메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 121, Issue 8, 2012, Pages 2216-2268

The antitrust/consumer protection paradox: Two policies at war with each other

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 84861886380     PISSN: 00440094     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (34)

References (323)
  • 2
    • 70349469049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interactions Between Competition and Consumer Policy
    • note
    • Mark Armstrong, Interactions Between Competition and Consumer Policy, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2008, at 97, 100-12.
    • (2008) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 3
    • 70350164638 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer Protection Policies, Economics, and Interactions with Competition Policy
    • note
    • Paul A. Pautler, Consumer Protection Policies, Economics, and Interactions with Competition Policy, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2008, at 83, 83-84.
    • (2008) Competition Pol'y Int'l , pp. 83-84
    • Pautler, P.A.1
  • 4
    • 70349469049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interactions Between Competition and Consumer Policy
    • note
    • Mark Armstrong, Interactions Between Competition and Consumer Policy, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2008, at 97, 100-12.
    • (2008) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Armstrong, M.1
  • 5
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 7
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5512(b)(4) (West 2010).
    • (2010) 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 8
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5512(b)(4) (West 2010).
    • (2010) 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 9
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5512(b)(4) (West 2010).
    • (2010) 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 10
    • 84861906259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comm'r, Fed. Trade Comm'n
    • note
    • Compare id. ("The Bureau may take any action... to prevent a covered person or service provider from committing or engaging in an unfair, deceptive, or abusive act or practice under Federal law in connection with any transaction with a consumer for a consumer financial product or service, or the offering of a consumer financial product or service. "), with 15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(2) (2006) ("The Commission is hereby empowered and directed to prevent persons... from using... unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce. "). The CFPB's enforcement authority is not limited by prior FTC interpretations and guidance. See Identification of Enforceable Rules and Orders, 76 Fed. Reg. 43,569, 43,570 (July 21, 2011) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. ch. X) (construing enforceable "rules and orders" to exclude guidance issued by the agencies that transferred rules to the CFPB). Some have expressed concerns that the lack of coordination between the FTC and the CFPB will weaken consumer protection. See William E. Kovacic, Comm'r, Fed. Trade Comm'n, The Consumer Financial Protection Agency and the Hazards of Regulatory Restructuring, Lombard Street, Sept, 14, 2009, at 19, 24-27, available at http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/ kovacic/090914hazzrdsrestructuring.pdf.
    • (2009) The Consumer Financial Protection Agency and the Hazards of Regulatory Restructuring
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 11
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5531(a) (conferring authority to prevent abusive acts or practices in addition to those that are unfair or deceptive).
    • 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 12
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5531(a) (conferring authority to prevent abusive acts or practices in addition to those that are unfair or deceptive).
    • 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 13
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5531(a) (conferring authority to prevent abusive acts or practices in addition to those that are unfair or deceptive).
    • 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 14
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5531(a) (conferring authority to prevent abusive acts or practices in addition to those that are unfair or deceptive).
    • 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 15
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 12 U.S.C.A. § 5531(a) (conferring authority to prevent abusive acts or practices in addition to those that are unfair or deceptive).
    • 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 16
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 17
    • 84861903660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Locating the Regulation of Data Privacy and Data Security
    • note
    • See, e.g., Edward J. Janger, Locating the Regulation of Data Privacy and Data Security, 5 Brook. J. Corp. Fin. & Com. L. 97, 97 (2010) ("The proposal for [an agency like the CFPB was] made initially by Elizabeth Warren and Oren Bar-Gill. ").
    • (2010) Brook. J. Corp. Fin. & Com. L. , vol.5 , pp. 97
    • Janger, E.J.1
  • 18
    • 84861900650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dynamic Federalism and Consumer Financial Protection: How the Dodd-Frank Act Changes the Preemption Debate
    • note
    • Jared Elosta, Recent Development, Dynamic Federalism and Consumer Financial Protection: How the Dodd-Frank Act Changes the Preemption Debate, 89 N.C. L. Rev. 1273, 1273 (2011) ("Adopting the idea of Bar-Gill and Warren, Dodd-Frank created the... CFPB.... ").
    • (2011) N.C. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 1273
    • Elosta, J.1
  • 19
    • 84861898400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard Epstein on the Dangerous Allure of Behavioral Economics: The Relationship Between Physical and Financial Products
    • note
    • Richard Epstein, Richard Epstein on the Dangerous Allure of Behavioral Economics: The Relationship Between Physical and Financial Products, Truth on the Market (Dec. 6, 2010, 1:20 PM), http://truthonthemarket.com/ 2010/12/06/richard-epstein-on-the-dangerous-allure-of-behavioral-economics-the-relationship-between-physical-and-financial-products (discussing financial regulation and finding that "[f]ew academic publications have had as much direct public influence on the law as the 2008 article by... Oren Bar-Gill... and Elizabeth Warren").
    • (2010) Truth on the Market
    • Epstein, R.1
  • 20
    • 84903035283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Richard H. Thaler & Cass R. Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness 7, 9 (2008) (explaining that "[h]undreds of studies confirm that human forecasts are flawed and biased, " and that "[h]uman decision making is not so great either, " and claiming that the assumption that "almost all people, almost all of the time, make choices that are in their best interest" is "obviously false").
    • (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness
    • Thaler, R.H.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 21
    • 1842863101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Libertarian Paternalism
    • note
    • Richard H. Thaler & Cass R. Sunstein, Libertarian Paternalism, 93 Am. Econ. Rev. 175, 175 (2003) ("The false assumption is that people always (usually?) make choices that are in their best interest.... We claim that [such an assumption] is testable and false-indeed, obviously false. ").
    • (2003) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 175
    • Thaler, R.H.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 22
    • 84861894165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Law and Economics: Its Origins, Fatal Flaws, and Implications for Liberty
    • note
    • See Joshua D. Wright & Douglas H. Ginsburg, Behavioral Law and Economics: Its Origins, Fatal Flaws, and Implications for Liberty, 106 Nw. U. L. Rev. (forthcoming Apr. 2012) (manuscript at 30-35) (cataloging these various proposals).
    • (2012) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.106
    • Wright, J.D.1    Ginsburg, D.H.2
  • 23
    • 0003646313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach 121 (9th ed. 2009) (describing revealed preference as the statement that "[i]f a bundle X is chosen over a bundle Y, then X must be preferred to Y").
    • (2009) Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach , pp. 121
    • Varian, H.R.1
  • 24
    • 0004164290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., W. Kip Viscusi, Joseph E. Harrington, Jr. & John M. Vernon, Economics of Regulation and Antitrust, at xviii (4th ed. 2005) (describing the foundational question in the economics of regulation as, "[W]hat particular market failures provide a rationale for government intervention?"). However, market failure is a necessary but not sufficient condition for regulation.
    • (2005) Economics of Regulation and Antitrust
    • Viscusi, W.K.1    Harrington Jr., J.E.2    Vernon, J.M.3
  • 25
    • 0002129358 scopus 로고
    • Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint
    • note
    • See, e.g., Harold Demsetz, Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 J.L. & Econ. 1, 1 (1969) (criticizing and comparing the "nirvana approach" with the comparative institutions approach, which presents the relevant policy choice as between "alternative real institutional arrangements").
    • (1969) J.L. & Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 1
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 26
    • 0003793346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • N. Gregory Mankiw, Principles of Economics 11 (5th ed. 2009). For a more technical definition of market failure, see Daniel F. Spulber, Regulation and Markets 3 (1989), which defines market failure as "a departure of the market equilibrium allocation from the set of Pareto optimal allocations of goods and services. "
    • (2009) Principles of Economics , pp. 11
    • Mankiw, N.G.1
  • 28
    • 85005305538 scopus 로고
    • The Market for "Lemons": Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism
    • George A. Akerlof, The Market for "Lemons": Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism, 84 Q.J. Econ. 488 (1970).
    • (1970) Q.J. Econ. , vol.84 , pp. 488
    • Akerlof, G.A.1
  • 29
    • 0000699305 scopus 로고
    • The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information
    • Howard Beales, Richard Craswell & Steven C. Salop, The Efficient Regulation of Consumer Information, 24 J.L. & Econ. 491 (1981).
    • (1981) J.L. & Econ. , vol.24 , pp. 491
    • Beales, H.1    Craswell, R.2    Salop, S.C.3
  • 30
    • 0003793346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • N. Gregory Mankiw, Principles of Economics 11 (5th ed. 2009). For a more technical definition of market failure, see Daniel F. Spulber, Regulation and Markets 3 (1989), which defines market failure as "a departure of the market equilibrium allocation from the set of Pareto optimal allocations of goods and services. "
    • (2009) Principles of Economics , pp. 11
    • Mankiw, N.G.1
  • 31
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 32
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics
    • note
    • Jolls, Sunstein, and Thaler describe these departures from perfect optimization as "bounded rationality, bounded willpower, and bounded self-interest. " Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 Stan. L. Rev. 1471, 1476 (1998).
