메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 86, Issue 6, 2008, Pages 1159-1222

Technocracy and antitrust

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 44649098126     PISSN: 00404411     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (72)

References (442)
  • 1
    • 44649145333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally RICHARD HOFSTADTER, What Happened to the Antitrust Movement?, in THE PARANOID STYLE IN AMERICAN POLITICS AND OTHER ESSAYS 188, 195-96 (1966) (The antitrust movement and its legislation are characteristically American. . . . The idea of competition as ameans of social regulation-as an economic, political, and moral force-has grown stronger roots in the United States than elsewhere, partly because it has had little to compete with in the way of aristocratic, militaristic, or labor-socialist theories.).
    • See generally RICHARD HOFSTADTER, What Happened to the Antitrust Movement?, in THE PARANOID STYLE IN AMERICAN POLITICS AND OTHER ESSAYS 188, 195-96 (1966) ("The antitrust movement and its legislation are characteristically American. . . . The idea of competition as ameans of social regulation-as an economic, political, and moral force-has grown stronger roots in the United States than elsewhere, partly because it has had little to compete with in the way of aristocratic, militaristic, or labor-socialist theories.").
  • 2
    • 44649099631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 7 HAROLD U. FAULKNER, THE ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES: THE DECLINE OF LAISSEZ FAIRE 1897-1917, at 177-78 (1951)
    • See, e.g., 7 HAROLD U. FAULKNER, THE ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES: THE DECLINE OF LAISSEZ FAIRE 1897-1917, at 177-78 (1951)
  • 3
    • 44649126839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing popular magazine articles attacking trusts from 1902 to 1907); ROBERT HIGGS, CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN: CRITICAL EPISODES IN THE GROWTH OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT 111 (1987) (discussing the political impact of muckraking journalism).
    • (describing popular magazine articles attacking trusts from 1902 to 1907); ROBERT HIGGS, CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN: CRITICAL EPISODES IN THE GROWTH OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT 111 (1987) (discussing the political impact of muckraking journalism).
  • 4
    • 0000789518 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Policy After Chicago, 84
    • For the Chicago School perspective on antitrust, see generally
    • For the Chicago School perspective on antitrust, see generally Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Policy After Chicago, 84 MICH. L. REV. 213, 215-16 (1985)
    • (1985) MICH. L. REV , vol.213 , pp. 215-216
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 5
    • 44649119360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Antitrust Policy]; Herbert Hovenkamp, Post-Chicago Antitrust: A Review and Critique, 2001 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 257, 266-67;
    • [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Antitrust Policy]; Herbert Hovenkamp, Post-Chicago Antitrust: A Review and Critique, 2001 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 257, 266-67;
  • 6
    • 44649202216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John E. Kwoka, Jr. & Lawrence J. White, Introduction to THE ANTITRUST REVOLUTION: ECONOMICS, COMPETITION, AND POLICY 1, 1-4 (John E. Kwoka, Jr. & Lawrence J. White eds., 4th ed. 2004);
    • John E. Kwoka, Jr. & Lawrence J. White, Introduction to THE ANTITRUST REVOLUTION: ECONOMICS, COMPETITION, AND POLICY 1, 1-4 (John E. Kwoka, Jr. & Lawrence J. White eds., 4th ed. 2004);
  • 7
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127
    • and Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925, 925-28 (1979).
    • (1979) U. PA. L. REV , vol.925 , pp. 925-928
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 8
    • 44649130156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally WILLIAM E. AKIN, TECHNOCRACY AND THE AMERICAN DREAM: THE TECHNOCRAT MOVEMENT, 1900-1941, at ix-xi (1977) (summarizing the rise and fall of the technocratic movement).
    • See generally WILLIAM E. AKIN, TECHNOCRACY AND THE AMERICAN DREAM: THE TECHNOCRAT MOVEMENT, 1900-1941, at ix-xi (1977) (summarizing the rise and fall of the technocratic movement).
  • 9
    • 44649102066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1
    • Id. at 1.
  • 10
    • 44649115906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 3
    • Id. at 3.
  • 11
    • 44649171689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at x. In his influential book arguing for technocratic- administrative approaches, James Landis argued that laissez-faire solutions had already come to an end.
    • Id. at x. In his influential book arguing for technocratic- administrative approaches, James Landis argued that laissez-faire solutions had already come to an end.
  • 12
    • 44649162591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JAMES M. LANDIS, THE ADMINISTRATIVE PROCESS 8 (1938) ([A]s the demands for positive solutions increased and, in the form of legislative measures, were precipitated upon the cathodes of governmental activity, laissez faire-the simple belief that only good could come by giving economic forces free play-came to an end.).
    • See JAMES M. LANDIS, THE ADMINISTRATIVE PROCESS 8 (1938) ("[A]s the demands for positive solutions increased and, in the form of legislative measures, were precipitated upon the cathodes of governmental activity, laissez faire-the simple belief that only good could come by giving economic forces free play-came to an end.").
  • 13
    • 44649109690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AKIN, supra note 4, at xi
    • AKIN, supra note 4, at xi.
  • 14
    • 0035491288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Americans with Disabilities Act as Risk Regulation, 101
    • Samuel R. Bagenstos, The Americans with Disabilities Act as Risk Regulation, 101 COLUM. L. REV. 1479, 1482 (2001).
    • (2001) COLUM. L. REV , vol.1479 , pp. 1482
    • Bagenstos, S.R.1
  • 15
    • 44649121573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890, codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 2000 & Supp. V 2005
    • Ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (2000 & Supp. V 2005)).
  • 16
    • 44649138705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ch. 311, 38 Stat. 717 (1914, codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 41-58 2000 & Supp. V 2005
    • Ch. 311, 38 Stat. 717 (1914) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 41-58 (2000 & Supp. V 2005)).
  • 17
    • 44649132718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27 (2000 & Supp. V 2005), 29 U.S.C. §§ 52-53 (2000 & Supp. II 2002)).
    • Ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (current version at 15 U.S.C. §§ 12-27 (2000 & Supp. V 2005), 29 U.S.C. §§ 52-53 (2000 & Supp. II 2002)).
  • 18
    • 44649132072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MARTIN J. SKLAR, THE CORPORATE RECONSTRUCTION OF AMERICAN CAPITALISM, 1890-1916: THE MARKET, THE LAW, AND POLITICS 357, 352-57 (1988) (It was, in Roosevelt's mind, the progressive response to modern industrial conditions that, by implementing reforms that populists and socialists may have initiated or advocated, sustained continuing material progress within a framework of a market society, private property, and the American democratic tradition.).
    • See MARTIN J. SKLAR, THE CORPORATE RECONSTRUCTION OF AMERICAN CAPITALISM, 1890-1916: THE MARKET, THE LAW, AND POLITICS 357, 352-57 (1988) ("It was, in Roosevelt's mind, the progressive response to modern industrial conditions that, by implementing reforms that populists and socialists may have initiated or advocated, sustained continuing material progress within a framework of a market society, private property, and the American democratic tradition.").
  • 19
    • 44649174474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 367 (describing President Taft's subsequent divergence from Roosevelt's ideas regarding the government's role in controlling the private sector and that Taft ultimately reverted to judicial supremacy in the regulation of corporations, or the private sector, in administering the market, subject to a secondary policing by the government, a policy break made overt after the Supreme Court's Rule of Reason decisions in May 1911).
    • See id. at 367 (describing President Taft's subsequent divergence from Roosevelt's ideas regarding the government's role in controlling the private sector and that Taft "ultimately reverted to judicial supremacy in the regulation of corporations, or the private sector, in administering the market, subject to a secondary policing by the government," a policy break made overt after the "Supreme Court's Rule of Reason decisions in May 1911").
  • 20
    • 44649197883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 425
    • Id. at 425.
  • 21
    • 44649083231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 1, at 188
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 1, at 188.
  • 22
    • 44649094668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 189 (noting that historians dropped the subject of antitrust at or around 1938 . . . because there is no longer an antitrust movement and they ignored antitrust for the same reason the public ignores it: it has become complex, difficult, and boring).
    • See id. at 189 (noting that historians dropped the subject of antitrust "at or around 1938 . . . because there is no longer an antitrust movement" and they ignored antitrust "for the same reason the public ignores it: it has become complex, difficult, and boring").
  • 23
    • 44649103382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 218-25
    • Id. at 218-25.
  • 24
    • 44649132073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 194
    • Id. at 194.
  • 25
    • 44649109689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 235
    • Id. at 235.
  • 26
    • 44649108397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 230-32. Arnold took over the reins of the Antitrust Division from Robert Jackson in March 1938. SPENCER WEBER WALLER, THURMAN ARNOLD: A BIOGRAPHY 83 (2005).
    • Id. at 230-32. Arnold took over the reins of the Antitrust Division from Robert Jackson in March 1938. SPENCER WEBER WALLER, THURMAN ARNOLD: A BIOGRAPHY 83 (2005).
  • 27
    • 44649151821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THURMAN W. ARNOLD, THE FOLKLORE OF CAPITALISM 207-29 (Beard Books 2000) (1937); see also WALLER, supra note 21, at 69 (Arnold . . . ridiculed the antitrust laws as empty symbolic vehicles designed to assuage popular fears of bigness and power without actually constraining the behavior of the modern business corporation.).
    • THURMAN W. ARNOLD, THE FOLKLORE OF CAPITALISM 207-29 (Beard Books 2000) (1937); see also WALLER, supra note 21, at 69 ("Arnold . . . ridiculed the antitrust laws as empty symbolic vehicles designed to assuage popular fears of bigness and power without actually constraining the behavior of the modern business corporation.").
  • 28
    • 44649161076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 1, at 230-32. See generally Spencer Weber Waller, The Antitrust Legacy of Thurman Arnold, 78 ST. JOHN'S L. REV. 569 (2004) (discussing Arnold's impact on antitrust). For a contrary view on the political nature of some of Arnold's enforcement actions, see Daniel A. Crane, The Story of United States v. Socony-Vacuum: Hot Oil and Antitrust in the Two New Deals, in ANTITRUST STORIES 91, 117-18 (Eleanor M. Fox & Daniel A. Crane eds., 2007) (discussing the Roosevelt Administration's opposition to Arnold's aggressive antitrust-enforcement policy post-Socony).
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 1, at 230-32. See generally Spencer Weber Waller, The Antitrust Legacy of Thurman Arnold, 78 ST. JOHN'S L. REV. 569 (2004) (discussing Arnold's impact on antitrust). For a contrary view on the political nature of some of Arnold's enforcement actions, see Daniel A. Crane, The Story of United States v. Socony-Vacuum: Hot Oil and Antitrust in the Two New Deals, in ANTITRUST STORIES 91, 117-18 (Eleanor M. Fox & Daniel A. Crane eds., 2007) (discussing the Roosevelt Administration's opposition to Arnold's aggressive antitrust-enforcement policy post-Socony).
  • 29
    • 44649151238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 94-435, 90 Stat. 1383 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15, 18, 28 U.S.C).
    • Pub. L. No. 94-435, 90 Stat. 1383 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15, 18, 28 U.S.C).
  • 30
    • 44149109925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Antifederalism, 96
    • Daniel A. Crane, Antitrust Antifederalism, 96 CAL. L. REV. 1, 50-51 (2008).
    • (2008) CAL. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 50-51
    • Crane, D.A.1
  • 31
    • 44649182235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Posner, supra note 3, at 925-28 describing pre-Chicago School interventionist views
    • See Posner, supra note 3, at 925-28 (describing pre-Chicago School interventionist views).
  • 32
    • 44649086265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Bruce Abramson, Intellectual Property and the Alleged Collapsing of Aftermarkets, 38 RUTGERS L.J. 399, 407 (2007) (asserting that Ronald Reagan ended what was, by general consensus, the most oppressive era of American antitrust enforcement when he arrived in Washington intent upon unshackling America's markets, followed soon thereafter by policy makers and courts shifting their views favorably toward Chicago School economics).
    • See, e.g., Bruce Abramson, Intellectual Property and the Alleged Collapsing of Aftermarkets, 38 RUTGERS L.J. 399, 407 (2007) (asserting that Ronald Reagan ended what was, "by general consensus, the most oppressive era of American antitrust enforcement" when he "arrived in Washington intent upon unshackling America's markets," followed soon thereafter by policy makers and courts shifting their views favorably toward Chicago School economics).
  • 33
    • 33745031620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Jonathan B. Baker, Competition Policy as a Political Bargain, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 483, 483 (2006) (commenting on the decline in the political salience of competition policy over the 20th century and observing that modern Presidential candidates rarely mention the antitrust laws).
    • See, e.g., Jonathan B. Baker, Competition Policy as a Political Bargain, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 483, 483 (2006) (commenting on the "decline in the political salience of competition policy over the 20th century" and observing that "modern Presidential candidates rarely mention the antitrust laws").
  • 34
    • 44649092498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally note 13, at, providing a history of the relevant period
    • See generally SKLAR, supra note 13, at 1-40 (providing a history of the relevant period).
    • supra , pp. 1-40
    • SKLAR1
  • 35
    • 0242676918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Previous studies have concluded that Congress exercises comparatively little control over the antitrust agencies. See Evan J. Ringquist, Jeff Worsham & Marc Allen Eisner, Salience, Complexity, and the Legislative Direction of Regulatory Bureaucracies, 13 J. PUB. ADMIN. RES. &THEORY 141, 149 (2003, characterizing antitrust enforcement as a low-salience and high-complexity enterprise over which Congress exercises comparatively little oversight);
    • Previous studies have concluded that Congress exercises comparatively little control over the antitrust agencies. See Evan J. Ringquist, Jeff Worsham & Marc Allen Eisner, Salience, Complexity, and the Legislative Direction of Regulatory Bureaucracies, 13 J. PUB. ADMIN. RES. &THEORY 141, 149 (2003) (characterizing antitrust enforcement as a low-salience and high-complexity enterprise over which Congress exercises comparatively little oversight);
  • 36
    • 44649145052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M. Albert Vachris, Federal Antitrust Enforcement: A Principal-Agent Perspective, 88 PUB. CHOICE 223, 236 (1996) ([W]hile congressional oversight does play a role in the determination of bureaucratic behavior, the Congress does not, in effect, dominate the [antitrust] bureaucracy.). Congress has not made a major legislative intervention in antitrust in over thirty years. For the first eighty-five years of American antitrust history, Congress intervened about once every generation-roughly once every twenty years-injecting significant legislative direction into the antitrust enterprise: 1890 (Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890)); 1914
    • M. Albert Vachris, Federal Antitrust Enforcement: A Principal-Agent Perspective, 88 PUB. CHOICE 223, 236 (1996) ("[W]hile congressional oversight does play a role in the determination of bureaucratic behavior, the Congress does not, in effect, dominate the [antitrust] bureaucracy."). Congress has not made a major legislative intervention in antitrust in over thirty years. For the first eighty-five years of American antitrust history, Congress intervened about once every generation-roughly once every twenty years-injecting significant legislative direction into the antitrust enterprise: 1890 (Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890)); 1914
  • 37
    • 44649112278 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Federal Trade Commission Act, ch. 311, 38 Stat. 717 (1914) and Clayton Act, ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730 (1914)); 1933-1937 (National Industrial Recovery Act, ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195 (1933), invalidated by A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935); Robinson-Patman Act, ch. 592, 49 Stat. 1526 (1936); and Miller-Tydings Act, ch. 690, tit. 8, 50 Stat. 673, 693 (1937) (repealed 1975)); 1950 (Celler-Kefauver Act, ch. 1184, 64 Stat. 1125 (1950)); 1975-1976 (Consumer Goods Pricing Act of 1975, Pub. L. No. 94- 145, 89 Stat. 801 and Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, Pub. L. No. 94-435, 90 Stat. 1383). Congressional interventions since 1976 have been relatively narrower and more issue specific and technical.
    • (Federal Trade Commission Act, ch. 311, 38 Stat. 717 (1914) and Clayton Act, ch. 323, 38 Stat. 730 (1914)); 1933-1937 (National Industrial Recovery Act, ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195 (1933), invalidated by A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935); Robinson-Patman Act, ch. 592, 49 Stat. 1526 (1936); and Miller-Tydings Act, ch. 690, tit. 8, 50 Stat. 673, 693 (1937) (repealed 1975)); 1950 (Celler-Kefauver Act, ch. 1184, 64 Stat. 1125 (1950)); 1975-1976 (Consumer Goods Pricing Act of 1975, Pub. L. No. 94- 145, 89 Stat. 801 and Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, Pub. L. No. 94-435, 90 Stat. 1383). Congressional interventions since 1976 have been relatively narrower and more issue specific and technical.
  • 38
    • 44649133731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Foreign Trade Antitrust Improvements Act of 1982, Pub. L. No. 97-290, 96 Stat. 1246 (specifying the jurisdictional reach of U.S. antitrust law as to foreign commerce).
    • See, e.g., Foreign Trade Antitrust Improvements Act of 1982, Pub. L. No. 97-290, 96 Stat. 1246 (specifying the jurisdictional reach of U.S. antitrust law as to foreign commerce).
  • 39
    • 44649168057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271 (6th Cir. 1898), aff'd, 175 U.S. 211 (1899).
    • United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271 (6th Cir. 1898), aff'd, 175 U.S. 211 (1899).
  • 40
    • 44649091100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAM HOWARD TAFT, THE ANTI-TRUST ACT AND THE SUPREME COURT (1914). Taft discussed antitrust in his March 4, 1909 inaugural address. President William Howard Taft, Inaugural Address (Mar. 4, 1909), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25830. Taft declared that he hoped to be able to submit at the first regular session of the incoming Congress, in December next, definite suggestions in respect to the needed amendments to the antitrust and the interstate commerce law and the changes required in the executive departments concerned in their enforcement. Id.
    • See WILLIAM HOWARD TAFT, THE ANTI-TRUST ACT AND THE SUPREME COURT (1914). Taft discussed antitrust in his March 4, 1909 inaugural address. President William Howard Taft, Inaugural Address (Mar. 4, 1909), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25830. Taft declared that he hoped "to be able to submit at the first regular session of the incoming Congress, in December next, definite suggestions in respect to the needed amendments to the antitrust and the interstate commerce law and the changes required in the executive departments concerned in their enforcement." Id.
  • 41
    • 44649189642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SKLAR, supra note 13, at 33, 90
    • SKLAR, supra note 13, at 33, 90.
  • 42
    • 44649096779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Jimmy Carter, The State of the Union Address Delivered Before a Joint Session of the Congress (Jan. 23, 1979), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=32 657. President Carter said: We must also fight inflation by improvements and better enforcementof our antitrust laws and by reducing government obstacles to competition in the private sector.
    • President Jimmy Carter, The State of the Union Address Delivered Before a Joint Session of the Congress (Jan. 23, 1979), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=32 657. President Carter said: "We must also fight inflation by improvements and better enforcementof our antitrust laws and by reducing government obstacles to competition in the private sector."
  • 43
    • 44649137195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Between Taft and Carter's last mention in 1979, antitrust appeared in nineteen State of the Union addresses: Wilson (1913); Hoover (1930, 1931, 1932); Roosevelt (1934, 1937, 1938, 1939, 1944, 1945); Truman (1947, 1948, 1949, 1950, 1953); Eisenhower (1961); Kennedy (1962); Ford (1976); and Carter (1978).
    • Id. Between Taft and Carter's last mention in 1979, antitrust appeared in nineteen State of the Union addresses: Wilson (1913); Hoover (1930, 1931, 1932); Roosevelt (1934, 1937, 1938, 1939, 1944, 1945); Truman (1947, 1948, 1949, 1950, 1953); Eisenhower (1961); Kennedy (1962); Ford (1976); and Carter (1978).
  • 44
    • 44649122588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., President Jimmy Carter, The State of the Union Address Delivered Before a Joint Session of the Congress (Jan. 19, 1978), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=30856; President Gerald Ford, Address Before a Joint Session of the Congress Reporting on the State of the Union (Jan. 19, 1976), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=5677
    • See, e.g., President Jimmy Carter, The State of the Union Address Delivered Before a Joint Session of the Congress (Jan. 19, 1978), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=30856; President Gerald Ford, Address Before a Joint Session of the Congress Reporting on the State of the Union (Jan. 19, 1976), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=5677
  • 45
    • 44649174821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter Ford's 1976 State of the Union]; President John F. Kennedy, Annual Message to the Congress on the State of the Union (Jan. 11, 1962), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=9082
    • [hereinafter Ford's 1976 State of the Union]; President John F. Kennedy, Annual Message to the Congress on the State of the Union (Jan. 11, 1962), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=9082
  • 46
    • 44649153623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter Kennedy's 1962 State of the Union]; President Dwight D. Eisenhower, Annual Message to the Congress on the State of the Union (Jan. 12, 1961), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid= 12074
    • [hereinafter Kennedy's 1962 State of the Union]; President Dwight D. Eisenhower, Annual Message to the Congress on the State of the Union (Jan. 12, 1961), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid= 12074
  • 47
    • 44649192877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter Eisenhower's 1961 State of the Union]. Carter's predecessors sounded similar antitrust themes.
    • [hereinafter Eisenhower's 1961 State of the Union]. Carter's predecessors sounded similar antitrust themes.
