-
1
-
-
79959986606
-
-
15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006)
-
15 U.S.C. § 1 (2006).
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
79959923127
-
-
322 F.3d 1133, 1152-54 9th Cir.
-
Freeman v. San Diego Ass'n of Realtors, 322 F.3d 1133, 1152-54 (9th Cir. 2003) (holding it per se unlawful to use the multi-list process to fix commission rates).
-
(2003)
Freeman v. San Diego Ass'n of Realtors
-
-
-
4
-
-
79959976064
-
-
547 F.3d 266, 27073 5th Cir. cert. denied, 129 S. Ct. 2055 (2009)
-
Golden Bridge Tech., Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., 547 F.3d 266, 270-73 (5th Cir. 2008), cert. denied, 129 S. Ct. 2055 (2009) (holding that standard setting by cellular telephone companies did not equate to a restraint of trade).
-
(2008)
Golden Bridge Tech., Inc. v. Motorola, Inc.
-
-
-
5
-
-
79959942448
-
-
457 U.S. 332, 344
-
In contrast to the per se rule, pursuant to which restraints that fall in a per se category are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable, Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332, 344 (1982), in rule-of-reason cases "the factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition."
-
(1982)
Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society
-
-
-
7
-
-
73049106205
-
-
522 U.S. 3, 10
-
Under the rule of reason, courts take "into account a variety of factors, including specific information about the relevant business, its condition before and after the restraint was imposed, and the restraint's history, nature, and effect." State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997).
-
(1997)
State Oil Co. v. Khan
-
-
-
8
-
-
79959960117
-
-
discussion infra notes 57, 220 and accompanying text
-
See discussion infra notes 57, 220 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
79959926011
-
-
467 U.S. 752, 771 (1984)
-
467 U.S. 752, 771 (1984).
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
79959927973
-
-
606 F.2d 704, 725-27 (7th Cir. 1979)
-
606 F.2d 704, 725-27 (7th Cir. 1979);
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
79959951308
-
-
392 U.S. 134
-
cf. Perma Life Mufflers, Inc. v. Int'l Parts Corp., 392 U.S. 134 (1968) (holding that parent and wholly owned subsidiaries could conspire to impose per se unlawful ties on dealers);
-
(1968)
Perma Life Mufflers, Inc. v. Int'l Parts Corp.
-
-
-
12
-
-
79952239382
-
-
340 U.S. 211
-
Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211 (1951) (holding that two wholly owned subsidiaries of a common parent could unlawfully conspire to impose resale price maintenance on their dealers).
-
(1951)
Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc.
-
-
-
13
-
-
78049294773
-
-
525 U.S. 128, 132
-
E.g., Nynex Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 132 (1998) (holding that a purely vertical agreement should be evaluated using the rule of reason);
-
(1998)
Nynex Corp. v. Discon, Inc.
-
-
-
14
-
-
76649128008
-
-
468 U.S. 85, 86
-
NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 86 (1984) (using the rule of reason to analyze a horizontal price fixing and output limitation where the industry at issue requires horizontal restraints on competition in order to make their product available).
-
(1984)
NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla
-
-
-
15
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2217
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2217 (2010).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
16
-
-
79959989122
-
-
The statute rather unhelpfully defines a "person" as "includ[ing] corporations and associations existing under or authorized" by law. 15 U.S.C. § 7 (2006)
-
The statute rather unhelpfully defines a "person" as "includ[ing] corporations and associations existing under or authorized" by law. 15 U.S.C. § 7 (2006).
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
79959930330
-
-
Id. § 2
-
Id. § 2 (condemning "every 'person' who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize . . . .").
-
-
-
-
18
-
-
79959974100
-
-
Id. § 1
-
Id. § 1 ("Every contract, combination . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce . . . is . . . illegal. Every person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty . . . .").
-
-
-
-
20
-
-
79959963561
-
-
538 F.3d 736, 740-41 7th Cir.
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 538 F.3d 736, 740-41 (7th Cir. 2008),
-
(2008)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
21
-
-
79959998979
-
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010)
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010).
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201 (No. 08661)
-
Brief for NFL Respondents at 4, Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010) (No. 08-661).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
23
-
-
78049288271
-
-
130 S. Ct.
-
Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2215.
-
Am. Needle
, pp. 2215
-
-
-
24
-
-
79959954019
-
-
Id. at 2214-15
-
Id. at 2214-15.
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
79959987413
-
-
Id. at 2215
-
Id. at 2215
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
84878051936
-
-
3d ed.
-
See 2B PHILUP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTTTRUST LAW 1 402, at 4-7 (3d ed. 2006) (discussing the nature and consequences of a perfectly competitive economy);
-
(2006)
Antttrust Law
, vol.402
, pp. 4-7
-
-
Areeda, P.E.1
Hovenkamp, H.2
-
29
-
-
84979188687
-
The nature of the firm
-
392
-
Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386, 392 (1937);
-
(1937)
Economica
, vol.4
, pp. 386
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
30
-
-
79251594595
-
Coasean markets
-
available at
-
see also Herbert Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, 31 EUR. J.L. & ECON. 63 (2010), available at http://www.springerlink.com.proxy.library.vanderbilt.edu/ content/65031035h363g164/fulltext.pdf (examining the relationship between Coasean firms and Coasean markets).
-
(2010)
Eur. J.L. & Econ.
, vol.31
, pp. 63
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
32
-
-
79959991319
-
-
modified and aff'd, 175 U.S. 211 (1899)
-
modified and aff'd, 175 U.S. 211 (1899) (explaining the difference between naked and ancillary restraints and applying the per se rule to the naked restraint at issue);
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
0004010763
-
-
11 ¶ 1906, 2d ed.
-
11 HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW, ¶ 1906, at 235-42 (2d ed. 2002) (defining and distinguishing naked and ancillary restraints).
-
(2002)
Antitrust Law
, pp. 235-242
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
34
-
-
79959919925
-
-
4A AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 973c, at 63-66
-
See 4A AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 973c, at 63-66 (discussing transactional alternatives to mergers and joint ventures);
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
79959958946
-
-
5 id. ¶ 1202, at 264-83
-
5 id. ¶ 1202, at 264-83 (explaining partial asset acquisitions);
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
79960003742
-
Initial thoughts on the American needle decision
-
Aug.
-
Gregory H. Werden, Initial Thoughts on the American Needle Decision, ANTITRUST SOURCE, Aug. 2010, at 1-7, http://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/ publishing/antitrust-source/Aug10-Werden8-2f.authcheckdam.pdf (discussing the implications of the American Needle decision);
-
(2010)
Antitrust Source
, pp. 1-7
-
-
Werden, G.H.1
-
37
-
-
78650632368
-
-
547 U.S. 1, 1
-
cf. Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 1 (2006) (holding it is not per se illegal for a lawful joint venture to set the prices at which it sells its products).
-
(2006)
Texaco Inc. v. Dagher
-
-
-
38
-
-
79952063413
-
-
288 U.S. 344, 375-78
-
E.g., Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States, 288 U.S. 344, 375-78 (1933) (upholding exclusive joint marketing scheme for Depression-era coal).
-
(1933)
Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States
-
-
-
39
-
-
79959918101
-
-
13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, 2100-04, at 3-46
-
See 13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, 2100-04, at 3-46 (providing a broad overview of joint ventures).
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
79959938082
-
-
3 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 651, at 96-130
-
See 3 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 651, at 96-130 (defining monopoly conduct).
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
79960006946
-
-
7 id. ¶ 1502, at 387-90
-
See 7 id. ¶ 1502, at 387-90;
-
-
-
-
44
-
-
79960028947
-
-
11 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 1912d, at 326-39
-
11 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 1912d, at 326-39 (discussing restraint of trade in horizontal trade cases).
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
79959954020
-
-
3A AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, 1 720, at 3-11
-
See 3A AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, 1 720, at 3-11 (examining why monopolies are allowed to charge a profit-maximizing price).
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
71949087433
-
-
422 U.S. 86, 116-17
-
See, e.g.. United States v. Citizens & S. Nat'l Bank, 422 U.S. 86, 116-17 (1975) (finding conspiracy between a bank and its partially owned branches);
-
(1975)
United States v. Citizens & S. Nat'l Bank
-
-
-
47
-
-
79959975283
-
-
332 U.S. 218, 224-25
-
United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. 218, 224-25 (1947) (finding a conspiracy between a taxicab manufacturing company and its wholly- or partially-owned operating company subsidiaries);
-
(1947)
United States v. Yellow Cab Co.
-
-
-
48
-
-
79959976063
-
-
7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, at 205-13
-
7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, at 205-13 (providing a general overview of Supreme Court cases on antitrustrelated conspiracy cases).
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
79960019863
-
-
467 U.S. 752, 777 (1984)
-
467 U.S. 752, 777 (1984).
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
79959980069
-
-
248 F.3d 131, 139 3d Cir.
-
See, e.g., Eichorn v. AT&T Corp., 248 F.3d 131, 139 (3d Cir. 2001) (stating that a "single entity in a parent-subsidiary relationship" is incapable of violating Section One of the Sherman Act).
-
(2001)
Eichorn v. AT&T Corp.
-
-
-
52
-
-
84896283703
-
-
95 F.3d 593, 600 7th Cir.
-
E.g., Chi. Profi Sports Ltd. P'ship v. NBA, 95 F.3d 593, 600 (7th Cir. 1996) (finding that professional basketball teams, although separately owned, were more similar to a single entity than multiple entities for purposes of an antitrust challenge to broadcast contracts);
-
(1996)
Chi. Profi Sports Ltd. P'ship v. NBA
-
-
-
53
-
-
79960017737
-
-
213 F.3d 198, 205 5th Cir.
-
cf. Eleven Line, Inc. v. N. Tex. State Soccer Ass'n, 213 F.3d 198, 205 (5th Cir. 2000) (finding a single entity where amateur soccer teams were not separately owned).
-
(2000)
Eleven Line, Inc. v. N. Tex. State Soccer Ass'n
-
-
-
54
-
-
79952065628
-
-
284 F.3d 47, 57-59 1st Cir.
-
See, e.g., Fraser v. Major League Soccer, 284 F.3d 47, 57-59 (1st Cir. 2002) (finding that the teams were distinct entities even though they were commonly owned).
-
(2002)
Fraser v. Major League Soccer
-
-
-
55
-
-
79960011692
-
-
7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶¶ 1467-69, at 237-58
-
For a full discussion of all lower court post-Copperweld decisions, see 7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶¶ 1467-69, at 237-58.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
79960028084
-
-
95F.3d at 593
-
95F.3d at 593.
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
79959963561
-
-
538 F.3d 736, 741-44 7th Cir.
-
Am. Needle Inc. v. NFL, 538 F.3d 736, 741-44 (7th Cir. 2008),
-
(2008)
Am. Needle Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
58
-
-
79959941274
-
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010)
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010).
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
79955422383
-
-
670 F.2d 1249, 1261-62 2d Cir.
-
The NFL historically prohibited both public ownership of the teams as well as crossownership. But see N. Am. Soccer League v. NFL, 670 F.2d 1249, 1261-62 (2d Cir. 1982) (finding that the NFL cross-ownership ban as applied to non-football teams violated the Sherman Act).
