메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 4, Issue 2, 2008, Pages 279-309

Abolishing the price squeeze as a theory of antitrust liability

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 50349084850     PISSN: 17446414     EISSN: 17446422     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhn018     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (43)

References (124)
  • 1
    • 50349090130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Nicholas Economides & Ioannis Lianos, The Elusive Antitrust Standard on Bundling in Europe and in the United States at the Aftermath of the Microsoft Cases, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. (forthcoming 2008).
    • See Nicholas Economides & Ioannis Lianos, The Elusive Antitrust Standard on Bundling in Europe and in the United States at the Aftermath of the Microsoft Cases, 75 ANTITRUST L.J. (forthcoming 2008).
  • 2
    • 50349090131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. §2
    • 15 U.S.C. §2.
  • 3
    • 50349083895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 415 n.4 (2004) [hereinafter Trinko (labeling a claim monopoly leveraging does not dispense with the requirement that the plaintiff demonstrate a dangerous probability of success in monopolizing a second market).
    • See Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 415 n.4 (2004) [hereinafter Trinko (labeling a claim "monopoly leveraging" does not dispense with the requirement that the plaintiff demonstrate a "dangerous probability of success" in monopolizing a second market).
  • 4
    • 50349093885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Article 82 of the EC Treaty may be characterized as the European Union's equivalent to section 2 of the Sherman Act, it penalizes the abuse of dominance rather than illegal acquisition or maintenance of monopoly power. Article 82 begins with a single sentence stating the concept: Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the common market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the common market insofar as it may affect trade between Member States. It continues: Such abuse may, in particular, consist in, directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions, Id. This article does not discuss the viability of the price-squeeze theory of liability under the abuse of dominance doctrine under Article 82
    • Although Article 82 of the EC Treaty may be characterized as the European Union's equivalent to section 2 of the Sherman Act, it penalizes the "abuse of dominance" rather than illegal acquisition or maintenance of monopoly power. Article 82 begins with a single sentence stating the concept: "Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the common market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the common market insofar as it may affect trade between Member States." It continues: "Such abuse may, in particular, consist in...directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions..." Id. This article does not discuss the viability of the price-squeeze theory of liability under the "abuse of dominance" doctrine under Article 82.
  • 5
    • 50349089269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993).
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993).
  • 6
    • 50349100856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945) [hereinafter Alcoa].
    • United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945) [hereinafter Alcoa].
  • 7
    • 50349086269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 437-48
    • Id. at 437-48.
  • 8
    • 50349089795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pacific Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 1137 (2008) (invitation for the Solicitor General to file a brief amicus curiae on behalf of the United States regarding the grant of a writ of certiorari).
    • Pacific Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine Commc'ns, Inc., 127 S. Ct. 1137 (2008) (invitation for the Solicitor General to file a brief amicus curiae on behalf of the United States regarding the grant of a writ of certiorari).
  • 9
    • 50349094201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The defendants are usually subsidiaries of AT&T, Verizon, or companies acquired by AT&T or Verizon after the suit was brought. For example, the defendants in linkLine are AT&T subsidiaries.
    • The defendants are usually subsidiaries of AT&T, Verizon, or companies acquired by AT&T or Verizon after the suit was brought. For example, the defendants in linkLine are AT&T subsidiaries.
  • 10
    • 50349089071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the purposes of this article, the ILEC and its affiliates, including its ISP affiliate, collectively will be referred to as the ILEC, although they may be legally separate entities.
    • For the purposes of this article, the ILEC and its affiliates, including its ISP affiliate, collectively will be referred to as the "ILEC," although they may be legally separate entities.
  • 11
    • 50349091064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 127 S. Ct. 1955 (2007). The Court observed that, it is one thing to be cautious before dismissing an antitrust complaint in advance of discovery, but quite another to forget that proceeding to antitrust discovery can be expensive. Id. at 1966. Notwithstanding its ruling in linkLine in September 2007, the Ninth Circuit, citing Twombly, said in March 2008 that discovery in antitrust cases frequently causes substantial expenditures and gives the plaintiff the opportunity to extort large settlements even where he does not have much of a case. Kendall v. VISA U.S.A., Inc., 518 F.3d 1042, 1047 (9th Cir. 2008).
