메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 39, Issue 3, 2009, Pages 539-558

Policy-seeking parties in a parliamentary democracy with proportional representation: A valence-uncertainty model

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 67749104761     PISSN: 00071234     EISSN: 14692112     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0007123408000562     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (72)

References (66)
  • 1
    • 0000113734 scopus 로고
    • Spatial Models of Party Competition
    • See
    • See Donald Stokes, 'Spatial Models of Party Competition', American Political Science Review, 57 (1963), 368-77;
    • (1963) American Political Science Review , vol.57 , pp. 368-377
    • Stokes, D.1
  • 2
    • 0001878947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valence Politics
    • Dennis Kavanagh, ed, Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • and Donald Stokes, 'Valence Politics', in Dennis Kavanagh, ed., Electoral Politics (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1992), pp. 141-62.
    • (1992) Electoral Politics , pp. 141-162
    • Stokes, D.1
  • 5
    • 67749139615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for instance, Roy Pierce, 'Candidate Evaluations and Presidential Electoral Choices in France', and Richard Johnston, 'Prime Ministerial Contenders in Canada', both in Anthony King, ed., Leaders' Personalities and the Outcomes of Democratic Elections (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), pp. 96-126 and pp. 158-83 respectively;
    • See, for instance, Roy Pierce, 'Candidate Evaluations and Presidential Electoral Choices in France', and Richard Johnston, 'Prime Ministerial Contenders in Canada', both in Anthony King, ed., Leaders' Personalities and the Outcomes of Democratic Elections (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000), pp. 96-126 and pp. 158-83 respectively;
  • 6
    • 0002094501 scopus 로고
    • Did Major Win It? Did Kinnock Lose? Leadership Effects in the 1992 Elections
    • and, eds, Aldershot, Hants, Dartmouth
    • and Ivor Crewe and Anthony King, 'Did Major Win It? Did Kinnock Lose? Leadership Effects in the 1992 Elections', in Anthony Heath, Roger Jowell and John Curtice, eds, Labour's Last Chance? The 1992 Election and Beyond (Aldershot, Hants.: Dartmouth, 1994), pp. 51-86.
    • (1994) Labour's Last Chance? The 1992 Election and Beyond , pp. 51-86
    • Crewe, I.1    King, A.2
  • 7
    • 0035538557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Timothy Groseclose, 'A Model of Candidate Location when One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage'
    • On two-party elections
    • On two-party elections, see Timothy Groseclose, 'A Model of Candidate Location when One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage', American Journal of Political Science, 45 (2001), 862-86;
    • (2001) American Journal of Political Science , vol.45 , pp. 862-886
  • 8
    • 0003299890 scopus 로고
    • Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote
    • William A. Barnett, Melvin Hinich and Norman Schofield, eds, New York: Cambridge University Press
    • and John Londregan and Thomas Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote', in William A. Barnett, Melvin Hinich and Norman Schofield, eds, Political Economy: Institutions, Competition, and Representation (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993), pp. 355-77.
    • (1993) Political Economy: Institutions, Competition, and Representation , pp. 355-377
    • Londregan, J.1    Romer, T.2
  • 11
    • 67749099455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
  • 12
    • 67749084261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the Londregan-Romer model this uncertainty relates to voters' evaluations of the candidates' abilities to perform constituent service, although we do not restrict the meaning of valence in this way. By contrast, in 'A Model of Candidate Location when One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage, Groseclose analyses a model in which the candidates' uncertainty is over the location of the median voter
    • In the Londregan-Romer model this uncertainty relates to voters' evaluations of the candidates' abilities to perform constituent service, although we do not restrict the meaning of valence in this way. By contrast, in 'A Model of Candidate Location when One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage', Groseclose analyses a model in which the candidates' uncertainty is over the location of the median voter.
  • 13
    • 84971725007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Studies that emphasize the importance of the parties in the governing coalition include David Austen-Smith and Jeffery Banks, Elections, Coalitions, and Legislative Outcomes, American Political Science Review, 82 1988, 405-22;
    • Studies that emphasize the importance of the parties in the governing coalition include David Austen-Smith and Jeffery Banks, 'Elections, Coalitions, and Legislative Outcomes', American Political Science Review, 82 (1988), 405-22;
  • 15
    • 0032164073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Studies on the importance of the formateur include David Baron, 'Comparative Dynamics of Parliamentary Governments'
    • Studies on the importance of the formateur include David Baron, 'Comparative Dynamics of Parliamentary Governments', American Political Science Review, 92 (1998), 593-609.