-
(1982)
N. Am. Soccer League v. NFL
-
-
-
60
-
-
79959934652
-
-
518 U.S. 231, 234-35
-
While the NFL member teams each hired and competed for players, they engaged in multi-employer collective bargaining as a group. See Brown v. Pro Football, 518 U.S. 231, 234-35 (1996) (describing one instance of the NFL's collective bargaining process).
-
(1996)
Brown v. Pro Football
-
-
-
61
-
-
79959930471
-
-
id.
-
See, e.g., id. (assuming that NFL teams were a combination of separate actors for purposes of coUective bargaining disputes and finding labor immunity);
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
76649128008
-
-
468 U.S. 85
-
NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85 (1984) (treating NCAA as a combination of its individual teams and applying the rule of reason to output limitations on national television advertising).
-
(1984)
NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of the Univ. of Okla
-
-
-
63
-
-
79952065628
-
-
284 F.3d 47, 57-59 1st Cir.
-
E.g. Fraser v. Major League Soccer, 284 F.3d 47, 57-59 (1st Cir. 2002) (finding that the teams were separate entities notwithstanding common ownership);
-
(2002)
Fraser v. Major League Soccer
-
-
-
64
-
-
79959948393
-
-
7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, 1 1478d3, at 368-77
-
see also 7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, 1 1478d3, at 368-77 (discussing the impact of American Needle on lower courts).
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2212
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2212 (2010) ("The NFL teams do not possess either the unitary decisionmaking quality or the single aggregation of economic power characteristic of independent action. Each of the teams is a substantial, independently owned, and independently managed business. [Further,] 'their general corporate actions are guided or determined' by 'separate corporate consciousnesses,' and '[t]heir objectives are' not 'common.' ")
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
67
-
-
47049099762
-
-
467 U.S. 752, 753
-
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 753 (1984) (holding a parent and wholly owned but separately incorporated subsidiary to be a single actor for antitrust purposes).
-
(1984)
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.
-
-
-
68
-
-
79959953439
-
-
dissented in Copperweld. Id.
-
Justice Stevens, the author of American Needle, dissented in Copperweld. Id. at 778-96.
-
American Needle
, pp. 778-796
-
-
Stevens, J.1
-
69
-
-
78049288271
-
-
130 S. Ct. at 2213
-
Directly relevant to this case, the teams compete in the market for intellectual property. To a firm making hats, the Saints and the Colts are two potentially competing suppliers of valuable trademarks. When each NFL team licenses its intellectual property, it is not pursuing the "common interests of the whole" league but is instead pursuing interests of each "corporation itself," teams are acting as "separate economic actors pursuing separate economic interests," and each team therefore is a potential "independent cente[r] of decisionmaking." Decisions by NFL teams to license their separately owned trademarks collectively and to only one vendor are decisions that "depriv[e] the marketplace of independent centers of decisionmaking," and therefore of actual or potential competition. Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2213
-
Am. Needle
-
-
-
70
-
-
79959924171
-
-
(quoting Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 769, 770)
-
(quoting Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 769, 770) (alterations in original).
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
79959996344
-
-
Id.
-
Id. ("Although NFL teams have common interests such as promoting the NFL brand, they are still separate, profit-maximizing entities, and their interests in licensing team trademarks are not necessarily aligned.")
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
0347340521
-
Exclusive joint ventures and antitrust policy
-
52-61
-
(citing Herbert Hovenkamp, Exclusive Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy, 1995 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 52-61,
-
Colum. Bus. L. Rev.
, vol.1995
, pp. 1
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
73
-
-
0038968237
-
Conflicts of interest and fiduciary duties in the operation of a joint venture
-
69-81
-
and Zenichi Shishido, Conflicts of Interest and Fiduciary Duties in the Operation of a Joint Venture, 39 HASTINGS L.J. 63, 69-81 (1987)).
-
(1987)
Hastings L.J.
, vol.39
, pp. 63
-
-
Shishido, Z.1
-
74
-
-
79959995789
-
-
id. at 2214-15
-
See id. at 2214-15 ("[F]or the same reasons the 32 teams' conduct is covered by § 1, NFLP's actions also are subject to § 1, at least with regards to its marketing of property owned by the separate teams . . . . For that reason, decisions by NFLP regarding the teams' separately owned intellectual property constitute concerted action."). In a footnote the Supreme Court also found it unnecessary to consider the position of the United States: For the purposes of resolving this case, there is no need to pass upon the Government's position that entities are incapable of conspiring under § 1 if they "have effectively merged the relevant aspect of their operations, thereby eliminating actual and potential competition . . . in that operational sphere" and "the challenged restraint [does] not significantly affect actual or potential competition . . . outside their merged operations." Brief for United States as Amicus Curiae 17.
-
-
-
-
75
-
-
79959924771
-
-
Id., at 32.
-
The Government urges that the choices "to offer only a blanket license" and "to have only a single headwear licensee" might not constitute concerted action under its test. Id., at 32.
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
79959950104
-
-
Id. at 2216 n.9
-
However, because the teams still own their own trademarks and are free to market those trademarks as they see fit, even those two choices were agreements amongst potential competitors and would constitute concerted action under the Government's own standard. At any point, the teams could decide to license their own trademarks. It is significant, moreover, that the teams here control NFLP. The two choices that the Government might treat as independent action, although nominally made by NFLP, are for all functional purposes choices made by the 32 entities with potentially competing interests. Id. at 2216 n.9.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
79959985489
-
-
7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 1478, at 340-77
-
See 7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 1478, at 340-77 (summarizing case law concerning whether joint venture decisions are unilateral or collaborative).
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
79959918680
-
-
258 F.3d 978, 98385 9th Cir.
-
E.g., Toscano v. PGA, 258 F.3d 978, 983-85 (9th Cir. 2001) (treating a professional golfers association as a single entity);
-
(2001)
Toscano v. PGA
-
-
-
81
-
-
79960017737
-
-
213 F.3d 198, 205 5th Cir.
-
Eleven Line, Inc. v. N. Tex. State Soccer Ass'n, 213 F.3d 198, 205 (5th Cir. 2000) (treating a volunteer association of coaches and players as a single entity);
-
(2000)
Eleven Line, Inc. v. N. Tex. State Soccer Ass'n
-
-
-
83
-
-
79960006357
-
-
181 F.3d 216, 233 2d Cir.
-
AD/SAT v. Associated Press, 181 F.3d 216, 233 (2d Cir. 1999) (finding an association of newspapers better treated as a single entity than as a conspiracy of its member newspapers);
-
(1999)
AD/SAT v. Associated Press
-
-
-
84
-
-
79959976062
-
-
No. 99 Civ. 11853 DLC, 2000 WL 1844764, at * 3-4 S.D.N.Y. Dec. 15
-
Nat'l Camp Ass'n v. Am. Camping Ass'n, No. 99 Civ. 11853 DLC, 2000 WL 1844764, at * 3-4 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 15, 2000) (treating an incorporated association of campgrounds as a single entity).
-
(2000)
Nat'l Camp Ass'n v. Am. Camping Ass'n
-
-
-
85
-
-
78049288271
-
-
130 S. Ct.
-
Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2215
-
Am. Needle
, pp. 2215
-
-
-
88
-
-
27744528594
-
What determines cartel success?
-
86
-
Margaret C. Levenstein & Valerie Y. Suslow, What Determines Cartel Success?, 44 J. ECON. LITERATURE 43, 86 (2006) ("Successful cartels develop mechanisms for sharing information, making decisions, and manipulating incentives through self-imposed carrots and sticks.").
-
(2006)
J. Econ. Literature
, vol.44
, pp. 43
-
-
Levenstein, M.C.1
Suslow, V.Y.2
-
89
-
-
79959947218
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1, at 148
-
See HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1, at 148 (examining how cartels fix prices);
-
-
-
-
90
-
-
0011545586
-
Previous cartel experience: Any lessons for OPEC?
-
Lawrence R. Klein & Jaime Marquez eds.
-
see also James M. Griffin, Previous Cartel Experience: Any Lessons For OPEC?, in ECONOMICS IN THEORY AND PRACTICE: AN ECLECTIC APPROACH: ESSAYS IN HONOR OF F.G. ADAMS 179, 179-206 (Lawrence R. Klein & Jaime Marquez eds., 1989) (examining the characteristics of fifty-four different cartels to determine what makes a cartel successful in the long-term).
-
(1989)
Economics in Theory and Practice: An Eclectic Approach: Essays in Honor of F.G. Adams
, vol.179
, pp. 179-206
-
-
Griffin, J.M.1
-
91
-
-
79959950103
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1, at 148
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1, at 148.
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
79960003193
-
-
infra notes 152-53 and accompanying text
-
These price negotiations are dangerous for cartel members because they increase the risk of detection and consequent criminal penalties. See infra notes 152-53 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
93
-
-
79960028946
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1, at 146-59
-
See HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1, at 146-59 (describing the basic economics of price fixing);
-
-
-
-
94
-
-
84984215416
-
Cartel problems: Comment
-
940
-
David E. Mills & Kenneth G. Elzinga, Cartel Problems: Comment, 68 AM. ECON. REV. 938, 940 (1978) (comparing single joint profit-maximizing points with multiple joint profit-maximizing points);
-
(1978)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.68
, pp. 938
-
-
Mills, D.E.1
Elzinga, K.G.2
-
95
-
-
0001101498
-
Cartel problems
-
841
-
D.K. Osborne, Cartel Problems, 66 AM. ECON. REV. 835, 841 (1976) (discussing the effect of single, nonmember firms on cartel pricing);
-
(1976)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.66
, pp. 835
-
-
Osborne, D.K.1
-
96
-
-
0003106058
-
An empirical survey of price fixing conspiracies
-
26-27
-
see also George A. Hay & Daniel Kelley, An Empirical Survey of Price Fixing Conspiracies, 17 J.L. & ECON. 13, 26-27 (1974) (suggesting that conspiracies are most likely to arise when "numbers are small, concentration is high, and the product is homogenous").
-
(1974)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.17
, pp. 13
-
-
Hay, G.A.1
Kelley, D.2
-
97
-
-
0004179740
-
-
9th ed.
-
See, e.g., RICHARD A. BREALEY ET AL., PRINCIPLES OF CORPORATE FINANCE 20-22 (9th ed. 2007) (discussing present value and the opportunity cost of capital);
-
(2007)
Principles of Corporate Finance
, pp. 20-22
-
-
Brealey, R.A.1
-
98
-
-
77953057454
-
Neoclassicism and the separation of ownership and control
-
386
-
Herbert Hovenkamp, Neoclassicism and the Separation of Ownership and Control, 4 VA. L. & BUS. REV. 373, 386 (2009) (discussing the Coasean vision of the firm as a profit-maximizer);
-
(2009)
Va. L. & Bus. Rev.
, vol.4
, pp. 373
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
99
-
-
0038533523
-
-
Harvard Bus. Sch., Working Paper, Oct. available at
-
Michael C. Jensen, Value Maximization, Stakeholder Theory, and the Corporate Objective Function 9 (Harvard Bus. Sch., Working Paper, Oct. 2001), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=220671 (proposing a new system for value maximization called enlightened value maximization).
