메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 123, Issue 7, 2010, Pages 1549-1595

Bundling and entrenchment

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77955542330     PISSN: 0017811X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (30)

References (104)
  • 1
    • 77955536753 scopus 로고
    • 219, 255-56, (discussing, respectively, omnibus bills generally, the passage of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, and the passage of the Natural Energy Act of 1978)
    • See, e.g., R. DOUGLAS ARNOLD, THE LOGIC OF CONGRESSIONAL ACTION 102-03, 219, 255-56 (1990) (discussing, respectively, omnibus bills generally, the passage of the Tax Reform Act of 1986, and the passage of the Natural Energy Act of 1978).
    • (1990) The Logic of Congressional Action , pp. 102-103
    • Arnold, R.D.1
  • 2
    • 77955535992 scopus 로고
    • In the face of controversy, packaging
    • Feb. 21, at B6 (providing examples of legislative package deals)
    • see also MARTIN TOLCHIN, In the Face of Controversy, Packaging, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 21, 1983, at B6 (providing examples of legislative package deals).
    • (1983) N.Y. Times
    • Tolchin, M.1
  • 3
    • 13244272076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 HARV. L. REV., 864-65, (discussing charter amendments and reincorporations)
    • See Lucian Arye Bebchuk, The Case for Increasing Shareholder Power, 118 HARV. L. REV. 833, 864-65 (2005) (discussing charter amendments and reincorporations).
    • (2005) The Case for Increasing Shareholder Power , pp. 833
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1
  • 6
    • 77951819963 scopus 로고
    • 89 COLUM. L. REV., 1577-79, (discussing charter amendments)
    • Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Mandatory Structure of Corporate Law, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 1549, 1577-79 (1989) (discussing charter amendments).
    • (1989) The Mandatory Structure of Corporate Law , pp. 1549
    • Gordon, J.N.1
  • 9
    • 77951735801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 33 DEL. J. CORP. L., (documenting management initiatives to destagger boards following shareholder pressure)
    • See, e.g., Mira Ganor, Why Do Managers Dismantle Staggered Boards?, 33 DEL. J. CORP. L. 149 (2008) (documenting management initiatives to destagger boards following shareholder pressure).
    • (2008) Why Do Managers Dismantle Staggered Boards? , pp. 149
    • Ganor, M.1
  • 10
    • 77955533362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • More boards may end staggered terms
    • June 8, (LEXIS) (same)
    • Bhattiprolu Murti, More Boards May End Staggered Terms, WALL ST. J., June 8, 2005 (LEXIS) (same).
    • Wall St. J. , vol.2005
    • Murti, B.1
  • 12
    • 77955545204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One might argue that the motivation for staggering the board in some of these mergers was to prevent one party's representatives on the combined firm's board from unseating the other party's representatives, rather than to prevent ouster of the entire board by a hostile bidder. Once in place, however, a staggered board retards both types of control changes, and it is forced upon shareholders as part of the deal, rather than as a feature they may choose to leave out
    • One might argue that the motivation for staggering the board in some of these mergers was to prevent one party's representatives on the combined firm's board from unseating the other party's representatives, rather than to prevent ouster of the entire board by a hostile bidder. Once in place, however, a staggered board retards both types of control changes, and it is forced upon shareholders as part of the deal, rather than as a feature they may choose to leave out.
  • 13
    • 0003422432 scopus 로고
    • For example, shareholder approval is required for reincorporation, and commentators have inferred from this requirement that reincorporations take place only when favored by shareholders
    • For example, shareholder approval is required for reincorporation, and commentators have inferred from this requirement that reincorporations take place only when favored by shareholders. See ROBERTA ROMANO, THE GENIUS OF AMERICAN CORPORATE LAW 18-19 (1993).
    • (1993) The Genius of American Corporate Law , pp. 18-19
    • Romano, R.1
  • 14
    • 77955535522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 101 (2001)
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 101 (2001).
