-
1
-
-
33745328093
-
Choices Parties Define: Policy Alternatives in Representative Elections-17 Countries 1945-1998
-
see also Michael McDonald and Ian Budge, Elections, Parties, and Democracy: Conferring the Median Mandate (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005).
-
Ian Budge and Michael McDonald, ‘Choices Parties Define: Policy Alternatives in Representative Elections-17 Countries 1945-1998’, Party Politics, 12 (2006), 451-66; see also Michael McDonald and Ian Budge, Elections, Parties, and Democracy: Conferring the Median Mandate (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005).
-
(2006)
Party Politics
, vol.12
, pp. 451-466
-
-
Budge, I.1
McDonald, M.2
-
2
-
-
0033484685
-
-
‘Equilibrium in Multicandidate Probabilistic Spatial Voting’, Public Choice, 98, 59-82; Norman Schofield, ‘Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15 (2003), 371-83; Norman Schofield and Itai Sened, Multiparty Democracy: Elections and Legislative Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006); James Adams and Samuel Merrill III, ‘Party Policy Equilibrium for Alternative Spatial Voting Models: An Application to the Norwegian Storting’, European Journal of Political Research, 36 (1999), 35-55; Melvin Hinich and Peter Ordeshook, ‘Plurality Maximization vs. Vote Maximization: A Spatial Analysis with Variable Participation’, American Political Science Review, 64 (1970)
-
These factors include (but are not limited to): the electoral salience of policies relative to unmeasured sources of voters’ party evaluations, the importance of ‘valence’ dimensions of voters’ party evaluations relative to policy dimensions of evaluation, the spatial distribution of voters’ partisan affiliations, and the strategic effects of voter abstention. See, for example, Tse-Min Lin, James Enelow and Han Dorussen, ‘Equilibrium in Multicandidate Probabilistic Spatial Voting’, Public Choice, 98 (1999), 59-82; Norman Schofield, ‘Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15 (2003), 371-83; Norman Schofield and Itai Sened, Multiparty Democracy: Elections and Legislative Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006); James Adams and Samuel Merrill III, ‘Party Policy Equilibrium for Alternative Spatial Voting Models: An Application to the Norwegian Storting’, European Journal of Political Research, 36 (1999), 35-55; Melvin Hinich and Peter Ordeshook, ‘Plurality Maximization vs. Vote Maximization: A Spatial Analysis with Variable Participation’, American Political Science Review, 64 (1970), 772-91.
-
(1999)
These factors include (but are not limited to): the electoral salience of policies relative to unmeasured sources of voters’ party evaluations, the importance of ‘valence’ dimensions of voters’ party evaluations relative to policy dimensions of evaluation, the spatial distribution of voters’ partisan affiliations, and the strategic effects of voter abstention.
, pp. 772-791
-
-
Lin, T.-M.1
Enelow, J.2
Dorussen, H.3
-
4
-
-
0003583341
-
-
(New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1967); William H. Riker, ‘The Two-Party System and Duverger's Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science’, American Political Science Review, 76, 753-66; Rein Taagepera and Matthew Shugart, Seats and Votes: The Effects and Determinants of Electoral Systems (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1989); Gary Cox, Making Votes Count (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997).
-
See also Douglas Rae, The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1967); William H. Riker, ‘The Two-Party System and Duverger's Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science’, American Political Science Review, 76 (1982), 753-66; Rein Taagepera and Matthew Shugart, Seats and Votes: The Effects and Determinants of Electoral Systems (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1989); Gary Cox, Making Votes Count (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997).
-
(1982)
The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws
-
-
Rae, D.1
-
5
-
-
0003978587
-
-
(Notre Dame, Ind.: Notre Dame University Press, )
-
F. A. Hermens, Democracy or Anarchy? (Notre Dame, Ind.: Notre Dame University Press, 1941), p. 19.
-
(1941)
Democracy or Anarchy?
