메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 20, Issue 2, 2006, Pages 132-159

The political economy of religion and social insurance in the United States, 1910-1939

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 33845878245     PISSN: 0898588X     EISSN: 14698692     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0898588X06000071     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (20)

References (219)
  • 1
    • 33644893686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recent examples include Margaret Weir, States, Race, and the Decline of New Deal Liberalism, Studies in American Political Development 19 (2005): 157-72;
    • Recent examples include Margaret Weir, "States, Race, and the Decline of New Deal Liberalism," Studies in American Political Development 19 (2005): 157-72;
  • 4
    • 0034949589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Group Loyalty and the Taste for Redistribution
    • Erzo Luttmer, "Group Loyalty and the Taste for Redistribution," Journal of Political Economy 109 (2001): 500-28;
    • (2001) Journal of Political Economy , vol.109 , pp. 500-528
    • Luttmer, E.1
  • 6
    • 0032325207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why the Poor do not Expropriate the Rich: An Old Argument in New Garb
    • and John Roemer, "Why the Poor do not Expropriate the Rich: an Old Argument in New Garb," Journal of Public Economics 70 (1998): 399-424.
    • (1998) Journal of Public Economics , vol.70 , pp. 399-424
    • Roemer, J.1
  • 7
    • 33646348461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Belief in a Just World and Redistributive Politics
    • Roland Benabou and Jean Tirole, "Belief in a Just World and Redistributive Politics," Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (2006): 699-746.
    • (2006) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.121 , pp. 699-746
    • Benabou, R.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 9
    • 33845877249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In making this argument, we draw on the arguments and empirical evidence presented by Mark Chaves, Congregations in America (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004);
    • In making this argument, we draw on the arguments and empirical evidence presented by Mark Chaves, Congregations in America (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004);
  • 11
    • 33845902617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and H. Paul Douglass and Edmund de Brunner, The Protestant Church as a Social Institution (New York: Harper and Brothers,1935).
    • and H. Paul Douglass and Edmund de Brunner, The Protestant Church as a Social Institution (New York: Harper and Brothers,1935).
  • 12
    • 82655160828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social Mobility and Redistributive Politics
    • A subject that has been analyzed in depth in Thomas Piketty, 110 1995
    • A subject that has been analyzed in depth in Thomas Piketty, "Social Mobility and Redistributive Politics," Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1995): 551-84.
    • Quarterly Journal of Economics , pp. 551-584
  • 13
    • 33845864799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In so doing we hope to contribute to the literature that examines the political economy of welfare state policies in a comparative context including Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003);
    • In so doing we hope to contribute to the literature that examines the political economy of welfare state policies in a comparative context including Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003);
  • 14
    • 0032377251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Historical Logic of National Insurance: Structure and Sequence in the Development of British, Canadian, and U.S. Medical Policy
    • Jacob Hacker, "The Historical Logic of National Insurance: Structure and Sequence in the Development of British, Canadian, and U.S. Medical Policy," Studies in American Political Development 12 (1998): 57-130;
    • (1998) Studies in American Political Development , vol.12 , pp. 57-130
    • Hacker, J.1
  • 16
    • 4043048784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Varieties of Capitalist Interests: Power Institutions, and the Regulatory Welfare State in the United States and Sweden
    • Peter Swenson, "Varieties of Capitalist Interests: Power Institutions, and the Regulatory Welfare State in the United States and Sweden," Studies in American Political Development 18 (2004): 1-29;
    • (2004) Studies in American Political Development , vol.18 , pp. 1-29
    • Swenson, P.1
  • 18
  • 19
    • 0035543616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inequality, Social Insurance, and Redistribution
    • Karl Moene and Michael Wallerstein, "Inequality, Social Insurance, and Redistribution," American Political Science Review 95 (2001): 859-73;
    • (2001) American Political Science Review , vol.95 , pp. 859-873
    • Moene, K.1    Wallerstein, M.2
  • 20
    • 0003636930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul Pierson, ed, Oxford: Oxford University Press
    • Paul Pierson, ed., The New Politics of the Welfare State (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001),
    • (2001) The New Politics of the Welfare State
  • 26
    • 0038792725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State
    • See
    • See Jacob Hacker and Paul Pierson, "Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State," Politics & Society 30 (2002): 277-325;
    • (2002) Politics & Society , vol.30 , pp. 277-325
    • Hacker, J.1    Pierson, P.2
  • 27
    • 34248236719 scopus 로고
    • When Effect Becomes Cause: Policy Feedback and Political Change
    • Paul Pierson, "When Effect Becomes Cause: Policy Feedback and Political Change," World Politics 45 (1993): 595-628;
    • (1993) World Politics , vol.45 , pp. 595-628
    • Pierson, P.1
  • 30
    • 0021545661 scopus 로고
    • Why Not Equal Protection? Explaining the Politics of Public Social Spending in Britain, 1900-1911, and the United States, 1880s-1920
    • See
    • See Ann Shola Orloff and Theda Skocpol, "Why Not Equal Protection? Explaining the Politics of Public Social Spending in Britain, 1900-1911, and the United States, 1880s-1920," American Sociological Review 49 (1984): 726-50;
    • (1984) American Sociological Review , vol.49 , pp. 726-750
    • Shola Orloff, A.1    Skocpol, T.2
  • 34
  • 35
    • 33845882301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Section 3, we discuss the contributions of several authors on this subject including Sydney Ahlstrom, A Religious History of the American People (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1972);
    • In Section 3, we discuss the contributions of several authors on this subject including Sydney Ahlstrom, A Religious History of the American People (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1972);
  • 42
    • 11544257066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Adoption of Workers' Compensation in the United States: 1900-1930
    • Price Fishback and Shawn Everett Kantor, "The Adoption of Workers' Compensation in the United States: 1900-1930," Journal of Law and Economics 41 (1998): 305-41;
    • (1998) Journal of Law and Economics , vol.41 , pp. 305-341
    • Fishback, P.1    Everett Kantor, S.2
  • 43
    • 0040681729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of Workers' Compensation Benefit Levels, 1910-1930
    • and Price Fishback and Shawn Everett Kantor, "The Political Economy of Workers' Compensation Benefit Levels, 1910-1930," Explorations in Economic History 35 (1998): 109-39.