  • 15
    • 77955544259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. § 109 (providing that the charter stands above the bylaws); id. § 141(a) (providing that the charter stands above board decisions)
    • See, e.g., id. § 109 (providing that the charter stands above the bylaws); id. § 141(a) (providing that the charter stands above board decisions).
  • 16
    • 77955542552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an example of a charter provision read narrowly to avoid conflict with the language of the code, see Waltuch v. Conticommodity Services, Inc., 88 F.3d 87 (2d Cir. 1996), which applied Delaware law. Board actions, in contrast, are subject to fiduciary-duty review even when they violate no statute
    • For an example of a charter provision read narrowly to avoid conflict with the language of the code, see Waltuch v. Conticommodity Services, Inc., 88 F.3d 87 (2d Cir. 1996), which applied Delaware law. Board actions, in contrast, are subject to fiduciary-duty review even when they violate no statute.
  • 17
    • 77955544895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Schnell v. Chris-Craft Indus., Inc., 285 A.2d 437, 439 (Del. 1971) ("Management contends that it has complied strictly with the provisions of the new Delaware Corporation Law in changing the by-law date. The answer to that contention, of course, is that inequitable action does not become permissible simply because it is legally possible.")
    • See, e.g., Schnell v. Chris-Craft Indus., Inc., 285 A.2d 437, 439 (Del. 1971) ("Management contends that it has complied strictly with the provisions of the new Delaware Corporation Law in changing the by-law date. The answer to that contention, of course, is that inequitable action does not become permissible simply because it is legally possible.").
  • 18
    • 77955523489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Seibert v. Gulton Indus., Inc., 5 DEL. J. CORP. L. 514 (Del. Ch. June 21, 1979), aff'd, 414 A.2d 822 (Del. 1980) (dismissing a challenge to the validity of a charter-based antitakeover defense)
    • See, e.g., Seibert v. Gulton Indus., Inc., 5 DEL. J. CORP. L. 514 (Del. Ch. June 21, 1979), aff'd, 414 A.2d 822 (Del. 1980) (dismissing a challenge to the validity of a charter-based antitakeover defense).
  • 19
    • 0004036363 scopus 로고
    • describing the right to vote on charter amendments as one of the basic rights of shareholder
    • See ROBERT CHARLES CLARK, CORPORATE LAW 94 (1986) (describing the right to vote on charter amendments as one of the basic rights of shareholders).
    • (1986) Corporate Law , vol.94
    • Clark, R.C.1
  • 20
    • 77955538502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 242(b)
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 242(b).
  • 21
    • 32544432717 scopus 로고
    • arguing that shareholders price charter provisions when the firm conducts an initial public offering
    • See, e.g., FRANK H. EASTERBROOK & DANIEL R. FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPORATE LAW 7, 17-22 (1991) (arguing that shareholders price charter provisions when the firm conducts an initial public offering).
    • (1991) The Economic Structure of Corporate Law , vol.7 , pp. 17-22
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1    Fischel, D.R.2
  • 23
    • 0011538807 scopus 로고
    • 89 COLUM. L. REV., 1601-02, (arguing that shareholders price charter provisions when the firm conducts an initial public offering and approve only value-increasing amendments thereafter); Stout, supra note 5 (arguing that the presence of staggered boards in the charters of firms conducting initial public offerings suggests that staggered boards are efficient)
    • Roberta Romano, Answering the Wrong Question: The Tenuous Case for Mandatory Corporate Laws, 89 COLUM. L. REV. 1599, 1601-02 (1989) (arguing that shareholders price charter provisions when the firm conducts an initial public offering and approve only value-increasing amendments thereafter); Stout, supra note 5 (arguing that the presence of staggered boards in the charters of firms conducting initial public offerings suggests that staggered boards are efficient).
    • (1989) Answering the Wrong Question: The Tenuous Case for Mandatory Corporate Laws , pp. 1599
    • Romano, R.1
  • 24
    • 77955547396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Bebchuk, supra note 3 (discussing reasons to doubt the efficiency of charter provisions of firms conducting initial public offerings)
    • But see Bebchuk, supra note 3 (discussing reasons to doubt the efficiency of charter provisions of firms conducting initial public offerings).