    • (1998) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.50
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 33
    • 84861854816 scopus 로고
    • Working Agreement Between Federal Trade Commission and Food and Drug Administration
    • note
    • The Food and Drug Administration and the FTC have long had an agreement to coordinate efforts to protect consumer welfare in food and drug markets. See Working Agreement Between Federal Trade Commission and Food and Drug Administration, 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 9850.01 (June 9, 1954), available at http://www.fda.gov/ohrms/dockets/ DOCKETS/06p0394/06p-0394-cp00001-10-Tab-08-Trade-Reg-Rpts-vol1.pdf.
    • (1954) Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) , vol.4
  • 34
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics
    • note
    • Jolls, Sunstein, and Thaler describe these departures from perfect optimization as "bounded rationality, bounded willpower, and bounded self-interest. " Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 Stan. L. Rev. 1471, 1476 (1998).
    • (1998) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.50
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 35
    • 84861854815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Obviously issues of paternalism become central here. ").
  • 36
    • 79955570431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Failure Is an Option: An Ersatz-Antitrust Approach to Financial Regulation
    • note
    • But cf. Jonathan R. Macey & James P. Holdcroft, Jr., Failure Is an Option: An Ersatz-Antitrust Approach to Financial Regulation, 120 Yale L.J. 1368 (2011) (arguing that an antitrust approach bolstered by new statutory authority would achieve Dodd-Frank's objective of reducing systemic risk).
    • (2011) Yale L.J. , vol.120 , pp. 1368
    • Macey, J.R.1    Holdcroft Jr., J.P.2
  • 39
    • 80051572658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is Antitrust Too Complicated for Generalist Judges? The Impact of Economic Complexity and Judicial Training on Appeals
    • note
    • See generally Michael R. Baye & Joshua D. Wright, Is Antitrust Too Complicated for Generalist Judges? The Impact of Economic Complexity and Judicial Training on Appeals, 54 J.L. & Econ. 1 (2011) (discussing the increasing complexity of economic analysis in judicial decisionmaking in antitrust and demonstrating judges with economic training exhibit improved performance).
    • (2011) J.L. & Econ. , vol.54 , pp. 1
    • Baye, M.R.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 40
    • 77951591164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg & Derek W. Moore, The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 89, 97.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1    Moore, D.W.2
  • 41
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 42
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 43
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 44
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 45
    • 13844259700 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Federal Trade Commission Act, ch. 311, § 5, 38 Stat. 717, 719 (1914) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(1) (2006).
    • (1914) Federal Trade Commission Act
  • 46
    • 79952083667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Outpost Years for a Start-Up Agency: The FTC from 1921-1925
    • See Marc Winerman & William E. Kovacic, Outpost Years for a Start-Up Agency: The FTC from 1921-1925, 77 Antitrust L. J 145, 193 (2010).
    • (2010) Antitrust L. J , vol.77
    • Winerman, M.1    Kovacic, W.E.2
  • 47
    • 84861898402 scopus 로고
    • note
    • FTC v. Raladam Co., 283 U.S. 643, 654 (1931).
    • (1931) FTC v. Raladam Co , vol.283
  • 48
    • 84861898401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(1).
  • 49
    • 84861906327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Common-Sense Construction of Consumer Protection Acts
    • Victor E. Schwartz & Cary Silverman, Common-Sense Construction of Consumer Protection Acts, 54 Kan. L. Rev. 1, 8 (2005).
    • (2005) Kan. L. Rev. , vol.54
    • Schwartz, V.E.1    Silverman, C.2
  • 52
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 53
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 54
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 55
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 56
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 58
    • 80052783541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Conn. Gen. Stat. § 42-110b (2011).
    • (2011) Conn. Gen. Stat.
  • 60
    • 68949208703 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mont. Code Ann. § 30-14-103 to-104 (2011).
    • (2011) Mont. Code Ann.
  • 62
  • 63
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 64
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 65
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 66
    • 4344671883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law
    • Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 Yale L.J. 541, 570-72 (2003).
    • (2003) Yale L.J. , vol.113
    • Schwartz, A.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 67
    • 4344671883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law
    • Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 Yale L.J. 541, 570-72 (2003).
    • (2003) Yale L.J. , vol.113
    • Schwartz, A.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 68
    • 15844381654 scopus 로고
    • Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking
    • note
    • Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (1964) Fed. Reg. , vol.29
  • 69
    • 15844381654 scopus 로고
    • Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking
    • note
    • Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (1964) Fed. Reg. , vol.29
  • 73
    • 77951531595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Economics as Applied to Firms: A Primer
    • note
    • See, e.g., Mark Armstrong & Steffen Huck, Behavioral Economics as Applied to Firms: A Primer, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 3.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l , pp. 3
    • Armstrong, M.1    Huck, S.2
  • 74
    • 8644277076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Seduction by Plastic
    • Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1373 (2004).
    • (2004) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.98 , pp. 1373
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 75
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics
    • note
    • Jolls, Sunstein, and Thaler describe these departures from perfect optimization as "bounded rationality, bounded willpower, and bounded self-interest. " Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 Stan. L. Rev. 1471, 1476 (1998).
    • (1998) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.50
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 76
    • 84884102400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Law and Economics
    • note
    • Christine Jolls, Behavioral Law and Economics, in Behavioral Economics and Its Applications 115 (Peter Diamond & Hannu Vartiainen eds., 2007).
    • (2007) Behavioral Economics and Its Applications , pp. 115
    • Jolls, C.1
  • 78
    • 84936526580 scopus 로고
    • Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem
    • note
    • Daniel Kahneman, Jack L. Knetsch & Richard H. Thaler, Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem, 98 J. Pol. Econ. 1325 (1990).
    • (1990) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.98 , pp. 1325
    • Kahneman, D.1    Knetsch, J.L.2    Thaler, R.H.3
  • 79
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 82
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 83
    • 83655208710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unsafe at Any Rate
    • note
    • Elizabeth Warren, Unsafe at Any Rate, Democracy, Summer 2007, at 8.
    • (2007) Democracy , pp. 8
    • Warren, E.1
  • 84
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 85
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 86
    • 79952671152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation
    • note
    • Michael S. Barr, Sendhil Mullainathan & Eldar Shafir, The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives on Regulation 25, 41-42 (David Moss & John Cisternino eds., 2009), available at http://www.tobinproject.org/sites/tobinproject.org/files/assets/ New_Perspectives_Ch2_Barr_Mullainathan_Shafir.pdf.
    • (2009) New Perspectives on Regulation
    • Barr, M.S.1    Mullainathan, S.2    Shafir, E.3
  • 87
    • 79952671152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation
    • note
    • Michael S. Barr, Sendhil Mullainathan & Eldar Shafir, The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives on Regulation 25, 41-42 (David Moss & John Cisternino eds., 2009), available at http://www.tobinproject.org/sites/tobinproject.org/files/assets/ New_Perspectives_Ch2_Barr_Mullainathan_Shafir.pdf.
    • (2009) New Perspectives on Regulation
    • Barr, M.S.1    Mullainathan, S.2    Shafir, E.3
  • 88
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 90
    • 84861915831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., 12 U.S.C.A. §§ 5532, 5536(a)(1)(B) (West 2010).
    • (2010) 12 U.S.C.A.
  • 91
    • 84861895951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Three Myths About the Consumer Financial Product Agency
    • note
    • The CFPB's disclosure authority requires disclosures that "are fully, accurately, and effectively disclosed to consumers in a manner that permits consumers to understand the costs, benefits, and risks associated with the product or service. " Id. § 5532(a). If the CFPB interprets the vague language in the statute to mean that all or nearly all consumers-rather than most consumers or even the reasonable consumer-understand disclosures before a product is authorized, then this authority is the functional equivalent of the plain vanilla requirement. Professor Warren has claimed that 95% of consumers would be likely to understand plain vanilla contracts, a target that would require significantly increased disclosures if deemed necessary for "full, accurate, and effective" disclosure by the CFPB. Elizabeth Warren, Three Myths About the Consumer Financial Product Agency, Baseline Scenario (July 21, 2009, 6:00 AM), http://baselinescenario.com/2009/07/21/three-myths-about-the-consumer-financial-product-agency. Others have recognized that the CFPB's broad disclosure authority is sufficient to replicate the plain vanilla provision through rulemaking. See Who's Watching the Watchmen? Oversight of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau: Hearing on H.R. 4173 Before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 112th Cong. 11 (2011) [hereinafter Who's Watching the Watchmen?] (statement of David S. Evans, Chairman, Global Economic Group) (explaining that, even without explicit authority to do so, "the CFPB has the ability through its rule making procedures [to] steer financial services companies towards offering 'plain vanilla products' by either banning products that do not conform to the CFPB's view or by making it legally risky and expensive for lenders to deviate too far from the products that the CFPB approves. In addition, it is possible for the CFPB to use disclosure requirements to force companies to standardize products around certain criteria that are the focus of those requirements").