    • 127 S. Ct. 1955 (2007). The Court observed that, "it is one thing to be cautious before dismissing an antitrust complaint in advance of discovery, but quite another to forget that proceeding to antitrust discovery can be expensive." Id. at 1966. Notwithstanding its ruling in linkLine in September 2007, the Ninth Circuit, citing Twombly, said in March 2008 that "discovery in antitrust cases frequently causes substantial expenditures and gives the plaintiff the opportunity to extort large settlements even where he does not have much of a case." Kendall v. VISA U.S.A., Inc., 518 F.3d 1042, 1047 (9th Cir. 2008).
  • 12
    • 50349102997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecomm. Servs., 17 F.C.C.R. 27,000 8 (2002).
    • See Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecomm. Servs., 17 F.C.C.R. 27,000 8 (2002).
  • 13
    • 50349097019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court's discussion of affirmative duties to deal in Aspen Skiing arose in the context of a prior voluntary course of dealing. The Court wrote: In the actual case that we must decide, the monopolist did not merely reject a novel offer to participate in a cooperative venture that had been proposed by a competitor. Rather, the monopolist elected to make an important change in a pattern of distribution that had originated in a competitive market and had persisted for several years. Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 604 (1985).
    • The Supreme Court's discussion of affirmative duties to deal in Aspen Skiing arose in the context of a prior voluntary course of dealing. The Court wrote: "In the actual case that we must decide, the monopolist did not merely reject a novel offer to participate in a cooperative venture that had been proposed by a competitor. Rather, the monopolist elected to make an important change in a pattern of distribution that had originated in a competitive market and had persisted for several years." Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 604 (1985).
  • 14
    • 50349097020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 398 F.3d 666 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
    • 398 F.3d 666 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
  • 15
    • 50349093447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 673
    • Id. at 673.
  • 16
    • 50349101609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (quoting 3A PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW 767c3, at 129-30 (2d ed. 2002)).
    • Id. (quoting 3A PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW 767c3, at 129-30 (2d ed. 2002)).
  • 17
    • 50349088206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 330 F.3d 176 (4th Cir. 2003).
    • 330 F.3d 176 (4th Cir. 2003).
  • 18
    • 50349085674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 540 U.S. 398 2004
    • 540 U.S. 398 (2004).
  • 19
    • 50349084731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 330 F.3d at 190
    • 330 F.3d at 190.
  • 20
    • 50349093128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 374 F.3d 1044 (11th Cir. 2004).
    • 374 F.3d 1044 (11th Cir. 2004).
  • 21
    • 50349083077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1050
    • Id. at 1050.
  • 22
    • 50349095656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 23
    • 50349085573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brooke Group 509 U.S. at 224.
    • Brooke Group 509 U.S. at 224.
  • 24
    • 50349100742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 503 F.3d 876 (9th Cir. 2007). Although the case has multiple plaintiffs and defendants, for ease of exposition I will simplify the facts to concern a dispute between linkLine and SBC.
    • 503 F.3d 876 (9th Cir. 2007). Although the case has multiple plaintiffs and defendants, for ease of exposition I will simplify the facts to concern a dispute between linkLine and SBC.
  • 25
    • 50349099765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 884-85
    • Id. at 884-85.
  • 26
    • 50349099000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A refusal to deal, a denial of access to an essential facility, and a price squeeze. Id. at 878-79. The court dismissed the refusal to deal and denial of access to an essential facility allegations as barred by Trinko, and ordered linkLine to file an amended complaint limited to the price-squeeze claim
    • The district court construed linkLine's original complaint as alleging three different forms of anticompetitive conduct
    • The district court construed linkLine's original complaint as alleging three different forms of anticompetitive conduct: A refusal to deal, a denial of access to an essential facility, and a price squeeze. Id. at 878-79. The court dismissed the refusal to deal and denial of access to an essential facility allegations as barred by Trinko, and ordered linkLine to file an amended complaint limited to the price-squeeze claim. Id.
