메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 18, Issue 1, 2004, Pages 1-29

Varieties of capitalist interests: Power, institutions, and the regulatory welfare state in the United States and Sweden

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 4043048784     PISSN: 0898588X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/s0898588x0400001x     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (78)

References (254)
  • 1
    • 0007679720 scopus 로고
    • The political origins of America's belated welfare state
    • ed. Margaret Weir, Ann Shola Orloff, and Theda Skocpol (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press)
    • For a discussion of America's "laggard" status, see Ann Shola Orloff, "The Political Origins of America's Belated Welfare State," in The Politics of Social Policy in the United States, ed. Margaret Weir, Ann Shola Orloff, and Theda Skocpol (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988), 38-80.
    • (1988) The Politics of Social Policy in the United States , pp. 38-80
    • Orloff, A.S.1
  • 2
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); on unemployment insurance, see 6
    • Detailed evidence for these and other assertions is presented in Peter Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); on unemployment insurance, see 6, 201-7, and 254-56. On business money for the Democrats, see Louise Overacker, "Campaign Funds in the Presidential Election of 1936," American Political Science Review 31(1937): 485-87; Thomas P. Ferguson, "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 (1984); Michael J. Webber, "Business, The Democratic Party, and the New Deal: An Empirical Critique of Thomas Ferguson's 'Investment Theory of Politics'," Sociological Perspectives 34 (1991): 486-87.
    • Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden , pp. 201-207
    • Swenson, P.1
  • 3
    • 0000819877 scopus 로고
    • Campaign funds in the presidential election of 1936
    • Detailed evidence for these and other assertions is presented in Peter Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare Slates in the United States and Sweden (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); on unemployment insurance, see 6, 201-7, and 254-56. On business money for the Democrats, see Louise Overacker, "Campaign Funds in the Presidential Election of 1936," American Political Science Review 31(1937): 485-87; Thomas P. Ferguson, "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 (1984); Michael J. Webber, "Business, The Democratic Party, and the New Deal: An Empirical Critique of Thomas Ferguson's 'Investment Theory of Politics'," Sociological Perspectives 34 (1991): 486-87.
    • (1937) American Political Science Review , vol.31 , pp. 485-487
    • Overacker, L.1
  • 4
    • 84973939734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From normalcy to new deal: Industrial structure, party competition, and American public policy in the great depression
    • Detailed evidence for these and other assertions is presented in Peter Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare Slates in the United States and Sweden (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); on unemployment insurance, see 6, 201-7, and 254-56. On business money for the Democrats, see Louise Overacker, "Campaign Funds in the Presidential Election of 1936," American Political Science Review 31(1937): 485-87; Thomas P. Ferguson, "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 (1984); Michael J. Webber, "Business, The Democratic Party, and the New Deal: An Empirical Critique of Thomas Ferguson's 'Investment Theory of Politics'," Sociological Perspectives 34 (1991): 486-87.
    • (1984) International Organization , vol.38
    • Ferguson, T.P.1
  • 5
    • 84970149825 scopus 로고
    • Business, the democratic party, and the new deal: An empirical critique of Thomas Ferguson's 'investment theory of politics'
    • Detailed evidence for these and other assertions is presented in Peter Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare Slates in the United States and Sweden (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); on unemployment insurance, see 6, 201-7, and 254-56. On business money for the Democrats, see Louise Overacker, "Campaign Funds in the Presidential Election of 1936," American Political Science Review 31(1937): 485-87; Thomas P. Ferguson, "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 (1984); Michael J. Webber, "Business, The Democratic Party, and the New Deal: An Empirical Critique of Thomas Ferguson's 'Investment Theory of Politics'," Sociological Perspectives 34 (1991): 486-87.
    • (1991) Sociological Perspectives , vol.34 , pp. 486-487
    • Webber, M.J.1
  • 6
    • 0004122279 scopus 로고
    • New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
    • Marquis Childs, Sweden: The Middle Way (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1936,1951) , and This is Democracy: Collective Bargaining in Scandinavia (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1938). In his recent study, Edwin Amenta finds that, in 1938, "The American performance outpaced the efforts of Sweden, today's world leader in social spending" (Bold Relief: Institutional Politics and the Origins of Modern American Social Policy [Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1998], 5). Had Amenta counted "general" not just central government spending, he would have found that Sweden actually surpassed the United States modestly in terms of social spending as a percent of GDP (about 8.5 percent for Sweden, 6.3 percent for the United States) and almost matched it in total government spending as a percent of GDP (27.6 percent in Sweden, 29.4 percent in the United States). The source for these calculations is Peter Flora et al., State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815-1975 (Chicago: St. James, 1983).
    • (1936) Sweden: The Middle Way
    • Childs, M.1
  • 7
    • 4043159332 scopus 로고
    • New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
    • Marquis Childs, Sweden: The Middle Way (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1936,1951) , and This is Democracy: Collective Bargaining in Scandinavia (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1938). In his recent study, Edwin Amenta finds that, in 1938, "The American performance outpaced the efforts of Sweden, today's world leader in social spending" (Bold Relief: Institutional Politics and the Origins of Modern American Social Policy [Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1998], 5). Had Amenta counted "general" not just central government spending, he would have found that Sweden actually surpassed the United States modestly in terms of social spending as a percent of GDP (about 8.5 percent for Sweden, 6.3 percent for the United States) and almost matched it in total government spending as a percent of GDP (27.6 percent in Sweden, 29.4 percent in the United States). The source for these calculations is Peter Flora et al., State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815-1975 (Chicago: St. James, 1983).
    • (1938) This is Democracy: Collective Bargaining in Scandinavia
  • 8
    • 4043094297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The American performance outpaced the efforts of Sweden, today's world leader in social spending
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Marquis Childs, Sweden: The Middle Way (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1936,1951) , and This is Democracy: Collective Bargaining in Scandinavia (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1938). In his recent study, Edwin Amenta finds that, in 1938, "The American performance outpaced the efforts of Sweden, today's world leader in social spending" (Bold Relief: Institutional Politics and the Origins of Modern American Social Policy [Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1998], 5). Had Amenta counted "general" not just central government spending, he would have found that Sweden actually surpassed the United States modestly in terms of social spending as a percent of GDP (about 8.5 percent for Sweden, 6.3 percent for the United States) and almost matched it in total government spending as a percent of GDP (27.6 percent in Sweden, 29.4 percent in the United States). The source for these calculations is Peter Flora et al., State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815-1975 (Chicago: St. James, 1983).
    • (1998) Bold Relief: Institutional Politics and the Origins of Modern American Social Policy , pp. 5
  • 9
    • 0003546848 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: St. James
    • Marquis Childs, Sweden: The Middle Way (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1936,1951) , and This is Democracy: Collective Bargaining in Scandinavia (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1938). In his recent study, Edwin Amenta finds that, in 1938, "The American performance outpaced the efforts of Sweden, today's world leader in social spending" (Bold Relief: Institutional Politics and the Origins of Modern American Social Policy [Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1998], 5). Had Amenta counted "general" not just central government spending, he would have found that Sweden actually surpassed the United States modestly in terms of social spending as a percent of GDP (about 8.5 percent for Sweden, 6.3 percent for the United States) and almost matched it in total government spending as a percent of GDP (27.6 percent in Sweden, 29.4 percent in the United States). The source for these calculations is Peter Flora et al., State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815-1975 (Chicago: St. James, 1983).
    • (1983) State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815-1975
    • Flora, P.1
  • 10
    • 4043057412 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: Government Printing Office
    • U.S. Department of Labor, Report of the President's Commission on Industrial Relations in Sweden (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1938); "President's Study of Swedish Labor Finds Peace is Key," New York Times, 25 Sept. 1938, 1.
    • (1938) Report of the President's Commission on Industrial Relations in Sweden
  • 11
    • 4043129746 scopus 로고
    • President's study of swedish labor finds peace is key
    • 25 Sept
    • U.S. Department of Labor, Report of the President's Commission on Industrial Relations in Sweden (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1938); "President's Study of Swedish Labor Finds Peace is Key," New York Times, 25 Sept. 1938, 1.
    • (1938) New York Times , pp. 1
  • 12
    • 0003463955 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Gøsta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), 21-22. Of course, employers gain from the disciplinary effect of workers' dependence on market income; however, the question remains whether that truth tidily sums up all of employers' complex managerial and market interests regarding social policy. A recent and growing literature indicates not. See, for example, Margarita Estevez-Abe, Torben Iversen, and David Soskice, "Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State," in Hall and Soskice eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 145-18; Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003); and Duane Swank and Cathie Jo Martin, "Employers and the Welfare State: The Political Economic Organization of Employers and Social Policy in Contemporary Capitalist Democracies," Comparative Political Studies 34 (2001).
    • (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism , pp. 21-22
    • Esping-Andersen, G.1
  • 13
    • 0012788468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Social protection and the formation of skills: A reinterpretation of the welfare State
    • Hall and Soskice eds., (Oxford: Oxford University Press)
    • Gøsta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), 21-22. Of course, employers gain from the disciplinary effect of workers' dependence on market income; however, the question remains whether that truth tidily sums up all of employers' complex managerial and market interests regarding social policy. A recent and growing literature indicates not. See, for example, Margarita Estevez-Abe, Torben Iversen, and David Soskice, "Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State," in Hall and Soskice eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 145-18; Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003); and Duane Swank and Cathie Jo Martin, "Employers and the Welfare State: The Political Economic Organization of Employers and Social Policy in Contemporary Capitalist Democracies," Comparative Political Studies 34 (2001).
    • (2001) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage , pp. 145-218
    • Estevez-Abe, M.1    Iversen, T.2    Soskice, D.3
  • 14
    • 4043121233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • Gøsta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), 21-22. Of course, employers gain from the disciplinary effect of workers' dependence on market income; however, the question remains whether that truth tidily sums up all of employers' complex managerial and market interests regarding social policy. A recent and growing literature indicates not. See, for example, Margarita Estevez-Abe, Torben Iversen, and David Soskice, "Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State," in Hall and Soskice eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 145-18; Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003); and Duane Swank and Cathie Jo Martin, "Employers and the Welfare State: The Political Economic Organization of Employers and Social Policy in Contemporary Capitalist Democracies," Comparative Political Studies 34 (2001).
    • (2003) The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development
    • Mares, I.1
  • 15
    • 0035603320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Employers and the welfare state: The political economic organization of employers and social policy in contemporary capitalist democracies
    • Gøsta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), 21-22. Of course, employers gain from the disciplinary effect of workers' dependence on market income; however, the question remains whether that truth tidily sums up all of employers' complex managerial and market interests regarding social policy. A recent and growing literature indicates not. See, for example, Margarita Estevez-Abe, Torben Iversen, and David Soskice, "Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State," in Hall and Soskice eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 145-18; Isabela Mares, The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003); and Duane Swank and Cathie Jo Martin, "Employers and the Welfare State: The Political Economic Organization of Employers and Social Policy in Contemporary Capitalist Democracies," Comparative Political Studies 34 (2001).
    • (2001) Comparative Political Studies , vol.34
    • Swank, D.1    Martin, C.J.2
  • 16
    • 0004348038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds, 105-38. See also Esping-Andersen and Roger Friedland, "Class Coalitions in the Making of West European Economies," in Political Power and Social Theory 3 (1982): 17, 47, where they argue that the power of the left "is the key to the evolution of Sweden's postwar political economy." "More than in any other European nation," they argue, the "working class has been capable of initiating and imposing its policy preferences." Recentwork continues in this vein, neglecting to theorize and research about interests in order to draw confident conclusions about the relative power of classes. See especially Evelyn Huber and John D. Stephens, Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001).
    • Three Worlds , pp. 105-138
    • Esping-Andersen1
  • 17
    • 84925974935 scopus 로고
    • Class coalitions in the making of west European economies
    • Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds, 105-38. See also Esping-Andersen and Roger Friedland, "Class Coalitions in the Making of West European Economies," in Political Power and Social Theory 3 (1982): 17, 47, where they argue that the power of the left "is the key to the evolution of Sweden's postwar political economy." "More than in any other European nation," they argue, the "working class has been capable of initiating and imposing its policy preferences." Recentwork continues in this vein, neglecting to theorize and research about interests in order to draw confident conclusions about the relative power of classes. See especially Evelyn Huber and John D. Stephens, Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001).
    • (1982) Political Power and Social Theory , vol.3 , pp. 17
    • Esping-Andersen1    Friedland, R.2
  • 18
    • 0003699173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • Esping-Andersen, Three Worlds, 105-38. See also Esping-Andersen and Roger Friedland, "Class Coalitions in the Making of West European Economies," in Political Power and Social Theory 3 (1982): 17, 47, where they argue that the power of the left "is the key to the evolution of Sweden's postwar political economy." "More than in any other European nation," they argue, the "working class has been capable of initiating and imposing its policy preferences." Recentwork continues in this vein, neglecting to theorize and research about interests in order to draw confident conclusions about the relative power of classes. See especially Evelyn Huber and John D. Stephens, Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001).
    • (2001) Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets
    • Huber, E.1    Stephens, J.D.2
  • 20
    • 0002644835 scopus 로고
    • The ruling class does not rule: Notes on the Marxist theory of the state
    • See especially Korpi's The Working Class and Welfare Capitalism: Work, Unions and Politics in Sweden (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978); Fred Block, "The Ruling Class Does Not Rule: Notes on the Marxist Theory of the State," Socialist Revolution 33 (1977).
    • (1977) Socialist Revolution , vol.33
    • Block, F.1
  • 21
    • 0038792725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business power and social policy: Employers and the formation of the American welfare state
    • Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, "Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State," Politics and. Society 30 (2002): 277-325. The synthesis is interesting because most historical institutionalist work, starting with Theda Skocpol, seems to have an underlying intellectual agenda against attributing decisive power over legislative events to capitalists. See for a relevant example Theda Skocpol and John Ikenberry, "The Political Formation of the American Welfare State in Historical and Comparative Perspective," Comparative Social Research 6 (1983): 87-148. Recent historical institutionalist work of Kathleen Thelen, by contrast, has begun seriously bringing capitalist interests into the story of labor market governance through social legislation. How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States and Japan (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004).