    • (2009) Baseline Scenario
    • Warren, E.1
  • 92
    • 84861897780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Act Establishes the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau as the Primary Regulator of Consumer Financial Products and Services
    • note
    • Brian C. McCormally et al., The Dodd-Frank Act Establishes the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau as the Primary Regulator of Consumer Financial Products and Services, Arnold & Porter LLP 7 (July 2010), http://www.aporter.net/resources/documents/Advisory-The_Dodd-Frank_Act_Establishes _the_Consumer_Financial_Protection_Bureau_071510.pdf.
    • (2010) Arnold & Porter LLP , pp. 7
    • McCormally, B.C.1
  • 95
    • 2942755980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Studying Optimal Paternalism, Illustrated by a Model of Sin Taxes
    • Ted O'Donoghue & Matthew Rabin, Studying Optimal Paternalism, Illustrated by a Model of Sin Taxes, 93 Am. Econ. Rev. 186 (2003).
    • (2003) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 186
    • O'Donoghue, T.1    Rabin, M.2
  • 96
    • 77957879408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sherman Antitrust Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7 (2006).
    • (2006) Sherman Antitrust Act , pp. 209
  • 97
  • 98
    • 0007101958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law 1 (2d ed. 2001) ("The courts have spent many years interpreting, or perhaps more accurately supplying, th[e] meaning [of the antitrust laws].... The result of the 'common-law' (that is, judge-made) character of antitrust law... is a considerable fluidity in the meaning and application of the law.... ").
    • (2001) Antitrust Law , pp. 1
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 99
    • 47049107976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Richard A. Posner, How Judges Think 5 (2008) ("American antitrust law is far more the creation of judicial decisions than of antitrust legislation: the most important antitrust laws are as skimpy and vague as most provisions of the Bill of Rights. ").
    • (2008) How Judges Think , pp. 5
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 100
    • 84861862449 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Bd. of Trade of Chi. v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918) (construing the term "restraint" under the Sherman Act as prohibiting only unreasonable restraints of trade).
    • (1918) Bd. of Trade of Chi. v. United States , vol.246
  • 101
    • 4344671883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law
    • Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 Yale L.J. 541, 570-72 (2003).
    • (2003) Yale L.J. , vol.113
    • Schwartz, A.1    Scott, R.E.2
  • 102
    • 84861898394 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 384 U.S. 270 (1966).
    • (1966) , pp. 270
  • 103
    • 84861854810 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 384 U.S. 270 (1966).
    • (1966) , pp. 270
  • 104
    • 0042649526 scopus 로고
    • Allocative Efficiency and the Limits of Antitrust
    • note
    • See Oliver E. Williamson, Allocative Efficiency and the Limits of Antitrust, 59 Am. Econ. Rev. 105, 113 (1969) (observing "the regrettable condition in which a company proposing a merger, an apparent effect of which is to realize economies, consciously suppresses the economies aspect lest it be used affirmatively by the government to attack the merger").
    • (1969) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.59
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 105
    • 84861913494 scopus 로고
    • Book Review
    • note
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Book Review, 33 Hastings L.J. 755, 761 n.44 (1982) (reviewing Theodore P. Kovaleff, Business and Government During the Eisenhower Administration: A Study of the Antitrust Policy of the Antitrust Division of the Justice Department (1980) (noting that the defendants in Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962), "were forced to argue that in fact the merger did not create any efficiency and that the post-merger company would not be any better able to undersell competitors").
    • (1982) Hastings L.J. , vol.33 , Issue.44
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 106
    • 3042795560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Law in Perspective: Cases, Concepts and Problems in Competition Policy
    • note
    • See Andrew I. Gavil, William E. Kovacic & Jonathan R. Baker, Antitrust Law in Perspective: Cases, Concepts and Problems in Competition Policy 65 (2d ed. 2008). See generally Joe S. Bain, Industrial Organization (2d ed. 1968) (discussing the structure-conduct-performance paradigm).
    • (2008) , pp. 65
    • Gavil, A.I.1    Kovacic, W.E.2    Baker, J.R.3
  • 107
    • 0041532037 scopus 로고
    • The Structure-Conduct-Performance Paradigm and Antitrust
    • note
    • Leonard W. Weiss, The Structure-Conduct-Performance Paradigm and Antitrust, 127 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1104, 1105 (1979) (same).
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127
    • Weiss, L.W.1
  • 108
    • 70349206862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Detecting and Reversing the Decline in Horizontal Merger Enforcement
    • note
    • Jonathan B. Baker & Carl Shapiro, Detecting and Reversing the Decline in Horizontal Merger Enforcement, Antitrust, Summer 2008, at 29, 29.
    • (2008) Antitrust , pp. 29
    • Baker, J.B.1    Shapiro, C.2
  • 109
    • 84861895946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see, e.g., Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 345-46 (condemning a merger that would have given Brown Shoe control over only 2.3% of all national retail shoe outlets).
    • Brown Shoe , vol.370 , pp. 345-346
  • 111
    • 77954645522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IP and Antitrust: Reformation and Harm
    • note
    • Christina Bohannan & Herbert Hovenkamp, IP and Antitrust: Reformation and Harm, 51 B.C. L. Rev. 905, 908-09 (2010) (discussing prior antitrust policies that condemned procompetitive conduct).
    • (2010) B.C. L. Rev. , vol.51
    • Bohannan, C.1    Hovenkamp, H.2
  • 112
    • 80755183827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and the Sherman Act
    • note
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Federal Trade Commission and the Sherman Act, 62 Fla. L. Rev. 871, 874 (2010) ("[I]n the Brown Shoe decision, the Supreme Court upheld an FTC order condemning exclusive dealing by a shoe manufacturer where there was no realistic expectation of harm to competition. ").
    • (2010) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.62
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 113
    • 0003927908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • But see Lawrence A. Sullivan & Warren S. Grimes, The Law of Antitrust: An Integrated Handbook 556-57 (2006) ("Despite the shortcomings of Brown Shoe, it is by no means clear that a merger with the characteristics of the Brown-Kinney consolidation would wholly escape antitrust merger enforcement under modern standards. ").
    • (2006) The Law of Antitrust: An Integrated Handbook , pp. 556-557
    • Sullivan, L.A.1    Grimes, W.S.2
  • 114
    • 70350458216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy
    • note
    • Timothy J. Muris, Improving the Economic Foundations of Competition Policy, 12 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 1, 8-9 (2003). See generally Industrial Concentration: The New Learning (Harvey J. Goldschmid, H. Michael Mann & J. Fred Weston eds., 1974) (memorializing the conference at which scholars from the Chicago School debunked the structure-conductperformance paradigm).
    • (2003) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.12
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 115
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis
    • note
    • Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. Pa. L. Rev. 925, 925-33 (1979) (discussing the Chicago School's development).
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 925-933
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 116
    • 0003241064 scopus 로고
    • Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research
    • note
    • R.H. Coase, Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in 3 Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization 59, 67 (Victor R. Fuchs ed., 1972), available at http://www.nber.org/ chapters/c7618.pdf ("[I]f an economist finds something-a business practice of one sort or other-that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly explanation. And as in this field we are very ignorant, the number of ununderstandable practices tends to be rather large, and the reliance on a monopoly explanation frequent.").
    • (1972) Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 117
    • 84861894163 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
    • (1977) , pp. 36
  • 118
    • 84861898396 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
    • (1977) , pp. 36
  • 119
    • 3042795560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Law in Perspective: Cases, Concepts and Problems in Competition Policy
    • note
    • See Andrew I. Gavil, William E. Kovacic & Jonathan R. Baker, Antitrust Law in Perspective: Cases, Concepts and Problems in Competition Policy 65 (2d ed. 2008). See generally Joe S. Bain, Industrial Organization (2d ed. 1968) (discussing the structure-conduct-performance paradigm).
    • (2008) , pp. 65
    • Gavil, A.I.1    Kovacic, W.E.2    Baker, J.R.3
  • 120
    • 78049257362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Originalism and Economic Analysis: Two Case Studies of Consistency and Coherence in Supreme Court Decision Making
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg, Originalism and Economic Analysis: Two Case Studies of Consistency and Coherence in Supreme Court Decision Making, 33 Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y 217, 218 (2010) ("Starting in the 1970s, the Supreme Court began systematically reworking antitrust doctrine in order to bring it into alignment with the modern economic understanding of competition. ").
    • (2010) Harv. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.33
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1
  • 121
    • 84861898395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 54-55.
    • Sylvania , vol.433 , pp. 54-55
  • 123
    • 84861908972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 58 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam) ("[T]o be condemned as exclusionary, a monopolist's act must... harm the competitive process and thereby harm consumers. ").
    • (2001) United States v. Microsoft Corp. , vol.253
  • 124
    • 84861916952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066, 1081-82 (D.D.C. 1997) (citing 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41,552 (Sept. 10, 1992), in the analysis of a proposed merger).
    • (1997) FTC v. Staples, Inc. , vol.970
  • 126
    • 84861895949 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 220 U.S. 373 (1911).