    • (1998) Explorations in Economic History , vol.35 , pp. 109-139
    • Fishback, P.1    Everett Kantor, S.2
  • 44
    • 84971164439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These include Robert Asher, Business and Workers' Welfare in the Progressive Era: Workmen's Compensation Reform in Massachusetts, 1880-1911, Business History Review 43 (1969): 452-75;
    • These include Robert Asher, "Business and Workers' Welfare in the Progressive Era: Workmen's Compensation Reform in Massachusetts, 1880-1911," Business History Review 43 (1969): 452-75;
  • 45
    • 0040319289 scopus 로고
    • Failure and Fulfillment: Agitation for Employers' Liability Legislation and the Origins of Workmen's Compensation in New York State, 1876-1910
    • Robert Asher, "Failure and Fulfillment: Agitation for Employers' Liability Legislation and the Origins of Workmen's Compensation in New York State, 1876-1910," Labor History 24 (1983): 198-222;
    • (1983) Labor History , vol.24 , pp. 198-222
    • Asher, R.1
  • 46
    • 0032286928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • R. Rudy Higgins-Evenson, From Industrial Police to Workmen's Compensation: Public Policy and Industrial Accidents in New York, 1880-1910, Labor History 39 (1998): 365-80;
    • R. Rudy Higgins-Evenson, "From Industrial Police to Workmen's Compensation: Public Policy and Industrial Accidents in New York, 1880-1910," Labor History 39 (1998): 365-80;
  • 47
    • 1542637731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inventing Industrial Accidents and Their Insurance: Discourse and Workers' Compensation in the United States, 1880s-1910s
    • Julian Go III, "Inventing Industrial Accidents and Their Insurance: Discourse and Workers' Compensation in the United States, 1880s-1910s," Social Science History 20 (1996): 401-38;
    • (1996) Social Science History , vol.20 , pp. 401-438
    • Julian III, G.1
  • 48
    • 0036024701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Workers' Compensation, Federalism, and the Heavy Hand of History
    • Christopher Howard, "Workers' Compensation, Federalism, and the Heavy Hand of History," Studies in American Political Development 16 (2002): 28-47;
    • (2002) Studies in American Political Development , vol.16 , pp. 28-47
    • Howard, C.1
  • 49
    • 33845886755 scopus 로고
    • Labor Legislation in Thirteen Southern States
    • Addison Cutler "Labor Legislation in Thirteen Southern States," Southern Economic Journal 7 (1941): 297-316;
    • (1941) Southern Economic Journal , vol.7 , pp. 297-316
    • Cutler, A.1
  • 50
    • 0347754391 scopus 로고
    • Big Business and the Origins of Workmen's Compensation
    • and James Weinstein, "Big Business and the Origins of Workmen's Compensation" Labor History 8 (1967): 156-74.
    • (1967) Labor History , vol.8 , pp. 156-174
    • Weinstein, J.1
  • 51
    • 33845912485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Its importance is easily measured by the fact that U.S. state governments continue to spend twice as much on workers' compensation as on unemployment insurance.
    • Its importance is easily measured by the fact that U.S. state governments continue to spend twice as much on workers' compensation as on unemployment insurance.
  • 53
    • 33845877783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Given the time period for our study, we do not consider the important question Weir raises in States, Race, and the Decline of New Deal Liberalism, where she argues that certain institutions put in place during the Progressive Era, such as independent boards for the administration of workers' compensation programs, ultimately undermined the subsequent possibility for state governments to pursue active welfare policies.
    • Given the time period for our study, we do not consider the important question Weir raises in "States, Race, and the Decline of New Deal Liberalism," where she argues that certain institutions put in place during the Progressive Era, such as independent boards for the administration of workers' compensation programs, ultimately undermined the subsequent possibility for state governments to pursue active welfare policies.
  • 54
    • 0003885645 scopus 로고
    • The early and extensive study provided by, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, provides a wealth of evidence on the Works Progress Administration
    • The early and extensive study provided by Donald S. Howard, The WPA and Federal Relief Policy (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1943) provides a wealth of evidence on the Works Progress Administration.
    • (1943) The WPA and Federal Relief Policy
    • Howard, D.S.1
  • 56
    • 0033794017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wage Wars: Institutional Politics, WPA Wages, and the Struggle for U.S. Social Policy
    • Amenta and Drew Halfmann, "Wage Wars: Institutional Politics, WPA Wages, and the Struggle for U.S. Social Policy," American Sociological Review 67 (2000): 506-28;
    • (2000) American Sociological Review , vol.67 , pp. 506-528
    • Amenta1    Halfmann, D.2
  • 57
    • 0002822709 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of New Deal Spending: An Econometric Analysis
    • and Gavin Wright, "The Political Economy of New Deal Spending: An Econometric Analysis," Review of Economics and Statistics 56 (1974): 30-38.