  • 25
    • 38849152003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 864-65, (discussing charter amendments and reincorporations)
    • See Bebchuk, The Case for Increasing Shareholder Power, supra note 2, at 864-65 (discussing charter amendments and reincorporations).
    • The Case for Increasing Shareholder Power
    • Bebchuk1
  • 26
    • 77955546311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 1475 (discussing reincorporations)
    • Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation, supra note 2, at 1475 (discussing reincorporations).
    • Federalism and the Corporation
    • Bebchuk1
  • 28
    • 77955532607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gordon, supra note 2, at 1577-80 (discussing charter amendments)
    • Gordon, supra note 2, at 1577-80 (discussing charter amendments).
  • 29
    • 77955522539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *14 (LEXIS) (setting forth the procedures for proposing dissolutions)
    • *14 (LEXIS) (setting forth the procedures for proposing dissolutions).
  • 30
    • 77955531698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The only fundamental change that shareholders can propose is to amend the bylaws. See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 109(a) (2001). Even this power, however, is limited because the bylaws must agree with the charter
    • The only fundamental change that shareholders can propose is to amend the bylaws. See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 109(a) (2001). Even this power, however, is limited because the bylaws must agree with the charter.
  • 31
    • 77955524123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. § 109(b). Thus, for example, shareholders cannot repeal a charter-based staggered-board structure through a bylaw amendment. Shareholders can also unanimously initiate a dissolution
    • See, e.g., id. § 109(b). Thus, for example, shareholders cannot repeal a charter-based staggered-board structure through a bylaw amendment. Shareholders can also unanimously initiate a dissolution.
  • 32
    • 77955532753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. § 275(c). But this power is impractical in public firms with numerous shareholders
    • See, e.g., id. § 275(c). But this power is impractical in public firms with numerous shareholders.
  • 33
    • 77955544415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Romano, supra note 14, at 1612
    • See Romano, supra note 14, at 1612.
  • 34
    • 77955519771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROMANO, supra note 7, at 2
    • See ROMANO, supra note 7, at 2.
  • 37
    • 77955526170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jarrell & Poulsen, supra note 20, at 130
    • See Jarrell & Poulsen, supra note 20, at 130.
  • 38
    • 77955528548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Once the plan was approved, individual shareholders were typically given the choice whether to exchange their stock for the new class of low-voting stock. It was rational for all individual stockholders to do so because their choice would have no impact on the likelihood of a takeover
    • Once the plan was approved, individual shareholders were typically given the choice whether to exchange their stock for the new class of low-voting stock. It was rational for all individual stockholders to do so because their choice would have no impact on the likelihood of a takeover.
  • 40
    • 77955533852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Voting Rights Listing Standards; Disenfranchisement Rule, 53 Fed. Reg. 26,376 (July 12, 1988) (codified as amended at 17 C.F.R. § 240.19C-4 (2009)), invalidated by Bus. Roundtable v. SEC, 905 F.2d 406 (D.C. Cir. 1990)
    • See Voting Rights Listing Standards; Disenfranchisement Rule, 53 Fed. Reg. 26,376 (July 12, 1988) (codified as amended at 17 C.F.R. § 240.19C-4 (2009)), invalidated by Bus. Roundtable v. SEC, 905 F.2d 406 (D.C. Cir. 1990).
  • 41
    • 77955539452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bus. Roundtable, 905 F.2d 406
    • See Bus. Roundtable, 905 F.2d 406.
  • 42
    • 77955531699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Order Granting Approval to Rule Changes Relating to the Exchanges' and Association's Rules Regarding Shareholder Voting Rights, Exchange Act Release No. 35,121, 59 Fed. Reg. 66,570, 66,570 (Dec. 27, 1994)
    • See Order Granting Approval to Rule Changes Relating to the Exchanges' and Association's Rules Regarding Shareholder Voting Rights, Exchange Act Release No. 35,121, 59 Fed. Reg. 66,570, 66,570 (Dec. 27, 1994).