    • (2002) Politics and Society , vol.30 , pp. 277-325
    • Hacker, J.S.1    Pierson, P.2
  • 22
    • 0038792725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political formation of the American welfare state in historical and comparative perspective
    • Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, "Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State," Politics and. Society 30 (2002): 277-325. The synthesis is interesting because most historical institutionalist work, starting with Theda Skocpol, seems to have an underlying intellectual agenda against attributing decisive power over legislative events to capitalists. See for a relevant example Theda Skocpol and John Ikenberry, "The Political Formation of the American Welfare State in Historical and Comparative Perspective," Comparative Social Research 6 (1983): 87-148. Recent historical institutionalist work of Kathleen Thelen, by contrast, has begun seriously bringing capitalist interests into the story of labor market governance through social legislation. How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States and Japan (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004).
    • (1983) Comparative Social Research , vol.6 , pp. 87-148
    • Skocpol, T.1    Ikenberry, J.2
  • 23
    • 84917029805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, "Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State," Politics and. Society 30 (2002): 277-325. The synthesis is interesting because most historical institutionalist work, starting with Theda Skocpol, seems to have an underlying intellectual agenda against attributing decisive power over legislative events to capitalists. See for a relevant example Theda Skocpol and John Ikenberry, "The Political Formation of the American Welfare State in Historical and Comparative Perspective," Comparative Social Research 6 (1983): 87-148. Recent historical institutionalist work of Kathleen Thelen, by contrast, has begun seriously bringing capitalist interests into the story of labor market governance through social legislation. How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States and Japan (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004).
    • (2004) How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States and Japan
    • Thelen, K.1
  • 24
    • 0010851302 scopus 로고
    • Constructive investigation and the industrial commission of wisconsin
    • 4 Jan
    • Commons, "Constructive Investigation and the Industrial Commission of Wisconsin," Survey, 4 Jan. 1913.
    • (1913) Survey
    • Commons1
  • 25
    • 0003714839 scopus 로고
    • Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin, emphasis added
    • Theron F. Schlabach, Edwin E. Witte: Cautious Reformer (Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin, 1969), 194, emphasis added.
    • (1969) Edwin E. Witte: Cautious Reformer , pp. 194
    • Schlabach, T.F.1
  • 26
    • 0000456233 scopus 로고
    • The theory of economic regulation
    • George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: (1971): 3-17; Sam Peltzman, "The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Special Issue (1987): 1-41; James Q. Wilson, "The Politics of Regulation," in James W. McKie, Social Responsibility and the Business Predicament (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1974).
    • (1971) Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , vol.2 , pp. 3-17
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 27
    • 0002329807 scopus 로고
    • The economic theory of regulation after a decade of deregulation
    • Special Issue
    • George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: (1971): 3-17; Sam Peltzman, "The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Special Issue (1987): 1-41; James Q. Wilson, "The Politics of Regulation," in James W. McKie, Social Responsibility and the Business Predicament (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1974).
    • (1987) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , pp. 1-41
    • Peltzman, S.1
  • 28
    • 0003314339 scopus 로고
    • The politics of regulation
    • James W. McKie, (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution)
    • George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: (1971): 3-17; Sam Peltzman, "The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Special Issue (1987): 1-41; James Q. Wilson, "The Politics of Regulation," in James W. McKie, Social Responsibility and the Business Predicament (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1974).
    • (1974) Social Responsibility and the Business Predicament
    • Wilson, J.Q.1
  • 30
    • 84973939734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From normalcy to new deal: Industrial structure, party competition, and American public policy in the great depression
    • Thomas P. Ferguson presents a deeply problematic logrolling argument for capitalist support of the New Deal. See his "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 (1984); and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 240-42.
    • (1984) International Organization , vol.38
    • Ferguson, T.P.1
  • 31
    • 84973939734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thomas P. Ferguson presents a deeply problematic logrolling argument for capitalist support of the New Deal. See his "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 (1984); and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 240-42.
    • Capitalists against Markets , pp. 240-242
    • Swenson1
  • 32
    • 0003874617 scopus 로고
    • New York: Macmillan
    • John R. Commons, Labor and Administration (New York: Macmillan, 1913), 91, 103-5; Edwin E. Witte, "Economic Aspects of Industry-Wide Collective Bargaining," in Industry-Wide Collective Bargaining; Promise or Menace?, ed. Colston E.Warne (Boston: D.C. Heath, 1950). For FDR's view on the clothing industry, see "The Situation in the Women's Garment Trades," Monthly Labor Review 29 (1929): 30.
    • (1913) Labor and Administration , pp. 91
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 33
    • 4043114349 scopus 로고
    • Economic aspects of industry-wide collective bargaining
    • ed. Colston E.Warne (Boston: D.C. Heath)
    • John R. Commons, Labor and Administration (New York: Macmillan, 1913), 91, 103-5; Edwin E. Witte, "Economic Aspects of Industry-Wide Collective Bargaining," in Industry-Wide Collective Bargaining; Promise or Menace?, ed. Colston E.Warne (Boston: D.C. Heath, 1950). For FDR's view on the clothing industry, see "The Situation in the Women's Garment Trades," Monthly Labor Review 29 (1929): 30.
    • (1950) Industry-wide Collective Bargaining; Promise or Menace?
    • Witte, E.E.1
  • 34
    • 4043102786 scopus 로고
    • The situation in the women's garment trades
    • John R. Commons, Labor and Administration (New York: Macmillan, 1913), 91, 103-5; Edwin E. Witte, "Economic Aspects of Industry-Wide Collective Bargaining," in Industry-Wide Collective Bargaining; Promise or Menace?, ed. Colston E.Warne (Boston: D.C. Heath, 1950). For FDR's view on the clothing industry, see "The Situation in the Women's Garment Trades," Monthly Labor Review 29 (1929): 30.
    • (1929) Monthly Labor Review , vol.29 , pp. 30
  • 35
    • 0003416615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jesse T. Carpenter, Competition and Collective Bargaining in the Needle Trades 1910-1967 (Ithaca, NY: New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, 1972); William Haber, Industrial Relations in the Building Industry (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1930); David Previant, "Economic and Political Implications of the National Trucking Agreement of 1964," Proceedings of New York University Seventeenth Annual Conference on Labor (Washington, DC: BNA Incorporated, 1964), 285-86; Garth Mangum and R. Scott McNabb, The Rise, Fall, and Replacement of Industrywide Bargaining in the Basic Steel Industry (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997), 13-46.
    • (1989) Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry
    • Bowman, J.R.1
  • 36
    • 0003399057 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, NY: New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations
    • John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jesse T. Carpenter, Competition and Collective Bargaining in the Needle Trades 1910-1967 (Ithaca, NY: New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, 1972); William Haber, Industrial Relations in the Building Industry (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1930); David Previant, "Economic and Political Implications of the National Trucking Agreement of 1964," Proceedings of New York University Seventeenth Annual Conference on Labor (Washington, DC: BNA Incorporated, 1964), 285-86; Garth Mangum and R. Scott McNabb, The Rise, Fall, and Replacement of Industrywide Bargaining in the Basic Steel Industry (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997), 13-46.
    • (1972) Competition and Collective Bargaining in the Needle Trades 1910-1967
    • Carpenter, J.T.1
  • 37
    • 0010846268 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jesse T. Carpenter, Competition and Collective Bargaining in the Needle Trades 1910-1967 (Ithaca, NY: New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, 1972); William Haber, Industrial Relations in the Building Industry (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1930); David Previant, "Economic and Political Implications of the National Trucking Agreement of 1964," Proceedings of New York University Seventeenth Annual Conference on Labor (Washington, DC: BNA Incorporated, 1964), 285-86; Garth Mangum and R. Scott McNabb, The Rise, Fall, and Replacement of Industrywide Bargaining in the Basic Steel Industry (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997), 13-46.
    • (1930) Industrial Relations in the Building Industry
    • Haber, W.1
  • 38
    • 4043092917 scopus 로고
    • Economic and political implications of the national trucking agreement of 1964
    • Washington, DC: BNA Incorporated
    • John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jesse T. Carpenter, Competition and Collective Bargaining in the Needle Trades 1910-1967 (Ithaca, NY: New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, 1972); William Haber, Industrial Relations in the Building Industry (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1930); David Previant, "Economic and Political Implications of the National Trucking Agreement of 1964," Proceedings of New York University Seventeenth Annual Conference on Labor (Washington, DC: BNA Incorporated, 1964), 285-86; Garth Mangum and R. Scott McNabb, The Rise, Fall, and Replacement of Industrywide Bargaining in the Basic Steel Industry (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997), 13-46.
    • (1964) Proceedings of New York University Seventeenth Annual Conference on Labor , pp. 285-286
    • Previant, D.1
  • 39
    • 0042092688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe
    • John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Jesse T. Carpenter, Competition and Collective Bargaining in the Needle Trades 1910-1967 (Ithaca, NY: New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, 1972); William Haber, Industrial Relations in the Building Industry (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1930); David Previant, "Economic and Political Implications of the National Trucking Agreement of 1964," Proceedings of New York University Seventeenth Annual Conference on Labor (Washington, DC: BNA Incorporated, 1964), 285-86; Garth Mangum and R. Scott McNabb, The Rise, Fall, and Replacement of Industrywide Bargaining in the Basic Steel Industry (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1997), 13-46.
    • (1997) The Rise, Fall, and Replacement of Industrywide Bargaining in the Basic Steel Industry , pp. 13-46
    • Mangum, G.1    McNabb, R.S.2
  • 43
    • 0003168436 scopus 로고
    • A theory of dual labor markets with application to industrial policy, discrimination, and keynesian unemployment
    • The term segmentalism is suggested by efficiency wage models of "labor market segmentation." Jeremy Bulow and Lawrence Summers, "A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment," Journal of Labor Economics 4 (1986): 376-414; Alan Krueger and Lawrence Summers, "Efficiency Wages and the Inter-Industry Wage Structure," Econometrica 56 (1988): 259-93; and Erica Groshen, "Five Reasons Why Wages Vary Among Employers," Industrial Relations 30 (1991), esp. 369-73.
    • (1986) Journal of Labor Economics , vol.4 , pp. 376-414
    • Bulow, J.1    Summers, L.2
  • 44
    • 0000722952 scopus 로고
    • Efficiency wages and the inter-industry wage structure
    • The term segmentalism is suggested by efficiency wage models of "labor market segmentation." Jeremy Bulow and Lawrence Summers, "A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment," Journal of Labor Economics 4 (1986): 376-414; Alan Krueger and Lawrence Summers, "Efficiency Wages and the Inter-Industry Wage Structure," Econometrica 56 (1988): 259-93; and Erica Groshen, "Five Reasons Why Wages Vary Among Employers," Industrial Relations 30 (1991), esp. 369-73.
    • (1988) Econometrica , vol.56 , pp. 259-293
    • Krueger, A.1    Summers, L.2
  • 45
    • 84987317308 scopus 로고
    • Five reasons why wages vary among employers
    • The term segmentalism is suggested by efficiency wage models of "labor market segmentation." Jeremy Bulow and Lawrence Summers, "A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment," Journal of Labor Economics 4 (1986): 376-414; Alan Krueger and Lawrence Summers, "Efficiency Wages and the Inter-Industry Wage Structure," Econometrica 56 (1988): 259-93; and Erica Groshen, "Five Reasons Why Wages Vary Among Employers," Industrial Relations 30 (1991), esp. 369-73.
    • (1991) Industrial Relations , vol.30 , pp. 369-373
    • Groshen, E.1
  • 46
    • 0004029644 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Useful introductions are Andrew Weiss, Efficiency Wages: Models of Unemployment, Layoffs, and Wage Dispersion (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), and George Akerlof and Janet Yellen, "Introduction," in Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market, ed. Akerlof and Yellen (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 1-21.
    • (1990) Efficiency Wages: Models of Unemployment, Layoffs, and Wage Dispersion
    • Weiss, A.1
  • 47
    • 0010049827 scopus 로고
    • Introduction
    • ed. Akerlof and Yellen (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • Useful introductions are Andrew Weiss, Efficiency Wages: Models of Unemployment, Layoffs, and Wage Dispersion (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), and George Akerlof and Janet Yellen, "Introduction," in Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market, ed. Akerlof and Yellen (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 1-21.
    • (1986) Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market , pp. 1-21
    • Akerlof, G.1    Yellen, J.2
  • 48
    • 0001902793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An introduction to varieties of capitalism
    • ed. Hall and Soskice (Oxford: Oxford University Press)
    • Recent literature seems to underplay the importance of workplace relational contracting in "liberal market economies" like the United States, implying that powerful institutions external to the firm are required to bring it about, not the microeconomic rationality of efficiency wage behavior. See, for example, Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, ed. Hall and Soskice (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), esp. 6-33.
    • (2001) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage , pp. 6-33
    • Hall, P.A.1    Soskice, D.2
  • 49
    • 0007986615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining for social rights: Unions and the reemergence of welfare capitalism
    • Michael K. Brown, "Bargaining for Social Rights: Unions and the Reemergence of Welfare Capitalism," Political Science Quarterly 112 (1997-1998).
    • (1997) Political Science Quarterly , vol.112
    • Brown, M.K.1
  • 51
    • 4043087176 scopus 로고
    • Long hours in steel industry reduced: Men generally satisfied with the changes
    • Jan
    • "Long Hours in Steel Industry Reduced: Men Generally Satisfied with the Changes," Iron Age, 3 Jan. 1924, 41.
    • (1924) Iron Age , vol.3 , pp. 41
  • 52
    • 0002341692 scopus 로고
    • Madison: University of Wisconsin Press
    • Robert Ozanne, Wages in Practice and Theory: McCormick and International Harvester 1860-1960 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1968), 52; Ozanne, A Century of Labor-Management Relations at McCormick and International Harvester (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1967), 159; M.C. Rorty, "Is Collective Bargaining Compatible with a Free Price and Wage System?" The Management Review 24 (1935): 36-38.
    • (1968) Wages in Practice and Theory: McCormick and International Harvester 1860-1960 , pp. 52
    • Ozanne, R.1
  • 53
    • 0004011457 scopus 로고
    • Madison: University of Wisconsin Press
    • Robert Ozanne, Wages in Practice and Theory: McCormick and International Harvester 1860-1960 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1968), 52; Ozanne, A Century of Labor-Management Relations at McCormick and International Harvester (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1967), 159; M.C. Rorty, "Is Collective Bargaining Compatible with a Free Price and Wage System?" The Management Review 24 (1935): 36-38.
