메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 92, Issue 7, 2014, Pages 1803-1838

The (still) shaky foundations of trade secret law

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84904052536     PISSN: 00404411     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (25)

References (123)
  • 2
    • 84904068158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 1 Melvin F. Jager, Trade Secrets Law § 3.11, at 3-49 (2010) (noting that "unlike a patent owner, a person who possesses a trade secret does not have an exclusive right to the information").
    • (2010) Melvin F. Jager, Trade Secrets Law , vol.1 , pp. 3-49
  • 3
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 4
    • 84881997065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrecy, Innovation and the Requirement of Reasonable Secrecy Precautions
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, Trade Secrecy, Innovation and the Requirement of Reasonable Secrecy Precautions, in The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research 46 (Rochelle C. Dreyfuss & Katherine J. Strandburg eds., 2011) [hereinafter Bone, Trade Secrecy] (critically analyzing the case for requiring secrecy precautions).
    • (2011) The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research , pp. 46
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 5
    • 84904054510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • John E. Jankowski, Business Use of Intellectual Property Protection Documented in NSF Survey, Nat'l Sci. Found. (Feb. 2012), http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/ infbrief/nsf12307/ns f12307.pdf (reporting results from a NSF survey showing heavy reliance on trade secrecy in some industries); Trends in Proprietary Information Loss: Survey Report, Asis Int'l 1-3 (June 2007), https://foundation.asisonline.org/FoundationResearch/Publications/Documents/trendsinproprietary informationloss.pdf (discussing the threat U.S. businesses face from foreign countries).
    • (2012) Business Use of Intellectual Property Protection Documented in NSF Survey
    • Jankowski, J.E.1
  • 6
    • 80052638052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in Federal Courts
    • note
    • David S. Almeling et al., A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in Federal Courts, 45 Gonz. L. Rev. 291, 293 (2009-2010) [hereinafter Almeling et al., Federal Courts] (reporting that published trade secret cases in federal court have grown "exponentially, " doubling between 1988 and 1995 and again between 1995 and 2004)
    • (2009) Gonz. L. Rev. , vol.45
    • Almeling, D.S.1
  • 7
    • 84897783797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts
    • note
    • David S. Almeling et al., A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts, 46 Gonz. L. Rev. 57, 61 (2010-2011) [hereinafter Almeling et al., State Courts] (reporting that published trade secret cases in state courts have grown at a linear rate).
    • (2010) Gonz. L. Rev. , vol.46
    • Almeling, D.S.1
  • 9
    • 80052634174 scopus 로고
    • The Confidence Game: An Approach to the Law About Trade Secrets
    • note
    • It is worth noting that I am not the only one who recommends confining trade secret law mostly to contract. See Thornton Robison, The Confidence Game: An Approach to the Law About Trade Secrets, 25 Ariz. L. Rev. 347, 383-84 (1983) (proposing that trade secret protection be based on contract in employer-employee settings).
    • (1983) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.25
    • Robison, T.1
  • 10
    • 77950653785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Unif. Trade Secrets Act (amended 1985), 14 U.L.A. 529 (2005). See generally 1 Roger M. Milgrim & Eric E. Bensen, Milgrim on Trade Secrets § 1.01[2] (2013) (discussing the UTSA).
    • (2005) Unif. Trade Secrets Act , vol.14 , pp. 529
  • 11
    • 84904047093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Unif. Trade Secrets Act § 1(4)
  • 13
    • 1442321335 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Restatement (First) of Torts § 757 cmt. f (1939); E.I. duPont deNemours & Co. v. Christopher, 431 F.2d 1012, 1017 (5th Cir. 1970) (holding that aerial photography was an "improper method" of obtaining a trade secret).
    • (1939) Restatement (First) of Torts
  • 14
    • 84897783797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts
    • note
    • David S. Almeling et al., A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts, 46 Gonz. L. Rev. 57, 61 (2010-2011) [hereinafter Almeling et al., State Courts] (reporting that published trade secret cases in state courts have grown at a linear rate).
    • (2010) Gonz. L. Rev. , vol.46
    • Almeling, D.S.1
  • 15
    • 84897783797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts
    • note
    • David S. Almeling et al., A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts, 46 Gonz. L. Rev. 57, 61 (2010-2011) [hereinafter Almeling et al., State Courts] (reporting that published trade secret cases in state courts have grown at a linear rate).