  • 48
    • 44649202619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ford's 1976 State of the Union, supra ([T]o foster competition and to bring prices down for the consumer[]. .. [t]his administration . . . will strictly enforce the Federal antitrust laws ....);
    • See, e.g., Ford's 1976 State of the Union, supra ("[T]o foster competition and to bring prices down for the consumer[]. .. [t]his administration . . . will strictly enforce the Federal antitrust laws ....");
  • 49
    • 44649127194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kennedy's 1962 State of the Union, supra (This administration has helped keep our economy competitive by widening the access of small business to credit and Government contracts, and by stepping up the drive against monopoly, price-fixing, and racketeering....);
    • Kennedy's 1962 State of the Union, supra ("This administration has helped keep our economy competitive by widening the access of small business to credit and Government contracts, and by stepping up the drive against monopoly, price-fixing, and racketeering....");
  • 50
    • 44649084805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eisenhower's 1961 State of the Union, supra (A major factor in strengthening our competitive enterprise system, and promoting economic growth, has been the vigorous enforcement of antitrust laws over the last eight years and a continuing effort to reduce artificial restraints on competition and trade and enhance our economic liberties.);
    • Eisenhower's 1961 State of the Union, supra ("A major factor in strengthening our competitive enterprise system, and promoting economic growth, has been the vigorous enforcement of antitrust laws over the last eight years and a continuing effort to reduce artificial restraints on competition and trade and enhance our economic liberties.");
  • 51
    • 44649110679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Harry S. Truman, Annual Message to the Congress on the State of the Union (Jan. 6, 1947), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=12762 ([W]e now find that to a greater extent than ever before, whole industries are dominated by one or a few large organizations which can restrict production in the interest of higher profits and thus reduce employment and purchasing power. In an effort to assure full opportunity and free competition to business we will vigorously enforce the anti-trust laws.).
    • President Harry S. Truman, Annual Message to the Congress on the State of the Union (Jan. 6, 1947), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=12762 ("[W]e now find that to a greater extent than ever before, whole industries are dominated by one or a few large organizations which can restrict production in the interest of higher profits and thus reduce employment and purchasing power. In an effort to assure full opportunity and free competition to business we will vigorously enforce the anti-trust laws.").
  • 52
    • 44649119725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, President Clinton mentioned antitrust in speeches or remarks on forty-six occasions, but an illustrative instance is his 1996 remarks welcoming the World Series champion Atlanta Braves, where he remarked: [The Braves] had great hitting, great fielding, and great pitching. Tom Glavine and Greg Maddux have won every Cy Young Award for the past 5 years. You may have an antitrust suit on your hands, even with baseball's exemption. [Laughter]. President William J. Clinton, Remarks Welcoming the World Series Champion Atlanta Braves (Feb. 26, 1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=52463&st=:atlanta+br ave s&stl.
    • For example, President Clinton mentioned antitrust in speeches or remarks on forty-six occasions, but an illustrative instance is his 1996 remarks welcoming the World Series champion Atlanta Braves, where he remarked: "[The Braves] had great hitting, great fielding, and great pitching. Tom Glavine and Greg Maddux have won every Cy Young Award for the past 5 years. You may have an antitrust suit on your hands, even with baseball's exemption. [Laughter]." President William J. Clinton, Remarks Welcoming the World Series Champion Atlanta Braves (Feb. 26, 1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=52463&st=:atlanta+brave s&stl.
  • 53
    • 44649158767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The findings discussed here are based on a search of the electronic archives of presidential speeches and addresses using the search terms antitrust, anti-trust, trusts, and monop. The archives searched were those maintained by the University of California at Santa Barbara. The American Presidency Project
    • The findings discussed here are based on a search of the electronic archives of presidential speeches and addresses using the search terms "antitrust," "anti-trust," "trusts," and "monop." The archives searched were those maintained by the University of California at Santa Barbara. The American Presidency Project, http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu.
  • 54
    • 44649145048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Curt Flood Act of 1998 (Oct. 27, 1998), available at http://www. presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=55156;
    • See, e.g., President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Curt Flood Act of 1998 (Oct. 27, 1998), available at http://www. presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=55156;
  • 55
    • 44649125266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Year 2000 Information and Readiness Disclosure Act (Oct. 19, 1998), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=55108;
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Year 2000 Information and Readiness Disclosure Act (Oct. 19, 1998), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=55108;
  • 56
    • 44649112905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (Feb. 8, 1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=52289;
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (Feb. 8, 1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=52289;
  • 57
    • 44649088113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the ICC Termination Act of 1995 (Dec. 29, 1995), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=52436;
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the ICC Termination Act of 1995 (Dec. 29, 1995), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/index.php?pid=52436;
  • 58
    • 44649104938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the International Antitrust Enforcement Assistance Act of 1994 (Nov. 2, 1994), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=49419;
    • President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the International Antitrust Enforcement Assistance Act of 1994 (Nov. 2, 1994), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=49419;
  • 59
    • 44649190991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President William J. Clinton, Remarks on Signing the National Cooperative Production Amendments of 1993 (June 10, 1993), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=46674.
    • President William J. Clinton, Remarks on Signing the National Cooperative Production Amendments of 1993 (June 10, 1993), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=46674.
  • 60
    • 33847126530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a compilation of political-party platforms, see The American Presidency Project
    • For a compilation of political-party platforms, see The American Presidency Project, Political-Party Platforms, http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ platforms.php.
    • Political-Party Platforms
  • 61
    • 44649091783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 62
    • 44649154282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id
    • See id.
  • 63
    • 44649172944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consistent with the recent Republican Party's general antipathy to antitrust enforcement, the platform promised to change anti-trust laws to let health care providers cooperate in holding down charges. REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 1996 (1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25848.
    • Consistent with the recent Republican Party's general antipathy to antitrust enforcement, the platform promised to "change anti-trust laws to let health care providers cooperate in holding down charges." REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 1996 (1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25848.
  • 64
    • 44649101241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A similar promise appeared in the 1992 platform (to modify outdated antitrust rules that prohibit hospitals from merging their resources to provide improved, cost-effective health care). REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 1992: THE VISION SHARED: THE REPUBLICAN PLATFORM, UNITING OUR FAMILY, OUR COUNTRY, OUR WORLD (1992), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25847.
    • A similar promise appeared in the 1992 platform (to "modify outdated antitrust rules that prohibit hospitals from merging their resources to provide improved, cost-effective health care"). REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 1992: THE VISION SHARED: THE REPUBLICAN PLATFORM, UNITING OUR FAMILY, OUR COUNTRY, OUR WORLD (1992), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25847.
  • 65
    • 44649108146 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 1976 (1976), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25843 (The Republican Party believes in and endorses the concept that the American economy is traditionally dependent upon fair competition in the marketplace. To assure fair competition, antitrust laws must treat all segments of the economy equally.).
    • See REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 1976 (1976), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=25843 ("The Republican Party believes in and endorses the concept that the American economy is traditionally dependent upon fair competition in the marketplace. To assure fair competition, antitrust laws must treat all segments of the economy equally.").
  • 66
    • 44649083570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1984 (1984), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29608.
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1984 (1984), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29608.
  • 67
    • 44649187315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 1988 platform pledged to prevent monopolistic mergers and to reinvigorat[e] the antitrust laws. DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1988 (1988), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/ index.php?pid=29609.
    • The 1988 platform pledged to prevent "monopolistic mergers" and to "reinvigorat[e]" the antitrust laws. DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1988 (1988), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/ index.php?pid=29609.
  • 68
    • 44649106836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 2004 (2004), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29613;
    • See DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 2004 (2004), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29613;
  • 69
    • 44649091099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 2000 (2000), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/? pid=29612;
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 2000 (2000), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/? pid=29612;
  • 70
    • 44649122587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1996: TODAY'S DEMOCRATIC PARTY: MEETING AMERICA'S CHALLENGES, PROTECTING AMERICA'S VALUES (1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29611;
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1996: TODAY'S DEMOCRATIC PARTY: MEETING AMERICA'S CHALLENGES, PROTECTING AMERICA'S VALUES (1996), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29611;
  • 71
    • 44649094387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1992: A NEW COVENANT WITH THE AMERICAN PEOPLE (1992), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29610.
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1992: A NEW COVENANT WITH THE AMERICAN PEOPLE (1992), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29610.
  • 72
    • 44649099385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 2004: A SAFER WORLD AND A MORE HOPEFUL AMERICA (2004), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=25850;
    • See REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 2004: A SAFER WORLD AND A MORE HOPEFUL AMERICA (2004), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=25850;
  • 73
    • 44649101242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 2000 (2000), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=25849.
    • REPUBLICAN NAT'L COMM., REPUBLICAN PARTY PLATFORM OF 2000 (2000), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=25849.
  • 74
    • 44649163078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000), aff'd in part, rev'd in part, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000), aff'd in part, rev'd in part, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
  • 75
    • 44649143035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Edward Cavanagh, Antitrust Remedies Revisited, 84 OR. L. REV. 147, 192 (2005) (Media coverage of the [Microsoft] trial was unprecedented in scope, and as the Microsoft story migrated from the business pages to the front pages of daily newspapers and to lead story on the evening news, even antitrust junkies began to feel like overdose victims.).
    • See Edward Cavanagh, Antitrust Remedies Revisited, 84 OR. L. REV. 147, 192 (2005) ("Media coverage of the [Microsoft] trial was unprecedented in scope, and as the Microsoft story migrated from the business pages to the front pages of daily newspapers and to lead story on the evening news, even antitrust junkies began to feel like overdose victims.").
  • 76
    • 0346617019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fred S. McChesney, Economics Versus Politics in Antitrust, 23 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 133, 134 (1999) (describing the various political efforts made to influence the Microsoft litigation).
    • See Fred S. McChesney, Economics Versus Politics in Antitrust, 23 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 133, 134 (1999) (describing the various political efforts made to influence the Microsoft litigation).
  • 77
    • 44649104319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 78
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 66-71 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 66-71 and accompanying text.
    • See infra
  • 79
    • 44649106834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To describe antitrust as an increasingly nonpolitical enterprise is not to deny that even technocratic forms of antitrust administration are political in some sense of the word. See Richard O. Lempert, Civil Juries and Complex Cases: Let's Not Rush to Judgment, 80 MICH. L. REV. 68, 84 1981, C]omplex cases-such as large-scale antitrust litigation-are some of the most 'political' cases that the system hears. Vast sums of money are involved, and the structure of the nation'slargest companies may be at issue, But antitrust is increasingly nonpolitical in the sense that it has ceased being a subject of partisan political discourse or control by the democratically elected branches
    • To describe antitrust as an increasingly nonpolitical enterprise is not to deny that even technocratic forms of antitrust administration are "political" in some sense of the word. See Richard O. Lempert, Civil Juries and Complex Cases: Let's Not Rush to Judgment, 80 MICH. L. REV. 68, 84 (1981) ("[C]omplex cases-such as large-scale antitrust litigation-are some of the most 'political' cases that the system hears. Vast sums of money are involved, and the structure of the nation'slargest companies may be at issue."). But antitrust is increasingly "nonpolitical" in the sense that it has ceased being a subject of partisan political discourse or control by the democratically elected branches.
  • 80
    • 44649144444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard Oil Co. of N.J. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911).
    • Standard Oil Co. of N.J. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911).
  • 81
    • 44649133090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982), aff'd sub nom.
    • United States v. AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982), aff'd sub nom.
  • 83
    • 44649149437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Standard Oil, 221 U.S. 1 (involving the oil industry);
    • See generally Standard Oil, 221 U.S. 1 (involving the oil industry);
  • 84
    • 44649177469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000) (involving the personal-computer industry), aff'd in part, rev'd in part, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001);
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000) (involving the personal-computer industry), aff'd in part, rev'd in part, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001);
  • 85
    • 44649119087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131 (involving the telecommunications industry).
    • AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131 (involving the telecommunications industry).
  • 86
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 29 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 29 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 87
    • 44649134406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner, supra note 3, at 926-33
    • Posner, supra note 3, at 926-33.
  • 89
    • 0742288973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 47 (D.C. Cir. 2001). The origins of the case date back to an earlier FTC investigation of Microsoft during the first Bush Administration and a 1995 consent decree during Bill Clinton's first term. William E. Kovacic, The Modern Evolution of U.S. Competition Policy Enforcement Norms, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 377, 453 n.275 (2003).
    • See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 47 (D.C. Cir. 2001). The origins of the case date back to an earlier FTC investigation of Microsoft during the first Bush Administration and a 1995 consent decree during Bill Clinton's first term. William E. Kovacic, The Modern Evolution of U.S. Competition Policy Enforcement Norms, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 377, 453 n.275 (2003).
  • 91
    • 44649112277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter Roosevelt's 1906 Special Message]. Roosevelt made additional public speeches singling out Standard Oil as the most dangerous members of the criminal class-the criminals of great wealth. EDMUND MORRIS, THEODORE REX 507 (2001). Although Roosevelt strongly approved of the Government's action against Standard Oil, after he left office he wrote privately that he disfavored the dissolution remedy sought by the Government and eventually affirmed by the Supreme Court.
    • [hereinafter Roosevelt's 1906 Special Message]. Roosevelt made additional public speeches singling out Standard Oil as "the most dangerous members of the criminal class-the criminals of great wealth." EDMUND MORRIS, THEODORE REX 507 (2001). Although Roosevelt strongly approved of the Government's action against Standard Oil, after he left office he wrote privately that he disfavored the dissolution remedy sought by the Government and eventually affirmed by the Supreme Court.
  • 92
    • 44649139684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Letter from Theodore Roosevelt to Arthur B. Farquhar (Aug. 11, 1911), in THEODORE ROOSEVELT: LETTERS AND SPEECHES 652, 652 (Louis Auchincloss ed., 1951) (I do not myself see what good can come from dissolving the Standard Oil Company into forty separate companies, all of which will still remain really under the same control. What we should have is a much stricter governmental supervision of these great companies . . . .).
    • See Letter from Theodore Roosevelt to Arthur B. Farquhar (Aug. 11, 1911), in THEODORE ROOSEVELT: LETTERS AND SPEECHES 652, 652 (Louis Auchincloss ed., 1951) ("I do not myself see what good can come from dissolving the Standard Oil Company into forty separate companies, all of which will still remain really under the same control. What we should have is a much stricter governmental supervision of these great companies . . . .").
  • 93
    • 44649185454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Roosevelt's 1906 Special Message, supra note 59.
    • Roosevelt's 1906 Special Message, supra note 59.
  • 94
    • 44649174820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., President Theodore Roosevelt, Special Message to the Senate and House of Representatives (Jan. 31, 1908), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=69649 (The Standard Oil Corporation and the railway company have both been found guilty by the courts of criminal misconduct; . . . each has issued and published . . . statements, asserting their innocence and denouncing as improper the action of the courts and juries in convicting them of guilt. These statements are very elaborate, are very ingenious, and are untruthful in important particulars.);
    • See, e.g., President Theodore Roosevelt, Special Message to the Senate and House of Representatives (Jan. 31, 1908), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=69649 ("The Standard Oil Corporation and the railway company have both been found guilty by the courts of criminal misconduct; . . . each has issued and published . . . statements, asserting their innocence and denouncing as improper the action of the courts and juries in convicting them of guilt. These statements are very elaborate, are very ingenious, and are untruthful in important particulars.");
  • 95
    • 44649196347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • President Theodore Roosevelt, Sixth Annual Message (Dec. 3, 1906), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29547 (Rebates, for instance, are ... often due to the pressure of big shippers[, ]as was shown in the investigation of the Standard Oil Company . . ..).
    • President Theodore Roosevelt, Sixth Annual Message (Dec. 3, 1906), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/?pid=29547 ("Rebates, for instance, are ... often due to the pressure of big shippers[, ]as was shown in the investigation of the Standard Oil Company . . ..").
  • 96
    • 44649174818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1912 (1912), available a/http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29590.
    • DEMOCRATIC NAT'L COMM., DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLATFORM OF 1912 (1912), available a/http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=29590.
  • 97
    • 44649116956 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Press Conference with President Franklin D. Roosevelt (Apr. 27, 1937), excerpt available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index. php?pid= 15397.
    • See Press Conference with President Franklin D. Roosevelt (Apr. 27, 1937), excerpt available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index. php?pid= 15397.
  • 98
    • 44649146328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Marcellus S. Snow, The AT&T Divestiture: A 10-Year Retrospective, in BEYOND COMPETITION: THE FUTURE OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS 207 (Donald M. Lamberton ed., 1995) (discussing the historic breakup and evaluating the costs and benefits ten years later).
    • See Marcellus S. Snow, The AT&T Divestiture: A 10-Year Retrospective, in BEYOND COMPETITION: THE FUTURE OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS 207 (Donald M. Lamberton ed., 1995) (discussing the historic breakup and evaluating the costs and benefits ten years later).
  • 100
    • 44649127832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 47 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
    • United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 47 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
  • 101
    • 44649187316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interview by Ron Insana with President William J. Clinton, in New York City, N.Y, Jan. 13, 2000, available at
    • Interview by Ron Insana with President William J. Clinton, in New York City, N.Y. (Jan. 13, 2000), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ ws/?pid=58387.
  • 102
    • 44649183194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interview by Wolf Blitzer with President William J. Clinton Feb. 14, 2000, available at
    • Interview by Wolf Blitzer with President William J. Clinton (Feb. 14, 2000), available at http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid= 58086.
  • 103
    • 44649128406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See John M. Broder, Microsoft Tries Another Court: Public Opinion, N.Y. TIMES, June 12, 2000, at Al (A Gallup poll taken in early May showed that 65% of the public had a favorable view of the company. The figure among computer users was even higher, 72%.).
    • See John M. Broder, Microsoft Tries Another Court: Public Opinion, N.Y. TIMES, June 12, 2000, at Al ("A Gallup poll taken in early May showed that 65% of the public had a favorable view of the company. The figure among computer users was even higher, 72%.").
  • 104
    • 44649196981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • quoting Vice President Gore
    • Id. (quoting Vice President Gore).
  • 105
    • 44649115022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 106
    • 44649111062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., David A. Balto, Antitrust Enforcement in the Clinton Administration, 9 CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 61, 62-63 (1999) (discussing the Reagan Administration's view of antitrust enforcement as overly intrusive and the Administration's substantial reduction of antitrust enforcement);
    • See, e.g., David A. Balto, Antitrust Enforcement in the Clinton Administration, 9 CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 61, 62-63 (1999) (discussing the Reagan Administration's view of antitrust enforcement as overly intrusive and the Administration's substantial reduction of antitrust enforcement);
  • 107
    • 44649089205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Half-Time at the Antitrust Modernization Commission, 40
    • describing antitrust enforcement during the Reagan Administration as being in severe retrenchment
    • Albert A. Foer, Half-Time at the Antitrust Modernization Commission, 40 U.S.F. L. REV. 601, 617 (2006) (describing antitrust enforcement during the Reagan Administration as being in "severe retrenchment");
    • (2006) U.S.F. L. REV , vol.601 , pp. 617
    • Foer, A.A.1
  • 108
    • 44649186704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Daniel Goldberg, Cornering the Market in a Post-9/11 World: The Future of Horizontal Restraints, 36 J. MARSHALL L. REV 557, 577 (2003) (asserting that antitrust enforcement approached dormancy during the 1980s);
    • Daniel Goldberg, Cornering the Market in a Post-9/11 World: The Future of Horizontal Restraints, 36 J. MARSHALL L. REV 557, 577 (2003) (asserting that antitrust enforcement approached dormancy during the 1980s);
  • 109
    • 44649097413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gregory J. Maier & Robert C. Mattson, State Street Bank in the Context of the Software Patent Saga, 8 GEO. MASON L. REV. 307, 321 1999, The Reagan Administration ended the era of antitrust ascendancy
    • Gregory J. Maier & Robert C. Mattson, State Street Bank in the Context of the Software Patent Saga, 8 GEO. MASON L. REV. 307, 321 (1999) ("The Reagan Administration ended the era of antitrust ascendancy.. . .");
  • 110
    • 44649166195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maurice E. Stucke, Behavioral Economists at the Gate: Antitrust in the Twenty-first Century, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 513, 540 (2007) (describing how the Chicago School's influence on the Reagan Administration resulted in the waning of civil nonmerger antitrust enforcement);
    • Maurice E. Stucke, Behavioral Economists at the Gate: Antitrust in the Twenty-first Century, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 513, 540 (2007) (describing how the Chicago School's influence on the Reagan Administration resulted in the "waning" of civil nonmerger antitrust enforcement);
  • 111
    • 44649154883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yane Svetiev, Antitrust Governance: The New Wave of Antitrust, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 593, 605-06, 605 n.33 (2007) (describing the Reagan Administration as a period of nonenforcement of antitrust law). Further sources calling the Reagan Administration a period of virtual nonenforcement are collected in Kovacic, supra note 58, at 381-86.
    • Yane Svetiev, Antitrust Governance: The New Wave of Antitrust, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 593, 605-06, 605 n.33 (2007) (describing the Reagan Administration as a period of nonenforcement of antitrust law). Further sources calling the Reagan Administration a period of virtual nonenforcement are collected in Kovacic, supra note 58, at 381-86.
  • 112
    • 0033842235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There have been various empirical studies of the Antitrust Division's case filings over the years. See, e.g., Joseph C. Gallo et al., Department of Justice Antitrust Enforcement 1955-1997: An Empirical Study, 17 REV. INDUS. ORG. 75, 90-91 (2000);
    • There have been various empirical studies of the Antitrust Division's case filings over the years. See, e.g., Joseph C. Gallo et al., Department of Justice Antitrust Enforcement 1955-1997: An Empirical Study, 17 REV. INDUS. ORG. 75, 90-91 (2000);
  • 113
    • 44649191594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard A. Posner, A Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement, 13 J.L. & ECON. 365 (1970), reprinted in THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF ANTITRUST: THE PUBLIC-CHOICE PERSPECTIVE 73 (Fred S. McChesney & William F. Shughart II eds., 1995). Bill Kovacic's comprehensive survey of government antitrust enforcement from the 1960s through the early 2000s presents a more qualitative approach. See Kovacic, supra note 58, at 383-91.