    • (1967) A Century of Labor-management Relations at McCormick and International Harvester , pp. 159
    • Ozanne1
  • 54
    • 4043136726 scopus 로고
    • Is collective bargaining compatible with a free price and wage system?
    • Robert Ozanne, Wages in Practice and Theory: McCormick and International Harvester 1860-1960 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1968), 52; Ozanne, A Century of Labor-Management Relations at McCormick and International Harvester (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1967), 159; M.C. Rorty, "Is Collective Bargaining Compatible with a Free Price and Wage System?" The Management Review 24 (1935): 36-38.
    • (1935) The Management Review , vol.24 , pp. 36-38
    • Rorty, M.C.1
  • 55
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 24-29 for more on the theory. For more on wage rigidity, see David Brody, "The Rise and Decline of Welfare Capitalism," in Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle (New York: Oxford University Press, 1980), 67; Anthony O'Brien, "A Behavioral Explanation for Nominal Wage Rigidity During the Great Depression," Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1989); Jason Taylor and George Selgin, "By Our Bootstraps: Origins and Effects of the High-Wage Doctrine and the Minimum Wage," Journal of Labor Research 20 (1999): 447-61; Truman Bewley, Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1999).
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 24-29
    • Swenson1
  • 56
    • 0004011118 scopus 로고
    • The rise and decline of welfare capitalism
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 24-29 for more on the theory. For more on wage rigidity, see David Brody, "The Rise and Decline of Welfare Capitalism," in Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle (New York: Oxford University Press, 1980), 67; Anthony O'Brien, "A Behavioral Explanation for Nominal Wage Rigidity During the Great Depression," Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1989); Jason Taylor and George Selgin, "By Our Bootstraps: Origins and Effects of the High-Wage Doctrine and the Minimum Wage," Journal of Labor Research 20 (1999): 447-61; Truman Bewley, Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1999).
    • (1980) Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle , pp. 67
    • Brody, D.1
  • 57
    • 0000248761 scopus 로고
    • A behavioral explanation for nominal wage rigidity during the great depression
    • See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 24-29 for more on the theory. For more on wage rigidity, see David Brody, "The Rise and Decline of Welfare Capitalism," in Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle (New York: Oxford University Press, 1980), 67; Anthony O'Brien, "A Behavioral Explanation for Nominal Wage Rigidity During the Great Depression," Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1989); Jason Taylor and George Selgin, "By Our Bootstraps: Origins and Effects of the High-Wage Doctrine and the Minimum Wage," Journal of Labor Research 20 (1999): 447-61; Truman Bewley, Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1999).
    • (1989) Quarterly Journal of Economics , vol.104
    • O'Brien, A.1
  • 58
    • 0041035204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • By our bootstraps: Origins and effects of the high-wage doctrine and the minimum wage
    • See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 24-29 for more on the theory. For more on wage rigidity, see David Brody, "The Rise and Decline of Welfare Capitalism," in Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle (New York: Oxford University Press, 1980), 67; Anthony O'Brien, "A Behavioral Explanation for Nominal Wage Rigidity During the Great Depression," Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1989); Jason Taylor and George Selgin, "By Our Bootstraps: Origins and Effects of the High-Wage Doctrine and the Minimum Wage," Journal of Labor Research 20 (1999): 447-61; Truman Bewley, Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1999).
    • (1999) Journal of Labor Research , vol.20 , pp. 447-461
    • Taylor, J.1    Selgin, G.2
  • 59
    • 0003456111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 24-29 for more on the theory. For more on wage rigidity, see David Brody, "The Rise and Decline of Welfare Capitalism," in Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle (New York: Oxford University Press, 1980), 67; Anthony O'Brien, "A Behavioral Explanation for Nominal Wage Rigidity During the Great Depression," Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1989); Jason Taylor and George Selgin, "By Our Bootstraps: Origins and Effects of the High-Wage Doctrine and the Minimum Wage," Journal of Labor Research 20 (1999): 447-61; Truman Bewley, Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1999).
    • (1999) Why Wages Don't Fall during a Recession
    • Bewley, T.1
  • 60
    • 4043115740 scopus 로고
    • Rev. Ed. (Cleveland: Corday & Gross)
    • P.W. Litchfield, The Industrial Republic: Reflections of an Industrial Lieutenant, rev. ed. (Cleveland: Corday & Gross, 1946), 98; Michael J. Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divided: Possibilities for Prosperity (New York: Basic, 1984), 57; Ozanne, A Century of Labor-Management Relations, 85-86.
    • (1946) The Industrial Republic: Reflections of an Industrial Lieutenant , pp. 98
    • Litchfield, P.W.1
  • 61
    • 4043139538 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic
    • P.W. Litchfield, The Industrial Republic: Reflections of an Industrial Lieutenant, rev. ed. (Cleveland: Corday & Gross, 1946), 98; Michael J. Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divided: Possibilities for Prosperity (New York: Basic, 1984), 57; Ozanne, A Century of Labor-Management Relations, 85-86.
    • (1984) The Second Industrial Divided: Possibilities for Prosperity , pp. 57
    • Piore, M.J.1    Sabel, C.F.2
  • 62
    • 84954457385 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • P.W. Litchfield, The Industrial Republic: Reflections of an Industrial Lieutenant, rev. ed. (Cleveland: Corday & Gross, 1946), 98; Michael J. Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divided: Possibilities for Prosperity (New York: Basic, 1984), 57; Ozanne, A Century of Labor-Management Relations, 85-86.
    • A Century of Labor-management Relations , pp. 85-86
    • Ozanne1
  • 63
    • 0040214858 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office
    • U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings on S. 1130 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1935), 284.
    • (1935) Economic Security Act: Hearings on S. 1130 , pp. 284
  • 64
    • 4043183531 scopus 로고
    • What business thinks
    • Oct
    • "What Business Thinks," Fortune, Oct. 1939.
    • (1939) Fortune
  • 65
    • 4043058786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Management's stake in the survival of contributory social insurance
    • box 64:614, Sterling Library, Yale University
    • "Management's Stake in the Survival of Contributory Social Insurance," box 64:614, Isidore Falk papers, Sterling Library, Yale University.
    • Isidore Falk Papers
  • 66
    • 0004217976 scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • In other words, they worked within an agenda constrained by capitalist power. See Peter Bachrach and Morton S. Baratz, Power and Poverty: Theory and Practice (New York: Oxford University Press, 1970); Steven Lukes, Power: A Radical View (Hampshire, UK: Macmillan, 1974).
    • (1970) Power and Poverty: Theory and Practice
    • Bachrach, P.1    Baratz, M.S.2
  • 67
    • 0004152506 scopus 로고
    • Hampshire, UK: Macmillan
    • In other words, they worked within an agenda constrained by capitalist power. See Peter Bachrach and Morton S. Baratz, Power and Poverty: Theory and Practice (New York: Oxford University Press, 1970); Steven Lukes, Power: A Radical View (Hampshire, UK: Macmillan, 1974).
    • (1974) Power: A Radical View
    • Lukes, S.1
  • 68
    • 0010851957 scopus 로고
    • New York: The Business Bourse
    • Gerard Swope, The Swope Plan: Details, Criticisms, Analysis (New York: The Business Bourse, 1931). On Folsom, see Jill Quadagno, The Transformation of Old Age Security: Class and Politics in the American Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), 112.
    • (1931) The Swope Plan: Details, Criticisms, Analysis
    • Swope, G.1
  • 71
    • 4043048906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Raymond B. Fosdick to John D. Rockefeller, Jr., 27 Apr. 1933, box 16, folder 127, Economic Reform [RG2COMRD], Rockefeller Archive Center (letter supplied to author by G. William Domhoff)
    • Raymond B. Fosdick to John D. Rockefeller, Jr., 27 Apr. 1933, box 16, folder 127, Economic Reform [RG2COMRD], Rockefeller Archive Center (letter supplied to author by G. William Domhoff).
  • 72
    • 4043150887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and representing the National Publishers' Association, Senate Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings
    • Telegrams and letters to Malcolm Muir, President of McGraw Hill Publishing Co., New York, submitted with statement of L.C. Morrow of McGraw-Hill, editor of Factory Management and Maintenance, and representing the National Publishers' Association, Senate Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings, 796.
    • Factory Management and Maintenance , pp. 796
    • Morrow, L.C.1
  • 73
    • 0005176311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • Sanford Jacoby, Modern Manors (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1998), 32-34.
    • (1998) Modern Manors , pp. 32-34
    • Jacoby, S.1
  • 74
    • 4043060204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Possibly for regulatory reasons, though certainly for the sake of the budget, the reformers imposed a $15 limit on earned income to qualify for social security. Had they not done so, some workers over 65, involuntarily retired by segmentalists, might simply have stayed in the labor market to work for low-standard employers, possibly even their competitors, to supplement their limited retirement benefits. Substandard employers could then depress standards even further. Thus, the government might have undermined the regulatory purpose of the new tax. Compare this with the Swedish system below. There, for clear regulatory reasons, all gainful employment was allowed without loss of benefits.
  • 78
    • 4043097104 scopus 로고
    • Discussion by E. Grosvenor Plowman
    • (Associated Industries of Massachusetts) (New York: American Management Association)
    • Stanley P. Farwell in "Discussion by E. Grosvenor Plowman" (Associated Industries of Massachusetts), in Pensions: A Problem of Management (New York: American Management Association, 1928), 33; Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change, 317. In some cases, companies controlled the expected damage by shifting partial funding onto employees. Raymond B. Fosdick to John D. Rockefeller, Jr., 27 Apr. 1933. See also Murray Webb Latimer, Industrial Pension Systems in the United States and Canada (New York: Industrial Relations Counselors, 1932), 902-5; Steven A. Sass, The Promise of Private. Pensions: The First Hundred Years (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997), 56-96.
    • (1928) Pensions: A Problem of Management , pp. 33
    • Farwell, S.P.1
  • 79
    • 4043148032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stanley P. Farwell in "Discussion by E. Grosvenor Plowman" (Associated Industries of Massachusetts), in Pensions: A Problem of Management (New York: American Management Association, 1928), 33; Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change, 317. In some cases, companies controlled the expected damage by shifting partial funding onto employees. Raymond B. Fosdick to John D. Rockefeller, Jr., 27 Apr. 1933. See also Murray Webb Latimer, Industrial Pension Systems in the United States and Canada (New York: Industrial Relations Counselors, 1932), 902-5; Steven A. Sass, The Promise of Private. Pensions: The First Hundred Years (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997), 56-96.
    • Policy Experts and Political Change , pp. 317
    • Manza1
  • 80
    • 0242395925 scopus 로고
    • New York: Industrial Relations Counselors
    • Stanley P. Farwell in "Discussion by E. Grosvenor Plowman" (Associated Industries of Massachusetts), in Pensions: A Problem of Management (New York: American Management Association, 1928), 33; Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change, 317. In some cases, companies controlled the expected damage by shifting partial funding onto employees. Raymond B. Fosdick to John D. Rockefeller, Jr., 27 Apr. 1933. See also Murray Webb Latimer, Industrial Pension Systems in the United States and Canada (New York: Industrial Relations Counselors, 1932), 902-5; Steven A. Sass, The Promise of Private. Pensions: The First Hundred Years (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997), 56-96.
    • (1932) Industrial Pension Systems in the United States and Canada , pp. 902-905
    • Latimer, M.W.1
  • 81
    • 84923598461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • Stanley P. Farwell in "Discussion by E. Grosvenor Plowman" (Associated Industries of Massachusetts), in Pensions: A Problem of Management (New York: American Management Association, 1928), 33; Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change, 317. In some cases, companies controlled the expected damage by shifting partial funding onto employees. Raymond B. Fosdick to John D. Rockefeller, Jr., 27 Apr. 1933. See also Murray Webb Latimer, Industrial Pension Systems in the United States and Canada (New York: Industrial Relations Counselors, 1932), 902-5; Steven A. Sass, The Promise of Private. Pensions: The First Hundred Years (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997), 56-96.
    • (1997) The Promise of Private. Pensions: The First Hundred Years , pp. 56-96
    • Sass, S.A.1
  • 83
    • 4043169320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Latimer, Industrial Pensions Systems, 880-82, 890; Letter to Malcolm Muir, U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings, 803-15; Testimony of R. G. Wagenet, U.S. Senate, Committee on Education and Labor, To Create a National Labor Board (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1934), pt. I, 283; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 201-7.
    • Industrial Pensions Systems , pp. 880-882
    • Latimer1
  • 84
    • 4043078668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Letter to Malcolm Muir, U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance
    • Latimer, Industrial Pensions Systems, 880-82, 890; Letter to Malcolm Muir, U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings, 803-15; Testimony of R. G. Wagenet, U.S. Senate, Committee on Education and Labor, To Create a National Labor Board (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1934), pt. I, 283; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 201-7.
    • Economic Security Act: Hearings , pp. 803-815
  • 85
    • 4043139540 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office
    • Latimer, Industrial Pensions Systems, 880-82, 890; Letter to Malcolm Muir, U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings, 803-15; Testimony of R. G. Wagenet, U.S. Senate, Committee on Education and Labor, To Create a National Labor Board (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1934), pt. I, 283; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 201-7.
    • (1934) To Create a National Labor Board , Issue.PART I , pp. 283
  • 86
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Latimer, Industrial Pensions Systems, 880-82, 890; Letter to Malcolm Muir, U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance, Economic Security Act: Hearings, 803-15; Testimony of R. G. Wagenet, U.S. Senate, Committee on Education and Labor, To Create a National Labor Board (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1934), pt. I, 283; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 201-7.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 201-207
    • Swenson1
  • 87
    • 0004099479 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • Jill Quadagno, The Transformation of Old Age Security: Class and Politics in the American Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), esp. 100-119; Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), esp. 240-79. See also Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change During the New Deal, 308-44.