    • (2010) Gonz. L. Rev. , vol.46
    • Almeling, D.S.1
  • 16
    • 10944256273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law 4 (2003) ("Today it is acknowledged that analysis and evaluation of intellectual property law are appropriately conducted within an economic framework that seeks to align that law with the dictates of economic efficiency. ")
    • (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law , vol.4
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 17
    • 84904052769 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 431 F.2d 1012 (5th Cir. 1970).
    • (1970) , vol.431 , pp. 1012
  • 18
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 19
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 20
    • 62449266716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Surprising Virtues of Treating Trade Secrets as IP Rights
    • note
    • It is well understood that firms, especially in certain industries, favor trade secret law over patent even for clearly patentable inventions when those inventions are difficult to reverse engineer. Mark A. Lemley, The Surprising Virtues of Treating Trade Secrets as IP Rights, 61 Stan. L. Rev. 311, 339-40 & n.121 (2008) (citing an empirical study to support the argument that some companies prefer trade secret protection for inventions that are "not transparent to the world")
    • (2008) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.61 , Issue.121
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 21
    • 84904054510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • John E. Jankowski, Business Use of Intellectual Property Protection Documented in NSF Survey, Nat'l Sci. Found. (Feb. 2012), http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/ infbrief/nsf12307/ns f12307.pdf (reporting results from a NSF survey showing heavy reliance on trade secrecy in some industries); Trends in Proprietary Information Loss: Survey Report, Asis Int'l 1-3 (June 2007), https://foundation.asisonline.org/FoundationResearch/Publications/Documents/trendsinproprietary informationloss.pdf (discussing the threat U.S. businesses face from foreign countries).
    • (2012) Business Use of Intellectual Property Protection Documented in NSF Survey
    • Jankowski, J.E.1
  • 22
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 23
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 24
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 25
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 27
    • 84904052998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alternative Corporate Responses to Internet Data Theft
    • note
    • Ian C. Ballon, Alternative Corporate Responses to Internet Data Theft, in 17th Annual Institute on Computer Law 737, 740 (1997) (stressing the detection problems with computer data theft)
    • (1997) 17th Annual Institute on Computer Law
    • Ballon, I.C.1
  • 28
    • 0041499021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding the Economic Espionage Act of 1996
    • note
    • James H.A. Pooley et al., Understanding the Economic Espionage Act of 1996, 5 Tex. Intell. Prop. L.J. 177, 224 (1997) (noting that "[i]nformation loss is inherently difficult to detect").
    • (1997) Tex. Intell. Prop. L.J. , vol.5
    • Pooley, J.H.A.1
  • 29
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 30
    • 84904060952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Am. Intellectual Prop. Law Ass'n, Report of the Economic Survey 2013, at 34-36 (2013), available at http://library.constantcontact.com/download/get/file/1109295819134-177/AIPLA+2013+Survey_Press_Summary+pages.pdf (reporting survey results showing that trade secret litigation costs on average $425,000 for suits worth less than a million dollars up to $2,950,000 for suits worth more than 25 million dollars, compared to patent litigation for which the comparable figures are $700,000 and $5,500,000, respectively).
    • (2013) Am. Intellectual Prop. Law Ass'n, Report of the Economic Survey , pp. 34-36
  • 31
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 32
    • 84904047062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • generally John Rawls, A Theory of Justice 17-22 (rev. ed. 1999) (describing the concept of the "original position").
    • (1999) A Theory of Justice 17-22
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 33
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 34
    • 84904052536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law
    • Robert G. Bone, The (Still) Shaky Foundations of Trade Secret Law, 92 Texas L. Rev. 1803 (2014)
    • (2014) Texas L. Rev. , vol.92 , pp. 1803
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 35
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 36
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 37
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 38
    • 84904047077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There is an argument that classification might help to cope with the problem of empirical uncertainty. I examine this argument in Part III below and explain why it does not work for trade secrecy.
  • 39
    • 10944256273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law 4 (2003) ("Today it is acknowledged that analysis and evaluation of intellectual property law are appropriately conducted within an economic framework that seeks to align that law with the dictates of economic efficiency. ")
    • (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law , vol.4
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 40
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 41
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 42
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 43
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 44
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 45
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 47
    • 21844522459 scopus 로고
    • Start-Ups, Spin-Offs, and Internal Projects
    • note
    • James J. Anton & Dennis A. Yao, Start-Ups, Spin-Offs, and Internal Projects, 11 J.L. Econ. & Org. 362, 362 (1995) (noting that many start-ups are created by former employees of established firms).