, pp. 19
-
-
Hermens, F.A.1
-
6
-
-
85022349121
-
-
‘A Comparison of Majoritarian and Proportional Electoral Systems Based on Spatial Modeling and “Rational” Politicians’ (paper presented at the Conference on Constitutional Issues in Modern Democracies, Messina, 1997); Jay K. Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections’, Electoral Studies
-
For examples of spatial mappings on more than one dimension, see Norman Schofield, ‘A Comparison of Majoritarian and Proportional Electoral Systems Based on Spatial Modeling and “Rational” Politicians’ (paper presented at the Conference on Constitutional Issues in Modern Democracies, Messina, 1997); Jay K. Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections’, Electoral Studies, 20 (2001), 109-25.
-
(2001)
For examples of spatial mappings on more than one dimension
, vol.20
, pp. 109-125
-
-
Schofield, N.1
-
7
-
-
85022426886
-
Choices Parties Define
-
Budge and McDonald, ‘Choices Parties Define’, p. 453.
-
-
-
McDonald, B.1
-
8
-
-
0003918519
-
-
(New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2000); John Huber and G. Bingham Powell, ‘Congruence between Citizens and Policymakers in Two Visions of Liberal Democracy’, World Politics, 46, 291-326; G. Bingham Powell and Georg S. Vanberg, ‘Election Laws, Disproportionality, and Median Correspondence: Implications for Two Visions of Democracy’, British Journal of Political Science, 30 (2000), 383-411; John Huber, ‘Values and Partisanship in Left-Right Orientations: Measuring Ideology’, European Journal of Political Research, 17 (1989), 599-621; McDonald and Budge, Elections, Parties, and Democracy.
-
See, for example, G. Bingham Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 2000); John Huber and G. Bingham Powell, ‘Congruence between Citizens and Policymakers in Two Visions of Liberal Democracy’, World Politics, 46 (1994), 291-326; G. Bingham Powell and Georg S. Vanberg, ‘Election Laws, Disproportionality, and Median Correspondence: Implications for Two Visions of Democracy’, British Journal of Political Science, 30 (2000), 383-411; John Huber, ‘Values and Partisanship in Left-Right Orientations: Measuring Ideology’, European Journal of Political Research, 17 (1989), 599-621; McDonald and Budge, Elections, Parties, and Democracy.
-
(1994)
Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions
-
-
Bingham Powell, G.1
-
9
-
-
0003422664
-
-
2nd edn (Chatham, N.J.: Chatham House Publishers, ).
-
Russell J. Dalton, Citizen Politics, 2nd edn (Chatham, N.J.: Chatham House Publishers, 1996).
-
(1996)
Citizen Politics
-
-
Dalton, R.J.1
-
10
-
-
34247641525
-
Does PR Promote Political Extremism? Evidence from the West European Parties of the Extreme Right
-
Elisabeth Carter, ‘Does PR Promote Political Extremism? Evidence from the West European Parties of the Extreme Right’, Representation, 40 (2004), 82-100.
-
(2004)
Representation
, vol.40
, pp. 82-100
-
-
Carter, E.1
-
11
-
-
21044456939
-
Party System Compactness: Consequences and Measures
-
R. Michael Alvarez and Jonathan Nagler, ‘Party System Compactness: Consequences and Measures’, Political Analysis, 12 (2004), 46-62.
-
(2004)
Political Analysis
, vol.12
, pp. 46-62
-
-
Michael Alvarez, R.1
Nagler, J.2
-
12
-
-
84934563194
-
Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems
-
Gary Cox, ‘Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems’, American Journal of Political Science, 34 (1990), 905-35.
-
(1990)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.34
, pp. 905-935
-
-
Cox, G.1
-
13
-
-
0242302034
-
Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems
-
Cox, ‘Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems’.
-
-
-
Cox1
-
14
-
-
85022419054
-
A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections
-
Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections’.