    • (1988) The Transformation of Old Age Security: Class and Politics in the American Welfare State , pp. 100-119
    • Quadagno, J.1
  • 88
    • 0003497226 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Jill Quadagno, The Transformation of Old Age Security: Class and Politics in the American Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), esp. 100-119; Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), esp. 240-79. See also Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change During the New Deal, 308-44.
    • (1994) New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America 1920-1935 , pp. 240-279
    • Gordon, C.1
  • 89
    • 4043082893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jill Quadagno, The Transformation of Old Age Security: Class and Politics in the American Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988), esp. 100-119; Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), esp. 240-79. See also Manza, Policy Experts and Political Change During the New Deal, 308-44.
    • Policy Experts and Political Change during the New Deal , pp. 308-344
    • Manza1
  • 90
    • 38249007677 scopus 로고
    • Efficiency wages and local versus central wage bargaining
    • Not surprisingly, the models come from Norway, a country with a history of highly centralized pay setting much like Sweden's. See Michael Hoel, "Efficiency Wages and Local Versus Central Wage Bargaining," Economics Letters 30 (1989): 175-79, and "Union Wage Policy: The Importance of Labour Mobility and the Degree of Centralization," Economica 58 (1991): 139-53; Asb-jørn Rødseth, "Efficiency Wages and Local Versus Central Bargaining," Oxford Economic Papers 45 (1993), 470-81.
    • (1989) Economics Letters , vol.30 , pp. 175-179
    • Hoel, M.1
  • 91
    • 38249007677 scopus 로고
    • Union wage policy: The importance of labour mobility and the degree of centralization
    • Not surprisingly, the models come from Norway, a country with a history of highly centralized pay setting much like Sweden's. See Michael Hoel, "Efficiency Wages and Local Versus Central Wage Bargaining," Economics Letters 30 (1989): 175-79, and "Union Wage Policy: The Importance of Labour Mobility and the Degree of Centralization," Economica 58 (1991): 139-53; Asb-jørn Rødseth, "Efficiency Wages and Local Versus Central Bargaining," Oxford Economic Papers 45 (1993), 470-81.
    • (1991) Economica , vol.58 , pp. 139-153
  • 92
    • 0008296520 scopus 로고
    • Efficiency wages and local versus central bargaining
    • Not surprisingly, the models come from Norway, a country with a history of highly centralized pay setting much like Sweden's. See Michael Hoel, "Efficiency Wages and Local Versus Central Wage Bargaining," Economics Letters 30 (1989): 175-79, and "Union Wage Policy: The Importance of Labour Mobility and the Degree of Centralization," Economica 58 (1991): 139-53; Asb-jørn Rødseth, "Efficiency Wages and Local Versus Central Bargaining," Oxford Economic Papers 45 (1993), 470-81.
    • (1993) Oxford Economic Papers , vol.45 , pp. 470-481
    • Rødseth, A.-J.1
  • 93
    • 0002076170 scopus 로고
    • Bargaining structure and economic performance
    • ed. R. J. Flanagan, K.O. Moene, and M. Wallerstein (Oxford: Clarendon)
    • Karl Ove Moene and Michael Wallerstein, "Bargaining Structure and Economic Performance," in Trade Union Behavior, Pay-Bargaining, and Economic Performance, ed. R. J. Flanagan, K.O. Moene, and M. Wallerstein (Oxford: Clarendon, 1993), esp. 90-93.
    • (1993) Trade Union Behavior, Pay-bargaining, and Economic Performance , pp. 90-93
    • Moene, K.O.1    Wallerstein, M.2
  • 94
    • 4043112927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the monitoring and compliance problem, see Hoel, "Efficiency Wages," 175, and Rødseth, "Efficiency Wages," 477.
    • Efficiency Wages , pp. 175
    • Hoel1
  • 95
    • 84862393341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the monitoring and compliance problem, see Hoel, "Efficiency Wages," 175, and Rødseth, "Efficiency Wages," 477.
    • Efficiency Wages , pp. 477
    • Rødseth1
  • 96
    • 0040601234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pay inequality
    • Compression across firms and industries probably also pays off in efficiency because it prods employers into investment in labor-saving technology by inhibiting the expansion of output to meet demand by using wage increases to hire more workers using more of the old technology. By holding back wages at the high end it also subsidizes more productive newer vintage capital, thus accelerating a Schumpeterian process of creative destruction. See Karl-Ove Moene and Michael Wallerstein, "Pay Inequality," Journal of Labor Economies 15 (1997): 403-30; Wallerstein and Moene, "Solidaristic Wage Bargaining," Nordic Journal of Political Economy 22 (1995): 79-94.
    • (1997) Journal of Labor Economies , vol.15 , pp. 403-430
    • Moene, K.-O.1    Wallerstein, M.2
  • 97
    • 0040601234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Solidaristic wage bargaining
    • Compression across firms and industries probably also pays off in efficiency because it prods employers into investment in labor-saving technology by inhibiting the expansion of output to meet demand by using wage increases to hire more workers using more of the old technology. By holding back wages at the high end it also subsidizes more productive newer vintage capital, thus accelerating a Schumpeterian process of creative destruction. See Karl-Ove Moene and Michael Wallerstein, "Pay Inequality," Journal of Labor Economies 15 (1997): 403-30; Wallerstein and Moene, "Solidaristic Wage Bargaining," Nordic Journal of Political Economy 22 (1995): 79-94.
    • (1995) Nordic Journal of Political Economy , vol.22 , pp. 79-94
    • Wallerstein1    Moene2
  • 98
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Third, solidarists will seek to manage and ration the supply of labor by coordinating recruitment practices, including restrictions on open advertising and direct poaching, promoting the formation and use of labor exchanges or bureaus for deployment of idle workers and skills, and regulating or collectivizing vocational training. See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 33-34.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 33-34
    • Swenson1
  • 99
    • 0003866624 scopus 로고
    • (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press), esp. chaps. 4-5
    • But there will be latent tensions if not open conflict with-in labor on control issues as a result. Egalitarian wage restraint means passing up opportunities to raise wages in highly profitable firms and sectors. For a discussion, see Swenson, Fair Shares: Unions, Pay, and Politics in Sweden and West Germany (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1989), esp. chaps. 4-5.
    • (1989) Fair Shares: Unions, Pay, and Politics in Sweden and West Germany
    • Swenson1
  • 105
    • 84862404924 scopus 로고
    • Utdrag ur protokoll [från] sammanträde med Styrelsen för Göteborgskretsen
    • Stockholm: Sveriges Textilindustriförbund
    • "Utdrag ur protokoll [från] sammanträde med Styrelsen för Göteborgskretsen"; Nils Bergsten, Sveriges Textilindustriförbund 1907-1950 (Stockholm: Sveriges Textilindustriförbund 1957), 229-30.
    • (1957) Sveriges Textilindustriförbund 1907-1950 , pp. 229-230
    • Bergsten, N.1
  • 106
    • 0042002052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thommy Svensson, Från ackord till månadslön, 118; "Ed strömiana. Utdrag av tal vid direktör J.S. Edströms middag å Riche," 7 Mar. 1939 (Kugelberg P6, Edström, J.S.); Lars Magnusson, Arbetet vid en svensk verkstad: Munktells 1900-1920 (Lund: Arkiv, 1987), 229; Peter Billing, Lars Olsson, and Mikael Stigendal, "Malmö - Our Town": Local Politics in Social Democracy," in Creating Social Democracy; A Century of the Social Democratic Labor Party in Sweden, ed. Klaus Misgeld, Karl Molin, and Klas Åmark (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 1992), 282.
    • Från Ackord Till Månadslön , pp. 118
    • Svensson, T.1
  • 107
    • 84862392507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 7 Mar. (Kugelberg P6, Edström, J.S.)
    • Thommy Svensson, Från ackord till månadslön, 118; "Ed strömiana. Utdrag av tal vid direktör J.S. Edströms middag å Riche," 7 Mar. 1939 (Kugelberg P6, Edström, J.S.); Lars Magnusson, Arbetet vid en svensk verkstad: Munktells 1900-1920 (Lund: Arkiv, 1987), 229; Peter Billing, Lars Olsson, and Mikael Stigendal, "Malmö - Our Town": Local Politics in Social Democracy," in Creating Social Democracy; A Century of the Social Democratic Labor Party in Sweden, ed. Klaus Misgeld, Karl Molin, and Klas Åmark (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 1992), 282.
    • Ed Strömiana. Utdrag av tal vid Direktör J.S. Edströms Middag å Riche , pp. 1939
  • 108
    • 0242629189 scopus 로고
    • Lund: Arkiv
    • Thommy Svensson, Från ackord till månadslön, 118; "Ed strömiana. Utdrag av tal vid direktör J.S. Edströms middag å Riche," 7 Mar. 1939 (Kugelberg P6, Edström, J.S.); Lars Magnusson, Arbetet vid en svensk verkstad: Munktells 1900-1920 (Lund: Arkiv, 1987), 229; Peter Billing, Lars Olsson, and Mikael Stigendal, "Malmö - Our Town": Local Politics in Social Democracy," in Creating Social Democracy; A Century of the Social Democratic Labor Party in Sweden, ed. Klaus Misgeld, Karl Molin, and Klas Åmark (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 1992), 282.
    • (1987) Arbetet vid en Svensk Verkstad: Munktells 1900-1920 , pp. 229
    • Magnusson, L.1
  • 111
    • 4043180701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • VF Circular No. 35-1921, 21 Dec. 1921; VF, Direktiv N:r 1-1922, 5 Jan. 1922
    • VF Circular No. 35-1921, 21 Dec. 1921; VF, Direktiv N:r 1-1922, 5 Jan. 1922; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 9 Sept. 1932.
  • 112
    • 4043140902 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 9 Sept
    • VF Circular No. 35-1921, 21 Dec. 1921; VF, Direktiv N:r 1-1922, 5 Jan. 1922; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 9 Sept. 1932.
    • (1932) Styrelse
  • 113
    • 4043177870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Aubrey Clayton to Edström, 12 Feb. 1907, Edström E21 [A3a/överstyrelsen]. Neither Metall nor the 1905 agreement blocked the apprentice solution; wages for apprentices were not regulated.
  • 114
    • 4043146645 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 25 Jan., 22 Mar., 26 Apr., 31 May, and 6 Sept
    • Low-pay sectors were particularly disturbed. For example some textile employers wanted to raise wages for fear of losing workers to higher-pay sectors like engineering. Engineering employers, frequently stealing workers from each other, dealt with the matter collectively by sharpening their rules against poaching. In some regions they agreed among themselves not to hire workers within a month of their departure from a fellow engineering employer. See for example SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 25 Jan., 22 Mar., 26 Apr., 31 May, and 6 Sept. 1945; SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 26 Sept. 1945.
    • (1945) Styrelse
  • 115
    • 4043110040 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 26 Sept
    • Low-pay sectors were particularly disturbed. For example some textile employers wanted to raise wages for fear of losing workers to higher-pay sectors like engineering. Engineering employers, frequently stealing workers from each other, dealt with the matter collectively by sharpening their rules against poaching. In some regions they agreed among themselves not to hire workers within a month of their departure from a fellow engineering employer. See for example SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 25 Jan., 22 Mar., 26 Apr., 31 May, and 6 Sept. 1945; SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 26 Sept. 1945.
    • (1945) Ombudsmannakonferens
  • 116
    • 4043102785 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 29 Aug
    • SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 29 Aug. 1946; Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 18 Nov. 1946.
    • (1946) Styrelse
  • 117
    • 4043183530 scopus 로고
    • Minutes, 18 Nov
    • SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 29 Aug. 1946; Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 18 Nov. 1946.
    • (1946) Ombudsmannakonferens
  • 118
    • 84862394427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SAF
    • SAF, Styrelse- och revisionsberättelser för år 1946, 35; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 29 Aug. and 24 Oct. 1946; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 16 Dec. 1946; "Anteckningar vid ett sammanträde i Göteborg ang. Situationen på arbetsmarknaden," 27 May 1946 (Edström 29/E3i/överstyrelsen).
    • Styrelse- Och Revisionsberättelser för År 1946 , pp. 35
  • 119
    • 4043102785 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 29 Aug. and 24 Oct
    • SAF, Styrelse- och revisionsberättelser för år 1946, 35; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 29 Aug. and 24 Oct. 1946; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 16 Dec. 1946; "Anteckningar vid ett sammanträde i Göteborg ang. Situationen på arbetsmarknaden," 27 May 1946 (Edström 29/E3i/överstyrelsen).
    • (1946) Styrelse
  • 120
    • 4043102785 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 16 Dec
    • SAF, Styrelse- och revisionsberättelser för år 1946, 35; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 29 Aug. and 24 Oct. 1946; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 16 Dec. 1946; "Anteckningar vid ett sammanträde i Göteborg ang. Situationen på arbetsmarknaden," 27 May 1946 (Edström 29/E3i/överstyrelsen).
    • (1946) Styrelse
  • 121
    • 84862394860 scopus 로고
    • 27 May (Edström 29/E3i/överstyrelsen)
    • SAF, Styrelse- och revisionsberättelser för år 1946, 35; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 29 Aug. and 24 Oct. 1946; SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 16 Dec. 1946; "Anteckningar vid ett sammanträde i Göteborg ang. Situationen på arbetsmarknaden," 27 May 1946 (Edström 29/E3i/överstyrelsen).
    • (1946) Anteckningar vid ett Sammanträde i Göteborg ang. Situationen På Arbetsmarknaden
  • 122
    • 4043102785 scopus 로고
    • SAF, 27 Nov
    • SAF, Styrelse, 27 Nov. 1946; Ombudsmannakonferens, 18 Nov., 16 Dec. 1946.
    • (1946) Styrelse
  • 123
    • 4043183530 scopus 로고
    • 18 Nov., 16 Dec
    • SAF, Styrelse, 27 Nov. 1946; Ombudsmannakonferens, 18 Nov., 16 Dec. 1946.
    • (1946) Ombudsmannakonferens
  • 124
    • 84862400218 scopus 로고
    • SAF, 25 June, and appendixes (F. Andersson, Nässjö Bryggeri AB to Bryggeriarbetsgivareförbundet, 14 June 1946 and Felix Brandel, Tranås Bryggeri AB to Bryggeriarbetsgivareförbundet, 15 June 1946);
    • SAF, Arbetsutskott, 25 June 1946, and appendixes (F. Andersson, Nässjö Bryggeri AB to Bryggeriarbetsgivareförbundet, 14 June 1946 and Felix Brandel, Tranås Bryggeri AB to Bryggeriarbetsgivareförbundet, 15 June 1946); SAF, "Cirkulär till Svenska Arbetsgivareföreningens delägare," Appendix A to Minutes, Styrelse, 28 Mar. 1946.