    • (1995) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.11 , pp. 362
    • Anton, J.J.1    Yao, D.A.2
  • 48
    • 10944256273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law 4 (2003) ("Today it is acknowledged that analysis and evaluation of intellectual property law are appropriately conducted within an economic framework that seeks to align that law with the dictates of economic efficiency. ")
    • (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law , vol.4
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 49
    • 80052621556 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Myth, Chameleon or Intellectual Property Olympian? A Normative Framework Supporting Trade Secret Law
    • Vincent Chiappetta, Myth, Chameleon or Intellectual Property Olympian? A Normative Framework Supporting Trade Secret Law, 8 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 69, 111-13 (1999)
    • (1999) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.8
    • Chiappetta, V.1
  • 50
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 51
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 52
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 53
    • 84904047067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Trade secret owners might file just to establish a reputation as fighters, but this is an expensive strategy to pursue.
  • 54
    • 78649951656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Revictimization of Companies by the Stock Market Who Report Trade Secret Theft Under the Economic Espionage Act
    • note
    • Chris Carr & Larry Gorman, The Revictimization of Companies by the Stock Market Who Report Trade Secret Theft Under the Economic Espionage Act, 57 Bus. Law. 25, 48 (2001) (reporting the results of an empirical study using event study methodology that shows a statistically and economically significant decline in stock market price after reporting trade secret theft under the Economic Espionage Act).
    • (2001) Bus. Law. , vol.57
    • Carr, C.1    Gorman, L.2
  • 55
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 56
    • 70350786058 scopus 로고
    • note
    • also Unif. Trade Secrets Act §§ 3-4 (amended 1985), 14 U.L.A. 633-34, 642 (2005) (providing for disgorgement and other damages for trade secret violations, including attorney's fees when misapropriation claims are made in bad faith).
    • (1985) Unif. Trade Secrets Act , pp. 3-4
  • 57
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 58
    • 0001930751 scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Frivolous Lawsuits on the Settlement of Litigation
    • note
    • Avery Katz, The Effect of Frivolous Lawsuits on the Settlement of Litigation, 10 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 3, 17-19 (1990) (presenting an asymmetric information model of frivolous litigation).
    • (1990) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.10
    • Katz, A.1
  • 59
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 60
    • 0000584479 scopus 로고
    • Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention
    • note
    • This is known as Arrow's Information Paradox. See Kenneth J. Arrow, Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention, in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors 609, 614-16 (1962) (describing the features of information as a commodity and the resulting difficulties in creating a market for information).
    • (1962) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors
    • Arrow, K.J.1
  • 61
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 62
    • 80053215321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Espionage: A Framework for a Workable Solution
    • note
    • Mark E.A. Danielson, Economic Espionage: A Framework for a Workable Solution, 10 Minn. J.L. Sci. & Tech. 503, 505-06 (2009) (noting the reluctance of firms to admit that trade secrets have been stolen and offering various reasons for this, including concerns about signaling vulnerability to information breach and admitting inability to secure sensitive information).
    • (2009) Minn. J.L. Sci. & Tech. , vol.10
    • Danielson, M.E.A.1
  • 63
    • 10944256273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law 4 (2003) ("Today it is acknowledged that analysis and evaluation of intellectual property law are appropriately conducted within an economic framework that seeks to align that law with the dictates of economic efficiency. ")
    • (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law , vol.4
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 64
    • 84904049667 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147, 1165-67 (1st Cir. 1994) (describing a licensing agreement in which the licensee was limited to using the licensor's proprietary information for explicitly stated purposes).
    • (1994) Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp , vol.36
  • 65
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 66
    • 84855830858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Where to File Your Patent Case
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Where to File Your Patent Case, 38 AIPLA Q.J. 401, 405 & tbl.2 (2010) (finding both districts to be among the most favored for patent lawsuits). Note, however, that because we count only cases with merits decisions, rather than all cases filed, a district's share of cases in our data set may not match their share of filed cases because cases in some districts are more likely to settle than others.
    • (2010) AIPLA Q.J. , vol.38
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 67
    • 84904047069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • And if those policies do not, then there is no other reason to enjoin-or so I argue.
  • 68
    • 4243124519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office
    • note
    • Mark A. Lemley, Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office, 95 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1495, 1501 (2001) ("The overwhelming majority of [patent] lawsuits settle or are abandoned before trial. ").