-
-
-
Dow1
-
15
-
-
85022371582
-
-
Theoretically, when voting is probabilistic and voters do not attach too much salience to policy distance compared with unmeasured, non-policy motivations, then a unique vote-maximizing equilibrium exists in which all parties in a multiparty election locate at the mean voter position (Lin, Enelow and Dorussen, ‘Equilibrium in Multicandidate Probabilistic Spatial Voting'; but see Schofield, ‘Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model'). Empirically, scholars report computations on survey data from real world elections which suggest that the non-centrist parties that contested these elections could have increased their support in elections held in Britain, France, The Netherlands, Germany and Canada ( ‘Measuring the Relative Impact of Issues and the Economy in Democratic Elections’, Electoral Studies, 19, 237-53; R. Michael Alvarez, Jonathan Nagler and Shaun Bowler, ‘Issues, Economics, and the Dynamics of Multiparty Elections: The 1997 British General Election’, American Political Science Review, 42 (2000), 55-96; James Adams and Samuel Merrill III, ‘Spatial Models of Candidate Competition and the 1988 French Presidential Election: Are Presidential Candidates Vote-Maximizers?’ Journal of Politics, 62 (2000), 729-56; James Adams, Samuel Merrill III and Bernard Grofman, A Unified Theory of Party Competition: A Cross-National Analysis Integrating Spatial and Behavioral Factors (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005). For static analyses, see also Lawrence Ezrow, ‘Are Moderate Parties Rewarded in Multiparty Systems? A Pooled Analysis of Western European Elections, 1984-98’, European Journal of Political Research, 44 (2005)
-
There is both a theoretical and empirically-based literature suggesting that parties in multiparty elections (i.e. elections involving at least three parties) maximize votes by presenting centrist positions. Theoretically, when voting is probabilistic and voters do not attach too much salience to policy distance compared with unmeasured, non-policy motivations, then a unique vote-maximizing equilibrium exists in which all parties in a multiparty election locate at the mean voter position (Lin, Enelow and Dorussen, ‘Equilibrium in Multicandidate Probabilistic Spatial Voting'; but see Schofield, ‘Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model'). Empirically, scholars report computations on survey data from real world elections which suggest that the non-centrist parties that contested these elections could have increased their support in elections held in Britain, France, The Netherlands, Germany and Canada (see R. Michael Alvarez, Jonathan Nagler and Jennifer Willette, ‘Measuring the Relative Impact of Issues and the Economy in Democratic Elections’, Electoral Studies, 19 (2000), 237-53; R. Michael Alvarez, Jonathan Nagler and Shaun Bowler, ‘Issues, Economics, and the Dynamics of Multiparty Elections: The 1997 British General Election’, American Political Science Review, 42 (2000), 55-96; James Adams and Samuel Merrill III, ‘Spatial Models of Candidate Competition and the 1988 French Presidential Election: Are Presidential Candidates Vote-Maximizers?’ Journal of Politics, 62 (2000), 729-56; James Adams, Samuel Merrill III and Bernard Grofman, A Unified Theory of Party Competition: A Cross-National Analysis Integrating Spatial and Behavioral Factors (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005). For static analyses, see also Lawrence Ezrow, ‘Are Moderate Parties Rewarded in Multiparty Systems? A Pooled Analysis of Western European Elections, 1984-98’, European Journal of Political Research, 44 (2005), 881-98.
-
(2000)
There is both a theoretical and empirically-based literature suggesting that parties in multiparty elections (i.e. elections involving at least three parties) maximize votes by presenting centrist positions.
