메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 12, Issue 4, 2000, Pages 417-444

The Institutional Foundation of U.S. Trade Policy: Revisiting Explanations for the 1934 Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 85011513708     PISSN: 08980306     EISSN: 15284190     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1353/jph.2000.0032     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (31)

References (70)
  • 1
    • 84984739566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Politics Matter: The 1997 Derailment of Fast-Track Trade Authority
    • The RTAA gave the President authority to alter tariff duties up to 50 percent of rates set under the 1930 Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act (United States Statutes at Large, 73d Congress, Sess. II, CH. 474: 943-46). It was renewed thirteen times between 1934 and 1962. The 1962 Trade Act altered the mechanism of the delegation so that it more closely resembled fast-track negotiating authority (officially adopted in 1974) in which Congress grants the authority for a President to commence negotiation of a trade agreement, and then Congress takes a simple yea/nay vote when the negotiation is concluded. In November 1997, Congress denied President Bill Clinton fast-track negotiating authority—the first time this authority has been denied to a President requesting it since Roosevelt.
    • The RTAA gave the President authority to alter tariff duties up to 50 percent of rates set under the 1930 Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act (United States Statutes at Large, 73d Congress, Sess. II, CH. 474: 943-46). It was renewed thirteen times between 1934 and 1962. The 1962 Trade Act altered the mechanism of the delegation so that it more closely resembled fast-track negotiating authority (officially adopted in 1974) in which Congress grants the authority for a President to commence negotiation of a trade agreement, and then Congress takes a simple yea/nay vote when the negotiation is concluded. In November 1997, Congress denied President Bill Clinton fast-track negotiating authority—the first time this authority has been denied to a President requesting it since Roosevelt. Karen Schnietz and Timothy Nieman, “Politics Matter: The 1997 Derailment of Fast-Track Trade Authority,” Business and Politics 1 (1999): 233-51.
    • (1999) Business and Politics , vol.1 , pp. 233-251
    • Schnietz, K.1    Nieman, T.2
  • 2
    • 85022366253 scopus 로고
    • (Washington, D.C. 73d Cong. 2d sess.):. New York Times, 1 March 1934, 1.
    • Congressional Record 78 (Washington, D.C. 73d Cong. 2d sess. 1934): 5614. New York Times, 1 March 1934, 1.
    • (1934) Congressional Record 78 , pp. 5614
  • 3
    • 85022413001 scopus 로고
    • Other explanations are not addressed in this article. First, the “deflection” thesis maintains that Congress wanted to divert protectionist pressure from itself because interest-group lobbying had become intolerable. (New York)
    • Other explanations are not addressed in this article. First, the “deflection” thesis maintains that Congress wanted to divert protectionist pressure from itself because interest-group lobbying had become intolerable. Raymond Bauer, Ithiel de Sola Pool, and Lewis Dexter, American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade (New York, 1963)
    • (1963) American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade
    • Bauer, R.1    de Sola Pool, I.2    Dexter, L.3
  • 5
    • 0024812901 scopus 로고
    • Domestic Political Preconditions of U.S. Trade Policy
    • However, Republicans, as the party of high tariffs, were exposed to the greatest political pressure in this area, but they were not the party that proposed or supported the delegation. Moreover, this explanation implies that Congress should delegate all but the most trivial policy obligations, which it clearly has not. Second, the “ideological” explanation maintains that Secretary of State Hull influenced political institutions and the political elite with his trade liberalism.
    • Douglas Nelson, “Domestic Political Preconditions of U.S. Trade Policy,” Journal of Public Policy 9 (1986): 83-108. However, Republicans, as the party of high tariffs, were exposed to the greatest political pressure in this area, but they were not the party that proposed or supported the delegation. Moreover, this explanation implies that Congress should delegate all but the most trivial policy obligations, which it clearly has not. Second, the “ideological” explanation maintains that Secretary of State Hull influenced political institutions and the political elite with his trade liberalism.
    • (1986) Journal of Public Policy , vol.9 , pp. 83-108
    • Nelson, D.1
  • 6
    • 84971840228 scopus 로고
    • The Impact of Ideas on Trade Policy: The Origins of U.S. Agricultural and Manufacturing Policies
    • Judith Goldstein, “The Impact of Ideas on Trade Policy: The Origins of U.S. Agricultural and Manufacturing Policies,” International Organization 43 (1989): 31-72.