    • (1911) , pp. 373
  • 127
    • 38949126237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court, 2006 Term-Leading Cases
    • note
    • 551 U.S. 877 (2007). In resale price maintenance, a manufacturer and its distributors agree that the latter will sell the former's products at certain prices or within specifies ranges of prices. If the distributors refuse to adhere to this agreement, either openly or covertly, the manufacturer may refuse to continue doing business with them. See The Supreme Court, 2006 Term-Leading Cases, 121 Harv. L. Rev. 185, 425-26 (2007).
    • (2007) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.121
  • 128
    • 84861895945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Leegin, 551 U.S. at 889-92.
    • Leegin , vol.551 , pp. 889-892
  • 130
    • 84861895948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 549 U.S. 312 (2007).
    • (2007) , pp. 312
  • 131
    • 84861854812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 549 U.S. 312 (2007).
    • (2007) , pp. 312
  • 132
    • 84861898398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Leegin, 551 U.S. at 889-98 (holding that vertical price restraints are not per se illegal because "economics literature is replete with procompetitive justifications for a manufacturer's use of resale price maintenance" and "recent studies documenting the competitive effects of resale price maintenance also cast doubt on the conclusion that the practice meets the criteria for a per se rule").
    • Leegin , vol.551 , pp. 889-898
  • 133
    • 84861898398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Leegin, 551 U.S. at 889-98 (holding that vertical price restraints are not per se illegal because "economics literature is replete with procompetitive justifications for a manufacturer's use of resale price maintenance" and "recent studies documenting the competitive effects of resale price maintenance also cast doubt on the conclusion that the practice meets the criteria for a per se rule").
    • Leegin , vol.551 , pp. 889-898
  • 134
    • 84861898398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Leegin, 551 U.S. at 889-98 (holding that vertical price restraints are not per se illegal because "economics literature is replete with procompetitive justifications for a manufacturer's use of resale price maintenance" and "recent studies documenting the competitive effects of resale price maintenance also cast doubt on the conclusion that the practice meets the criteria for a per se rule").
    • Leegin , vol.551 , pp. 889-898
  • 135
    • 79952822900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Credit Suisse Sec. (USA) LLC v. Billing, 551 U.S. 264, 282 (2007) (focusing upon the possibility of error costs and noting that "antitrust courts are likely to make unusually serious mistakes" in determining whether conduct is pro-or anticompetitive).
    • (2007) Credit Suisse Sec. (USA) LLC v. Billing , vol.551
  • 136
    • 0003241064 scopus 로고
    • Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research
    • note
    • R.H. Coase, Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in 3 Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization 59, 67 (Victor R. Fuchs ed., 1972), available at http://www.nber.org/ chapters/c7618.pdf ("[I]f an economist finds something-a business practice of one sort or other-that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly explanation. And as in this field we are very ignorant, the number of ununderstandable practices tends to be rather large, and the reliance on a monopoly explanation frequent.").
    • (1972) Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 137
    • 84861895947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Leegin, 551 U.S. at 878.
    • Leegin , vol.551 , pp. 878
  • 138
    • 84861899013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Misbehavioral Economics: The Case Against Behavioral Antitrust
    • See, e.g., Joshua D. Wright & Judd E. Stone II, Misbehavioral Economics: The Case Against Behavioral Antitrust, 33 Cardozo L. Rev. 1517 (2012).
    • (2012) Cardozo L. Rev. , vol.33 , pp. 1517
    • Wright, J.D.1    Stone II, J.E.2
  • 139
    • 84861901736 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 107 (1984) ("Congress designed the Sherman Act as a consumer welfare prescription. A restraint that has the effect of reducing the importance of consumer preference in setting price and output is not consistent with this fundamental goal of antitrust law. " (citation and internal quotation marks omitted).
    • (1984) Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla. , vol.468
  • 140
    • 84861901736 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 107 (1984) ("Congress designed the Sherman Act as a consumer welfare prescription. A restraint that has the effect of reducing the importance of consumer preference in setting price and output is not consistent with this fundamental goal of antitrust law. " (citation and internal quotation marks omitted).
    • (1984) Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla. , vol.468
  • 144
    • 84861898397 scopus 로고
    • note
    • FTC v. Algoma Lumber Co., 291 U.S. 67, 78 (1934) (citations omitted). The notion that existing consumer protection law shares antitrust law's approach to consumer welfare is taken for granted in modern consumer protection. A leading modern consumer protection law treatise begins with the assertion that "[i]t is widely understood that competition and consumer protection law are mutually reinforcing" and have "shared objectives: fair competition and consumer welfare. " Am. Bar Ass'n Section of Antitrust Law, Consumer Protection Law Developments, at iii (2009).
    • (1934) FTC v. Algoma Lumber Co. , vol.291
  • 145
    • 2942755980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Studying Optimal Paternalism, Illustrated by a Model of Sin Taxes
    • Ted O'Donoghue & Matthew Rabin, Studying Optimal Paternalism, Illustrated by a Model of Sin Taxes, 93 Am. Econ. Rev. 186 (2003).
    • (2003) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 186
    • O'Donoghue, T.1    Rabin, M.2
  • 146
    • 77949338293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Little Brother Is Watching You: New Paternalism on the Slippery Slopes
    • note
    • Mario J. Rizzo & Douglas Glen Whitman, Little Brother Is Watching You: New Paternalism on the Slippery Slopes, 51 Ariz. L. Rev. 685, 701 (2009) ("[T]he normative standard inherent in any attempt to 'help' agents with hyperbolic preferences is inherently vague. We do not know where 'reasonable' impatience ends and 'excessive' patience begins. ").
    • (2009) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.51
    • Rizzo, M.J.1    Whitman, D.G.2
  • 147
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 148
    • 0002129358 scopus 로고
    • Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint
    • note
    • See, e.g., Harold Demsetz, Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 J.L. & Econ. 1, 1 (1969) (criticizing and comparing the "nirvana approach" with the comparative institutions approach, which presents the relevant policy choice as between "alternative real institutional arrangements").
    • (1969) J.L. & Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 1
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 149
    • 0040106877 scopus 로고
    • The Corporate Governance Movement
    • note
    • see also Daniel R. Fischel, The Corporate Governance Movement, 35 Vand. L. Rev. 1259, 1272 (1982) ("Those who purport to discover discrepancies between an ideal norm and existing imperfect institutional arrangements and then conclude that existing arrangements should be displaced... commit the nirvana fallacy well known in economic literature. ").
    • (1982) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.35
    • Fischel, D.R.1
  • 150
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 151
    • 34248996858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Viewpoint: On the Generalizability of Lab Behaviour to the Field
    • note
    • See generally Steven D. Levitt & John A. List, Viewpoint: On the Generalizability of Lab Behaviour to the Field, 40 Can. J. Econ. 347, 351 (2007) (finding that "it is likely that the qualitative findings of the lab are generalizable, even when the quantitative magnitudes are not").
    • (2007) Can. J. Econ. , vol.40
    • Levitt, S.D.1    List, J.A.2
  • 152
    • 53249092475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Law and Economics, Paternalism, and Consumer Contracts: An Empirical Perspective
    • note
    • Joshua D. Wright, Behavioral Law and Economics, Paternalism, and Consumer Contracts: An Empirical Perspective, 2 N.Y.U. J.L. & Liberty 470 (2007) (concluding that conventional price-theoretic approaches have greater explanatory power than behavioral approaches for explaining firm behavior and consumer contracts).
    • (2007) N.Y.U. J.L. & Liberty , vol.2 , pp. 470
    • Wright, J.D.1
  • 156
    • 0002129358 scopus 로고
    • Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint
    • note
    • See, e.g., Harold Demsetz, Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint, 12 J.L. & Econ. 1, 1 (1969) (criticizing and comparing the "nirvana approach" with the comparative institutions approach, which presents the relevant policy choice as between "alternative real institutional arrangements").
    • (1969) J.L. & Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 1
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 157
    • 0002734011 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Information
    • George J. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69 J. Pol. Econ. 213, 216 (1961).
    • (1961) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.69
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 158
    • 84861900387 scopus 로고
    • note
    • 603 F.2d 263 (2d Cir. 1979).
    • (1979) , pp. 263
  • 159
    • 84861888501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Abbott Labs. v. Teva Pharm. USA, Inc., 432 F. Supp. 2d 408 (D. Del. 2006) (denying motion to dismiss).
    • (2006) Abbott Labs. v. Teva Pharm. USA, Inc. , vol.432 , pp. 408
  • 161
    • 84861913215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice & FTC, Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 9 (2010), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.pdf ("The prospect of entry into the relevant market will alleviate concerns about adverse competitive effects only if such entry will deter or counteract any competitive effects of concern so the merger will not substantially harm customers."). The antitrust laws also give some deference to new products in the form of immunizing them from per se treatment. See, e.g., Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 9 (1979) ("[I]t is only after considerable experience with certain business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations.") (citing United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 607-08 (1972).
