메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 86, Issue 2, 2011, Pages 499-542

Coase, institutionalism, and the origins of law and economics

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79952587676     PISSN: 00196665     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (13)

References (409)
  • 1
    • 0003774434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 6th ed. noting that the "new law and economics" began with Ronald Coase's The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960) [hereinafter Coase, Problem of Social Cost]
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 23 (6th ed. 2003) (noting that the "new law and economics" began with Ronald Coase's The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960) [hereinafter Coase, Problem of Social Cost],
    • (2003) Economic Analysis of Law , pp. 23
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 2
    • 0000670301 scopus 로고
    • Some thoughts on risk distribution and the law of torts
    • and Guido Calabresi's Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts, 70 YALE L.J. 499 (1961)).
    • (1961) Yale L.J. , vol.70 , pp. 499
    • Calabresi'S, G.1
  • 3
    • 0042688399 scopus 로고
    • Economics at LSE in the 1930s: A Personal View
    • See RONALD H. COASE, Economics at LSE in the 1930s: A Personal View, in ESSAYS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMISTS 208 (1994) [hereinafter COASE, Economics at LSE];
    • (1994) Essays on Economics and Economists , pp. 208
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 4
    • 34250230292 scopus 로고
    • The distinctive LSE ethos in the inter-war years
    • 21
    • see also A.W. Coats, The Distinctive LSE Ethos in the Inter-War Years, 10 ATLANTIC ECON. J. 18, 21(1982).
    • (1982) Atlantic Econ. J. , vol.10 , pp. 18
    • Coats, A.W.1
  • 5
    • 79952594333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lord Lionel Robbins was chair of political economy at LSE from 1929 until 1961. Coase described Robbins as the most influential figure of all at LSE in the 1930s. COASE, Economics at LSE
    • Lord Lionel Robbins was chair of political economy at LSE from 1929 until 1961. Coase described Robbins as "the most influential figure of all" at LSE in the 1930s. COASE, Economics at LSE,
  • 6
    • 79952582319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 211
    • supra note 2, at 211;
  • 10
    • 5844339983 scopus 로고
    • On the demise of pigovian economics
    • See Nahid Aslanbeigui, On the Demise of Pigovian Economics, 56 S. ECON. J. 616 (1990);
    • (1990) S. Econ. J. , vol.56 , pp. 616
    • Aslanbeigui, N.1
  • 11
    • 77949545739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robbins welfare economics: A reappraisal
    • On the relationships of Pigou, Robbins, and Coase, see Nahid Aslanbeigui, Introduction to ARTHUR CECIL PIGOU, THE ECONOMICS OF WELFARE, at li-lx (Transaction Publishers 2002) (1932)
    • Roger E. Backhouse, Robbins and Welfare Economics: A Reappraisal, 31 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 474 (2009). On the relationships of Pigou, Robbins, and Coase, see Nahid Aslanbeigui, Introduction to ARTHUR CECIL PIGOU, THE ECONOMICS OF WELFARE, at li-lx (Transaction Publishers 2002) (1932);
    • (2009) J. Hist. Econ. Thought , vol.31 , pp. 474
    • Backhouse, R.E.1
  • 12
    • 0347173914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond the dark clouds: Pigou and coase on social cost
    • Nahid Aslanbeigui & Steven G. Medema, Beyond the Dark Clouds: Pigou and Coase on Social Cost, 30 HIST. POL. ECON. 601 (1998);
    • (1998) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.30 , pp. 601
    • Aslanbeigui, N.1    Medema, S.G.2
  • 13
    • 79251600688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The coase theorem and arthur cecil pigou
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Coase Theorem and Arthur Cecil Pigou, 51 ARIZ. L. REV. 633 (2009) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Coase Theorem];
    • (2009) Ariz. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 633
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 15
    • 79952298986 scopus 로고
    • Alfred marshall and the establishment of the cambridge economic tripos
    • see Peter D. Groenewegen, Alfred Marshall and the Establishment of the Cambridge Economic Tripos, 20 HIST. POL. ECON. 627(1988).
    • (1988) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.20 , pp. 627
    • Groenewegen, P.D.1
  • 16
    • 84917106186 scopus 로고
    • The nature of the firm: Origin
    • Coase took a Bachelor of Commerce degree at LSE in 1932 and was on its teaching staff from 1935 to 1951, except for an assignment as a government statistician during World War II; he also made a visit to the United States in 1931 and 1932, where he collected observations for his article The Nature of the Firm. See R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm: Origin, 4 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 3 (1988) [hereinafter Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin].
    • (1988) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.4 , pp. 3
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 17
    • 0344355338 scopus 로고
    • Introductory: LSE and the robbins circle
    • Harvard Univ. Press
    • For a good history of the principal faculty and most famous students at LSE, see the website at http://homepage.newschool.edU/het//schools/lse.htm. For John Hicks's perspective, see JOHN HICKS, Introductory: LSE and the Robbins Circle, in 2 MONEY, INTEREST AND WAGES: COLLECTED ESSAYS ON ECONOMIC THEORY 3 (Harvard Univ. Press 1982).
    • (1982) Money, Interest and Wages: Collected Essays on Economic Theory , vol.2 , pp. 3
    • Hicks, J.1
  • 18
    • 79952609129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 6 (recalling that in his years at LSE as a student he took no courses in economics and spent most of his time studying law, particularly "industrial law")
    • See Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 6 (recalling that in his years at LSE as a student he took no courses in economics and spent most of his time studying law, particularly "industrial law").
  • 19
    • 79952604853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronald H. Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, The Institutional Structure of Production (Dec. 9, 1991) [hereinafter Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture]
    • See, e.g., Ronald H. Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, The Institutional Structure of Production (Dec. 9, 1991) [hereinafter Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture], available at http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/1991/coase- lecture.html;
  • 20
    • 0242278700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new institutional economics
    • see also Ronald Coase, The New Institutional Economics, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 72 (1998) [hereinafter Coase, New Institutional Economics].
    • (1998) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 72
    • Coase, R.1
  • 21
    • 69849097554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New institutional economics
    • Steven N. Durlaf & Lawrence E. Blume eds, 2d ed.
    • See L.J. Alston, New Institutional Economics, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS (Steven N. Durlaf & Lawrence E. Blume eds, 2d ed. 2008), available at http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008- N000170;
    • (2008) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
    • Alston, L.J.1
  • 25
    • 79952581725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nonetheless, the old institutionalists continue to publish journals, including The Journal of Economic Issues and the Journal of Institutional Economics. Several scholarly organizations support their work, including the Association for Evolutionary Economics
    • Nonetheless, the old institutionalists continue to publish journals, including The Journal of Economic Issues and the Journal of Institutional Economics. Several scholarly organizations support their work, including the Association for Evolutionary Economics.
  • 26
    • 79952615454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ASS'N FOR EVOLUTIONARY ECON, http://www. associationforevolutionaryeconomics.org/ divison.php?page=institutional- economics&sub=associations.
    • Ass'n for Evolutionary Econ
  • 28
    • 79952610580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 123-24
    • See infra text accompanying notes 123-24.
  • 29
    • 79952596888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part II
    • See infra Part II.
  • 30
    • 79952583897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 162-69
    • See infra text accompanying notes 162-69.
  • 31
    • 0242278700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This statement seems quite true, notwithstanding that in an essay on new institutional economics, Coase specifically acknowledged the work of our colleagues in law, anthropology, sociology, political science, sociobiology, and other disciplines Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72.
    • This statement seems quite true, notwithstanding that in an essay on new institutional economics, Coase specifically acknowledged "the work of our colleagues in law, anthropology, sociology, political science, sociobiology, and other disciplines." Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72.
  • 32
    • 79952606744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 168-69
    • See infra text accompanying notes 168-69.
  • 33
    • 79952613069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coasean markets
    • forthcoming 2011 [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets] published online Dec. 8, 2010
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, 31 EUR. J.L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2011) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets] (published online Dec. 8, 2010, available at http://www.springerlink.com/content/65031035h363gl 64/fulltext.pdf).
    • Eur. J.L. & Econ. , vol.31
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 34
    • 0001055815 scopus 로고
    • The new institutionalism: New but not institutionalist
    • See William Dugger, The New Institutionalism: New but Not Institutionalist, 24 J. ECON. ISSUES 423 (1990) (criticizing New Institutionalism for rejecting earlier commitments to behaviorism, cognition, and the study of nonmarket transfers of resources).
    • (1990) J. Econ. Issues , vol.24 , pp. 423
    • Dugger, W.1
  • 35
    • 79952595211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The sveriges riksbank prize in economic sciences in memory of alfred nobel
    • NIE's most prominent spokesperson other than Coase himself, received the Nobel Prize. Oct. 24
    • In 2009 Oliver E. Williamson, NIE's most prominent spokesperson other than Coase himself, received the Nobel Prize. The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2009, NOBELPRIZE.ORG (Oct. 24, 2010), http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/2009.
    • (2010) Nobelprize.Org , vol.2009
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 36
    • 85071381340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harvard, Chicago, and transaction cost economics in antitrust analysis
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Harvard, Chicago, and Transaction Cost Economics in Antitrust Analysis, 55 ANTITRUST BULL. 613 (2010).
    • (2010) Antitrust Bull. , vol.55 , pp. 613
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 39
    • 0012498663 scopus 로고
    • 1870-1889
    • See RICHARD S. HOWEY, THE RISE OF THE MARGINAL UTILITY SCHOOL: 1870-1889, at 1-24 (1960) (discussing the origins of marginalist neoclassical economics in the work of William Stanley Jevons in the late 1860s and 1870s).