    • (1989) International Organization , vol.43 , pp. 31-72
    • Goldstein, J.1
  • 7
    • 85022410658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, Hull's freetrade bias was at least partially shaped by his experience as a Democratic congressman, and many legislators shared it. Relatedly, the “Hull did it” explanation focuses on Hull's pivotal role in persuading Roosevelt to submit the RTAA to Congress. (Kent, Ohio)
    • However, Hull's freetrade bias was at least partially shaped by his experience as a Democratic congressman, and many legislators shared it. Relatedly, the “Hull did it” explanation focuses on Hull's pivotal role in persuading Roosevelt to submit the RTAA to Congress. Michael Butler, Cautious Visionary: Cordell Hull and Trade Reform, 1933-1937 (Kent, Ohio, 1998)
    • (1998) Cautious Visionary: Cordell Hull and Trade Reform, 1933-1937
    • Butler, M.1
  • 13
    • 85022409919 scopus 로고
    • (Boston). Although Hull exercised critical influence on Roosevelt, this thesis fails to describe why congressional Democrats supported such a large delegation of policymaking authority to the President.
    • Arthur Schlesinger Jr. The Coming of the New Deal (Boston, 1957). Although Hull exercised critical influence on Roosevelt, this thesis fails to describe why congressional Democrats supported such a large delegation of policymaking authority to the President.
    • (1957) The Coming of the New Deal
    • Schlesinger, A.1
  • 14
    • 85022377702 scopus 로고
    • Under the 1828 Tariff of Abominations, the average tariff rate on dutiable goods rose to 61.7 percent. (Washington, D.C. 73d Cong. 2d sess.)
    • Under the 1828 Tariff of Abominations, the average tariff rate on dutiable goods rose to 61.7 percent. U.S. Census Bureau, Historical Statistics of the United States 78 (Washington, D.C. 73d Cong. 2d sess. 1934), 888.
    • (1934) Historical Statistics of the United States , vol.78 , pp. 888
  • 15
    • 84976179289 scopus 로고
    • Revisiting Smoot- Hawley
    • See the following challenges to the prevailing wisdom that the Smoot-Hawley Tariff was the highest U.S. tariff ever:, :, and
    • See the following challenges to the prevailing wisdom that the Smoot-Hawley Tariff was the highest U.S. tariff ever: Alfred Eckes, “Revisiting Smoot- Hawley,” Journal of Policy History 7 (1995): 295-310, and
    • (1995) Journal of Policy History , vol.7 , pp. 295-310
    • Eckes, A.1
  • 16
    • 0040344700 scopus 로고
    • Effective Rates of Protection and the Fordney-McCumber and Smoot-Hawley Tariff Acts
    • Marc Hayford and Carl Pasurka Jr. “Effective Rates of Protection and the Fordney-McCumber and Smoot-Hawley Tariff Acts,” Applied Economics 23 (1991): 1385-92.
    • (1991) Applied Economics , vol.23 , pp. 1385-1392
    • Hayford, M.1    Pasurka, C.2
  • 19
    • 0032275503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Smoot-Hawley Tariff: A Quantitative Assessment
    • Douglas Irwin estimates that a quarter of the 40 percent decline in imports following the Smoot-Hawley Tariff can be attributed to the combination of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff rates and deflation.
    • Douglas Irwin estimates that a quarter of the 40 percent decline in imports following the Smoot-Hawley Tariff can be attributed to the combination of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff rates and deflation. “The Smoot-Hawley Tariff: A Quantitative Assessment,” Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (1998): 326-34.
    • (1998) Review of Economics and Statistics , vol.80 , pp. 326-334
  • 20
    • 49549131607 scopus 로고
    • Monetary and Other Explanations of the Start of the Great Depression
    • Allan Meltzer, “Monetary and Other Explanations of the Start of the Great Depression,” Journal of Monetary Economics 2 (1976): 455-71.
    • (1976) Journal of Monetary Economics , vol.2 , pp. 455-471
    • Meltzer, A.1
  • 21
    • 0002535899 scopus 로고
    • The Open Economy: Implications for Monetary and Fiscal Policy
    • However, there is disagreement over the “true” economic consequences of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff. See, in, ed. Robert Gordon (Chicago), and
    • However, there is disagreement over the “true” economic consequences of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff. See Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley Fisher, “The Open Economy: Implications for Monetary and Fiscal Policy,” in The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, ed. Robert Gordon (Chicago, 1986), and
    • (1986) The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change
    • Dornbusch, R.1    Fisher, S.2
  • 22
    • 0011519864 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff
    • in, ed. Roger Ransom (Connecticut).