    • (1974) Review of Economics and Statistics , vol.56 , pp. 30-38
    • Wright, G.1
  • 64
    • 0034343619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Spirit of Capitalism? Religious Doctrine, Values, and Economic Attitude Constructs
    • David C. Barker and Christopher Jan Carman, "The Spirit of Capitalism? Religious Doctrine, Values, and Economic Attitude Constructs," Political Behavior 22 (2000): 1-27;
    • (2000) Political Behavior , vol.22 , pp. 1-27
    • Barker, D.C.1    Jan Carman, C.2
  • 65
    • 23944490165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Religious Roots of Modern Poverty Policy: Catholic, Lutheran, and Reformed Protestant Traditions Compared
    • and Sigrun Kahl, "The Religious Roots of Modern Poverty Policy: Catholic, Lutheran, and Reformed Protestant Traditions Compared," European Journal of Sociology 46 (2005): 91-126.
    • (2005) European Journal of Sociology , vol.46 , pp. 91-126
    • Kahl, S.1
  • 66
    • 0001322910 scopus 로고
    • The Redistributive Roles of Unemployment Insurance and the Dynamics of Voting
    • Randall Wright, "The Redistributive Roles of Unemployment Insurance and the Dynamics of Voting," Journal of Public Economics 31 (1986): 377-99.
    • (1986) Journal of Public Economics , vol.31 , pp. 377-399
    • Wright, R.1
  • 67
    • 0001122602 scopus 로고
    • Unhappiness and Unemployment
    • See
    • See Andrew Clark and Andrew Oswald, "Unhappiness and Unemployment," The Economic Journal 104 (1994): 648-59;
    • (1994) The Economic Journal , vol.104 , pp. 648-659
    • Clark, A.1    Oswald, A.2
  • 69
    • 33845863992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is also worth noting that the formal presentation of our model in Appendix A illustrates precisely why this third assumption matters
    • It is also worth noting that the formal presentation of our model in Appendix A illustrates precisely why this third assumption matters.
  • 71
    • 0141754075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Religiousness and Depression: Evidence for a Main Effect and Moderating Influence of Stressful Life Events
    • Timothy Smith, Michael McCullough, and Justin Poll, "Religiousness and Depression: Evidence for a Main Effect and Moderating Influence of Stressful Life Events," Psychological Bulletin 129 (2003): 614-36;
    • (2003) Psychological Bulletin , vol.129 , pp. 614-636
    • Smith, T.1    McCullough, M.2    Poll, J.3
  • 72
    • 0025484243 scopus 로고
    • Intrinsic Religiousness and Religious Coping as Life Stress Moderators for Catholics versus Protestants
    • and Crystal Park, Lawrence Cohen, and Lisa Herb, "Intrinsic Religiousness and Religious Coping as Life Stress Moderators for Catholics versus Protestants," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 59 (1990): 562-74.
    • (1990) Journal of Personality and Social Psychology , vol.59 , pp. 562-574
    • Park, C.1    Cohen, L.2    Herb, L.3
  • 75
    • 33845901866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sigmund Freud, The Future of an Illusion (1927; London: Vintage, The Hogarth Press, and the Institute of Psycho-Analysis, 2001);
    • Sigmund Freud, The Future of an Illusion (1927; London: Vintage, The Hogarth Press, and the Institute of Psycho-Analysis, 2001);
  • 78
    • 0026071531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This same correlation is shown in Christopher Ellison, Religious Involvement and Subjective Well-Being, Journal of Health and Social Behavior 32 1991, 80-99
    • This same correlation is shown in Christopher Ellison, "Religious Involvement and Subjective Well-Being," Journal of Health and Social Behavior 32 (1991): 80-99,
  • 79
    • 84935664376 scopus 로고
    • Does Religious Commitment Contribute to Individual Life Satisfaction
    • as well as in a second study by, which demonstrates that religiosity has a positive correlation with subjective life satisfaction even when controlling for levels of sociability
    • as well as in a second study by Ellison, David Gay, and Thomas Glass, "Does Religious Commitment Contribute to Individual Life Satisfaction," Social Forces 68 (1989): 100-123, which demonstrates that religiosity has a positive correlation with subjective life satisfaction even when controlling for levels of sociability.
    • (1989) Social Forces , vol.68 , pp. 100-123
    • Ellison, D.G.1    Glass, T.2
  • 80
    • 33748927586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • NBER Working Paper 11377 , has recently presented related evidence using a novel instrument for religiosity involving the density of a religion in a particular area given the area's ancestral mix
    • Jonathan Gruber, "Religious Market Structure, Religious Participation, and Outcomes: Is Religion Good for You?" NBER Working Paper 11377 (2005), has recently presented related evidence using a novel instrument for religiosity involving the density of a religion in a particular area given the area's ancestral mix.
    • (2005) Religious Market Structure, Religious Participation, and Outcomes: Is Religion Good for You
    • Gruber, J.1
  • 82
    • 33845880957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Smith, McCullough, and Poll, Religiousness and Depression.
    • and Smith, McCullough, and Poll, "Religiousness and Depression."
  • 84
    • 0039519689 scopus 로고
    • Examining Life Insurance Ownership through Demographic and Psychographic Characteristics
    • John Burnett and Bruce Palmer, "Examining Life Insurance Ownership through Demographic and Psychographic Characteristics," Journal of Risk and Insurance 51 (1984): 453-67.