    • Id
  • 27
    • 50349084828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LinkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. SBC Cal., Inc., No. 03-5265, at 6 (C.D. Cal. Apr. 1, 2005) (order granting SBC's motion to strike and certifying order for interlocutory appeal and denying SBC's motion to dismiss).
    • LinkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. SBC Cal., Inc., No. 03-5265, at 6 (C.D. Cal. Apr. 1, 2005) (order granting SBC's motion to strike and certifying order for interlocutory appeal and denying SBC's motion to dismiss).
  • 28
    • 50349097558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 29
    • 50349093660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 6-7
    • Id. at 6-7.
  • 30
    • 50349101390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 7
    • Id. at 7.
  • 31
    • 50349092691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 32
    • 50349101294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8-9. To set up its price-squeeze theory, linkLine postulated the existence of a retail DSL market in which retail cable modem ISP service is not considered a substitute for retail DSL ISP service.
    • Id. at 8-9. To set up its price-squeeze theory, linkLine postulated the existence of a retail DSL market in which retail cable modem ISP service is not considered a substitute for retail DSL ISP service.
  • 33
    • 50349083481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 8
    • Id. at 8.
  • 34
    • 50349094752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 9
    • Id. at 9.
  • 35
    • 50349095189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 36
    • 50349085469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 10
    • Id. at 10.
  • 37
    • 50349097463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 9
    • Id. at 9.
  • 38
    • 50349086000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 39
    • 50349083798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 11
    • Id. at 11.
  • 40
    • 50349083376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 12
    • Id. at 12.
  • 41
    • 50349101293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • linkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. SBC Cal., Inc., CV 03-5265 SVW, at 12 (C.D. Cal. April 1, 2005) (order granting SBC's motion to strike and certifying order for interlocutory appeal and denying SBC's motion to dismiss).
    • linkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. SBC Cal., Inc., CV 03-5265 SVW, at 12 (C.D. Cal. April 1, 2005) (order granting SBC's motion to strike and certifying order for interlocutory appeal and denying SBC's motion to dismiss).
  • 42
    • 50349093984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 15 (citing Covad Commc'ns Co. v. BellSouth Corp., 374 F.3d 1044, 1050 (11th Cir. 2004)).
    • Id. at 15 (citing Covad Commc'ns Co. v. BellSouth Corp., 374 F.3d 1044, 1050 (11th Cir. 2004)).
  • 43
    • 50349087775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 44
    • 50349102016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 20
    • Id. at 20.
  • 45
    • 50349087991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 26
    • Id. at 26.
  • 46
    • 50349087318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 26-28
    • Id. at 26-28.
  • 47
    • 50349098478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 28
    • Id. at 28.
  • 48
    • 50349088652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 29
    • Id. at 29.
  • 49
    • 50349097357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 30
    • Id. at 30.
  • 50
    • 50349099541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Covad Commc'ns Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666, 673 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
    • Covad Commc'ns Co. v. Bell Atl. Corp., 398 F.3d 666, 673 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
  • 51
    • 50349094977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inc. v. Cal., Inc., 503 F.3d 876
    • LinkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. Cal., Inc., 503 F.3d 876, 880 (9th Cir. 2007).
    • (2007) 880 (9th Cir
    • Commc'ns, L.1
  • 52
    • 50349097982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 955 F.2d 1373 (9th Cir. 1992).
    • 955 F.2d 1373 (9th Cir. 1992).
  • 53
    • 50349102899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 503 F.3d at 880-81 (quoting City of Anaheim, 955 F.2d at 1377).
    • 503 F.3d at 880-81 (quoting City of Anaheim, 955 F.2d at 1377).