, pp. 881-898
-
-
Michael Alvarez, R.1
Nagler, J.2
Willette, J.3
-
16
-
-
0346671333
-
-
By contrast disproportional, plurality-based voting systems frequently manufacture single-party parliamentary majorities, as is the case in Britain, as well as in New Zealand prior to its switch to proportional representation for the 1996 election (for a review of evidence on this issue, see Michael McDonald, Sylvie Mendes and Ian Budge, ‘What are Elections For? Conferring the Median Mandate’, British Journal of Political Science, 34, 1-26). In these cases, ‘losing’ parties have no chance of becoming part of the government. Alternatively, proportional systems give small parties the opportunity to coalesce with larger parties and take part in the governing coalition (e.g., the Free Democratic Party (FDP) throughout most of the post-war period in Germany).
-
In addition, votes are less directly tied to office in proportional systems-i.e., parties with smaller vote shares can still participate in governing coalitions in PR systems. By contrast disproportional, plurality-based voting systems frequently manufacture single-party parliamentary majorities, as is the case in Britain, as well as in New Zealand prior to its switch to proportional representation for the 1996 election (for a review of evidence on this issue, see Michael McDonald, Sylvie Mendes and Ian Budge, ‘What are Elections For? Conferring the Median Mandate’, British Journal of Political Science, 34 (2004), 1-26). In these cases, ‘losing’ parties have no chance of becoming part of the government. Alternatively, proportional systems give small parties the opportunity to coalesce with larger parties and take part in the governing coalition (e.g., the Free Democratic Party (FDP) throughout most of the post-war period in Germany).
-
(2004)
addition, votes are less directly tied to office in proportional systems-i.e., parties with smaller vote shares can still participate in governing coalitions in PR systems.
-
-
-
17
-
-
0242302034
-
Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems
-
Cox, ‘Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems’.
-
-
-
Cox1
-
18
-
-
84916079532
-
The Principle of Minimum Differentiation Reconsidered: Some New Developments in the Theory of Spatial Competition
-
See also Curtis B. Eaton and Richard G. Lipsey, ‘The Principle of Minimum Differentiation Reconsidered: Some New Developments in the Theory of Spatial Competition’, Review of Economic Studies, 42 (1975), 27-49.
-
(1975)
Review of Economic Studies
, vol.42
, pp. 27-49
-
-
Eaton, C.B.1
Lipsey, R.G.2
-
19
-
-
0013317298
-
Centrifugal Incentives in Multi-Candidate Elections
-
Samuel Merrill III and James Adams, ‘Centrifugal Incentives in Multi-Candidate Elections’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 14 (2002), 275-300.
-
(2002)
Journal of Theoretical Politics
, vol.14
, pp. 275-300
-
-
Merrill, S.1
Adams, J.2
-
22
-
-
0003541391
-
-
(New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, ); Taagepera and Shugart, Seats and Votes; Cox, Making Votes Count.
-
See Arend Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1999); Taagepera and Shugart, Seats and Votes; Cox, Making Votes Count.
-
(1999)
Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries
-
-
Lijphart, A.1
-
25
-
-
84949792766
-
Effective” Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe
-
Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy.
-
Markku Laakso and Rein Taagepera, ‘ “Effective” Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 12 (1979), 3-27; Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy.
-
(1979)
Comparative Political Studies
, vol.12
, pp. 3-27
-
-
Laakso, M.1
Taagepera, R.2
-
26
-
-
84970315639
-
Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies
-
1, 73-111; Francis Castles and Peter Mair, ‘Left-Right Political Scales: Some Expert Judgments’, European Journal of Political Research, 12 (1984)
-
John Huber and Ronald Inglehart, ‘Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies’, Party Politics, 1 (1995), 73-111; Francis Castles and Peter Mair, ‘Left-Right Political Scales: Some Expert Judgments’, European Journal of Political Research, 12 (1984), 73-88.
-
(1995)
Party Politics
, pp. 73-88
-
-
Huber, J.1
Inglehart, R.2
-
27
-
-
85022405547
-
Issues, Economics, and the Dynamics of Multiparty Elections';
-
‘Party Policy Equilibrium for Alternative Spatial Voting Models'; Adams and Merrill, ‘Spatial Models of Candidate Competition and the French Presidential Election?’