-
(2001)
Value Maximization, Stakeholder Theory, and the Corporate Objective Function
, pp. 9
-
-
Jensen, M.C.1
-
101
-
-
79959955408
-
-
Id. at 15
-
Id. at 15 ("Though there did not appear to be much disagreement among firms over price, there is a well-documented episode of disagreement with regards to discounts. In the isostatic graphite cartel, members disagreed about the 20% discount to machine shops and distributors; the source of the disagreement appeared to be the different composition of cartel members' demands.").
-
-
-
-
102
-
-
79959921063
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
103
-
-
79959965661
-
Price fixing begins to hit bottom line
-
May 4
-
Robert D. Paul & J. Mark Gidley, Price Fixing Begins to Hit Bottom Line, LEGAL TIMES, May 4, 1998, at S44.
-
(1998)
Legal Times
-
-
Paul, R.D.1
Mark Gidley, J.2
-
104
-
-
79960009997
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 12
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 12.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
79959966244
-
-
Id. at 7, 15
-
Id. at 7, 15.
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
79959972925
-
-
Id. at 7
-
Id. at 7.
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
84923618755
-
The social organization of conspiracy: Iillegal networks in the heavy electrical equipment industry
-
838
-
Wayne E. Baker & Robert R. Faulkner, The Social Organization of Conspiracy: Illegal Networks in the Heavy Electrical Equipment Industry, 58 AM. SOC. REV. 837, 838 (1993).
-
(1993)
Am. Soc. Rev.
, vol.58
, pp. 837
-
-
Baker, W.E.1
Faulkner, R.R.2
-
108
-
-
0035584667
-
The vitamins case: Cartel prosecutions and the coming of international competition law
-
715
-
Harry First, The Vitamins Case: Cartel Prosecutions and the Coming of International Competition Law, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 711, 715 (2001).
-
(2001)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.68
, pp. 711
-
-
First, H.1
-
109
-
-
79959927350
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 20-21
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 20-21.
-
-
-
-
110
-
-
79959952867
-
-
Id. at 24
-
Id. at 24.
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
79959930327
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
113
-
-
79959943648
-
-
infra notes 96-100
-
See infra notes 96-100 (discussing cartel cheating and common responses).
-
-
-
-
114
-
-
1642634001
-
Trust, distrust, and antitrust
-
624
-
Christopher R. Leslie, Trust, Distrust, and Antitrust, 82 TEX. L. REV. 515, 624 (2004).
-
(2004)
Tex. L. Rev.
, vol.82
, pp. 515
-
-
Leslie, C.R.1
-
115
-
-
79959970611
-
-
Id. at 579
-
Id. at 579
-
-
-
-
116
-
-
0040971869
-
Rules, communication, and collusion: Narrative evidence from the sugar institute case
-
383
-
(citing David Genesove & Wallace P. Mullin, Rules, Communication, and Collusion: Narrative Evidence from the Sugar Institute Case, 91 AM. ECON. REV. 379, 383 (2001)).
-
(2001)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.91
, pp. 379
-
-
Genesove, D.1
Mullin, W.P.2
-
118
-
-
79959943078
-
-
Id. at 80
-
Id. at 80
-
-
-
-
119
-
-
79960028083
-
-
333 U.S. 683 (No. 3,167)
-
(citing Brief in Support of the Complaint at 414-22, Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Cement Inst., 333 U.S. 683 (No. 3,167)) ("It was against the rules of the Compendium, for example, to grant allowances for cloth sacks when they were not returned in good order.").
-
Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Cement Inst.
-
-
-
120
-
-
79960026905
-
-
MASON, supra note 70, at 169
-
MASON, supra note 70, at 169.
-
-
-
-
121
-
-
79959930329
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 12
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 12.
-
-
-
-
122
-
-
79959988562
-
-
id. at 6
-
See id. at 6 ("Collusion also extended to prices for ancillary services and non-price dimensions in order to avoid cheating through these avenues.").
-
-
-
-
123
-
-
79960008201
-
-
Id. at 9-10 (quoting EMCG-EC2, 91-3)
-
Id. at 9-10 (quoting EMCG-EC2, 91-3).
-
-
-
-
125
-
-
79960028083
-
-
333 U.S. 683, 713 n.15
-
The record in the Cement Institute case two decades prior to the heavy equipment cartel had produced the following set of bids on a job sought by the United States Engineer Office, Tucumcari, New Mexico, April 23, 1936, all identical to the one ten-thousandth cent per barrel: Table presented Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Cement Inst., 333 U.S. 683, 713 n.15 (1948).
-
(1948)
Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Cement Inst.
-
-
-
126
-
-
0005419541
-
Identical bid prices
-
150
-
See generally Vernon A. Mund, Identical Bid Prices, 68 J. POL. ECON. 150,150 (1960) (discussing identical bid process).
-
(1960)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.68
, pp. 150
-
-
Mund, V.A.1
-
128
-
-
79960009413
-
-
Id. at 71
-
Id. at 71 ("This plan, proposed in January, 1930, and accepted by practically 75% of the industry within four months, continued in force until July, 1933.").
-
-
-
-
129
-
-
79959954571
-
-
263 U.S. 403, 413
-
In one well known antitrust decision, the National Window Glass Manufacturers association reached an agreement under which one group of firms operated for six months of the year while the other group operated for the other six months. Writing for the Court, Justice Holmes approved the agreement as a reasonable way of allocating a shortage of laborers. Nat'l Ass'n of Window Glass Mfrs. v. United States, 263 U.S. 403, 413 (1923).
-
(1923)
Nat'l Ass'n of Window Glass Mfrs. v. United States
-
-
-
130
-
-
40749084517
-
-
216 F.3d 645, 652 7th Cir.
-
See, e.g., United States v. Andreas, 216 F.3d 645, 652 (7th Cir. 2000) (discussing volume allocation in the lysine cartel).
-
(2000)
United States v. Andreas
-
-
-
131
-
-
79959937485
-
-
forthcoming
-
See ROGER D. BLAIR AND JEFFREY L. HARRISON, MONOPSONY IN LAW AND ECONOMICS (forthcoming 2011) (noting that in a bilateral monopoly, the output is typically determinable, but the division of the surplus is indeterminate and must be negotiated);
-
(2011)
Monopsony in Law and Economics
-
-
Blair, R.D.1
Harrison, J.L.2
-
132
-
-
79959997835
-
-
Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 15
-
Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 15.
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
79960005783
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 28-30
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 28-30 (discussing examples in copper plumbing tubes, organic peroxides, vitamins A and E, folic acid, and citric acid cartels).
-
-
-
-
134
-
-
79959975286
-
-
Id. at 31 (discussing lysine cartel)
-
Id. at 31 (discussing lysine cartel).
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
79959929184
-
-
Id. at 6, 24
-
Id. at 6, 24.
-
-
-
-
137
-
-
79959976692
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 37
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 37 (discussing the chlorine and chloride cartel).
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
79959940663
-
-
BOIES, supra note 89, at 233
-
See BOIES, supra note 89, at 233 ("By assigning particular customers to particular suppliers, the conspirators reduce the incentive suppliers have to depart from the agreed price in search of more sales.").
-
-
-
-
139
-
-
79959962932
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 40
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 40 (discussing zinc phosphate cartel).
-
-
-
-
140
-
-
79959987998
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
141
-
-
0030527182
-
When are cartels stable contracts?
-
247
-
Andrew R. Dick, When Are Cartels Stable Contracts?, 39 J.L. & ECON. 241, 247 (1996) ("As predicted by theory, cartels tended to export relatively homogeneous, less highly processed commodities.").
-
(1996)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.39
, pp. 241
-
-
Dick, A.R.1
-
142
-
-
0004010763
-
-
13 ¶ 2136, 2d ed.
-
On product standardization agreements facilitating collusion, see 13 HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 2136, at 231-32 (2d ed. 2005).
-
(2005)
Antitrust Law
, pp. 231-232
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
143
-
-
79959934651
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 250
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 250 ("For example, cartels covering slightly more differentiated products such as textiles and office equipment dissolved after members discovered that 'foreign market development could be better handled on an individual basis.'").
-
-
-
-
145
-
-
79960001417
-
-
cert, denied, 401 U.S. 948 (1971)
-
cert, denied, 401 U.S. 948 (1971) (defendants eliminated lower quality bathroom fixtures that had been subject to heavy discounting);
-
-
-
-
147
-
-
79960023230
-
-
cert, denied, 344 U.S. 892 (1952)
-
cert, denied, 344 U.S. 892 (1952) (defendants standardized fire extinguishers in order to facilitate bid rigging);
-
-
-
-
148
-
-
79959980068
-
-
152 F.2d 478, 482 7th Cir.
-
Milk & Ice Cream Can Inst. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n, 152 F.2d 478, 482 (7th Cir. 1946) (defendants standardized milk containers in order to facilitate bid rigging, and court stated, "it was easier to reach the goal of uniform prices on a standard product than on one which was not");
-
(1946)
Milk & Ice Cream Can Inst. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n
-
-
-
149
-
-
79959971761
-
-
446 U.S. 643, 644-45
-
see also Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643, 644-45 (1980) (per curiam) (standardization of credit terms);
-
(1980)
Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc.
-
-
-
151
-
-
79959948392
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 5-8
-
see also Harrington, supra note 59, at 5-8.
-
-
-
-
152
-
-
79960024394
-
-
MACHLUP, supra note 75, at 80
-
MACHLUP, supra note 75, at 80
-
-
-
-
153
-
-
79960028083
-
-
333 U.S. 683 (No. 3, 167)
-
(citing Brief in Support of the Complaint at 414-22, Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Cement Inst., 333 U.S. 683 (No. 3, 167)).
-
Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Cement Inst.
-
-
-
154
-
-
79960017147
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 9 (quoting Graphite electrodes EC, 56)
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 9 (quoting Graphite electrodes EC, 56).
-
-
-
-
155
-
-
79960014140
-
-
Id. at 9
-
Id. at 9.
-
-
-
-
156
-
-
2942604302
-
Contemporary international cartels and developing countries: Economics effects and implications for competition policy
-
835-36
-
See, e.g., Margaret Levenstein & Valerie Y. Suslow, Contemporary International Cartels and Developing Countries: Economics Effects and Implications for Competition Policy, 71 ANTITRUST L.J. 801, 835-36 (2004) (discussing disagreements within the graphic electrodes cartel).
-
(2004)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.71
, pp. 801
-
-
Levenstein, M.1
Suslow, V.Y.2
-
157
-
-
79959967071
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
158
-
-
84971946261
-
Canada's role in the international uranium cartel
-
663
-
Larry R. Stewart, Canada's Role in the International Uranium Cartel, 35 INT'L ORG. 657, 663 (1981) (discussing disagreements within the uranium cartel).
-
(1981)
Int'l Org.
, vol.35
, pp. 657
-
-
Stewart, L.R.1
-
159
-
-
79959930328
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 31
-
See Harrington, supra note 59, at 31 (discussing dispute within lysine cartel).