  • 54
    • 50349095761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 882. Apart from the question of whether such reasoning in City of Anaheim survives Trinko, the separate question arises of whether that reasoning had already been overruled by the Supreme Court's analysis in NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc, 525 U.S. 128 1998, There, a downstream competitor alleged a per se unlawful boycott by a regulated telephone company, New York Telephone, which chose to buy certain services at allegedly inflated prices from its own downstream affiliate. Unobservant regulators allegedly permitted New York Telephone to recover the padded costs from ratepayers. Justice Breyer, writing for a unanimous Court, rejected the proposition that hoodwinking regulators, id. at 132, stated an antitrust cause of action: We concede Discon's claim that [New York Telephone's] behavior hurt consumers by raising telephone service rates. But that consumer injury naturally flowed not so much from a less competitive market for removal services
    • Id. at 882. Apart from the question of whether such reasoning in City of Anaheim survives Trinko, the separate question arises of whether that reasoning had already been overruled by the Supreme Court's analysis in NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128 (1998). There, a downstream competitor alleged a per se unlawful boycott by a regulated telephone company, New York Telephone, which chose to buy certain services at allegedly inflated prices from its own downstream affiliate. Unobservant regulators allegedly permitted New York Telephone to recover the padded costs from ratepayers. Justice Breyer, writing for a unanimous Court, rejected the proposition that "hoodwinking regulators," id. at 132, stated an antitrust cause of action: We concede Discon's claim that [New York Telephone's] behavior hurt consumers by raising telephone service rates. But that consumer injury naturally flowed not so much from a less competitive market for removal services [for obsolete telephone equipment, supplied by New York Telephone's affiliate], as from the exercise of market power that is lawfully in the hands of a monopolist, namely, New York Telephone, combined with a deception worked upon the regulatory agency that prevented the agency from controlling New York Telephone's exercise of its monopoly power. To apply the per se rule here-where the buyer's decision, though not made for competitive reasons, composes part of a regulatory fraud-would transform cases involving business behavior that is improper for various reasons, say, cases involving nepotism or personal pique, into treble-damages antitrust cases. And that per se rule would discourage firms from changing suppliers-even where the competitive process itself does not suffer harm. Id. at 129 (emphasis in original). Justice Breyer stressed that Discon had the burden of "alleg[ing] and prov[ing] harm, not just to a single competitor, but to the competitive process, i.e., to competition itself." Id. at 135. Remarkably, the Ninth Circuit's decision in linkLine contains no mention of Discon whatsoever.
  • 55
    • 50349102452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • linkLine, 503 F.3d at 882-83. In the district court, SBC had argued that Trinko held that its reasoning preserved only well established antitrust claims, rather than merely existing claims, and that because price-squeeze claims are no more well established than are refusal-to-deal claims, Trinko's preservation of antitrust claims does not apply to price squeezes. LinkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. SBC Cal, Inc, CV 03-5265 SVW, at 31 C.D. Cal. April 1, 2005, order granting SBC's motion to strike and certifying order for interlocutory appeal and denying SBC's motion to dismiss, The Ninth Circuit used City of Anaheim in linkLine to justify a hoodwinking regulators rationale for antitrust liability of the sort that the Supreme Court rejected in Discon. 525 U.S. at 132. Discon preceded Trinko by six years. It was therefore incongruous for the Ninth Circuit to characterize the reasoning of City of Anaheim as
    • linkLine, 503 F.3d at 882-83. In the district court, SBC had argued that Trinko held that its reasoning preserved only "well established" antitrust claims, rather than merely existing claims, and that because price-squeeze claims are no more well established than are refusal-to-deal claims, Trinko's preservation of antitrust claims does not apply to price squeezes. LinkLine Commc'ns, Inc. v. SBC Cal., Inc., CV 03-5265 SVW, at 31 (C.D. Cal. April 1, 2005) (order granting SBC's motion to strike and certifying order for interlocutory appeal and denying SBC's motion to dismiss). The Ninth Circuit used City of Anaheim in linkLine to justify a "hoodwinking regulators" rationale for antitrust liability of the sort that the Supreme Court rejected in Discon. 525 U.S. at 132. Discon preceded Trinko by six years. It was therefore incongruous for the Ninth Circuit to characterize the reasoning of City of Anaheim as "well established" when the Supreme Court decided Trinko in 2004.
  • 56
    • 50349084513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 883 (quoting Trinko, 540 U.S. at 412).