    • Richard A. Posner, A Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement, 13 J.L. & ECON. 365 (1970), reprinted in THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF ANTITRUST: THE PUBLIC-CHOICE PERSPECTIVE 73 (Fred S. McChesney & William F. Shughart II eds., 1995). Bill Kovacic's comprehensive survey of government antitrust enforcement from the 1960s through the early 2000s presents a more qualitative approach. See Kovacic, supra note 58, at 383-91.
  • 114
    • 44649168056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BUREAU OF ECON. ANALYSIS, CURRENT-DOLLAR AND REAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (2008), http://www.bea.gov/national/xls/ gdplev.xls (estimating, in chained dollars, the 1940 real gross domestic product at $1,034 billion and the 2000 real gross domestic product at $9,817 billion).
    • See BUREAU OF ECON. ANALYSIS, CURRENT-DOLLAR AND "REAL" GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (2008), http://www.bea.gov/national/xls/ gdplev.xls (estimating, in chained dollars, the 1940 real gross domestic product at $1,034 billion and the 2000 real gross domestic product at $9,817 billion).
  • 115
    • 44649193688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The underlying data are pooled from two sources. For 1938-2006, the data were provided to the author by the Department of Justice Antitrust Division. For earlier years, the data were drawn from Posner, supra note 73, at 82 tbl.5.5. Posner's data were compiled from the Commerce Clearing House (CCH).
    • The underlying data are pooled from two sources. For 1938-2006, the data were provided to the author by the Department of Justice Antitrust Division. For earlier years, the data were drawn from Posner, supra note 73, at 82 tbl.5.5. Posner's data were compiled from the Commerce Clearing House (CCH).
  • 116
    • 44649168663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 73
    • Id. at 73.
  • 117
    • 44649106198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the years in which there was overlap between Posner's CCH data and the data provided by the Department of Justice, there were slight but relatively insignificant differences. The real GDP numbers are chained 2000 dollars. Numbers from 1929 forward are collected from BUREAU OF ECON. ANALYSIS, supra note 74. Pre-1929 numbers are collected from Louis D. Johnston & Samuel H. Williamson, What Was the U.S. GDP Then? (2007), http://eh.net/hmit/gdp. An asterisk appears next to the 2005-2006 period because that period is weighted to reflect a two-year, rather than a five-year, period.
    • For the years in which there was overlap between Posner's CCH data and the data provided by the Department of Justice, there were slight but relatively insignificant differences. The real GDP numbers are chained 2000 dollars. Numbers from 1929 forward are collected from BUREAU OF ECON. ANALYSIS, supra note 74. Pre-1929 numbers are collected from Louis D. Johnston & Samuel H. Williamson, What Was the U.S. GDP Then? (2007), http://eh.net/hmit/gdp. An asterisk appears next to the 2005-2006 period because that period is weighted to reflect a two-year, rather than a five-year, period.
  • 118
    • 44649123204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crane, supra note 23, at 101, 101-03, 108 (discussing the dramatic shift in the role and activity of the Antitrust Division that was caused by Robert Jackson and Thurman Arnold, two New Deal giants who would place enduring stamps on the Antitrust Division).
    • See Crane, supra note 23, at 101, 101-03, 108 (discussing the dramatic shift in the role and activity of the Antitrust Division that was caused by "Robert Jackson and Thurman Arnold, two New Deal giants who would place enduring stamps on the Antitrust Division").
  • 119
    • 44649143036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What is interesting about the data from the Reagan years is that the total number of filed cases remained in line with the filings from the previous four or five administrations but the ratio of criminal to civil cases swung dramatically in favor of criminal cases, which is in line with the fact that the Reagan Administration prosecuted cartel cases far more vigorously than mergers and other civil matters
    • What is interesting about the data from the Reagan years is that the total number of filed cases remained in line with the filings from the previous four or five administrations but the ratio of criminal to civil cases swung dramatically in favor of criminal cases, which is in line with the fact that the Reagan Administration prosecuted cartel cases far more vigorously than mergers and other civil matters.
  • 120
    • 44649175547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kovacic, supra note 58, at 417, 416-20 (explaining that while the achievements of the Department of Justice (DOJ) in criminal enforcement in the 1990s were certainly noteworthy, credit must be given to the DOJ's efforts in 1970s and 1980s because of a vital phenomenon in competition policy-that progress toward a given level of enforcement occurs (and, sometimes, can best be pursued) incrementally rather than in a single leap). Some commentators have disparaged the Reagan Administration's criminal enforcement of antitrust violations.
    • See Kovacic, supra note 58, at 417, 416-20 (explaining that while the achievements of the Department of Justice (DOJ) in criminal enforcement in the 1990s were certainly "noteworthy," credit must be given to the DOJ's efforts in 1970s and 1980s because of a "vital phenomenon in competition policy-that progress toward a given level of enforcement occurs (and, sometimes, can best be pursued) incrementally rather than in a single leap"). Some commentators have disparaged the Reagan Administration's criminal enforcement of antitrust violations.
  • 121
    • 44649086263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 416 ([T]he pendulum narrative views the Reagan criminal antitrust program as commercially unimportant [and] a pedestrian exercise in bringing the same comparatively trivial case repeatedly.). Yet, Kovacic shows that the Reagan Administration's criminal enforcement against bid rigging in the public contracting and major-infrastructure sectors was important and effective. Id. at 417.
    • See id. at 416 ("[T]he pendulum narrative views the Reagan criminal antitrust program as commercially unimportant [and] a pedestrian exercise in bringing the same comparatively trivial case repeatedly."). Yet, Kovacic shows that the Reagan Administration's criminal enforcement against bid rigging in the public contracting and major-infrastructure sectors was important and effective. Id. at 417.
  • 122
    • 44649122586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The gap between antitrust enforcement and economic growth does not necessarily signal a failure of antitrust because it is possible that the growth areas of the New Economy require less policing than traditional smokestack industries. Arguably, however, New Economy industries-which are characterized by low marginal costs, tremendous scale economies, and network effects-require more, not less, policing. See Daniel L. Rubinfeld & John Hoven, Innovation and Antitrust Enforcement, in DYNAMIC COMPETITION AND PUBLIC POLICY: TECHNOLOGY, INNOVATION, AND ANTITRUST ISSUES 65, 79 Jerry Ellig ed, 2001, describing anticompetitive tendencies in innovation-intensive markets
    • The gap between antitrust enforcement and economic growth does not necessarily signal a failure of antitrust because it is possible that the growth areas of the New Economy require less policing than traditional smokestack industries. Arguably, however, New Economy industries-which are characterized by low marginal costs, tremendous scale economies, and network effects-require more, not less, policing. See Daniel L. Rubinfeld & John Hoven, Innovation and Antitrust Enforcement, in DYNAMIC COMPETITION AND PUBLIC POLICY: TECHNOLOGY, INNOVATION, AND ANTITRUST ISSUES 65, 79 (Jerry Ellig ed., 2001) (describing anticompetitive tendencies in innovation-intensive markets).
  • 123
    • 44649196348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BUREAU OF ECON. ANALYSIS, supra note 74; Posner, supra note 73, at 82 tbl.5.5.
    • See BUREAU OF ECON. ANALYSIS, supra note 74; Posner, supra note 73, at 82 tbl.5.5.
  • 124
    • 44649091784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kovacic, supra note 58, at 407, 407-08 (explaining some limitations with a raw count[] of cases approach to measuring federal antitrust enforcement).
    • See Kovacic, supra note 58, at 407, 407-08 (explaining some limitations with a "raw count[] of cases" approach to measuring federal antitrust enforcement).
  • 125
    • 44649168662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although comparing both the Antitrust Division's and the FTC's budgets and antitrust-enforcement activities to GDP would provide a fuller analysis, the FTC did not begin separately reporting its antitrust budget until the 1950s, and its data on antitrust-case filings go back only to 1978. Accordingly, I have used Justice Department statistics as the most reliable historical proxy for the level of federal antitrust enforcement. See ANTITRUST DIV, U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, APPROPRIATION FIGURES FOR THE ANTITRUST DIVISION FISCAL YEARS 1903-2008 2007
    • Although comparing both the Antitrust Division's and the FTC's budgets and antitrust-enforcement activities to GDP would provide a fuller analysis, the FTC did not begin separately reporting its antitrust budget until the 1950s, and its data on antitrust-case filings go back only to 1978. Accordingly, I have used Justice Department statistics as the most reliable historical proxy for the level of federal antitrust enforcement. See ANTITRUST DIV., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, APPROPRIATION FIGURES FOR THE ANTITRUST DIVISION FISCAL YEARS 1903-2008 (2007), http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/10804a.htm.
  • 126
    • 0347599173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, Federalism in Antitrust, 26 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 877, 891 (2003) (At the federal level, the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act pre-merger notification rules provide antitrust authorities with substantial information on the merging companies, which tends to weed out mergers unlikely to cause anticompetitive harm, resulting in fewer merger cases scrutinized by federal authorities reaching litigation.).
    • See Robert W. Hahn & Anne Layne-Farrar, Federalism in Antitrust, 26 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 877, 891 (2003) ("At the federal level, the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act pre-merger notification rules provide antitrust authorities with substantial information on the merging companies, which tends to weed out mergers unlikely to cause anticompetitive harm, resulting in fewer merger cases scrutinized by federal authorities reaching litigation.").
  • 127
    • 44649185453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This includes filing amicus curiae briefs in civil matters and other agencies' cases, negotiating with and giving advice to foreign governments and international organizations, and engaging in industry outreach. See generally Kovacic, supra note 58, at 409 explaining the value of agency advocacy and research
    • This includes filing amicus curiae briefs in civil matters and other agencies' cases, negotiating with and giving advice to foreign governments and international organizations, and engaging in industry outreach. See generally Kovacic, supra note 58, at 409 (explaining the value of agency "advocacy and research").
  • 128
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 87-88 and Figure 4
    • See infra text accompanying notes 87-88 and Figure 4.
    • See infra
  • 129
    • 44649096182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995, 15 U.S.C. § 78u-4 2000, amending the procedures for private securities litigation in the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934 to reduce abusive litigation
    • See Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995, 15 U.S.C. § 78u-4 (2000) (amending the procedures for private securities litigation in the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934 to reduce abusive litigation);
  • 130
    • 44649127193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Securities Litigation Uniform Standards Act (SLUSA) of 1998, Pub. L. No. 105-353, 11 Stat. 3227 codified as amended in scattered sections of 15 U.S.C, amending the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 to limit securities class actions under state law
    • Securities Litigation Uniform Standards Act (SLUSA) of 1998, Pub. L. No. 105-353, 11 Stat. 3227 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15 U.S.C.) (amending the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 to limit securities class actions under state law).
  • 131
    • 33745958413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Outside Director Liability Across Countries, 84
    • noting the financial risks faced by outside directors of public companies after the Enron and WorldCom scandals and analyzing those risks of out-of-pocket payments on a cross-border basis, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Brian R. Cheffins & Bernard S. Black, Outside Director Liability Across Countries, 84 TEXAS L. REV. 1385 (2006) (noting the financial risks faced by outside directors of public companies after the Enron and WorldCom scandals and analyzing those risks of out-of-pocket payments on a cross-border basis);
    • (2006) TEXAS L. REV , vol.1385
    • Cheffins, B.R.1    Black, B.S.2
  • 132
    • 38349018164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Zachary Beasley, Note, A Legislative Solution: Solving the Contemporary Challenge of Forced Waiver of Privilege, 86 TEXAS L. REV. 385 (2007) (explaining the attorney-client relationship and prevalence of privilege waivers in the aftermath of the Enron and WorldCom scandals);
    • Robert Zachary Beasley, Note, A Legislative Solution: Solving the Contemporary Challenge of Forced Waiver of Privilege, 86 TEXAS L. REV. 385 (2007) (explaining the attorney-client relationship and prevalence of privilege waivers in the aftermath of the Enron and WorldCom scandals);
  • 133
    • 44649199734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eric Lichtblau, Bush Officials Vowing to Seek Tough Penalties in Wall St. Cases, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 19, 2002, at Cl (reporting that the Justice Department planned to seek tough penalties for white-collar criminals, including those involved in the Enron and WorldCom scandals).
    • Eric Lichtblau, Bush Officials Vowing to Seek Tough Penalties in Wall St. Cases, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 19, 2002, at Cl (reporting that the Justice Department planned to seek tough penalties for white-collar criminals, including those involved in the Enron and WorldCom scandals).
  • 134
    • 44649135037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The private-enforcement data through 1959 are drawn from Posner, supra note 73, at 79 tbl.5.3. After 1959, they are drawn from the reports of the Administrative Offices of the U.S. Courts.
    • The private-enforcement data through 1959 are drawn from Posner, supra note 73, at 79 tbl.5.3. After 1959, they are drawn from the reports of the Administrative Offices of the U.S. Courts.
  • 135
    • 44649172943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JAMES C. DUFF, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2006 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURTS: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR (2006), available at http:// www.uscourts.gov/judbus2006/completejudicialbusiness.pdf. The annual reports for the years 1997-2006 are available online at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbususc/ judbus.html.
    • See, e.g., JAMES C. DUFF, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2006 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURTS: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR (2006), available at http:// www.uscourts.gov/judbus2006/completejudicialbusiness.pdf. The annual reports for the years 1997-2006 are available online at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbususc/ judbus.html.
  • 136
    • 44649190271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adjustment for real GDP follows the methodology described supra note 75. The 2005-2006 cell is based on a two-year rather than five-year sample, which does not affect the results since they are being shown on a percentage basis.
    • Adjustment for real GDP follows the methodology described supra note 75. The 2005-2006 cell is based on a two-year rather than five-year sample,
  • 137
    • 44649187743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Celler-Kefauver Act of December 29, 1950, 15 U.S.C. §§ 18, 21 (2000). See generally Rudolph J.R. Peritz, Toward a Dynamic Antitrust Analysis of Strategic Market Behavior, 47 N.Y.L. SCH. L. REV. 101, 110 (2003) (describing the Celler-Kefauver Act as reflecting an impulse toward Jeffersonian entrepreneurialism) .
    • See Celler-Kefauver Act of December 29, 1950, 15 U.S.C. §§ 18, 21 (2000). See generally Rudolph J.R. Peritz, Toward a Dynamic Antitrust Analysis of Strategic Market Behavior, 47 N.Y.L. SCH. L. REV. 101, 110 (2003) (describing the Celler-Kefauver Act as reflecting an "impulse toward Jeffersonian entrepreneurialism") .
  • 138
    • 84887973142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Modesty, 105
    • describing an implicit bargain in which antitrust enforcers trade political salience for independence, See
    • See Daniel A. Crane, Antitrust Modesty, 105 MICH. L. REV. 1193, 1210 (2007) (describing an implicit bargain in which antitrust enforcers trade political salience for independence).
    • (2007) MICH. L. REV , vol.1193 , pp. 1210
    • Crane, D.A.1
  • 139
    • 44649142404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crane, note 25, at, describing differing models of antitrust enforcement considered during the Progressive Era
    • See Crane, supra note 25, at 17-21 (describing differing models of antitrust enforcement considered during the Progressive Era).
    • supra , pp. 17-21
  • 140
    • 44649129011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See AKIN, supra note 4, at 3 describing the rise of technocratic sentiment during the early part of the twentieth century
    • See AKIN, supra note 4, at 3 (describing the rise of technocratic sentiment during the early part of the twentieth century).
  • 141
    • 44649153393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Between 1998 and 2007, the Department of Justice's Antitrust Division initiated an average of only 17.3 civil cases and 45.4 criminal cases per year. See ANTITRUST DIV., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION WORKLOAD STATISTICS FY 1998-2007, available at http://0225.01 45.01.040/atr/public/workstats.pdf The Federal Trade Commission initiates a similarly small number of nonmerger civil enforcement actions.
    • Between 1998 and 2007, the Department of Justice's Antitrust Division initiated an average of only 17.3 civil cases and 45.4 criminal cases per year. See ANTITRUST DIV., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION WORKLOAD STATISTICS FY 1998-2007, available at http://0225.01 45.01.040/atr/public/workstats.pdf The Federal Trade Commission initiates a similarly small number of nonmerger civil enforcement actions.
  • 142
    • 44649106201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BUREAU OF COMPETITION, FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT ACTIVITIES: FISCAL YEAR 2002-MARCH 15, 2006 (2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/reports/aba/abaspring2006.pdf (showing a maximum of sixteen FTC nonmerger civil enforcement actions in any of the years from 2002 to 2005). Private litigants file over 800 federal antitrust cases a year, almost all of them seeking damages for past violations.
    • See BUREAU OF COMPETITION, FED. TRADE COMM'N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT ACTIVITIES: FISCAL YEAR 2002-MARCH 15, 2006 (2006), available at http://www.ftc.gov/reports/aba/abaspring2006.pdf (showing a maximum of sixteen FTC nonmerger civil enforcement actions in any of the years from 2002 to 2005). Private litigants file over 800 federal antitrust cases a year, almost all of them seeking damages for past violations.
  • 143
    • 44649099384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DUFF, supra note 87, at 162 tbl.D-2 (showing that private litigants filed 967 antitrust cases in 2006).
    • See, e.g., DUFF, supra note 87, at 162 tbl.D-2 (showing that private litigants filed 967 antitrust cases in 2006).
  • 144
    • 44649156176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ALEXIS DE TOCQUEVILLE, DEMOCRACY IN AMERICA 261 (Harvey C. Mansfield & Delba Winthrop eds., Univ. of Chi. Press 2000) (1835).
    • ALEXIS DE TOCQUEVILLE, DEMOCRACY IN AMERICA 261 (Harvey C. Mansfield & Delba Winthrop eds., Univ. of Chi. Press 2000) (1835).
  • 145
    • 44649134405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Powers v. Ohio, 499 U.S. 400, 407 (1991) ([W]ith the exception of voting, for most citizens the honor and privilege of jury duty is their most significant opportunity to participate in the democratic process.).
    • See Powers v. Ohio, 499 U.S. 400, 407 (1991) ("[W]ith the exception of voting, for most citizens the honor and privilege of jury duty is their most significant opportunity to participate in the democratic process.").
  • 146
    • 37149040266 scopus 로고
    • The Bill of Rights as a Constitution, 100
    • Akhil Reed Amar, The Bill of Rights as a Constitution, 100 YALE L.J. 1131, 1190 (1991).
    • (1991) YALE L.J , vol.1131 , pp. 1190
    • Reed Amar, A.1
  • 147
    • 0347574001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assessing Punitive Damages (with Notes on Cognition and Valuation in the Law), 107
    • Cass R. Sunstein et al., Assessing Punitive Damages (with Notes on Cognition and Valuation in the Law), 107 YALE L.J. 2071, 2120-21 (1998).
    • (1998) YALE L.J. 2071 , pp. 2120-2121
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 148
    • 44649124680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 149
    • 84956547845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 15a, 2000
    • 15 U.S.C. § 15(a) (2000).
    • 15 U.S.C
  • 150
    • 44649153621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Indeed, leading antitrust scholars argue that antitrust law has no moral character at all. See HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 10 (2005) (Antitrust is an economic, not a moral, enterprise.);
    • Indeed, leading antitrust scholars argue that antitrust law has no moral character at all. See HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 10 (2005) ("Antitrust is an economic, not a moral, enterprise.");
  • 151
    • 44649182580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 47 (Antitrust is not good at transferring wealth, and cannot be defended on that basis in any event. Nor does it have any moral content of its own, and is not well designed to provide rules of business ethics.);
    • id. at 47 ("Antitrust is not good at transferring wealth, and cannot be defended on that basis in any event. Nor does it have any moral content of its own, and is not well designed to provide rules of business ethics.");
  • 152
    • 44649176207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295, 345 (D. Mass. 1953) (The violation with which United is now charged depends not on moral considerations, but on solely economic considerations. ), aff'd per curiam, 347 U.S. 521 (1954).
    • see also United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295, 345 (D. Mass. 1953) ("The violation with which United is now charged depends not on moral considerations, but on solely economic considerations. "), aff'd per curiam, 347 U.S. 521 (1954).
  • 153
    • 44649101239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962) (holding that the boundaries of a product market are determined by interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it);
    • See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962) (holding that the boundaries of a product market are determined by "interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it");
  • 154
    • 44649176208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 394, 393-404 (1956) (holding that the relevant market is determined by whether there is 'cross-elasticity' of demand between cellophane and other wrappings).
    • United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 394, 393-404 (1956) (holding that the relevant market is determined by whether there is "'cross-elasticity' of demand" between cellophane and other wrappings).
  • 155
    • 44649142412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 109 n.38 (1984) (Market power is the ability to raise prices above those that would be charged in a competitive market.).
    • See NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 109 n.38 (1984) ("Market power is the ability to raise prices above those that would be charged in a competitive market.").
  • 156
    • 44649118475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 137, 139-40 (1998) (holding that the plaintiff cannot succeed in an antitrust case without showing harm to the competitive process and noting that even conduct that may be fraudulent, tortious, or otherwise unlawful does not implicate antitrust unless it causes harm to the competitive process).
    • See NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 137, 139-40 (1998) (holding that the plaintiff cannot succeed in an antitrust case without showing harm to the competitive process and noting that even conduct that may be fraudulent, tortious, or otherwise unlawful does not implicate antitrust unless it causes harm to the competitive process).
  • 157
    • 44649174819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 59 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (holding that once the plaintiff succeeds in showing that the defendant's conduct was anticompetitive, the burden shifts to the defendant to offer efficiency justifications).
    • See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 59 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (holding that once the plaintiff succeeds in showing that the defendant's conduct was anticompetitive, the burden shifts to the defendant to offer efficiency justifications).