-
-
-
-
160
-
-
79959944253
-
-
id. at 33
-
See id. at 33 ("Though stability of market shares was common, it was not universal. In negotiating in 1992 in the market for vitamin B2, Roche agreed to allow BASF's market share to rise from 35% in 1990 to 38% by 1994.").
-
-
-
-
161
-
-
79959998978
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 249-50
-
See Dick, supra note 94, at 249-50 (discussing potash cartel).
-
-
-
-
162
-
-
79959921062
-
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 526
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 526.
-
-
-
-
163
-
-
79959995788
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, at 149-50
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, at 149-50;
-
-
-
-
165
-
-
0347214391
-
-
On cartel cheating and the relationship between the size of the markup and the likelihood of cheating, see GEORGE M. STOCKING & MYRON M. WATKINS, CARTELS OR COMPETITION? 94 (1948).
-
(1948)
Cartels or Competition?
, pp. 94
-
-
Stocking, G.M.1
Watkins, M.M.2
-
166
-
-
84875169553
-
Regulatory conflict in the gilded age: Federalism and the railroad problem
-
1018
-
See Herbert Hovenkamp, Regulatory Conflict in the Gilded Age: Federalism and the Railroad Problem, 97 YALE L.J. 1017, 1018 (1988) (noting that, for example, in the railroad industry, both collusion and cheating were widespread during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries).
-
(1988)
Yale L.J.
, vol.97
, pp. 1017
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
167
-
-
84928308594
-
On the incidence and duration of price wars
-
416-18
-
See Robert H. Porter, On the Incidence and Duration of Price Wars, 33 J. INDUS. ECON. 415, 416-18 (1985) (writing on price wars as cartel destabilizers).
-
(1985)
J. Indus. Econ.
, vol.33
, pp. 415
-
-
Porter, R.H.1
-
168
-
-
79959960713
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 249
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 249 ("Webb-Pomerene cartels dissolved under two general sets of circumstances. The first were enforcement failures. Many price-fixing cartels were undermined by their failure to detect and punish members' attempts to undercut the agreed-on price or to exceed quota allocations.").
-
-
-
-
169
-
-
79959950726
-
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 611-15
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 611-15.
-
-
-
-
170
-
-
79959921961
-
-
id. at 618-20
-
See id. at 618-20 (discussing examples);
-
-
-
-
171
-
-
79960001279
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 63
-
see also Harrington, supra note 59, at 63 ("In the carbonless paper cartel, cartel member AWA had a market share in Europe of 30-35% and was the largest producer with capacity exceeding twice that of any other firm. It used its dominant position in the market to threaten aggressive pricing if firms did not comply with the collusive agreement.") (internal citations omitted).
-
-
-
-
172
-
-
79959922558
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 57-58
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 57-58.
-
-
-
-
173
-
-
79960012253
-
-
Id. at 58
-
Id. at 58 (discussing the citric acid and vitamins A and E cartels).
-
-
-
-
174
-
-
79959995787
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 100, at 833
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 100, at 833 (citation omitted).
-
-
-
-
175
-
-
79959938081
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 250
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 250.
-
-
-
-
176
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2213
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2213 (2010).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
177
-
-
79960002607
-
-
MASON, supra note 70, at 122-23, 133-34
-
Following an agreement between the chairmen of Sotheby's and Christie's, the CEOs of the two rival firms met and fixed commissions, among other cooperation. MASON, supra note 70, at 122-23, 133-34.
-
-
-
-
178
-
-
79959987412
-
-
Hay & Kelley, supra note 56, at 21
-
See Hay & Kelley, supra note 56, at 21 (indicating that there are many cases in which larger groups conspire).
-
-
-
-
179
-
-
79959938652
-
-
Id. at 21
-
Id. at 21 ("In seven out of eight [cartel] cases with more than fifteen firms in the conspiracy, a formal industry trade association was involved.").
-
-
-
-
182
-
-
79959964482
-
-
WHITNEY, supra note 82, at 40
-
see WHITNEY, supra note 82, at 40 ("[E]arly trade associations were little more than permanent pools.").
-
-
-
-
183
-
-
79959986605
-
-
WHITNEY, supra note 82, at 78
-
See WHITNEY, supra note 82, at 78 (discussing the Institute of Carpet Manufacturers of America).
-
-
-
-
184
-
-
0000715044
-
The great school milk conspiracies of the 1980s
-
429
-
Robert F. Lanzillotti, The Great School Milk Conspiracies of the 1980s, 11 REV. INDUS. ORG. 413, 429 n.44 (1996) ("In the Western Kentucky case, according to testimony by industry witnesses, the bid-rigging arrangements were hatched at meetings of the Western Kentucky Dairy Products Association, which were usually held in conjunction with or following meetings of the Kentucky Milk Marketing and Anti-Monopoly Commission.").
-
(1996)
Rev. Indus. Org.
, vol.11
, Issue.44
, pp. 413
-
-
Lanzillotti, R.F.1
-
185
-
-
79959996645
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 75
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 75. ("In the carbonless paper cartel, general planning meetings were conducted under the cover of the meetings of the Association of European Manufacturers of Carbonless Paper.") (internal citation omitted).
-
-
-
-
186
-
-
2342589345
-
-
See JOHN M. CONNOR, GLOBAL PRICE FIXING 134-35 (2001) (discussing European Citric Acid Manufacturers' Association and the citric acid cartel);
-
(2001)
Global Price Fixing
, pp. 134-135
-
-
Connor, J.M.1
-
187
-
-
0013086091
-
-
KURT EICHENWALD, THE INFORMANT 3 (2000) (discussing how the cartel had "formed bogus industry associations as a cover for [its] illegal meetings").
-
(2000)
The Informant
, pp. 3
-
-
Eichenwald, K.1
-
188
-
-
79960009412
-
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 220
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 220 (discussing the "formation of a formal lysine association to facilitate the conspiracy").
-
-
-
-
189
-
-
79959947796
-
-
Id. at 316
-
Id. at 316 (discussing how a meeting between the manufacturers turned into an agreement "to raise the North American price of choline chloride");
-
-
-
-
190
-
-
79960023229
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 75-76
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 75-76 ("With choline chloride, meetings were generally (though not exclusively) scheduled either before or after the meetings of the European Chemical Industry Counccil.") (internal citation omitted).
-
-
-
-
191
-
-
79960007575
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 76
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 76 ("Coordination with trade association meetings also took place with cartels in copper plumbing tubes.") (internal citation omitted).
-
-
-
-
192
-
-
1142301907
-
Crime by committee: Conspirators and company men in the illegal electrical industry cartel, 1954-1959
-
530
-
Robert R. Faulkner, Eric R. Cheney, Gene A. Fisher & Wayne E. Baker, Crime by Committee: Conspirators and Company Men in the Illegal Electrical Industry Cartel, 1954-1959, 41 CRIMINOLOGY 511, 530 (2003).
-
(2003)
Criminology
, vol.41
, pp. 511
-
-
Faulkner, R.R.1
Cheney, E.R.2
Fisher, G.A.3
Baker, W.E.4
-
194
-
-
79959927972
-
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 202
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 202 ("ADM proposed forming a world lysine association that would meet on a regular basis. The new association would collect and distribute mostly production and market-share information, much like the Corn Refiners Association did for the U.S. corn wet milling products (Tr. 1734-36). Wilson also suggested that, like the European Citric Acid Manufacturers' Association, the new association would provide a convenient cover for illegal price-fixing discussions (Tr. 2186). In a year or two, a lysine association in fact emerged that met quarterly and performed the two functions that Wilson proposed.").
-
-
-
-
195
-
-
79959940100
-
-
EICHENWALD, supra note 125, at 205
-
EICHENWALD, supra note 125, at 205 ("That's where the scheme came in. No one would question why each company had collected monthly sales data if it was turned over to the association. Then secretly, the companies could swap the numbers among themselves to enforce the volume agreement.").
-
-
-
-
196
-
-
79959980650
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 76
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 76 ("Scheduling to convene the cartel at a trade association meeting is obviously convenient-as many of the executives are to be there anywaybut it also serves the purposes of avoiding detection of the cartel. The trade association meeting provides a cover for why executives of competing firms are all at the same venue.").
-
-
-
-
197
-
-
0002150317
-
Market structure and price collusion: An empirical analysis
-
39
-
Arthur G. Fraas & Douglas F. Greer, Market Structure and Price Collusion: An Empirical Analysis, 26 J. INDUS. ECON. 21, 39 (1977).
-
(1977)
J. Indus. Econ.
, vol.26
, pp. 21
-
-
Fraas, A.G.1
Greer, D.F.2
-
198
-
-
85015092927
-
-
See LAWRENCE A. SULLIVAN & WARREN S. GRIMES, THE LAW OF ANTITRUST 233-34 (2000) ("Routine activities include publications containing useful general information about the industry and about technological and governmental developments affecting it, lobbying activities, standard setting, safety and other 'seal of approval' programs, providing media for arbitration, intra-industry promotion and advertising, and the publication of industry statistics.").
-
(2000)
The Law of Antitrust
, pp. 233-234
-
-
Sullivan, L.A.1
Grimes, W.S.2
-
199
-
-
33751207752
-
-
See HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTTTRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION 137 (2005) (stating that trade associations "also engage in rule making and standard setting for their industries" and that "the great majority of trade associations' activities are procompetitive").
-
(2005)
The Antttrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution
, pp. 137
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
200
-
-
79959930326
-
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 135
-
See CONNOR, supra note 125, at 135 ("There were about 25 face-to-face meetings of the [citric acid cartel] and about a dozen bilateral meetings (Tr. 2614-2801).");
-
-
-
-
201
-
-
79959968188
-
-
HERLING, supra note 130, at 315
-
HERLING, supra note 130, at 315 (discussing one of the heavy equipment cartels).
-
-
-
-
202
-
-
79959946061
-
-
HERLING, supra note 130, at 104
-
See HERLING, supra note 130, at 104 (noting one heavy equipment cartel whose working group "met on an average of once every six to eight weeks");
-
-
-
-
203
-
-
79959970610
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 55
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 55 ("The lysine, zinc phosphate, and citric acid cartels monitored on a regular monthly basis.");
-
-
-
-
204
-
-
79960000068
-
-
id.
-
id. ("In the case of the vitamin B5 cartel, firms initially reported sales data on a quarterly basis but later chose to do it on a monthly basis.").
-
-
-
-
206
-
-
79959935807
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 74-75
-
See Harrington, supra note 59, at 74-75 (discussing how meetings to implement an allocation of sales quotas have "a frequency dictated by the flow of new projects and customers").
-
-
-
-
207
-
-
79959999546
-
-
Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 840-41
-
Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 840-41.
-
-
-
-
208
-
-
79959958347
-
-
Id. at 841
-
Id. at 841.
-
-
-
-
209
-
-
79959967604
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 75
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 75 ("Most cartels exchanged information-generally regarding sales-on a monthly or quarterly basis with some doing it as often as weekly through phone or fax rather than face-to-face meetings.");
-
-
-
-
210
-
-
79959979475
-
-
Id. at 55
-
Id. at 55 ("While the vitamins A and E cartel met monthly for monitoring purposes, they communicated weekly by phone.").