  • 43
    • 77955542070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some may think that bundling has been precluded by SEC Rule 14a-4(a)(3), which is known as the "unbundling rule." See 17 C.F.R. § 240.14a-4(a)(3) (2009). Despite its name, however, this rule does not prevent management from presenting proposals to shareholders for approval as a package. The unbundling rule permits management to condition the adoption of one proposal on the approval of another proposal. The rule requires only that shareholders be able to vote on the proposals separately - even if the approval of only one means that neither is implemented. Moreover, even this weak rule does not cover charter amendments effected through the merger of firms with different charters
    • Some may think that bundling has been precluded by SEC Rule 14a-4(a)(3), which is known as the "unbundling rule." See 17 C.F.R. § 240.14a-4(a)(3) (2009). Despite its name, however, this rule does not prevent management from presenting proposals to shareholders for approval as a package. The unbundling rule permits management to condition the adoption of one proposal on the approval of another proposal. The rule requires only that shareholders be able to vote on the proposals separately - even if the approval of only one means that neither is implemented. Moreover, even this weak rule does not cover charter amendments effected through the merger of firms with different charters.
  • 44
    • 77955537669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DIV. OF CORP. FIN., U.S. SEC. & EXCH. COMM'N, MANUAL of Publicly Available Telephone Interpretations (5th Supp. 2004), http://www.sec.gov/ interps/telephone/phonesupplement5.htm
    • See DIV. OF CORP. FIN., U.S. SEC. & EXCH. COMM'N, MANUAL of Publicly Available Telephone Interpretations (5th Supp. 2004), http://www.sec.gov/ interps/telephone/phonesupplement5.htm.
  • 45
    • 77955546455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Prior research has documented the emergence of charter-based antitakeover defenses in midstream, but not through bundling. Thus, it is now known that in corporate spinoffs (in which public firms take their subsidiaries public), staggered boards are more common among the spinoff firms than among their parents
    • Prior research has documented the emergence of charter-based antitakeover defenses in midstream, but not through bundling. Thus, it is now known that in corporate spinoffs (in which public firms take their subsidiaries public), staggered boards are more common among the spinoff firms than among their parents.
  • 47
    • 77955535663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spinoffs, however, do not involve bundling because they are effected either through a distribution of the subsidiary's shares to the parent's shareholders or through a sale of those shares in a public offering
    • Spinoffs, however, do not involve bundling because they are effected either through a distribution of the subsidiary's shares to the parent's shareholders or through a sale of those shares in a public offering.
  • 48
    • 77955537066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 9 (reporting that from a sample of 277 spinoffs from mid-1993 through 1997, 91 were share distributions and 186 were public offerings). In a share distribution, shareholders have no say. In a public offering, shareholders can price the offered shares and are not limited to accepting or rejecting the deal on management's terms
    • See id. at 9 (reporting that from a sample of 277 spinoffs from mid-1993 through 1997, 91 were share distributions and 186 were public offerings). In a share distribution, shareholders have no say. In a public offering, shareholders can price the offered shares and are not limited to accepting or rejecting the deal on management's terms.
  • 49
    • 77955535381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 141(d) (Supp. 2008). Although this statute also permits company bylaws to stagger the board, this option is less commonly used than staggering the board in the charter because shareholders can amend the bylaws to eliminate the staggered structure
    • See, e.g., DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 141(d) (Supp. 2008). Although this statute also permits company bylaws to stagger the board, this option is less commonly used than staggering the board in the charter because shareholders can amend the bylaws to eliminate the staggered structure.
  • 51
    • 77955536906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some states permit staggered boards with four classes. See, e.g., N.Y. BUS. CORP. Law § 704(a) (McKinney 2003)
    • Some states permit staggered boards with four classes. See, e.g., N.Y. BUS. CORP. Law § 704(a) (McKinney 2003).
