    • 39449108799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 1.0;
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, § 1.0;
  • 75
    • 39449092411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d 151, 160 (D.D.C. 2000);
    • FTC v. Swedish Match, 131 F. Supp. 2d 151, 160 (D.D.C. 2000);
  • 76
    • 39449098331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • California v. Sutter Health Sys., 130 F. Supp. 2d 1109, 1120 (N.D. Cal. 2001).
    • California v. Sutter Health Sys., 130 F. Supp. 2d 1109, 1120 (N.D. Cal. 2001).
  • 77
    • 0942302420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Critical Loss: Let's Tell the Whole Story
    • See also, Spring, at
    • See also Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Critical Loss: Let's Tell the Whole Story, ANTITRUST, Spring 2003, at 49.
    • (2003) ANTITRUST , pp. 49
    • Katz, M.L.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 78
    • 39449115607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, §§ 1.0 & 1.11.
    • Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, §§ 1.0 & 1.11.
  • 79
    • 39449136098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We are assuming that the baseline price is greater than or equal to incremental cost
    • We are assuming that the baseline price is greater than or equal to incremental cost.
  • 80
    • 39449137452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. SunGard Data Sys., 172 F. Supp. 2d 172, 182-88 (D.D.C. 2001) (example of how difficult it can be to determine where along a continuum of products a clean market boundary can be drawn).
    • See United States v. SunGard Data Sys., 172 F. Supp. 2d 172, 182-88 (D.D.C. 2001) (example of how difficult it can be to determine where along a continuum of products a clean market boundary can be drawn).
  • 81
    • 39449103502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 9, 2004).
    • United States v. Oracle Corp., 331 F. Supp. 2d 1098 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 9, 2004).
  • 82
    • 39449084017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 41
    • Id. at 41.
  • 83
    • 39449123206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Arch Coal Inc., 2004 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 15996 (D.D.C. Aug. 16, 2004).
    • FTC v. Arch Coal Inc., 2004 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 15996 (D.D.C. Aug. 16, 2004).
  • 84
    • 33947669365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Product Differentiation: Contemporary Empirical Merger Analysis, 5
    • Jonathan B. Baker, Product Differentiation: Contemporary Empirical Merger Analysis, 5 GEO. MASON L. REV. 347, 351 (1997).
    • (1997) GEO. MASON L. REV , vol.347 , pp. 351
    • Baker, J.B.1
  • 85
    • 33947643623 scopus 로고
    • Understanding Econometric Methods of Market Definition
    • Summer, at
    • Janusz A. Ordover & Daniel M. Wall, Understanding Econometric Methods of Market Definition, ANTITRUST, Summer 1989, at 20.
    • (1989) ANTITRUST , pp. 20
    • Ordover, J.A.1    Wall, D.M.2
  • 86
    • 39449115905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, the very question asked by the hypothetical monopolist test raises issues about the separation of market definition and competitive effects analysis. Under the Merger Guidelines' approach, the answer to the following question provides the basis of market definition: Would a hypothetical monopolist with control and ownership of a particular set of products be able to raise price profitably in a significant way, holding the prices of other products constant? But why not make predictions about what actual suppliers would do rather than focus on a hypothetical monopolist? Specifically, why not ask directly whether the merging parties would find it profitable to raise price by a significant amount post-merger? If one possesses the answer to that question, then the answer to the hypothetical monopolist question is superfluous. One distinction is that the second question does not entail holding other prices fixed. But in unilateral effects cases, an assumption along somewhat si
    • Indeed, the very question asked by the hypothetical monopolist test raises issues about the separation of market definition and competitive effects analysis. Under the Merger Guidelines' approach, the answer to the following question provides the basis of market definition: Would a hypothetical monopolist with control and ownership of a particular set of products be able to raise price profitably in a significant way, holding the prices of other products constant? But why not make predictions about what actual suppliers would do rather than focus on a hypothetical monopolist? Specifically, why not ask directly whether the merging parties would find it profitable to raise price by a significant amount post-merger? If one possesses the answer to that question, then the answer to the hypothetical monopolist question is superfluous. One distinction is that the second question does not entail holding other prices fixed. But in unilateral effects cases, an assumption along somewhat similar lines is made.
  • 87
    • 39449107944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They would, however, have to establish significant expected harm to consumer welfare
    • They would, however, have to establish significant expected harm to consumer welfare.
  • 88
    • 39449104439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This kind of issue is particularly likely to arise in markets with spatial differentiation, where each supplier competes with its neighbors, which then has effects on their neighbors, but the decay of this chaining process-and thus where a Merger Guidelines-style relevant market ends-is difficult to determine
    • This kind of issue is particularly likely to arise in markets with spatial differentiation, where each supplier competes with its neighbors, which then has effects on their neighbors, but the decay of this chaining process-and thus where a Merger Guidelines-style relevant market ends-is difficult to determine.
