메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 49, Issue 3, 1997, Pages 309-338

The institutional roots of American trade policy : Politics, coalitions, and international trade

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE; POLICY MAKING; RECIPROCAL TRADE AGREEMENTS ACT (1934); TRADE POLICY;

EID: 0030823816     PISSN: 00438871     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1353/wp.1997.0007     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (211)

References (52)
  • 1
    • 0003592616 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: Aldine-Atherton
    • Raymond Bauer, Ithiel de Sola Pool, and Lewis Dexter, American Business and Public Policy, 2d ed. (Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1972), 14; Douglas Nelson, "Domestic Political Preconditions of U.S. Trade Policy: Liberal Structure and Protectionist Dynamics," Journal of Public Policy 9 (January-April 1986).
    • (1972) American Business and Public Policy, 2d Ed. , pp. 14
    • Bauer, R.1    De Sola Pool, I.2    Dexter, L.3
  • 2
    • 0024812901 scopus 로고
    • Domestic Political Preconditions of U.S. Trade Policy: Liberal Structure and Protectionist Dynamics
    • January-April
    • Raymond Bauer, Ithiel de Sola Pool, and Lewis Dexter, American Business and Public Policy, 2d ed. (Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1972), 14; Douglas Nelson, "Domestic Political Preconditions of U.S. Trade Policy: Liberal Structure and Protectionist Dynamics," Journal of Public Policy 9 (January-April 1986).
    • (1986) Journal of Public Policy , vol.9
    • Nelson, D.1
  • 5
    • 0004256642 scopus 로고
    • Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics
    • I. M. Destler, American Trade Politics, 2d ed. (Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1994), 14. See also Robert Baldwin, The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1985); and Robert Pastor, Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980).
    • (1994) American Trade Politics, 2d Ed. , pp. 14
    • Destler, I.M.1
  • 6
    • 84936174635 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: MIT Press
    • I. M. Destler, American Trade Politics, 2d ed. (Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1994), 14. See also Robert Baldwin, The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1985); and Robert Pastor, Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980).
    • (1985) The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy
    • Baldwin, R.1
  • 7
    • 85033299967 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • I. M. Destler, American Trade Politics, 2d ed. (Washington D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1994), 14. See also Robert Baldwin, The Political Economy of U.S. Import Policy (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1985); and Robert Pastor, Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980).
    • (1980) Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy
    • Pastor, R.1
  • 8
    • 85033320300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Destler (fn. 4), 71
    • See, for example, Destler (fn. 4), 71.
  • 9
    • 0039801230 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934
    • G. John Ikenberry, David Lake, and Michael Mastanduno, eds., Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
    • Stephan Haggard, "The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934," in G. John Ikenberry, David Lake, and Michael Mastanduno, eds., The State and American Foreign Economic Policy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1988), 113.
    • (1988) The State and American Foreign Economic Policy , pp. 113
    • Haggard, S.1
  • 10
    • 85033312719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schnietz (fn. 3), 129
    • Schnietz (fn. 3), 129.
  • 11
    • 84973939734 scopus 로고
    • From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression
    • Winter
    • Ibid., 128-32. For a third thesis, see Thomas Ferguson, "From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International! Organization 38 (Winter 1984). He argues that the New Deal coalition was not one of workers, poor, and minorities, but one of capital-intensive industries, investment banks, and internationally oriented commercial banks. Haggard offers a persuasive critique. First, Ferguson writes that this new coalition congealed "by 1938"; it was not clear that it was a powerful force in 1934 when the New Deal was clearly hostile to capital, pushing policies such as the NIRA. Second, Ferguson studies the preferences of one block to explain outcomes, ignoring other actors; see Haggard (fn. 6), 98.
    • (1984) International! Organization , vol.38
    • Ferguson, T.1
  • 12
    • 0003673460 scopus 로고
    • Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, Pastor (fn. 4)
    • For a more complete review of congressional policy, see Judith Goldstein, Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993); Pastor (fn. 4); John Evans, The Kennedy Round in American Trade Policy (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971); Ernest Preeg, Traders and Diplomats (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1973).