    • (1998) American Political Science Review , vol.92 , pp. 593-609
  • 16
    • 0003579088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, emphasize the importance of the party with jurisdiction over the relevant government ministry
    • Michael Laver and Kenneth Shepsle, Making and Breaking Governments (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), emphasize the importance of the party with jurisdiction over the relevant government ministry.
    • (1996) Making and Breaking Governments
    • Laver, M.1    Shepsle, K.2
  • 18
    • 0035605130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We note that a related literature analyses the relationship between parties' policy programmes and the published policy declarations of the government (see, e.g, Paul Warwick, Coalition Policies in Parliamentary Democracies: Who Gets How Much and Why, Comparative Political Studies, 34 2001, 1212-36
    • We note that a related literature analyses the relationship between parties' policy programmes and the published policy declarations of the government (see, e.g., Paul Warwick, 'Coalition Policies in Parliamentary Democracies: Who Gets How Much and Why', Comparative Political Studies, 34 (2001), 1212-36).
  • 19
    • 67749113310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note, however, that these studies take as their dependent variable the government's policy declarations rather than the actual government policy outputs that were observed. Policy-seeking parties are presumably concerned with actual policy outputs as opposed to policy promises.
    • Note, however, that these studies take as their dependent variable the government's policy declarations rather than the actual government policy outputs that were observed. Policy-seeking parties are presumably concerned with actual policy outputs as opposed to policy promises.
  • 20
    • 67749114291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McDonald and Budge, Elections, Parties, and Democracy, Tables 12.3-12.5 on pp. 220-4.
    • See McDonald and Budge, Elections, Parties, and Democracy, Tables 12.3-12.5 on pp. 220-4.
  • 21
    • 67749137258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to the McDonald-Budge results, we note that Seok-ju Cho and John Duggan (in 'Bargaining Foundations of the Median Voter Theorem', Journal of Economic Theory, forthcoming) present important theoretical results that, as legislators become arbitrarily patient, a large class of bargaining models of distributive politics collapse to the position of the median legislator. This result, which runs counter to the folk theorem for repeated games that any possible division of resources can be supported as a subgame perfect equilibrium outcome, also supports our assumption of the policy primacy of the MPP. Thus we have both theoretical and empirical reasons to believe that our model is relevant to policy making in real world democracies.
    • In addition to the McDonald-Budge results, we note that Seok-ju Cho and John Duggan (in 'Bargaining Foundations of the Median Voter Theorem', Journal of Economic Theory, forthcoming) present important theoretical results that, as legislators become arbitrarily patient, a large class of bargaining models of distributive politics collapse to the position of the median legislator. This result, which runs counter to the folk theorem for repeated games that any possible division of resources can be supported as a subgame perfect equilibrium outcome, also supports our assumption of the policy primacy of the MPP. Thus we have both theoretical and empirical reasons to believe that our model is relevant to policy making in real world democracies.
  • 22
    • 67749086052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
  • 23
    • 0001773832 scopus 로고
    • Spatial Strategies When Candidates Have Policy Preferences
    • See also Theorem 4 in, James Enelow and Melvin Hinich, eds, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • See also Theorem 4 in Donald Wittman, 'Spatial Strategies When Candidates Have Policy Preferences', in James Enelow and Melvin Hinich, eds, Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 66-98.
    • (1990) Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting , pp. 66-98
    • Wittman, D.1
  • 24
    • 67749129165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schofield and Sened, Multiparty Democracy: Elections and Legislative Politics.
    • Schofield and Sened, Multiparty Democracy: Elections and Legislative Politics.
  • 26
    • 85078868130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 ≤ . . . ≤ sk, then the MPP is that party kM such that the set of parties 1,..., kM and parties kM, kM + 1,..., K each include a majority of the seats in parliament.
    • 2 ≤ . . . ≤ sk, then the MPP is that party kM such that the set of parties 1,..., kM and parties kM, kM + 1,..., K each include a majority of the seats in parliament.