    • (1960) The Rise of The Marginal Utility School , pp. 1-24
    • Howey, R.S.1
  • 40
    • 79952584666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally id. (tracing rise of marginalist thought in England, Continental Europe, and the United States)
    • See generally id. (tracing rise of marginalist thought in England, Continental Europe, and the United States).
  • 42
    • 79952600273 scopus 로고
    • The origins of marginalism
    • Richard S. Howey, The Origins of Marginalism, 4 HIST. POL. ECON. 281 (1972);
    • (1972) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 281
    • Howey, R.S.1
  • 43
    • 0001129346 scopus 로고
    • Development of utility theory. II
    • George J. Stigler, The Development of Utility Theory. II, 58 J. POL. ECON. 373 (1950).
    • (1950) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.58 , pp. 373
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 44
    • 79952610188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most prominent classical political economists were Adam Smith, David Ricardo, James Mill and his son John Stuart Mill, Thomas Malthus, and Jean-Baptiste Say
    • The most prominent classical political economists were Adam Smith, David Ricardo, James Mill and his son John Stuart Mill, Thomas Malthus, and Jean-Baptiste Say.
  • 45
    • 79952586200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BLAUG, supra note 10, at 33-214. On the divide between pre-marginalist and marginalist economics in United States policy
    • See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 33-214. On the divide between pre-marginalist and marginalist economics in United States policy,
  • 47
    • 84979188687 scopus 로고
    • The nature of the firm
    • 392
    • R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386, 392 (1937) [hereinafter Coase, Nature of the Firm].
    • (1937) Economica , vol.4 , pp. 386
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 48
    • 0347569357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marshall's dilemma: Equilibrium versus evolution
    • 1139
    • See Neil Hart, Marshall's Dilemma: Equilibrium Versus Evolution, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 1139, 1139-40 (2003) (discussing tension between evolutionary and engineering models in Marshall's thought).
    • (2003) J. Econ. Issues , vol.37 , pp. 1139-1140
    • Hart, N.1
  • 49
    • 0007131267 scopus 로고
    • 1867-1890, On Jevons's and Marshall's indebtedness to Cournot, see HOWEY, supra note 23, at 80-85.
    • See, e.g., 1 ALFRED MARSHALL, THE EARLY WRITINGS OF ALFRED MARSHALL, 1867-1890, at 38-39 (1975). On Jevons's and Marshall's indebtedness to Cournot, see HOWEY, supra note 23, at 80-85.
    • (1975) The Early Writings of Alfred Marshall , pp. 38-39
    • Marshall, A.1
  • 50
    • 79952577507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 277-353
    • See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 277-353.
  • 51
    • 79952582318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preference transitivity, a condition of rationality, is a logical consistency condition that if someone prefers A over B and B over C, then she must also prefer A over C
    • Preference transitivity, a condition of rationality, is a logical consistency condition that if someone prefers A over B and B over C, then she must also prefer A over C.
  • 53
    • 0000873771 scopus 로고
    • The representative firm
    • 389
    • See Lionel Robbins, The Representative Firm, 38 ECON. J. 387, 389 (1928) (noting highly abstract nature of business firm in Marshall's Principles);
    • (1928) Econ. J. , vol.38 , pp. 387
    • Robbins, L.1
  • 54
    • 5844323369 scopus 로고
    • The place of marshall's principles in the development of economics
    • John K. Whitaker ed
    • cf. George J. Stigler, The Place of Marshall's Principles in the Development of Economics, in CENTENARY ESSAYS ON ALFRED MARSHALL 8 (John K. Whitaker ed, 1990) (noting that study of the firm in price theory is largely intended to ascertain its behavior as a demander of inputs and a supplier of outputs);
    • (1990) Centenary Essays on Alfred Marshall , pp. 8
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 55
    • 14944367299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monopolization, exclusion, and the theory of the firm
    • Alan J. Meese, Monopolization, Exclusion, and the Theory of the Firm, 89 MINN. L. REV. 743 (2005) (similar).
    • (2005) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 743
    • Meese, A.J.1
  • 56
    • 0001731516 scopus 로고
    • The institutional structure of production
    • 714
    • See Ronald H. Coase, The Institutional Structure of Production, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 713, 714 (1992);
    • (1992) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 713
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 57
    • 0001763518 scopus 로고
    • The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm
    • 377
    • cf. Harold Demsetz, The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm, 26 J.L. & ECON. 375, 377 (1983) ("The chief mission of neoclassical economics [i.e., price theory] is to understand how the price system coordinates the use of resources, not to understand the inner workings of real firms.");
    • (1983) J.L. & Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 375
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 58
    • 77958132013 scopus 로고
    • The theory of the firm revisited
    • 143
    • Harold Demsetz, The Theory of the Firm Revisited, 4 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 141, 143 (1988) (noting extent to which the firm in neoclassical economics is an abstraction).
    • (1988) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.4 , pp. 141
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 61
    • 79952593713 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 388-92
    • See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 388-92.
  • 62
    • 0003542293 scopus 로고
    • See DOUGLASS C. NORTH, STRUCTURE AND CHANGE IN ECONOMIC HISTORY 5 (1981). [T]his neoclassical formulation appears to beg all of the interesting questions. The world with which it is concerned is a frictionless one in which institutions do not exist and all change occurs through perfectly operating markets. In short, the costs of acquiring information, uncertainty, and transactions costs do not exist. Id.
    • (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History , pp. 5
    • North, D.C.1
  • 63
    • 79952585767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. III, §3, at 138
    • See PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. III, §3, at 138.
  • 65
    • 77953074502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law of vertical integration and the business firm, 18801960
    • 863, [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Law of Vertical Integration]
    • see also Herbert Hovenkamp, The Law of Vertical Integration and the Business Firm, 18801960, 95 IOWA L. REV. 863, 871-72 (2010) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Law of Vertical Integration], available at http://papers.ssm.com/ sol3/papers.cftn?abstract-id=1268328 (discussing Marshall's Industry and Trade as an early theory of vertical integration).
    • (2010) Iowa L. Rev. , vol.95 , pp. 87172
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 66
    • 79952605706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 56-59, 799-802 (discussing textile production and markets)
    • See, e.g., MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 56-59, 799-802 (discussing textile production and markets);
  • 67
    • 79952583693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 94-95, 21821, 802-03 (discussing steel production and markets)
    • id. at 94-95, 218-21, 802-03 (discussing steel production and markets).
  • 68
    • 79952580457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 589
    • Id. at 589.
  • 69
    • 79952607650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 392 ("[T]he operation of a market costs something and by forming an organization and allowing some authority (an 'entrepreneur') to direct the resources, certain marketing costs are saved.)
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 392 ("[T]he operation of a market costs something and by forming an organization and allowing some authority (an 'entrepreneur') to direct the resources, certain marketing costs are saved.");
  • 70
    • 79952592264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. at 395 ([A] point must be reached where the loss through the waste of resources is equal to the marketing costs of the exchange transaction in the open market...")
    • see also id. at 395 ("[A] point must be reached where the loss through the waste of resources is equal to the marketing costs of the exchange transaction in the open market...").
  • 72
    • 79952605279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 322
    • MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 322.
  • 73
    • 79952592911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 324
    • Id. at 324.
  • 74
    • 79952585075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 76
    • 77953057454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neoclassicism and the separation of ownership and control
    • 375
    • On this point, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Neoclassicism and the Separation of Ownership and Control, 4 VA. L. & Bus. REV. 373, 375 (2009);
    • (2009) Va. L. & Bus. Rev. , vol.4 , pp. 373
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 77
    • 84924756636 scopus 로고
    • Retrospect: Berle and means
    • see also Thomas K. McCraw, In Retrospect: Berle and Means, 18 REV. AM. HIST. 578 (1990).
    • (1990) Rev. Am. Hist. , vol.18 , pp. 578
    • McCraw, T.K.1
  • 78
    • 0003593983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 38, 37577, 385-87
    • MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 368, 375-77, 385-87.
    • Industry and Trade , pp. 368
    • Marshall1
  • 81
    • 57349178972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles babbage's influence on the development of alfred marshall's theory of the firm
    • Neil B. Niman, Charles Babbage's Influence on the Development of Alfred Marshall's Theory of the Firm, 30 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 479 (2008).
    • (2008) J. Hist. Econ. Thought , vol.30 , pp. 479
    • Niman, N.B.1
  • 82
    • 79952603113 scopus 로고
    • The appointment of pigou as marshall's successor
    • RONALD H. COASE, 151
    • On Pigou's appointment, see RONALD H. COASE, The Appointment of Pigou as Marshall's Successor, in RONALD H. COASE, ESSAYS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMISTS 151, 151-66(1994).
    • (1994) Essays on Economics and Economists , pp. 151-166
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 83
    • 79952600858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt II, ch. III, §3, at 138
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt II, ch. III, §3, at 138;
  • 84
    • 79751490010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 4
    • see Hovenkamp, Coase Theorem, supra note 4 (comparing Pigou's broader conception of cost of movement against Coase's conception of transaction costs).
    • Coase Theorem
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 85
    • 79952600069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. Ill, §3, at 138-39
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. Ill, §3, at 138-39.
  • 86
    • 79952598645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. pt. II, ch. VII, §1, at 158. Guido Calabresi, the other person that Richard Posner cites as a founder of modem law and economics in the United States, also used cost much more broadly in this fashion
    • Id. pt. II, ch. VII, §1, at 158. Guido Calabresi, the other person that Richard Posner cites as a founder of modem law and economics in the United States, also used "cost" much more broadly in this fashion.