    • (1993) Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy
    • Goldstein, J.1
  • 13
    • 0040964455 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Harvard University Press
    • For a more complete review of congressional policy, see Judith Goldstein, Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993); Pastor (fn. 4); John Evans, The Kennedy Round in American Trade Policy (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971); Ernest Preeg, Traders and Diplomats (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1973).
    • (1971) The Kennedy Round in American Trade Policy
    • Evans, J.1
  • 14
    • 0007347776 scopus 로고
    • Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution
    • For a more complete review of congressional policy, see Judith Goldstein, Ideas, Interests, and American Trade Policy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993); Pastor (fn. 4); John Evans, The Kennedy Round in American Trade Policy (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971); Ernest Preeg, Traders and Diplomats (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1973).
    • (1973) Traders and Diplomats
    • Preeg, E.1
  • 16
    • 85033319055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bauer, Pool, and Dexter (fn. 1), 33; Pastor (fn. 4), 101
    • Bauer, Pool, and Dexter (fn. 1), 33; Pastor (fn. 4), 101.
  • 17
    • 85033289582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Haggard (fn. 6), 91
    • Haggard (fn. 6), 91.
  • 18
    • 0003507560 scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • Reciprocity in trade legislation had a long history before the RTAA. The first explicitly reciprocal treaty was with the German Zollverein in 1844. (It was rejected by the Senate.) Many of the previous measures on trade contained provisions for reciprocal agreements, but none was nearly as broad as the RTAA. See Goldstein (fn. 9), 93; and Sharyn O'Halloran, Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994).
    • (1994) Politics, Process, and American Trade Policy
    • O'Halloran, S.1
  • 19
    • 85033288161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consistent with section 317 of the 1922 Fordney-McCumber Act, concessions granted any one country would be generalized to all others receiving most-favored-nation status.
  • 20
    • 85033278280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Haggard (fn. 6), 106-7
    • Haggard (fn. 6), 106-7.
  • 21
    • 0039312227 scopus 로고
    • New York: Macmillan
    • See Cordell Hull, Memoirs (New York: Macmillan, 1948), 353; Goldstein (fn. 9), 154-58; and Haggard (fn. 6), 97. The clash between free traders such as Secretary of State Hull and protectionists led Moley to comment that "nothing which we have been dealing with has been subject to such wide differences of opinion"; Goldstein (fn. 9), 142. By 1935 Moley was an outspoken critic of the administration's trade policy. See Arthur Schatz, "Cordell Hull and the Struggle for the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Program, 1932-1940" (Ph.D. diss., University of Oregon, 1965), 240.
    • (1948) Memoirs , pp. 353
    • Hull, C.1
  • 22
    • 85033302567 scopus 로고
    • Ph.D. diss., University of Oregon
    • See Cordell Hull, Memoirs (New York: Macmillan, 1948), 353; Goldstein (fn. 9), 154-58; and Haggard (fn. 6), 97. The clash between free traders such as Secretary of State Hull and protectionists led Moley to comment that "nothing which we have been dealing with has been subject to such wide differences of opinion"; Goldstein (fn. 9), 142. By 1935 Moley was an outspoken critic of the administration's trade policy. See Arthur Schatz, "Cordell Hull and the Struggle for the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Program, 1932-1940" (Ph.D. diss., University of Oregon, 1965), 240.
    • (1965) Cordell Hull and the Struggle for the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Program, 1932-1940 , pp. 240
    • Schatz, A.1
  • 23
    • 85033305884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While Southern Democrats favored lower tariffs, they were not necessarily free traders. In general they shared the belief with Republicans that tariffs were necessary to protect wages, but disagreed with Republicans on the extent and level of tariffs. See Goldstein (fn. 9), 92.
  • 24
    • 5844384208 scopus 로고
    • Congressional Tariff Policy
    • September
    • Frank Fetter, "Congressional Tariff Policy," American Economic Review 23 (September 1933), 416.
    • (1933) American Economic Review , vol.23 , pp. 416
    • Fetter, F.1
  • 26
    • 85033288476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldstein (fn. 9), 142; Schatz (fn. 16), 51
    • Goldstein (fn. 9), 142; Schatz (fn. 16), 51.