  • 27
    • 67749088190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The assumption that politicians who gain power are constrained to implement their pre-election policy promises is standard in spatial models with policy-seeking parties/candidates; for a review of this literature, see John Roemer, Political Competition: Theory and Applications Cambridge, Mass, Harvard University Press, 2001, This assumption is typically justified on the grounds that politicians project that, in future elections, retrospective voters will punish office-holders who violate their pre-election policy promises, and that these projected future electoral reverses will in turn generate policy losses that exceed the policy gains office-holders can achieve by reneging on their promises during the current inter-election period
    • The assumption that politicians who gain power are constrained to implement their pre-election policy promises is standard in spatial models with policy-seeking parties/candidates; for a review of this literature, see John Roemer, Political Competition: Theory and Applications (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2001). This assumption is typically justified on the grounds that politicians project that, in future elections, retrospective voters will punish office-holders who violate their pre-election policy promises, and that these projected future electoral reverses will in turn generate policy losses that exceed the policy gains office-holders can achieve by reneging on their promises during the current inter-election period.
  • 28
    • 67749111531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We say that a function U is concave and peaks at x0 if it is continuous, and if for all x in the domain of U for which x≠x0, ∂ 2U/∂x2(x) ≤ 0 and U(x0) > U(x, This is a special case of strict single-peakedness, Note that if U is concave and peaks at x0, then U is strictly increasing on the left of x0 and strictly decreasing on the right, i.e, if x1 < x2 ≤ x0, then U(x1) ≤ U(x2) and if x0 ≤ x1 ≤ x2, then U(x1) Ux2
    • 2).
  • 29
    • 67749086386 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two striking recent examples of such phenomena occurred during the course of the German parliamentary election campaign in September 2002, and the Spanish election campaign in March 2004. In Germany the disciplined, forceful campaign waged by the SDP and its leader, Gerhard Schroeder, enhanced the party's valence image and helped it achieve an unexpectedly strong election result. In Spain, the response of the governing party (the People's party) to the Madrid train bombing, which occurred just days before the election, was widely believed to have harmed its reputation for competence and honesty, thereby contributing to its unexpectedly poor showing
    • Two striking recent examples of such phenomena occurred during the course of the German parliamentary election campaign in September 2002, and the Spanish election campaign in March 2004. In Germany the disciplined, forceful campaign waged by the SDP and its leader, Gerhard Schroeder, enhanced the party's valence image and helped it achieve an unexpectedly strong election result. In Spain, the response of the governing party (the People's party) to the Madrid train bombing - which occurred just days before the election - was widely believed to have harmed its reputation for competence and honesty, thereby contributing to its unexpectedly poor showing.
  • 30
    • 67749129166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An anonymous reviewer notes that this assumption is consistent with a model of 'expressive' voting, i.e. one where citizens derive utilities from casting votes that express their sincere preferences, rather than deriving instrumental benefits from influencing the election outcome (on this point, see Geoffrey Brennan and Loren Lomansky, Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993, In Remark 2 below we address the issue of instrumental (i.e. outcomeoriented) voting
    • An anonymous reviewer notes that this assumption is consistent with a model of 'expressive' voting, i.e. one where citizens derive utilities from casting votes that express their sincere preferences, rather than deriving instrumental benefits from influencing the election outcome (on this point, see Geoffrey Brennan and Loren Lomansky, Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993). In Remark 2 below we address the issue of instrumental (i.e. outcomeoriented) voting.
  • 31
    • 84869564777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M is the MPP under sincere voting.
    • M is the MPP under sincere voting.
  • 32
    • 67749097640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This equilibrium among voters is not to be confused with the equilibrium among parties that is the primary topic of this article. Denote by jM the MPP under sincere (expressive) voting. Assume that all voters other than a focal voter are sincere. A focal voter who prefers jM, which includes the median voter, cannot improve her utility by switching her vote. Secondly, a focal voter who prefers a party located to the left of jM can only alter the identity of the MPP by switching her vote to a party located to the right of jM. However, given that (1) all voters who prefer a party located to the left of jM must themselves be located to the left of the median voter's position m, and (2) all voters located to the left of the median voter prefer jM to all parties located right of jM see fn. 19, it follows that no focal voter located to the left of m can have an instrumental incentive to switch her vote in order to alter the elec
    • M to all parties located right of jM (see fn. 19), it follows that no focal voter located to the left of m can have an instrumental incentive to switch her vote in order to alter the election outcome in an attempt to change the identity of the MPP. A similar argument applies to a focal voter located to the right of m.