  • 52
    • 77955530297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A poison pill is a dividend of rights allowing all shareholders other than the hostile bidder to buy additional shares at a deep discount if the bidder crosses a threshold of share ownership, which dramatically raises the cost of the takeover
    • A poison pill is a dividend of rights allowing all shareholders other than the hostile bidder to buy additional shares at a deep discount if the bidder crosses a threshold of share ownership, which dramatically raises the cost of the takeover.
  • 54
    • 0036579045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 54 STAN. L. REV. 887, (reporting that 6% of staggered boards were installed before 1974, when hostile takeovers became legitimate in the corporate marketplace, that another 17% were installed before 1985, when the Delaware courts validated the use of a poison pill by the board to resist takeovers, and that another 53% were installed before 1990, when the Delaware courts permitted the board to resist takeovers indefinitely)
    • See Lucian Arye Bebchuk, John C. Coates IV & Guhan Subramanian, The Powerful Anti-takeover Force of Staggered Boards: Theory, Evidence, and Policy, 54 STAN. L. REV. 887, 940-43 (2002) (reporting that 6% of staggered boards were installed before 1974, when hostile takeovers became legitimate in the corporate marketplace, that another 17% were installed before 1985, when the Delaware courts validated the use of a poison pill by the board to resist takeovers, and that another 53% were installed before 1990, when the Delaware courts permitted the board to resist takeovers indefinitely).
    • (2002) The Powerful Anti-takeover Force of Staggered Boards: Theory, Evidence, and Policy , pp. 940-943
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1    Coates IV, J.C.2    Subramanian, G.3
  • 55
    • 44649133185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 14 J. CORE FIN. 274, (reporting that most of the firms in a sample of firms with staggered boards staggered their boards before 1990 and that most of the firms that staggered their boards later did so before going public)
    • see also Re-Jin Guo, Timothy A. Kruse & Tom Nohel, Undoing the Powerful Anti-Takeover Force of Staggered Boards, 14 J. CORE FIN. 274, 275 n.7 (2008) (reporting that most of the firms in a sample of firms with staggered boards staggered their boards before 1990 and that most of the firms that staggered their boards later did so before going public).
    • (2008) Undoing the Powerful Anti-takeover Force of Staggered Boards , Issue.7 , pp. 275
    • Guo, R.-J.1    Kruse, T.A.2    Nohel, T.3
  • 56
    • 77955539277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bebchuk, supra note 3, at 724-25; Klausner, supra note 3, at 758-59 (providing statistics)
    • See Bebchuk, supra note 3, at 724-25; Klausner, supra note 3, at 758-59 (providing statistics).
  • 57
    • 77955539898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • fig.3A, Feb. 1, (unpublished manuscript), available at, (documenting a gradual increase in the incidence of staggered boards from 1978 until 1995, followed by a gradual decrease from 1996 until 2006)
    • Martijn Cremers & Allen Ferrell, Thirty Years of Shareholder Rights and Firm Valuation 35 fig.3A (Feb. 1, 2010) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://ssrn,com/abstract=1413133 (documenting a gradual increase in the incidence of staggered boards from 1978 until 1995, followed by a gradual decrease from 1996 until 2006).
    • (2010) Thirty Years of Shareholder Rights and Firm Valuation , vol.35
    • Cremers, M.1    Ferrell, A.2
  • 58
    • 77955539449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ganor, supra note 4, at 155-58; Guo et al., supra note 30, at 275; Murti, supra note 4; sources cited supra note 31
    • See Ganor, supra note 4, at 155-58; Guo et al., supra note 30, at 275; Murti, supra note 4; sources cited supra note 31.
  • 59
    • 77955548626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This statistic is based on the 1996 to 2007 editions of the Georgeson Annual Corporate Governance Review, last visited March 27
    • This statistic is based on the 1996 to 2007 editions of the Georgeson Annual Corporate Governance Review. See Georgeson, Annual Corporate Governance Review, http://www.georgesonshareholder.com/usa%20/acgro9.php (last visited March 27, 2010).
    • (2010) Annual Corporate Governance Review
    • Georgeson1
  • 62
    • 77955529053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Georgeson, supra note 33
    • See Georgeson, supra note 33.