  • 89
    • 39449139831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One might wonder why the plaintiff would not simply include product 3 in the market on the grounds that the defendant would never attack the market definition for being overinclusive, In cases where the marginal product is clearly irrelevant, such an approach would make sense. In cases where the effect of the marginal product is ambiguous but potentially undermines plaintiffs theory of harm, the plaintiff would want to plead the narrower market in the hope of eliminating consideration of product 3 's potential effects. Moreover, in our experience, the government in practice often fails to take the broader approach, possibly in the belief that there is always some gain to the plaintiff from establishing a narrower market.
    • One might wonder why the plaintiff would not simply include product 3 in the market on the grounds that the defendant would never attack the market definition for being overinclusive, In cases where the marginal product is clearly irrelevant, such an approach would make sense. In cases where the effect of the marginal product is ambiguous but potentially undermines plaintiffs theory of harm, the plaintiff would want to plead the narrower market in the hope of eliminating consideration of product 3 's potential effects. Moreover, in our experience, the government in practice often fails to take the broader approach, possibly in the belief that there is always some gain to the plaintiff from establishing a narrower market.
  • 90
    • 39449135793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentista, 476 U.S. 447, 458 (1986) (quoting 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1511, at 429 (1986)).
    • FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentista, 476 U.S. 447, 458 (1986) (quoting 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1511, at 429 (1986)).
  • 91
    • 39449084892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 206 (2d Cir. 2001).
    • Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 206 (2d Cir. 2001).
  • 92
    • 0347486703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew I. Gavil, Copperweld 2000: The Vanishing Gap Between Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 87, 99 (2000).
    • Andrew I. Gavil, Copperweld 2000: The Vanishing Gap Between Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 87, 99 (2000).
  • 93
    • 39449111773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Similarly, the effects of myopia might run in either direction. For example, the agencies and courts might fail to recognize that there will be significantly fewer competitors in the future, or they might fail to recognize significant new entry that will be occurring as the result of ongoing innovation
    • Similarly, the effects of myopia might run in either direction. For example, the agencies and courts might fail to recognize that there will be significantly fewer competitors in the future, or they might fail to recognize significant new entry that will be occurring as the result of ongoing innovation.
  • 94
    • 39449094187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Section 13(b) of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. § 53b
    • Section 13(b) of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. § 53(b).
  • 95
    • 39449108224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1071 (D.D.C. 1997).
    • See, e.g., FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1071 (D.D.C. 1997).
  • 96
    • 39449106256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 97
    • 39449121534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 1072
    • Id at 1072.
  • 98
    • 39449114135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1071
    • Id. at 1071.
  • 100
    • 39449111465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is important to note that the Commission does not have to show irreparable harm to prevail in its request for a preliminary injunction. FTC v. H.J. Heinz, 246 F.3d 708, 714 (D.C. Cir. 2001);
    • It is important to note that the Commission does not have to show irreparable harm to prevail in its request for a preliminary injunction. FTC v. H.J. Heinz, 246 F.3d 708, 714 (D.C. Cir. 2001);
  • 101
    • 39449100157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Staples, 970 F. Supp at 1071 n.2.
    • Staples, 970 F. Supp at 1071 n.2.
  • 102
    • 39449125203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Heinz, 246 F.3d at 726 (quoting FTC v. Dean Foods Co., 384 U.S. 597 (1966)).
    • See, e.g., Heinz, 246 F.3d at 726 (quoting FTC v. Dean Foods Co., 384 U.S. 597 (1966)).
  • 103
    • 39449126693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 727
    • Id. at 727.
  • 104
    • 39449135032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent work in economics and psychology suggests that people systematically misestimate probabilities and exhibit other biases in making judgments under uncertainty. An interesting avenue for future research is to incorporate recognition of established biases into the analytical and litigation process. For example, one might want explicitly to impose a rule that various conditional probabilities have to be logically consistent with one another. For an accessible survey of the many different biases, see MAX H. BAZERMAX, JUDGMENT IN MANAGERIAL DECISION MAKING 5th ed. 2002
    • Recent work in economics and psychology suggests that people systematically misestimate probabilities and exhibit other biases in making judgments under uncertainty. An interesting avenue for future research is to incorporate recognition of established biases into the analytical and litigation process. For example, one might want explicitly to impose a rule that various conditional probabilities have to be logically consistent with one another. For an accessible survey of the many different biases, see MAX H. BAZERMAX, JUDGMENT IN MANAGERIAL DECISION MAKING (5th ed. 2002).
  • 105
    • 39449116204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, in particular, the discussion id. at 25 and 26 (observing that many people ascribe a higher probability to event A than event B even when the occurrence of event A is conditional on event B's taking place).
    • See, in particular, the discussion id. at 25 and 26 (observing that many people ascribe a higher probability to event A than event B even when the occurrence of event A is conditional on event B's taking place).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.