-
-
-
-
211
-
-
79959923125
-
-
id. at 81
-
See id. at 81 ("To implement such a complex arrangement, some cartels created an impressive organizational structure that entailed frequent communication and face-to-face meetings.").
-
-
-
-
212
-
-
79959981966
-
-
HERLING, supra note 130, at 33
-
See, e.g., HERLING, supra note 130, at 33 (discussing the heavy electrical manufacturing cartel).
-
-
-
-
213
-
-
79960019862
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59, at 77
-
See Harrington, supra note 59, at 77 ("Other cartels organized themselves into both a general group - comprised of all cartel members-and regional sub-groups.").
-
-
-
-
214
-
-
79960008200
-
-
Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 839
-
Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 839.
-
-
-
-
215
-
-
79960009411
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 100, at 833
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 100, at 833.
-
-
-
-
216
-
-
79959957763
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1a
-
See HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, § 4.1a;
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
33846645138
-
Examining models of collusion: The market for lysine
-
see also Nicolas de Roos, Examining Models of Collusion: The Market for Lysine, 24 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 1083 (2006);
-
(2006)
Int'l J. Indus. Org.
, vol.24
, pp. 1083
-
-
De Roos, N.1
-
219
-
-
79959975284
-
-
Dick, supra note 94
-
Dick, supra note 94;
-
-
-
-
220
-
-
79960008812
-
-
Harrington, supra note 59
-
Harrington, supra note 59;
-
-
-
-
221
-
-
79959920476
-
-
Hay & Kelley, supra note 56
-
Hay & Kelley, supra note 56;
-
-
-
-
222
-
-
84934452640
-
Anticompetitive exclusion: Raising rivals' costs to achieve power over price
-
238-40
-
Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power over Price, 96 YALE L.J. 209, 238-40 (1986) (describing the role of the cartel "ringmaster");
-
(1986)
Yale L.J.
, vol.96
, pp. 209
-
-
Krattenmaker, T.G.1
Salop, S.C.2
-
223
-
-
57349187778
-
Antitrust amnesty, game theory, and cartel stability
-
Christopher R. Leslie, Antitrust Amnesty, Game Theory, and Cartel Stability, 31 J. CORP. L. 453 (2006) [hereinafter Leslie, Antitrust Amnesty];
-
(2006)
J. Corp. L.
, vol.31
, pp. 453
-
-
Leslie, C.R.1
-
224
-
-
79959972381
-
Cartels, agency costs and finding virtue in faithless agents
-
Christopher R. Leslie, Cartels, Agency Costs and Finding Virtue in Faithless Agents, 49 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1621 (2008) [hereinafter Leslie, Cartels];
-
(2008)
Wm. & Mary L. Rev.
, vol.49
, pp. 1621
-
-
Leslie, C.R.1
-
225
-
-
79959986061
-
-
Leslie, supra note 73
-
Leslie, supra note 73;
-
-
-
-
226
-
-
84875158313
-
Breaking up is hard to do: Determinants of cartel duration
-
forthcoming Sept.
-
Margaret C. Levenstein & Valerie Y. Suslow, Breaking up Is Hard to Do: Determinants of Cartel Duration, J.L. & ECON. (forthcoming Sept. 2010) ("Cartels respond to imperfect or noisy information by trying to . . . better align individual firm incentives with those of the group" which would reduce agency costs);
-
(2010)
J.L. & Econ.
-
-
Levenstein, M.C.1
Suslow, V.Y.2
-
227
-
-
79959982500
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52.
-
-
-
-
228
-
-
0036487679
-
Relational contracts and the theory of the firm
-
70
-
See George Baker, Robert Gibbons & Kevin J. Murphy, Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm, 117 Q.J. ECON. 39, 70 (2002) (concluding that "vertical integration is an efficient response");
-
(2002)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.117
, pp. 39
-
-
Baker, G.1
Gibbons, R.2
Murphy, K.J.3
-
229
-
-
79960000685
-
-
Ctr. for Econ. Pol'y Research, Discussion Paper No. 6829, available at
-
Mattias Ganslandt, Lars Persson & Helder Vosconcelos, Asymmetric Cartels - A Theory of Ring Leaders 3 (Ctr. for Econ. Pol'y Research, Discussion Paper No. 6829, 2008), available at http://www.porto.ucp.pt/feg/docentes/ hvasconcelos/docs/CEPR-DP6829.pdf (discussing "why so many cartels have a ringleader and why the leading firm is so frequently substantially larger than other firms in a collusive market").
-
(2008)
Asymmetric Cartels - A Theory of Ring Leaders
, pp. 3
-
-
Ganslandt, M.1
Persson, L.2
Vosconcelos, H.3
-
230
-
-
44649197264
-
Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure
-
308 (1976)
-
See Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305, 308 (1976) (discussing how "agency costs" arise when a principal cannot fully control his agents);
-
J. Fin. Econ.
, vol.3
, pp. 305
-
-
Jensen, M.C.1
Meckling, W.H.2
-
231
-
-
79953330157
-
Trust protectors, agency costs, and fiduciary duty
-
2763
-
Stewart E. Sterk, Trust Protectors, Agency Costs, and Fiduciary Duty, 27 CARDOZO L. REV. 2761, 2763 (2006) (discussing how a "trust protector" has "the potential to serve as a monitor of the trustee's performance, reducing agency costs").
-
(2006)
Cardozo L. Rev.
, vol.27
, pp. 2761
-
-
Sterk, S.E.1
-
232
-
-
78649905302
-
Communication and concerted action
-
425
-
E.g., William H. Page, Communication and Concerted Action, 38 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 405, 425 (2007) ("What is decisive in these cases is noneconomic evidence of the cause, particularly involving communications.");
-
(2007)
Loy. U. Chi. L.J.
, vol.38
, pp. 405
-
-
Page, W.H.1
-
233
-
-
70349604352
-
Twombly and communication: The emerging definition of concerted action under the new pleading standards
-
William H. Page, Twombly and Communication: The Emerging Definition of Concerted Action under the New Pleading Standards, 5 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 439 (2009).
-
(2009)
J. Competition L. & Econ.
, vol.5
, pp. 439
-
-
Page, W.H.1
-
234
-
-
79960022533
-
-
Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 855
-
See Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 855 ("In a decentralized network, however, there is no periphery. Many eyewitnesses to activities of numerous conspirators can be obtained, resulting in a much higher conviction rate, as in the switchgear and transformers conspiracies.").
-
-
-
-
237
-
-
79959931014
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 136, at 184-91
-
For a discussion on the massive retail druggists cartel that occasioned the resale price maintenance scheme in Dr. Miles, see HOVENKAMP, supra note 136, at 184-91;
-
-
-
-
238
-
-
79959978477
-
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 121, at 331-47
-
HOVENKAMP, supra note 121, at 331-47.
-
-
-
-
239
-
-
0040657315
-
The incentive to cheat: An empirical analysis of OPEC
-
306
-
James M. Griffin & Weiwen Xiong, The Incentive to Cheat: An Empirical Analysis of OPEC, 40 J.L. & ECON. 289, 306 (1997) ("Historically, Saudi Arabia has played key roles in effectuating OPEC pricing strategies.").
-
(1997)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.40
, pp. 289
-
-
Griffin, J.M.1
Xiong, W.2
-
240
-
-
77649251552
-
Rationality analysis in antitrust
-
32528
-
See Christopher R. Leslie, Rationality Analysis in Antitrust, 158 U. PA. L. REV. 261, 325-28 (2010).
-
(2010)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.158
, pp. 261
-
-
Leslie, C.R.1
-
241
-
-
79959930325
-
-
Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 855
-
See Baker & Faulkner, supra note 66, at 855 ("[A] lower conviction rate is found in a centralized network because only the core 'ringleaders' can be successfully prosecuted.").
-
-
-
-
242
-
-
79959926010
-
-
U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, pt. A6 available at
-
U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, CORPORATE LENIENCY PROGRAM pt. A6 (1993), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/0091.htm;
-
(1993)
Corporate Leniency Program
-
-
-
243
-
-
79959932200
-
-
Leslie, Antitrust Amnesty, supra note 149
-
see also Leslie, Antitrust Amnesty, supra note 149 (advocating making ringleaders eligible for amnesty because this would destabilize cartels by making ringleaders less trustworthy).
-
-
-
-
245
-
-
79959992472
-
-
aff'd, 175 U.S. 211 (1899)
-
aff'd, 175 U.S. 211 (1899).
-
-
-
-
246
-
-
79959932199
-
-
517 F.2d 635, 647 5th Cir.
-
Greene v. Gen. Foods Corp., 517 F.2d 635, 647 (5th Cir. 1975) (describing Addyston Pipe).
-
(1975)
Greene v. Gen. Foods Corp.
-
-
-
249
-
-
79960016560
-
-
779 F.2d 592, 594 11th Cir.
-
See, e.g., Nat'l Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 779 F.2d 592, 594 (11th Cir. 1986) (refusing to condemn a merchant interchange fee being challenged that applied only when the merchant's bank and the card issuer's bank facilitated their transaction through Visa's own interconnection system, called BASE II; "[s]ignificantly, the parties to the interchange are not required to use BASE II. Merchant and issuer institutions are free to negotiate a different rate and bypass the BASE II system entirely");
-
(1986)
Nat'l Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. Visa U.S.A., Inc.
-
-
-
250
-
-
79960004583
-
-
259 F. Supp. 2d 992 N.D. Cal.
-
cf. Reyn's Pasta Bella, LLC v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 259 F. Supp. 2d 992 (N.D. Cal. 2003) (condemning an interchange fee found to be exclusive, and distinguishing NaBanco).
-
(2003)
LLC v. Visa U.S.A., Inc.
-
-
Bella, P.1
-
251
-
-
79959974098
-
-
13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 2001
-
See generally 13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 2001 (discussing the requirement of exclusivity for anticompetitive horizontal agreements);
-
-
-
-
252
-
-
79959939213
-
-
id. ¶ 2104
-
id. ¶ 2104 (discussing the significance of joint venture exclusivity).
-
-
-
-
253
-
-
79959963559
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69.
-
-
-
-
254
-
-
79959961796
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 273
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 273 ("Cartels that were organized as common sales agencies centralized exporting logistics by negotiating prices and terms of sale, assigning orders to member firms, bargaining with shippers over freight and insurance rates, and collecting remittances.").
-
-
-
-
255
-
-
79959968785
-
-
Id. at 246-47
-
Id. at 246-47 ("Four-fifths of the cartels set a common price and/or allocated markets, and slightly more than one-half centralized export distribution through a common sales agency.");
-
-
-
-
256
-
-
79960017146
-
-
13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 2132
-
see also 13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 2132 (discussing how those participating in a market will necessarily have to agree about many things, some of which can be regarded as price-affecting or output-limiting, such as jointly made pricing rules and joint selling).
-
-
-
-
258
-
-
79959976691
-
-
Id. at 146-47. 170
-
Id. at 146-47. 170.