  • 64
    • 77955521320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 2-3
    • See id. at 2-3.
  • 66
    • 77955545847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bebchuk et al., supra note 30, at 930 fig.3
    • See Bebchuk et al., supra note 30, at 930 fig.3.
  • 67
    • 77955521164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 934-35
    • See id. at 934-35.
  • 71
    • 77955544572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bebchuk & Cohen, supra note 41, at 426-28
    • See Bebchuk & Cohen, supra note 41, at 426-28.
  • 72
    • 77955529850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Guo et al., supra note 30, at 287
    • See Guo et al., supra note 30, at 287.
  • 73
    • 77955537209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Faleye, supra note 41, at 503
    • See Faleye, supra note 41, at 503.
  • 76
    • 77955531399 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 658
    • Id. at 658.
  • 77
    • 77955534473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 675-76
    • Id. at 675-76.
  • 78
    • 77955532153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Even commentators who believe that a staggered board can negotiate better deals on behalf of shareholders agree that shareholders should be the judges of whether to have a staggered board, especially when the board structure is modified after the shareholders bought their shares
    • Even commentators who believe that a staggered board can negotiate better deals on behalf of shareholders agree that shareholders should be the judges of whether to have a staggered board, especially when the board structure is modified after the shareholders bought their shares.
  • 80
    • 77955536454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 52-53 and accompanying text
    • See infra notes 52-53 and accompanying text.
  • 81
    • 77955542241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A merger of A into B itself is often referred to as a "direct merger," and a merger of A with a subsidiary of B is often referred to as a "triangular merger." A triangular merger can be structured as a merger of B's subsidiary into A (a "reverse triangular merger") or as a merger of A into B's subsidiary (a "forward triangular merger")
    • A merger of A into B itself is often referred to as a "direct merger," and a merger of A with a subsidiary of B is often referred to as a "triangular merger." A triangular merger can be structured as a merger of B's subsidiary into A (a "reverse triangular merger") or as a merger of A into B's subsidiary (a "forward triangular merger").
  • 82
    • 77955538793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Takeover law and practice
    • at 201-02 (PLI Corp. Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series No. B-1740, 2009) (describing the various merger structures)
    • See Theodore N. Mirvis, Takeover Law and Practice 2008, in WHAT ALL BUSINESS LAWYERS MUST KNOW ABOUT DELAWARE LAW DEVELOPMENTS 2009, at 201-02 (PLI Corp. Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series No. B-1740, 2009) (describing the various merger structures).
    • (2008) What All Business Lawyers Must Know About Delaware Law Developments 2009
    • Mirvis, T.N.1
  • 83
    • 77955538504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 251 (2001 & Supp. 2008) (requiring that mergers be approved by the shareholders of the "constituent corporations"). Unlike the shareholders of A, the shareholders of B will vote on arms-length mergers only if B issues new stock that amounts to at least 20% of its outstanding common stock to pay the shareholders of A
    • See DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 251 (2001 & Supp. 2008) (requiring that mergers be approved by the shareholders of the "constituent corporations"). Unlike the shareholders of A, the shareholders of B will vote on arms-length mergers only if B issues new stock that amounts to at least 20% of its outstanding common stock to pay the shareholders of A.
  • 84
    • 77955526330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 251(g) (referring to mergers of A into B); NYSE Euronext, Inc., NYSE Listed Company Manual § 312.03(c) (2008) (referring to mergers of A with a subsidiary of B); NASDAQ, Inc., NASDAQ Stock Market Rules § 5635(a)(1) (2009) (referring to mergers of A with a subsidiary of B); NYSE Euronext, Inc., NYSE Amex Company Guide § 712(b) (2008) (referring to mergers of A with a subsidiary of B). For our purposes, however, the vote of interest is the vote by the shareholders of A because it is A's board structure that is changing. Their right to vote does not depend on how much common stock B will issue in the merger
    • See id. § 251(g) (referring to mergers of A into B); NYSE Euronext, Inc., NYSE Listed Company Manual § 312.03(c) (2008) (referring to mergers of A with a subsidiary of B); NASDAQ, Inc., NASDAQ Stock Market Rules § 5635(a)(1) (2009) (referring to mergers of A with a subsidiary of B); NYSE Euronext, Inc., NYSE Amex Company Guide § 712(b) (2008) (referring to mergers of A with a subsidiary of B). For our purposes, however, the vote of interest is the vote by the shareholders of A because it is A's board structure that is changing. Their right to vote does not depend on how much common stock B will issue in the merger.