  • 158
    • 44649110678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. (holding that once the defendant shows that there are procompetitive justifications for its conduct, the burden shifts back to the plaintiff to show that the anticompetitive effects outweigh the procompetitive effects);
    • See id. (holding that once the defendant shows that there are procompetitive justifications for its conduct, the burden shifts back to the plaintiff to show that the anticompetitive effects outweigh the procompetitive effects);
  • 159
    • 44649087508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Brown Univ., 5 F.3d 658, 679 (3d Cir. 1993) (Once a defendant demonstrates that its conduct promotes a legitimate goal, the plaintiff, in order to prevail, bears the burden of proving that there exists a viable less restrictive alternative.).
    • United States v. Brown Univ., 5 F.3d 658, 679 (3d Cir. 1993) ("Once a defendant demonstrates that its conduct promotes a legitimate goal, the plaintiff, in order to prevail, bears the burden of proving that there exists a viable less restrictive alternative.").
  • 160
    • 44649094386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977) (holding that the plaintiff in a private antitrust case for damages must show not only anticompetitive conduct but also that the harm suffered by the plaintiff was of the kind that the antitrust laws were intended to prevent).
    • See Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977) (holding that the plaintiff in a private antitrust case for damages must show not only anticompetitive conduct but also that the harm suffered by the plaintiff was of the kind that the antitrust laws were intended to prevent).
  • 161
    • 44649116957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 225 (1993) (Even an act of pure malice by one business competitor against another does not, without more, state a claim under the federal antitrust laws.).
    • See, e.g., Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 225 (1993) ("Even an act of pure malice by one business competitor against another does not, without more, state a claim under the federal antitrust laws.").
  • 162
    • 44649131787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is no question as to the Sixth Amendment right to a jury in criminal antitrust cases and only slight doubt as to the Seventh Amendment right to a jury in civil antitrust cases. See Crane, supra note 25, at 33
    • There is no question as to the Sixth Amendment right to a jury in criminal antitrust cases and only slight doubt as to the Seventh Amendment right to a jury in civil antitrust cases. See Crane, supra note 25, at 33.
  • 163
    • 44649095521 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra note 125. Although statistically few criminal antitrust cases go to juries, as noted below, the percentage of jury adjudications in criminal cases is much higher than in civil cases. See infra note 125.
    • See infra note 125. Although statistically few criminal antitrust cases go to juries, as noted below, the percentage of jury adjudications in criminal cases is much higher than in civil cases. See infra note 125.
  • 164
    • 44649198474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crane, supra note 25, at 35 n.188 (presenting rate-of-dismissal statistics).
    • See Crane, supra note 25, at 35 n.188 (presenting rate-of-dismissal statistics).
  • 165
    • 44649177470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • About another 1% are tried as bench trials, usually by consent of the parties. Id.
    • About another 1% are tried as bench trials, usually by consent of the parties. Id.
  • 167
    • 44649178107 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 35-37
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 35-37.
  • 168
    • 44649169533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 127 S. Ct. 1955, 1964 (2007) (discussing the need to guard against false positives in conspiracy cases);
    • See Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 127 S. Ct. 1955, 1964 (2007) (discussing the need to guard against false positives in conspiracy cases);
  • 169
    • 44649108765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004) (The cost of false positives counsels against an undue expansion of § 2 [monopolization] liability.);
    • Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004) ("The cost of false positives counsels against an undue expansion of § 2 [monopolization] liability.");
  • 170
    • 44649106835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 226 (1993) ('[Mistaken inferences [of predatory pricing and the resulting false condemnations] are especially costly, because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect.' (quoting Cargill, Inc. v. Montfort of Colo., Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 122 n.17 (1986))). Open criticism of the jury as an institution is often considered bad manners.
    • Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 226 (1993) ("'[Mistaken inferences [of predatory pricing and the resulting false condemnations] are especially costly, because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect.'" (quoting Cargill, Inc. v. Montfort of Colo., Inc., 479 U.S. 104, 122 n.17 (1986))). Open criticism of the jury as an institution is often considered bad manners.
  • 171
    • 44649157541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Edwin J. Hughes, The Left Side of Antitrust: What Fairness Means and Why It Matters, 11 MARQ. L. REV. 265, 286 (1994) (The distrust of this system evident in the economic approach to antitrust and the movement toward a system more akin to administrative law for resolving these claims is [sic] antidemocratic, reflecting a distrust of both the citizens sitting on juries and of the informal, consensus-building model of decision-making that the jury system embodies.).
    • See, e.g., Edwin J. Hughes, The Left Side of Antitrust: What Fairness Means and Why It Matters, 11 MARQ. L. REV. 265, 286 (1994) ("The distrust of this system evident in the economic approach to antitrust and the movement toward a system more akin to administrative law for resolving these claims is [sic] antidemocratic, reflecting a distrust of both the citizens sitting on juries and of the informal, consensus-building model of decision-making that the jury system embodies.").
  • 172
    • 44649190993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 127 S. Ct. 1955(2007).
    • 127 S. Ct. 1955(2007).
  • 173
    • 44649098723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 1964-66.
    • See id. at 1964-66.
  • 174
    • 44649202618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1975 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
    • Id. at 1975 (Stevens, J., dissenting).
  • 175
    • 44649137193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1967 (majority opinion) (quoting id. at 1975 (Stevens, J., dissenting)).
    • Id. at 1967 (majority opinion) (quoting id. at 1975 (Stevens, J., dissenting)).
  • 176
    • 44649192203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The possibility of jury error was discussed tangentially in the parties' briefs. See, e.g., Brief in Opposition at 18, Twombly, 127 S. Ct. 1955 (No. 05-1126).
    • The possibility of jury error was discussed tangentially in the parties' briefs. See, e.g., Brief in Opposition at 18, Twombly, 127 S. Ct. 1955 (No. 05-1126).
  • 177
    • 44649197593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In another antitrust case contemporary with Twombly, the Court justified its holding that securities law preempted antitrust lawsuits against syndicates underwriting initial public offerings by noting the risk of the threat of antitrust mistakes and error in the adjudication of antitrust lawsuits. Credit Suisse Sec. (USA) LLC v. Billing, 127 S. Ct. 2383, 2396 (2007). See generally Crane, supra note 25, at 35-36 (discussing earlier precedents evidencing concern over false positives in antitrust jury trials).
    • In another antitrust case contemporary with Twombly, the Court justified its holding that securities law preempted antitrust lawsuits against syndicates underwriting initial public offerings by noting the risk of "the threat of antitrust mistakes" and "error" in the adjudication of antitrust lawsuits. Credit Suisse Sec. (USA) LLC v. Billing, 127 S. Ct. 2383, 2396 (2007). See generally Crane, supra note 25, at 35-36 (discussing earlier precedents evidencing concern over false positives in antitrust jury trials).
  • 178
    • 44649093137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574 (1986).
    • Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574 (1986).
  • 179
    • 0041654697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Arthur R. Miller, The Pretrial Rush to Judgment: Are the Litigation Explosion, Liability Crisis, and Efficiency Clichés Eroding Our Day in Court and Jury Trial Commitments, 78 N.Y.U. L. REV. 982, 1032 (2003, Thus, there are compelling arguments that the Supreme Court's holding in Matsushita, declaring the plaintiffs' requested inference implausible, was mandated by substantive antitrust law and the traditional conception of summary judgment, not by any heightened standard to be generally imposed on parties defending against the motion, id. at 1055 describing courts' willingness to take the Supreme Court's willingness to grant summary judgment in a complex antitrust action as a signal to be receptive to the motion in other contexts as well
    • See Arthur R. Miller, The Pretrial Rush to Judgment: Are the "Litigation Explosion," "Liability Crisis, " and Efficiency Clichés Eroding Our Day in Court and Jury Trial Commitments?, 78 N.Y.U. L. REV. 982, 1032 (2003) ("Thus, there are compelling arguments that the Supreme Court's holding in Matsushita, declaring the plaintiffs' requested inference implausible, was mandated by substantive antitrust law and the traditional conception of summary judgment, not by any heightened standard to be generally imposed on parties defending against the motion."); id. at 1055 (describing courts' willingness to take the Supreme Court's willingness to grant summary judgment in a complex antitrust action as a signal to be receptive to the motion in other contexts as well).
  • 180
    • 44649098019 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although there is relatively little empirical work on the performance of juries in modern antitrust cases, the little that there is seems to confirm the suspicion that juries are woefully unable to keep up with the complexities of antitrust trials. See Arthur Austin, The Jury System at Risk from Complexity, the New Media, and Deviancy, 73 DENV. U. L. REV. 51, 54, 52-59 1995, reporting based on a study of five juries in private antitrust cases: [T]he jurors were overwhelmed, frustrated, and confused by testimony well beyond their comprehension. I concluded that at no time did any juror grasp-even at the margins-the law, the economics or any other testimony relating to the allegations or defense
    • Although there is relatively little empirical work on the performance of juries in modern antitrust cases, the little that there is seems to confirm the suspicion that juries are woefully unable to keep up with the complexities of antitrust trials. See Arthur Austin, The Jury System at Risk from Complexity, the New Media, and Deviancy, 73 DENV. U. L. REV. 51, 54, 52-59 (1995) (reporting based on a study of five juries in private antitrust cases: "[T]he jurors were overwhelmed, frustrated, and confused by testimony well beyond their comprehension. I concluded that at no time did any juror grasp-even at the margins-the law, the economics or any other testimony relating to the allegations or defense").
  • 181
    • 44649193516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gary R. Spratling, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Address Before the Bar Association of the District of Columbia's 35th Annual Symposium on Associations and Antitrust: Making Companies an Offer They Shouldn't Refuse: The Antitrust Division's Corporate Leniency Policy-An Update 5 (Feb. 16, 1999), available at http://www.usdoj .gov/atr/public/speeches/2247.pdf (noting greater success in criminal enforcement against international cartels since the adoption of the amnesty policy).
    • See Gary R. Spratling, Deputy Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Address Before the Bar Association of the District of Columbia's 35th Annual Symposium on Associations and Antitrust: Making Companies an Offer They Shouldn't Refuse: The Antitrust Division's Corporate Leniency Policy-An Update 5 (Feb. 16, 1999), available at http://www.usdoj .gov/atr/public/speeches/2247.pdf (noting greater success in criminal enforcement against international cartels since the adoption of the amnesty policy).
  • 182
    • 44649117850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 35 n.188.
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 35 n.188.
  • 183
    • 44649190992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The statistics reported here are based on the annual reports of the Director of the Administrative Offices of the U.S. Courts for the years 1997-2006. The data are collected from Table D-4 (Criminal Defendants Disposed of, by Type of Disposition and Major Offense) of the Detailed Statistical Tables for U.S. District Courts. The data show that during these years, of 326 defendant dispositions, only 7 were by dismissal. See, e.g., DUFF, supra note 87, at 249 tbl.D-4;
    • The statistics reported here are based on the annual reports of the Director of the Administrative Offices of the U.S. Courts for the years 1997-2006. The data are collected from Table D-4 (Criminal Defendants Disposed of, by Type of Disposition and Major Offense) of the Detailed Statistical Tables for U.S. District Courts. The data show that during these years, of 326 defendant dispositions, only 7 were by dismissal. See, e.g., DUFF, supra note 87, at 249 tbl.D-4;
  • 184
    • 44649187317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LEONIDAS RALPH MECHAM, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2004 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURTS: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR 217 tbl.D-4 (2004), available at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2004/appendices/d4.pdf;
    • LEONIDAS RALPH MECHAM, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2004 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURTS: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR 217 tbl.D-4 (2004), available at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2004/appendices/d4.pdf;
  • 185
    • 44649198220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LEONIDAS RALPH MECHAM, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2002 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURTS: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR 211 tbl.D-4 (2002), available at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2002/ appendices/d04sep02.pdf;
    • LEONIDAS RALPH MECHAM, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2002 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURTS: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR 211 tbl.D-4 (2002), available at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2002/ appendices/d04sep02.pdf;
  • 186
    • 44649088112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LEONIDAS RALPH MECHAM, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2000 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURT: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR 221 tbl.D-4 (2000), available at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2000/appendices/d04sep00.pdf.
    • LEONIDAS RALPH MECHAM, ADMIN. OFFICE OF THE U.S. COURTS, 2000 JUDICIAL BUSINESS OF THE UNITED STATES COURT: ANNUAL REPORT OF THE DIRECTOR 221 tbl.D-4 (2000), available at http://www.uscourts.gov/judbus2000/appendices/d04sep00.pdf.
  • 187
    • 44649186072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 35 n.188.
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 35 n.188.
  • 188
    • 44649164319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 125
    • See supra note 125.
  • 189
    • 44649092496 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 125
    • See supra note 125.
  • 190
    • 44649109420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cavanagh, supra note 48, at 209 (observing the increased use after Matsushita of summary judgment to dispose of antitrust cases);
    • See Cavanagh, supra note 48, at 209 (observing the increased use after Matsushita of summary judgment to dispose of antitrust cases);
  • 191
    • 70349797774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Notice Pleading, 45
    • observing the persistent use of heightened pleading standards by judges to remove antitrust cases from their caseloads
    • Christopher S. Fairman, The Myth of Notice Pleading, 45 ARIZ. L. REV. 987, 1013-21 (2003) (observing the persistent use of heightened pleading standards by judges to remove antitrust cases from their caseloads).
    • (2003) ARIZ. L. REV , vol.987 , pp. 1013-1021
    • Fairman, C.S.1
  • 192
    • 44649161717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cavanagh, supra note 48, at 149-51 (focusing on sentencing guidelines and leniency agreements in his discussion of the Antitrust Division's criminal powers).
    • See Cavanagh, supra note 48, at 149-51 (focusing on sentencing guidelines and leniency agreements in his discussion of the Antitrust Division's criminal powers).
  • 193
    • 44649110677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A good example of this is the Justice Department's criminal prosecution of executives involved in the price-fixing conspiracy between Christie's and Sotheby's. See generally CHRISTOPHER MASON, THE ART OF THE STEAL: INSIDE THE SOTHEBY'S-CHRISTIE'S AUCTION HOUSE SCANDAL (2004). After incriminating facts emerged, it became apparent that a price-fixing conspiracy had been effectuated between the two firms, a matter that sealed the fate of the corporate defendants in the class-action lawsuits brought by aggrieved buyers and sellers against the auction houses.
    • A good example of this is the Justice Department's criminal prosecution of executives involved in the price-fixing conspiracy between Christie's and Sotheby's. See generally CHRISTOPHER MASON, THE ART OF THE STEAL: INSIDE THE SOTHEBY'S-CHRISTIE'S AUCTION HOUSE SCANDAL (2004). After incriminating facts emerged, it became apparent that a price-fixing conspiracy had been effectuated between the two firms, a matter that sealed the fate of the corporate defendants in the class-action lawsuits brought by aggrieved buyers and sellers against the auction houses.
  • 194
    • 44649183834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 290 (Both Sotheby's and Christie's knew that the evidence against them [in the class action] . . . was so overwhelming that a jury would have no trouble finding both companies liable.). Nonetheless, there remained ample questions for the jury's determination in the ensuing criminal cases, which focused largely on who at the various firms was responsible for the illegal agreement, and to what degree.
    • See id. at 290 ("Both Sotheby's and Christie's knew that the evidence against them [in the class action] . . . was so overwhelming that a jury would have no trouble finding both companies liable."). Nonetheless, there remained ample questions for the jury's determination in the ensuing criminal cases, which focused largely on who at the various firms was responsible for the illegal agreement, and to what degree.
  • 195
    • 44649145049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 319-46 (describing the trial of Sotheby's Chairman Alfred Taubman).
    • See, e.g., id. at 319-46 (describing the trial of Sotheby's Chairman Alfred Taubman).
  • 196
    • 44649097412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Criminal enforcement of antitrust is sometimes handled by generalist prosecutors outside the Antitrust Division. See ANTITRUST DIV, U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION MANUAL ch. VII.B 3d ed. 1998, available at, Most criminal antitrust investigations are conducted by the Antitrust Division's field offices and litigating sections, In some cases, however, it may be more advantageous for the U.S. Attorney's office to investigate and prosecute a matter
    • Criminal enforcement of antitrust is sometimes handled by generalist prosecutors outside the Antitrust Division. See ANTITRUST DIV., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION MANUAL ch. VII.B (3d ed. 1998), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/foia/divisionmanual/ch7.htm#b ("Most criminal antitrust investigations are conducted by the Antitrust Division's field offices and litigating sections .... In some cases, however, it may be more advantageous for the U.S. Attorney's office to investigate and prosecute a matter .. . .").
  • 197
    • 44649089864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., W. KIP VISCUSI, JOSEPH E. HARRINGTON, JR. & JOHN M. VERNON, ECONOMICS OF REGULATION AND ANTITRUST xviii (4th ed. 2005) (The traditional emphasis of economics textbooks on business and government is on the character of regulations and antitrust policies.).
    • See, e.g., W. KIP VISCUSI, JOSEPH E. HARRINGTON, JR. & JOHN M. VERNON, ECONOMICS OF REGULATION AND ANTITRUST xviii (4th ed. 2005) ("The traditional emphasis of economics textbooks on business and government is on the character of regulations and antitrust policies.").
  • 198
    • 33745675388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ken I. Kersch, Justice Breyer's Mandarin Liberty, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 759, 760-61 (2006) (reviewing STEPHEN BREYER, ACTIVE LIBERTY: INTERPRETING OUR DEMOCRATIC CONSTITUTION (2005)) (describing Justice Breyer's technocratic outlook).
    • See Ken I. Kersch, Justice Breyer's Mandarin Liberty, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 759, 760-61 (2006) (reviewing STEPHEN BREYER, ACTIVE LIBERTY: INTERPRETING OUR DEMOCRATIC CONSTITUTION (2005)) (describing Justice Breyer's technocratic outlook).
  • 199
    • 44649095002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Town of Concord, Mass. v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 22 (1st Cir. 1990).
    • Town of Concord, Mass. v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17, 22 (1st Cir. 1990).
  • 200
    • 44649103124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supranote 25, at 2
    • Crane, supranote 25, at 2.
  • 201
    • 44649182579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ENTERPRISE AND AMERICAN LAW 1836-1937, at 163-68 (1991).
    • HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ENTERPRISE AND AMERICAN LAW 1836-1937, at 163-68 (1991).
  • 202
    • 44649198473 scopus 로고
    • The Interstate Commerce Commission- Disintegration of an American Legal Institution, 34
    • Paul Stephen Dempsey, The Interstate Commerce Commission- Disintegration of an American Legal Institution, 34 AM. U. L. REV. 1, 2 (1984).
    • (1984) AM. U. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 2
    • Stephen Dempsey, P.1
  • 203
    • 33747484898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defining Deference Down: Independent Agencies and Chevron Deference, 58
    • describing the technocratic origins of the ICC, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Randolph J. May, Defining Deference Down: Independent Agencies and Chevron Deference, 58 ADMIN. L. REV. 429, 445 (2006) (describing the technocratic origins of the ICC);
    • (2006) ADMIN. L. REV , vol.429 , pp. 445
    • May, R.J.1
  • 204
    • 44649115632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keith E. Whittington, Dismantling the Modern State? The Changing Structural Foundations of Federalism, 25 HASTINGS CONST. L.Q. 483, 494 (1998) (using the ICC as an example of the administrative ethic, with its focus on technocratic expertise).
    • Keith E. Whittington, Dismantling the Modern State? The Changing Structural Foundations of Federalism, 25 HASTINGS CONST. L.Q. 483, 494 (1998) (using the ICC as an example of "the administrative ethic, with its focus on technocratic expertise").
  • 205
    • 44649100000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Whittington, supra note 139, at 493 (Railroad economists .. . were active in shaping the political decision to regulate railroad rates-which, in turn, required the establishment of the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC), staffed with economists-rather than to prohibit identified practices or to break up some companies legislatively.).
    • See Whittington, supra note 139, at 493 ("Railroad economists .. . were active in shaping the political decision to regulate railroad rates-which, in turn, required the establishment of the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC), staffed with economists-rather than to prohibit identified practices or to break up some companies legislatively.").
  • 206
    • 44649183835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SKLAR, supra note 13, at 324 (describing the two possible models for controlling the trusts as a statist regulatory model along the lines of the ICC and a nonstatist model of indirect regulation along the lines of the Sherman and FTC Acts).
    • See SKLAR, supra note 13, at 324 (describing the two possible models for controlling the trusts as a statist regulatory model along the lines of the ICC and a nonstatist model of indirect regulation along the lines of the Sherman and FTC Acts).
  • 207
    • 44649111679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., William H. Page, Interest Groups, Antitrust, and State Regulation: Parker v. Brown in the Economic Theory of Legislation, 1987 DUKE L.J. 618, 659 (describing the Sherman Act's open texture).
    • See, e.g., William H. Page, Interest Groups, Antitrust, and State Regulation: Parker v. Brown in the Economic Theory of Legislation, 1987 DUKE L.J. 618, 659 (describing the Sherman Act's open texture).