-
-
-
-
259
-
-
79960008811
-
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 621
-
See Leslie, supra note 73, at 621 (discussing other examples of cartels employing a joint sales agency);
-
-
-
-
260
-
-
79960008199
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 100, at 825-26
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 100, at 825-26 (noting cartel's use of a combination of joint sales agency and joint venture).
-
-
-
-
262
-
-
47049099762
-
-
467 U.S. 752, 763 & n.7
-
On the relevance of the status of Appalachian Coals as a corporation independent of its coal producer constituents, see Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 763 & n.7 (1984).
-
(1984)
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.
-
-
-
263
-
-
79959948391
-
-
288 U.S.
-
Appalachian Coals, 288 U.S. at 357-58.
-
Appalachian Coals
, pp. 357-358
-
-
-
264
-
-
79959991318
-
-
Id. at 358
-
Id. at 358.
-
-
-
-
265
-
-
79959960712
-
-
id. at 360
-
See id. at 360.
-
-
-
-
266
-
-
79959979474
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69 (noting that the joint sales agency "eliminates the possibility that individual firms will engage in secret cheating").
-
-
-
-
267
-
-
79959930470
-
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 621, 634. 178
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 621, 634. 178.
-
-
-
-
268
-
-
79959938079
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69.
-
-
-
-
269
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2215
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2215 (2010).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
270
-
-
79960004584
-
-
Id. at 2207
-
Id. at 2207 (noting that prior to 2000 the licenses had been nonexclusive, but in December of 2000 the teams authorized NFLP to grant exclusive licenses).
-
-
-
-
271
-
-
79959984316
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69 (cartels that used joint sales agencies "were among the more successful cartels").
-
-
-
-
272
-
-
79959938080
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 256
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 256.
-
-
-
-
273
-
-
79959974099
-
-
Id. at 275
-
Id. at 275.
-
-
-
-
274
-
-
84977280604
-
The cartelization of world commodity markets
-
157
-
Robert S. Pindyck, The Cartelization of World Commodity Markets, 69 AM. ECON. REV. 154, 157 (1979).
-
(1979)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.69
, pp. 154
-
-
Pindyck, R.S.1
-
275
-
-
79959996342
-
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 241
-
Dick, supra note 94, at 241 ("Contracts in which the cartel centralized its control through a common sales agency tended to be more stable.");
-
-
-
-
276
-
-
79959920475
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 69 ("Cartels that control the distribution of goods, through a joint sales agency or some other mechanism, appear to be more stable.").
-
-
-
-
277
-
-
0003729109
-
-
See DEBORA L. SPAR, THE COOPERATIVE EDGE 53 (1994) ("It is generally understood, however, that DeBeers insists on being both the sole purchaser and the price setter and that the CSO is the sole distributor.");
-
(1994)
The Cooperative Edge
, pp. 53
-
-
Spar, D.L.1
-
278
-
-
79960012855
-
Debeers may be losing grip on diamond market
-
Sept. 3
-
see aiso Bill Keller, DeBeers May Be Losing Grip on Diamond Market, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 3, 1992, at Al.
-
(1992)
N.Y. Times
-
-
Keller, B.1
-
279
-
-
0000079986
-
Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry
-
119
-
Lisa Bernstein, Opting out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115, 119 (1992).
-
(1992)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.21
, pp. 115
-
-
Bernstein, L.1
-
280
-
-
79959984886
-
The diamond cartel
-
1407
-
One mid-century report explained part of the corporate structure of the diamond cartel as follows: The diamond industry's marketing system, and DeBeers' dominant position in it, became fully established in the early 1930's with the creation of three new corporate entities-the Diamond Trading Corporation, Ltd., the Diamond Producers Association, Ltd., and the Diamond Trading Company, Ltd. - all controlled by DeBeers. The Diamond Corporation holds exclusive contracts for the purchase of the alluvial diamond production of Western and Central Africa. The Diamond Producers Association functions as the sole purchaser of South African diamonds. Both the Diamond Corporation and Diamond Producers Association sell their diamonds exclusively to the Diamond Trading Company, which is thus the single distributing agency for ninety-seven percent of the African diamond production. Note, The Diamond Cartel, 56 YALE L.J. 1404, 1407 (1947).
-
(1947)
Yale L.J.
, vol.56
, pp. 1404
-
-
-
281
-
-
79960007574
-
-
Bernstein, supra note 187, at 121
-
Bernstein, supra note 187, at 121.
-
-
-
-
282
-
-
79959980067
-
-
Note, supra note 187, at 1408-09
-
Note, supra note 187, at 1408-09.
-
-
-
-
283
-
-
79959924170
-
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 71
-
Levenstein & Suslow, supra note 52, at 71.
-
-
-
-
285
-
-
79959993073
-
-
Id. at 769
-
Id. at 769.
-
-
-
-
286
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2209
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2209 (2010).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
287
-
-
79959949538
-
-
Id. at 2210
-
Id. at 2210 ("We have similarly looked past the form of a legally 'single entity' when competitors were part of professional organizations or trade groups.").
-
-
-
-
288
-
-
79959968187
-
-
Id. at 2212
-
Id. at 2212.
-
-
-
-
289
-
-
79960024393
-
-
Id. at 2213
-
Id. at 2213.
-
-
-
-
290
-
-
79960028082
-
-
Id. at 2212
-
Id. at 2212.
-
-
-
-
291
-
-
79959972382
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
292
-
-
78049294773
-
-
525 U.S. 128
-
See, e.g., Nynex Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128 (1998) (purely vertical boycott to be governed under rule of reason).
-
(1998)
Nynex Corp. v. Discon, Inc.
-
-
-
293
-
-
79960000686
-
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 27
-
CONNOR, supra note 125, at 27.
-
-
-
-
295
-
-
79959963561
-
-
538 F.3d 736, 743 7th Cir.
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 538 F.3d 736, 743 (7th Cir. 2008),
-
(2008)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
296
-
-
79960027508
-
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010)
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010);
-
-
-
-
297
-
-
79952062680
-
-
991 F.2d 1389, 1397 8th Cir.
-
see also Int'l Travel Arrangers v. NWA, Inc., 991 F.2d 1389, 1397 (8th Cir. 1993) (jury instruction stated: "Where the entities possess an inherent unity of economic interest and purpose, they are not separate entities capable of conspiring").
-
(1993)
Int'l Travel Arrangers v. NWA, Inc.
-
-
-
298
-
-
79959970067
-
-
538 F.3d at 737
-
538 F.3d at 737,
-
-
-
-
299
-
-
79959955407
-
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010)
-
rev'd, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010).
-
-
-
-
300
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2213
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2213 (2010)
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
301
-
-
0347340521
-
Exclusive joint ventures and antitrust policy
-
52-61
-
(citing Herbert Hovenkamp, Exclusive Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy, 1995 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 52-61;
-
Colum. Bus. L. Rev.
, vol.1995
, pp. 1
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
302
-
-
0038968237
-
Conflicts of interest and fiduciary duties in the operation of a joint venture
-
69-81
-
Zenichi Shishido, Conflicts of Interest and Fiduciary Duties in the Operation of a Joint Venture, 39 HASTINGS L.J. 63, 69-81 (1987)).
-
(1987)
Hastings L.J.
, vol.39
, pp. 63
-
-
Shishido, Z.1
-
303
-
-
79959948913
-
-
Id. at 2214
-
Id. at 2214.
-
-
-
-
304
-
-
79960021969
-
-
Id.
-
Id. ("The justification for cooperation is not relevant to whether that cooperation is concerted or independent action.").
-
-
-
-
305
-
-
79959965049
-
-
Id. at 2213
-
Id. at 2213 ("But illegal restraints often are in the common interests of the parties to the restraint, at the expense of those who are not parties.").
-
-
-
-
306
-
-
79960021395
-
-
Id. at 2215 n.6
-
Id. at 2215 n.6
-
-
-
-
309
-
-
79959969382
-
-
infra notes 262-269 and accompanying text
-
See infra notes 262-269 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
310
-
-
79959952866
-
-
Dagher, 547 U.S. at 7
-
Dagher, 547 U.S. at 7.
-
-
-
-
311
-
-
79960019861
-
-
156 F.3d 452, 456 3d Cir.
-
Occasionally concerted refusals to deal and similar tactics are used to coerce firms into joining a cartel, but these are themselves actionable under the antitrust laws. See, e.g., Rossi v. Standard Roofing, Inc., 156 F.3d 452, 456 (3d Cir. 1998) (members of roofing cartel conspired to deny price cutter access to materials);
-
(1998)
Rossi v. Standard Roofing, Inc.
-
-
-
312
-
-
79960021394
-
-
8 F.3d 1217, 1219-20 7th Cir.
-
Denny's Marina v. Renfro Prods., 8 F.3d 1217, 1219-20 (7th Cir. 1993) (defendant boat sellers conspired to deny price cutting seller access to annual boat show).
-
(1993)
Denny's Marina v. Renfro Prods.
-
-
-
313
-
-
33846567255
-
-
509 U.S. 764, 770-78
-
This was also a fair reading of the claim in Hartford Fire Insurance Co. v. California, 509 U.S. 764, 770-78 (1993), namely, that the defendant insurers
-
(1993)
Hartford Fire Insurance Co. v. California
-
-
-
314
-
-
79960013523
-
-
13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 2201
-
See generally 13 HOVENKAMP, supra note 22, ¶ 2201 (discussing several cases in which concerted refusal to deal with respect to one transaction in order to get the target to change its behavior with respect to another and unrelated transaction was subject to legal action under antitrust laws).
-
-
-
-
315
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2215
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2215 (2010)
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
316
-
-
0347340521
-
Exclusive joint ventures and antitrust policy
-
52-61
-
(citing Herbert Hovenkamp, Exclusive Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy, 1995 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 1, 52-61).
-
Colum. Bus. L. Rev.
, vol.1995
, pp. 1
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
317
-
-
79955455211
-
-
Brief for the NFL Respondents at *7, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (No. 08661), 2009 WL 3865438
-
Brief for the NFL Respondents at *7, Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201 (2010) (No. 08-661), 2009 WL 3865438.
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL
-
-
-
318
-
-
79959987164
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
319
-
-
79959918679
-
-
130 S. Ct.
-
Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2209
-
Am. Needle
, pp. 2209
-
-
-
321
-
-
79959977883
-
-
On Sealy, see infra the discussion accompanying notes 222-42
-
On Sealy, see infra the discussion accompanying notes 222-42.
-
-
-
-
325
-
-
57149104413
-
-
326 U.S. 1, 26 (Frankfurter, J., concurring)
-
Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1, 26 (1945) (Frankfurter, J., concurring);
-
(1945)
Associated Press v. United States
-
-
-
327
-
-
79960009410
-
-
130 S. Ct.
-
Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2213 ("The NFL respondents may be similar in some sense to a single enterprise that owns several pieces of intellectual property and licenses them jointly, but they are not similar in the relevant functional sense. Although NFL teams have common interests such as promoting the NFL brand, they are still separate, profit-maximizing entities, and their interests in licensing team trademarks are not necessarily aligned.").
-
Am. Needle
, pp. 2213
-
-
-
328
-
-
79959946060
-
-
Id. at 2207. 219
-
Id. at 2207. 219.