    • (2010) U.S. Dep't of Justice & FTC, Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 162
    • 84861859936 scopus 로고
    • note
    • White Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U.S. 253, 261 (1963) ("This is the first case involving a territorial restriction in a vertical arrangement.
    • (1963) White Motor Co. v. United States , vol.372
  • 163
    • 84861900391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • and we know too little of the actual impact of both that restriction and the one respecting customers to reach a conclusion on the bare bones of the documentary evidence before us. ").
  • 164
    • 0003241064 scopus 로고
    • Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research
    • note
    • R.H. Coase, Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in 3 Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization 59, 67 (Victor R. Fuchs ed., 1972), available at http://www.nber.org/ chapters/c7618.pdf ("[I]f an economist finds something-a business practice of one sort or other-that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly explanation. And as in this field we are very ignorant, the number of ununderstandable practices tends to be rather large, and the reliance on a monopoly explanation frequent.").
    • (1972) Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 165
    • 0003241064 scopus 로고
    • Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research
    • note
    • R.H. Coase, Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research, in 3 Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization 59, 67 (Victor R. Fuchs ed., 1972), available at http://www.nber.org/ chapters/c7618.pdf ("[I]f an economist finds something-a business practice of one sort or other-that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly explanation. And as in this field we are very ignorant, the number of ununderstandable practices tends to be rather large, and the reliance on a monopoly explanation frequent.").
    • (1972) Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization , vol.3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 166
    • 84977424533 scopus 로고
    • How Many Cheers for Antitrust's 100 Years?
    • See Harold Demsetz, How Many Cheers for Antitrust's 100 Years?, 30 Econ. Inquiry 207, 209 (1992).
    • (1992) Econ. Inquiry , vol.30
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 167
    • 27844549838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust
    • Alan J. Meese, Market Failure and Non-Standard Contracting: How the Ghost of Perfect Competition Still Haunts Antitrust, 1 J. Competition L. & Econ. 21, 26-27 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.1
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 168
    • 0001426594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Valuation of New Goods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition
    • note
    • Jerry A. Hausman, Valuation of New Goods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competition, in The Economics of New Goods 209, 213-16 (Timothy F. Bresnahan & Robert J. Gordon eds., 1997) (discussing the consumer welfare gains from new product introductions and product line extensions). The same lesson can be applied to new business models.
    • The Economics of New Goods
    • Hausman, J.A.1
  • 169
    • 38549133528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer Benefits from Increased Competition in Shopping Outlets: Measuring the Effect of Wal-Mart
    • note
    • See Jerry Hausman & Ephraim Leibtag, Consumer Benefits from Increased Competition in Shopping Outlets: Measuring the Effect of Wal-Mart, 22 J. Applied Econometrics 1157 (2007).
    • (2007) J. Applied Econometrics , vol.22 , pp. 1157
    • Hausman, J.1    Leibtag, E.2
  • 170
    • 0036693747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Quantifying the Benefits of New Products: The Case of the Minivan
    • Amil Petrin, Quantifying the Benefits of New Products: The Case of the Minivan, 110 J. Pol. Econ. 705 (2002).
    • (2002) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.110 , pp. 705
    • Petrin, A.1
  • 172
    • 84861898393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • it is an important element of the free-market system. The opportunity to charge monopoly prices-at least for a short period-is what attracts 'business acumen' in the first place.
  • 173
    • 84861898392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth. ").
  • 174
    • 27844532782 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 226 (1993) (describing ease of entry as justifying summary disposition of predatory pricing claims on the grounds that monopolists could not recoup losses sustained during the predation period).
    • (1993) Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. , vol.509
  • 175
    • 27844479319 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 589 (1986) ("[I]t is not enough simply to achieve monopoly power, as monopoly pricing may breed quick entry by new competitors eager to share in the excess profits. ").
    • (1986) Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp. , vol.475
  • 176
    • 27844479319 scopus 로고
    • note
    • Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 589 (1986) ("[I]t is not enough simply to achieve monopoly power, as monopoly pricing may breed quick entry by new competitors eager to share in the excess profits. ").
    • (1986) Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp. , vol.475
  • 177
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Antitrust
    • note
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 Tex. L. Rev. 1, 2-3 (1984) ("Monopoly prices eventually attract entry, " thus allowing the market to self-correct in the face of a false negative).
    • (1984) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 178
    • 79952671152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation
    • note
    • Michael S. Barr, Sendhil Mullainathan & Eldar Shafir, The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives on Regulation 25, 41-42 (David Moss & John Cisternino eds., 2009), available at http://www.tobinproject.org/sites/tobinproject.org/files/assets/ New_Perspectives_Ch2_Barr_Mullainathan_Shafir.pdf.
    • (2009) New Perspectives on Regulation
    • Barr, M.S.1    Mullainathan, S.2    Shafir, E.3
  • 179
    • 84861909173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Letter from Barney Frank, Chairman, House Comm. on Fin. Servs., to Democratic Members, House Comm. on Fin. Servs. (Sept. 22, 2009), available at http://garrett.house.gov/ UploadedFiles/FSCMemberMemoreCFPA092209.pdf (explaining that the plain vanilla requirement would be removed in the final version of the bill). However, the structure and broad authority of the CFPB indicate that, even absent an express provision, the Bureau can still implement a plain vanilla requirement.
    • (2009) Letter from Barney Frank, Chairman, House Comm. on Fin. Servs., to Democratic Members, House Comm. on Fin. Servs.
  • 180
    • 84861909173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Letter from Barney Frank, Chairman, House Comm. on Fin. Servs., to Democratic Members, House Comm. on Fin. Servs. (Sept. 22, 2009), available at http://garrett.house.gov/ UploadedFiles/FSCMemberMemoreCFPA092209.pdf (explaining that the plain vanilla requirement would be removed in the final version of the bill). However, the structure and broad authority of the CFPB indicate that, even absent an express provision, the Bureau can still implement a plain vanilla requirement.
    • (2009) Letter from Barney Frank, Chairman, House Comm. on Fin. Servs., to Democratic Members, House Comm. on Fin. Servs.
  • 181
    • 79952671152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation
    • note
    • Michael S. Barr, Sendhil Mullainathan & Eldar Shafir, The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives on Regulation 25, 41-42 (David Moss & John Cisternino eds., 2009), available at http://www.tobinproject.org/sites/tobinproject.org/files/assets/ New_Perspectives_Ch2_Barr_Mullainathan_Shafir.pdf.
    • (2009) New Perspectives on Regulation
    • Barr, M.S.1    Mullainathan, S.2    Shafir, E.3
  • 182
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 183
    • 84861858456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Effect of the Consumer Financial Protections Agency Act of 2009 on Consumer Credit
    • note
    • see also David S. Evans & Joshua D. Wright, The Effect of the Consumer Financial Protections Agency Act of 2009 on Consumer Credit, 22 Loy. Consumer L. Rev. 277, 319-20 (2010) (discussing the CFPA's authority to ban consumer lending products).
    • (2010) Loy. Consumer L. Rev. , vol.22
    • Evans, D.S.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 184
    • 2142639369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tax Incidence When Individuals Are Time-Inconsistent: The Case of Cigarette Excise Taxes
    • note
    • Jonathan Gruber & Botond Koszegi, Tax Incidence When Individuals Are Time-Inconsistent: The Case of Cigarette Excise Taxes, 88 J. Pub. Econ. 1959 (2004) (discussing excise taxes on cigarettes).
    • (2004) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.88 , pp. 1959
    • Gruber, J.1    Koszegi, B.2
  • 185
    • 2942755980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Studying Optimal Paternalism, Illustrated by a Model of Sin Taxes
    • Ted O'Donoghue & Matthew Rabin, Studying Optimal Paternalism, Illustrated by a Model of Sin Taxes, 93 Am. Econ. Rev. 186 (2003).
    • (2003) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.93 , pp. 186
    • O'Donoghue, T.1    Rabin, M.2
  • 186
    • 84861895943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There is another possible conflict. Regulatory barriers to entry erected for new consumer financial products could favor incumbent firms over new entrants, increasing market concentration and rendering acquisition of monopoly power and antitrust scrutiny more likely.
  • 187
    • 84861854809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although the possibility of predatory pricing resulting in long-run increased prices can complicate the simple neoclassical model, it is important to recognize that antitrust law's real objection to lower prices is not that they are too low, but that consumer welfare will ultimately be taxed by higher prices when the monopolist has driven its rivals to exit the market and is finally free from competition.
  • 189
    • 84861872363 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vertical Price Restraints After Leegin
    • see Edward D. Cavanagh, Vertical Price Restraints After Leegin, 21 Loy. Consumer L. Rev. 1, 19 (2008).
    • (2008) Loy. Consumer L. Rev. , vol.21
    • Cavanagh, E.D.1
  • 190
    • 78049245949 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rambus, Innovation Efficiency, and Section 5 of the FTC Act
    • Richard Dagen, Rambus, Innovation Efficiency, and Section 5 of the FTC Act, 90 B.U. L. Rev. 1479, 1493 (2010).