  • 208
    • 44649171433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Nat'l Soc'y of Prof 1 Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 688 (1978) (Congress, however, did not intend the text of the Sherman Act to delineate the full meaning of the statute or its application in concrete situations. The legislative history makes it perfectly clear that it expected the courts to give shape to the statute's broad mandate by drawing on common-law tradition.);
    • See, e.g., Nat'l Soc'y of Prof 1 Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 688 (1978) ("Congress, however, did not intend the text of the Sherman Act to delineate the full meaning of the statute or its application in concrete situations. The legislative history makes it perfectly clear that it expected the courts to give shape to the statute's broad mandate by drawing on common-law tradition.");
  • 209
    • 44649126546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW H 103d2, at 59 (2d ed. 2000) (stating that the legislative history of other antitrust statutes demonstrates that the Sherman Act invest[ed] the federal courts with a jurisdiction to create and develop an 'antitrust law' in the manner of the common law courts);
    • PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW H 103d2, at 59 (2d ed. 2000) (stating that the legislative history of other antitrust statutes demonstrates that the Sherman Act "invest[ed] the federal courts with a jurisdiction to create and develop an 'antitrust law' in the manner of the common law courts");
  • 210
    • 44649176826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • William F. Baxter, Separation of Powers, Prosecutorial Discretion, and the Common Law Nature of Antitrust Law, 60 TEXAS L. REV. 661, 663 (1982) (Congress adopted what is in essence enabling legislation that has permitted a common-law refinement of antitrust law through an evolution guided by only the most general statutory directions.);
    • William F. Baxter, Separation of Powers, Prosecutorial Discretion, and the "Common Law" Nature of Antitrust Law, 60 TEXAS L. REV. 661, 663 (1982) ("Congress adopted what is in essence enabling legislation that has permitted a common-law refinement of antitrust law through an evolution guided by only the most general statutory directions.");
  • 211
    • 44649142411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, Statutes' Domains, 50 U. CHI. L. REV. 533, 544 (1983) (The statute books are full of laws, of which the Sherman Act is a good example, that effectively authorize courts to create new lines of common law.).
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, Statutes' Domains, 50 U. CHI. L. REV. 533, 544 (1983) ("The statute books are full of laws, of which the Sherman Act is a good example, that effectively authorize courts to create new lines of common law.").
  • 212
    • 44649087507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Oliver Wendell Holmes, Codes, and the Arrangement of the Law, 5 AM. L. REV. 1, 1 (1870), reprinted in 1 THE COLLECTED WORKS OF JUSTICE HOLMES 212, 212
    • See, e.g., Oliver Wendell Holmes, Codes, and the Arrangement of the Law, 5 AM. L. REV. 1, 1 (1870), reprinted in 1 THE COLLECTED WORKS OF JUSTICE HOLMES 212, 212
  • 213
    • 44649127192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Sheldon M. Novick ed., 1995) (It is the merit of the common law that it decides the case first and determines the principle afterwards.). For a recent exchange on the merits of common law rule making, see Frederick Schauer, Do Cases Make Bad Law?, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 883, 912-13 (2006), which argues that cognitive biases distort adjudicatory rule making,
    • (Sheldon M. Novick ed., 1995) ("It is the merit of the common law that it decides the case first and determines the principle afterwards."). For a recent exchange on the merits of common law rule making, see Frederick Schauer, Do Cases Make Bad Law?, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 883, 912-13 (2006), which argues that cognitive biases distort adjudicatory rule making,
  • 214
    • 33749498650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judges as Rulemakers, 73
    • which defends common law adjudication based on its focus on real-world disputes
    • and Emily Sherwin, Judges as Rulemakers, 73 U. CHI. L. REV. 919, 923-24 (2006), which defends common law adjudication based on its focus on real-world disputes.
    • (2006) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.919 , pp. 923-924
    • Sherwin, E.1
  • 215
    • 34948851844 scopus 로고
    • Mass Torts: An Institutional Evolutionist Perspective, 80
    • discussing the advantages of adjudication over regulation in the context of mass-tort litigation, See
    • See Peter H. Schuck, Mass Torts: An Institutional Evolutionist Perspective, 80 CORNELL L. REV. 941, 974-76 (1995) (discussing the advantages of adjudication over regulation in the context of mass-tort litigation).
    • (1995) CORNELL L. REV , vol.941 , pp. 974-976
    • Schuck, P.H.1
  • 216
    • 44649089204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 973 (discussing the radically decentralized nature of adjudication's decision-making process).
    • See id. at 973 (discussing the "radically decentralized" nature of adjudication's decision-making process).
  • 217
    • 70749159230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statutory Interpretation and Decision Theory, 74
    • book review, discussing tunnel-vision and agency-capture concerns that may lend generalist judges some advantages over specialized agencies, See
    • See Caleb Nelson, Statutory Interpretation and Decision Theory, 74 U. CHI. L. REV. 329, 351 (2007) (book review) (discussing tunnel-vision and agency-capture concerns that may lend generalist judges some advantages over specialized agencies).
    • (2007) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.329 , pp. 351
    • Nelson, C.1
  • 218
    • 0013468683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Richard A. Nagareda, Turning from Tort to Administration, 94 MICH. L. REV. 899, 902-03 (1996) (discussing models of public-agency involvement in private mass-tort litigation to help achieve appropriate compensation terms).
    • But see Richard A. Nagareda, Turning from Tort to Administration, 94 MICH. L. REV. 899, 902-03 (1996) (discussing models of public-agency involvement in private mass-tort litigation to help achieve appropriate compensation terms).
  • 219
    • 44649157539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra subpart III(A) (discussing the untechnocratic implications of civil juries and criminal enforcement); infra notes 191-213 and text accompanying (discussing the FTC's role as a law-enforcement agency).
    • See supra subpart III(A) (discussing the untechnocratic implications of civil juries and criminal enforcement); infra notes 191-213 and text accompanying (discussing the FTC's role as a law-enforcement agency).
  • 220
    • 84944588755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 4, at, describing the progressive technocratic movement as based on a problem-solving approach to social and economic problems
    • See AKIN, supra note 4, at 1-3 (describing the progressive technocratic movement as based on a problem-solving approach to social and economic problems).
    • supra , pp. 1-3
    • AKIN1
  • 221
    • 44649099998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Whose Dispute Is It Anyway?: A Philosophical and Democratic Defense of Settlement (in Some Cases), 83 GEO. L.J. 2663, 2674-75 (1995) (arguing that adjudication, by producing binary win-lose results, fails to recognize the ambiguities and contradictions in modern life); see also WOLF HEYDEBRAND & CARROLL SERON, RATIONALIZING JUSTICE: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF FEDERAL DISTRICT COURTS 45-57, 81-89 (1990) (analyzing the shift from adjudication toward technocratic administration in the federal courts).
    • See Carrie Menkel-Meadow, Whose Dispute Is It Anyway?: A Philosophical and Democratic Defense of Settlement (in Some Cases), 83 GEO. L.J. 2663, 2674-75 (1995) (arguing that adjudication, by producing "binary win-lose results," fails to "recognize the ambiguities and contradictions in modern life"); see also WOLF HEYDEBRAND & CARROLL SERON, RATIONALIZING JUSTICE: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF FEDERAL DISTRICT COURTS 45-57, 81-89 (1990) (analyzing the shift from adjudication toward "technocratic administration" in the federal courts).
  • 222
    • 44649113548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is possible, of course, that the fact finder might find the defendant guilty or liable on some counts but not others, but as to each count there are only two possibilities: guilty or liable and not guilty or not liable
    • It is possible, of course, that the fact finder might find the defendant guilty or liable on some counts but not others, but as to each count there are only two possibilities: guilty or liable and not guilty or not liable.
  • 223
    • 22444455024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is International Antitrust Possible?, 73
    • noting that a merger can simultaneously create productive efficiencies and economies of scale, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Andrew T. Guzman, Is International Antitrust Possible?, 73 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1501, 1509 (1998) (noting that a merger can simultaneously create productive efficiencies and economies of scale);
    • (1998) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.1501 , pp. 1509
    • Guzman, A.T.1
  • 224
    • 14944367299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alan J. Meese, Monopolization, Exclusion, and the Theory of the Firm, 89 MINN. L. REV. 743, 781-82 (2005) (discussing economic perspectives on simultaneous increases in market power and economies of scale brought about by aggregations of capital);
    • Alan J. Meese, Monopolization, Exclusion, and the Theory of the Firm, 89 MINN. L. REV. 743, 781-82 (2005) (discussing economic perspectives on simultaneous increases in market power and economies of scale brought about by aggregations of capital);
  • 225
    • 44649189640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oliver E. Williamson, Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs, 58 AM. ECON. REV. 18, 21-23 (1968) (discussing how even a merger to monopoly can increase social welfare if it results in increased economies of scale).
    • Oliver E. Williamson, Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs, 58 AM. ECON. REV. 18, 21-23 (1968) (discussing how even a merger to monopoly can increase social welfare if it results in increased economies of scale).
  • 226
    • 44649158766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 344 F.3d 229, 238 (2d Cir. 2003) (applying a three-step rule of reason, including: (1) initial proof by the plaintiff that the relevant agreement created market power, (2) proof by the defendant that the restraint created efficiencies sufficient to negate any anticompetitive effects, and (3) opportunity for the plaintiff to show that the restraint was not reasonably necessary to achieve alleged efficiencies);
    • See, e.g., United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 344 F.3d 229, 238 (2d Cir. 2003) (applying a three-step rule of reason, including: (1) initial proof by the plaintiff that the relevant agreement created market power, (2) proof by the defendant that the restraint created efficiencies sufficient to negate any anticompetitive effects, and (3) opportunity for the plaintiff to show that the restraint was not reasonably necessary to achieve alleged efficiencies);
  • 227
    • 4944230133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Andrew I. Gavil, Exclusionary Distribution Strategies by Dominant Firms: Striking a Better Balance, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 2, 54 n.193 (2004) ([M]uch of modern antitrust law today is driven by common, core concepts, such as market power, entry, and efficiency, which are relevant to the application of Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, and Section 7 of the Clayton Act.);
    • Andrew I. Gavil, Exclusionary Distribution Strategies by Dominant Firms: Striking a Better Balance, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 2, 54 n.193 (2004) ("[M]uch of modern antitrust law today is driven by common, core concepts, such as market power, entry, and efficiency, which are relevant to the application of Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, and Section 7 of the Clayton Act.");
  • 228
    • 44649160469 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spencer Weber Waller, Microsoft and Trinko: A Tale of Two Courts, 2006 UTAH L. REV. 741, 750 (One can equally persuasively argue from economic theory that antitrust principally fears durable market power unaccompanied by substantial efficiencies .. . .).
    • Spencer Weber Waller, Microsoft and Trinko: A Tale of Two Courts, 2006 UTAH L. REV. 741, 750 ("One can equally persuasively argue from economic theory that antitrust principally fears durable market power unaccompanied by substantial efficiencies .. . .").
  • 229
    • 44649108764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Visa, 344 F.3d at 238 (As an initial matter, the government must demonstrate that the defendant conspirators have 'market power' in a particular market for goods or services.).
    • See, e.g., Visa, 344 F.3d at 238 ("As an initial matter, the government must demonstrate that the defendant conspirators have 'market power' in a particular market for goods or services.").
  • 230
    • 44649137775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. (describing the defendant's burden to produce a procompetitive justification for the challenged restraint once the Government has shown sufficient market power).
    • See, e.g., id. (describing the defendant's burden to produce "a procompetitive justification for the challenged restraint" once the Government has shown sufficient market power).
  • 231
    • 0035637472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Proposed Antitrust Approach to Collaborations Among Competitors, 86
    • discussing situations where joint ventures create both efficiencies and market power, See
    • See Thomas A. Piraino, Jr., A Proposed Antitrust Approach to Collaborations Among Competitors, 86 IOWA L. REV. 1137, 1187-88 (2001) (discussing situations where joint ventures create both efficiencies and market power).
    • (2001) IOWA L. REV , vol.1137 , pp. 1187-1188
    • Piraino Jr., T.A.1
  • 232
    • 44649154880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 281-83 (2d Cir. 1979) (holding that a court may not balance improvements in a dominant firm's products against anticompetitive effects on the dominant firm's rivals).
    • See, e.g., Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 281-83 (2d Cir. 1979) (holding that a court may not balance improvements in a dominant firm's products against anticompetitive effects on the dominant firm's rivals).
  • 233
    • 44649142408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Alan A. Fisher, Efficiency Considerations in Merger Enforcement, 71 CAL. L. REV. 1580, 1599-600 (1983) (discussing research and development synergies in merger enforcement).
    • See generally Alan A. Fisher, Efficiency Considerations in Merger Enforcement, 71 CAL. L. REV. 1580, 1599-600 (1983) (discussing research and development synergies in merger enforcement).
  • 234
    • 1642634001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trust, Distrust, and Antitrust, 82
    • Federal judges should balance any expected productive efficiencies against the possibility of allocative inefficiencies caused by cartel-like agreements spawned by the joint venture relationships, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Christopher R. Leslie, Trust, Distrust, and Antitrust, 82 TEXAS L. REV. 515, 671 (2004) ("Federal judges should balance any expected productive efficiencies against the possibility of allocative inefficiencies caused by cartel-like agreements spawned by the joint venture relationships.").
    • (2004) TEXAS L. REV , vol.515 , pp. 671
    • Leslie, C.R.1
  • 235
    • 44649119085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Daniel A. Crane, Rules Versus Standards in Antitrust Adjudication, 64 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 49, 99, 99-100 (2007) ([T]he substantial costs of an adverse judgment will deter most dominant firms from straying too close to the line drawn by [any] rule.).
    • See Daniel A. Crane, Rules Versus Standards in Antitrust Adjudication, 64 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 49, 99, 99-100 (2007) ("[T]he substantial costs of an adverse judgment will deter most dominant firms from straying too close to the line drawn by [any] rule.").
  • 236
    • 44649186071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 108 outlining problems with an antitrust approach that turns on balancing the social costs of monopoly against increases in efficiency from the challenged practice
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 108 (outlining problems with an antitrust approach that turns on balancing the social costs of monopoly against increases in efficiency from the challenged practice).
  • 237
    • 44649148823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sullivan v. NFL, 34 F.3d 1091, 1103 (1st Cir. 1994) (One basic tenet of the rule of reason is that a given restriction is not reasonable, that is, its benefits cannot outweigh its harm to competition, if a reasonable, less restrictive alternative to the policy exists that would provide the same benefits as the current restraint.);
    • See Sullivan v. NFL, 34 F.3d 1091, 1103 (1st Cir. 1994) ("One basic tenet of the rule of reason is that a given restriction is not reasonable, that is, its benefits cannot outweigh its harm to competition, if a reasonable, less restrictive alternative to the policy exists that would provide the same benefits as the current restraint.");
  • 238
    • 44649174817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mozart Co. v. Mercedes-Benz of North America, Inc., 833 F.2d 1342, 1349 (9th Cir. 1987) (A tie-in does not violate the antitrust laws 'if implemented for a legitimate purpose and if no less restrictive alternative is available.' (quoting Phonetele, Inc. v. AT&T, 664 F.2d 716, 739 (9th Cir. 1981))).
    • Mozart Co. v. Mercedes-Benz of North America, Inc., 833 F.2d 1342, 1349 (9th Cir. 1987) ("A tie-in does not violate the antitrust laws 'if implemented for a legitimate purpose and if no less restrictive alternative is available.'" (quoting Phonetele, Inc. v. AT&T, 664 F.2d 716, 739 (9th Cir. 1981))).
  • 239
    • 44649188998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., NFL v. N. Am. Soccer League, 459 U.S. 1074, 1079-80 (1982) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting) (criticizing the Second Circuit for adopting a least-restrictive-alternative test in antitrust cases and arguing that such an approach is inconsistent with Supreme Court precedent);
    • See, e.g., NFL v. N. Am. Soccer League, 459 U.S. 1074, 1079-80 (1982) (Rehnquist, J., dissenting) (criticizing the Second Circuit for adopting a least-restrictive-alternative test in antitrust cases and arguing that such an approach is inconsistent with Supreme Court precedent);
  • 240
    • 44649107500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N & U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS § 3.36(b) (2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf (explaining that the agencies do not demand showing that restraint was essential to achieving the efficiencies but merely that the efficiency could not have been achieved by practical, significantly less restrictive means).
    • FED. TRADE COMM'N & U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS § 3.36(b) (2000), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf (explaining that the agencies do not demand showing that restraint was essential to achieving the efficiencies but merely that the efficiency could not have been achieved by "practical, significantly less restrictive means").
  • 241
    • 44649089863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hovenkamp, Antitrust Policy, supra note 3, at 264-82 (discussing the Chicago School's insights on the efficiency of various competitive practices).
    • See Hovenkamp, Antitrust Policy, supra note 3, at 264-82 (discussing the Chicago School's insights on the efficiency of various competitive practices).
  • 242
    • 44649202617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Joseph F. Brodley, Antitrust Standing in Private Merger Cases: Reconciling Private Incentives and Public Enforcement Goals, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1, 23 n.88 (1995) (noting that predatory-pricing plaintiffs must overcome deliberately underinclusive liability rules);
    • See, e.g., Joseph F. Brodley, Antitrust Standing in Private Merger Cases: Reconciling Private Incentives and Public Enforcement Goals, 94 MICH. L. REV. 1, 23 n.88 (1995) (noting that predatory-pricing plaintiffs "must overcome deliberately underinclusive liability rules");
  • 243
    • 44649142407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 72 (noting that both the Chicago and Harvard Schools of antitrust have contributed to underinclusive liability norms for dominant-firm behavior);
    • William E. Kovacic, The Intellectual DNA of Modern U.S. Competition Law for Dominant Firm Conduct: The Chicago/Harvard Double Helix, 2007 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 72 (noting that both the Chicago and Harvard Schools of antitrust have contributed to underinclusive liability norms for dominant-firm behavior);
  • 244
    • 27844475213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exclusionary Conduct After Trinko, 80
    • noting that the Supreme Court has created deliberately underinclusive liability norms for refusals to deal by dominant firms
    • Frank X. Schoen, Exclusionary Conduct After Trinko, 80 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1625, 1647 (2005) (noting that the Supreme Court has created deliberately underinclusive liability norms for refusals to deal by dominant firms).
    • (2005) N.Y.U. L. REV , vol.1625 , pp. 1647
    • Schoen, F.X.1
  • 245
    • 44649185450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally A. Douglas Melamed, Antitrust: The New Regulation, ANTITRUST, Fall 1995, at 13, 13 (discussing the differences between the Law Enforcement Model, an approach to antitrust that focuses on whether past conduct violates legal norms, and the Regulatory Model, which tends to focus more on prospective regulation of the private sector by the government and tends to ask .. . how private entities should behave or how private property could be used to maximize social welfare).
    • See generally A. Douglas Melamed, Antitrust: The New Regulation, ANTITRUST, Fall 1995, at 13, 13 (discussing the differences between the "Law Enforcement Model," an approach to antitrust that focuses on whether past conduct violates legal norms, and the "Regulatory Model," which "tends to focus more on prospective regulation of the private sector by the government" and "tends to ask .. . how private entities should behave or how private property could be used to maximize social welfare").
  • 246
    • 84956547845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 18aa, 2000
    • 15 U.S.C. § 18a(a) (2000).
    • 15 U.S.C
  • 250
    • 44649201968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See E. Thomas Sullivan, The Antitrust Division as a Regulatory Agency: An Enforcement Policy in Transition, 64 WASH. U. L.Q. 997, 1031 (1986) (The [Hart-Scott-Rodino] Act does not change the substantive antitrust law governing the legality of mergers . . . .). Nor does the agency's negotiation of a divestiture package preclude private parties from arguing that the agencies did not go far enough to ensure a competitive market.
    • See E. Thomas Sullivan, The Antitrust Division as a Regulatory Agency: An Enforcement Policy in Transition, 64 WASH. U. L.Q. 997, 1031 (1986) ("The [Hart-Scott-Rodino] Act does not change the substantive antitrust law governing the legality of mergers . . . ."). Nor does the agency's negotiation of a divestiture package preclude private parties from arguing that the agencies did not go far enough to ensure a competitive market.
  • 251
    • 44649105575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Six W. Retail Acquisition, Inc. v. Sony Theatre Mgmt. Corp., No. 97 CIV. 5499(DNE), 2000 WL 264295, at *23 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 9, 2000) (noting that the negotiation of a divestiture package has no prima facie effect in any subsequent private lawsuit).
    • See Six W. Retail Acquisition, Inc. v. Sony Theatre Mgmt. Corp., No. 97 CIV. 5499(DNE), 2000 WL 264295, at *23 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 9, 2000) (noting that the negotiation of a divestiture package "has no prima facie effect in any subsequent private lawsuit").
  • 252
    • 44649189639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sullivan, supra note 172, at 1025-42 (illustrating how the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act's premerger-notification requirement allows the Antitrust Division to review a particular merger's effects and, where those effects implicate anticompetitive concerns, to negotiate with the merging parties to alleviate those concerns).
    • See Sullivan, supra note 172, at 1025-42 (illustrating how the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act's premerger-notification requirement allows the Antitrust Division to review a particular merger's effects and, where those effects implicate anticompetitive concerns, to negotiate with the merging parties to alleviate those concerns).
  • 253
    • 44649125265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 52
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 52.
  • 254
    • 44649161074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sullivan, supra note 172, at 1034-35 (describing the fix it first policy of the Antitrust Division, which favors informal negotiation prior to the consummation of the merger).
    • See Sullivan, supra note 172, at 1034-35 (describing the "fix it first" policy of the Antitrust Division, which favors informal negotiation prior to the consummation of the merger).
  • 255
    • 44649170183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES 1 (rev. ed. 1997), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg.pdf
    • See, e.g., U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM'N, HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES 1 (rev. ed. 1997), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg.pdf
  • 256
    • 44649091096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES] ([These Guidelines] describe the analytical framework and specific standards normally used by the Agency in analyzing mergers. . . . [However,] it is not possible to remove the exercise of judgment from the evaluation of mergers under the antitrust laws.).
    • [hereinafter HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES] ("[These Guidelines] describe the analytical framework and specific standards normally used by the Agency in analyzing mergers. . . . [However,] it is not possible to remove the exercise of judgment from the evaluation of mergers under the antitrust laws.").