    • (1946) Arbetsutskott
  • 125
    • 84862402431 scopus 로고
    • Cirkulär till Svenska Arbetsgivareföreningens delägare
    • SAF, Appendix A to Minutes, 28 Mar
    • SAF, Arbetsutskott, 25 June 1946, and appendixes (F. Andersson, Nässjö Bryggeri AB to Bryggeriarbetsgivareförbundet, 14 June 1946 and Felix Brandel, Tranås Bryggeri AB to Bryggeriarbetsgivareförbundet, 15 June 1946); SAF, "Cirkulär till Svenska Arbetsgivareföreningens delägare," Appendix A to Minutes, Styrelse, 28 Mar. 1946.
    • (1946) Styrelse
  • 126
    • 84862394426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SAF
    • On tight labor market conditions in 1947, see SAF, Styrelseoch revisionsberättelser för år 1947, 49-50. High level discussions into the 1950s regarding labor scarcity can be found, among other places, in SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 27 Feb., 28 Aug., and 30 Oct. 1947; 26 Aug., 21 Oct., and 11 Nov. 1948; 17 Feb. and 15 Sept. 1949; 23 May and 19 Oct. 1950; 15 Nov. 1951; 22-23 Apr., 16 Sept., 21-22 Oct., and 18 Nov. 1954; 15 Sept. 1955; 18 Oct. 1956; 17 Oct. and 25 Apr. 1957. See also SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens (Förbundsdirektörskonferens), 13-14 Sept. 1954; 11-12 Nov. 1957; and 15 Sept. 1958; and SAF, Minutes, Arbetsutskott, 13 July 1955.
    • Styrelseoch Revisionsberättelser för år 1947 , pp. 49-50
  • 127
    • 84862402097 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 27 Feb., 28 Aug., and 30 Oct.; 26 Aug., 21 Oct., and 11 Nov. 1948; 17 Feb. and 15 Sept. 1949; 23 May and 19 Oct. 1950; 15 Nov. 1951; 22-23 Apr., 16 Sept., 21-22 Oct., and 18 Nov. 1954; 15 Sept. 1955; 18 Oct. 1956; 17 Oct. and 25 Apr. 1957
    • On tight labor market conditions in 1947, see SAF, Styrelseoch revisionsberättelser för år 1947, 49-50. High level discussions into the 1950s regarding labor scarcity can be found, among other places, in SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 27 Feb., 28 Aug., and 30 Oct. 1947; 26 Aug., 21 Oct., and 11 Nov. 1948; 17 Feb. and 15 Sept. 1949; 23 May and 19 Oct. 1950; 15 Nov. 1951; 22-23 Apr., 16 Sept., 21-22 Oct., and 18 Nov. 1954; 15 Sept. 1955; 18 Oct. 1956; 17 Oct. and 25 Apr. 1957. See also SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens (Förbundsdirektörskonferens), 13-14 Sept. 1954; 11-12 Nov. 1957; and 15 Sept. 1958; and SAF, Minutes, Arbetsutskott, 13 July 1955.
    • (1947) Styrelse
  • 128
    • 84862393360 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 13-14 Sept.; 11-12 Nov. 1957; and 15 Sept. 1958
    • On tight labor market conditions in 1947, see SAF, Styrelseoch revisionsberättelser för år 1947, 49-50. High level discussions into the 1950s regarding labor scarcity can be found, among other places, in SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 27 Feb., 28 Aug., and 30 Oct. 1947; 26 Aug., 21 Oct., and 11 Nov. 1948; 17 Feb. and 15 Sept. 1949; 23 May and 19 Oct. 1950; 15 Nov. 1951; 22-23 Apr., 16 Sept., 21-22 Oct., and 18 Nov. 1954; 15 Sept. 1955; 18 Oct. 1956; 17 Oct. and 25 Apr. 1957. See also SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens (Förbundsdirektörskonferens), 13-14 Sept. 1954; 11-12 Nov. 1957; and 15 Sept. 1958; and SAF, Minutes, Arbetsutskott, 13 July 1955.
    • (1954) Ombudsmannakonferens (Förbundsdirektörskonferens)
  • 129
    • 4043135333 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 13 July
    • On tight labor market conditions in 1947, see SAF, Styrelseoch revisionsberättelser för år 1947, 49-50. High level discussions into the 1950s regarding labor scarcity can be found, among other places, in SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 27 Feb., 28 Aug., and 30 Oct. 1947; 26 Aug., 21 Oct., and 11 Nov. 1948; 17 Feb. and 15 Sept. 1949; 23 May and 19 Oct. 1950; 15 Nov. 1951; 22-23 Apr., 16 Sept., 21-22 Oct., and 18 Nov. 1954; 15 Sept. 1955; 18 Oct. 1956; 17 Oct. and 25 Apr. 1957. See also SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens (Förbundsdirektörskonferens), 13-14 Sept. 1954; 11-12 Nov. 1957; and 15 Sept. 1958; and SAF, Minutes, Arbetsutskott, 13 July 1955.
    • (1955) Arbetsutskott
  • 130
    • 84862401805 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Utrednings- och Upplysningsbyrå Oct. [SAF A1/27ec]
    • The 1952 survey, with a response rate of 86 percent, covered firms with at least 50 workers. Vacation pay was subtracted from the 1952 totals to make them roughly comparable with the 1948 survey. SAF, Utrednings- och Upplysningsbyrå, "Utredning rörande sociala åtgärder inom industrin," Oct. 1948 [SAF A1/27ec]; SAF, "Företagens indirekta personalkostnader år 1952 - Preliminär redogörelse, " SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, Appendix 6, April 1954. On wartime solidarism in the United States, see Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 168-75.
    • (1948) Utredning Rörande Sociala Åtgärder Inom Industrin
  • 131
    • 84862392851 scopus 로고
    • Företagens indirekta personalkostnader år 1952 - Preliminär redogörelse
    • SAF, SAF, Minutes, Appendix 6, April
    • The 1952 survey, with a response rate of 86 percent, covered firms with at least 50 workers. Vacation pay was subtracted from the 1952 totals to make them roughly comparable with the 1948 survey. SAF, Utrednings- och Upplysningsbyrå, "Utredning rörande sociala åtgärder inom industrin," Oct. 1948 [SAF A1/27ec]; SAF, "Företagens indirekta personalkostnader år 1952 - Preliminär redogörelse, " SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, Appendix 6, April 1954. On wartime solidarism in the United States, see Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 168-75.
    • (1954) Styrelse
  • 132
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The 1952 survey, with a response rate of 86 percent, covered firms with at least 50 workers. Vacation pay was subtracted from the 1952 totals to make them roughly comparable with the 1948 survey. SAF, Utrednings- och Upplysningsbyrå, "Utredning rörande sociala åtgärder inom industrin," Oct. 1948 [SAF A1/27ec]; SAF, "Företagens indirekta personalkostnader år 1952 - Preliminär redogörelse, " SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, Appendix 6, April 1954. On wartime solidarism in the United States, see Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 168-75.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 168-175
    • Swenson1
  • 135
    • 84862400064 scopus 로고
    • 23 Jan. SAF A150 (18x)
    • Fritjof Söderbäck, "Till Konungen," 23 Jan. 1946. SAF A150 (18x). See also "Lag om folkpensionering/yttrande"; Socialvårdskommitténs Betänkande XI - Utredning och förslag angående lag om folkpensionering. SOU 1945:46 (Stockholm: Statens Offentliga Utredningar, 1945), 134-35. SAF accepted incomes-tested supplementary housing benefits for those in high-rent areas only because universalistic benefits would put too much strain on government finances. However, the 1934 deducibility rules for company pensions were preserved, as employers wanted.
    • (1946) Till Konungen
    • Söderbäck, F.1
  • 136
    • 84862392505 scopus 로고
    • Lag om folkpensionering/yttrande
    • SOU 1945:46 (Stockholm: Statens Offentliga Utredningar)
    • Fritjof Söderbäck, "Till Konungen," 23 Jan. 1946. SAF A150 (18x). See also "Lag om folkpensionering/yttrande"; Socialvårdskommitténs Betänkande XI - Utredning och förslag angående lag om folkpensionering. SOU 1945:46 (Stockholm: Statens Offentliga Utredningar, 1945), 134-35. SAF accepted incomes-tested supplementary housing benefits for those in high-rent areas only because universalistic benefits would put too much strain on government finances. However, the 1934 deducibility rules for company pensions were preserved, as employers wanted.
    • (1945) Socialvårdskommitténs Betänkande XI - Utredning Och Förslag Angående Lag Om Folkpensionering , pp. 134-135
  • 137
    • 4043166422 scopus 로고
    • 9 Feb
    • Dagens Nyheter, 9 Feb. 1946; Åke Elḿer, Folkpensioneringen i Sverige (Lund: CWK Gleerup, 1960), 85, 90, 140.
    • (1946) Dagens Nyheter
  • 139
    • 84862396590 scopus 로고
    • 5 Jan. SAF:A150/18x/Lag om folkpensionering/yttranden från förbund
    • Biltrafikens Arbetsgivareförbund to SAF, 5 Jan. 1946. SAF:A150/18x/Lag om folkpensionering/yttranden från förbund; SAF, Styrelse, 30 May 1947 (discussion by Eric Brodén).
    • (1946) Biltrafikens Arbetsgivareförbund to SAF
  • 140
    • 84862402097 scopus 로고
    • SAF, 30 May (discussion by Eric Brodén)
    • Biltrafikens Arbetsgivareförbund to SAF, 5 Jan. 1946. SAF:A150/18x/Lag om folkpensionering/yttranden från förbund; SAF, Styrelse, 30 May 1947 (discussion by Eric Brodén).
    • (1947) Styrelse
  • 141
    • 84862402097 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 30 May
    • SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 30 May 1947.
    • (1947) Styrelse
  • 143
    • 4043122690 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 12 Nov
    • SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 12 Nov. 1931.
    • (1931) Styrelse
  • 145
    • 4043125512 scopus 로고
    • 17 Mar.
    • Implementation of earlier legislation, passed in 1946 against SAF's strong opposition, had been repeatedly postponed, until it was actually scrapped in 1951. The evidence indicates that among the Social Democrats' second thoughts were SAF's first: labor and materials shortages for hospital construction and personnel made it "impossible to implement." SAF also strenuously objected to the first law's flat-rate sick pay benefit, which was well above many rural incomes. This would have made it difficult for Swedish industry to continue attracting labor away from agriculture. "Den nya sjukkasselagen," (no date), SAF/A 1350/22å-I/Diverse PM och diskussionsanteckningar; "Högerledaren: Ogenomförbar reform är propagandareform," Svenska Dagbladet, 17 Mar. 1946; Fritjof Söderbäck, Remissyttrande över en inom socialdepartementet upprättad promemoria angående . . . allmän sjukförsäkring, 27 June 1945. SAF/A 1350/22m/Yttrande 1945.
    • (1946) Svenska Dagbladet
  • 146
    • 84862401453 scopus 로고
    • 27 June . SAF/A 1350/22m/Yttrande 1945
    • Implementation of earlier legislation, passed in 1946 against SAF's strong opposition, had been repeatedly postponed, until it was actually scrapped in 1951. The evidence indicates that among the Social Democrats' second thoughts were SAF's first: labor and materials shortages for hospital construction and personnel made it "impossible to implement." SAF also strenuously objected to the first law's flat-rate sick pay benefit, which was well above many rural incomes. This would have made it difficult for Swedish industry to continue attracting labor away from agriculture. "Den nya sjukkasselagen," (no date), SAF/A 1350/22å-I/Diverse PM och diskussionsanteckningar; "Högerledaren: Ogenomförbar reform är propagandareform," Svenska Dagbladet, 17 Mar. 1946; Fritjof Söderbäck, Remissyttrande över en inom socialdepartementet upprättad promemoria angående . . . allmän sjukförsäkring, 27 June 1945. SAF/A 1350/22m/Yttrande 1945.
    • (1945) Remissyttrande över en Inom Socialdepartementet Upprättad Promemoria Angående . . . Allmän Sjukförsäkring
    • Söderbäck, F.1
  • 149
    • 84862405095 scopus 로고
    • 17 Oct. SAF 1350/22å/Svar från styrelseledamöter; Träindustriförbundet, Yttrande över förslaget till yrkesskadeförsäkring. TIF/Yrkesskadeförsäkring 1950-51
    • "PM angående sjukförsäkring" (by Sven Hydén), 17 Oct. 1952. SAF 1350/22å/Svar från styrelseledamöter; Träindustriförbundet, Yttrande över förslaget till yrkesskadeförsäkring. TIF/ Yrkesskadeförsäkring 1950-51.
    • (1952) PM Angående Sjukförsäkring
    • Hydén, S.1
  • 152
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ALMP's administrative structures and even basic policies were actually introduced earlier, albeit on a limited scale, and with employer support in the 1930s and 1940s. See Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 277-79.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 277-279
    • Swenson1
  • 154
    • 4043146644 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 13 Dec
    • Tommy Svensson, Från ackord till månadslön - En Studie av lönepolitiken, fackföreningarna och rationaliseringarna inom svensk varvsindustri under 1900-talet (Stockholm: Svenska Varv, 1983), 344-45; SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 13 Dec. 1954; Bertil Kugelberg, "Minnesanteckningar från diskussion på Hotell Tunneln i Malmö," 8 Nov. 1954 (Kugelberg collection, SAF); SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 21-22 Oct. 1954, and 18 Nov. 1954.
    • (1954) Ombudsmannakonferens
  • 155
    • 84862401022 scopus 로고
    • 8 Nov. (Kugelberg collection, SAF)
    • Tommy Svensson, Från ackord till månadslön - En Studie av lönepolitiken, fackföreningarna och rationaliseringarna inom svensk varvsindustri under 1900-talet (Stockholm: Svenska Varv, 1983), 344-45; SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 13 Dec. 1954; Bertil Kugelberg, "Minnesanteckningar från diskussion på Hotell Tunneln i Malmö," 8 Nov. 1954 (Kugelberg collection, SAF); SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 21-22 Oct. 1954, and 18 Nov. 1954.