    • (1984) Journal of Risk and Insurance , vol.51 , pp. 453-467
    • Burnett, J.1    Palmer, B.2
  • 85
    • 0018195309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Viviana A. Zelizer, Human Values and the Market: The Case of Life Insurance and Death in Nineteenth-Century America American Journal of Sociology 84 (1978): 591-610, provides historical evidence to demonstrate that the growth of the life insurance industry in nineteenth century America was initially limited by religious beliefs involving trusting in God to provide for one's future, among other factors.
    • Viviana A. Zelizer, "Human Values and the Market: The Case of Life Insurance and Death in Nineteenth-Century America" American Journal of Sociology 84 (1978): 591-610, provides historical evidence to demonstrate that the growth of the life insurance industry in nineteenth century America was initially limited by religious beliefs involving trusting in God to provide for one's future, among other factors.
  • 86
    • 33845863742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Redistributive Taxation with Endogenous Sentiments, Matteo Cervellati, Joan Esteban, and Laurence Kranich provide an example of a model of redistributive politics where utility from income and from a psychic benefit are not additively separable (available online at http://ideas.repec.org/p/iza/izadps/dp2312.html [last viewed 2 Oct. 2006]).
    • In "Redistributive Taxation with Endogenous Sentiments," Matteo Cervellati, Joan Esteban, and Laurence Kranich provide an example of a model of redistributive politics where utility from income and from a "psychic benefit" are not additively separable (available online at http://ideas.repec.org/p/iza/izadps/dp2312.html [last viewed 2 Oct. 2006]).
  • 89
    • 33845909912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On this, see Appendix A, below, for significant supporting detail
    • On this, see Appendix A, below, for significant supporting detail.
  • 91
    • 33845904206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Belief in a Just World, Benabou and Tirole also consider a model where attitudes toward redistribution depend on religious beliefs. In this case, even when all individuals know the true influence of effort on individual income, they might have different redistributive preferences if they have different beliefs about the extent to which industriousness is rewarded in the afterlife. Individuals who expect that industriousness is rewarded in this manner expect to exert more effort and thus prefer less redistributive taxation.
    • In "Belief in a Just World," Benabou and Tirole also consider a model where attitudes toward redistribution depend on religious beliefs. In this case, even when all individuals know the true influence of effort on individual income, they might have different redistributive preferences if they have different beliefs about the extent to which industriousness is rewarded in the afterlife. Individuals who expect that industriousness is rewarded in this manner expect to exert more effort and thus prefer less redistributive taxation.
  • 92
    • 33845884125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We would like to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point
    • We would like to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point.
  • 95
    • 33845905317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Rauschenbusch's views, Douglass F. Ottati, Foreward in Rauschenbusch, Christianity and the Social Crisis, (1991 ed.).
    • On Rauschenbusch's views, Douglass F. Ottati, "Foreward" in Rauschenbusch, Christianity and the Social Crisis, (1991 ed.).
  • 104
    • 33845885909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some of the best evidence on this period is offered in Miller's thorough study of Protestant publications (Miller, American Protestantism and Social Issues, 17-47. ibid.).
    • Some of the best evidence on this period is offered in Miller's thorough study of Protestant publications (Miller, American Protestantism and Social Issues, 17-47. ibid.).
  • 108
    • 33749856323 scopus 로고
    • 22 Feb
    • Literary Digest, 22 Feb. 1936, 8,
    • (1936) Literary Digest , pp. 8
  • 109
    • 33845865351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • cited in Miller, American Protestantism and Social Issues, 122.
    • cited in Miller, American Protestantism and Social Issues, 122.
  • 110
    • 33845876417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Bishops' Program for Social Reconstruction, Feb. 1919. This program suggested that social insurance should be maintained until such time a legal minimum wage was established at a level sufficiently high to allow workers to make sufficient precautionary savings.
    • "The Bishops' Program for Social Reconstruction," Feb. 1919. This program suggested that social insurance should be maintained until such time a legal minimum wage was established at a level sufficiently high to allow workers to make sufficient precautionary savings.
  • 113
    • 33845895051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pelikan suggests this was reinforced by the medieval papal doctrine that there were two swords, namely, the spiritual and the temporal and both were wielded by the church (Jaroslav Pelikan, The Christian Tradition: A History of the Development of the Doctrine, 5: Christian Doctrine and Modern Culture Since 1700 [Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989], 322).
    • Pelikan suggests this was reinforced by the medieval papal doctrine that there were "two swords, namely, the spiritual and the temporal" and both were wielded by the church (Jaroslav Pelikan, The Christian Tradition: A History of the Development of the Doctrine, Volume 5: Christian Doctrine and Modern Culture Since 1700 [Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989], 322).
  • 114
    • 33845904994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cited in Ahlstrom, Religious History of the American People, 789 (emphasis in orig.). In Religious Roots of Modern Poverty Policy, Sigrun Kahl has recently presented evidence on the traditional division between Catholic, Lutheran, and Calvinist beliefs about the responsibility of the poor for their own condition, based on edicts from the Reformation concerning begging and poor relief.
    • Cited in Ahlstrom, Religious History of the American People, 789 (emphasis in orig.). In "Religious Roots of Modern Poverty Policy," Sigrun Kahl has recently presented evidence on the traditional division between Catholic, Lutheran, and Calvinist beliefs about the responsibility of the poor for their own condition, based on edicts from the Reformation concerning begging and poor relief.
  • 115
    • 0039973260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In early work on individual level support for New Deal policies, Wesley Allinsmith and Beverly Allinsmith, concluded that average support was clearly correlated with average income levels across denominations (Religious Affiliation and Politico-Economic Attitude, Public Opinion Quarterly 12 [1948]: 377-89).