  • 257
    • 34250173786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See W. Jonathan Cardi, Über-middlemen: Reshaping the Broken Landscape of Music Copyright, 92 IOWA L. REV. 835, 846-47 (2007) (describing the consent decree negotiated by ASCAP and BMI in response to the Justice Department's investigation into the two organizations' licensing and rate-setting practices);
    • See W. Jonathan Cardi, Über-middlemen: Reshaping the Broken Landscape of Music Copyright, 92 IOWA L. REV. 835, 846-47 (2007) (describing the consent decree negotiated by ASCAP and BMI in response to the Justice Department's investigation into the two organizations' licensing and rate-setting practices);
  • 258
    • 17044413553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Timothy Wu, Copyright's Communications Policy, 103 MICH. L. REV. 278, 304-11 (2004) (detailing how the antitrust litigation of ASCAP and BMI achieved results similar to those of copyright settlements). The essential mechanisms of the modified decree, as applied to BMI, are discussed in United States v. Broadcast Music, Inc., 426 F.3d 91, 95 (2d Cir. 2005). The rate-setting provision is codified in 17 U.S.C. § 513 (2000).
    • Timothy Wu, Copyright's Communications Policy, 103 MICH. L. REV. 278, 304-11 (2004) (detailing how the antitrust litigation of ASCAP and BMI achieved results similar to those of copyright settlements). The essential mechanisms of the modified decree, as applied to BMI, are discussed in United States v. Broadcast Music, Inc., 426 F.3d 91, 95 (2d Cir. 2005). The rate-setting provision is codified in 17 U.S.C. § 513 (2000).
  • 259
    • 44649171432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economic justifications for the BMI and ASCAP system are discussed in Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 4-5 (1979).
    • The economic justifications for the BMI and ASCAP system are discussed in Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 4-5 (1979).
  • 260
    • 44649187740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 261
    • 44649151587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 30 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (Virtually every domestic copyrighted composition is in the repertoire of either ASCAP or BMI.).
    • See id. at 30 (Stevens, J., dissenting) ("Virtually every domestic copyrighted composition is in the repertoire of either ASCAP or BMI.").
  • 262
    • 84919503441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 177, at, describing the antitrust litigation and resulting consent decree, which was modified several times in its forty-year history
    • See Wu, supra note 177, at 304-11 (describing the antitrust litigation and resulting consent decree, which was modified several times in its forty-year history).
    • supra , pp. 304-311
    • Wu1
  • 263
    • 44649139681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Broad. Music, Inc., 426 F.3d at 92 n. 1.
    • E.g., Broad. Music, Inc., 426 F.3d at 92 n. 1.
  • 265
    • 44649196346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In a recent study highly critical of many antitrust consent decrees, Richard Epstein generally approves of the BMI and ASCAP decree as conform[ing, by and large, to the golden rule: Keep consent decrees simple, and tie them to the core violations to which they are directed. RICHARD A. EPSTEIN, ANTITRUST CONSENT DECREES IN THEORY AND PRACTICE: WHY LESS IS MORE 39 2007
    • In a recent study highly critical of many antitrust consent decrees, Richard Epstein generally approves of the BMI and ASCAP decree as "conform[ing], by and large, to the golden rule: Keep consent decrees simple, and tie them to the core violations to which they are directed." RICHARD A. EPSTEIN, ANTITRUST CONSENT DECREES IN THEORY AND PRACTICE: WHY LESS IS MORE 39 (2007).
  • 266
    • 44649164915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Daniel A. Crane, Patent Pools, RAND Commitments, and the Problematics of Price Discrimination, in WORKING WITHIN THE BOUNDARIES OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW (Rochelle Dreyfuss, Diane L. Zimmerman & Harry First eds., forthcoming 2008) (manuscript of chapter at 2-3, on file with author) (describing the voluntary acceptance of RAND commitments by members of standard-setting organizations).
    • See Daniel A. Crane, Patent Pools, RAND Commitments, and the Problematics of Price Discrimination, in WORKING WITHIN THE BOUNDARIES OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW (Rochelle Dreyfuss, Diane L. Zimmerman & Harry First eds., forthcoming 2008) (manuscript of chapter at 2-3, on file with author) (describing the voluntary acceptance of RAND commitments by members of standard-setting organizations).
  • 267
    • 44649119084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (manuscript at 5-6).
    • Id. (manuscript at 5-6).
  • 268
    • 44649148822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (manuscript at 2).
    • Id. (manuscript at 2).
  • 269
    • 44649188997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (manuscript at 11).
    • Id. (manuscript at 11).
  • 270
    • 44649172320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (manuscript at 9-10).
    • Id. (manuscript at 9-10).
  • 271
    • 44649139054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (manuscript at 20-21).
    • Id. (manuscript at 20-21).
  • 272
    • 44649090479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., May, supra note 139, at 445; William T. Mayton, The Possibilities of Collective Choice: Arrow's Theorem, Article I, and the Delegation of Legislative Power to Administrative Agencies, 1986 DUKE L.J. 948, 948 n.4.
    • E.g., May, supra note 139, at 445; William T. Mayton, The Possibilities of Collective Choice: Arrow's Theorem, Article I, and the Delegation of Legislative Power to Administrative Agencies, 1986 DUKE L.J. 948, 948 n.4.
  • 273
    • 44649175542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See May, supra note 139, at 445 (describing Humphrey's Executor v. United States, 295 U.S. 602 (1935) as following [t]he dominant idea. . . that the expertise of the commissioners would primarily guide these essentially nonpolitical agencies).
    • See May, supra note 139, at 445 (describing Humphrey's Executor v. United States, 295 U.S. 602 (1935) as following "[t]he dominant idea. . . that the expertise of the commissioners would primarily guide these essentially nonpolitical agencies").
  • 274
    • 44649188996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 295 U.S. 6021935
    • 295 U.S. 602(1935).
  • 275
    • 44649115631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 618
    • Id. at 618.
  • 276
    • 44649172319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 630-31
    • Id. at 630-31.
  • 277
    • 34247641671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See
    • § 41 2000, Not more than three [out of five] of the Commissioners shall be members of the same political party
    • See 15 U.S.C. § 41 (2000) ("Not more than three [out of five] of the Commissioners shall be members of the same political party.").
    • 15 U.S.C
  • 278
    • 44649163075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ELEANOR M. FOX, LAWRENCE A. SULLIVAN & RUDOLPH J.R. PERITZ, CASES AND MATERIALS ON U.S. ANTITRUST IN GLOBAL CONTEXT 645 (2d ed. 2004) (describing the structure of the Federal Trade Commission).
    • See ELEANOR M. FOX, LAWRENCE A. SULLIVAN & RUDOLPH J.R. PERITZ, CASES AND MATERIALS ON U.S. ANTITRUST IN GLOBAL CONTEXT 645 (2d ed. 2004) (describing the structure of the Federal Trade Commission).
  • 279
    • 44649093751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SKLAR, supra note 13, at 344-45
    • SKLAR, supra note 13, at 344-45.
  • 280
    • 44649125263 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 367, 369.
  • 281
    • 44649152143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 422
    • Id. at 422.
  • 282
    • 44649165533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 25 WOODROW WILSON, A Campaign Address in Sioux City, Iowa, in THE PAPERS OF WOODROW WILSON 148, 154 (Arthur S. Link ed., 1978).
    • 25 WOODROW WILSON, A Campaign Address in Sioux City, Iowa, in THE PAPERS OF WOODROW WILSON 148, 154 (Arthur S. Link ed., 1978).
  • 283
    • 44649121963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The FTC has a separate consumer-protection mission where it does engage in legislative functions, such as promulgating the popular Do Not Call registry in conjunction with the Federal Communications Commission. Telemarketing Sales Rule, 68 Fed. Reg. 4580, 4582 (Jan. 29, 2003), codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 310 (2007).
    • The FTC has a separate consumer-protection mission where it does engage in legislative functions, such as promulgating the popular "Do Not Call" registry in conjunction with the Federal Communications Commission. Telemarketing Sales Rule, 68 Fed. Reg. 4580, 4582 (Jan. 29, 2003), codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 310 (2007).
  • 284
    • 44649103731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FOX, SULLIVAN & PERITZ, supra note 197, at 645.
    • FOX, SULLIVAN & PERITZ, supra note 197, at 645.
  • 285
    • 44649114418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Memorandum of Agreement Between the Federal Trade Commission and the Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice Concerning Clearance Procedures for Investigations March 5, available at
    • See Memorandum of Agreement Between the Federal Trade Commission and the Antitrust Division of the United States Department of Justice Concerning Clearance Procedures for Investigations (March 5, 2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2002/02/clearance/ftcdojagree.pdf.
    • (2002)
  • 286
    • 44649178466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 3-4
    • Id. at 3-4.
  • 287
    • 44649161073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. app.A
    • Id. app.A.
  • 288
    • 38349006616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lauren Kearney Peay, Note, The Cautionary Tale of the Failed 2002 FTC/DOJ Merger Clearance Accord, 60 VAND. L. REV. 1307, 1333-38 (2007) (describing the successful efforts of Senator Ernest F. Hollings in derailing the clearance agreement).
    • See Lauren Kearney Peay, Note, The Cautionary Tale of the Failed 2002 FTC/DOJ Merger Clearance Accord, 60 VAND. L. REV. 1307, 1333-38 (2007) (describing the successful efforts of Senator Ernest F. Hollings in derailing the clearance agreement).
  • 289
    • 44649143696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The FTC has the power to make substantive antitrust rules, subject to various procedural requirements. 15 U.S.C. § 57a 2000, The view that the FTC should engage in more rule making was strongly articulated by administrative law scholar Kenneth Culp Davis during the 1970s
    • The FTC has the power to make substantive antitrust rules, subject to various procedural requirements. 15 U.S.C. § 57a (2000). The view that the FTC should engage in more rule making was strongly articulated by administrative law scholar Kenneth Culp Davis during the 1970s.
  • 290
    • 44649142406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See KENNETH CULP DAVIS, DISCRETIONARY JUSTICE: A PRELIMINARY INQUIRY 70-74 (1969).
    • See KENNETH CULP DAVIS, DISCRETIONARY JUSTICE: A PRELIMINARY INQUIRY 70-74 (1969).
  • 291
    • 44649133088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Jeter v. Credit Bureau, Inc., 760 F.2d 1168, 1174 n.5 (11th Cir. 1985);
    • E.g., Jeter v. Credit Bureau, Inc., 760 F.2d 1168, 1174 n.5 (11th Cir. 1985);
  • 292
    • 44649138411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holloway v. Bristol-Myers Corp., 485 F.2d 986, 987-89 (D.C. Cir. 1973).
    • Holloway v. Bristol-Myers Corp., 485 F.2d 986, 987-89 (D.C. Cir. 1973).
  • 293
    • 77955083322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Guideline Institutionalization: The Role of Merger Guidelines in Antitrust Discourse, 48
    • discussing the fact that the DOJ would not be bound by antitrust prohibitions codified by the FTC, See
    • See Hillary Greene, Guideline Institutionalization: The Role of Merger Guidelines in Antitrust Discourse, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 771, 841 (2006) (discussing the fact that the DOJ would not be bound by antitrust prohibitions codified by the FTC).
    • (2006) WM. & MARY L. REV , vol.771 , pp. 841
    • Greene, H.1
  • 294
    • 44649156174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 92
    • See supra note 92.
  • 295
    • 44649103121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Habermas, Proceduralism and the Private Cause of Action Under Rule 10b-5: The Implications for Democracy, 31
    • discussing the scope of the Rule 10b-5 cause of action, See
    • See Thomas F. McInerney III, Habermas, Proceduralism and the Private Cause of Action Under Rule 10b-5: The Implications for Democracy, 31 CREIGHTON L. REV. 805, 805 (1998) (discussing the scope of the Rule 10b-5 cause of action).
    • (1998) CREIGHTON L. REV , vol.805 , pp. 805
    • McInerney III, T.F.1
  • 296
    • 44649168053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A 1989 report by the American Bar Association found that the FTC had promulgated only one antitrust-specific rule - a prohibition on discriminatory practices in the men's and boys' tailored-clothing industry. ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Report of the American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law Special Committee to Study the Role of the Federal Trade Commission, 58 ANTITRUST L.J. 43, 91 n.103 (1989).
    • A 1989 report by the American Bar Association found that the FTC had promulgated only one antitrust-specific rule - a prohibition on discriminatory practices in the men's and boys' tailored-clothing industry. ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Report of the American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law Special Committee to Study the Role of the Federal Trade Commission, 58 ANTITRUST L.J. 43, 91 n.103 (1989).
  • 298
    • 44649149435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 769-81 (1999) (holding that the FTC's abbreviated rule-of-reason analysis was inadequate to establish anticompetitive advertising);
    • See, e.g., Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 769-81 (1999) (holding that the FTC's abbreviated rule-of-reason analysis was inadequate to establish anticompetitive advertising);
  • 299
    • 44649152141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1076 (11th Cir. 2005) (setting aside an FTC decision that a patent-litigation settlement agreement constituted an unreasonable restraint of trade);
    • Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1076 (11th Cir. 2005) (setting aside an FTC decision that a patent-litigation settlement agreement constituted an unreasonable restraint of trade);
  • 300
    • 44649119083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boise Cascade Corp. v. FTC, 637 F.2d 573, 577-81 (9th Cir. 1980) (determining that the FTC presented insufficient evidence of anticompetitive pricing to establish a violation of the FTC Act);
    • Boise Cascade Corp. v. FTC, 637 F.2d 573, 577-81 (9th Cir. 1980) (determining that the FTC presented insufficient evidence of anticompetitive pricing to establish a violation of the FTC Act);
  • 301
    • 44649192200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d 109, 157-60 (D.D.C. 2004) (rejecting the FTC's theory of tacit coordination to deny a merger of coal companies).
    • FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc., 329 F. Supp. 2d 109, 157-60 (D.D.C. 2004) (rejecting the FTC's theory of tacit coordination to deny a merger of coal companies).
  • 302
    • 44649104315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 21, 38
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 21, 38.
  • 303
    • 44649172065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Daniel A. Crane, Patent Settlements, in ISSUES IN COMPETITION POLICY (Dale Collins ed., forthcoming 2008) (manuscript at 4-6, on file with the Texas Law Review) (addressing the problem of whether pharmaceutical-patent settlements utilizing exit payments result in monopolistic, deadweight losses, or increased incentives for innovation).
    • See generally Daniel A. Crane, Patent Settlements, in ISSUES IN COMPETITION POLICY (Dale Collins ed., forthcoming 2008) (manuscript at 4-6, on file with the Texas Law Review) (addressing the problem of whether pharmaceutical-patent settlements utilizing exit payments result in monopolistic, deadweight losses, or increased incentives for innovation).
  • 304
    • 44649096178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FED. TRADE COMM'N, GENERIC DRUG ENTRY PRIOR TO PATENT EXPIRATION: AN FTC STUDY (2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/genericdrugstudy.pdf.
    • See FED. TRADE COMM'N, GENERIC DRUG ENTRY PRIOR TO PATENT EXPIRATION: AN FTC STUDY (2002), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/genericdrugstudy.pdf.
  • 306
    • 44649147566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See In re Schering-Plough Corp., No. 9297, 2003 WL 22989651 (F.T.C. Dec. 8, 2003), vacated sub nom. Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056.
    • See In re Schering-Plough Corp., No. 9297, 2003 WL 22989651 (F.T.C. Dec. 8, 2003), vacated sub nom. Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056.
  • 307
    • 44649148820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See SEC v. Chenery Corp. (Chenery II), 332 U.S. 194, 201-02 (1947) (permitting the practice of agency adjudicatory rule making).
    • See SEC v. Chenery Corp. (Chenery II), 332 U.S. 194, 201-02 (1947) (permitting the practice of agency adjudicatory rule making).
  • 308
    • 44649135928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Commission Rules Schering-Plough, Upsher, and AHP Illegally Delayed Entry of Lower-Cost Generic Drug (Dec. 18, 2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/12/ schering.shtm ([T]he Commission's order announced today applies only to Schering and Upsher. The order broadly prohibits litigation settlements under which a generic manufacturer 'receives anything of value' and agrees itself to defer its own research and development, production, or sales activities.).
    • See Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm'n, Commission Rules Schering-Plough, Upsher, and AHP Illegally Delayed Entry of Lower-Cost Generic Drug (Dec. 18, 2003), available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2003/12/ schering.shtm ("[T]he Commission's order announced today applies only to Schering and Upsher. The order broadly prohibits litigation settlements under which a generic manufacturer 'receives anything of value' and agrees itself to defer its own research and development, production, or sales activities.").
  • 309
    • 44649141740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1076 (11th Cir. 2005). The United States Supreme Court denied the FTC's petition for certiorari upon the recommendation of the Solicitor General's office, doubtlessly creating some friction between the Justice Department and the FTC. See FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 126
    • denying certiorari, Schering-Plough Corp
    • Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1076 (11th Cir. 2005). The United States Supreme Court denied the FTC's petition for certiorari upon the recommendation of the Solicitor General's office, doubtlessly creating some friction between the Justice Department and the FTC. See FTC v. Schering-Plough Corp., 126 S. Ct. 2929 (2006) (denying certiorari);
    • (2006) S. Ct , vol.2929
  • 310
    • 44649166810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae, FTC, 126 S. Ct. 2929 (No. 05-273) (arguing for denial of certiorari).
    • Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae, FTC, 126 S. Ct. 2929 (No. 05-273) (arguing for denial of certiorari).
  • 311
    • 44649190990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schering-Plough Corp., 402 F.3d at 1063 (beginning its legal analysis with the framework established in Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1312-13 (11th Cir. 2003)).
    • See Schering-Plough Corp., 402 F.3d at 1063 (beginning its legal analysis with the framework established in Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1312-13 (11th Cir. 2003)).
  • 312
    • 44649095518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Valley Drug Co., 344 F.3d at 1295-96 (introducing the case as a private antitrust lawsuit, or rather numerous private antitrust lawsuits, brought against three pharmaceuticals manufacturers).
    • See Valley Drug Co., 344 F.3d at 1295-96 (introducing the case as "a private antitrust lawsuit, or rather numerous private antitrust lawsuits, brought against three pharmaceuticals manufacturers").
  • 313
    • 44649083569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schering-Plough Corp., 402 F.3dat 1064, 1066-67, 1068 n.18, 1073, 1075 n.26, 1076.
    • Schering-Plough Corp., 402 F.3dat 1064, 1066-67, 1068 n.18, 1073, 1075 n.26, 1076.
  • 314
    • 44649187739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geneva Pharm., Inc
    • Valley Drug Co. v
    • Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharm., Inc., 344 F.3d 1294, 1312-13 (11th Cir. 2003).
    • (2003) 344 F.3d 1294, 1312-13 (11th Cir
  • 315
    • 44649096179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Compare Valley Drug Co., 344 F.3d 1294 (issuing its opinion in a private antitrust suit on September 15, 2003), with In re Schering-Plough Corp., No. 9297, 2003 WL 22989651 (F.T.C. Dec. 8, 2003) (announcing the $2 million limit on reverse payments for the first time on December 8, 2003), vacated sub nom. Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056.
    • Compare Valley Drug Co., 344 F.3d 1294 (issuing its opinion in a private antitrust suit on September 15, 2003), with In re Schering-Plough Corp., No. 9297, 2003 WL 22989651 (F.T.C. Dec. 8, 2003) (announcing the $2 million limit on reverse payments for the first time on December 8, 2003), vacated sub nom. Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056.
  • 316
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 168-74 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 168-74 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 317
    • 44649146323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., supra note 131 and accompanying text (describing a jury's particular strength in determining intent, truthfulness, knowledge, and moral culpability-necessary determinations in a criminal enforcement proceeding-and discussing the jury's role in price-fixing prosecution of executives from the auction houses of Sotheby's and Christie's).
    • See, e.g., supra note 131 and accompanying text (describing a jury's particular strength in determining intent, truthfulness, knowledge, and moral culpability-necessary determinations in a criminal enforcement proceeding-and discussing the jury's role in price-fixing prosecution of executives from the auction houses of Sotheby's and Christie's).
  • 318
    • 44649176823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thomas O. Barnett, Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Presentation at the Georgetown Law Global Antitrust Enforcement Symposium: Global Antitrust Enforcement 1-2 (Sept. 26, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/226334.pdf (Here in the United States, prosecuting cartel offenses-and deterring the formation of cartels and the activities of cartelists - continues to be our highest priority.).
    • See Thomas O. Barnett, Assistant Att'y Gen., Antitrust Div., U.S. Dep't of Justice, Presentation at the Georgetown Law Global Antitrust Enforcement Symposium: Global Antitrust Enforcement 1-2 (Sept. 26, 2007), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/226334.pdf ("Here in the United States, prosecuting cartel offenses-and deterring the formation of cartels and the activities of cartelists - continues to be our highest priority.").
  • 319
    • 44649165531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Knevelbaard Dairies v. Kraft Foods, Inc., 232 F.3d 979, 986 (9th Cir. 2000) (discussing price-fixing agreements as per se antitrust violations).
    • See Knevelbaard Dairies v. Kraft Foods, Inc., 232 F.3d 979, 986 (9th Cir. 2000) (discussing price-fixing agreements as per se antitrust violations).
  • 320
    • 44649112903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. (When a per se violation such as horizontal price fixing has occurred, there is no need to define a relevant market or to show that the defendants had power within the market).
    • See, e.g., id. ("When a per se violation such as horizontal price fixing has occurred, there is no need to define a relevant market or to show that the defendants had power within the market").