  • 85
    • 77955520217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This deal structure is often referred to as a "double-dummy merger." See Mirvis, supra note 51, at 202
    • This deal structure is often referred to as a "double-dummy merger." See Mirvis, supra note 51, at 202.
  • 87
    • 77955543356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The double dummy can be very smart
    • Mar. 19, at 26, 26
    • Allan Sloan, The Double Dummy Can Be Very Smart, NEWSWEEK, Mar. 19, 2007, at 26, 26.
    • (2007) Newsweek
    • Sloan, A.1
  • 89
    • 77955535988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While we assume for simplicity that the only possible merger is between A and B, the analysis remains similar when a third party, C, proposes an alternative merger that is not bundled with a staggering of the board. First, to win shareholder approval, C's alternative merger will have to produce synergies that exceed the net value of the merger between A and B. Second, to have its alternative merger even considered, C will need to overcome the array of defenses protecting the deal between A and B. In many cases, at least one of these conditions will not be met and the bundled merger between A and B will face no competition
    • While we assume for simplicity that the only possible merger is between A and B, the analysis remains similar when a third party, C, proposes an alternative merger that is not bundled with a staggering of the board. First, to win shareholder approval, C's alternative merger will have to produce synergies that exceed the net value of the merger between A and B. Second, to have its alternative merger even considered, C will need to overcome the array of defenses protecting the deal between A and B. In many cases, at least one of these conditions will not be met and the bundled merger between A and B will face no competition.
  • 90
    • 0019610159 scopus 로고
    • 12 BELL J. ECON., (finding that managers engage in value-destroying conglomerate mergers to lower the risk of losing their job)
    • See, e.g., Yakov Amihud & Baruch Lev, Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers, 12 BELL J. ECON. 605, 615 (1981) (finding that managers engage in value-destroying conglomerate mergers to lower the risk of losing their job).
    • (1981) Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers , vol.605 , pp. 615
    • Amihud, Y.1    Lev, B.2
  • 91
    • 33947266977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 62 J. FIN., (finding that managers of acquiring firms are richly compensated even for poor acquisitions)
    • Jarrad Harford & Kai Li, Decoupling CEO Wealth and Firm Performance: The Case of Acquiring CEOs, 62 J. FIN. 917, 919 (2007) (finding that managers of acquiring firms are richly compensated even for poor acquisitions).
    • (2007) Decoupling CEO Wealth and Firm Performance: The Case of Acquiring CEOs , vol.917 , pp. 919
    • Harford, J.1    Li, K.2
  • 92
    • 77955541501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 31
    • See sources cited supra note 31.
  • 93
    • 77955548026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Table 2, p. 1576, and accompanying text; cf. infra note 94
    • See infra Table 2, p. 1576, and accompanying text; cf. infra note 94.
  • 94
    • 77955528547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 52-53 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 52-53 and accompanying text.
  • 96
    • 77955536156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deal planners may prefer to keep the party with dual-class capitalization public also to avoid the need for a separate vote on the merger by each class, which would invite holdups. Some states seem to require separate class votes in such mergers. See, e.g., N.Y. BUS. CORP. LAW § 903(a)(2) (McKinney 2003); MODEL BUS. CORP. ACT § 11.04(f)(1) (2008). As a precautionary measure, planners often assume that a separate class vote is needed in these states
    • Deal planners may prefer to keep the party with dual-class capitalization public also to avoid the need for a separate vote on the merger by each class, which would invite holdups. Some states seem to require separate class votes in such mergers. See, e.g., N.Y. BUS. CORP. LAW § 903(a)(2) (McKinney 2003); MODEL BUS. CORP. ACT § 11.04(f)(1) (2008). As a precautionary measure, planners often assume that a separate class vote is needed in these states.