    • Barry Eichengreen, “The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff,” in Research in Economic History, vol. 12, ed. Roger Ransom (Connecticut, 1989): 1-43.
    • (1989) Research in Economic History , vol.12 , pp. 1-43
    • Eichengreen, B.1
  • 26
    • 84929067976 scopus 로고
    • Interests or Institutions: An Inquiry into Congressional-ITC Relations
    • Judith Goldstein and Stefanie Lenway, “Interests or Institutions: An Inquiry into Congressional-ITC Relations,” International Studies Quarterly 33 (1989): 303-27
    • (1989) International Studies Quarterly , vol.33 , pp. 303-327
    • Goldstein, J.1    Lenway, S.2
  • 27
    • 0001494982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Negotiations, Information, and Domestic Politics: The Role of Domestic Groups
    • Helen Milner and B. Peter Rosendorff, “Trade Negotiations, Information, and Domestic Politics: The Role of Domestic Groups, Economics and Politics 8 (1996): 145-89
    • (1996) Economics and Politics , vol.8 , pp. 145-189
    • Milner, H.1    Peter Rosendorff, B.2
  • 31
    • 33644898282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Political Economy in the Gilded Age: The Republican Party's Industrial Policy
    • On the intense partisanship of tariff politics, see
    • On the intense partisanship of tariff politics, see Charles Calhoun, “Political Economy in the Gilded Age: The Republican Party's Industrial Policy,” Journal of Policy History 8 (1996): 291-309
    • (1996) Journal of Policy History , vol.8 , pp. 291-309
    • Calhoun, C.1
  • 32
    • 0030534499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Partisan Paradox and the U.S. Tariff, 1877-1934
    • and
    • David Epstein and Sharyn O’Halloran, “The Partisan Paradox and the U.S. Tariff, 1877-1934,” International Organization 50 (1996): 301-24; and
    • (1996) International Organization , vol.50 , pp. 301-324
    • Epstein, D.1    O’Halloran, S.2
  • 34
    • 0039904483 scopus 로고
    • The Changing Nature of U.S. Trade Policy since WWII
    • in, ed. Robert Baldwin and Anne Krueger (Chicago)
    • Robert Baldwin, “The Changing Nature of U.S. Trade Policy since WWII,” in Structure and Evolution of Recent U.S. Trade Policy, ed. Robert Baldwin and Anne Krueger (Chicago, 1984)
    • (1984) Structure and Evolution of Recent U.S. Trade Policy
    • Baldwin, R.1
  • 37
    • 84972370292 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934
    • and
    • Stephan Haggard, “The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934,” International Organization 42 (1988): 91-119; and
    • (1988) International Organization , vol.42 , pp. 91-119
    • Haggard, S.1
  • 38
    • 85022416522 scopus 로고
    • The Politics of U.S. International Trade: Protection
    • (Boston).
    • Stefanie Lenway, The Politics of U.S. International Trade: Protection, Expansion, and Escape (Boston, 1985).
    • (1985) Expansion, and Escape
  • 39
    • 84970189566 scopus 로고
    • Trade Policy as Foreign Policy
    • in, ed. Robert Stern (Cambridge, Mass.) and
    • Richard Cooper, “Trade Policy as Foreign Policy,” in U.S. Trade Policies in a Changing World Economy, ed. Robert Stern (Cambridge, Mass. 1987) and
    • (1987) U.S. Trade Policies in a Changing World Economy
    • Cooper, R.1
  • 40
    • 84972091498 scopus 로고
    • State Power and the Structure of International Trade
    • Stephen Krasner, “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics 28 (1976): 317-47.
    • (1976) World Politics , vol.28 , pp. 317-347
    • Krasner, S.1
  • 42
    • 85022357475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Today (independent national weekly published in New York by Vincent Astor), in the Herbert Feis Papers, Library of Congress, Manuscript Division, container 21 (with documents primarily from 1934). Hereafter Feis Papers.
    • Undated article, “Toward a Democratic Tariff Policy,” Today (independent national weekly published in New York by Vincent Astor), in the Herbert Feis Papers, Library of Congress, Manuscript Division, container 21 (with documents primarily from 1934). Hereafter Feis Papers.