  • 321
    • 84886336150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 123-31 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 123-31 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 322
    • 44649103730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Broad. Music, Inc. v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 8 (1979) (describing price-fixing agreements as illegal per se because they are so plainly anticompetitive, and so often lack . . . any redeeming virtue (citations and internal quotation marks omitted));
    • See, e.g., Broad. Music, Inc. v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1, 8 (1979) (describing price-fixing agreements as illegal per se because they "are so plainly anticompetitive, and so often lack . . . any redeeming virtue" (citations and internal quotation marks omitted));
  • 323
    • 17244376322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Restraints and Antitrust Policy, 72
    • describing price fixing as entirely lacking in possible redeeming economic virtues
    • Richard A. Posner, Vertical Restraints and Antitrust Policy, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 229, 241 (2005) (describing price fixing as "entirely lacking in possible redeeming economic virtues").
    • (2005) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.229 , pp. 241
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 324
    • 33947712364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Hart-Scott-Rodino premerger notification system that tends to limit criminal enforcement by federal authorities does not restrict private litigants, note 82 and accompanying text
    • The Hart-Scott-Rodino premerger notification system that tends to limit criminal enforcement by federal authorities does not restrict private litigants. See supra note 82 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 325
    • 44649150060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, Switzerland, which does not have a general antitrust law, enacted an anticartel statute effective April 1, 2004. J. Anthony Chavez, The Carrot and the Stick Approach to Antitrust Enforcement, in 2 47TH ANNUAL ANTITRUST LAW INSTITUTE 519, 531 (PLI Corporate Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series No. B-1542, 2006).
    • For example, Switzerland, which does not have a general antitrust law, enacted an anticartel statute effective April 1, 2004. J. Anthony Chavez, The Carrot and the Stick Approach to Antitrust Enforcement, in 2 47TH ANNUAL ANTITRUST LAW INSTITUTE 519, 531 (PLI Corporate Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series No. B-1542, 2006).
  • 326
    • 84886336150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 168-74 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 168-74 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 327
    • 84956547845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 15a, 2000
    • 15 U.S.C. § 15(a) (2000).
    • 15 U.S.C
  • 328
    • 0036921969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Robert Pitofsky, Donna Patterson & Jonathan Hooks, The Essential Facilities Doctrine Under U.S. Antitrust Law, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 443, 443-45 (2002) (describing problems arising from the essential facilities doctrine).
    • See generally Robert Pitofsky, Donna Patterson & Jonathan Hooks, The Essential Facilities Doctrine Under U.S. Antitrust Law, 70 ANTITRUST L.J. 443, 443-45 (2002) (describing problems arising from the "essential facilities" doctrine).
  • 329
    • 44649110047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 31-32 (2006) (explaining that upon incorporation of petitioners' patented components into printers, manufacturers were required to purchase unpatented ink exclusively from petitioners).
    • See, e.g., Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 31-32 (2006) (explaining that upon incorporation of petitioners' patented components into printers, manufacturers were required to purchase unpatented ink exclusively from petitioners).
  • 330
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 185-90 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 185-90 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 331
    • 44649188992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 60-62 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (describing license provisions prohibiting manufacturers from removing desktop icons, altering the initial boot sequence, and altering the appearance of the desktop).
    • See, e.g., United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 60-62 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (describing license provisions prohibiting manufacturers from removing desktop icons, altering the initial boot sequence, and altering the appearance of the desktop).
  • 332
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 185-90 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 185-90 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 333
    • 44649095517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 185 (manuscript at 20, 23).
    • Crane, supra note 185 (manuscript at 20, 23).
  • 334
    • 44649165530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (manuscript at 24).
    • Id. (manuscript at 24).
  • 335
    • 44649203250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These are essentially the facts of Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 207 F.3d 1039, 1044 (8th Cir. 2000).
    • These are essentially the facts of Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 207 F.3d 1039, 1044 (8th Cir. 2000).
  • 336
    • 44649198214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., FED. TRADE COMM'N, MEDICARE PRESCRIPTION DRUG AND IMPROVEMENT ACT REQUIRES DRUG COMPANIES TO FILE CERTAIN AGREEMENTS WITH THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION AND U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE (2004), http://www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/040106pharmrules.pdf (highlighting the filing requirement for certain agreements made by brand-namedrug manufacturers and generic-drug applicants).
    • See, e.g., FED. TRADE COMM'N, MEDICARE PRESCRIPTION DRUG AND IMPROVEMENT ACT REQUIRES DRUG COMPANIES TO FILE CERTAIN AGREEMENTS WITH THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION AND U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE (2004), http://www.ftc.gov/os/2004/01/040106pharmrules.pdf (highlighting the filing requirement for certain agreements made by brand-namedrug manufacturers and generic-drug applicants).
  • 337
    • 44649107499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 149, 191-213 and accompanying text.
    • See supra notes 149, 191-213 and accompanying text.
  • 338
    • 44649167449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Res. Def Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 865-66 (1984) (holding that courts should generally defer to agency interpretation of ambiguous statutes). There is also a weaker form of deference-Skidmore deference, which is based on the Supreme Court's decision in Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 323 U.S. 134 (1944) and applies when the agency's decision has power to persuade because of its thoroughness . .. , the validity of its reasoning, [and] its consistency with earlier and later pronouncements.
    • See generally Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Res. Def Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 865-66 (1984) (holding that courts should generally defer to agency interpretation of ambiguous statutes). There is also a weaker form of deference-"Skidmore deference," which is based on the Supreme Court's decision in Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 323 U.S. 134 (1944) and applies when the agency's decision has "power to persuade" because of its "thoroughness . .. , the validity of its reasoning, [and] its consistency with earlier and later pronouncements."
  • 339
    • 0036018163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronald M. Levin, Mead and the Prospective Executive of Discretion, 54 ADMIN. L. REV. 771, 772 (2002)
    • Ronald M. Levin, Mead and the Prospective Executive of Discretion, 54 ADMIN. L. REV. 771, 772 (2002)
  • 340
    • 44649130534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (quoting Skidmore, 323 U.S. at 140).
    • (quoting Skidmore, 323 U.S. at 140).
  • 341
    • 44649085465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Estiverne v. Sak's Fifth Ave., 9 F.3d 1171, 1173 (5th Cir. 1993) (according Chevron deference to FTC commentary and interpretative readings under the Fair Credit Reporting Act).
    • See, e.g., Estiverne v. Sak's Fifth Ave., 9 F.3d 1171, 1173 (5th Cir. 1993) (according Chevron deference to FTC commentary and interpretative readings under the Fair Credit Reporting Act).
  • 342
    • 44649124071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mainstream Mktg. Servs., Inc. v. FTC, 358 F.3d 1228, 1236 (10th Cir. 2004).
    • Mainstream Mktg. Servs., Inc. v. FTC, 358 F.3d 1228, 1236 (10th Cir. 2004).
  • 343
    • 44649119721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mattox v. FTC, 752 F.2d 116, 123-25 (5th Cir. 1985) (deferring to the FTC's interpretation of the document-privacy provisions of the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act).
    • See Mattox v. FTC, 752 F.2d 116, 123-25 (5th Cir. 1985) (deferring to the FTC's interpretation of the document-privacy provisions of the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act).
  • 344
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 220-27 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 220-27 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 345
    • 34548702657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Lisa Schultz Bressman, Deference and Democracy, 75 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 761, 762 (2007) (In recent cases ... the Court has not displayed unwavering commitment to the Chevron decision or its principle.); Levin, supra note 250, at 779 ([T]he Supreme Court's actual administration of. .. deference has been far from tidy or predictable.);
    • See generally Lisa Schultz Bressman, Deference and Democracy, 75 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 761, 762 (2007) ("In recent cases ... the Court has not displayed unwavering commitment to the Chevron decision or its principle."); Levin, supra note 250, at 779 ("[T]he Supreme Court's actual administration of. .. deference has been far from tidy or predictable.");
  • 346
    • 0346403923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas W. Merrill & Kristin E. Hickman, Chevron's Domain, 89 GEO. L.J. 833, 835 (2001) (Little effort has been made to spell out what Congress must do to charge an agency with a statute's administration, or what sorts of agency interpretations qualify for Chevron deference once an agency has been so charged.);
    • Thomas W. Merrill & Kristin E. Hickman, Chevron's Domain, 89 GEO. L.J. 833, 835 (2001) ("Little effort has been made to spell out what Congress must do to charge an agency with a statute's administration, or what sorts of agency interpretations qualify for Chevron deference once an agency has been so charged.");
  • 347
    • 0036018161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas W. Merrill, The Mead Doctrine: Rules and Standards, Meta-rules and Metastandards, 54 ADMIN. L. REV. 807, 813 (2002) (arguing that while Mead provided important clarifications of Chevron, the decision left major uncertainties, such as when a particular agency interpretation has the force of law, thereby triggering Chevron deference);
    • Thomas W. Merrill, The Mead Doctrine: Rules and Standards, Meta-rules and Metastandards, 54 ADMIN. L. REV. 807, 813 (2002) (arguing that while Mead provided important clarifications of Chevron, the decision left major uncertainties, such as when a particular agency interpretation has the force of law, thereby triggering Chevron deference);
  • 348
    • 33744467723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Chevron Step Zero, 92 VA. L. REV. 187, 190 (2006) (In the last fifteen years,... the simplest interpretations of Chevron have unraveled. . . . [T]he result has ... produc[ed] not only a decrease in agency authority, but also a significant increase in uncertainty about the appropriate approach.).
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Chevron Step Zero, 92 VA. L. REV. 187, 190 (2006) ("In the last fifteen years,... the simplest interpretations of Chevron have unraveled. . . . [T]he result has ... produc[ed] not only a decrease in agency authority, but also a significant increase in uncertainty about the appropriate approach.").
  • 350
    • 57049140677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 143 and accompanying text discussing antitrust law as a form of federal common law
    • See supra note 143 and accompanying text (discussing antitrust law as a form of federal common law).
    • See supra
  • 351
    • 44649120670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co., 405 U.S. 233, 240 (1972) (citing the FTC Act's legislative history indicating that Congress deliberately avoided enumeration of unfair trade practices, preferring to leave it to the commission to determine what practices were unfair (quoting S. REP. No. 63-597, at 13 (1914))).
    • See, e.g., FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co., 405 U.S. 233, 240 (1972) (citing the FTC Act's legislative history indicating that Congress deliberately avoided enumeration of unfair trade practices, preferring to "leave it to the commission to determine what practices were unfair" (quoting S. REP. No. 63-597, at 13 (1914))).
  • 352
    • 44649146946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 843 n.9 (1984) (The judiciary is the final authority on issues of statutory construction and must reject administrative constructions which are contrary to clear congressional intent).
    • See Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 843 n.9 (1984) ("The judiciary is the final authority on issues of statutory construction and must reject administrative constructions which are contrary to clear congressional intent").
  • 353
    • 44649172316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sunstein, supra note 255, at 199 describing post-Chevron case law that seemed to argue for deferential review of agency interpretations of law but stringent judicial review of agency judgments about policy
    • See Sunstein, supra note 255, at 199 (describing post-Chevron case law that "seemed to argue for deferential review of agency interpretations of law but stringent judicial review of agency judgments about policy").
  • 354
    • 44649166190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arguably, the need for judicial deference to an administrative decision is greater when the statute is vague - that is to say, susceptible to a variety of possible meanings - than when it is ambiguous - susceptible to two different meanings. See Michael Herz, Deference Running Riot: Separating Interpretation and Lawmaking Under Chevron, 6 ADMIN. L.J. AM. U. 187, 207 n.108 (1992) (discussing Chevron deference and the distinction between vagueness and ambiguity).
    • Arguably, the need for judicial deference to an administrative decision is greater when the statute is vague - that is to say, susceptible to a variety of possible meanings - than when it is ambiguous - susceptible to two different meanings. See Michael Herz, Deference Running Riot: Separating Interpretation and Lawmaking Under Chevron, 6 ADMIN. L.J. AM. U. 187, 207 n.108 (1992) (discussing Chevron deference and the distinction between vagueness and ambiguity).
  • 355
    • 44649105574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Whether or not this is the case is an open question. See Bressman, supra note 255, at 786-87 (explaining that many scholars have justified Chevron as a doctrine based on congressional intent but explaining that there is doubt as to whether that account is complete).
    • Whether or not this is the case is an open question. See Bressman, supra note 255, at 786-87 (explaining that many scholars have justified Chevron as a doctrine based on congressional intent but explaining that there is doubt as to whether that account is complete).
  • 356
    • 44649128401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Levin, supra note 250, at 773 (arguing that when an agency has the power to implement a statute with the force of law, t]he 'format' or procedural vehicle in which such an administrative interpretation appears should not matter, Although Chevron deference may only apply to agency decisions that have the force of law, United States v. Mead Corp, 533 U.S. 218, 226-27 2001, this should not be an obstacle for the FTC. Cass Sunstein has asserted that the FTC's rules do not have the force of law because the Commission issues orders that cannot be enforced without a judicial proceeding, Sunstein, supra note 255, at 223, but this is probably a mistaken view of legal effectiveness of the FTC's orders. Since 1973, violations of the FTC's orders, whether or not those orders have been confirmed by a court, give rise to strict liability for fines
    • See Levin, supra note 250, at 773 (arguing that when an agency has the power to implement a statute with the force of law, "[t]he 'format' or procedural vehicle in which such an administrative interpretation appears should not matter"). Although Chevron deference may only apply to agency decisions that have the "force of law," United States v. Mead Corp., 533 U.S. 218, 226-27 (2001), this should not be an obstacle for the FTC. Cass Sunstein has asserted that "the FTC's rules do not have the force of law" because the Commission issues orders that cannot be enforced without a judicial proceeding, Sunstein, supra note 255, at 223, but this is probably a mistaken view of legal effectiveness of the FTC's orders. Since 1973, violations of the FTC's orders, whether or not those orders have been confirmed by a court, give rise to strict liability for fines.
  • 357
    • 44649102448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Merrill & Hickman, supra note 255, at 890-91 (describing legislative changes that made FTC's orders self-enforcing and hence binding with the force of law for Chevron purposes).
    • See Merrill & Hickman, supra note 255, at 890-91 (describing legislative changes that made FTC's orders self-enforcing and hence binding with the force of law for Chevron purposes).
  • 358
    • 44649198215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ABA Section of Antitrust Law, supra note 213, at 91 n.103 ([W]e are not optimistic about the chances that the FTC could codify antitrust-oriented prohibitions on specific types of business conduct.);
    • See ABA Section of Antitrust Law, supra note 213, at 91 n.103 ("[W]e are not optimistic about the chances that the FTC could codify antitrust-oriented prohibitions on specific types of business conduct.");
  • 359
    • 49249133863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mark A. Lemley & Christopher R. Leslie, Categorical Analysis in Antitrust Jurisprudence, 93 IOWA L. REV (forthcoming 2008) (manuscript at 22-23, on file with author) (arguing against categorical antitrust decision making in certain contexts).
    • Mark A. Lemley & Christopher R. Leslie, Categorical Analysis in Antitrust Jurisprudence, 93 IOWA L. REV (forthcoming 2008) (manuscript at 22-23, on file with author) (arguing against categorical antitrust decision making in certain contexts).
  • 360
    • 44649103726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crane, note 161, at, arguing that on many issues, rules can and should play an important role in antitrust
    • See Crane, supra note 161, at 98-101 (arguing that on many issues, rules can and should play an important role in antitrust).
    • supra , pp. 98-101
  • 361
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 220-22 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 220-22 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 362
    • 44649182576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard W. Murphy, Judicial Deference, Agency Commitment, and Force of Law, 66 OHIO ST. L.J. 1013, 1052-53 (2005) (arguing that Chevron deference should only apply when agency interpretations are meant to be of general applicability).
    • See Richard W. Murphy, Judicial Deference, Agency Commitment, and Force of Law, 66 OHIO ST. L.J. 1013, 1052-53 (2005) (arguing that Chevron deference should only apply when agency interpretations are meant to be of general applicability).
  • 363
    • 44649183189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 129 (2007), available at http://www.amc.gov/report_recommendation/amc_final_report.pdf.
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, REPORT AND RECOMMENDATIONS 129 (2007), available at http://www.amc.gov/report_recommendation/amc_final_report.pdf.
  • 364
    • 44649158141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The FTC describes its own powers as for the most part, co-extensive with the Sherman Act. In re Schering-Plough Corp., No. 9297, 2003 WL 22989651, at n.107 (F.T.C. Dec. 8, 2007), vacated sub nom. Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
    • The FTC describes its own powers as "for the most part, co-extensive with the Sherman Act." In re Schering-Plough Corp., No. 9297, 2003 WL 22989651, at n.107 (F.T.C. Dec. 8, 2007), vacated sub nom. Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
  • 365
    • 33645752468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kevin M. Stack, The President's Statutory Authority to Administer the Laws, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 263, 292 n.129 (2006) (collecting cases).
    • See Kevin M. Stack, The President's Statutory Authority to Administer the Laws, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 263, 292 n.129 (2006) (collecting cases).
  • 366
    • 44649164912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The congressionally appointed Antitrust Modernization Commission recently considered the possibility of consolidating antitrust enforcement in a single agency and recommended against such consolidation over the dissent of three out of twelve commissioners. See ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, supra note 268, at 129-32 (acknowledging criticism of the system of dual enforcement but recommending no comprehensive changes because the costs of moving to a single-agency system would outweigh the benefits).
    • The congressionally appointed Antitrust Modernization Commission recently considered the possibility of consolidating antitrust enforcement in a single agency and recommended against such consolidation over the dissent of three out of twelve commissioners. See ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, supra note 268, at 129-32 (acknowledging criticism of the system of dual enforcement but recommending no comprehensive changes because the costs of moving to a single-agency system would outweigh the benefits).
  • 367
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 205-06 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 205-06 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 368
    • 44649198471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mclnerney, supra note 212, at 807-08 (describing how Rule 10b-5 came to create an implied cause of action enforceable in private litigation).
    • See Mclnerney, supra note 212, at 807-08 (describing how Rule 10b-5 came to create an implied cause of action enforceable in private litigation).
  • 369
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 209 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 209 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 370
    • 44649196976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Schering decision, discussed supra notes 223-27 and accompanying text, is a recent example of a court rejecting the FTC's interpretation of the FTC Act based on an earlier Sherman Act decision in private litigation. Other similar decisions are discussed in Crane, supra note 25, at 41-42.
    • The Schering decision, discussed supra notes 223-27 and accompanying text, is a recent example of a court rejecting the FTC's interpretation of the FTC Act based on an earlier Sherman Act decision in private litigation. Other similar decisions are discussed in Crane, supra note 25, at 41-42.
  • 371
    • 44649149434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 41-42
    • Crane, supra note 25, at 41-42.
  • 372
    • 44649139051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 373
    • 44649152140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In theory, at least, the courts' past interpretations of the antitrust statutes should not override the FTC's reasonable interpretation of the FTC Act. See Nat'l Cable & Telecomms. Ass'n v. Brand X Internet Servs, 545 U.S. 967, 982 2005, holding that a court's prior judicial construction of a statute trumps an agency's construction only if the prior court decision holds that its construction follows from the unambiguous terms of the statute and thus leaves no room for agency discretion, But this assumes that the courts are viewing the FTC's creation of antitrust liability rules through the lens of Chevron deference, which does not appear to be the case
    • In theory, at least, the courts' past interpretations of the antitrust statutes should not override the FTC's reasonable interpretation of the FTC Act. See Nat'l Cable & Telecomms. Ass'n v. Brand X Internet Servs., 545 U.S. 967, 982 (2005) (holding that a court's prior judicial construction of a statute trumps an agency's construction "only if the prior court decision holds that its construction follows from the unambiguous terms of the statute and thus leaves no room for agency discretion"). But this assumes that the courts are viewing the FTC's creation of antitrust liability rules through the lens of Chevron deference, which does not appear to be the case.
  • 374
    • 44649176205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In one sense, giving the FTC a greater norm-creation role at the expense of Article III courts would seem to be a countertechnocratic move. Insofar as technocratic solutions aim to insulate decision makers from popular political pressure, Article III judges with life tenure seem to be more insulated than FTC commissioners. Further, administrative law, unlike the judicial process, typically requires public consultation through notice and comment
    • In one sense, giving the FTC a greater norm-creation role at the expense of Article III courts would seem to be a countertechnocratic move. Insofar as technocratic solutions aim to insulate decision makers from popular political pressure, Article III judges with life tenure seem to be more insulated than FTC commissioners. Further, administrative law, unlike the judicial process, typically requires public consultation through notice and comment.
  • 375
    • 44649200332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 5 U.S.C. §§ 552-553 (2000). So it is possible that judicial norm creation is more politically insulated whereas administrative decision making is more specialized, which would result in the courts and agencies splitting attributes of technocracy as I have defined them. However, as described above, judicial norm creation is untechnocratic insofar as Article III courts borrow antitrust norms heavily from their experiences with private litigation, which is driven by private interests and occur under the shadow of populist juries.
    • See 5 U.S.C. §§ 552-553 (2000). So it is possible that judicial norm creation is more politically insulated whereas administrative decision making is more specialized, which would result in the courts and agencies splitting attributes of technocracy as I have defined them. However, as described above, judicial norm creation is untechnocratic insofar as Article III courts borrow antitrust norms heavily from their experiences with private litigation, which is driven by private interests and occur under the shadow of populist juries.
  • 376
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 208-27 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 208-27 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 377
    • 44649176821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Laws of Fear, 115
    • book review
    • Cass R. Sunstein, The Laws of Fear, 115 HARV. L. REV. 1119, 1164-65 (2002) (book review).