-
-
-
-
329
-
-
79952058106
-
-
394 U.S. 131, 134-36
-
See Citizen Publ'g Co. v. United States, 394 U.S. 131, 134-36 (1969) (holding that agreement between the only two newspapers in the county to jointly set their subscription and advertising rates, pool their profits, and refrain from engaging in business that competed with the newspapers was illegal for violating Section One);
-
(1969)
Citizen Publ'g Co. v. United States
-
-
-
330
-
-
79959950725
-
-
94 F. Supp. 2d 399, 422 S.D.N.Y.
-
Spitzer v. St. Francis Hosp., 94 F. Supp. 2d 399, 422 (S.D.N.Y. 2000) (holding that agreement between hospitals to fix rates, terms and conditions for services and allocating markets violated Section One);
-
(2000)
Spitzer v. St. Francis Hosp
-
-
-
331
-
-
79959942447
-
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 645-46
-
Leslie, supra note 73, at 645-46 (discussing how those wishing to withdraw from price-fixing conspiracies should confess so as to avoid antitrust liability still attached to the agreement).
-
-
-
-
332
-
-
79959996341
-
-
supra notes 191-201 and accompanying text. 221
-
See supra notes 191-201 and accompanying text. 221. Under the Supreme Court's Leegin decision, which adopted a rule of reason for resale price maintenance, a horizontal agreement among dealers in a single brand to fix prices could be treated under the per se rule, while a vertical agreement between a supplier and its dealers facilitating such a cartel would be treated under the rule of reason. Both, however, would be treated as collaborative activity.
-
-
-
-
333
-
-
76649105370
-
-
551 U.S. 877, 893
-
See Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 893 (2007) ("A horizontal cartel among competing manufacturers or competing retailers that decreases output or reduces competition in order to increase price is, and ought to be, per se unlawful . . . . To the extent a vertical agreement setting minimum resale prices is entered upon to facilitate either type of cartel, it, too, would need to be held unlawful under the rule of reason.") (citations omitted);
-
(2007)
Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.
-
-
-
334
-
-
79959919299
-
-
530 F.3d 204, 217, 225 3d Cir.
-
see also Toledo Mack Sales & Serv., Inc. v. Mack Trucks, Inc., 530 F.3d 204, 217, 225 (3d Cir. 2008) (relying on this passage to deny summary judgment on complaint that a truck manufacturer maintained resale prices at the behest of a cartel of its dealers).
-
(2008)
Toledo Mack Sales & Serv., Inc. v. Mack Trucks, Inc.
-
-
-
335
-
-
78049242597
-
-
130 S. Ct.
-
Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2216-17 (finding conspiratorial capacity and remanding for consideration of the restraint under the rule of reason).
-
Am. Needle
, pp. 2216-2217
-
-
-
337
-
-
79960014139
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
338
-
-
79959918100
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
339
-
-
49249133863
-
Categorical analysis in antitrust jurisprudence
-
See Mark A. Lemley & Christopher R. Leslie, Categorical Analysis in Antitrust Jurisprudence, 93 IOWA L. REV. 1207 (2008) (questioning the value of the Sealy horizontal versus vertical debate).
-
(2008)
Iowa L. Rev.
, vol.93
, pp. 1207
-
-
Lemley, M.A.1
Leslie, C.R.2
-
340
-
-
79959962363
-
-
7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 1463
-
On such findings prior to Copperweld, see 7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶ 1463 (discussing Supreme Court intraenterprise cases from Yellow Cab to Copperweld).
-
-
-
-
341
-
-
79952214772
-
-
Brief for Appellee, Sealy, Inc. at 6, 388 U.S. 350 (No. 9), 1966 WL 100609 [hereinafter Sealy Respondent Brief]
-
Brief for Appellee, Sealy, Inc. at 6, United States v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350 (1967) (No. 9), 1966 WL 100609 [hereinafter Sealy Respondent Brief];
-
(1967)
United States v. Sealy, Inc.
-
-
-
342
-
-
79959969381
-
-
id. at 21
-
see also id. at 21 ("Sealy's separate existence as a profitable enterprise operated for its overall best interests, and not as a mere instrumentality or creature of its licensees.").
-
-
-
-
343
-
-
79959974662
-
-
Id. at 31
-
Id. at 31.
-
-
-
-
344
-
-
40749084517
-
-
Transcript of Oral Argument at 45, 388 U.S. 350 (No. 9) [hereinafter Sealy Transcript]
-
Richard W. McLaren, Transcript of Oral Argument at 45, United States v. Sealy, 388 U.S. 350 (1967) (No. 9) [hereinafter Sealy Transcript] (arguing that Simmons is "an integrated firm; and that's one of the points we argue: Why should a licensee manufacturer under a trademark have to go out and compete with other people under that trademark when a brand owner, he doesn't?");
-
(1967)
United States v. Sealy
-
-
McLaren, R.W.1
-
345
-
-
79959921960
-
-
id.
-
id. ("And that's a basic issue in this case: Does a licensee trademark manufacturer have the same sort of rights as a trademark owner, or is he some sort of second-class citizen where he has to compete against other people manufacturing under the same brand?").
-
-
-
-
346
-
-
79959930469
-
-
Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. at 352
-
Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. at 352 ("If we look at substance rather than form, there is little room for debate. These must be classified as horizontal restraints.").
-
-
-
-
347
-
-
79959937483
-
-
Id. at 356
-
Id. at 356.
-
-
-
-
348
-
-
79960001278
-
-
Id. at 352
-
Id. at 352.
-
-
-
-
349
-
-
79952214772
-
-
Brief for the United States at 7, 388 U.S. 350 (No. 9), 1966 WL 100610 [hereinafter Sealy Petitioner Brief]
-
Brief for the United States at 7, United States v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350 (1967) (No. 9), 1966 WL 100610 [hereinafter Sealy Petitioner Brief].
-
(1967)
United States v. Sealy, Inc.
-
-
-
350
-
-
79959969380
-
-
United States v. Sealy, Inc., Motion to Affirm at 29, available at 1955 Term - 1975 Term, Philip B. Kurland & Gerhard Casper, eds.
-
United States v. Sealy, Inc., Motion to Affirm at 29, available at 21 ANTITRUST LAW: MAJOR BRIEFS AND ORAL ARGUMENTS OF THE SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES, 1955 Term - 1975 Term, at 815 (Philip B. Kurland & Gerhard Casper, eds., 1979) (emphasis in original).
-
(1979)
Antitrust Law: Major Briefs and Oral Arguments of the Supreme Court of the United States
, vol.21
, pp. 815
-
-
-
351
-
-
79959995232
-
-
Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. at 351
-
Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. at 351.
-
-
-
-
352
-
-
79959940099
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
353
-
-
79959958945
-
-
id. at 355-56 (1967)
-
see also id. at 355-56 (1967) ("Appellee has not appealed the order of the District Court enjoining continuation of this price-fixing, but the existence and impact of the practice cannot be ignored in our appraisal of the territorial limitations. In the first place, this flagrant and pervasive price-fixing, in obvious violation of the law, was, as the trial court found, the activity of the 'stockholder representatives' acting through and in collaboration with Sealy mechanisms.").
-
-
-
-
356
-
-
79960017736
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
357
-
-
79960022532
-
-
supra notes 111-14 and accompanying text
-
See supra notes 111-14 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
358
-
-
79959987411
-
-
supra note 231
-
Daniel Friedman, Sealy Transcript, supra note 231, at 7 (citing specific instances).
-
Sealy Transcript
, pp. 7
-
-
Friedman, D.1
-
359
-
-
79959937484
-
-
supra note 229, 245
-
Sealy Respondent Brief, supra note 229, at 21. 245.
-
Sealy Respondent Brief
, pp. 21
-
-
-
360
-
-
79959961795
-
-
Id. at 21-22
-
Id. at 21-22.
-
-
-
-
361
-
-
79960020794
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
363
-
-
79959923742
-
-
Id. at 353
-
Id. at 353.
-
-
-
-
365
-
-
79959960711
-
-
id. at 24
-
id. at 24 ("Sealy . . . is not an independent firm responsive to interests other than those of its licensees. It is completely dominated by the licensees.").
-
-
-
-
366
-
-
79959987411
-
-
supra note 231
-
See Daniel Friedman, Sealy Transcript, supra note 231, at 4 ("[Licensees are] independent in the sense that they're not controlled by Sealy. And they're also independent in the sense that each one makes its own judgments as to how best exploit his particular market.")
-
Sealy Transcript
, pp. 4
-
-
Friedman, D.1
-
367
-
-
79959951874
-
-
Leslie, Cartels, supra note 149, at 1638
-
See Leslie, Cartels, supra note 149, at 1638 ("Each firm makes an independent decision as to whether joining or remaining in a cartel is in the firm's own best interest.").
-
-
-
-
368
-
-
79959991317
-
-
Id. at 596
-
Id. at 596.
-
-
-
-
369
-
-
79959926009
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
370
-
-
79959941273
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
371
-
-
79959936869
-
-
Id. at 612
-
Id. at 612.
-
-
-
-
372
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2215
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2215 (2010).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. V. NFL
-
-
-
373
-
-
79959941863
-
-
Id. at 2210
-
Id. at 2210.
-
-
-
-
374
-
-
79959973518
-
-
Topco Assoc., Inc., 405 U.S. at 598
-
Topco Assoc., Inc., 405 U.S. at 598.
-
-
-
-
375
-
-
79959997250
-
-
11 HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW, supra note 22, ¶ 1910c2
-
See 11 HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST LAW, supra note 22, ¶ 1910c2 (criticizing the Topeo Court's application of a per se rule against horizontal territorial restraints);
-
-
-
-
376
-
-
79959922557
-
-
id. ¶ 2033b
-
id. ¶ 2033b (criticizing the Court's classification of the restraints in Sealy and Topco as "vertical");
-
-
-
-
377
-
-
79959920474
-
-
id. ¶ 2134c
-
id. ¶ 2134c (criticizing the use of the per se rule in Sealy and Topco);
-
-
-
-
378
-
-
79952214772
-
-
388 U.S. 350, 361 n.2
-
see also United States v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350, 361 n.2 (Harlan J., dissenting) (discussing the lack of market power in Sealy)
-
United States V. Sealy, Inc.
-
-
-
379
-
-
79959931592
-
-
Topco, 405 U.S. at 600
-
Topco, 405 U.S. at 600 (discussing same in Topco;) .
-
-
-
-
380
-
-
79952216877
-
-
792 F.2d 210, 224 D.C. Cir
-
Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc., 792 F.2d 210, 224 (D.C. Cir. 1986) (applying this approach to a nationwide moving company, which was owned by local moving companies and that imposed geographic restraints on the latter
-
(1986)
Rothery Storage & Van Co. V. Atlas Van Lines, Inc.
-
-
-
381
-
-
79952233717
-
-
776 F.2d 185 7th Cir
-
); Polk Bros., Inc. v. Forest City Enter., Inc., 776 F.2d 185 (7th Cir. 1985) (applying this approach to an ancillary market division agreement in a shopping mall).
-
(1985)
Polk Bros., Inc. V. Forest City Enter., Inc.