    • (1954) Minnesanteckningar Från Diskussion På Hotell Tunneln i Malmö
    • Kugelberg, B.1
  • 156
    • 4043156510 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 21-22 Oct., and 18 Nov. 1954
    • Tommy Svensson, Från ackord till månadslön - En Studie av lönepolitiken, fackföreningarna och rationaliseringarna inom svensk varvsindustri under 1900-talet (Stockholm: Svenska Varv, 1983), 344-45; SAF, Minutes, Ombudsmannakonferens, 13 Dec. 1954; Bertil Kugelberg, "Minnesanteckningar från diskussion på Hotell Tunneln i Malmö," 8 Nov. 1954 (Kugelberg collection, SAF); SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 21-22 Oct. 1954, and 18 Nov. 1954.
    • (1954) Styrelse
  • 157
    • 79551703600 scopus 로고
    • Finansministrarna, LO-ekonomerna och arbetsmarknadspolitiken
    • Stockholm: Norstedts
    • Rehn, "Finansministrarna, LO-ekonomerna och arbetsmarknadspolitiken, " Ekonomisk debatt och ekonomisk politik - National-ekonomiska Föreningen 100 år (Stockholm: Norstedts, 1977). "Den nya arbetsmarknadspolitiken," Svensk sparbankstidskrift 43 (1959): 221, emphasis added.
    • (1977) Ekonomisk Debatt Och Ekonomisk Politik - National-ekonomiska Föreningen 100 år
    • Rehn1
  • 158
    • 4043125515 scopus 로고
    • Den nya arbetsmarknadspolitiken
    • emphasis added
    • Rehn, "Finansministrarna, LO-ekonomerna och arbetsmarknadspolitiken, " Ekonomisk debatt och ekonomisk politik - National-ekonomiska Föreningen 100 år (Stockholm: Norstedts, 1977). "Den nya arbetsmarknadspolitiken," Svensk sparbankstidskrift 43 (1959): 221, emphasis added.
    • (1959) Svensk Sparbankstidskrift , vol.43 , pp. 221
  • 160
    • 0141462350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The conflict concerned what the LO economists regarded as the government's excessive reliance on traditional and rather clumsy expansionary macroeconomic policies to counteract increases in unemployment, while expecting the unions to exercise voluntary restraint on wages - even with unemployment dipping below 1 percent. Predictably, as in 1948, 1951, and 1955, the result was an explosion of wages and prices triggered by wage drift. Firms systematically violated centrally negotiated wage increases. Paying more than unions had settled for was of course deeply embarrassing to them, so they who would then rush in with militant demands to reclaim leadership in representing workers' interests. Rehn, "Finansministrarna, LO-ekonomerna och arbetsmarknadspolitiken," 234-37.
    • Finansministrarna, LO-ekonomerna Och Arbetsmarknadspolitiken , pp. 234-237
    • Rehn1
  • 161
    • 4043071461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • SAF objected, for example, to eliminating AMS's role in procuring nannies (hemvårdarinnor) for families with two working parents. "It is of greatest importance, "SAF wrote, "that the potential manpower reserve consisting of non-gainfully employed women, is supplied to production." Yttrande, 8 Feb. 1951 [SAF A7100(2u) Betr. den offentliga arbetsförmedlingens organisation].
  • 162
    • 84925974935 scopus 로고
    • Class coalitions in the making of West European economies
    • Esping-Andersen and Friedland, "Class Coalitions in the Making of West European Economies," Political Power and Social Theory 3 (1982):17, 19, 47.
    • (1982) Political Power and Social Theory , vol.3 , pp. 17
    • Esping-Andersen1    Friedland2
  • 164
    • 84862395736 scopus 로고
    • Limits of active labour market policy, especially with respect to the case of Sweden
    • Nürnberg, Germany, 20-21 June
    • Rudolf Meidner, "Limits of Active Labour Market Policy, especially with Respect to the Case of Sweden," SAMF-Conference on "Public Policy to Combat Unemployment," (Nürnberg, Germany, 20-21 June 1983), 3; Gösta Rehn, "Swedish Active Labor Market Policy: Retrospect and Prospect," Industrial Relations 24 (1985): 73.
    • (1983) SAMF-conference on "Public Policy to Combat Unemployment" , pp. 3
    • Meidner, R.1
  • 165
    • 84970384125 scopus 로고
    • Swedish active labor market policy: Retrospect and prospect
    • Rudolf Meidner, "Limits of Active Labour Market Policy, especially with Respect to the Case of Sweden," SAMF-Conference on "Public Policy to Combat Unemployment," (Nürnberg, Germany, 20-21 June 1983), 3; Gösta Rehn, "Swedish Active Labor Market Policy: Retrospect and Prospect," Industrial Relations 24 (1985): 73.
    • (1985) Industrial Relations , vol.24 , pp. 73
    • Rehn, G.1
  • 167
    • 84862393724 scopus 로고
    • Arbetsmarknadspolitiken bör ses som arbetsgivarnas bundsförvant
    • 8 Mar.
    • Lars Gunnar Albåge, "Arbetsmarknadspolitiken bör ses som arbetsgivarnas bundsförvant," Arbetsgivaren 8 Mar. 1968, 5; Magnus Jerneck, SAFs Framtidssyn: Förutsägelser, makättningar och dilemman (Stockholm: SAF, 1986), 116.
    • (1968) Arbetsgivaren , pp. 5
    • Albåge, L.G.1
  • 169
    • 0038792725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Business power and social policy: Employers and the formation of the American welfare state
    • Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson, "Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State," Politics and Society 30 (2002): 277-325.
    • (2002) Politics and Society , vol.30 , pp. 277-325
    • Hacker, J.S.1    Pierson, P.2
  • 171
    • 0003873852 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press
    • Eric Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1994), 25-50; Lars Jonung, "Riksbankens politik 1945 - En krönika," in Från räntereglering till inflationsnorm - Det finansiella systemet och riksbankens politik 1945-1990, ed. Lars Werin (Stockholm: SNS, 1993), 317-18, 329, 343-44, 361-64, and 370-71.
    • (1994) States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s , pp. 25-50
    • Helleiner, E.1
  • 172
    • 84862395549 scopus 로고
    • Riksbankens politik 1945 - En krönika
    • ed. Lars Werin (Stockholm: SNS)
    • Eric Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1994), 25-50; Lars Jonung, "Riksbankens politik 1945 - En krönika," in Från räntereglering till inflationsnorm - Det finansiella systemet och riksbankens politik 1945-1990, ed. Lars Werin (Stockholm: SNS, 1993), 317-18, 329, 343-44, 361-64, and 370-71.
    • (1993) Från Räntereglering Till Inflationsnorm - Det Finansiella Systemet Och Riksbankens Politik 1945-1990 , pp. 317-318
    • Jonung, L.1
  • 173
    • 0003730806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • If we turn to capitalists' "instrumental" power (exercised in electoral financing, lobbying, and opinion making) the puzzle remains: given that the Democratic Party depended heavily on capitalist funds, why would the New Dealers have so brazenly defied capital? A recent work by Mark Smith suggests a possible answer consistent with the power outage argument. The contributors may have invested campaign contributions mostly for particularistic benefits (subsidies, regulations, and tax breaks) that both parties trafficked in. Thus capitalist money for Democrats was for other things than correct social policy. Even had the New Dealers defied unified capital in the social policy realm, they could have continued delivering all manner of particularistic advantages. They could reform with impunity, yet the money would continue to flow. It should be clear by now, however, that it is wrong to starkly differentiate social welfare issues from particularistic ones. Social insurance reform was less a "unifying issue" (in Smith's sense, uniting capitalists against reformers) than meets the eye. Mark Smith, American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000).
    • (2000) American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy
    • Smith, M.1
  • 175
    • 0003556059 scopus 로고
    • New York: Aldine de Gruyter
    • That criticism needs no repetition here. See Domhoff, The Power Elite and the State: Haw Policy is Made in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1990), 54-57; Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance: Case Studies of Policy Making in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1996), 161-63; Swenson, "Arranged Alliance: Business Interests in the New Deal," Politics and Society 25 (1997): 88-90; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 223-26.
    • (1990) The Power Elite and the State: Haw Policy Is Made in America , pp. 54-57
    • Domhoff1
  • 176
    • 0003425351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Aldine de Gruyter
    • That criticism needs no repetition here. See Domhoff, The Power Elite and the State: Haw Policy is Made in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1990), 54-57; Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance: Case Studies of Policy Making in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1996), 161-63; Swenson, "Arranged Alliance: Business Interests in the New Deal," Politics and Society 25 (1997): 88-90; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 223-26.
    • (1996) State Autonomy or Class Dominance: Case Studies of Policy Making in America , pp. 161-163
    • Domhoff1
  • 177
    • 0031285954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arranged alliance: Business interests in the new deal
    • That criticism needs no repetition here. See Domhoff, The Power Elite and the State: Haw Policy is Made in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1990), 54-57; Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance: Case Studies of Policy Making in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1996), 161-63; Swenson, "Arranged Alliance: Business Interests in the New Deal," Politics and Society 25 (1997): 88-90; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 223-26.
    • (1997) Politics and Society , vol.25 , pp. 88-90
    • Swenson1
  • 178
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That criticism needs no repetition here. See Domhoff, The Power Elite and the State: Haw Policy is Made in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1990), 54-57; Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance: Case Studies of Policy Making in America (New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 1996), 161-63; Swenson, "Arranged Alliance: Business Interests in the New Deal," Politics and Society 25 (1997): 88-90; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 223-26.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 223-226
    • Swenson1
  • 179
    • 4043107228 scopus 로고
    • Old age pensions and compulsory old age insurance of wage workers
    • Charles L. Edgar, William R. Willcox, and P. Tecumseh Sherman, (New York: National Civic Federation)
    • P. Tecumseh Sherman, "Old Age Pensions and Compulsory Old Age Insurance of Wage Workers," in Charles L. Edgar, William R. Willcox, and P. Tecumseh Sherman, Old Age Pensions Conference (New York: National Civic Federation, 1927), 7.
    • (1927) Old Age Pensions Conference , pp. 7
    • Sherman, P.T.1
  • 180
    • 0010851957 scopus 로고
    • New York: The Business Bourse
    • Gerard Swope, The Swope Plan: Details, Criticisms, Analysis (New York: The Business Bourse, 1931), 25-27; Henry I. Harriman, "The Stabilization of Business and Employment," American Economic Review 22 (1932), 63-74. Robert Himmelberg speculates, like Hacker and Pierson, that Swope and Harriman were strategically trying to preempt legislative action "that Congress might begin to move toward," but also trying to sweeten the cartelist "planned production" pill (see discussion of the NRA below). He ignores, inappropriately, Swope's explicit reasoning, which was entirely in line with, not extraneous to the cartelist project. Of course, all three reasons, being noncontradictory, could be correct. Robert F. Himmelberg, The Origins of the National Recovery Administration: Business, Government, and the Trade Association Issue, 1921-1933 (New York: Fordham University Press, 1993), 135.
    • (1931) The Swope Plan: Details, Criticisms, Analysis , pp. 25-27
    • Swope, G.1
  • 181
    • 4043129745 scopus 로고
    • The stabilization of business and employment
    • Gerard Swope, The Swope Plan: Details, Criticisms, Analysis (New York: The Business Bourse, 1931), 25-27; Henry I. Harriman, "The Stabilization of Business and Employment," American Economic Review 22 (1932), 63-74. Robert Himmelberg speculates, like Hacker and Pierson, that Swope and Harriman were strategically trying to preempt legislative action "that Congress might begin to move toward," but also trying to sweeten the cartelist "planned production" pill (see discussion of the NRA below). He ignores, inappropriately, Swope's explicit reasoning, which was entirely in line with, not extraneous to the cartelist project. Of course, all three reasons, being noncontradictory, could be correct. Robert F. Himmelberg, The Origins of the National Recovery Administration: Business, Government, and the Trade Association Issue, 1921-1933 (New York: Fordham University Press, 1993), 135.
    • (1932) American Economic Review , vol.22 , pp. 63-74
    • Harriman, H.I.1
  • 182
    • 0040244028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Fordham University Press
    • Gerard Swope, The Swope Plan: Details, Criticisms, Analysis (New York: The Business Bourse, 1931), 25-27; Henry I. Harriman, "The Stabilization of Business and Employment," American Economic Review 22 (1932), 63-74. Robert Himmelberg speculates, like Hacker and Pierson, that Swope and Harriman were strategically trying to preempt legislative action "that Congress might begin to move toward," but also trying to sweeten the cartelist "planned production" pill (see discussion of the NRA below). He ignores, inappropriately, Swope's explicit reasoning, which was entirely in line with, not extraneous to the cartelist project. Of course, all three reasons, being noncontradictory, could be correct. Robert F. Himmelberg, The Origins of the National Recovery Administration: Business, Government, and the Trade Association Issue, 1921-1933 (New York: Fordham University Press, 1993), 135.
    • (1993) The Origins of the National Recovery Administration: Business, Government, and the Trade Association Issue, 1921-1933 , pp. 135
    • Himmelberg, R.F.1
  • 184
    • 4043055958 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: Government Printing Office
    • U.S. Senate, Committee on Education and Labor, Violations of Free Speech and Rights of Labor Labor Policies of Employers' Associations, Part III (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1939), 211-12. Filene is quoted in David C.D. Jacobs, Business Lobbies and the Power Structure in America (Westport, CT: Quorum, 1999), 81-92.
    • (1939) Violations of Free Speech and Rights of Labor Labor Policies of Employers' Associations, Part III , pp. 211-212
  • 185
    • 0003716623 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Westport, CT: Quorum
    • U.S. Senate, Committee on Education and Labor, Violations of Free Speech and Rights of Labor Labor Policies of Employers' Associations, Part III (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1939), 211-12. Filene is quoted in David C.D. Jacobs, Business Lobbies and the Power Structure in America (Westport, CT: Quorum, 1999), 81-92.