    • (2001) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.95
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 69
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 70
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 71
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 72
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 73
    • 77952013419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?
    • Michael Risch, Why Do We Have Trade Secrets?, 11 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 50 n.235 (2007)
    • (2007) Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. , vol.11 , Issue.235
    • Risch, M.1
  • 74
    • 84904047070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I discuss this point a bit more in Part III(B)(1).
  • 75
    • 34248353448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unnatural Rights: Hegel and Intellectual Property
    • note
    • In addition, Professor Jeanne Schroeder has offered a Hegelian account of trade secret law. Jeanne L. Schroeder, Unnatural Rights: Hegel and Intellectual Property, 60 U. Miami L. Rev. 453, 466 (2006).
    • (2006) U. Miami L. Rev. , vol.60
    • Schroeder, J.L.1
  • 76
    • 33745779138 scopus 로고
    • Normative Economic Analysis of Trademark Law
    • note
    • William P. Kratzke, Normative Economic Analysis of Trademark Law, 21 Memphis St. U. L. Rev. 199, 223 (1991) (arguing that free riders can create value and foster competition).
    • (1991) Memphis St. U. L. Rev. , vol.21
    • Kratzke, W.P.1
  • 77
    • 84904068462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations
    • note
    • James W. Hill, Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations, 4 Va. J.L. & Tech., art. 2, paras. 44-47 (1999), http://www.vjolt.net/vol4/issue/home_art2.html. See generally Hanoch Dagan, Unjust Enrichment (1997) (presenting a positive theory of unjust enrichment that connects it to the "core social values" of the community in which it is applied). I hasten to add that my discussion in this Part focuses on Hill's particular application of Dagan's theory and not on Dagan's theory itself.
    • (1999) Va. J.L. & Tech. , vol.4 , pp. 44-47
    • Hill, J.W.1
  • 78
    • 84904068462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations
    • note
    • James W. Hill, Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations, 4 Va. J.L. & Tech., art. 2, paras. 44-47 (1999), http://www.vjolt.net/vol4/issue/home_art2.html. See generally Hanoch Dagan, Unjust Enrichment (1997) (presenting a positive theory of unjust enrichment that connects it to the "core social values" of the community in which it is applied). I hasten to add that my discussion in this Part focuses on Hill's particular application of Dagan's theory and not on Dagan's theory itself.
    • (1999) Va. J.L. & Tech. , vol.4 , pp. 44-47
    • Hill, J.W.1
  • 79
    • 84904068462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations
    • note
    • James W. Hill, Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations, 4 Va. J.L. & Tech., art. 2, paras. 44-47 (1999), http://www.vjolt.net/vol4/issue/home_art2.html. See generally Hanoch Dagan, Unjust Enrichment (1997) (presenting a positive theory of unjust enrichment that connects it to the "core social values" of the community in which it is applied). I hasten to add that my discussion in this Part focuses on Hill's particular application of Dagan's theory and not on Dagan's theory itself.
    • (1999) Va. J.L. & Tech. , vol.4 , pp. 44-47
    • Hill, J.W.1
  • 80
    • 84904047071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • And, I must say, a bit confusing in parts.
  • 81
    • 84936068266 scopus 로고
    • note
    • generally Ronald Dworkin, Law's Empire 49-113 (1986) (describing an interpretivist approach)
    • (1986) Law's Empire , pp. 49-113
    • Dworkin, R.1
  • 82
    • 84904047062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • generally John Rawls, A Theory of Justice 17-22 (rev. ed. 1999) (describing the concept of the "original position").
    • (1999) A Theory of Justice 17-22
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 83
    • 84904047062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • generally John Rawls, A Theory of Justice 17-22 (rev. ed. 1999) (describing the concept of the "original position").
    • (1999) A Theory of Justice 17-22
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 84
    • 84904068462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations
    • note
    • James W. Hill, Trade Secrets, Unjust Enrichment, and the Classification of Obligations, 4 Va. J.L. & Tech., art. 2, paras. 44-47 (1999), http://www.vjolt.net/vol4/issue/home_art2.html. See generally Hanoch Dagan, Unjust Enrichment (1997) (presenting a positive theory of unjust enrichment that connects it to the "core social values" of the community in which it is applied). I hasten to add that my discussion in this Part focuses on Hill's particular application of Dagan's theory and not on Dagan's theory itself.