-
-
-
383
-
-
79959947216
-
-
Id. at 6
-
Id. at 6.
-
-
-
-
384
-
-
79959984315
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
386
-
-
79959993442
-
-
Id. at 7
-
Id. at 7.
-
-
-
-
387
-
-
79959998977
-
-
Id. at 5
-
Id. at 5.
-
-
-
-
388
-
-
79960022531
-
-
Id. at 7
-
Id. at 7.
-
-
-
-
389
-
-
79955455211
-
-
130 S. Ct. 2201, 2212
-
Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 130 S. Ct. 2201, 2212 (2010).
-
(2010)
Am. Needle, Inc. V. NFL
-
-
-
390
-
-
79960009409
-
-
Dagher, 547 U.S. at 6
-
Dagher, 547 U.S. at 6.
-
-
-
-
391
-
-
79959951873
-
-
Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2214-15
-
See Am. Needle, 130 S. Ct. at 2214-15 ("Apart from their agreement to cooperate in exploiting those assets, including their decisions as NFLP, there would be nothing to prevent each of the teams from making its own market decisions relating to purchases of apparel and headwear, to the sale of such items, and to the granting of licenses to use its trademarks.").
-
-
-
-
393
-
-
79959931012
-
-
Id. at 960-61
-
Id. at 960-61.
-
-
-
-
394
-
-
79959931013
-
-
id.
-
See, e.g., id. (addressing whether Visa's refusal to admit Sears to its joint venture restrains trade in violation of Section One of the Sherman Act).
-
-
-
-
395
-
-
79959930468
-
-
Id.
-
Id. (refusing to condemn exclusivity rules that enabled Visa and MasterCard to be issued by one another's banks but excluded rival cards such as Discover and American Express; to the extent it is relevant, one of the authors was consulted by the plaintiff).
-
-
-
-
396
-
-
78650811154
-
-
344 F.3d 229, 238 n.4 2d Cir
-
United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 344 F.3d 229, 238 n.4 (2d Cir. 2003) (condemning governance duality and exclusivity rules under rule of reason; to the extent it is relevant, one of the authors was consulted by the government);
-
(2003)
United States V. Visa U.S.A., Inc.
-
-
-
397
-
-
79959953438
-
-
No. 04-CV-7844, 2008 WL 4067445 S.D.N.Y. Aug. 26
-
see also Discover Fin. Servs. v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., No. 04-CV-7844, 2008 WL 4067445 (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 26, 2008) (denying summary judgment on claim by Discover, issuer of a rival card).
-
(2008)
Discover Fin. Servs. V. Visa U.S.A., Inc.
-
-
-
400
-
-
78650702033
-
-
280 F.3d 124, 130 2d Cir
-
In re Visa Check/MasterMoney Antitrust Litig., 280 F.3d 124, 130 (2d Cir. 2001) (certifying class action by large retailers).
-
(2001)
Visa Check/MasterMoney Antitrust Litig.
-
-
-
402
-
-
21844489932
-
The antitrust economics of credit card networks
-
Dennis W. Carlton & Alan Frankel, The Antitrust Economics of Credit Card Networks, 63 ANTITRUST L.J. 643 (1995) (discussing the potential for anticompetitive harm to result from collective action by members of credit card joint ventures);
-
(1995)
Antitrust L.J.
, vol.63
, pp. 643
-
-
Carlton, D.W.1
Frankel, A.2
-
403
-
-
49449099735
-
Priceless? the economic costs of credit card merchant restraints
-
Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Economic Costs of Credit Card Merchant Restraints, 55 UCLA L. REV. 1321 (2008) (arguing that merchant restraints should be banned as antitrust violations);
-
(2008)
Ucla L. Rev.
, vol.55
, pp. 1321
-
-
Levitin, A.J.1
-
404
-
-
79959991884
-
Payment card regulation and the (Mis)application of the economics of two-sided markets
-
517-18
-
Timothy J. Muris, Payment Card Regulation and the (Mis)Application of the Economics of Two-Sided Markets, 2005 COLUM. Bus. L. REV. 515, 517-18 (discussing the economics of two-sided markets);
-
Colum. Bus. L. Rev.
, vol.2005
, pp. 515
-
-
Muris, T.J.1
-
405
-
-
0036993844
-
Cooperation among competitors: Some economics of payment card associations
-
Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Cooperation Among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations, 33 RAND J. ECON. 549 (2002) (analyzing the cooperative determination of the interchange fee by member banks in a payment card association);
-
(2002)
Rand J. Econ.
, vol.33
, pp. 549
-
-
Rochet, J.-C.1
Tirole, J.2
-
406
-
-
0040763498
-
The economics of credit cards
-
Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, 3 CHAP. L. REV. 79 (2000) (dismissing the link between credit cards and the bankruptcy crisis);
-
(2000)
Chap. L. Rev.
, vol.3
, pp. 79
-
-
Zywicki, T.J.1
-
408
-
-
79959998976
-
-
George Mason Law & Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 10-26
-
Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees and the Limits of Regulation (George Mason Law & Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 10-26, 2010), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/so13/papers.cfm?abstract-id= 1624002 (arguing against interchange fee regulation);
-
(2010)
The Economics of Payment Card Interchange Fees and the Limits of Regulation
-
-
Zywicki, T.J.1
-
410
-
-
79952971065
-
The mastercard IPO: Protecting the priceless brand
-
145
-
Victor Fleischer, The MasterCard IPO: Protecting the Priceless Brand, 12 HARV. NEGOT. L. REV. 137, 145 (2007) (tracing development of MasterCard IPO);
-
(2007)
Harv. Negot. L. Rev.
, vol.12
, pp. 137
-
-
Fleischer, V.1
-
411
-
-
77950563870
-
Payment wars: The merchant-bank struggle for control of payment systems
-
463-67
-
see also Adam J. Levitin, Payment Wars: The Merchant-Bank Struggle for Control of Payment Systems, 12 STAN. J.L. Bus. & FIN. 425, 463-67 (2007).
-
(2007)
Stan. J.L. Bus. & Fin.
, vol.12
, pp. 425
-
-
Levitin, A.J.1
-
412
-
-
41849096183
-
-
AEI-Brookings Joint Ctr. for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 06-03
-
See generally Robert E. Litan & Alex J. Pollock, The Future of Charge Card Networks 6 (AEI-Brookings Joint Ctr. for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 06-03, 2006) (discussing the reorganization of MasterCard and Visa). MasterCard, Inc. trades on the New York Stock Exchange under the symbol "MA," and Visa, Inc. trades under the symbol "V."
-
(2006)
The Future of Charge Card Networks
, vol.6
-
-
Litan, R.E.1
Pollock, A.J.2
-
413
-
-
79959936397
-
-
Fleischer, supra note 279, at 145
-
Fleischer, supra note 279, at 145.
-
-
-
-
414
-
-
79959947215
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
415
-
-
79959939212
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
416
-
-
79959992471
-
-
Visa, Inc., (Form DEF 14A), Dec. 1
-
Visa, Inc., Proxy Statement (Form DEF 14A), at 26 (Dec. 1, 2009), available at http://investor.visa.com/phoenix.zhtml?c=215693&p=proxy (explaining that class B and C shares have no voting rights). In the Visa, Inc. IPO, Class B shareholders are financial institutions issuing Visa cards in the United States, while Class C shares are similar institutions in Canada.
-
(2009)
Proxy Statement
, pp. 26
-
-
-
417
-
-
79959932198
-
-
See GOLDMAN SACHS FIN. INST. GROUP, VISA IPO (2008), http://www. sharpeinvesting.com/2008/01/visa-ipo-goldman-sachs-financial-institutions-group. html (discussing Visa's organization as an IPO).
-
(2008)
Goldman Sachs Fin. Inst. Group, Visa IPO
-
-
-
418
-
-
34250024408
-
The mythical benefits of shareholder control
-
802-03
-
In the Google, Inc. IPO, Class A shares were entitled to one vote each but class B shares received ten votes. See Lynn A. Stout, The Mythical Benefits of Shareholder Control, 93 VA. L. REV. 789, 802-03 (2007) (describing Google structure as leaving outside investors largely powerless).
-
(2007)
Va. L. Rev.
, vol.93
, pp. 789
-
-
Stout, L.A.1
-
419
-
-
68349144499
-
How are U.S. family firms controlled?
-
3066
-
Belen Villalonga & Raphael Amit, How Are U.S. Family Firms Controlled?, 22 REV. FIN. STUD. 3047, 3066 (2009) (noting that as of 1998, the Ford family owned six percent of shares but controlled forty percent of votes).
-
(2009)
Rev. Fin. Stud.
, vol.22
, pp. 3047
-
-
Villalonga, B.1
Amit, R.2
-
420
-
-
79959941862
-
-
supra note 279
-
Some authors have noted that this was very likely an intended result of the switch from a joint venture to a corporate structure. In addition to Fleischer, supra note 279,
-
-
-
-
421
-
-
79959957165
-
The mastercard IPO: Mastercard's single entity strategy
-
see Joshua D. Wright, The MasterCard IPO: MasterCard's Single Entity Strategy, 12 HARV. NEGOT. L. REV. 225 (2007) (expanding on Fleischer's analysis of the antitrust implications of MasterCard's new governance structure).
-
(2007)
Harv. Negot. L. Rev.
, vol.12
, pp. 225
-
-
Wright, J.D.1
-
422
-
-
78650811154
-
-
344 F.3d 229, 238 n.4 2d Cir
-
See United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 344 F.3d 229, 238 n.4 (2d Cir. 2003) (analyzing the government's claim under a rule of reason);
-
(2003)
United States V. Visa U.S.A., Inc.
-
-
-
425
-
-
79959937482
-
-
3B AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶¶ 772-73
-
see also 3B AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 20, ¶¶ 772-73 (discussing unUateral refusals to deal and "essential facility" doctrine).
-
-
-
-
426
-
-
79960016560
-
-
Inc., 779 F.2d 592 11th Cir
-
See, e.g., Nat'l Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 779 F.2d 592 (11th Cir. 1986) (applying rule of reason analysis instead of per se analysis to Visa's conduct).
-
(1986)
Nat'l Bancard Corp. (NaBanco) V. Visa U.S.A.
-
-
-
427
-
-
79959650806
-
Unilaterally imposed tying arrangements and antitrust's concerted action requirement
-
Christopher R. Leslie, Unilaterally Imposed Tying Arrangements and Antitrust's Concerted Action Requirement, 60 OHIO ST. L.J. 1773 (1999) (arguing that most tying arrangements are essentially unilateral).
-
(1999)
Ohio St. L.J.
, vol.60
, pp. 1773
-
-
Leslie, C.R.1
-
428
-
-
79959997834
-
Tying conspiracies
-
Christopher R. Leslie, Tying Conspiracies, 48 WM. & MARY L. REV. 2247 (2007) (advocating per se illegality for tying conspiracies).
-
(2007)
Wm. & Mary L. Rev.
, vol.48
, pp. 2247
-
-
Leslie, C.R.1
-
429
-
-
79960015930
-
-
Fleischer, supra note 279
-
See Fleischer, supra note 279 (making this argument about the MasterCard IPO).
-
-
-
|