    • Id. at 883 (quoting Trinko, 540 U.S. at 412).
  • 57
    • 50349093985 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 883-84
    • Id. at 883-84.
  • 58
    • 50349090234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 885
    • Id. at 885.
  • 59
    • 50349096967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 60
    • 50349090644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 61
    • 50349100400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 886
    • Id. at 886.
  • 62
    • 50349086888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 885
    • Id. at 885.
  • 63
    • 50349087888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 64
    • 50349083482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 885-86
    • Id. at 885-86.
  • 65
    • 50349102453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 886
    • Id. at 886.
  • 66
    • 50349095425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 887
    • Id. at 887.
  • 67
    • 50349087091 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004)
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004)
  • 69
    • 50349091394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993)
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993)
  • 70
    • 50349096398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128 (1998).
    • NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128 (1998).
  • 71
    • 50349085054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • linkLine Commc'ns Inc. v. Pac. Bell Tel. Co., 503 F.3d 876, 885 (9th Cir. 2007) (Gould, J., dissenting).
    • linkLine Commc'ns Inc. v. Pac. Bell Tel. Co., 503 F.3d 876, 885 (9th Cir. 2007) (Gould, J., dissenting).
  • 72
    • 50349102995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert W. Crandall & Hal J. Singer, Life Support for Unaffiliated ISPs, REGULATION, Fall 2005, at 46. Some, on both sides of the Atlantic, may argue that Europe is moving closer to a consumer-welfare model. One might say that, given the stage of development of European competition law, addressing as it does many industries that have been dominated by state-owned or state-granted monopolies, an emphasis at the level of the European Commission on abuse of dominance-as opposed to consumer welfare-has been an expedient, perhaps necessary, means to break down the barriers resulting from member-state competition laws that insulate favored national players that exploit their dominant positions. So, one might argue, as European competition law progresses, an interpretation of abuse of dominance to protect competitors will give way to an American-style interpretation of abuse of dominance to protect consumers. This argument would be more persuasive if the notable
    • See Robert W. Crandall & Hal J. Singer, Life Support for Unaffiliated ISPs?, REGULATION, Fall 2005, at 46. Some, on both sides of the Atlantic, may argue that Europe is moving closer to a consumer-welfare model. One might say that, given the stage of development of European competition law, addressing as it does many industries that have been dominated by state-owned or state-granted monopolies, an emphasis at the level of the European Commission on abuse of dominance-as opposed to consumer welfare-has been an expedient, perhaps necessary, means to break down the barriers resulting from member-state competition laws that insulate favored national players that exploit their dominant positions. So, one might argue, as European competition law progresses, an interpretation of abuse of dominance to protect competitors will give way to an American-style interpretation of abuse of dominance to protect consumers. This argument would be more persuasive if the notable targets of recent EC abuse-of-dominance cases were not American multinational corporations doing business in Europe.
  • 73
    • 50349084617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM J. BAUMOL & J. GREGORY SIDAK, TOWARD COMPETITION IN LOCAL TELEPHONY (MIT Press 1994)
    • See, e.g., WILLIAM J. BAUMOL & J. GREGORY SIDAK, TOWARD COMPETITION IN LOCAL TELEPHONY (MIT Press 1994)
  • 74
    • 0000599652 scopus 로고
    • The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors, 11
    • William J. Baumol & J. Gregory Sidak, The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors, 11 YALE J. ON REG. 171 (1994)
    • (1994) YALE J. ON REG , vol.171
    • Baumol, W.J.1    Gregory Sidak, J.2
  • 75
    • 0042894018 scopus 로고
    • The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors: Rejoinder and Epilogue, 12
    • William J. Baumol & J. Gregory Sidak, The Pricing of Inputs Sold to Competitors: Rejoinder and Epilogue, 12 YALE J. ON REG. 177 (1995)
    • (1995) YALE J. ON REG , vol.177
    • Baumol, W.J.1    Gregory Sidak, J.2
  • 76
    • 50349088311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jerry A. Hausman & Timothy J. Tardiff, Efficient Local Exchange Competition, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 529 (1995).