    • (1999) Va. J.L. & Tech. , vol.4 , pp. 44-47
    • Hill, J.W.1
  • 85
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 86
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 87
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 88
    • 84875469352 scopus 로고
    • note
    • John Locke, The Second Treatise of Civil Government, in Two Treatises of Government 133, 134 (Thomas I. Cook ed., Hafner Publishing Co. 1947) (1690) ("Whatsoever then he removes out of the state that nature hath provided and left it in, he hath mixed his labour with, and joined to it something that is his own, and thereby makes it his property. ").
    • (1947) The Second Treatise of Civil Government, in Two Treatises of Government
    • Locke, J.1
  • 89
    • 33747461394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hunting Goodwill: A History of the Concept of Goodwill in Trademark Law
    • note
    • For example, despite being anchored in natural property rights closely associated with Lockean theory, late nineteenth century trademark law only required use of the mark in trade to satisfy the appropriation requirement. See Robert G. Bone, Hunting Goodwill: A History of the Concept of Goodwill in Trademark Law, 86 B.U. L. Rev. 547, 562-67 (2006) (outlining the development of trademark law in the nineteenth century).
    • (2006) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.86
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 90
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 91
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 92
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 93
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 94
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 95
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 96
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 97
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 98
    • 84904047055 scopus 로고
    • note
    • also Rohm & Haas Co. v. Adco Chem. Co., 689 F.2d 424 (3d Cir. 1982) (focusing on the wrongfulness of the appropriation in determining whether trade secret law had been violated).
    • (1982) Rohm & Haas Co. v. Adco Chem. Co , vol.689 , pp. 424
  • 99
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 100
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 101
    • 80052632906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Secrets as Property: Theory and Consequences
    • note
    • Charles Tait Graves, Trade Secrets as Property: Theory and Consequences, 15 J. Intell. Prop. L. 39, 46 n.8 (2007) (grounding trade secrecy in property rights)
    • (2007) J. Intell. Prop. L. , vol.15 , Issue.8
    • Graves, C.T.1
  • 103
    • 84904047057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is conceivable that expected benefits might just equal expected costs, but that is highly unlikely and not what I am claiming here. The point is rather that empirics are too thin to support a conclusion that benefits equal, exceed, or fall below costs. There might well be situations involving non-actuarial risks, where we simply cannot predict what will happen. In such cases, we might assign equal probabilities to all contingencies, but doing so simply expresses our lack of information.
  • 104
    • 0004211737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bayesian decision making is not the only way to make decisions. Still, the alternatives are only as good as their empirical inputs. See generally José M. Bernardo & Adrian F.M. Smith, Bayesian Theory 443-88 (2000) (describing some non-Bayesian decision-making theories).
    • (2000) Bayesian Theory , pp. 443-488
    • Bernardo, J.M.1    Smith, A.F.M.2
  • 105
    • 84904047044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Obviously, the confidence level itself must be justified.
  • 106
    • 0347447847 scopus 로고
    • What Economists Can Tell Lawyers About Intellectual Property: Comment on Cheung
    • note
    • George L. Priest, What Economists Can Tell Lawyers About Intellectual Property: Comment on Cheung, in 8 Research in Law & Economics 19, 22-23 (John Palmer & Richard O. Zerbe, Jr. eds., 1986) (arguing that the ability of economists to draw conclusions about welfare effects is also plagued by lack of normative consensus on the optimal scope of IP protection).
    • (1986) Research in Law & Economics , vol.8
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 107
    • 10944256273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law 4 (2003) ("Today it is acknowledged that analysis and evaluation of intellectual property law are appropriately conducted within an economic framework that seeks to align that law with the dictates of economic efficiency. ")
    • (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law , vol.4
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 108
    • 84904047052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • And I take it as obvious that if a property rights regime is optimal, the IP regime would certainly include the core rights of copyright and patent, and trade secret law would at best complement those core rights.
  • 109
    • 77953394560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Robert P. Merges, Justifying Intellectual Property 13-20 (2012) (drawing on Kant, Locke, and Rawls to construct the normative foundations of IP law).
    • (2012) Justifying Intellectual Property , pp. 13-20
    • Merges, R.P.1
  • 110
    • 84904047051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I say "in theory" because, in practice, we cannot entirely ignore social costs even when legal rights are justified on nonconsequentialist grounds. However, the existence of a nonconsequentialist justification supports putting the burden on those who would impose limits to demonstrate that the social costs are severe enough to justify limits. In any event, empirical uncertainty should be much less troubling for a nonconsequentialist approach.