-
Alvarez, Nagler and Bowler, ‘Issues, Economics, and the Dynamics of Multiparty Elections'; Adams and Merrill, ‘Party Policy Equilibrium for Alternative Spatial Voting Models'; Adams and Merrill, ‘Spatial Models of Candidate Competition and the 1988 French Presidential Election?’
-
(1988)
Adams and Merrill
-
-
Nagler, A.1
Bowler2
-
28
-
-
0004162268
-
-
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, ). In addition, scholars have employed the technique of multidimensional scaling, which involves estimating the parties’ positions relative to voters’ positions via analyses of voters’ policy preferences in combination with their party evaluations (see Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections'; Schofield and Sened, Multiparty Democracy).
-
Ian Budge, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Judith Bara and Eric Tanenbaum, Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001). In addition, scholars have employed the technique of multidimensional scaling, which involves estimating the parties’ positions relative to voters’ positions via analyses of voters’ policy preferences in combination with their party evaluations (see Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections'; Schofield and Sened, Multiparty Democracy).
-
(2001)
Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945-1998
-
-
Budge, I.1
Klingemann, H.-D.2
Volkens, A.3
Bara, J.4
Tanenbaum, E.5
-
29
-
-
85022429056
-
Party System Compactness';
-
Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections'; Ken Kollman, John H. Miller, and Scott E. Page, ‘Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes’, British Journal of Political Science, 28, 139-58. The argument for weighting average party policy extremism by party size is that such weighting accounts for the fact that the small parties in some countries (e.g., the American Green party, the British Socialist party, and so on) have virtually no political influence, so that their policy proposals do not enlarge the menu of policy choices available to voters in any meaningful sense. The arguments for relying on an unweighted measure of party policy extremism are, first, that any weighting system is unavoidably arbitrary given that parties’ policy influence does not necessarily correlate with vote (or seat) share, and, secondly, that small parties provide a vehicle through which voters can express their policy preferences, regardless of whether or not such parties significantly influence government policy outputs.
-
Alvarez and Nagler, ‘Party System Compactness'; Dow, ‘A Comparative Spatial Analysis of Majoritarian and Proportional Elections'; Ken Kollman, John H. Miller, and Scott E. Page, ‘Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes’, British Journal of Political Science, 28 (1998), 139-58. The argument for weighting average party policy extremism by party size is that such weighting accounts for the fact that the small parties in some countries (e.g., the American Green party, the British Socialist party, and so on) have virtually no political influence, so that their policy proposals do not enlarge the menu of policy choices available to voters in any meaningful sense. The arguments for relying on an unweighted measure of party policy extremism are, first, that any weighting system is unavoidably arbitrary given that parties’ policy influence does not necessarily correlate with vote (or seat) share, and, secondly, that small parties provide a vehicle through which voters can express their policy preferences, regardless of whether or not such parties significantly influence government policy outputs.
-
(1998)
-
-
Nagler, A.1
-
30
-
-
85022431963
-
-
‘Special Symposium: Comparing Measures of Party Positioning: Expert Manifesto, and Survey Data’, Electoral Studies, 26, 1-141).
-
Aspecial issue of Electoral Studies presents several articles which analyse the tradeoffs that accompany each approach used to estimate parties’ policy positions (Gary Marks, ed., ‘Special Symposium: Comparing Measures of Party Positioning: Expert Manifesto, and Survey Data’, Electoral Studies, 26 (2007), 1-141).
-
(2007)
Aspecial issue of Electoral Studies presents several articles which analyse the tradeoffs that accompany each approach used to estimate parties’ policy positions
-
-
Marks, G.1
-
31
-
-
85022429056
-
Party System Compactness';
-
Kollman, Miller and Page, ‘Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes’.
-
Alvarez and Nagler, ‘Party System Compactness'; Kollman, Miller and Page, ‘Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes’.