    • Jerry A. Hausman & Timothy J. Tardiff, Efficient Local Exchange Competition, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 529 (1995).
  • 77
    • 50349085888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Town of Concord v. Boston Ed. Co., 915 F.2d 17, 25 (1st Cir. 1990).
    • Town of Concord v. Boston Ed. Co., 915 F.2d 17, 25 (1st Cir. 1990).
  • 78
    • 50349094753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. AT&T Corp., 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982), aff 'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983).
    • United States v. AT&T Corp., 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982), aff 'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983).
  • 79
    • 50349087319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 412-16.
    • See Trinko, 540 U.S. at 412-16.
  • 80
    • 50349096085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Deutsche Telekom AG v. Commission, Case T-271/03, Judgment of the Court of First Instance April 10, 2008
    • See Deutsche Telekom AG v. Commission, Case T-271/03, Judgment of the Court of First Instance (April 10, 2008).
  • 81
    • 45949092505 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For legal and economic analyses of other recent European price-squeeze cases, see Michele Polo, Price Squeeze: Lessons from the Telecom Italia Case, 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 453 (2007)
    • For legal and economic analyses of other recent European price-squeeze cases, see Michele Polo, Price Squeeze: Lessons from the Telecom Italia Case, 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 453 (2007)
  • 82
    • 34547133765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Laura Ferrari Bravo & Paolo Siciliani, Exclusionary Pricing and Consumer Harm: The European Commission's Practice in the DSL Market, 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 243 (2007)
    • Laura Ferrari Bravo & Paolo Siciliani, Exclusionary Pricing and Consumer Harm: The European Commission's Practice in the DSL Market, 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 243 (2007)
  • 83
    • 27844473775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Damien Geradin & Robert O'Donoghue, The Concurrent Application of Competition Law and Regulation: The Case of Margin Squeeze Abuses in the Telecommunications Sector, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 355 (2005)
    • Damien Geradin & Robert O'Donoghue, The Concurrent Application of Competition Law and Regulation: The Case of Margin Squeeze Abuses in the Telecommunications Sector, 1 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 355 (2005)
  • 85
    • 50449109362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dennis Carlton observes that, just as in the case of predatory pricing, any sensible price squeeze theory must use the costs of an efficient firm in applying the financial viability test. See Dennis W. Carlton, Should Price Squeeze Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 271 (2008).
    • Dennis Carlton observes that, "just as in the case of predatory pricing, any sensible price squeeze theory must use the costs of an efficient firm in applying the financial viability test." See Dennis W. Carlton, Should "Price Squeeze" Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, 4 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 271 (2008).
  • 86
    • 45949097810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A separate question is whether it is a violation of the separation of powers for a court to regulate prices through its administration of a consent decree, because ratemaking is considered a legislative function. See Farrell Malone & J. Gregory Sidak, Should Antitrust Consent Decrees Regulate Post-Merger Pricing, 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 471 2007
    • A separate question is whether it is a violation of the separation of powers for a court to regulate prices through its administration of a consent decree, because ratemaking is considered a legislative function. See Farrell Malone & J. Gregory Sidak, Should Antitrust Consent Decrees Regulate Post-Merger Pricing?, 3 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 471 (2007).
  • 87
    • 50349093337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dennis Carlton observes that another perverse alternative available to the vertically integrated monopolist-whether it is regulated or unregulated-seeking to avoid price-squeeze liability is to exit the downstream market: Where there is a duty to deal under the antitrust laws, application of the theory is likely to create incentives for inefficiency as firms either raise price or cease production to avoid liability. Where there is no duty to deal under the antitrust laws, application of the theory is likely to lead to withdrawal of goods from the market to the detriment of consumers as firms cease dealing with each other in order not to trigger liability
    • Dennis Carlton observes that another perverse alternative available to the vertically integrated monopolist-whether it is regulated or unregulated-seeking to avoid price-squeeze liability is to exit the downstream market: Where there is a duty to deal under the antitrust laws, application of the theory is likely to create incentives for inefficiency as firms either raise price or cease production to avoid liability. Where there is no duty to deal under the antitrust laws, application of the theory is likely to lead to withdrawal of goods from the market to the detriment of consumers as firms cease dealing with each other in order not to trigger liability.