  • 87
    • 79952591394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calabresi, supra note 1 (speaking not of transaction costs, but rather of such costs as those of running the insurance system, costs of administering the system of enterprise liability, and the like). For Posner's comment crediting Calabresi, see supra note 1
    • See Calabresi, supra note 1 (speaking not of transaction costs, but rather of such costs as those of running the insurance system, costs of administering the system of enterprise liability, and the like). For Posner's comment crediting Calabresi, see supra note 1.
  • 88
    • 0000964163 scopus 로고
    • Were the ordinalists wrong about welfare economics?
    • 507
    • See, e.g., Robert Cooter & Peter Rappoport, Were the Ordinalists Wrong About Welfare Economics?, 22 J. ECON. LIT. 507, 515-16 (1984).
    • (1984) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.22 , pp. 515-516
    • Cooter, R.1    Rappoport, P.2
  • 90
    • 0004148224 scopus 로고
    • Penguin Books 1970
    • See WILLIAM STANLEY JEVONS, THE THEORY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY (Penguin Books 1970) (1871). In the introduction, Jevons stated: The reader will find, again, that there is never, in any single instance, an attempt to compare the amount of feeling in one mind with that in another. I see no means by which such comparison can be accomplished. The susceptibility of one mind may, for what we know, be a thousand times greater than that of another. But, provided that the susceptibility was different in a like ratio in all directions, we should never be able to discover the difference. Every mind is thus inscrutable to every other mind, and no common denominator of feeling seems to be possible. ... [T]he motive in one mind is weighed only against other motives in the same mind never against the motives in other minds. Id. at 85;
    • (1871) The Theory of Political Economy
    • Jevons, W.S.1
  • 94
    • 0003733205 scopus 로고
    • Cooter Rappoport, supra note 54, at 515 quoting
    • Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 515 (quoting VILFREDO PARETO, COURS D'ECONOMIE POLITIQUE 3 (1896)).
    • (1896) Cours D'economie Politique , pp. 3
    • Pareto, V.1
  • 95
    • 79952609986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 96
    • 79952611613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 97
    • 84935190124 scopus 로고
    • The first great law and economics movement
    • 1053
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law and Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993, 1053(1990).
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 993
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 98
    • 79952599057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The present position of economics, inaugural lecture at cambridge university
    • Feb. 24, 1885, 131
    • Alfred Marshall, The Present Position of Economics, Inaugural Lecture at Cambridge University (Feb. 24, 1885), in 1 J. INSTITUTIONAL ECON. 121, 131 (2005);
    • (2005) J. Institutional Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 121
    • Marshall, A.1
  • 100
    • 79952608690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 89
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 89.
  • 103
    • 0005160493 scopus 로고
    • Some aspects of welfare economies
    • 292
    • Arthur C. Pigou, Some Aspects of Welfare Economies, 41 AM. ECON. REV. 287, 292 (1951).
    • (1951) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 287
    • Pigou, A.C.1
  • 104
    • 79952592912 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 91.
    • PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 91.
  • 107
    • 79952587507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 18-19
    • Id. at 18-19.
  • 108
    • 79952599456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pigou, supra note 65, at 292 (emphasis in original)
    • Pigou, supra note 65, at 292 (emphasis in original).
  • 109
    • 0003736757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 68, at bk. II, ch. iii, §3
    • MARSHALL, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS, supra note 68, at bk. II, ch. iii, §3, at 67-68 ("This brings us to consider the term Necessaries. It is common to distinguish necessaries, comforts, and luxuries; the first class including all things required to meet wants which must be satisfied, while the latter consist of things that meet wants of a less urgent character. But here again there is a troublesome ambiguity. When we say that a want must be satisfied, what are the consequences which we have in view if it is not satisfied? Do they include death? Or do they extend only to the loss of strength and vigour? In other words, are necessaries the things which are necessary for life, or those which are necessary for efficiency?").
    • Principles of Economics , pp. 67-68
    • Marshall1
  • 110
    • 79952593715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The distinction is developed in Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 513-14
    • The distinction is developed in Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 513-14.
  • 111
    • 37949051459 scopus 로고
    • A statistical method for measuring marginal utility and testing the justice of a progressive income tax
    • Jacob H. Hollander ed
    • Irving Fisher, A Statistical Method for Measuring "Marginal Utility" and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax, in ECONOMIC ESSAYS CONTRIBUTED IN HONOR OF JOHN BATES CLARK 181 (Jacob H. Hollander ed, 1927) [hereinafter Fisher, Statistical Method];
    • (1927) Economic Essays Contributed in Honor of John Bates Clark , pp. 181
    • Fisher, I.1
  • 113
    • 79952578583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fisher, Statistical Method, supra note 73, at 159
    • Fisher, Statistical Method, supra note 73, at 159;
  • 114
    • 34547358954 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Retrospectives: Edgeworth 's hedonimeter and the quest to measure utility
    • 215
    • see David Colander, Retrospectives: Edgeworth 's Hedonimeter and the Quest to Measure Utility, 21 J. ECON. PERSP. 215, 219-21 (2007) (discussing Fisher's model) .
    • (2007) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.21 , pp. 219-221
    • Colander, D.1
  • 115
    • 0004260377 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JOHN R. COMMONS, THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 10 (1893) ("To the poor man all the marginal increments may afford high satisfaction, because his supplies are limited; but to the rich man the marginal increments may give little satisfaction. Yet each, though on different levels, endeavours to make the marginal increments in all lines equal.");
    • (1893) The Distribution of Wealth , pp. 10
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 116
    • 79952592484 scopus 로고
    • §6, at 132 3d ed.
    • F.W. TAUSSIG, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS ch. 9, §6, at 132 (3d ed. 1921) ("The principle of diminishing utility, if applied unflinchingly, leads to the conclusion that inequality of incomes brings a less sum of human well-being than equality of incomes, and that the greater the inequality, the less the approach to the maximum.");
    • (1921) Principles of Economics Ch. 9
    • Taussig, F.W.1
  • 117
    • 79952584274 scopus 로고
    • GEORGE P. WATKINS, WELFARE AS AN ECONOMIC QUANTITY 185-90 (1915) (arguing that total social utility would increase if incomes were leveled somewhat and the right to inherit severely curtailed);
    • (1915) Welfare as an Economic Quantity , pp. 185-190
    • Watkins, G.P.1
  • 118
    • 37949009312 scopus 로고
    • The ultimate standard of value
    • J.B. Clark, The Ultimate Standard of Value, 1 YALE REV. 258 (1892) (arguing that social welfare is a function of aggregated individual utilities);
    • (1892) Yale Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 258
    • Clark, J.B.1
  • 119
    • 1542456089 scopus 로고
    • The scope of political economy
    • Simon N. Patten, The Scope of Political Economy, 2 YALE REV. 264 (1893) (arguing that homogeneity of wealth and property tends to increase total utility);
    • (1893) Yale Rev. , vol.2 , pp. 264
    • Patten, S.N.1
  • 120
    • 0039781391 scopus 로고
    • The utility concept in value theory and its critics
    • pts. 1 & 2, 638, 644
    • Jacob Viner, The Utility Concept in Value Theory and Its Critics (pts. 1 & 2), 33 J. POL. ECON. 369, 638, 644 (1925) ("Changes in the relative distribution of income as between different classes will bring about changes in the amount of welfare, even though the aggregate real income of the community remains the same.").
    • (1925) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.33 , pp. 369
    • Viner, J.1
  • 121
    • 79952606315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139-40 (emphasis in original)
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139-40 (emphasis in original);
  • 122
    • 0001059988 scopus 로고
    • Interpersonal comparisons of utility: A comment
    • see also Lionel Robbins, Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility: A Comment, 48 ECON. J. 635 (1938).
    • (1938) Econ. J. , vol.48 , pp. 635
    • Robbins, L.1
  • 123
    • 79952581724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139.
  • 124
    • 79952585982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 137
    • Id. at 137.
  • 125
    • 79952576881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 126
    • 26444502901 scopus 로고
    • The limits of preference-based legal policy
    • 4, 6-10, 22-24
    • On this point, see Herbert Hovenkamp, The Limits of Preference-Based Legal Policy, 89 Nw. U. L. REV. 4, 6-10, 22-24, 29-40 (1994).
    • (1994) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 29-40
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 127
    • 79952603115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Viner, supra note 75, at 657
    • Viner, supra note 75, at 657.
  • 128
    • 60949940121 scopus 로고
    • Concept of normal price in value and distribution
    • 67
    • F.H. Knight, The Concept of Normal Price in Value and Distribution, 32 Q.J. ECON. 66, 67 (1917).
    • (1917) Q.J. Econ. , vol.32 , pp. 66
    • Knight, F.H.1
  • 129
    • 84919387812 scopus 로고
    • Traditional economic theory
    • Discussion, 145
    • Irving Fisher, Frank H. Knight & Carl E. Parry, Discussion, Traditional Economic Theory, 11 AM. ECON. REV. 143, 145 (1921).
    • (1921) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.11 , pp. 143
    • Fisher, I.1    Knight, F.H.2    Parry, C.E.3
  • 130
    • 84963062664 scopus 로고
    • The production function and the theory of capital
    • See Joan Robinson, The Production Function and the Theory of Capital, 21 REV. ECON. STUD. 81 (1953);
    • (1953) Rev. Econ. Stud. , vol.21 , pp. 81
    • Robinson, J.1
  • 131
    • 0242379960 scopus 로고
    • The production function
    • 67
    • see also Joan Robinson, The Production Function, 65 ECON. J. 67, 67 (1955) (using illustration of the production function of a robin as measured by the number of grubs caught in relation to the number of robin-minutes worked).