    • In early work on individual level support for New Deal policies, Wesley Allinsmith and Beverly Allinsmith, concluded that average support was clearly correlated with average income levels across denominations ("Religious Affiliation and Politico-Economic Attitude," Public Opinion Quarterly 12 [1948]: 377-89).
  • 121
    • 84929067016 scopus 로고
    • State Timing of Policy Adoption: Workmen's Compensation in the United States, 1909-1929
    • Eliza K. Pavalko, "State Timing of Policy Adoption: Workmen's Compensation in the United States, 1909-1929," American Journal of Sociology 95 (1989): 592-615.
    • (1989) American Journal of Sociology , vol.95 , pp. 592-615
    • Pavalko, E.K.1
  • 122
    • 33845903930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The discussion in this subsection draws on a number of sources including Asher, Business and Workers' Welfare in the Progressive Era;
    • The discussion in this subsection draws on a number of sources including Asher, "Business and Workers' Welfare in the Progressive Era";
  • 135
    • 33845866419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State, for concise discussions of these principles. Ibid.
    • Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State, for concise discussions of these principles. Ibid.
  • 136
    • 33845878320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Katz, in Shadow of the Poorhouse, draws a more pessimistic conclusion on the achievements of workers' compensation legislation, he does not present evidence to contradict Fishback and Kantor's conclusions on expected accident payments
    • Although Katz, in Shadow of the Poorhouse, draws a more pessimistic conclusion on the achievements of workers' compensation legislation, he does not present evidence to contradict Fishback and Kantor's conclusions on expected accident payments.
  • 142
    • 33845879419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • notes that several large companies including U.S. Steel and International Harvester actually started voluntary workmen's compensation programs whereby workers could have a certain amounted deducted from their salary in exchange for benefits that would apply in the case of an accident
    • Weinstein, "Big Business and the Origins of Workmen's Compensation," notes that several large companies including U.S. Steel and International Harvester actually started voluntary workmen's compensation programs whereby workers could have a certain amounted deducted from their salary in exchange for benefits that would apply in the case of an accident.
    • Big Business and the Origins of Workmen's Compensation
    • Weinstein1
  • 146
    • 33845874178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Varieties of Capitalist Interests. It should be noted that these observations about business support for workers' compensation insurance parallel those Mares made regarding France and Germany in Politics of Social
    • and Swenson, "Varieties of Capitalist Interests." It should be noted that these observations about business support for workers' compensation insurance parallel those Mares made regarding France and Germany in Politics of Social Risk.
    • Risk
    • Swenson1
  • 153
    • 33845903931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The electronic file for Fishback and Kantor's data used in our analysis differs slightly on the year of adoption variable from Table 4.3 in Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State, for Arizona, Maryland, and Nevada.
    • The electronic file for Fishback and Kantor's data used in our analysis differs slightly on the year of adoption variable from Table 4.3 in Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State, for Arizona, Maryland, and Nevada.
  • 154
    • 33845907457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We resolved the discrepancy in favor of the date in the electronic file based on other sources (e.g., Pavalko, State Timing of Policy Adoption).
    • We resolved the discrepancy in favor of the date in the electronic file based on other sources (e.g., Pavalko, "State Timing of Policy Adoption").
  • 156
    • 33845904207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State. Ibid.
    • Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State. Ibid.
  • 157
    • 33845869942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Except for the religious variables, all of the data employed in this section are from this source. For details on original sources and data construction, see, esp. appendices
    • Except for the religious variables, all of the data employed in this section are from this source. For details on original sources and data construction, see Fishback and Kantor, Prelude to the Welfare State, esp. appendices.
    • Prelude to the Welfare State
    • Fishback1    Kantor2
  • 158
    • 33845871799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Data on state religious characteristics is from the United States Census of Religious Bodies, 1906, 1916, 1926, 1936 and the Statistics of Churches in the United States, 1890. The data were accessed from electronic files available at the American Religion Data Archive (http://www.thearda.com; acquired Sept. 2005).
    • Data on state religious characteristics is from the United States Census of Religious Bodies, 1906, 1916, 1926, 1936 and the Statistics of Churches in the United States, 1890. The data were accessed from electronic files available at the American Religion Data Archive (http://www.thearda.com; acquired Sept. 2005).
  • 161
    • 33845910193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For our purposes, the southern states are: Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maryland, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas, and Virginia
    • For our purposes, the southern states are: Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maryland, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas, and Virginia.
  • 166
    • 33845913589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Our application of the Cox model allowed for time-varying covariates and used Efron's method for handling tied events in the calculation of the log partial likelihood
    • Our application of the Cox model allowed for time-varying covariates and used Efron's method for handling tied events in the calculation of the log partial likelihood.
  • 167
    • 0036006532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These models are often referred to in the literature as competing risks models. We use the term multivariate hazard model for clarity as the occurrences of each of the six specific event types coded in Reform Adoption are not mutually exclusive. For example, once a state adopts a workers' compensation law including agricultural workers but excluding domestic workers, this does not preclude it from subsequently modifying the law to include domestic workers. For a discussion of estimation of competing risks models, see Sanford Gordon, Stochastic Dependence in Competing Risks, American Journal of Political Science 46 2002, 200-17
    • These models are often referred to in the literature as "competing risks" models. We use the term "multivariate hazard model" for clarity as the occurrences of each of the six specific event types coded in Reform Adoption are not mutually exclusive. For example, once a state adopts a workers' compensation law including agricultural workers but excluding domestic workers, this does not preclude it from subsequently modifying the law to include domestic workers. For a discussion of estimation of competing risks models, see Sanford Gordon, "Stochastic Dependence in Competing Risks," American Journal of Political Science 46 (2002): 200-17.