  • 27
    • 85033309140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tasca (fn. 19), 24
    • Tasca (fn. 19), 24.
  • 28
    • 85033315264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, the relative weight members assign foreign tariffs vis-à-vis imports will vary. Our assumption, however, is that all members put at least some weight on foreign tariffs and prefer lower foreign tariffs for any given level of U.S. tariffs.
  • 29
    • 0019679509 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics
    • June
    • For an argument relating constituency size to concern of the representative with particularistic policies, see Barry Weingast, Kenneth Shepsle, and Christopher Johnsen, "The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics," Journal of Political Economy 89 (June 1981).
    • (1981) Journal of Political Economy , vol.89
    • Weingast, B.1    Shepsle, K.2    Johnsen, C.3
  • 30
    • 0000796327 scopus 로고
    • The Industrial Organization of Congress
    • June
    • See Barry Weingast and William Marshall, "The Industrial Organization of Congress," Journal of Political Economy 96 (June 1988); Gary Cox and Mathew McCubbins, Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991); and Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organization (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991).
    • (1988) Journal of Political Economy , vol.96
    • Weingast, B.1    Marshall, W.2
  • 31
    • 0004009780 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • See Barry Weingast and William Marshall, "The Industrial Organization of Congress," Journal of Political Economy 96 (June 1988); Gary Cox and Mathew McCubbins, Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991); and Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organization (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991).
    • (1991) Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House
    • Cox, G.1    McCubbins, M.2
  • 32
    • 85059187701 scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • See Barry Weingast and William Marshall, "The Industrial Organization of Congress," Journal of Political Economy 96 (June 1988); Gary Cox and Mathew McCubbins, Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1991); and Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organization (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991).
    • (1991) Information and Legislative Organization
    • Krehbiel, K.1
  • 33
    • 85033300209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for example, Hull (fn. 16), 357; Bauer, Pool, and Dexter (fn. 1). The argument of the paper holds even if we were to assume the floor median could set the agenda.
  • 34
    • 85033288497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The level of foreign tariffs at the start of the game is assumed to be the level of tariffs the foreign government sets if there is no agreement with the U.S. As long as Congress sets tariffs unilaterally, the foreign country is assumed to choose this level of tariffs.
  • 35
    • 84971922229 scopus 로고
    • Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence
    • Autumn
    • The situation is more complicated if there is divided government. These results are deemphasized, since major tariff legislation occurred under unified rule. The equilibria are easily established, however. If the status quo is Q- and an election puts a Republican president and Democratic Congress in power, the Democrats will propose nothing and the status quo will remain Q-. However, if the status quo is Q- and a Democratic president and Republican Congress win, the Republicans will propose an increase in rates. Because an increase to Q+ would be vetoed by the Democratic president, the Republicans will only propose an increase to the maximum point in the preferred set over Q- held by the veto player to the left of the median. The veto player to the left of the median is the member the Republicans will need in order to pass a two-thirds override of a presidential veto. Similar reasoning establishes the remaining possibilities. On divided government and tariff policy, see Susanne Lohmann and Sharyn O'Halloran, "Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy: Theory and Evidence," International Organization 48 (Autumn 1994).
    • (1994) International Organization , vol.48
    • Lohmann, S.1    O'Halloran, S.2
  • 36
    • 85033291950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We concentrate on the implications of unified government, as most tariff changes occurred under unified government. The effects of divided government can be determined in this framework, however. There is also no change if the Democrats retain control of Congress but a Republican wins the presidency. The foreign government would not negotiate a U.S. tariff increase, as the president might wish, because it prefers the status quo to such an agreement. Congressional agenda setters would also desire no change. If Republicans win Congress and Democrats retain the presidency, there is also no change, as the president can veto any efforts by Republicans to increase tariffs and not be overturned. A sufficient condition for this is that D is equal to, or to the right of, the thirty-third percentile member. In 1934 this was an accurate depiction of the situation. Democrats controlled about two-thirds of the seats in Congress. The median Democrat was therefore roughly at the thirty-third percentile. Given that T* was chosen by Democrats when they could have chosen a higher level, we know that they will not prefer a tariff increase to T*. They would therefore not support any effort to overturn a presidential veto of legislation raising tariffs.