    • (1955) Econ. J. , vol.65 , pp. 67
    • Robinson, J.1
  • 132
    • 79952576499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 135-37
    • E.g., ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 135-37.
  • 133
    • 79952612006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Infra Text Accompanying Notes 96-97
    • See infra text accompanying notes 96-97.
  • 135
    • 79952597088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 54142 (seed)
    • id. at 54142 (seed).
  • 136
    • 79952601099 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 528
    • Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 528.
  • 138
    • 79952608256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oct. 25
    • A woman did not receive the Nobel Prize in Economics until 2009, when it was given to Elinor Ostrom. Noble Prize Awarded Women, NOBLEPRIZE.ORG (Oct. 25, 2010), http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/lists/women.html.
    • (2010) Noble Prize Awarded Women
    • Ostrom, E.1
  • 140
    • 21144473011 scopus 로고
    • The marginalist revolution in legal thought
    • 305
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Legal Thought, 46 VAND. L. REV. 305, 305-06 (1993).
    • (1993) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 305-306
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 141
    • 79952583896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOWEY, supra note 23, at 1-35
    • See HOWEY, supra note 23, at 1-35.
  • 142
    • 79952601695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Natura non facit saltum in alfred marshall (and Charles Darwin)
    • 59
    • On Alfred Marshall and Darwin, see Geoffrey Fishburn, Natura Non Facit Saltum in Alfred Marshall (and Charles Darwin), 40 HIST. ECON. REV. 59, 59 (2004) ("Nature does not make a leap.");
    • (2004) Hist. Econ. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 59
    • Fishburn, G.1
  • 143
    • 0347569357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Marshall's dilemma: Equilibrium versus evolution
    • Neil Hart, Marshall's Dilemma: Equilibrium versus Evolution, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 1139 (2003). On uses of Darwin by early American economists,
    • (2003) J. Econ. Issues , vol.37 , pp. 1139
    • Hart, N.1
  • 144
    • 0041187326 scopus 로고
    • Evolutionary models in jurisprudence
    • see Herbert Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models in Jurisprudence, 64 TEX. L. REV. 645 (1985) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models];
    • (1985) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 645
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 145
    • 84935190124 scopus 로고
    • The first great law & economics movement
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993 (1990). More generally,
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 993
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 148
    • 0011036471 scopus 로고
    • Social darwinism revisited
    • Bernard Bailyn, Donald Fleming & Stephan Themstrom eds
    • see also Donald C. Bellomy, "Social Darwinism" Revisited, in 1 PERSPECTIVES IN AMERICAN HISTORY 1 (Bernard Bailyn, Donald Fleming & Stephan Themstrom eds, 1984) (noting how Social Darwinism has been caricatured);
    • (1984) PerspectIves in American History , vol.1 , pp. 1
    • Bellomy, D.C.1
  • 149
    • 67349198642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Origins of the myth of social darwinism: The ambiguous legacy of richard hofstadter's social darwinism in American thought
    • Thomas C. Leonard, Origins of the Myth of Social Darwinism: The Ambiguous Legacy of Richard Hofstadter's Social Darwinism in American Thought, 71 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 37 (2009).
    • (2009) J. Econ. Behav. & Org. , vol.71 , pp. 37
    • Leonard, T.C.1
  • 150
    • 79952613066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 6-7
    • See HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 6-7.
  • 151
    • 84935560114 scopus 로고
    • See DOROTHY ROSS, THE ORIGINS OF AMERICAN SOCIAL SCIENCE 156-62 (1991). Ross uses the term "liberal exceptionalism" rather than "Reform Darwinism." Importantly, Reform Darwinism, by whatever name it is called, also led to eugenics and the use of controlled breeding or sterilization to improve the human race, along with exclusion of certain immigrants and other racist policies that quickly became classified as horrific after the rise of Adolf Hitler.
    • (1991) The Origins Of American Social Science , pp. 156-162
    • Ross, D.1
  • 154
    • 0011593973 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of immigration restriction in the United States
    • 1890 to 1921, Claudia Goldin and Gary D. Libecap eds
    • see Claudia Goldin, The Political Economy of Immigration Restriction in the United States, 1890 to 1921, in THE REGULATED ECONOMY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY 223 (Claudia Goldin and Gary D. Libecap eds, 1994);
    • (1994) The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to Political Economy , pp. 223
    • Goldin, C.1
  • 155
    • 33645806734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Retrospectives: Eugenics and economics in the progressive Era
    • Thomas C Leonard, Retrospectives: Eugenics and Economics in the Progressive Era, 19 J. ECON. PERSP. 207 (2005).
    • (2005) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.19 , pp. 207
    • Leonard, T.C.1
  • 159
    • 79952604056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 94
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 94.
  • 160
    • 79952614133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.; see also BANNISTER, supra note 97
    • See id.; see also BANNISTER, supra note 97;
  • 165
    • 84928841903 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of substantive due process
    • 379
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Political Economy of Substantive Due Process, 40 STAN. L. REV. 379, 417-20 (1988) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Political Economy];
    • (1988) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 417-420
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 166
    • 0040001176 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The survival of the fittest and the origins of social darwinism
    • 223
    • see also Gregory Claeys, The "Survival of the Fittest" and the Origins of Social Darwinism, 61 J. HIST. IDEAS 223, 223-24 (2000). Reform Darwinist Lester Frank Ward made plain his belief that so-called Social Darwinism was not a biological doctrine at all, but rather emanated from classical political economy.
    • (2000) J. Hist. Ideas , vol.61 , pp. 223-224
    • Claeys, G.1
  • 167
    • 10044295245 scopus 로고
    • Social and biological struggles
    • 292
    • See Lester F. Ward, Social and Biological Struggles, 13 AM. J. SOC. 289, 292 (1907).
    • (1907) Am. J. Soc. , vol.13 , pp. 289
    • Ward, L.F.1
  • 168
    • 79952583467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54. The only allusion to the theory of evolution occurs in a footnote discussing Pareto that refers to his conception of material welfare as "some Spencerian ideas of evolutionary fitness." Id. at 516 n.22
    • See Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54. The only allusion to the theory of evolution occurs in a footnote discussing Pareto that refers to his conception of material welfare as "some Spencerian ideas of evolutionary fitness." Id. at 516 n.22.
  • 169
    • 0037344986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Darwinism and institutional economics
    • 85
    • See Geoffrey M. Hodgson, Darwinism and Institutional Economics, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 85, 91-95 (2003).
    • (2003) J. Econ. Issues , vol.37 , pp. 91-95
    • Hodgson, G.M.1
  • 170
    • 79952579014 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 78-79 ("The main postulate of the theory of value is the fact that individuals can arrange their preferences in an order, and in fact do so.")
    • ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 78-79 ("The main postulate of the theory of value is the fact that individuals can arrange their preferences in an order, and in fact do so.").
  • 171
    • 79952586402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 91-92 ("[I]n a state of equilibrium the relative significance of divisible commodities is equal to their price does involve the assumption that each final choice is consistent with every other, in the sense that if I prefer A to B and B to C, I also prefer A to C ....").
    • See id. at 91-92 ("[I]n a state of equilibrium the relative significance of divisible commodities is equal to their price does involve the assumption that each final choice is consistent with every other, in the sense that if I prefer A to B and B to C, I also prefer A to C ....").
  • 172
    • 79952615648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robbins's famous definition of economics: Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses. Id. at 16
    • See Robbins's famous definition of economics: "Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses." Id. at 16.
  • 174
    • 77949561217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defining economics: The long road to acceptance of the robbins definition
    • see also Roger E. Backhouse & Steve G. Medema, Defining Economics: The Long Road to Acceptance of the Robbins Definition, 76 ECONOMICA 805 (2009);
    • (2009) Economica , vol.76 , pp. 805
    • Backhouse, R.E.1    Medema, S.G.2
  • 175
    • 77949647520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Effective tension in robbins' economic methodology
    • D. Wade Hands, Effective Tension in Robbins' Economic Methodology, 76 ECONOMICA 831 (2009);
    • (2009) Economica , vol.76 , pp. 831
    • Wade Hands, D.1
  • 176
    • 4744370322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Origins of lionel robbins's essay on the nature and significance of economic science
    • Susan Howson, The Origins of Lionel Robbins's Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, 36 HIST. POL. ECON. 413 (2004);
    • (2004) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.36 , pp. 413
    • Howson, S.1
  • 178
    • 0001574498 scopus 로고
    • Competition, cooperation, and conflict in economics and biology
    • 238
    • On the connection, see J. Hirshleifer, Competition, Cooperation, and Conflict in Economics and Biology, 68 AM. ECON. REV. 238, 241 (1978);
    • (1978) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 241
    • Hirshleifer, J.1
  • 179
    • 0003172533 scopus 로고
    • Evolutionary models in economics and law: Cooperation versus conflict strategies
    • Jack Hirshleifer, Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation Versus Conflict Strategies, 4 RES. L. & ECON. 1 (1982).