  • 168
    • 33745595609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond Logit and Probit: Cox Duration Models for State Policy Adoption
    • To implement the model, we stratified on reform type, used Efron's method for handling tied events in the calculation of the log partial likelihood, and adjusted the standard errors for clustering by state
    • Bradford Jones and Regina Branton, "Beyond Logit and Probit: Cox Duration Models for State Policy Adoption," State Politics and Policy Quarterly (2005): 420-43. To implement the model, we stratified on reform type, used Efron's method for handling tied events in the calculation of the log partial likelihood, and adjusted the standard errors for clustering by state.
    • (2005) State Politics and Policy Quarterly , pp. 420-443
    • Jones, B.1    Branton, R.2
  • 169
    • 33845901588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note again that a positive coefficient estimate for the Catholic Membership variable is consistent with arguments about the effects of religious doctrine on economic beliefs but it is also consistent with other hypotheses such as that states with high concentrations of Catholics faced higher economic risks not measured by the control variables.
    • Note again that a positive coefficient estimate for the Catholic Membership variable is consistent with arguments about the effects of religious doctrine on economic beliefs but it is also consistent with other hypotheses such as that states with high concentrations of Catholics faced higher economic risks not measured by the control variables.
  • 170
    • 33845890626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to the estimates reported in Table 2, we evaluated the sensitivity of our results to model specification. We reestimated the model dropping various sets of control variables (e.g, all the partisan control variables) and found that the results for the correlation between religiosity and the adoption of workers' compensation reforms were qualitatively similar
    • In addition to the estimates reported in Table 2, we evaluated the sensitivity of our results to model specification. We reestimated the model dropping various sets of control variables (e.g., all the partisan control variables) and found that the results for the correlation between religiosity and the adoption of workers' compensation reforms were qualitatively similar.
  • 172
    • 33845914802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should also be noted that these are the probabilities of each type of accident occurring, not the probability of each type of accident occurring given that some type of accident has occurred
    • It should also be noted that these are the probabilities of each type of accident occurring, not the probability of each type of accident occurring given that some type of accident has occurred.
  • 173
    • 33845868035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to the estimates reported in Table 3, we evaluated the sensitivity of our results to model specification. We reestimated the model dropping various sets of control variables e.g, all the partisan control variables, For the specifications that include the Catholic membership variable, the results for the correlation between religiosity and benefit levels were qualitatively similar across all specifications. For those omitting the Catholic membership variable, the coefficient on religiosity was not statistically significant in a few sparse specifications which omitted most of the control variables, but otherwise these alternative specifications generated qualitatively similar results
    • In addition to the estimates reported in Table 3, we evaluated the sensitivity of our results to model specification. We reestimated the model dropping various sets of control variables (e.g., all the partisan control variables). For the specifications that include the Catholic membership variable, the results for the correlation between religiosity and benefit levels were qualitatively similar across all specifications. For those omitting the Catholic membership variable, the coefficient on religiosity was not statistically significant in a few sparse specifications which omitted most of the control variables, but otherwise these alternative specifications generated qualitatively similar results.
  • 174
    • 33845875520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gallup Poll Number 1939-0149 with field dates 24 Feb. through 1 Mar. and a sample size of 3,134; Gallup Poll Number 1939-0143 with field dates 9-14 Jan. and a sample size of 3,063.
    • Gallup Poll Number 1939-0149 with field dates 24 Feb. through 1 Mar. and a sample size of 3,134; Gallup Poll Number 1939-0143 with field dates 9-14 Jan. and a sample size of 3,063.
  • 176
    • 33845906433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Based on the figures Howard reports in WPA and Federal Relief Policy, the WPA employed 2.93 million workers in January 1939, in addition to the 0.44 million workers employed on other federal work projects (ibid., 854-57). In January 1941, the WPA continued to employ 1.8 million individuals while the number of workers employed on other federal work projects increased to 0.78 million. The figures provided for other federal work projects here are exclusive of employment for the Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC) and the National Youth Administration (NYA).
    • Based on the figures Howard reports in WPA and Federal Relief Policy, the WPA employed 2.93 million workers in January 1939, in addition to the 0.44 million workers employed on "other federal work projects" (ibid., 854-57). In January 1941, the WPA continued to employ 1.8 million individuals while the number of workers employed on other federal work projects increased to 0.78 million. The figures provided for "other federal work projects" here are exclusive of employment for the Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC) and the National Youth Administration (NYA).
  • 180
    • 33845907456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Conflict over WPA wages is analyzed in detail in Amenta and Halfmann, Wage Wars: Institutional Politics, WPA Wages, and the Struggle for U.S. Social Policy;
    • Conflict over WPA wages is analyzed in detail in Amenta and Halfmann, "Wage Wars: Institutional Politics, WPA Wages, and the Struggle for U.S. Social Policy";
  • 184
    • 33845908292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The exact wording of the Sunday attendance question was Did you happen to go to church last Sunday? The exact wording of the relative attendance question varied across the two forms of the survey instrument for Gallup Poll Number 1939-0149. For Form A, the phrasing was Did your parents go to church more often or less often than you do? For Form B, the phrasing was Do you go to church more often or less often than your parents did?
    • The exact wording of the Sunday attendance question was "Did you happen to go to church last Sunday?" The exact wording of the relative attendance question varied across the two forms of the survey instrument for Gallup Poll Number 1939-0149. For Form A, the phrasing was "Did your parents go to church more often or less often than you do?" For Form B, the phrasing was "Do you go to church more often or less often than your parents did?"