  • 37
    • 85033279873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Here it is assumed that the foreign country raises tariffs back to their unilateral tariff level if the U.S. nullifies the RTAA agreements and raises tariffs.
  • 38
    • 85033319329 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Schnietz (fn. 3) has made a similar claim, that the RTAA increased the durability of liberal trade policies. She uses a one-dimensional model to argue that holding the median constant, the RTAA mitigates protectionist potential. That is, when Republicans take over after Democrats, a relatively liberal Republican president will raise tariffs to co-opt the extremist Republican Congress. We make a much stronger claim. Holding the median constant, the RTAA eliminates protectionist potential under general conditions. In addition, in our model the RTAA'S low tariffs are robust to a whole class of preference changes. Also, note that, in Schnietz's argument, the RTAA will lead to more protection than if there were no RTAA when a Republican president and Democratic Congress win; a Republican president in this situation would be able to use his authority to preempt more extreme Democratic cuts in tariffs.
  • 39
    • 85033288769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weingast, Shepsle, and Johnsen (fn. 23)
    • Weingast, Shepsle, and Johnsen (fn. 23).
  • 41
    • 85033277692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tasca (fn. 19)
    • Tasca (fn. 19).
  • 44
    • 56349162805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions
    • United States Bureau of the Census, U.S. Commodity Exports and Imports as Related to Output (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions).
    • U.S. Commodity Exports and Imports as Related to Output
  • 46
    • 0003804592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions
    • United States Bureau of the Census, The Census of Agriculture (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions); United States Bureau of the Census, United States Census of Manufactures (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions); United States Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975).
    • The Census of Agriculture
  • 47
    • 0003584226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions
    • United States Bureau of the Census, The Census of Agriculture (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions); United States Bureau of the Census, United States Census of Manufactures (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions); United States Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975).
    • United States Census of Manufactures
  • 48
    • 0003465534 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office
    • United States Bureau of the Census, The Census of Agriculture (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions); United States Bureau of the Census, United States Census of Manufactures (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, various editions); United States Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975).
    • (1975) Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970
  • 49
    • 84936374946 scopus 로고
    • Patterns of Congressional Voting
    • February
    • For an explanation of the ideology scores, see Keith Poole and Howard Rosenthal, "Patterns of Congressional Voting," American Journal of Political Science 35 (February 1991). For a formal theory of low-dimensional ideological consistency, see Melvin Hinich and Michael Munger, Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995).
    • (1991) American Journal of Political Science , vol.35
    • Poole, K.1    Rosenthal, H.2
  • 50
    • 85058918116 scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • For an explanation of the ideology scores, see Keith Poole and Howard Rosenthal, "Patterns of Congressional Voting," American Journal of Political Science 35 (February 1991). For a formal theory of low-dimensional ideological consistency, see Melvin Hinich and Michael Munger, Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995).
    • (1995) Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice
    • Hinich, M.1    Munger, M.2
  • 52
    • 85033294917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • American trade politics has historically shown strong regional variation. We also ran estimations that included regional dummy variables in our equations. The result was consistent with the previous analysis; but there were interesting differences across regions. Among the Republicans in 1953, an increase of two standard deviations in exports led to a 13 percent increase in the chance that representatives from the Northeast will vote for trade liberalization, an 18 percent increase for those from the Midwest, and a huge, 51 percent hike for those from the West. For Democrats in 1953, the comparable numbers were 2 percent Northeast; 10 percent Midwest; 31 percent West; 8 percent South; 5 percent Border (no South or Border results are reported for Republicans given the scarcity in the number of representatives). In 1962 the increase in probability of a free-trade vote with a two-standard deviation rise in exports was for Republicans: 8 percent Northeast; 25 percent Midwest; and 18 percent West. For Democrats in 1962, the vote effects were 2 percent Northeast; 2 percent Midwest; 5 percent West; 11 percent South, and 6 percent Border.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.