    • (1982) Res. L. & Econ. , vol.4 , pp. 1
    • Hirshleifer, J.1
  • 180
    • 0004269732 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge University Press 1992
    • See T.R. MALTHUS, AN ESSAY ON THE PRINCIPLE OF POPULATION (Cambridge University Press 1992) (1798). On the extent of Darwin's borrowings from Malthus, as well as other political economists, and the extent to which later economists relied on Darwin,
    • (1798) An Essay on the Principle of Population
    • Malthus, T.R.1
  • 181
    • 0007256786 scopus 로고
    • Biological analogies in the theory of the firm: Comment
    • see Armen A. Alchian, Biological Analogies in the Theory of the Firm: Comment, 43 AM. ECON. REV. 600 (1953)
    • (1953) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.43 , pp. 600
    • Alchian, A.A.1
  • 182
    • 0000433523 scopus 로고
    • Biological analogies in the theory of the firm
    • (responding to Edith Tilton Penrose, Biological Analogies in the Theory of the Firm, 42 AM. ECON. REV. 804 (1952));
    • (1952) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 804
    • Penrose, E.T.1
  • 183
    • 0015029748 scopus 로고
    • Darwin, malthus and selection
    • Sandra Herbert, Research Note, Darwin, Malthus and Selection, 4 J. HIST. BIOLOGY 209 (1971);
    • (1971) J. Hist. Biology , vol.4 , pp. 209
    • Herbert, S.1    Note, R.2
  • 184
    • 0042835889 scopus 로고
    • Darwin, malthus, and the theory of natural selection
    • Peter Vorzimmer, Darwin, Malthus, and the Theory of Natural Selection, 30 J. HIST. IDEAS 527 (1969);
    • (1969) J. Hist. Ideas , vol.30 , pp. 527
    • Vorzimmer, P.1
  • 186
    • 0041636182 scopus 로고
    • Darwin and political economy: The connection reconsidered
    • see also Scott Gordon, Darwin and Political Economy: The Connection Reconsidered, 22 J. HIST. BIOLOGY 437 (1989).
    • (1989) J. Hist. Biology , vol.22 , pp. 437
    • Gordon, S.1
  • 187
    • 33846352506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The road not taken: How psychology was removed from economics, and how it might be brought back
    • See Luigino Bruni & Robert Sugden, The Road Not Taken: How Psychology Was Removed from Economics, and How It Might Be Brought Back, 117 ECON. J. 146 (2007).
    • (2007) Econ. J. , vol.117 , pp. 146
    • Bruni, L.1    Sugden, R.2
  • 192
    • 0012234442 scopus 로고
    • (Johnson Reprint Corp. 1968) [hereinafter WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY]
    • LESTER FRANK WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY (Johnson Reprint Corp. 1968) (1883) [hereinafter WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY];
    • (1883) Dynamic Sociology
    • Ward, L.F.1
  • 193
    • 26444574206 scopus 로고
    • [hereinafter WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS].
    • LESTER F. WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS (1913) [hereinafter WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS].
    • (1913) Glimpses of the Cosmos
    • Ward, L.F.1
  • 196
    • 0013089330 scopus 로고
    • Morris Janowitz ed
    • ROBERT E.L. FARIS, CHICAGO SOCIOLOGY, 1920-1932 (Morris Janowitz ed, 1967);
    • (1967) Chicago Sociology , pp. 1920-1932
    • Faris, R.E.L.1
  • 197
    • 79952577312 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 64-84
    • HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 64-84;
  • 199
    • 79952577726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For further development, see Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models, supra note 93, at 654-61, 671-83.
    • For further development, see Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models, supra note 93, at 654-61, 671-83.
  • 200
    • 79952601286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 38-44 (discussing Spencer's beliefs).
    • See HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 38-44 (discussing Spencer's beliefs).
  • 201
    • 79952591609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 199-226
    • See, e.g., COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 199-226;
  • 203
    • 79952585571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 112, at
    • 3 WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS, supra note 112, at 35;
    • Glimpses of the Cosmos , pp. 35
  • 204
    • 79952598230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 112, at
    • see also 1 WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY, supra note 112, at 542.
    • Dynamic Sociology , pp. 542
  • 205
    • 79952585571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 112, at
    • 4 WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS, supra note 112, at 354.
    • Glimpses of the Cosmos , pp. 354
  • 206
    • 79952596889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 355.
    • Id. at 355.
  • 207
    • 79952613445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 208
    • 0141529374 scopus 로고
    • Natural selection, social selection, and heredity
    • 90
    • JOHN R. COMMONS, Natural Selection, Social Selection, and Heredity, 18 ARENA 90, 90 (1897),
    • (1897) Arena , vol.18 , pp. 90
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 209
    • 79952589330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 43-49 (Malcolm Rutherford & Warren J. Samuels eds, 1996).
    • reprinted in 1 JOHN R. COMMONS: SELECTED ESSAYS 43, 43-49 (Malcolm Rutherford & Warren J. Samuels eds, 1996).
    • Selected Essays , pp. 43
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 210
    • 0040762629 scopus 로고
    • Commons's legal economic theory
    • 88
    • See generally R.A. Gonce, John R. Commons's Legal Economic Theory, 5 J. ECON. ISSUES 80, 88 (1971) (discussing Commons's attempt to integrate a theory of artificial selection into economics);
    • (1971) J. Econ. Issues , vol.5 , pp. 80
    • Gonce, R.A.1    John, R.2
  • 211
    • 0002246090 scopus 로고
    • On the nature of economic evolution: John R. commons and the metaphor of artificial selection
    • Lars Magnusson ed., (same).
    • Yngve Ramstad, On the Nature of Economic Evolution: John R. Commons and the Metaphor of Artificial Selection, in EVOLUTIONARY AND NEO-SCHUMPETERIAN APPROACHES TO ECONOMICS 65 (Lars Magnusson ed., 1994) (same).
    • (1994) Evolutionary and Neo-Schumpeterian Approaches to Economics , pp. 65
    • Ramstad, Y.1
  • 212
    • 79952610365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BERNARD & BERNARD, supra note 112, at 611-69 (discussing the rise of social science in American colleges);
    • See BERNARD & BERNARD, supra note 112, at 611-69 (discussing the rise of social science in American colleges);
  • 214
    • 79952590348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FARIS, supra note 112, at 3-37
    • FARIS, supra note 112, at 3-37;
  • 217
    • 79952604647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ross, supra note 96, at 91-99.
    • Ross, supra note 96, at 91-99.
  • 218
    • 79952594332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 87-88 (addressing critique that preferences cannot be observed, but that behavior can be, so behaviorism would provide a better tool for economic analysis).
    • See ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 87-88 (addressing critique that preferences cannot be observed, but that behavior can be, so behaviorism would provide a better tool for economic analysis).
  • 219
    • 79952585573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 87.
    • Id. at 87.
  • 220
    • 79952598644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700.
    • BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700.
  • 221
    • 0039758248 scopus 로고
    • The socializing of theoretical economics
    • Rexford Guy Tugwell ed.
    • See John Maurice Clark, The Socializing of Theoretical Economics, in THE TREND OF ECONOMICS 73 (Rexford Guy Tugwell ed., 1924) [hereinafter Clark, Socializing];
    • (1924) The Trend of Economics , pp. 73
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 222
    • 0040168515 scopus 로고
    • The institutional approach to economic theory
    • Supp.
    • Walton H. Hamilton, The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 309 (Supp. 1919);
    • (1919) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 309
    • Hamilton, W.H.1
  • 223
    • 0039165689 scopus 로고
    • Experimental economics
    • Rexford Guy Tugwell ed
    • Rexford Guy Tugwell, Experimental Economics, in THE TREND OF ECONOMICS 371 (Rexford Guy Tugwell ed, 1924);
    • (1924) The Trend of Economics , vol.371
    • Tugwell, R.G.1
  • 224
    • 79952584470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Ross, supra note 112, at 407-08
    • see also Ross, supra note 112, at 407-08;
  • 225
    • 24944432809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The transformation of U.S. economics, 1920-1960, viewed through a survey of journal articles
    • Supp.
    • Roger E. Backhouse, The Transformation of U.S. Economics, 1920-1960, Viewed Through a Survey of Journal Articles, 30 HIST. POL. ECON. 85 (Supp. 1998);
    • (1998) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.30 , pp. 85
    • Backhouse, R.E.1
  • 226
    • 0141685780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commons and the foundations of institutional economics
    • Geoffrey M. Hodgson, John R. Commons and the Foundations of Institutional Economics, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 547 (2003);
    • (2003) J. Econ. Issues , vol.37 , pp. 547
    • Hodgson, G.M.1    John, R.2
  • 227
    • 0039384695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding institutional economics: 1918-1929
    • Malcolm Rutherford, Understanding Institutional Economics: 1918-1929, 22 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 277 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Hist. Econ. Thought , vol.22 , pp. 277
    • Rutherford, M.1
  • 228
    • 79952594331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a good analysis, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
    • For a good analysis, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
  • 229
    • 0003359437 scopus 로고
    • The limitations of marginal utility
    • [hereinafter Veblen, Limitations]
    • See Thorstein Veblen, The Limitations of Marginal Utility, 17 J. POL. ECON. 620 (1909) [hereinafter Veblen, Limitations];
    • (1909) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.17 , pp. 620
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 230
    • 84898535750 scopus 로고
    • The preconceptions of economic science (pt. 3)
    • Thorstein Veblen, The Preconceptions of Economic Science (pt. 3), 14 Q.J. ECON. 240 (1900);
    • (1900) Q.J. Econ. , vol.14 , pp. 240
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 231
    • 33748687275 scopus 로고
    • Why is economics not an evolutionary science?
    • Thorstein Veblen, Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?, 12 Q.J. ECON. 373 (1898).
    • (1898) Q.J. Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 373
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 235
    • 0003620618 scopus 로고
    • On Veblen, institutionalism, and the business corporation
    • THORSTEIN VEBLEN, THE THEORY OF THE LEISURE CLASS (1899). On Veblen, institutionalism, and the business corporation,
    • (1899) The Theory of the Leisure Class
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 236
    • 85028739126 scopus 로고
    • Veblen, berle and the modern corporation
    • see Forest G. Hill, Veblen, Berle and the Modern Corporation, 26 AM. J. ECON. Soc. 279 (1967).