  • 97
    • 77955535989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1 LOU R. Kling & Eileen T. Nugent, Negotiated Acquisitions of Companies, Subsidiaries and Divisions § 4.12 (2009)
    • See 1 LOU R. Kling & Eileen T. Nugent, Negotiated Acquisitions of Companies, Subsidiaries and Divisions § 4.12 (2009).
  • 98
    • 77955542240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See VIRGINIA K. ROSENBAUM, INSTITUTIONAL S'HOLDER SERVS. INC., CORPORATE TAKEOVER DEFENSES, at vi, xi (2006) (reporting staggered boards in 59.7% of 1925 firms comprising S&P 1500 firms plus additional firms "selected primarily on the basis of market capitalization and high institutional ownership levels" in 2004, and 56.4% of these firms in 2005). For similar figures, see Bebchuk et al., supra note 30, at 895 & fig.1
    • See VIRGINIA K. ROSENBAUM, INSTITUTIONAL S'HOLDER SERVS. INC., CORPORATE TAKEOVER DEFENSES, at vi, xi (2006) (reporting staggered boards in 59.7% of 1925 firms comprising S&P 1500 firms plus additional firms "selected primarily on the basis of market capitalization and high institutional ownership levels" in 2004, and 56.4% of these firms in 2005). For similar figures, see Bebchuk et al., supra note 30, at 895 & fig.1.
  • 99
    • 77955545036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 51
    • See supra note 51.
  • 100
    • 77955542730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 51
    • See supra note 51.
  • 101
    • 77955532305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Wilcoxon signed-rank test is a nonparametric statistical hypothesis test for two related samples or repeated measurements on a single sample. It is an alternative to the paired Student's t-test when the population cannot be assumed to be normally distributed
    • The Wilcoxon signed-rank test is a nonparametric statistical hypothesis test for two related samples or repeated measurements on a single sample. It is an alternative to the paired Student's t-test when the population cannot be assumed to be normally distributed.
  • 102
    • 77955521475 scopus 로고
    • 1 BIOMETRICS BULL., We use it here because the mean of the parties' staggered board indicators can take only one of three values (-1, 0, or 1), and so the mean cannot be assumed to be normally distributed
    • See Frank Wilcoxon, Individual Comparisons by Ranking Methods, 1 BIOMETRICS BULL. 80 (1945). We use it here because the mean of the parties' staggered board indicators can take only one of three values (-1, 0, or 1), and so the mean cannot be assumed to be normally distributed.
    • (1945) Individual Comparisons by Ranking Methods , vol.80
    • Wilcoxon, F.1
  • 103
    • 0345399126 scopus 로고
    • A t-test is a statistical hypothesis test in which the test statistic has a Student's t distribution if the null hypothesis is true. It is applied when the population is assumed to be normally distributed, See Student, 6 BIOMETRIKA
    • A t-test is a statistical hypothesis test in which the test statistic has a Student's t distribution if the null hypothesis is true. It is applied when the population is assumed to be normally distributed. See Student, The Probable Error of a Mean, 6 BIOMETRIKA 1 (1908).
    • (1908) The Probable Error of a Mean , vol.1
  • 104
    • 1442308223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 152 U. PA. L. REV., (describing provisions in company agreements with third parties that make the agreements terminable or impose penalties on the companies upon a change of control)
    • See Jennifer Arlen & Eric Talley, Unregulable Defenses and the Perils of Shareholder Choice, 152 U. PA. L. REV. 577, 614-23 (2003) (describing provisions in company agreements with third parties that make the agreements terminable or impose penalties on the companies upon a change of control).
    • (2003) Unregulable Defenses and the Perils of Shareholder Choice , vol.577 , pp. 614-623
    • Arlen, J.1    Talley, E.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.