  • 185
    • 33845892205 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The categories used were 1 for poor; 2 for poor plus; 3 for average; 4 for average plus; and 5 for wealthy
    • The categories used were 1 for "poor"; 2 for "poor plus"; 3 for "average"; 4 for "average plus"; and 5 for "wealthy."
  • 186
    • 0035285349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data: An Alternative Algorithm for Multiple Imputation
    • Gary King, James Honaker, Anne Joseph, and Kenneth Scheve, "Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data: An Alternative Algorithm for Multiple Imputation," American Political Science Review 95 (2001): 49-69;
    • (2001) American Political Science Review , vol.95 , pp. 49-69
    • King, G.1    Honaker, J.2    Joseph, A.3    Scheve, K.4
  • 191
    • 33845891940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is also necessary to assume the parameters describing the missing data process are distinct from parameters of the data model so that the missing data mechanism is ignorable. Again, because the missingness in this analysis is primarily due to questions not asked, there is no reason to think this assumption is violated. See Gelman, King, and Liu, Not Asked or Not Answered, for further discussion of the application of multiple imputation to the problem of missing questions in independent cross-sectional surveys
    • It is also necessary to assume the parameters describing the missing data process are distinct from parameters of the data model so that the missing data mechanism is ignorable. Again, because the "missingness" in this analysis is primarily due to questions not asked, there is no reason to think this assumption is violated. See Gelman, King, and Liu, "Not Asked or Not Answered," for further discussion of the application of multiple imputation to the problem of missing questions in independent cross-sectional surveys.
  • 192
    • 33845882573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The imputation procedures were implemented using the Amelia software package
    • The imputation procedures were implemented using the Amelia software package.
  • 193
    • 33845880958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • King, Honaker, Joseph, and Scheve, Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data. In this analysis, the imputation model was multivariate normal with a slight ridge prior.
    • King, Honaker, Joseph, and Scheve, "Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data". In this analysis, the imputation model was multivariate normal with a slight ridge prior.
  • 194
    • 33845882057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See King, Honaker, Joseph, and Scheve, Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data. In this analysis, the imputation model was multivariate normal with a slight ridge prior. ibid.,
    • See King, Honaker, Joseph, and Scheve, "Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data". In this analysis, the imputation model was multivariate normal with a slight ridge prior. ibid.,
  • 195
    • 0003398574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Data for a complete description of these variances. Another potential problem with the Gallup surveys is that they were conducted using quota control sampling rather than probability sampling methods
    • and Schafer, Analysis of Incomplete Multivariate Data) for a complete description of these variances. Another potential problem with the Gallup surveys is that they were conducted using quota control sampling rather than probability sampling methods.
    • Analysis of Incomplete Multivariate
    • Schafer1
  • 196
    • 33845908542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adam Berinsky, American Public Opinion in the 1930s and 1940s: The Analysis of Quota-Controlled Sample Survey Data, (mimeo, 2005; version available online at http://web.mit.edu/berinsky/www/QCS.pdf; last viewed 2 Oct. 2006), discusses the methodology of these early surveys and the problems that these methods may generate for various types of analyses. For individual-level regression analyses like those conducted in this section, the recommended method for dealing with potential biases from non-representative quota samples is to control for those demographic variables that may influence sample selection.
    • Adam Berinsky, "American Public Opinion in the 1930s and 1940s: The Analysis of Quota-Controlled Sample Survey Data," (mimeo, 2005; version available online at http://web.mit.edu/berinsky/www/QCS.pdf; last viewed 2 Oct. 2006), discusses the methodology of these early surveys and the problems that these methods may generate for various types of analyses. For individual-level regression analyses like those conducted in this section, the recommended method for dealing with potential biases from non-representative quota samples is to control for those demographic variables that may influence sample selection.
  • 197
    • 33845881251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Andrew Gelman, Struggles with Survey Weighting and Regression Modeling, (mimeo, 2005; available online at http://polmeth.wustl.edu/retrieve.php?id=565; last viewed 2 Oct. 2006). For example, quota samples are known to have undersampled women and therefore sex should be controlled for in the regression analyses. As discussed above, our baseline analysis includes a fairly full set of demographic controls including sex, age, race, and wealth. Moreover, in the robustness checks below, we include a comprehensive set of control variables including indicators for region, occupation, and living in an urban area.
    • See also Andrew Gelman, "Struggles with Survey Weighting and Regression Modeling," (mimeo, 2005; available online at http://polmeth.wustl.edu/retrieve.php?id=565; last viewed 2 Oct. 2006). For example, quota samples are known to have undersampled women and therefore sex should be controlled for in the regression analyses. As discussed above, our baseline analysis includes a fairly full set of demographic controls including sex, age, race, and wealth. Moreover, in the robustness checks below, we include a comprehensive set of control variables including indicators for region, occupation, and living in an urban area.
  • 200
    • 33845890360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note again that differences between Catholics and Protestants may be a function of differences in economic risk not accounted for in our control variables. While we think the mixed results for the economic beliefs effect are interesting, the main point here is that there is evidence of a negative correlation between the religiosity measure and unemployment spending preferences, controlling for denominational membership. We note also that other studies including our own analysis of contemporary social insurance policy opinions in the United States have found systematic differences between Catholics and Protestants see Kenneth Scheve and David Stasavage, Religion and Social Insurance: Evidence from the United States, 1970-2002, mimeo, 2005; Not available online
    • Note again that differences between Catholics and Protestants may be a function of differences in economic risk not accounted for in our control variables. While we think the mixed results for the economic beliefs effect are interesting, the main point here is that there is evidence of a negative correlation between the religiosity measure and unemployment spending preferences, controlling for denominational membership. We note also that other studies including our own analysis of contemporary social insurance policy opinions in the United States have found systematic differences between Catholics and Protestants (see Kenneth Scheve and David Stasavage, "Religion and Social Insurance: Evidence from the United States, 1970-2002," [mimeo, 2005; Not available online]).