    • (1967) Am. J. Econ. Soc. , vol.26 , pp. 279
    • Hill, F.G.1
  • 237
    • 79952612824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 126, at
    • VEBLEN, ABSENTEE OWNERSHIP, supra note 126, at 101 n. 1.
    • Absentee Ownership , Issue.1 , pp. 101
    • Veblen1
  • 238
    • 79952577729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hamilton, supra note 124, at 316.
    • See Hamilton, supra note 124, at 316.
  • 239
    • 0141863734 scopus 로고
    • The emancipation of economics
    • See Lawrence K. Frank, The Emancipation of Economics, 14 AM. ECON. REV. 17 (1924).
    • (1924) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.14 , pp. 17
    • Frank, L.K.1
  • 241
    • 0039989904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • American institutionalism and the history of economics
    • 178
    • See Malcolm Rutherford, American Institutionalism and the History of Economics, 19 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 178, 178-79 (1997);
    • (1997) J. Hist. Econ. Thought , vol.19 , pp. 178-179
    • Rutherford, M.1
  • 242
    • 0012532721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Veblen's evolutionary programme: A promise unfulfilled
    • see also Malcolm Rutherford, Veblen's Evolutionary Programme: A Promise Unfulfilled, 22 CAMBRIDGE J. ECON. 463 (1998).
    • (1998) Cambridge J. Econ. , vol.22 , pp. 463
    • Rutherford, M.1
  • 244
    • 0141863731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Waging war against mechanical man: The knight-copeland controversy over behaviorism in economics
    • Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds
    • See, e.g., Pier Franceso Asso & Luca Fiorito, Waging War Against Mechanical Man: The Knight-Copeland Controversy over Behaviorism in Economics, in 21-A RESEARCH IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT AND METHODOLOGY 65 (Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds, 2003);
    • (2003) A Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology , vol.21 , pp. 65
    • Asso, P.F.1    Fiorito, L.2
  • 245
    • 0012589267 scopus 로고
    • Economic theory and the natural science point of view
    • University of Chicago economist Frank Knight, who toyed with various aspects of institutionalism throughout his career, was very critical of behaviorism because its list of "instincts" defied rigorous analysis.
    • Morris A. Copeland, Economic Theory and the Natural Science Point of View, 21 AM. ECON. REV. 67 (1931). University of Chicago economist Frank Knight, who toyed with various aspects of institutionalism throughout his career, was very critical of behaviorism because its list of "instincts" defied rigorous analysis.
    • (1931) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.21 , pp. 67
    • Copeland, M.A.1
  • 246
    • 84951549673 scopus 로고
    • Ethics and the economic interpretation
    • 467 ("If instincts are to be scientifically useful, it must surely be possible to get some idea of their number and identity. But there has always been substantially unanimous disagreement on this point. Logically the choice seems to lie between a meaningless single instinct to do things-in-general and the equally meaningless hypothesis of a separate instinct for every possible act").
    • See Frank H. Knight, Ethics and the Economic Interpretation, 36 Q.J. ECON. 454, 467 (1922) ("If instincts are to be scientifically useful, it must surely be possible to get some idea of their number and identity. But there has always been substantially unanimous disagreement on this point. Logically the choice seems to lie between a meaningless single instinct to do things-in-general and the equally meaningless hypothesis of a separate instinct for every possible act").
    • (1922) Q.J. Econ. , vol.36 , pp. 454
    • Knight, F.H.1
  • 247
    • 0000520990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economics and psychology: Lessons for our own day from the early twentieth century
    • On behaviorism in American institutionalism, see generally Shira B. Lewin, Economics and Psychology: Lessons for Our Own Day from the Early Twentieth Century, 34 J. ECON. LITERATURE 1293 (1996);
    • (1996) J. Econ. Literature , vol.34 , pp. 1293
    • Lewin, S.B.1
  • 248
    • 0034412430 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutionalism between the wars
    • 298 For a very good discussion of the development of behaviorist psychology among institutionalists as an alternative to neoclassical marginal utility theory
    • Malcolm Rutherford, Institutionalism Between the Wars, 34 J. ECON. ISSUES 291, 298 (2000). For a very good discussion of the development of behaviorist psychology among institutionalists as an alternative to neoclassical marginal utility theory,
    • (2000) J. Econ. Issues , vol.34 , pp. 291
    • Rutherford, M.1
  • 250
    • 79952614130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Ross, supra note 96, at 414-15 (describing tumultuous meeting of American Economics Association in 1927, where a large majority of economists reacted against the use of empirical analysis to revise economic theory as a throwback to German-style historicism).
    • see also Ross, supra note 96, at 414-15 (describing tumultuous meeting of American Economics Association in 1927, where a large majority of economists reacted against the use of empirical analysis to revise economic theory as a throwback to German-style historicism).
  • 253
    • 79952599868 scopus 로고
    • Fact research in law administration
    • A few examples include Charles E. Clark, Fact Research in Law Administration, 2 CONN. B.J. 211 (1928);
    • (1928) Conn. B.J. , vol.2 , pp. 211
    • Clark, C.E.1
  • 254
    • 37949045178 scopus 로고
    • A factual study of bankruptcy administration and some suggestions
    • William O. Douglas & J. Howard Marshall, A Factual Study of Bankruptcy Administration and Some Suggestions, 32 COLUM. L. REV. 25 (1932);
    • (1932) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.32 , pp. 25
    • Douglas, W.O.1    Howard Marshall, J.2
  • 255
    • 37949057402 scopus 로고
    • An institutional approach to the law of commercial banking
    • Underhill Moore & Theodore S. Hope, Jr., An Institutional Approach to the Law of Commercial Banking, 38 YALE L.J. 703 (1929);
    • (1929) Yale L.J. , vol.38 , pp. 703
    • Moore, U.1    Hope Jr., T.S.2
  • 256
    • 1842639071 scopus 로고
    • Legal and institutional methods applied to the debiting of direct discounts
    • 555, 752, 928, 1055, 1219 (series of articles describing empirical studies).
    • Underhill Moore & Gilbert Sussman, Legal and Institutional Methods Applied to the Debiting of Direct Discounts, 40 YALE L.J. 381, 555, 752, 928, 1055, 1219 (1931) (series of articles describing empirical studies).
    • (1931) Yale L.J. , vol.40 , pp. 381
    • Moore, U.1    Sussman, G.2
  • 257
    • 0347664771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Knowledge about welfare: Legal realism and the separation of law and economics
    • [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Knowledge About Welfare]
    • On the relationship between institutionalism and American legal realism, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Knowledge About Welfare: Legal Realism and the Separation of Law and Economics, 84 MINN. L. REV. 805 (2000) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Knowledge About Welfare];
    • (2000) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 805
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 260
    • 0004327857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beacon Press (1944) ("In spite of the chorus of academic incantations so persistent in the nineteenth century, gain and profit made on exchange never before played an important part in human economy.")
    • KARL POLANYI, THE GREAT TRANSFORMATION 45-69 (Beacon Press 2001) (1944) ("In spite of the chorus of academic incantations so persistent in the nineteenth century, gain and profit made on exchange never before played an important part in human economy.");
    • (2001) The Great Transformation , pp. 45-69
    • Polanyi, K.1
  • 261
    • 0001902356 scopus 로고
    • The corporation versus the market
    • 397, (comparing Coase's and Polanyi's concepts of exchange)
    • see also John Adams, The Corporation Versus the Market, 26 J. ECON. ISSUES 397, 397-98 (1992) (comparing Coase's and Polanyi's concepts of exchange);
    • (1992) J. Econ. Issues , vol.26 , pp. 397-398
    • Adams, J.1
  • 262
    • 84974253454 scopus 로고
    • Karl polanyi's concept of non-market trade
    • Abraham Rotstein, Karl Polanyi's Concept of Non-Market Trade, 30 J. ECON. HIST. 117 (1970).
    • (1970) J. Econ. Hist. , vol.30 , pp. 117
    • Rotstein, A.1
  • 263
    • 55249093479 scopus 로고
    • Karl Polanyi and american institutionalism: A strange case of convergence
    • Kari PolanyiLevitt ed
    • On Polanyi and institutionalism, see Walter C. Neale, Karl Polanyi and American Institutionalism: A Strange Case of Convergence, in THE LIFE AND WORK OF KARL POLANYI 145 (Kari PolanyiLevitt ed, 1990);
    • (1990) The Life and Work oOf Karl Polanyi , pp. 145
    • Neale, W.C.1
  • 264
    • 79952612823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stanford Univ. Working Paper, available at (comparing coercive and exchange economies and identifying secure property rights and contract enforceability as the distinguishing factors).
    • see also Avner Greif, Coercion and Exchange: How Did Markets Evolve? (Stanford Univ. Working Paper, 2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1304204 (comparing coercive and exchange economies and identifying secure property rights and contract enforceability as the distinguishing factors).
    • (2008) Coercion and Exchange: How Did Markets Evolve?
    • Greif, A.1
  • 266
    • 79952579805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See POLANYI, supra note 138, at 45-69.
    • See POLANYI, supra note 138, at 45-69.
  • 267
    • 79952584868 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 268
    • 0141752178 scopus 로고
    • An institutional analysis of the law
    • 480, (using cultural anthropology to account for institutions of private property and contract). On this point, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
    • See, e.g., Lawrence K. Frank, An Institutional Analysis of the Law, 24 COLUM. L. REV. 480, 482-84 (1924) (using cultural anthropology to account for institutions of private property and contract). On this point, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
    • (1924) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.24 , pp. 482-484
    • Frank, L.K.1
  • 269
    • 79952581262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Veblen, Limitations, supra note 126.