    • (1999) Business Lobbies and the Power Structure in America , pp. 81-92
    • Jacobs, D.C.D.1
  • 187
    • 4043180700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • J. Douglas Brown to Edwin E. Witte, 13 Feb. 1935. Seeley G. Mudd Manuscript Library, Princeton University
    • J. Douglas Brown to Edwin E. Witte, 13 Feb. 1935. J. Douglas Brown Papers, Seeley G. Mudd Manuscript Library, Princeton University.
    • J. Douglas Brown Papers
  • 188
    • 85050416030 scopus 로고
    • Employers and the welfare state: The role of Marion B. Folsom
    • Sanford Jacoby, "Employers and the Welfare State: The Role of Marion B. Folsom," Journal of American History 80 (1993), 544. See also Domhoff, The Power Elite and the Stale, 56.
    • (1993) Journal of American History , vol.80 , pp. 544
    • Jacoby, S.1
  • 189
    • 4043118493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sanford Jacoby, "Employers and the Welfare State: The Role of Marion B. Folsom," Journal of American History 80 (1993), 544. See also Domhoff, The Power Elite and the Stale, 56.
    • The Power Elite and the Stale , pp. 56
    • Domhoff1
  • 190
    • 85050835182 scopus 로고
    • The movement toward unemployment insurance in Ohio
    • I.M. Rubinow, "The Movement Toward Unemployment Insurance in Ohio," Social Service Review 7 (1933): 213. When Roosevelt optimistically invited William P. Wrigley of Chicago, who had installed a company unemployment insurance plan, on the advisory committee, the response was a curt and off-putting letter from his secretary. We do not know why, but nevertheless, Wrigley contributed to the Democratic party in 1936. Witte, Development of the Social Security Act, 50; Overacker, "Campaign Funds," 473-98, Berkowitz and McQuaid, Creating the Welfare State, 118; Nelson, Unemployment Insurance, 63.
    • (1933) Social Service Review , vol.7 , pp. 213
    • Rubinow, I.M.1
  • 191
    • 0003983026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.M. Rubinow, "The Movement Toward Unemployment Insurance in Ohio," Social Service Review 7 (1933): 213. When Roosevelt optimistically invited William P. Wrigley of Chicago, who had installed a company unemployment insurance plan, on the advisory committee, the response was a curt and off-putting letter from his secretary. We do not know why, but nevertheless, Wrigley contributed to the Democratic party in 1936. Witte, Development of the Social Security Act, 50; Overacker, "Campaign Funds," 473-98, Berkowitz and McQuaid, Creating the Welfare State, 118; Nelson, Unemployment Insurance, 63.
    • Development of the Social Security Act , pp. 50
    • Witte1
  • 192
    • 0004335542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.M. Rubinow, "The Movement Toward Unemployment Insurance in Ohio," Social Service Review 7 (1933): 213. When Roosevelt optimistically invited William P. Wrigley of Chicago, who had installed a company unemployment insurance plan, on the advisory committee, the response was a curt and off-putting letter from his secretary. We do not know why, but nevertheless, Wrigley contributed to the Democratic party in 1936. Witte, Development of the Social Security Act, 50; Overacker, "Campaign Funds," 473-98, Berkowitz and McQuaid, Creating the Welfare State, 118; Nelson, Unemployment Insurance, 63.
    • Campaign Funds , pp. 473-498
    • Overacker1
  • 193
    • 0004195751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.M. Rubinow, "The Movement Toward Unemployment Insurance in Ohio," Social Service Review 7 (1933): 213. When Roosevelt optimistically invited William P. Wrigley of Chicago, who had installed a company unemployment insurance plan, on the advisory committee, the response was a curt and off-putting letter from his secretary. We do not know why, but nevertheless, Wrigley contributed to the Democratic party in 1936. Witte, Development of the Social Security Act, 50; Overacker, "Campaign Funds," 473-98, Berkowitz and McQuaid, Creating the Welfare State, 118; Nelson, Unemployment Insurance, 63.
    • Creating the Welfare State , pp. 118
    • Berkowitz1    McQuaid2
  • 194
    • 0010807554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I.M. Rubinow, "The Movement Toward Unemployment Insurance in Ohio," Social Service Review 7 (1933): 213. When Roosevelt optimistically invited William P. Wrigley of Chicago, who had installed a company unemployment insurance plan, on the advisory committee, the response was a curt and off-putting letter from his secretary. We do not know why, but nevertheless, Wrigley contributed to the Democratic party in 1936. Witte, Development of the Social Security Act, 50; Overacker, "Campaign Funds," 473-98, Berkowitz and McQuaid, Creating the Welfare State, 118; Nelson, Unemployment Insurance, 63.
    • Unemployment Insurance , pp. 63
    • Nelson1
  • 195
    • 0010777940 scopus 로고
    • Chamber distorts voice of business
    • 4 May
    • "Chamber Distorts Voice of Business," New York Times, 4 May 1935; Raymond Moley, "Misrepresenting American Business," Today, 11 May 1935, 12-13; Folsom, "Millions of Workers Still Lack Adequate Benefits," in Business and Social Progress: Views of Two Generations of Executives, ed. Clarence C. Walton (New York: Praeger, 1970), 99.
    • (1935) New York Times
  • 196
    • 0010844185 scopus 로고
    • Misrepresenting American business
    • 11 May
    • "Chamber Distorts Voice of Business," New York Times, 4 May 1935; Raymond Moley, "Misrepresenting American Business," Today, 11 May 1935, 12-13; Folsom, "Millions of Workers Still Lack Adequate Benefits," in Business and Social Progress: Views of Two Generations of Executives, ed. Clarence C. Walton (New York: Praeger, 1970), 99.
    • (1935) Today , pp. 12-13
    • Moley, R.1
  • 197
    • 4043182121 scopus 로고
    • Millions of workers still lack adequate benefits
    • ed. Clarence C. Walton (New York: Praeger)
    • "Chamber Distorts Voice of Business," New York Times, 4 May 1935; Raymond Moley, "Misrepresenting American Business," Today, 11 May 1935, 12-13; Folsom, "Millions of Workers Still Lack Adequate Benefits," in Business and Social Progress: Views of Two Generations of Executives, ed. Clarence C. Walton (New York: Praeger, 1970), 99.
    • (1970) Business and Social Progress: Views of Two Generations of Executives , pp. 99
    • Folsom1
  • 199
    • 4043182123 scopus 로고
    • The Wisconsin unemployment reserves and compensation system
    • New York: American Management Association
    • See for example H. W. Story, "The Wisconsin Unemployment Reserves and Compensation System," in Pooled Versus Reserve funds for Unemployment Compensation (New York: American Management Association, 1935), 10-13. Story was vice president for Allis-Chalmers, a major Wisconsin manufacturer. See also Daniel Nelson, Unemployment Insurance: The American Experience 1915-1935 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1969), 120, 124, 128.
    • (1935) Pooled Versus Reserve Funds for Unemployment Compensation , pp. 10-13
    • Story, H.W.1
  • 200
    • 0003612656 scopus 로고
    • Madison: University of Wisconsin Press
    • See for example H. W. Story, "The Wisconsin Unemployment Reserves and Compensation System," in Pooled Versus Reserve funds for Unemployment Compensation (New York: American Management Association, 1935), 10-13. Story was vice president for Allis-Chalmers, a major Wisconsin manufacturer. See also Daniel Nelson, Unemployment Insurance: The American Experience 1915-1935 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1969), 120, 124, 128.
    • (1969) Unemployment Insurance: The American Experience 1915-1935 , pp. 120
    • Nelson, D.1
  • 201
    • 4043061632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hacker and Pierson diminish the importance of Domhoff's revealing research on the IRC, relied on here, by mistakenly calling his claims "conspiratorial." Unfortunately, they pay no attention to the strategic element in the personnel choices that no one else but Domhoff has so excellently illuminated. Hacker and Pierson, "Business Power and Social Policy," 307-8.
    • Business Power and Social Policy , pp. 307-308
    • Hacker1    Pierson2
  • 206
    • 4043150886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mudd Library, Princeton University
    • The other companies included U.S. Steel, Socony-Vacuum, Du Pont, U.S. Rubber, Union Carbide, Western Electric, and "a number of others." Brown to Witte, 13 Feb. 1935 and 23 Feb. 1935. J. Douglas Brown Papers, Mudd Library, Princeton University. See also Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance?, esp. 167-69, for evidence of big employers' views on the Clark option.
    • J. Douglas Brown Papers
  • 207
    • 0003425351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The other companies included U.S. Steel, Socony-Vacuum, Du Pont, U.S. Rubber, Union Carbide, Western Electric, and "a number of others." Brown to Witte, 13 Feb. 1935 and 23 Feb. 1935. J. Douglas Brown Papers, Mudd Library, Princeton University. See also Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance?, esp. 167-69, for evidence of big employers' views on the Clark option.
    • State Autonomy or Class Dominance? , pp. 167-169
    • Domhoff1
  • 208
    • 4043135336 scopus 로고
    • 1 Feb. (document generously provided to author by G. William Domhoff)
    • Industrial Relations Counselors, Inc., "Company Pension Plans and the Economic Security Bill," 1 Feb. 1935 (document generously provided to author by G. William Domhoff).
    • (1935) Company Pension Plans and the Economic Security Bill
  • 209
    • 4043135335 scopus 로고
    • J. Douglas Brown to Murray Latimer, 12 Aug. George Washington University Library, Washington D.C
    • J. Douglas Brown to Murray Latimer, 12 Aug. 1935. Murray Latimer Collection, George Washington University Library, Washington D.C.
    • (1935) Murray Latimer Collection
  • 211
    • 4043169319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a letter to Latimer, Brown asks him how he broke the jam, and "did the attitude of the large corporations affect the decision[?]" (Brown to Latimer, 12 Aug. 1935).
  • 212
    • 4043048905 scopus 로고
    • Aug. 16 (document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff)
    • Brown to Witte, 13 Feb. 1935. Within days after passage the IRC informed its segmentalist clients that "the long debate on this matter was due mainly to a misunderstanding of the issues on the part of some members of Congress and by a few industrial companies, as well as to the pressure from lobbying." Industrial Relations Counselors, "Memorandum to Clients," No. 14, Aug. 16, 1935 (document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff).
    • (1935) Memorandum to Clients , Issue.14
  • 214
    • 4043177869 scopus 로고
    • Company annuity plans and the federal old age benefit plan
    • Folsom, "Company Annuity Plans and the Federal Old Age Benefit Plan," Harvard Business Review 14 (1936): 420. On "lukewarm," see Folsom quote in Robbins, Preliminary Report, 1936 (document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff from Rockefeller Archive Center). The adverse selection problem was already known, before passage of the SSA, by IRC/CES expert Latimer from the IRC. This may help explain Folsom's earlier lukewarmness. Murray Latimer, "Memorandum on Proposed Amendments Permitting Employers with Private Pension Plans to Contract out of the Government System," unpublished CES study, 1935 (www.ssa.gov/history/reports/ces/ces2latimer.l.html) . See also economist Paul Douglas's view that "the competitive advantage of young employees would enable such a firm to undersell competitors with older employees, and thus force the elimination of older employees or their employment only on the condition that they join the federal plan." Rainard Robbins, Preliminary Report, 24.
    • (1936) Harvard Business Review , vol.14 , pp. 420
    • Folsom1
  • 215
    • 4043126922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff from Rockefeller Archive Center
    • Folsom, "Company Annuity Plans and the Federal Old Age Benefit Plan," Harvard Business Review 14 (1936): 420. On "lukewarm," see Folsom quote in Robbins, Preliminary Report, 1936 (document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff from Rockefeller Archive Center). The adverse selection problem was already known, before passage of the SSA, by IRC/CES expert Latimer from the IRC. This may help explain Folsom's earlier lukewarmness. Murray Latimer, "Memorandum on Proposed Amendments Permitting Employers with Private Pension Plans to Contract out of the Government System," unpublished CES study, 1935 (www.ssa.gov/history/reports/ces/ces2latimer.l.html) . See also economist Paul Douglas's view that "the competitive advantage of young employees would enable such a firm to undersell competitors with older employees, and thus force the elimination of older employees or their employment only on the condition that they join the federal plan." Rainard Robbins, Preliminary Report, 24.
    • (1936) Preliminary Report
    • Robbins1
  • 216
    • 84862400011 scopus 로고
    • unpublished CES study
    • Folsom, "Company Annuity Plans and the Federal Old Age Benefit Plan," Harvard Business Review 14 (1936): 420. On "lukewarm," see Folsom quote in Robbins, Preliminary Report, 1936 (document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff from Rockefeller Archive Center). The adverse selection problem was already known, before passage of the SSA, by IRC/CES expert Latimer from the IRC. This may help explain Folsom's earlier lukewarmness. Murray Latimer, "Memorandum on Proposed Amendments Permitting Employers with Private Pension Plans to Contract out of the Government System," unpublished CES study, 1935 (www.ssa.gov/history/reports/ces/ces2latimer.l.html) . See also economist Paul Douglas's view that "the competitive advantage of young employees would enable such a firm to undersell competitors with older employees, and thus force the elimination of older employees or their employment only on the condition that they join the federal plan." Rainard Robbins, Preliminary Report, 24.
    • (1935) Memorandum on Proposed Amendments Permitting Employers with Private Pension Plans to Contract Out of the Government System
    • Latimer, M.1
  • 217
    • 4043126922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Folsom, "Company Annuity Plans and the Federal Old Age Benefit Plan," Harvard Business Review 14 (1936): 420. On "lukewarm," see Folsom quote in Robbins, Preliminary Report, 1936 (document generously supplied by G. William Domhoff from Rockefeller Archive Center). The adverse selection problem was already known, before passage of the SSA, by IRC/CES expert Latimer from the IRC. This may help explain Folsom's earlier lukewarmness. Murray Latimer, "Memorandum on Proposed Amendments Permitting Employers with Private Pension Plans to Contract out of the Government System," unpublished CES study, 1935 (www.ssa.gov/history/reports/ces/ces2latimer.l.html) . See also economist Paul Douglas's view that "the competitive advantage of young employees would enable such a firm to undersell competitors with older employees, and thus force the elimination of older employees or their employment only on the condition that they join the federal plan." Rainard Robbins, Preliminary Report, 24.