  • 201
    • 33845888052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The obvious problem with this analysis is that to the extent that support for Roosevelt is determined by attitudes toward redistribution and social insurance, it does not make sense to enter this variable in the regression. For this reason, our baseline specification excludes the support for Roosevelt measure
    • The obvious problem with this analysis is that to the extent that support for Roosevelt is determined by attitudes toward redistribution and social insurance, it does not make sense to enter this variable in the regression. For this reason, our baseline specification excludes the support for Roosevelt measure.
  • 203
    • 33845888051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We also considered the possibility that the marginal effect of religiosity varied across different levels of income or wealth. We added interaction terms between religiosity and our measures of wealth to the baseline specification. The coefficient estimates for the interaction terms are positive but not statistically significant. It is important to note that although the argument and its formalization presented in the appendix assumes that utility from monetary consumption and psychic benefits are not additively separable and thus implies that the psychological benefits of religion are greater for those with lower incomes, the model does not generate any direct predictions about the relationship between religiosity, income, and spending preferences see equation 7, Even if we assume that economic insecurity is correlated with income, the model does not make unambiguous predictions about the magnitude of the effect of religiosity for different levels of economic insecurity
    • We also considered the possibility that the marginal effect of religiosity varied across different levels of income or wealth. We added interaction terms between religiosity and our measures of wealth to the baseline specification. The coefficient estimates for the interaction terms are positive but not statistically significant. It is important to note that although the argument and its formalization presented in the appendix assumes that utility from monetary consumption and "psychic benefits" are not additively separable and thus implies that the psychological benefits of religion are greater for those with lower incomes, the model does not generate any direct predictions about the relationship between religiosity, income, and spending preferences (see equation 7). Even if we assume that economic insecurity is correlated with income, the model does not make unambiguous predictions about the magnitude of the effect of religiosity for different levels of economic insecurity. Thus, the lack of a significant interaction term between religiosity and the wealth measures is not inconsistent with the model.
  • 205
    • 33845911289 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The analysis here provides substantial evidence of a robust correlation between religiosity and unemployment spending preferences, controlling for measured characteristics of respondents. It remains possible that there are unobserved characteristics omitted from the model that could generate biased estimates. Although not available for the 1930s data analyzed here, in Religion and Social Insurance: Evidence from the United States, 1970-2002, we use parental religiosity in an analysis of contemporary U.S. social insurance policy opinions to address this issue and document further evidence that increasing religiosity decreases support for general social insurance programs.
    • The analysis here provides substantial evidence of a robust correlation between religiosity and unemployment spending preferences, controlling for measured characteristics of respondents. It remains possible that there are unobserved characteristics omitted from the model that could generate biased estimates. Although not available for the 1930s data analyzed here, in "Religion and Social Insurance: Evidence from the United States, 1970-2002," we use parental religiosity in an analysis of contemporary U.S. social insurance policy opinions to address this issue and document further evidence that increasing religiosity decreases support for general social insurance programs.
  • 212
    • 33845905315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One way of stating this assumption in words is that someone who currently has a job is more likely to be employed in the next period than is someone who is currently unemployed
    • One way of stating this assumption in words is that someone who currently has a job is more likely to be employed in the next period than is someone who is currently unemployed.
  • 213
    • 0036266890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The advantages and disadvantages of including a psychic benefit directly in a utility function of this sort is discussed by Jean Tirole, Rational Irrationality: Some Economics of Self-Management, European Economic Review 46 2002, 633-55
    • The advantages and disadvantages of including a psychic benefit directly in a utility function of this sort is discussed by Jean Tirole, "Rational Irrationality: Some Economics of Self-Management," European Economic Review 46 (2002): 633-55.
  • 214
    • 33646089849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a related application, see, mimeo, version available online at, last viewed 2 Oct
    • For a related application, see Roland Benabou and Jean Tirole, "Incentives and Prosocial Behavior," (mimeo, 2004; version available online at http://ideas.repec.org/p/iza/izadps/dp1695.html; last viewed 2 Oct. 2006).
    • (2004) Incentives and Prosocial Behavior
    • Benabou, R.1    Tirole, J.2
  • 215
    • 33646341907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • we explored the possibility that individuals choose their level of religiosity under the constraint that greater time spent on religion leaves less time for other leisure activities, and we obtained similar theoretical predictions to those reported here
    • In Scheve and Stasavage, "Religion and Preferences for Social Insurance," we explored the possibility that individuals choose their level of religiosity under the constraint that greater time spent on religion leaves less time for other leisure activities, and we obtained similar theoretical predictions to those reported here.
    • Religion and Preferences for Social Insurance
    • Scheve, I.1    Stasavage2
  • 216
    • 33845905316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • One would also continue to observe a preferred level of social insurance that is decreasing in the level of religiosity even if individuals were partially altruistic, if one followed the proposal in Anthony Atkinson, Income Maintenance for the Unemployed in Britain and the Response to High Unemployment, Ethics 1990, 569-85, for modeling altruism
    • One would also continue to observe a preferred level of social insurance that is decreasing in the level of religiosity even if individuals were partially altruistic, if one followed the proposal in Anthony Atkinson, "Income Maintenance for the Unemployed in Britain and the Response to High Unemployment," Ethics (1990): 569-85, for modeling altruism.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.