    • See Veblen, Limitations, supra note 126.
  • 270
    • 79952615455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Clark's marginalism, see infra Part III.D.
    • On Clark's marginalism, see infra Part III.D.
  • 271
    • 0004197282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Transaction Publishers 4th prtg. 1990) [hereinafter COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS].
    • In particular, see JOHN R. COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS: ITS PLACE IN POLITICAL ECONOMY (Transaction Publishers 4th prtg. 1990) (1934) [hereinafter COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS].
    • (1934) Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 272
    • 79952593917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joseph Schumpeter's critique was particularly harsh, notwithstanding his own sympathy with historical methods generally. He lumped the institutionalists together with practical nonacademic economists who wrote about policy and had no use for theory
    • Joseph Schumpeter's critique was particularly harsh, notwithstanding his own sympathy with historical methods generally. He lumped the institutionalists together with practical nonacademic economists who wrote about policy and had no use for theory:
  • 273
    • 79952595860 scopus 로고
    • note (Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter ed, Oxford Univ. Press rev. ed. 1996) (internal citation omitted).
    • They... looked upon 'marginalism' as a sort of speculative philosophy or as a new sectarian 'ism' which it was precisely their business to eliminate by what they considered truly scientific and realistic research. Hence they passed, in methodological and programmatic pronouncements, all sorts of sweeping judgments upon it. On the surface, the result was bedlam, especially in Germany and in the United States - a multitude of discordant voices, all of which seemed to testify to the presence of an impasse. JOSEPH A. SCHUMPETER, HISTORY OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 954 (Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter ed, Oxford Univ. Press rev. ed. 1996) (1954) (internal citation omitted).
    • (1954) History of Economic Analysis , pp. 954
    • Schumpeter, J.A.1
  • 274
    • 79952600651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 227-46 (1950) (lengthy discussion of Veblen, while John Bates Clark is barely mentioned and incorrectly identified as a "classical economist")
    • Cf. COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 227-46 (1950) (lengthy discussion of Veblen, while John Bates Clark is barely mentioned and incorrectly identified as a "classical economist");
  • 275
    • 0004229723 scopus 로고
    • (much greater treatment of Veblen than Clark)
    • RICHARD HOFSTADTER, THE AGE OF REFORM (1955) (much greater treatment of Veblen than Clark);
    • (1955) The Age of Reform
    • Hofstadter, R.1
  • 276
    • 79952601098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WHITE, supra note 99 (lengthy discussion of Veblen but no reference to John Bates Clark or Irving Fisher).
    • WHITE, supra note 99 (lengthy discussion of Veblen but no reference to John Bates Clark or Irving Fisher).
  • 277
    • 79952580244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700-03 (briefly describing American institutionalism).
    • See, e.g., BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700-03 (briefly describing American institutionalism).
  • 278
    • 79952606743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 85-87 and accompanying text (arguing that Robbins narrowed the scope of economics so as to exclude psychology)
    • See supra notes 85-87 and accompanying text (arguing that Robbins narrowed the scope of economics so as to exclude psychology);
  • 279
    • 0033446524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The scope, method and significance of original institutional economics
    • 231
    • James Ronald Stanfield, The Scope, Method and Significance of Original Institutional Economics, 33 J. ECON. ISSUES 231, 233-36 (1999).
    • (1999) J. Econ. Issues , vol.33 , pp. 233-236
    • Stanfield, J.R.1
  • 283
    • 84935190124 scopus 로고
    • The first great law & economics movement
    • see also Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993 (1990).
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 993
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 284
    • 0001814852 scopus 로고
    • Coercion and distribution in a supposedly non-coercive state
    • Robert L. Hale, Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State, 38 POL. SCI. Q. 470 (1923);
    • (1923) Pol. Sci. Q. , vol.38 , pp. 470
    • Hale, R.L.1
  • 285
    • 79952594552 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Frank, supra note 141, at 481-89 (describing evolution of coercion in historical cultures, including legal mies among other structural norms and taboos).
    • see also Frank, supra note 141, at 481-89 (describing evolution of coercion in historical cultures, including legal mies among other structural norms and taboos).
  • 288
    • 79952577944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BERLE & MEANS, supra note 46.
    • BERLE & MEANS, supra note 46.
  • 289
    • 79952598231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The writings of Oliver E. Williamson are representative of NIE. See, e.g., WILLIAMSON, supra note 9, at 12, 26, 45, 220, 251, 371
    • The writings of Oliver E. Williamson are representative of NIE. See, e.g., WILLIAMSON, supra note 9, at 12, 26, 45, 220, 251, 371;
  • 291
    • 79952588925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 3, 6, 24, 254.
    • WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 3, 6, 24, 254.
  • 293
    • 79952593714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. For some of those sympathetic with institutionalism, such as Richard T. Ely and Robert L. Hale, even bargaining transactions were seen as coercive because they tended to reinforce pre-existing distributions of power and increased the maldistribution of wealth in the process.
    • Id. For some of those sympathetic with institutionalism, such as Richard T. Ely and Robert L. Hale, even bargaining transactions were seen as coercive because they tended to reinforce pre-existing distributions of power and increased the maldistribution of wealth in the process.
  • 294
    • 79952601284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ELY, supra note 150; Hale, supra note 151. These views eventually found their way into judicial decision making and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts.
    • See, e.g., ELY, supra note 150; Hale, supra note 151. These views eventually found their way into judicial decision making and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts.
  • 295
    • 0003726851 scopus 로고
    • (describing the destruction of contract theory at the hands of legal realists, such as Benjamin Cardozo and Arthur L. Corbin, and the incorporation of these views into the Second Restatement of Contracts).
    • See GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (1974) (describing the destruction of contract theory at the hands of legal realists, such as Benjamin Cardozo and Arthur L. Corbin, and the incorporation of these views into the Second Restatement of Contracts).
    • (1974) The Death of Contract
    • Gilmore, G.1
  • 296
    • 0004197282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 144, at ("From this universal principle of collective action in control of individual action by different kinds of sanctions arise the ethical and legal relations of rights, duties, no-rights, no-duties, and the economic relations not only of Security, Conformity, Liberty, and Exposure, but also of Assets and Liabilities.").
    • See COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS, supra note 144, at 72 ("From this universal principle of collective action in control of individual action by different kinds of sanctions arise the ethical and legal relations of rights, duties, no-rights, no-duties, and the economic relations not only of Security, Conformity, Liberty, and Exposure, but also of Assets and Liabilities.").
    • Institutional Economics , pp. 72
    • Commons1
  • 299
    • 33846535805 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The institutional economics of John R. commons: Complement and substitute for neoclassical economic theory
    • 3
    • Bruce E. Kaufman, The Institutional Economics of John R. Commons: Complement and Substitute for Neoclassical Economic Theory, 5 SOCIO-ECON. REV. 3, 22-34 (2007);
    • (2007) Socio-Econ. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 22-34
    • Kaufman, B.E.1
  • 300
    • 0001223444 scopus 로고
    • Commons's institutional economics
    • Malcolm Rutherford, J.R. Commons's Institutional Economics, 17 J. ECON. ISSUES 721 (1983).
    • (1983) J. Econ. Issues , vol.17 , pp. 721
    • Malcolm Rutherford, J.R.1
  • 301
    • 0010061125 scopus 로고
    • Law and economics
    • John R. Commons, Law and Economics, 34 YALE L.J. 371 (1925).
    • (1925) Yale L.J. , vol.34 , pp. 371
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 302
    • 0003932268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ronald Coase and american institutionalism
    • 51, Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds
    • On the relationship between Commons, Coase, and The Nature of the Firm, see Steven G. Medema, Ronald Coase and American Institutionalism, in 14 RESEARCH IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT AND METHODOLOGY 51, 68-70 (Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds, 1996).
    • (1996) Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology , vol.14 , pp. 68-70
    • Medema, S.G.1
  • 303
    • 79952595654 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An excellent but typically overlooked example is Lawrence Kelso Frank, whose 1924 Columbia Law Review article, An Institutionalist Analysis of Law, described the evolution of property and contract as social norms, much like tribal taboos, but which had become much more social (rather than individual) as a result of the revolution in "machine production," which Frank believed gave rise to legal mies that emphasized cooperation more than individualism.
  • 304
    • 79952584271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Frank, supra note 141. Frank argued that the movement for the new Restatements of the law, which were just underway at the time of his writing, were an effort to bridge the hyper-individualistic tendencies of nineteenth-century law with the realities of coordinated production in the machine age. He saw this as a failed attempt to "pour new wine into old bottles."
    • See Frank, supra note 141. Frank argued that the movement for the new Restatements of the law, which were just underway at the time of his writing, were an effort to bridge the hyper-individualistic tendencies of nineteenth-century law with the realities of coordinated production in the machine age. He saw this as a failed attempt to "pour new wine into old bottles."
  • 305
    • 79952594550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 491-92. He ultimately concluded that legislative rather than common law rules were the preferred route for legal change.
    • Id. at 491-92. He ultimately concluded that legislative rather than common law rules were the preferred route for legal change.
  • 306
    • 79952576684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 495.
    • Id. at 495.
  • 307
    • 0000156633 scopus 로고
    • The chicago school of antitrust analysis
    • 928 (speaking of viewing all of antitrust law through the lens of "price theory").
    • The phrase, somewhat misplaced, comes from Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925, 928 (1979) (speaking of viewing all of antitrust law through the lens of "price theory").
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 925
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 314
    • 0011224145 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (unpublished manuscript), available at (explaining how developmental policy is determined by institutionalism).
    • Douglass C North, The New Institutional Economics and Development (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/ NewInstE.North.pdf (explaining how developmental policy is determined by institutionalism).