    • Toward a Democratic Tariff Policy
    • article, U.1
  • 43
    • 85022438114 scopus 로고
    • Hull did not serve in the 67th Congress, having been narrowly defeated by his Republican opponent in the 1920 election. Hull served on the Pensions and Civil Service Reform Committees during his first two terms as congressman, but thereafter served only on Ways and Means, indicating how salient tariff issues were to him. (New York)
    • Hull did not serve in the 67th Congress, having been narrowly defeated by his Republican opponent in the 1920 election. Hull served on the Pensions and Civil Service Reform Committees during his first two terms as congressman, but thereafter served only on Ways and Means, indicating how salient tariff issues were to him. As Hull noted in his Memoirs (New York, 1948): 89
    • (1948) As Hull noted in his Memoirs , pp. 89
  • 44
    • 72449206503 scopus 로고
    • The International Trade Philosophy of Cordell Hull, 1907-1933
    • “I [have] devoted my life to a close study of tariffs, revenue, finance and economics.” See also.
    • “I [have] devoted my life to a close study of tariffs, revenue, finance and economics.” See also William Allen, “The International Trade Philosophy of Cordell Hull, 1907-1933,” American Economic Review 43 (1953): 107.
    • (1953) American Economic Review , vol.43 , pp. 107
    • Allen, W.1
  • 45
    • 0039312227 scopus 로고
    • For accounts of the 1913 federal income tax and the 1916 Tariff Commission, see
    • For accounts of the 1913 federal income tax and the 1916 Tariff Commission, see Hull, Memoirs (1948)
    • (1948) Memoirs
    • Hull1
  • 48
    • 0040633742 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democrats' 1916 Tariff Commission: Responding to Dumping Fears and Illustrating the Consumer Costs of Protectionism
    • and
    • Karen Schnietz, “Democrats' 1916 Tariff Commission: Responding to Dumping Fears and Illustrating the Consumer Costs of Protectionism,” Business History Review 72 (1998): 1-46; and
    • (1998) Business History Review , vol.72 , pp. 1-46
    • Schnietz, K.1
  • 51
    • 0040062805 scopus 로고
    • New York Times, 30 December 1933, 3. Few historians have sought to explain the cause of Roosevelt's transformation on the RTAA; indeed, in many accounts, the first attempt at passing the RTAA is more extensively discussed than the second, successful attempt. For instance, (New York)
    • New York Times, 30 December 1933, 3. Few historians have sought to explain the cause of Roosevelt's transformation on the RTAA; indeed, in many accounts, the first attempt at passing the RTAA is more extensively discussed than the second, successful attempt. For instance, Kenneth Davis, FDR: The New Deal Years, 1933-37 (New York, 1986)
    • (1986) FDR: The New Deal Years, 1933-37
    • Davis, K.1
  • 57
    • 84963069213 scopus 로고
    • Protection and Real Wages
    • There are four welfare effects associated with a tariff: (1) the transfer of consumer surplus to protected domestic producers in the form of higher prices; (2) the transfer of consumer and foreign producer surpluses to the government in the form of the tariff duty; (3) the consumer surplus lost through inefficient domestic production; and (4) the consumer loss associated with having less supply of the dutied product than would exist under free trade.
    • There are four welfare effects associated with a tariff: (1) the transfer of consumer surplus to protected domestic producers in the form of higher prices; (2) the transfer of consumer and foreign producer surpluses to the government in the form of the tariff duty; (3) the consumer surplus lost through inefficient domestic production; and (4) the consumer loss associated with having less supply of the dutied product than would exist under free trade. Wolfgang Stolper and Paul Samuelson, “Protection and Real Wages,” Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 58.
    • (1941) Review of Economic Studies , vol.9 , pp. 58
    • Stolper, W.1    Samuelson, P.2
  • 61
    • 3042640988 scopus 로고
    • (Washington, D.C.).
    • U.S. Tariff Commission, The Tariff and Its History (Washington, D.C. 1934).
    • (1934) The Tariff and Its History
  • 62
    • 85022359805 scopus 로고
    • The difference in electoral constituencies for the President and members of Congress yields systematic differences in their policy preferences. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.)