  • 88
    • 50349086991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should "Price Squeeze" Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, supra note 74, at 278 (emphasis added). However, exit is not so simple for a regulated firm
    • Carlton, Should "Price Squeeze" Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, supra note 74, at 278 (emphasis added). However, exit is not so simple for a regulated firm. The firm often has an "obligation to serve" as a matter of state public utility law and thus faces a statutory or regulatory barrier to exit.
    • The firm often has an obligation to serve
    • Carlton1
  • 89
    • 50349100065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT: THE COMPETITIVE TRANSFORMATION OF NETWORK INDUSTRIES IN THE UNITED STATES (1997).
    • See J. GREGORY SIDAK & DANIEL F. SPULBER, DEREGULATORY TAKINGS AND THE REGULATORY CONTRACT: THE COMPETITIVE TRANSFORMATION OF NETWORK INDUSTRIES IN THE UNITED STATES (1997).
  • 90
    • 50349102017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 525 U.S. 366 1999
    • 525 U.S. 366 (1999).
  • 91
    • 50349083799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 392, 399-400, 416-18.
    • Id. at 392, 399-400, 416-18.
  • 92
    • 0010332510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks, 109
    • See
    • See Jerry A. Hausman & J. Gregory Sidak, A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Mandatory Unbundling of Telecommunications Networks, 109 YALE L.J. 417 (1999).
    • (1999) YALE L.J , vol.417
    • Hausman, J.A.1    Gregory Sidak, J.2
  • 93
    • 46049095068 scopus 로고
    • Aspen Skiing Co. v, U.S
    • Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985).
    • (1985) Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp , vol.472 , pp. 585
  • 94
    • 50349089070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carlton, Should Price Squeeze Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct, supra note 74, at 275
    • See Carlton, Should "Price Squeeze" Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, supra note 74, at 275.
  • 95
    • 50349092239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gerald R. Faulhaber, Cross-Subsidization: Pricing in Public Enterprise, 65 AM. ECON. REV. 966 (1975). For a 30-year retrospective on the acceptance and application of Faulhaber's cross-subsidization analysis by regulators, see Gerald R. Faulhaber, Cross-Subsidy Analysis with More Than Two Services, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 441 (2005).
    • Gerald R. Faulhaber, Cross-Subsidization: Pricing in Public Enterprise, 65 AM. ECON. REV. 966 (1975). For a 30-year retrospective on the acceptance and application of Faulhaber's cross-subsidization analysis by regulators, see Gerald R. Faulhaber, Cross-Subsidy Analysis with More Than Two Services, 2 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 441 (2005).
  • 96
    • 0002007807 scopus 로고
    • A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, 37
    • Frank Ramsey, A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation, 37 ECON. J. 47 (1927).
    • (1927) ECON. J , vol.47
    • Ramsey, F.1
  • 97
    • 0009950695 scopus 로고
    • Sur la Gestion des Monoples Publics Astreints à l'Equilibre Budgétaire, 24 ECONOMETRICA 22 (1956), republished in English as Marcel Boiteux, On the Management of Public Monopolies Subject to Budgetary Constraints, 3
    • The relevance of Ramsey's seminal article to public utility pricing was first enunciated in Marcel Boiteux
    • The relevance of Ramsey's seminal article to public utility pricing was first enunciated in Marcel Boiteux, Sur la Gestion des Monoples Publics Astreints à l'Equilibre Budgétaire, 24 ECONOMETRICA 22 (1956), republished in English as Marcel Boiteux, On the Management of Public Monopolies Subject to Budgetary Constraints, 3 J. ECON. THEORY 219 (1971).
    • (1971) J. ECON. THEORY , vol.219
  • 98
    • 0001029919 scopus 로고
    • Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing, 60
    • See
    • See William J. Baumol & David F. Bradford, Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing, 60 AM. ECON. REV. 265 (1970).