  • 33
    • 67749147138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Policy-Seeking Parties in Proportional Systems with Valence-Related Uncertainty: Does Collective Responsibility for Performance Alter Party Strategies?
    • For an extension of our model that relaxes this independence assumption, see, forthcoming
    • For an extension of our model that relaxes this independence assumption, see James Adams, Lawrence Ezrow, Samuel Merrill III and Zeynep Somer-Topcu, 'Policy-Seeking Parties in Proportional Systems with Valence-Related Uncertainty: Does Collective Responsibility for Performance Alter Party Strategies?' Public Choice (forthcoming).
    • Public Choice
    • Adams, J.1    Ezrow, L.2    Merrill III, S.3    Somer-Topcu, Z.4
  • 34
    • 67749137259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Logit analysis has been employed extensively both in empirical studies of voting behaviour (see Schofield and Sened, Multiparty Democracy: Elections and Legislative Politics), and in spatial models of multiparty competition, see, e.g., Samuel Merrill III and James Adams, 'Computing Nash Equilibria in Probabilistic, Multiparty Spatial Models with Non-Policy Components', Political Analysis, 9 (2001), 347-61.
    • Logit analysis has been employed extensively both in empirical studies of voting behaviour (see Schofield and Sened, Multiparty Democracy: Elections and Legislative Politics), and in spatial models of multiparty competition, see, e.g., Samuel Merrill III and James Adams, 'Computing Nash Equilibria in Probabilistic, Multiparty Spatial Models with Non-Policy Components', Political Analysis, 9 (2001), 347-61.
  • 35
    • 67749113311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See chap. 3 in Kenneth Train, Qualitative Choice Analysis (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 1986) for a proof that the logit model implies choice probabilities of the functional form given by Equation 2
    • See chap. 3 in Kenneth Train, Qualitative Choice Analysis (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 1986) for a proof that the logit model implies choice probabilities of the functional form given by Equation 2
  • 36
    • 67749122154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, under quadratic-loss utility for parties and voters, Equation presented
    • For example, under quadratic-loss utility for parties and voters, (Equation presented)
  • 38
    • 84869574413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 0, then it is single-peaked.
    • 0, then it is single-peaked.
  • 40
    • 67749129167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
  • 41
    • 67749101238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In every scenario we have tested using quadratic voter utility, all parties have moved in the same direction as the focal party; using linear utility, some parties remain fixed while others move in the same direction as that of the focal party. See examples below
    • In every scenario we have tested using quadratic voter utility, all parties have moved in the same direction as the focal party; using linear utility, some parties remain fixed while others move in the same direction as that of the focal party. See examples below.
  • 42
    • 0038321701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model
    • Norman Schofield, 'Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model', Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15 (2003), 371-83;
    • (2003) Journal of Theoretical Politics , vol.15 , pp. 371-383
    • Schofield, N.1
  • 43
    • 67749103651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Norman Schofield, The Median Voter Theorem under Proportional and Plurality Rule, paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Public Choice Society, New Orleans, 2004, We note that Schofield's work on multiparty elections also considers parties' policy-seeking objectives, as well as their expectations about post-election coalition negotiations. However, here we consider only Schofield's conclusions about vote-maximizing parties
    • and Norman Schofield, 'The Median Voter Theorem under Proportional and Plurality Rule' (paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Public Choice Society, New Orleans, 2004). We note that Schofield's work on multiparty elections also considers parties' policy-seeking objectives, as well as their expectations about post-election coalition negotiations. However, here we consider only Schofield's conclusions about vote-maximizing parties.
  • 44
    • 67749111475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schofield shows that the degree of policy moderation by high-valence parties depends on the specifics of the election context. However, if there is more than one high-valence party, as is typically the case in competitive multiparty systems, then the competing high-valence parties will typically not converge all the way to the centre of the voter distribution
    • Schofield shows that the degree of policy moderation by high-valence parties depends on the specifics of the election context. However, if there is more than one high-valence party - as is typically the case in competitive multiparty systems - then the competing high-valence parties will typically not converge all the way to the centre of the voter distribution.