-
-
-
Nagler, A.1
-
32
-
-
85022429056
-
Party System Compactness
-
Alvarez and Nagler, ‘Party System Compactness’.
-
-
-
Nagler, A.1
-
33
-
-
0000113734
-
Spatial Models of Party Competition
-
See Donald Stokes, ‘Spatial Models of Party Competition’, American Political Science Review, 57 (1963), 368-77.
-
(1963)
American Political Science Review
, vol.57
, pp. 368-377
-
-
Stokes, D.1
-
34
-
-
19944423422
-
Modeling the Interaction of Parties, Activists and Voters: Why Is the Political Centre so Empty?
-
44 (2005), 355-90; Schofield, ‘Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model'; James Adams, ‘Policy Divergence in Multiparty Probabilistic Spatial Voting’, Public Choice, 100, 103-22. See also Stuart Elaine Macdonald and George Rabinowitz, ‘Solving the Paradox of Nonconvergence: Valence, Position, and Direction in Democratic Politics’, Electoral Studies, 17 (1998)
-
See Norman Schofield and Itai Sened, ‘Modeling the Interaction of Parties, Activists and Voters: Why Is the Political Centre so Empty?’ European Journal of Political Research, 44 (2005), 355-90; Schofield, ‘Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model'; James Adams, ‘Policy Divergence in Multiparty Probabilistic Spatial Voting’, Public Choice, 100 (1999), 103-22. See also Stuart Elaine Macdonald and George Rabinowitz, ‘Solving the Paradox of Nonconvergence: Valence, Position, and Direction in Democratic Politics’, Electoral Studies, 17 (1998), 281-300.
-
(1999)
European Journal of Political Research
, pp. 281-300
-
-
Schofield, N.1
Sened, I.2
-
35
-
-
0037709798
-
Activists and Partisan Realignment in the United States
-
(2003), John Aldrich, ‘A Downsian Spatial Model with Party Activists’, American Political Science Review, 77, 974-90; John Aldrich, ‘A Spatial Model with Party Activists: Implications for Electoral Dynamics’, Public Choice, 41 (1983), 63-100; John Aldrich, Why Parties? (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995).
-
Gary Miller and Norman Schofield, ‘Activists and Partisan Realignment in the United States’, American Political Science Review, 97 (2003), 245-60; John Aldrich, ‘A Downsian Spatial Model with Party Activists’, American Political Science Review, 77 (1983), 974-90; John Aldrich, ‘A Spatial Model with Party Activists: Implications for Electoral Dynamics’, Public Choice, 41 (1983), 63-100; John Aldrich, Why Parties? (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995).
-
(1983)
American Political Science Review
, vol.97
, pp. 245-260
-
-
Miller, G.1
Schofield, N.2
-
36
-
-
0032260628
-
Multiparty Electoral Competition in the Netherlands and Germany: A Model Based on Multinomial Probit
-
Public Choice
-
Norman Schofield, Andrew Martin, Kevin Quinn and David Nixon, ‘Multiparty Electoral Competition in the Netherlands and Germany: A Model Based on Multinomial Probit’, Public Choice, 97 (1999), 257-93.
-
(1999)
, vol.97
, pp. 257-293
-
-
Schofield, N.1
Martin, A.2
Quinn, K.3
Nixon, D.4
-
37
-
-
0003494983
-
-
(Chicago: Markham, ); Michael Laver and Kenneth Shepsle, Making and Breaking Governments (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy; Huber and Powell, ‘Congruence between Citizens and Policymakers in Two Visions of Liberal Democracy’.
-
See Robert Axelrod, Conflict of Interest (Chicago: Markham, 1970); Michael Laver and Kenneth Shepsle, Making and Breaking Governments (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Powell, Elections as Instruments of Democracy; Huber and Powell, ‘Congruence between Citizens and Policymakers in Two Visions of Liberal Democracy’.
-
(1970)
Conflict of Interest
-
-
Axelrod, R.1
|