    • (1970) AM. ECON. REV , vol.265
    • Baumol, W.J.1    Bradford, D.F.2
  • 99
    • 50349095191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JEAN-JACQUES LAFFONT & JEAN TIROLE, COMPETITION IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS 60-65 (MIT Press 2000).
    • See, e.g., JEAN-JACQUES LAFFONT & JEAN TIROLE, COMPETITION IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS 60-65 (MIT Press 2000).
  • 100
    • 50349095655 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • linkLine, 503 F.3d at 880.
    • linkLine, 503 F.3d at 880.
  • 101
    • 50349102898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 883
    • Id. at 883.
  • 102
    • 50349099974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 438.
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 438.
  • 103
    • 50349093661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 399.
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 399.
  • 104
    • 50349094200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare, for example, how the D.C. Circuit in Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, 792 F.2d 210, 226 (D.C. Cir. 1986) (Bork, J.), reasoned that, by 1986, certain Supreme Court decisions had been implicitly overruled by the analysis contained in the Court's more recent cases embracing the consumer-welfare approach.
    • Compare, for example, how the D.C. Circuit in Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, 792 F.2d 210, 226 (D.C. Cir. 1986) (Bork, J.), reasoned that, by 1986, certain Supreme Court decisions had been implicitly overruled by the analysis contained in the Court's more recent cases embracing the consumer-welfare approach.
  • 105
    • 50349085470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408.
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408.
  • 106
    • 50349092566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 429 (emphasis added).
    • Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 429 (emphasis added).
  • 107
    • 50349087776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 52 (1978). Bork elsewhere concluded: The Alcoa decision...stands revealed as a thoroughly perverse judicial tour de force, contrary to the legislative intent of the Sherman Act, the great 1911 cases that formulated the 'rule of reason,' and the entire spirit of antitrust. Id. at 170.
    • ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 52 (1978). Bork elsewhere concluded: "The Alcoa decision...stands revealed as a thoroughly perverse judicial tour de force, contrary to the legislative intent of the Sherman Act, the great 1911 cases that formulated the 'rule of reason,' and the entire spirit of antitrust." Id. at 170.
  • 108
    • 50349086454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 103, 196, 250, 263 (2d ed. 2001).
    • RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 103, 196, 250, 263 (2d ed. 2001).
  • 110
    • 50349098272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Town of Concord v. Boston Ed. Co., 915 F.2d 17 (1st Cir. 1990).
    • Town of Concord v. Boston Ed. Co., 915 F.2d 17 (1st Cir. 1990).
  • 111
    • 50349102015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 18
    • Id. at 18.
  • 113
    • 50349086990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Town of Concord, 915 F.2d at 21-22 (citations omitted).
    • Town of Concord, 915 F.2d at 21-22 (citations omitted).
  • 114
    • 50349099764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 115
    • 50349090233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 24
    • Id. at 24.
  • 116
    • 50349090958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 24-25
    • Id. at 24-25.
  • 117
    • 50349096179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 3A AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 16, 758b at 30.
    • See, e.g., 3A AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 16, 758b at 30.
  • 118
    • 50349093773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Town of Concord, 915 F.2d at 25.
    • Town of Concord, 915 F.2d at 25.
  • 119
    • 50349088431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408.
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408.
  • 120
    • 0035583308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen Skiing and Kodak Are Misguided, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 659, 662 (2001).
    • Dennis W. Carlton, A General Analysis of Exclusionary Conduct and Refusal to Deal-Why Aspen Skiing and Kodak Are Misguided, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 659, 662 (2001).
  • 121
    • 50349084228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408, 414.
    • Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408, 414.
  • 122
    • 50349095423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 123
    • 50349084115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Furthermore, asserting that a price squeeze justifies a different analysis because it effectuates some sort of abuse of dominance conflicts with Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447 (1993).
    • Furthermore, asserting that a price squeeze justifies a different analysis because it effectuates some sort of "abuse of dominance" conflicts with Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447 (1993).
  • 124
    • 50349091902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Carlton, Should Price Squeeze Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct, supra note 74, at 276
    • Carlton, Should "Price Squeeze" Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, supra note 74, at 276.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.