    • (2010) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.90
    • Dagen, R.1
  • 191
    • 84861898390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Enforcement and the Consumer
    • note
    • Antitrust Enforcement and the Consumer, U.S. Dep't of Justice, http://www.justice.gov/atr/ public/div_stats/276198.pdf (last visited Mar. 19, 2012).
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice
  • 193
    • 80053045807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In re Travel Agent Comm'n Antitrust Litig., 583 F.3d 896 (6th Cir. 2009) (involving an allegation of agreement to cut commission rates for travel agents).
    • (2009) Travel Agent Comm'n Antitrust Litig. , vol.583 , pp. 896
  • 194
    • 84933489792 scopus 로고
    • Cooperative Buying, Monopsony Power, and Antitrust Policy
    • note
    • see also Roger D. Blair & Jeffrey L. Harrison, Cooperative Buying, Monopsony Power, and Antitrust Policy, 86 Nw. U. L. Rev. 331, 335 (1992) ("Monopsony's social welfare effects are analogous to those of monopoly in that too few resources will be employed. ").
    • (1992) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.86
    • Blair, R.D.1    Harrison, J.L.2
  • 195
    • 84861849770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing
    • note
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi, The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing, in Antitrust Law and Economics 116, 116-17 (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2010).
    • (2010) Antitrust Law and Economics , pp. 116-117
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 200
    • 84861895941 scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Am. Drugs, Inc., 891 S.W.2d 30, 34 (Ark. 1995) (requiring specific intent to harm competition rather than probability of recoupment).
    • (1995) Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Am. Drugs, Inc. , vol.891
  • 201
    • 84861911305 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bay Guardian Co. v. New Times Media LLC, 114 Cal. Rptr. 3d 392, 404-06 (Ct. App. 2010) (finding that California's predatory pricing law does not require a showing of probability of recoupment or anticompetitive impact).
    • (2010) Bay Guardian Co. v. New Times Media LLC , vol.114
  • 202
    • 84861875991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Generic Retail Drug Pricing and States: $4 and Free Drug Promotions by Large Chains Affected by State Laws
    • note
    • See Generic Retail Drug Pricing and States: $4 and Free Drug Promotions by Large Chains Affected by State Laws, Nat'l Conference of State Legislatures (Mar. 2011), http://www.ncsl.org/default.aspx?tabid=14440.
    • (2011) Nat'l Conference of State Legislatures
  • 203
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 204
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 205
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 206
    • 79551521125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law, Marketing and Behavioral Economics of Consumer Rebates
    • Matthew A. Edwards, The Law, Marketing and Behavioral Economics of Consumer Rebates, 12 Stan. J.L. Bus. & Fin. 362, 384-90 (2007).
    • (2007) Stan. J.L. Bus. & Fin. , vol.12
    • Edwards, M.A.1
  • 207
    • 10044298804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis
    • Russell Korobkin, The Endowment Effect and Legal Analysis, 97 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1227, 1228 (2003).
    • (2003) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.97
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 208
    • 31944445616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Does Economics Provide a Reliable Guide To Regulating Commodity Bundling by Firms? A Survey of the Economic Literature
    • note
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi, Does Economics Provide a Reliable Guide To Regulating Commodity Bundling by Firms? A Survey of the Economic Literature, 1 J. Competition L. & Econ. 707, 707 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 707
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 209
    • 0036001752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic Bundling of Products and Prices: A New Synthesis for Marketing
    • note
    • Stefan Stremersch & Gerard J. Tellis, Strategic Bundling of Products and Prices: A New Synthesis for Marketing, 66 J. Marketing 55, 55 (2002).
    • (2002) J. Marketing , vol.66 , pp. 55
    • Stremersch, S.1    Tellis, G.J.2
  • 210
    • 84861849770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing
    • note
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi, The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing, in Antitrust Law and Economics 116, 116-17 (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2010).
    • (2010) Antitrust Law and Economics , pp. 116-117
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 211
    • 84861906069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See U.S. Dep't of Justice & FTC, Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition 103 (2007), available at http://www.ftc.gov/ reports/innovation/P040101PromotingInnovationandCompetitionrpt0704.pdf ("Tying and bundling [are] so ubiquitous that we forget they are there.... Tying and bundling [are], roughly speaking, what the modern firm does. It's the rationale. It puts things together and offers them in packages to consumers.").
    • (2007) U.S. Dep't of Justice & FTC, Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition , pp. 103
  • 212
    • 57649173658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Issues Raised by the Emerging Global Internet Economy
    • David S. Evans, Antitrust Issues Raised by the Emerging Global Internet Economy, 102 Nw. U. L. Rev. 285, 304-05 (2008).
    • (2008) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.102
    • Evans, D.S.1
  • 213
    • 31344439723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive Markets and Implications for Tying Law
    • For economic analysis of bundling in competitive markets, see David S. Evans & Michael Salinger, Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 Yale J. on Reg. 37 (2005).
    • (2005) Yale J. on Reg. , vol.22 , pp. 37
    • Evans, D.S.1    Salinger, M.2
  • 214
    • 0036001752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic Bundling of Products and Prices: A New Synthesis for Marketing
    • note
    • Stefan Stremersch & Gerard J. Tellis, Strategic Bundling of Products and Prices: A New Synthesis for Marketing, 66 J. Marketing 55, 55 (2002).
    • (2002) J. Marketing , vol.66 , pp. 55
    • Stremersch, S.1    Tellis, G.J.2
  • 215
    • 0000383136 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Loew's Inc.: A Note on Block-Booking
    • See, e.g., George J. Stigler, United States v. Loew's Inc.: A Note on Block-Booking, 1963 Sup. Ct. Rev. 152, 155.
    • (1963) Sup. Ct. Rev.
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 216
    • 84881914852 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Block Booking
    • note
    • But see Roy W. Kenney & Benjamin Klein, The Economics of Block Booking, 26 J.L. & Econ. 497, 500, 539 (1983) (explaining that block booking did not facilitate price discrimination, but rather reduced transaction costs by preventing buyers from rejecting components of a package of products that is average-priced in order to reduce opportunism in the form of investments in informational advantages with little or no social value).
    • (1983) J.L. & Econ. , vol.26
    • Kenney, R.W.1    Klein, B.2
  • 217
    • 84861849770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing
    • note
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi, The Law and Economics of Predatory Pricing, in Antitrust Law and Economics 116, 116-17 (Keith N. Hylton ed., 2010).
    • (2010) Antitrust Law and Economics , pp. 116-117
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 221
  • 222
    • 33645758674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bundling and Consumer Misperception
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill, Bundling and Consumer Misperception, 73 U. Chi. L. Rev. 33, 36 (2006) ("When bundling reduces welfare, regulation that discourages bundling may provide a valuable tool for policymakers. "). The argument that bundling is a competitive response to consumers' cognitive biases has also been discussed in the economics literature.
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73
    • Bar-Gill, O.1
  • 223
    • 0042148568 scopus 로고
    • Tying Requirements in Competitive Markets: The Consumer Protection Issues
    • See Richard Craswell, Tying Requirements in Competitive Markets: The Consumer Protection Issues, 62 B.U. L. Rev. 661, 681-87 (1982).
    • (1982) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.62
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 224
    • 2542591648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contract Design and Self-Control: Theory and Evidence
    • Stefano DellaVigna & Ulrike Malmendier, Contract Design and Self-Control: Theory and Evidence, 119 Q.J. Econ. 353, 357 (2004).
    • (2004) Q.J. Econ. , vol.119
    • Della Vigna, S.1    Malmendier, U.2
  • 225
    • 0000538440 scopus 로고
    • Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice
    • Richard Thaler, Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice, 4 Marketing Sci. 199, 211 (1985).
    • (1985) Marketing Sci. , vol.4
    • Thaler, R.1
  • 226
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 227
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 228
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 229
    • 21844516933 scopus 로고
    • Aftermarkets and Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak
    • note
    • This analysis is highly related to the inefficiencies in aftermarket tying in the antitrust context. See Carl Shapiro, Aftermarkets and Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak, 63 Antitrust L.J. 483, 511 (1995).
    • (1995) , vol.63
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 230
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 231
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 232
    • 0742271634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability
    • note
    • cf. Russell Korobkin, Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability, 70 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1203 (2003) (discussing inclusion in standard form contracts of inefficient, nonsalient terms that do not affect consumer perception of the contracts' values although they benefit drafters).
    • (2003) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 1203
    • Korobkin, R.1
  • 233
    • 33645794938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boundedly Rational Borrowing
    • note
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Boundedly Rational Borrowing, 73 U. Chi. L. Rev. 249, 260 (2006) (discussing companies' incentives to exploit consumers' bounded rationality in order to extract high fees and late charges).
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 234
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 235
    • 33645778709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paying with Plastic: Maybe Not So Crazy
    • Empirical evidence is not consistent with the "seduction" hypothesis. See Tom Brown & Lacey Plache, Paying with Plastic: Maybe Not So Crazy, 73 U. Chi. L. Rev. 63, 66-67 (2006).