  • 111
    • 84904054435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • generally 1 Donald S. Chisum, Chisum on Patents OV (2013) (outlining the considerations Congress took into account when enacting the Patent Act); 1 Melville B. Nimmer & David Nimmer, Nimmer On Copyright OV (2013) (outlining the considerations Congress took into account when enacting the Copyright Act).
    • (2013) Chisum on Patents OV
    • Chisum, D.S.1
  • 112
    • 84902173554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Evolution of Trade Secret Law and Why Courts Commit Error When They Do Not Follow the Uniform Trade Secrets Act
    • note
    • generally Sharon K. Sandeen, The Evolution of Trade Secret Law and Why Courts Commit Error When They Do Not Follow the Uniform Trade Secrets Act, 33 Hamline L. Rev. 493, 502-21 (2010) (describing the history of the UTSA).
    • (2010) Hamline L. Rev. , vol.33
    • Sandeen, S.K.1
  • 113
    • 84904060778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Empirical Look at Trade Secret Law's Shift from Common to Statutory Law
    • note
    • Michael Risch, An Empirical Look at Trade Secret Law's Shift from Common to Statutory Law, in Intellectual Property and the Common Law 151, 173-74 (Shyamkrishna Balganesh ed., 2013) (finding significant reliance on the common law in UTSA jurisdictions, but not necessarily in a way that displaces the UTSA).
    • (2013) Intellectual Property and the Common Law
    • Risch, M.1
  • 114
    • 84904047050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law § 22.7 (9th ed. 2014) (discussing how inefficient rules will be litigated more frequently than efficient ones, increasing the likelihood they will be replaced with more efficient rules).
    • (2014) Economic Analysis of Law , vol.22 , Issue.7
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 115
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 116
    • 0001628664 scopus 로고
    • Can Litigation Improve the Law Without the Help of Judges?
    • note
    • Robert Cooter & Lewis Kornhauser, Can Litigation Improve the Law Without the Help of Judges?, 9 J. Legal Stud. 139, 140 (1980) (concluding that the common law efficiency hypothesis does not support the idea that the legal system will blindly evolve to the best state or continuously improve itself).
    • (1980) J. Legal Stud. , vol.9
    • Cooter, R.1    Kornhauser, L.2
  • 117
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 118
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 119
    • 80052612599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy
    • note
    • Eric R. Claeys, Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy, 4 J. Tort L., no. 2, art. 2 (2011), http://www.degruyter.com/view/j/jtl.2011.4.2/jtl.2011.4.2.1115/jtl.2011.4.2.1115.xml?-format=INT (arguing that the normative interest in a trade secret makes the most sense as a usufructuary property interest) [hereinafter Claeys, Private Law Theory].
    • (2011) J. Tort L. , vol.4 , Issue.2
    • Claeys, E.R.1
  • 120
    • 0346762517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification
    • note
    • Robert G. Bone, A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification, 86 Calif. L. Rev. 241 (1998) [hereinafter Bone, A New Look];
    • (1998) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 241
    • Bone, R.G.1
  • 121
    • 79956151028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty
    • note
    • Daniel A. Farber, Uncertainty, 99 Geo. L.J. 901, 914-19 (2011) (describing the precautionary principle and applying it to catastrophic losses where the risk of occurrence is highly uncertain)
    • (2011) Geo. L.J. , vol.99
    • Farber, D.A.1
  • 122
    • 33645149718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Core Precautionary Principle
    • note
    • Stephen M. Gardiner, A Core Precautionary Principle, 14 J. Pol. Phil. 33, 45-54 (2006) (constructing and defending a "Rawlsian core precautionary principle" for use in environmental policymaking). There are variations on this principle, such as!-maximin, which calls for taking an!-weighted combination of the best and worst case scenarios under each option.
    • (2006) J. Pol. Phil. , vol.14
    • Gardiner, S.M.1
  • 123
    • 79956151028 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Uncertainty
    • note
    • Daniel A. Farber, Uncertainty, 99 Geo. L.J. 901, 914-19 (2011) (describing the precautionary principle and applying it to catastrophic losses where the risk of occurrence is highly uncertain)
    • (2011) Geo. L.J. , vol.99
    • Farber, D.A.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.