    • Preliminary Report , pp. 24
    • Robbins, R.1
  • 218
    • 4043101289 scopus 로고
    • The basic philosophy of the federal old-age security program
    • New York: American Management Association
    • J. Douglas Brown, "The Basic Philosophy of the Federal Old-Age Security Program," in Practical Aspects of Unemployment Insurance and Old-Age Security (New York: American Management Association, 1935), 41.
    • (1935) Practical Aspects of Unemployment Insurance and Old-age Security , pp. 41
    • Brown, J.D.1
  • 219
    • 4043085728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Industrial Relations Counselors
    • Industrial Relations Counselors, "Memorandum to Clients."
    • Memorandum to Clients
  • 220
    • 4043065877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Dimly" because at one point, Hacker and Pierson admit that the regulatory/cost-shifting effects of OAI were "partly anticipated." Unfortunately, they do not indicate what exactly was known, and how partly, in order to explain why the foreknowledge does not partly weaken their argument. They also explain business support for OAI arising because of later tax incentives for voluntary plans. For criticism of the anticipated cross-class alliance argument this is irrelevant; if anything it confirms the importance of cross-class alliances in American social policy. As the logic of negotiated segmentalism or "unionized welfare capitalism" would predict, employers and organized labor have both benefitted from and defended tax expenditures on employment-based private welfare. To put it another way, the advantages of the tax breaks would have been wholly, not partly anticipated when introduced. Cross-class alliance making was an ongoing process. Hacker and Pierson, "Business Power," 310-11.
    • Business Power , pp. 310-311
    • Hacker1    Pierson2
  • 221
    • 0003753260 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press
    • Robert H. Wiebe, Businessmen and Reform: A Study of the Progressive Movement (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962), 48-50; 55-56; Morton Keller, Regulating a New Economy: Public Policy and Economic Change in America 1900-1933 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990), 46-48.
    • (1962) Businessmen and Reform: A Study of the Progressive Movement , pp. 48-50
    • Wiebe, R.H.1
  • 222
  • 226
    • 0004177332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hawley, The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly, 27 (quote), 57-62, 67-68, 79-82, 89-90, 93-95, 101-1, 108-9, 120-21, 124; Himmelberg, Origins of the National Recovery Administration, ix, xv, 3, 48-49.
    • The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly , pp. 27
    • Hawley1
  • 229
    • 0004177332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Material in this and the preceding paragraph is from Hawley, The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly, 26-28; Himmelberg, Origins of the National Recovery Administration, 81-83, 90-93, 111-14, 187, 202.
    • The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly , pp. 26-28
  • 231
    • 0001458898 scopus 로고
    • State capacity and economic intervention in the early new deal
    • It neither weakened the political will to install the NRA; nor can it tidily sum up except in a tautological way what happened afterward. For the "state capacity" argument see Theda Skocpol and Kenneth Finegold, "State Capacity and Economic Intervention in the Early New Deal," Political Science Quarterly 97 (1982): 255-78. For critiques, see Donald Brand, Corporatism and the Rule of Law: A Study of the National Recovery Administration (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1988), 311 , and Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance?, 56-72, 101-16.
    • (1982) Political Science Quarterly , vol.97 , pp. 255-278
    • Skocpol, T.1    Finegold, K.2
  • 232
    • 0011336262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press
    • It neither weakened the political will to install the NRA; nor can it tidily sum up except in a tautological way what happened afterward. For the "state capacity" argument see Theda Skocpol and Kenneth Finegold, "State Capacity and Economic Intervention in the Early New Deal," Political Science Quarterly 97 (1982): 255-78. For critiques, see Donald Brand, Corporatism and the Rule of Law: A Study of the National Recovery Administration (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1988), 311 , and Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance?, 56-72, 101-16.
    • (1988) Corporatism and the Rule of Law: A Study of the National Recovery Administration , pp. 311
    • Brand, D.1
  • 233
    • 0003425351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It neither weakened the political will to install the NRA; nor can it tidily sum up except in a tautological way what happened afterward. For the "state capacity" argument see Theda Skocpol and Kenneth Finegold, "State Capacity and Economic Intervention in the Early New Deal," Political Science Quarterly 97 (1982): 255-78. For critiques, see Donald Brand, Corporatism and the Rule of Law: A Study of the National Recovery Administration (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1988), 311 , and Domhoff, State Autonomy or Class Dominance?, 56-72, 101-16.
    • State Autonomy or Class Dominance? , pp. 56-72
    • Domhoff1
  • 235
    • 0011336262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See especially Brand, Corporatism and the Rule of Law, 175-206; and Bernard Bellush, The Failure of the NRA (New York: Norton, 1975), 55-84.
    • Corporatism and the Rule of Law , pp. 175-206
    • Brand1
  • 236
    • 0040244086 scopus 로고
    • New York: Norton
    • See especially Brand, Corporatism and the Rule of Law, 175-206; and Bernard Bellush, The Failure of the NRA (New York: Norton, 1975), 55-84.
    • (1975) The Failure of the NRA , pp. 55-84
    • Bellush, B.1
  • 239
    • 4043160742 scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press, See also 70, 91, 126-27, 158, 260, and 263 for other references to distributions and balances of power
    • Peter Hall, Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), 231-33, 283. See also 70, 91, 126-27, 158, 260, and 263 for other references to distributions and balances of power.
    • (1986) Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France , pp. 231-233
    • Hall, P.1
  • 242
    • 85033846597 scopus 로고
    • Den solidariska lönepolitikens resultat
    • Stockholm: LO
    • In 1970, Swedish auto workers earned only 110 percent of the average for all manual workers in manufacturing, while their American counterparts earned 126 percent. Add fringe benefits, and the difference is greater. Ingvar Ohlsson, "Den solidariska lönepolitikens resultat," in Lönepolitik och solidaritet - Debattinlägg via Meidnerseminariet 1980 (Stockholm: LO, 1980). On the postNew Deal period, see Howell John Harris, The Right to Manage: Industrial Relations Policies of American Business in the 1940s (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1982), 170; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic, 1995), 297. Anders Kjellgren, Facklig organisationsutvechling i tolv länder (Lund: Arkiv, 1983), 269-319; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 75-76.
    • (1980) Lönepolitik och Solidaritet - Debattinlägg via Meidnerseminariet 1980
    • Ohlsson, I.1
  • 243
    • 0003602458 scopus 로고
    • Madison: University of Wisconsin Press
    • In 1970, Swedish auto workers earned only 110 percent of the average for all manual workers in manufacturing, while their American counterparts earned 126 percent. Add fringe benefits, and the difference is greater. Ingvar Ohlsson, "Den solidariska lönepolitikens resultat," in Lönepolitik och solidaritet - Debattinlägg via Meidnerseminariet 1980 (Stockholm: LO, 1980). On the postNew Deal period, see Howell John Harris, The Right to Manage: Industrial Relations Policies of American Business in the 1940s (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1982), 170; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic, 1995), 297. Anders Kjellgren, Facklig organisationsutvechling i tolv länder (Lund: Arkiv, 1983), 269-319; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 75-76.
    • (1982) The Right to Manage: Industrial Relations Policies of American Business in the 1940s , pp. 170
    • Harris, H.J.1
  • 244
    • 0003787774 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic
    • In 1970, Swedish auto workers earned only 110 percent of the average for all manual workers in manufacturing, while their American counterparts earned 126 percent. Add fringe benefits, and the difference is greater. Ingvar Ohlsson, "Den solidariska lönepolitikens resultat," in Lönepolitik och solidaritet - Debattinlägg via Meidnerseminariet 1980 (Stockholm: LO, 1980). On the postNew Deal period, see Howell John Harris, The Right to Manage: Industrial Relations Policies of American Business in the 1940s (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1982), 170; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic, 1995), 297. Anders Kjellgren, Facklig organisationsutvechling i tolv länder (Lund: Arkiv, 1983), 269-319; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 75-76.
    • (1995) The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and the Fate of American Labor , pp. 297
    • Lichtenstein, N.1
  • 245
    • 84862400382 scopus 로고
    • Lund: Arkiv
    • In 1970, Swedish auto workers earned only 110 percent of the average for all manual workers in manufacturing, while their American counterparts earned 126 percent. Add fringe benefits, and the difference is greater. Ingvar Ohlsson, "Den solidariska lönepolitikens resultat," in Lönepolitik och solidaritet - Debattinlägg via Meidnerseminariet 1980 (Stockholm: LO, 1980). On the postNew Deal period, see Howell John Harris, The Right to Manage: Industrial Relations Policies of American Business in the 1940s (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1982), 170; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic, 1995), 297. Anders Kjellgren, Facklig organisationsutvechling i tolv länder (Lund: Arkiv, 1983), 269-319; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 75-76.
    • (1983) Facklig Organisationsutvechling i Tolv Länder , pp. 269-319
    • Kjellgren, A.1
  • 246
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In 1970, Swedish auto workers earned only 110 percent of the average for all manual workers in manufacturing, while their American counterparts earned 126 percent. Add fringe benefits, and the difference is greater. Ingvar Ohlsson, "Den solidariska lönepolitikens resultat," in Lönepolitik och solidaritet - Debattinlägg via Meidnerseminariet 1980 (Stockholm: LO, 1980). On the postNew Deal period, see Howell John Harris, The Right to Manage: Industrial Relations Policies of American Business in the 1940s (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1982), 170; Nelson Lichtenstein, The Most Dangerous Man in Detroit: Walter Reuther and the Fate of American Labor (New York: Basic, 1995), 297. Anders Kjellgren, Facklig organisationsutvechling i tolv länder (Lund: Arkiv, 1983), 269-319; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 75-76.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 75-76
    • Wenson1
  • 247
    • 84862393695 scopus 로고
    • De svenska arbetsgivarnas organisationsformer
    • draft of an article, Edström collection
    • Axel Brunius, "De svenska arbetsgivarnas organisationsformer," draft of an article for Chalmerska jubileumsskriften, no date (probably 1929), Edström collection, vol. 34 (A14d); SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 28 Feb. 1934; Ivar Larson to Axel Palmgren, IS Feb. 1936, Axel Palmgren papers, Åbo Akademin, Åbo, Finland. On the construction conflict, see Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 100-109.
    • (1929) Chalmerska Jubileumsskriften , vol.34 , Issue.A14D
    • Brunius, A.1
  • 248
    • 4043063060 scopus 로고
    • SAF, Minutes, 28 Feb
    • Axel Brunius, "De svenska arbetsgivarnas organisationsformer," draft of an article for Chalmerska jubileumsskriften, no date (probably 1929), Edström collection, vol. 34 (A14d); SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 28 Feb. 1934;
    • (1934) Styrelse
  • 249
    • 0010524222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Axel Brunius, "De svenska arbetsgivarnas organisationsformer," draft of an article for Chalmerska jubileumsskriften, no date (probably 1929), Edström collection, vol. 34 (A14d); SAF, Minutes, Styrelse, 28 Feb. 1934; Ivar Larson to Axel Palmgren, IS Feb. 1936, Axel Palmgren papers, Åbo Akademin, Åbo, Finland. On the construction conflict, see Swenson, Capitalists against Markets, 100-109.
    • Capitalists Against Markets , pp. 100-109
    • Swenson1
  • 250
    • 84862394421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • VF, Minutes, Extra allmänt möte, 21 Feb. 1920; Hjalmar von Sydow to Axel Palmgren, 17 Dec. 1927, Åbo Akademin, Åbo, Finland;
    • VF, Minutes, Extra allmänt möte, 21 Feb. 1920; Hjalmar von Sydow to Axel Palmgren, 17 Dec. 1927, Palmgren collection, vol. 7, Åbo Akademin, Åbo, Finland; "P.M. rörande oorganiserade arbetares förhållande under arbetskonflikt," Dec. 1934 [SAF-A555/20b]; Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand, Örjan Armfelt-Hansell and Arne Törnqvist, Sågverksförbundet 1907-1957 (Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1962), 240.
    • Palmgren Collection , vol.7
  • 251
    • 84862397170 scopus 로고
    • Dec. [SAF-A555/20b]
    • VF, Minutes, Extra allmänt möte, 21 Feb. 1920; Hjalmar von Sydow to Axel Palmgren, 17 Dec. 1927, Palmgren collection, vol. 7, Åbo Akademin, Åbo, Finland; "P.M. rörande oorganiserade arbetares förhållande under arbetskonflikt," Dec. 1934 [SAF-A555/20b]; Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand, Örjan Armfelt-Hansell and Arne Törnqvist, Sågverksförbundet 1907-1957 (Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1962), 240.
    • (1934) P.M. Rörande Oorganiserade Arbetares Förhållande under Arbetskonflikt
  • 252
    • 84862405137 scopus 로고
    • Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell
    • VF, Minutes, Extra allmänt möte, 21 Feb. 1920; Hjalmar von Sydow to Axel Palmgren, 17 Dec. 1927, Palmgren collection, vol. 7, Åbo Akademin, Åbo, Finland; "P.M. rörande oorganiserade arbetares förhållande under arbetskonflikt," Dec. 1934 [SAF-A555/20b]; Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand, Örjan Armfelt-Hansell and Arne Törnqvist, Sågverksförbundet 1907-1957 (Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1962), 240.
    • (1962) Sågverksförbundet 1907-1957 , pp. 240
    • Hildebrand, K.-G.1    Armfelt-Hansell, Ö.2    Törnqvist, A.3
  • 253
    • 4043153647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This conclusion applies to the major pension reform of 1959 as well. Employers, despite initial strong opposition, turned out to be happy with the final form the legislation took. See Swenson, Labor Markets and Welfare States, 281-92.
    • Labor Markets and Welfare States , pp. 281-292
    • Swenson1
  • 254
    • 0001902793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An introduction to varieties of capitalism
    • Hall and Soskice eds., (Oxford: Oxford University Press)
    • See Peter Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 1-68, and an extension of the "Varieties" analysis in Estevez-Abe, Iversen, and Soskice, "Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State."
    • (2001) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage , pp. 1-68
    • Hall, P.1    Soskice, D.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.