    • (2006) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.73
    • Brown, T.1    Plache, L.2
  • 236
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 237
    • 84861905666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Howard Beales & Lacey L. Plache, Rationality, Revolving, and Rewards: An Analysis of Revolving Behavior on New Credit Cards 9 (Apr. 20, 2007) (unpublished manuscript), http://www.ftc.gov/be/consumerbehavior/docs/papers/ Beales _Plache_Paper.pdf. Interestingly, following Brown and Plache, supra, Beales and Plache present microlevel data on VISA consumers who choose to switch to new rewards cards. Their behavioral theories predict that these consumers should be more likely to revolve debt and that the probability of their doing so should increase over time. The authors find a significant difference between rewards and non-rewards cards and the likelihood of carrying a balance, but it cuts against the behavioral theories. Notably, the authors find that holders of new rewards cards are significantly less likely to revolve debt than holders of non-rewards cards.
    • (2007) Rationality, Revolving, and Rewards: An Analysis of Revolving Behavior on New Credit Cards , pp. 9
    • Beales, H.1    Plache, L.L.2
  • 238
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 239
    • 67249163950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Banning Subprime Mortgages
    • See Alan M. White, The Case for Banning Subprime Mortgages, 77 U. Cin. L. Rev. 617 (2008).
    • (2008) U. Cin. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 617
    • White, A.M.1
  • 240
    • 58149114797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Making Credit Safer
    • note
    • Oren Bar-Gill & Elizabeth Warren, Making Credit Safer, 157 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 6-7 (2008) (identifying a "need for systemic regulation" in the financial services market and advocating for creation of a new federal agency to regulate consumer credit products). Numerous academics credit Bar-Gill and Warren's work for influencing the creation of the CFPB.
    • (2008) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.157
    • Bar-Gill, O.1    Warren, E.2
  • 241
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 242
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 243
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 244
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 246
    • 84861905671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The costs arising from the uncertainty generated by this conflict are significant in their own right. However, uncertainty attributable to conflicting laws is not the only source of costs consumers will face as a result of the intellectual rift in consumer law. There are also the consumer welfare costs of policy error. Ultimately, the most restrictive consumer policy-whether antitrust-or consumer protection-based-will govern firm behavior. As discussed, many of the behavioral consumer protection policies have included proposals to prohibit outright products that economists of all methodological stripes would agree produce value for some consumers.
  • 247
    • 26644444764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I adopt the New Institutional Economics' broad conception of institutions. See Claude Ménard & Mary M. Shirley, Introduction to Handbook of New Institutional Economics 1, 1 (Claude Ménard & Mary M. Shirley eds., 2005) (defining institutions as the "written and unwritten rules, norms and constraints that humans devise to reduce uncertainty and control their environment" which include "(i) written rules and agreements that govern contractual relations and corporate governance, (ii) constitutions, laws and rules that govern politics, government, finance, and society more broadly, and (iii) unwritten codes of conduct, norms of behavior, and beliefs").
    • (2005) Introduction to Handbook of New Institutional Economics , pp. 1
    • Ménard, C.1    Shirley, M.M.2
  • 248
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis
    • note
    • Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. Pa. L. Rev. 925, 925-33 (1979) (discussing the Chicago School's development).
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 925-933
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 250
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis
    • note
    • Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. Pa. L. Rev. 925, 925-33 (1979) (discussing the Chicago School's development).
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 925-933
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 251
    • 77951591164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg & Derek W. Moore, The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 89, 97.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1    Moore, D.W.2
  • 252
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 253
    • 77951591164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg & Derek W. Moore, The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 89, 97.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1    Moore, D.W.2
  • 254
    • 0348246071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics
    • note
    • Jolls, Sunstein, and Thaler describe these departures from perfect optimization as "bounded rationality, bounded willpower, and bounded self-interest. " Christine Jolls, Cass R. Sunstein & Richard Thaler, A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics, 50 Stan. L. Rev. 1471, 1476 (1998).
    • (1998) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.50
    • Jolls, C.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Thaler, R.3
  • 255
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 256
    • 77951591164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg & Derek W. Moore, The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 89, 97.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1    Moore, D.W.2
  • 257
    • 84861905669 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • That price theory ideally generates determinate results is its great virtue as an aspect of jurisprudence. ").
  • 258
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 259
    • 84959810873 scopus 로고
    • A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice
    • note
    • Herbert A. Simon, A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice, 69 Q.J. Econ. 99 (1955). The window appears to be closing, if not closed.
    • (1955) Q.J. Econ. , vol.69 , pp. 99
    • Simon, H.A.1
  • 260
    • 79952086138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behavioral Antitrust
    • note
    • See, e.g., Amanda P. Reeves & Maurice E. Stucke, Behavioral Antitrust, 86 Ind. L.J. 1527 (2011) (describing the potential for incorporating behavioral economics into antitrust agencies' analyses).
    • (2011) Ind. L.J. , vol.86 , pp. 1527
    • Reeves, A.P.1    Stucke, M.E.2
  • 263
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 266
    • 84861843275 scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
    • (1992) 504 U.S. , pp. 451
  • 267
    • 13444276477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-Chicago Antitrust: A Review and Critique
    • see Herbert Hovenkamp, Post-Chicago Antitrust: A Review and Critique, 2001 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 257, 283-86.
    • (2001) Colum. Bus. L. Rev.
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 268
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 269
    • 0346746606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Game Theory and Antitrust: A Post-Mortem
    • note
    • see also Bruce H. Kobayashi, Game Theory and Antitrust: A Post-Mortem, 5 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 411 (1997) (explaining the limited role of the game-theoretical approach in antitrust law). Following the post-Chicago School's Supreme Court debut, lower courts applying Kodak have construed it as narrowly as possible in similar aftermarket "lock-in" cases.
    • (1997) Geo. Mason L. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 411
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1
  • 270
    • 4944266176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Fall of the Kodak Aftermarket Doctrine: Dying a Slow Death in the Lower Courts
    • see also David A.J. Goldfine & Kenneth M. Vorrasi, The Fall of the Kodak Aftermarket Doctrine: Dying a Slow Death in the Lower Courts, 72 Antitrust L.J. 209 (2004).
    • (2004) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72 , pp. 209
    • Goldfine, D.A.J.1    Vorrasi, K.M.2
  • 271
    • 69549098449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism, Substantive Preemption, and Limits on Antitrust: An Application to Patent Holdup
    • note
    • Bruce H. Kobayashi & Joshua D. Wright, Federalism, Substantive Preemption, and Limits on Antitrust: An Application to Patent Holdup, 5 J. Competition L. & Econ. 469, 484-86 (2009) (discussing Kodak's treatment in lower courts).
    • (2009) J. Competition L. & Econ. , vol.5
    • Kobayashi, B.H.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 273
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 274
    • 77951591164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg & Derek W. Moore, The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 89, 97.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1    Moore, D.W.2
  • 275
    • 84861876001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Who's Watching the Watchmen? (statement of Todd Zywicki, Foundation Professor of Law, George Mason University).
  • 276
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 277
    • 84861875995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?
    • note
    • C. Boyden Gray & John Shu, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?, Engage, Dec. 2010, at 66, 67.
    • (2010) Engage, Dec.
    • Gray, C.B.1    Shu, J.2
  • 278
    • 84861909236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Who's Watching the Watchmen?, (statement of Todd Zywicki, Foundation Professor of Law, George Mason University).
  • 279
    • 84861909237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Troy A. Paredes, Comm'r, SEC, Remarks at the 43rd Annual Rocky Mountain Securities Conference (May 26, 2011) (noting that the SEC's structure of five commissioners, of whom no more than three may be from the same political party, allows for "five unique perspectives" and thus a "better regulatory regime"), available at http://www.mondovisione.com/ media-and-resources/news/speech-by-sec-commissioner-troy-a-paredes-remarks-at-the-43rd-annual-rocky-mou. Elizabeth Warren and proponents of the CFPB appear to have originally agreed with this approach, proposing a commission rather than a single-directorheaded bureau.
    • (2011) Comm'r, SEC, Remarks at the 43rd Annual Rocky Mountain Securities Conference
    • Paredes, T.A.1
  • 280
    • 34548629694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What Happened on Deliberation Day?
    • note
    • cf. David Schkade, Cass R. Sunstein & Reid Hastie, What Happened on Deliberation Day?, 95 Calif. L. Rev. 915, 929 (2007) (discussing deliberation within groups with mixed viewpoints and the benefits gained from increased political tolerance and openness to potential counterarguments).
    • (2007) Calif. L. Rev. , vol.95
    • Schkade, D.1    Sunstein, C.R.2    Hastie, R.3
  • 281
    • 79952845605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics Behaving Badly
    • note
    • George Loewenstein & Peter Ubel, Op-Ed., Economics Behaving Badly, N.Y. Times, July 14, 2010, http://www.nytimes.com/2010/07/15/opinion/15loewenstein.html.