    • (2002) HARV. L. REV , vol.1119 , pp. 1164-1165
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 378
    • 44649193685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 1 (reporting that consensus has been reached on the goals of antitrust law); Cavanagh, supra note 48, at 220 (Over the last fifteen years, a bipartisan consensus has emerged regarding the goals of antitrust enforcement.);
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 1 (reporting that consensus has been reached on the goals of antitrust law); Cavanagh, supra note 48, at 220 ("Over the last fifteen years, a bipartisan consensus has emerged regarding the goals of antitrust enforcement.");
  • 379
    • 44649193684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert T. Pitofsky, Antitrust at the Turn of the Twenty-first Century: A View from the Middle, 76 ST. JOHN'S L. REV. 583, 583 (2002) (noting the broad 'convergence' of antitrust thinking in the United States).
    • Robert T. Pitofsky, Antitrust at the Turn of the Twenty-first Century: A View from the Middle, 76 ST. JOHN'S L. REV. 583, 583 (2002) (noting the broad "'convergence' of antitrust thinking in the United States").
  • 380
    • 44649088110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 15-45 (1978) (detailing the history of antitrust policy in the United States);
    • See ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 15-45 (1978) (detailing the history of antitrust policy in the United States);
  • 381
    • 44649105573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 1-2 (remarking on a few of the early antitrust-policy goals that were directly at odds with consumer welfare);
    • HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 1-2 (remarking on a few of the early antitrust-policy goals that were directly at odds with consumer welfare);
  • 382
    • 0040339507 scopus 로고
    • Distributive Justice and the Antitrust Laws, 51
    • describing a few of the wide variety of alternative policy goals for antitrust law
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Distributive Justice and the Antitrust Laws, 51 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 1, 1 (1982) (describing a few of the "wide variety" of alternative policy goals for antitrust law);
    • (1982) GEO. WASH. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 1
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 383
    • 0346877185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 50
    • articulating alternative purposes served by the existence of antitrust laws
    • Robert H. Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 50 HASTINGS L.J. 871, 911-35 (1999) (articulating alternative purposes served by the existence of antitrust laws).
    • (1999) HASTINGS L.J , vol.871 , pp. 911-935
    • Lande, R.H.1
  • 384
    • 44649106829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the legislative history of the Sherman Act, see WILLIAM LETWIN, LAW AND ECONOMIC POLICY IN AMERICA: THE EVOLUTION OF THE SHERMAN ANTITRUST ACT 53-99 (1965), which traces the history of the Sherman Act's passage.
    • On the legislative history of the Sherman Act, see WILLIAM LETWIN, LAW AND ECONOMIC POLICY IN AMERICA: THE EVOLUTION OF THE SHERMAN ANTITRUST ACT 53-99 (1965), which traces the history of the Sherman Act's passage.
  • 385
    • 44649099996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, supra note 268, at 35-36;
    • ANTITRUST MODERNIZATION COMM'N, supra note 268, at 35-36;
  • 386
    • 44649088763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also HOVENKAMP, note 99, at, stating that there is a broad consensus about the goals of antitrust law, the primary goal being the protection of consumers
    • see also HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 1 (stating that there is a broad consensus about the goals of antitrust law, the primary goal being the protection of consumers);
    • supra , pp. 1
  • 387
    • 44649148819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 2 (2d ed. 2001) ([T]he only goal of antitrust law should be to promote efficiency in the economic sense . . . .);
    • RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW 2 (2d ed. 2001) ("[T]he only goal of antitrust law should be to promote efficiency in the economic sense . . . .");
  • 388
    • 44649172939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas O. Barnett, Substantial Lessening of Competition-The Section 7 Standard, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 293, 295-96 (One critical development during the last thirty years of antitrust enforcement has been the consensus that antitrust should focus on consumer welfare.);
    • Thomas O. Barnett, Substantial Lessening of Competition-The Section 7 Standard, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 293, 295-96 ("One critical development during the last thirty years of antitrust enforcement has been the consensus that antitrust should focus on consumer welfare.");
  • 389
    • 0040130485 scopus 로고
    • Monopoly Power and Market Power in Antitrust Law, 76
    • arguing that a consensus is emerging that antitrust law should protect consumer welfare
    • Thomas G. Krattenmaker et al., Monopoly Power and Market Power in Antitrust Law, 76 GEO. L.J. 241, 244 (1987) (arguing that a consensus is emerging that antitrust law should protect consumer welfare).
    • (1987) GEO. L.J , vol.241 , pp. 244
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1
  • 390
    • 44649175539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Williamson, supra note 153, at 18-19
    • Williamson, supra note 153, at 18-19.
  • 391
    • 44649184795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Barnett, supra note 283, at 297 (illustrating this principle with a graph entitled Welfare: Producers Gain and Consumers Lose). Barnett, who is currently the Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division, reports that the consumer welfare and total welfare standards can diverge, although I think it is a rare case in practice. Id.
    • See, e.g., Barnett, supra note 283, at 297 (illustrating this principle with a graph entitled "Welfare: Producers Gain and Consumers Lose"). Barnett, who is currently the Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division, reports that "the consumer welfare and total welfare standards can diverge, although I think it is a rare case in practice." Id.
  • 392
    • 44649148209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 11 (describing the history of U.S. antitrust law as overly ideological).
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 11 (describing the history of U.S. antitrust law as "overly ideological").
  • 393
    • 44649171431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally RUDOLPH J.R. PERITZ, COMPETITION POLICY IN AMERICA, 1888-1992: HISTORY, RHETORIC, LAW (1996) (chronicling the course of competition policy with respect to freedom from both government and private economic power through six eras in American history).
    • See generally RUDOLPH J.R. PERITZ, COMPETITION POLICY IN AMERICA, 1888-1992: HISTORY, RHETORIC, LAW (1996) (chronicling the course of competition policy with respect to freedom from both government and private economic power through six eras in American history).
  • 394
    • 0040519649 scopus 로고
    • Ideological Conflict and the Origins of Antitrust Policy, 66
    • noting Americans' dissatisfaction with the laissez-faire approach and the subsequent growth of interventionist reform movements and their supporting ideologies, See
    • See William H. Page, Ideological Conflict and the Origins of Antitrust Policy, 66 TUL. L. REV. 1, 28-29 (1991) (noting Americans' dissatisfaction with the laissez-faire approach and the subsequent growth of interventionist reform movements and their supporting ideologies).
    • (1991) TUL. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 28-29
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 395
    • 0002349749 scopus 로고
    • The Political Content of Antitrust, 127
    • Robert Pitofsky, The Political Content of Antitrust, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 1051, 1051 (1979).
    • (1979) U. PA. L. REV , vol.1051 , pp. 1051
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 396
    • 0000575129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Beyond Competition: Market Failures, Total Welfare, and the Challenge of Intramarket Second-Best Tradeoffs, 98
    • detailing the alternative benefits and drawbacks that must be weighed during the application of antitrust law, See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Peter J. Hammer, Antitrust Beyond Competition: Market Failures, Total Welfare, and the Challenge of Intramarket Second-Best Tradeoffs, 98 MICH. L. REV. 849, 853-67 (2000) (detailing the alternative benefits and drawbacks that must be weighed during the application of antitrust law);
    • (2000) MICH. L. REV , vol.849 , pp. 853-867
    • Hammer, P.J.1
  • 397
    • 44649125873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also BORK, supra note 282, at 80, 79-80 (describing [v]alue trade-offs in antitrust litigation).
    • see also BORK, supra note 282, at 80, 79-80 (describing "[v]alue trade-offs in antitrust litigation").
  • 398
    • 34248538397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Authorized Generics: A Prescription for Hatch-Waxman Reform, 93
    • discussing the competitive harms of authorized generics, See generally
    • See generally Thomas Chen, Authorized Generics: A Prescription for Hatch-Waxman Reform, 93 VA. L. REV. 459, 478-86 (2007) (discussing the competitive harms of authorized generics).
    • (2007) VA. L. REV , vol.459 , pp. 478-486
    • Chen, T.1
  • 399
    • 84935415626 scopus 로고
    • Public Administration and Public Deliberation: An Interpretive Essay, 94
    • Robert B. Reich, Public Administration and Public Deliberation: An Interpretive Essay, 94 YALE L.J. 1617, 1637 (1985).
    • (1985) YALE L.J , vol.1617 , pp. 1637
    • Reich, R.B.1
  • 401
    • 44649112901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1633
    • Id. at 1633.
  • 402
    • 44649202616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • Id. at 1632-33.
  • 403
    • 44649083566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at, Ultimately, the ASARCO question was mooted when the mine closed because of falling copper prices. Id. at
    • See id. at 1635-37. Ultimately, the ASARCO question was mooted when the mine closed because of falling copper prices. Id. at 1634;
    • See id
  • 404
    • 84885215480 scopus 로고
    • Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62
    • arguing that the results of the ASARCO experiment were, at best, mixed because the issues may have been too sophisticated for public input, see also
    • see also Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein, Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1, 89-91 (1995) (arguing that the results of the ASARCO experiment were, at best, mixed because the issues may have been too sophisticated for public input).
    • (1995) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 89-91
    • Pildes, R.H.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 405
    • 44649127187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Donald T. Hornstein, Reclaiming Environmental Law: A Normative Critique of Comparative Risk Analysis, 92 COLUM. L. REV. 562, 631, 630-31 (1992) ([T]he substance of modem environmental law is a composite of moral decisions-about the levels of protection to be accorded such noncommodity values as human health, aesthetics, and responsibility toward nonhuman species and ecosystems-and instrumental decisions about the best way to achieve these morally based goals.).
    • See, e.g., Donald T. Hornstein, Reclaiming Environmental Law: A Normative Critique of Comparative Risk Analysis, 92 COLUM. L. REV. 562, 631, 630-31 (1992) ("[T]he substance of modem environmental law is a composite of moral decisions-about the levels of protection to be accorded such noncommodity values as human health, aesthetics, and responsibility toward nonhuman species and ecosystems-and instrumental decisions about the best way to achieve these morally based goals.").
  • 406
    • 44649110046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reich, supra note 291, at 1632
    • Reich, supra note 291, at 1632.
  • 407
    • 44649137188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democratizing the Administrative State, 48
    • Richard J. Pierce, Jr., Democratizing the Administrative State, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 559, 597 (2006);
    • (2006) WM. & MARY L. REV , vol.559 , pp. 597
    • Pierce Jr., R.J.1
  • 408
    • 44649086257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also David Schoenbrod, Goals Statutes or Rules Statutes: The Case of the
    • see also David Schoenbrod, Goals Statutes or Rules Statutes: The Case of the
  • 409
    • 44649156880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clean Air Act, 30 UCLA L. REV. 740, 756-62 (1983) (describing conflicts in the goals of the Clean Air Act).
    • Clean Air Act, 30 UCLA L. REV. 740, 756-62 (1983) (describing conflicts in the goals of the Clean Air Act).
  • 410
    • 0346983715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Regulation, Ideology, and the D.C. Circuit, 83
    • finding that ideology significantly influences the D.C. Circuit's decision making in environmental matters, See
    • See Richard L. Revesz, Environmental Regulation, Ideology, and the D.C. Circuit, 83 VA. L. REV. 1717, 1719 (1997) (finding that ideology significantly influences the D.C. Circuit's decision making in environmental matters).
    • (1997) VA. L. REV , vol.1717 , pp. 1719
    • Revesz, R.L.1
  • 411
    • 44649154877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reich, supra note 291, at 1633-34
    • Reich, supra note 291, at 1633-34.
  • 412
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 122 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 122 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 413
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 107-13 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 107-13 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 414
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 144-47 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 144-47 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 415
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 151-52 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 151-52 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 416
    • 44649130532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., STEPHEN BREYER, BREAKING THE VICIOUS CIRCLE: TOWARD EFFECTIVE RISK REGULATION 22-29 (1993) (describing multiple flaws in human decision making about risks and giving examples);
    • See, e.g., STEPHEN BREYER, BREAKING THE VICIOUS CIRCLE: TOWARD EFFECTIVE RISK REGULATION 22-29 (1993) (describing multiple flaws in human decision making about risks and giving examples);
  • 417
    • 44649164311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • W. KIP VISCUSI, RATIONAL RISK POLICY 97-99 (1998) (arguing that policy makers do not follow a rational cost-benefit analysis when spending money to avert risks of death) .
    • W. KIP VISCUSI, RATIONAL RISK POLICY 97-99 (1998) (arguing that policy makers do not follow a rational cost-benefit analysis when spending money to avert risks of death) .
  • 418
    • 34247536004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Barbara S. Swain & Dan R. Gallipeau, Juror Attitudes in Antitrust Cases, ANTITRUST, Summer 1994, at 14, 15, 15-17 (In some venues, as many as 75 percent of the jurors think that large corporations regularly use unethical and unfair tactics to bully smaller competitors and squeeze them out of the marketplace.). A recent empirical study of patent litigation reports a similar juror bias against large corporations in patent cases. See Kimberly A. Moore, Populism and Patents, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 69 (2007).
    • See Barbara S. Swain & Dan R. Gallipeau, Juror Attitudes in Antitrust Cases, ANTITRUST, Summer 1994, at 14, 15, 15-17 ("In some venues, as many as 75 percent of the jurors think that large corporations regularly use unethical and unfair tactics to bully smaller competitors and squeeze them out of the marketplace."). A recent empirical study of patent litigation reports a similar juror bias against large corporations in patent cases. See Kimberly A. Moore, Populism and Patents, 82 N.Y.U. L. REV. 69 (2007).
  • 419
    • 44649198470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 283, at 215
    • POSNER, supra note 283, at 215.
  • 420
    • 44649184794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally WILLIAM F. SHUGHART II, ANTITRUST POLICY AND INTEREST-GROUP POLITICS 82-120 (1990) (describing private interests as factors in public enforcement of antitrust at the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission and the influence of special-interest politics in congressional antitrust involvement);
    • See generally WILLIAM F. SHUGHART II, ANTITRUST POLICY AND INTEREST-GROUP POLITICS 82-120 (1990) (describing private interests as factors in public enforcement of antitrust at the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission and the influence of special-interest politics in congressional antitrust involvement);
  • 421
    • 44649176204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas W. Merrill, Capture Theory and the Courts: 1967-1983, 72 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1039, 1059-67 (1997) (arguing that enhanced judicial control over administrative agencies from 1967 to 1983 was driven by concerns about agency capture);
    • Thomas W. Merrill, Capture Theory and the Courts: 1967-1983, 72 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1039, 1059-67 (1997) (arguing that enhanced judicial control over administrative agencies from 1967 to 1983 was driven by concerns about agency capture);
  • 422
    • 0037766205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Rise and Demise of the Technology-Specific Approach to the First Amendment, 91
    • Experience with the administrative process and growing concerns about agency capture have shattered faith in technocracy that characterized the Progressive era
    • Christopher S. Yoo, The Rise and Demise of the Technology-Specific Approach to the First Amendment, 91 GEO. L.J. 245, 350 (2003) ("Experience with the administrative process and growing concerns about agency capture have shattered faith in technocracy that characterized the Progressive era.").
    • (2003) GEO. L.J , vol.245 , pp. 350
    • Yoo, C.S.1
  • 423
    • 44649178106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 HARV. L. REV. 1669, 1713 (1975) (It has become widely accepted, not only by public interest lawyers, but by academic critics, legislators, judges, and even by some agency members, that the comparative overrepresentation of regulated or client interests in the process of agency decision results in a persistent policy bias in favor of these interests. (footnotes omitted));
    • See Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 HARV. L. REV. 1669, 1713 (1975) ("It has become widely accepted, not only by public interest lawyers, but by academic critics, legislators, judges, and even by some agency members, that the comparative overrepresentation of regulated or client interests in the process of agency decision results in a persistent policy bias in favor of these interests." (footnotes omitted));
  • 424
    • 34548299197 scopus 로고
    • Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101
    • collecting agency-capture literature, see also
    • see also Einer R. Elhauge, Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review?, 101 YALE L.J. 31, 42 (1991) (collecting agency-capture literature).
    • (1991) YALE L.J , vol.31 , pp. 42
    • Elhauge, E.R.1
  • 425
    • 44649086258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kovacic, supra note 166, at 77 describing the Chicago School view that the antitrust-enforcement agencies desired and greatly succeeded in aggrandizing their power because the affected private sector interests were too timid or well-organized to resist DOJ and FTC efforts to expand their authority
    • See Kovacic, supra note 166, at 77 (describing the Chicago School view that the antitrust-enforcement agencies "desired and greatly succeeded in aggrandizing their power because the affected private sector interests were too timid or well-organized to resist DOJ and FTC efforts to expand their authority").
  • 426
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 167-83 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 167-83 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 427
    • 44649150059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pitofsky, supra note 288, at 1065
    • Pitofsky, supra note 288, at 1065.
  • 428
    • 44649182577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 176, at 15
    • HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES, supra note 176, at 15.
  • 429
    • 44649190988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 213
    • HOVENKAMP, supra note 99, at 213.
  • 430
    • 21644488588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Ken Heyer, A World of Uncertainty: Economics and the Globalization of Antitrust, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 375, 379, 378-79 (2005) (noting that while the advancement of quantitative tools has aided antitrust analysis, [d]ealing efficiently with [the] uncertainty and imprecision of those tools is extremely important). Heyer, the Economics Director at the Justice Department's Antitrust Division, admits that the new and improved economic tools, their high degree of sophistication, and emphasis on quantitative prediction risk leaving one with a false sense as to their accuracy and precision.
    • See, e.g., Ken Heyer, A World of Uncertainty: Economics and the Globalization of Antitrust, 72 ANTITRUST L.J. 375, 379, 378-79 (2005) (noting that while the advancement of quantitative tools has aided antitrust analysis, "[d]ealing efficiently with [the] uncertainty and imprecision" of those tools is extremely important). Heyer, the Economics Director at the Justice Department's Antitrust Division, admits that "the new and improved economic tools, their high degree of sophistication, and emphasis on quantitative prediction risk leaving one with a false sense as to their accuracy and precision."
  • 432
    • 34249085148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at
    • See, e.g., id. at 417-18.
    • See, e.g., id , pp. 417-418
  • 433
    • 44649094383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This argument is simply an application of the Coase theorem, which predicts that where transaction costs are zero, parties will bargain to the efficient solution regardless of the initial assignment of rights. See R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1, 43, 42-44 1960, arguing that consideration of negative externalities and costs borne by society must be incorporated into an opportunity cost approach to economic policy
    • This argument is simply an application of the Coase theorem, which predicts that where transaction costs are zero, parties will bargain to the efficient solution regardless of the initial assignment of rights. See R.H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1, 43, 42-44 (1960) (arguing that consideration of negative externalities and costs borne by society must be incorporated into an "opportunity cost approach" to economic policy).
  • 434
    • 44649155542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 109-10 and accompanying text.
    • See supra notes 109-10 and accompanying text.
  • 435
    • 84963456897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes 177-83 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 177-83 and accompanying text.
    • See supra
  • 436
    • 44649186069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Broad. Music, Inc., 426 F.3d 91, 92 (2d Cir. 2005).
    • United States v. Broad. Music, Inc., 426 F.3d 91, 92 (2d Cir. 2005).
  • 437
    • 0002254318 scopus 로고
    • The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13
    • The most important assumption of [our] model is that potential litigants form rational estimates of the likely decision, whether it is based on applicable legal precedent or judicial or jury bias, See
    • See George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 4 (1984) ("The most important assumption of [our] model is that potential litigants form rational estimates of the likely decision, whether it is based on applicable legal precedent or judicial or jury bias.").
    • (1984) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.1 , pp. 4
    • Priest, G.L.1    Klein, B.2
  • 438
    • 44649180315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • William J. Baer, Reflections on Twenty Years of Merger Enforcement Under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 825, 825-26 (1997).
    • William J. Baer, Reflections on Twenty Years of Merger Enforcement Under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 825, 825-26 (1997).
  • 439
    • 44649111056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., AKIN, supra note 4, at 164-65 (explaining American society's rejection of technocracy in the 1930s as partially based on the perceived incompatibility between democratic control and technocratic methods).
    • See, e.g., AKIN, supra note 4, at 164-65 (explaining American society's rejection of technocracy in the 1930s as partially based on the perceived incompatibility between democratic control and technocratic methods).
  • 440
    • 44649120669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crane, supra note 89, at 1210-11 arguing that modern American antitrust history is not characterized by gradual change but instead by significant shifts in dominant schools of thought over different time periods
    • See Crane, supra note 89, at 1210-11 (arguing that modern American antitrust history is not characterized by gradual change but instead by significant shifts in dominant schools of thought over different time periods).
  • 441
    • 44649093135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 1211 (predicting that the current antitrust epoch of modesty might be upset by a rise in antiglobalization political movements that could reinterpret antitrust regulations to limit international corporate growth).
    • See, e.g., id. at 1211 (predicting that the current antitrust "epoch of modesty" might be upset by a rise in antiglobalization political movements that could reinterpret antitrust regulations to limit international corporate growth).
  • 442
    • 44649174815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Former Democratic presidential candidate John Edwards, who has generally advocated protectionist economic views, issued a call for much more aggressive antitrust enforcement. See Senator John Edwards, Submission to the American Antitrust Institute 1 (Oct. 2, 2007), available at http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/archives/files/aai- %20Presidential%20campaign%20%20Edwards%2010-1-07_100220071538.pdf ([F]orces in Washington sometimes seem to have forgotten that antitrust law even exists.).
    • Former Democratic presidential candidate John Edwards, who has generally advocated protectionist economic views, issued a call for much more aggressive antitrust enforcement. See Senator John Edwards, Submission to the American Antitrust Institute 1 (Oct. 2, 2007), available at http://www.antitrustinstitute.org/archives/files/aai- %20Presidential%20campaign%20%20Edwards%2010-1-07_100220071538.pdf ("[F]orces in Washington sometimes seem to have forgotten that antitrust law even exists.").


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.