  • 46
    • 67749130772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An exception is a party with centrist policy preferences, which will invariably adopt a centrist policy strategy
    • An exception is a party with centrist policy preferences, which will invariably adopt a centrist policy strategy.
  • 47
    • 84974191786 scopus 로고
    • Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternatives
    • Donald Wittman, 'Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternatives', American Political Science Review, 77 (1983), 142-57;
    • (1983) American Political Science Review , vol.77 , pp. 142-157
    • Wittman, D.1
  • 48
    • 67749147137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote';
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote';
  • 50
    • 67749133482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The parameter a 50.25 is suggested by empirical voting analyses reported in chaps 4 and 6 in Adams, Merrill and Grofman, A Unified Theory of Party Competition. Substantively, this value implies that if the median voter M is located three units closer to Party A than to Party B along the 1-7 left-right scale, and these parties have equal valence images (i.e. V A =VB, then the probability that M will prefer A to B on election day is approximately 90 per cent. We note that realistic variations in the specified value of a did not substantially affect the parties' equilibrium positions (decreasing a resulted in somewhat more dispersed positions and increasing a somewhat depressed party dispersion, With respect to variations in the other model parameters used for our examples, we found that: (1) results for linear loss utility for parties were similar to those for quadratic losses, but somewhat more dispersed; (2) results for larger
    • B), then the probability that M will prefer A to B on election day is approximately 90 per cent. We note that realistic variations in the specified value of a did not substantially affect the parties' equilibrium positions (decreasing a resulted in somewhat more dispersed positions and increasing a somewhat depressed party dispersion). With respect to variations in the other model parameters used for our examples, we found that: (1) results for linear loss utility for parties were similar to those for quadratic losses, but somewhat more dispersed; (2) results for larger party systems (i.e. more than four parties) were somewhat more dispersed. Results for alternative sets of assumptions about the parties' valence images are reported below.
  • 51
    • 85078869736 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • D = 0) imply that if the median voter M is indifferent between a high-valence party (B or C) and a low-valence party (A or D) on policy grounds, the probability that M will prefer the high-valence party on election day is roughly 88 per cent.
    • D = 0) imply that if the median voter M is indifferent between a high-valence party (B or C) and a low-valence party (A or D) on policy grounds, the probability that M will prefer the high-valence party on election day is roughly 88 per cent.
  • 52
    • 67749117905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Similar equilibrium strategies are also found in scenario 3A, in which parties B and D (the centre-left and far right parties) have high valence scores VB, VD, 2, whereas parties A and C (the extreme left and centre-right parties) have low valence scores VA, V C, 0. This scenario plausibly captures the strategic situation in Germany, which features four major parties, the Greens, the Social Democratic Party (SDP, the Free Democrats (FDP, and the CDU/CSU, of which the two smallest are the Greens who espouse sharply left-wing policies, and the FDP which currently espouses centre-right positions. As the valence of either left-of-centre party is increased see scenarios 3B-3E, the optimum strategies at equilibrium for all parties shift to the left
    • C = 0. This scenario plausibly captures the strategic situation in Germany, which features four major parties - the Greens, the Social Democratic Party (SDP), the Free Democrats (FDP), and the CDU/CSU - of which the two smallest are the Greens who espouse sharply left-wing policies, and the FDP which currently espouses centre-right positions. As the valence of either left-of-centre party is increased (see scenarios 3B-3E), the optimum strategies at equilibrium for all parties shift to the left.
  • 54
    • 67749127401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See fn. 37 for the effects of varying other parameters
    • See fn. 37 for the effects of varying other parameters.
  • 55
    • 67749116116 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For instance, when Party A is the focal party, if the preferred positions for the other parties are equally-spaced at RB, 3.25, RC, 4.75, and RD =6 .25, VB, VC, VD, 0, and if VA, 1, the parameters given by the regression equation predict that the (unnormalized) optimal strategy for party A is sA*≅2.97 when (the unnormalized location) RA, 2.50; that s A*52.80 when RA, 1.75; and that sA*52.72 when RA, 1.00. A similar example in which Party B is the focal party suggests that its optimal strategy becomes more extreme by 0.94 units as RB moves from 4.00 to 2.50
    • B moves from 4.00 to 2.50.