    • (2010) N.Y. Times
    • Loewenstein, G.1    Ubel, P.2
  • 282
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 283
    • 84861875995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?
    • note
    • C. Boyden Gray & John Shu, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?, Engage, Dec. 2010, at 66, 67.
    • (2010) Engage, Dec.
    • Gray, C.B.1    Shu, J.2
  • 284
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 285
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential Administration
    • See Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 Harv. L. Rev. 2245, 2250 (2001).
    • (2001) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.114
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 286
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 287
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 288
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 289
    • 84861875994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Organizing Economists at the CFPB
    • note
    • Josh Wright, Organizing Economists at the CFPB, Truth on the Market (May 13, 2011, 12:16 PM), http://truthonthemarket.com/2011/05/13/organizing-economists-at-the-cfpb (discussing the potential role and influence of economists within the CFPB based upon the Bureau's design).
    • (2011) Truth on the Market
    • Wright, J.1
  • 290
    • 79952671152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation
    • note
    • Michael S. Barr, Sendhil Mullainathan & Eldar Shafir, The Case for Behaviorally Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives on Regulation 25, 41-42 (David Moss & John Cisternino eds., 2009), available at http://www.tobinproject.org/sites/tobinproject.org/files/assets/ New_Perspectives_Ch2_Barr_Mullainathan_Shafir.pdf.
    • (2009) New Perspectives on Regulation
    • Barr, M.S.1    Mullainathan, S.2    Shafir, E.3
  • 291
    • 77951591164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence
    • note
    • Douglas H. Ginsburg & Derek W. Moore, The Future of Behavioral Economics in Antitrust Jurisprudence, Competition Pol'y Int'l, Spring 2010, at 89, 97.
    • (2010) Competition Pol'y Int'l
    • Ginsburg, D.H.1    Moore, D.W.2
  • 293
    • 84861875995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?
    • note
    • C. Boyden Gray & John Shu, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?, Engage, Dec. 2010, at 66, 67.
    • (2010) Engage, Dec.
    • Gray, C.B.1    Shu, J.2
  • 294
    • 84861909235 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Who's Watching the Watchmen?, (statement of Todd Zywicki, Foundation Professor of Law, George Mason University).
  • 295
    • 84861875995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?
    • note
    • C. Boyden Gray & John Shu, The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010: Is It Constitutional?, Engage, Dec. 2010, at 66, 67.
    • (2010) Engage, Dec.
    • Gray, C.B.1    Shu, J.2
  • 296
    • 84861900394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Presidents have traditionally declined to exercise authority, through the OMB, over independent agencies. See Exec. Order No. 12,866, § 3(b), 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735, 51,737 (Sept. 30, 1993) (excluding independent agencies from the Order's scope).
  • 297
    • 84861900393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ("[A] statutory delegation to an executive agency official-although not to an independent agency head-usually should be read as allowing the President to assert directive authority... over the exercise of the delegated discretion. " (emphasis added). President Obama has indicated a desire for independent agencies to comply with his orders but has not required them to do so. Exec. Order No. 13,579, § 1(c), 76 Fed. Reg. 41,587, 41,587 (July 11, 2011) (stating only that independent agencies "should" comply with Executive Order Number 13,563, 76 Fed. Reg. 3821 (Jan. 18, 2011).
  • 298
    • 84861875993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Memorandum from President Barack Obama on Regulation and Independent Regulatory Agencies (July 11, 2011), http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2011/07/11/memorandum-regulation-and-independent-regulatory-agencies ("I am asking [independent agencies] today to join in this review and produce your own plans to reassess and streamline regulations.").
    • (2011) Memorandum from President Barack Obama on Regulation and Independent Regulatory Agencies
  • 299
    • 0038914762 scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement
    • William E. Kovacic, The Federal Trade Commission and Congressional Oversight of Antitrust Enforcement, 17 Tulsa L.J. 587, 592 (1982).
    • (1982) Tulsa L.J. , vol.17
    • Kovacic, W.E.1
  • 300
    • 84861903755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Wheeler-Lea Act of 1938, Pub. L. No. 75-447, § 3, 52 Stat. 111, 111 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 45(a) (2006).
    • (2006) Wheeler-Lea Act of 1938
  • 301
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection
    • note
    • J. Howard Beales III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 192, 192-93 (2003) (quoting Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.22 , pp. 192-193
    • Beales III, J.H.1
  • 302
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection
    • note
    • J. Howard Beales III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 192, 192-93 (2003) (quoting Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.22 , pp. 192-193
    • Beales III, J.H.1
  • 303
    • 84861899836 scopus 로고
    • 405 U.S. 233 (1972).
    • (1972) 405 U.S. , pp. 233
  • 304
    • 24144475529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Three Rules and a Constitution: Consumer Protection Finds Its Limits in Competition Policy
    • William MacLeod, Elizabeth Brunins & Anna Kertesz, Three Rules and a Constitution: Consumer Protection Finds Its Limits in Competition Policy, 72 Antitrust L.J. 943, 947 (2005).
    • (2005) Antitrust L.J. , vol.72
    • McLeod, W.1    Brunins, E.2    Kertesz, A.3
  • 305
    • 84861875999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Sperry & Hutchinson, 405 U.S. at 241-42.
    • Sperry & Hutchinson , vol.405 , pp. 241-242
  • 306
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection
    • note
    • J. Howard Beales III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 192, 192-93 (2003) (quoting Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.22 , pp. 192-193
    • Beales III, J.H.1
  • 307
    • 0345358562 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC
    • note
    • Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC, Regulation, May/June 1982, at 33, 34-35.
    • (1982) Regulation
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 308
    • 84861845694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?
    • Henry N. Butler & Joshua D. Wright, Are State Consumer Protection Acts Really Little-FTC Acts?, 63 Fla. L. Rev. 163, 168-69 (2011).
    • (2011) Fla. L. Rev. , vol.63
    • Butler, H.N.1    Wright, J.D.2
  • 309
    • 0345358562 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC
    • note
    • Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC, Regulation, May/June 1982, at 33, 34-35.
    • (1982) Regulation
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 310
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 311
    • 0345358562 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC
    • note
    • Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC, Regulation, May/June 1982, at 33, 34-35.
    • (1982) Regulation
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 312
    • 84861863035 scopus 로고
    • Stoning the National Nanny: Congress and the FTC in the Late 1970s
    • note
    • Michael Pertschuk, Stoning the National Nanny: Congress and the FTC in the Late 1970s, in Revolt Against Regulation: The Rise and Pause of the Consumer Movement 69, 69 (1982) (quoting The FTC as National Nanny, Wash. Post, Mar. 1, 1978, at A22).
    • (1982) Revolt Against Regulation: The Rise and Pause of the Consumer Movement , pp. 69
    • Pertschuk, M.1
  • 313
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 314
    • 0345358562 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC
    • note
    • Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC, Regulation, May/June 1982, at 33, 34-35.
    • (1982) Regulation
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 315
    • 0345358562 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC
    • note
    • Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC, Regulation, May/June 1982, at 33, 34-35.
    • (1982) Regulation
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 316
    • 0345358562 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC
    • note
    • Barry R. Weingast & Mark J. Moran, The Myth of Runaway Bureaucracy: The Case of the FTC, Regulation, May/June 1982, at 33, 34-35.
    • (1982) Regulation
    • Weingast, B.R.1    Moran, M.J.2
  • 317
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection
    • note
    • J. Howard Beales III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 192, 192-93 (2003) (quoting Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.22 , pp. 192-193
    • Beales III, J.H.1
  • 318
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 319
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 320
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 321
    • 0348173832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection
    • note
    • J. Howard Beales III, The Federal Trade Commission's Use of Unfairness Authority: Its Rise, Fall, and Resurrection, 22 J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing 192, 192-93 (2003) (quoting Statement of Basis and Purpose of Trade Regulation Rule 408, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking, 29 Fed. Reg. 8324, 8355 (July 2, 1964) (codified at 16 C.F.R. § 408).
    • (2003) J. Pub. Pol'y & Marketing , vol.22 , pp. 192-193
    • Beales III, J.H.1
  • 322
    • 84861840325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD
    • note
    • William MacLeod, Org. for Econ. Co-operation and Dev., DAF/COMP/GF/WD (2008)37, The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies 3 (2008), available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/31/56/40080545.pdf.
    • (2008) The Interface Between Competition and Consumer Policies , pp. 37
    • McLeod, W.1
  • 323
    • 27844571017 scopus 로고
    • The Role of the Courts in Applying Economics
    • note
    • The intellectual regime change in antitrust economics also played a considerable role at the Antitrust Division. See Robert H. Bork, The Role of the Courts in Applying Economics, 54 Antitrust L.J. 21, 25 (1985) ("[I]t would have been politically impossible for... [William] Baxter to have done what he did [as head of the DOJ Antitrust Division], had there not been an intellectual shift in the underpinnings of antitrust.... ").
    • (1985) Antitrust L.J. , vol.54
    • Bork, R.H.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.