    • The difference in electoral constituencies for the President and members of Congress yields systematic differences in their policy preferences. James Burns, The Deadlock of Democracy (Englewood Cliffs, N.J. 1963)
    • (1963) The Deadlock of Democracy
    • Burns, J.1
  • 63
    • 0000239162 scopus 로고
    • Political Institutions: The Neglected Side of the Story
    • and
    • Terry Moe, “Political Institutions: The Neglected Side of the Story,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 6 (1990): 213-53; and
    • (1990) Journal of Law, Economics and Organization , vol.6 , pp. 213-253
    • Moe, T.1
  • 64
    • 0019679509 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics
    • Barry Weingast, Kenneth Shepsle, and Christopher Johnsen, “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics,” Journal of Political Economy 89 (1981): 642-64.
    • (1981) Journal of Political Economy , vol.89 , pp. 642-664
    • Weingast, B.1    Shepsle, K.2    Johnsen, C.3
  • 65
    • 34247166414 scopus 로고
    • For a formal demonstration of how Presidentially-led tariff-setting resulted in lower tariffs, see, Ph.D. dissertation (University of California Berkeley).
    • For a formal demonstration of how Presidentially-led tariff-setting resulted in lower tariffs, see Karen Schnietz, “To Delegate or Not to Delegate: Institutional Choices in the Regulation of Foreign Trade, 1916-1934,” Ph.D. dissertation (University of California Berkeley, 1994).
    • (1994) To Delegate or Not to Delegate: Institutional Choices in the Regulation of Foreign Trade, 1916-1934
    • Schnietz, K.1
  • 66
    • 85022421770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Today article
    • Feis Papers, container 21.
    • Today article, “Toward a Democratic Tariff Policy,” Feis Papers, container 21.
    • Toward a Democratic Tariff Policy
  • 67
    • 0003507560 scopus 로고
    • William Stone in Finance Hearings, 285 and 283. Similarly, see 6 March 1934 letter from J. Belger to Rep. R. Doughton (D-N.C.), Ways & Means Papers, container 185. For a formal articulation of how the RTAA eliminated logrolling, see, (Ann Arbor).
    • William Stone in Finance Hearings, 285 and 283. Similarly, see 6 March 1934 letter from J. Belger to Rep. R. Doughton (D-N.C.), Ways & Means Papers, container 185. For a formal articulation of how the RTAA eliminated logrolling, see Sharyn O’Halloran, Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy (Ann Arbor, 1994).
    • (1994) Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy
    • O’Halloran, S.1
  • 68
    • 0003950875 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empirical support has been offered for this analysis. Although legislators did not take into account the export dependence of their districts in votes on tariff-policy prior to the RTAA, they did do so after the RTAA. (Ann Arbor).
    • Empirical support has been offered for this analysis. Although legislators did not take into account the export dependence of their districts in votes on tariff-policy prior to the RTAA, they did do so after the RTAA. Michael Gilligan, Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective Action in American Trade Policy (Ann Arbor, 1997).
    • (1997) Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective Action in American Trade Policy
    • Gilligan, M.1
  • 69
    • 0030823816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Roots of American Trade Policy: Politics, Coalitions and International Trade
    • Similarly, districtlevel export-dependence, more than partisanship, affected voting behavior on several trade bills in 1953 and 1962.
    • Similarly, districtlevel export-dependence, more than partisanship, affected voting behavior on several trade bills in 1953 and 1962. Michael Bailey, Barry Weingast, and Judy Goldstein, “The Institutional Roots of American Trade Policy: Politics, Coalitions and International Trade,” World Politics 49 (1998): 309-38.
    • (1998) World Politics , vol.49 , pp. 309-338
    • Bailey, M.1    Weingast, B.2    Goldstein, J.3
  • 70
    • 85022413064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition, empirical evidence has been offered to show that private interests understood how fundamentally the RTAA would alter trade policy outcomes; investors in firms heavily dependent on export sales in 1934 bid up the stock prices of those firms significantly following news of the RTAA's likely passage. Working Paper, Rice University.
    • In addition, empirical evidence has been offered to show that private interests understood how fundamentally the RTAA would alter trade policy outcomes; investors in firms heavily dependent on export sales in 1934 bid up the stock prices of those firms significantly following news of the RTAA's likely passage. Karen Schnietz, “Investor Response to Trade Regulatory Change: The 1934 Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act,” Working Paper, Rice University.
    • Investor Response to Trade Regulatory Change: The 1934 Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act
    • Schnietz, K.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.