  • 56
    • 67749101237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, when Party A is the focal party, if the (unnormalized) party preferred positions are equally-spaced at 1.75, 3.25, 4.75 and 6.25, and VB, VB, VD, 0, then the regression equation projects that the (unnormalized) optimal strategies for party A are sA*52.92 when VA, 0; that s A*52.80 when VA =1; and that s A*52.69 when VA, 2, i.e, Party A's optimal strategy becomes more extreme by 0.23 units as VA increases from 0.0 to 2.0. A similar example, in which Party B is the focal party, projects that its optimal strategy becomes more extreme by only 0.07 units as VB increases from 0.0 to 2.0
    • B increases from 0.0 to 2.0.
  • 58
    • 67749124121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Party Policy Strategies and Valence Issues: An Empirical Study of Ten Post-Communist European Party Systems
    • presented at the, Binghamton
    • Zeynep Somer-Topcu, 'Party Policy Strategies and Valence Issues: An Empirical Study of Ten Post-Communist European Party Systems' (presented at the Conference on the Dynamics of Party Position-Taking, Binghamton, 2007).
    • (2007) Conference on the Dynamics of Party Position-Taking
    • Somer-Topcu, Z.1
  • 59
    • 0004162268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ian Budge, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum and Judith Bara, eds, Oxford: Oxford University Press
    • See Ian Budge, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum and Judith Bara, eds, Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001).
    • (2001) Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998
  • 60
    • 77049117346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Party Policy Adjustment in Response to Rival Parties' Policy Shifts: Spatial Theory and the Dynamics of Party Competition in Twenty-Five Post-War Democracies'
    • forthcoming
    • James Adams and Zeynep Somer-Topcu, 'Party Policy Adjustment in Response to Rival Parties' Policy Shifts: Spatial Theory and the Dynamics of Party Competition in Twenty-Five Post-War Democracies', British Journal of Political Science, forthcoming 2009.
    • (2009) British Journal of Political Science
    • Adams, J.1    Somer-Topcu, Z.2
  • 61
    • 84933494084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Dominant and Central Parties on Cabinet Composition and Durability
    • Peter Van Roozendaal, 'The Effect of Dominant and Central Parties on Cabinet Composition and Durability', Legislative Studies Quarterly, 17 (2002), 5-36.
    • (2002) Legislative Studies Quarterly , vol.17 , pp. 5-36
    • Van Roozendaal, P.1
  • 62
    • 67749109940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
    • Londregan and Romer, 'Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote'.
  • 63
    • 67749099454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Party Shifts and Electoral Penalties: Testing Theories of Party Competition in Britain
    • Numerical calculations for a valence-uncertainty model in which parties have mixed vote-maximizing and policy-seeking motivations yielded equilibrium strategies intermediate between dispersed strategies under policy-seeking and centrist strategies under vote-maximization. With respect to the issue of variable turnout in the electorate, see, forthcoming
    • Numerical calculations for a valence-uncertainty model in which parties have mixed vote-maximizing and policy-seeking motivations yielded equilibrium strategies intermediate between dispersed strategies under policy-seeking and centrist strategies under vote-maximization. With respect to the issue of variable turnout in the electorate, see Jane Green, 'Party Shifts and Electoral Penalties: Testing Theories of Party Competition in Britain', Journal of Politics (forthcoming).
    • Journal of Politics
    • Green, J.1
  • 64
    • 33750217483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Small, Centrist Third Parties Motivate Policy Divergence by Major Parties
    • On this point, see
    • On this point, see James Adams and Samuel Merrill III, 'Why Small, Centrist Third Parties Motivate Policy Divergence by Major Parties', American Political Science Review, 100 (2006), 403-17;
    • (2006) American Political Science Review , vol.100 , pp. 403-417
    • Adams, J.1    Merrill III, S.2
  • 65
    • 69649107706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parties' Policy Programmes and the Dog that Didn't Bark: No Evidence that Proportional Systems Promote Extreme Party Positioning'
    • and Lawrence Ezrow, 'Parties' Policy Programmes and the Dog that Didn't Bark: No Evidence that Proportional Systems Promote Extreme Party Positioning', British Journal of Political Science, 38 (2008), 470-97.
    • (2008) British Journal of Political Science , vol.38 , pp. 470-497
    • Ezrow, L.1
  • 66
    • 85078868547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • k will not change the location of Party k's optimal position.
    • k will not change the location of Party k's optimal position.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.