    • The New Institutional Economics and Development
    • North, D.C.1
  • 315
    • 79952588128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 50-51 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 50-51 and accompanying text;
  • 316
    • 79952583051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
    • see also Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
  • 317
    • 79952598436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 43-70 and accompanying text.
    • See supra notes 43-70 and accompanying text.
  • 319
    • 79952598017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see supra note 39 and accompanying text.
    • see supra note 39 and accompanying text.
  • 320
    • 79952608059 scopus 로고
    • The integration of industry in the United States
    • 108 (describing the development of vertical integration by English store owners). For an overview of vertical integration during this period
    • See, e.g., William Franklin Willoughby, The Integration of Industry in the United States, 16 Q.J. ECON. 94, 108 (1902) (describing the development of vertical integration by English store owners). For an overview of vertical integration during this period,
    • (1902) Q.J. Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 94
    • Willoughby, W.F.1
  • 322
    • 84862857817 scopus 로고
    • The antitrust movement and the rise of industrial organization
    • [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Antitrust Movement]
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Antitrust Movement and the Rise of Industrial Organization, 68 TEX. L. REV. 105 (1989) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Antitrust Movement];
    • (1989) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.68 , pp. 105
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 326
    • 0002011547 scopus 로고
    • The significance of industrial integration
    • Lawrence K. Frank, The Significance of Industrial Integration, 33 J. POL. ECON. 179 (1925).
    • (1925) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.33 , pp. 179
    • Frank, L.K.1
  • 327
    • 79952614547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 174. Id. at 179-80.
    • 174. Id. at 179-80.
  • 328
    • 79952583694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 180 ("[T]he machine process split up production into an ever growing number of separate processes, separate because of the invention of new techniques and new machines for performing each step in the formerly unified handicraft operations.").
    • Id. at 180 ("[T]he machine process split up production into an ever growing number of separate processes, separate because of the invention of new techniques and new machines for performing each step in the formerly unified handicraft operations.").
  • 329
    • 79952586848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 185-86 ("For undoubtedly vertical integration is an attempt to bring together under one management the separate stages of the industrial process which technically require unified direction and control. Since this technical requirement cannot effectively nor continuously be met through buying and selling of goods between separately owned stages, however ingeniously and elaborately those pecuniary operations be conducted, it has become both feasible and desirable to bring a number of consecutive stages of production under one managerial control.").
  • 330
    • 79952608693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 190.
    • Id. at 190.
  • 331
    • 0041163978 scopus 로고
    • Soundings in non-euclidian economics
    • John Maurice Clark, Soundings in Non-Euclidian Economics, 11 AM. ECON. REV. SUPP. 132 (1921).
    • (1921) Am. Econ. Rev. Supp. , vol.11 , pp. 132
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 333
    • 77953069110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States competition policy in crisis: 1890-1955
    • 311, [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Competition Policy].
    • see Herbert Hovenkamp, United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955, 94 MINN. L. REV. 311, 323-24 (2009) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Competition Policy].
    • (2009) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 323-324
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 334
    • 79952583895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clark, Socializing, supra note 124.
    • Clark, Socializing, supra note 124.
  • 335
    • 0005947799 scopus 로고
    • Toward a concept of workable competition
    • 241
    • J.M. Clark, Toward a Concept of Workable Competition, 30 AM. ECON. REV. 241, 241-43 (1940);
    • (1940) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.30 , pp. 241-243
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 336
    • 22944431922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 179, at 323
    • see Hovenkamp, Competition Policy, supra note 179, at 323, 342-43.
    • Competition Policy , pp. 342-343
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 338
    • 79952611195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 13.
    • Id. at 13.
  • 339
    • 84953304793 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 25, at
    • See HOVENKAMP, ENTERPRISE, supra note 25, at 308-22;
    • Enterprise , pp. 308-322
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 340
    • 0020365518 scopus 로고
    • Decreasing average cost and competition: A new look at the addyston pipe case
    • see also George Bittlingmayer, Decreasing Average Cost and Competition: A New Look at the Addyston Pipe Case, 25 J.L. & ECON. 201 (1982);
    • (1982) J.L. & Econ. , vol.25 , pp. 201
    • Bittlingmayer, G.1
  • 341
    • 84985407497 scopus 로고
    • The economic problem of fixed costs and what legal research can contribute
    • The cost controversy culminated in the 1930s in a debate that gave rise to modem theories of imperfect competition.
    • George Bittlingmayer, The Economic Problem of Fixed Costs and What Legal Research Can Contribute, 14 LAW & SOC. INQUIRY 739 (1989). The cost controversy culminated in the 1930s in a debate that gave rise to modem theories of imperfect competition.
    • (1989) Law & Soc. Inquiry , vol.14 , pp. 739
    • Bittlingmayer, G.1
  • 342
    • 0346002471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The cost controversy: Pigouvian economics in disequilibrium
    • See Nahid Aslanbeigui, The Cost Controversy: Pigouvian Economics in Disequilibrium, 3 EUR. J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 275 (1996);
    • (1996) Eur. J. Hist. Econ. Thought , vol.3 , pp. 275
    • Aslanbeigui, N.1
  • 343
    • 2142781475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the methodological foundation of modern microeconomics: Frank knight and the "cost controversy" in the 1920s
    • Roberto Marchionatti, On the Methodological Foundation of Modern Microeconomics: Frank Knight and the "Cost Controversy" in the 1920s, 35 HIST. POL. ECON. 49 (2003).
    • (2003) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.35 , pp. 49
    • Marchionatti, R.1
  • 344
    • 79952583052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 182, at ix (introducing the book as "a study of discrepancies between an ever fluctuating demand and a relatively inelastic fund of productive capacity, resulting in wastes of partial idleness, and many other economic disturbances. Unused capacity is its central theme").
    • CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at ix (introducing the book as "a study of discrepancies between an ever fluctuating demand and a relatively inelastic fund of productive capacity, resulting in wastes of partial idleness, and many other economic disturbances. Unused capacity is its central theme").
    • Overhead Costs
    • Clark1
  • 345
    • 79952588129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Frank made similar observations in Institutionalist Analysis. Frank, supra note 141, at 491. He noted that, historically, under hand-production there was a close relationship between output and prices because production was responsive to demand virtually on a unitby-unit basis. By contrast, machine production led for the need of machines that kept running at high output regardless of demand. This fact, plus the offsetting correctives made by managers, led to booms and busts as industries swung between over- and underproduction. Joseph Schumpeter's massive study of business cycles came almost two decades later but developed many of the same points with copious historical examples.
  • 347
    • 33748329567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schumpeter's business cycles as business history
    • 231
    • See Thomas K. McCraw, Schumpeter's Business Cycles as Business History, 80 BUS. HIS. REV. 231,231 (2006).
    • (2006) Bus. His. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 231
    • McCraw, T.K.1
  • 348
    • 79952583052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 182, at
    • CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 258-97.
    • Overhead Costs , pp. 258-297
    • Clark1
  • 349
    • 79952597504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 318-34.
    • Id. at 318-34.
  • 350
    • 79952578164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at ix.
    • Id. at ix.
  • 351
    • 0000827401 scopus 로고
    • Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process
    • (applying transaction cost economics to problems of vertical contracting)
    • See, e.g., Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford & Armen A. Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297 (1978) (applying transaction cost economics to problems of vertical contracting);
    • (1978) J.L. & Econ. , vol.21 , pp. 297
    • Klein, B.1    Crawford, R.G.2    Alchian, A.A.3
  • 352
    • 79952613067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WILLIAMSON, supra note 42 (same).
    • WILLIAMSON, supra note 42 (same).
  • 353
    • 79952583052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 182, at 403-07.
    • CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 23-24, 403-07.
    • Overhead Costs , pp. 23-24
    • Clark1
  • 354
    • 79952579803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 386.
    • Id. at 386.
  • 355
    • 79952612214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 402.
    • Id. at 402.
  • 356
    • 79952588330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 31-33.
    • Cf. WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 31-33.
  • 357
    • 79952583052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 182, at
    • CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 136-37.
    • Overhead Costs , pp. 136-137
    • Clark1
  • 358
    • 79952601691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 137 ("[A]nother gain from integration arises, in the shape of great reliability in the supplying of materials. The two concerns adapt their process to each other, and the supply of materials, both in quality and regularity, can be more carefully suited to the needs of the user....").
    • Id. at 137 ("[A]nother gain from integration arises, in the shape of great reliability in the supplying of materials. The two concerns adapt their process to each other, and the supply of materials, both in quality and regularity, can be more carefully suited to the needs of the user....").
  • 359
    • 79952598642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • M at 137.
    • M at 137
  • 360
    • 79952586637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 119-22
    • Id. at 119-22.
  • 361
    • 79952602688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 399-400
    • Id. at 399-400.
  • 362
    • 79952611800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 138
    • Id. at 138.
  • 363
    • 79952605045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 137-38
    • Id. at 137-38.
  • 364
    • 79952597306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 138
    • Id. at 138.
  • 365
    • 79952593541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 366
    • 67649495819 scopus 로고
    • Integration in marketing
    • Id. at 138-39 citing
    • Id. at 138-39 (citing Lewis H. Haney, Integration in Marketing, 10 AM. ECON. REV. 528 (1920)).
    • (1920) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 528
    • Haney, L.H.1
  • 367
    • 79952578384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 140
    • Id. at 140.
  • 368
    • 79952614783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 139
    • Id. at 139.
  • 369
    • 79952613270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 140-41
    • Id. at 140-41.
  • 370
    • 79952583695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klein et al, supra note 190, at 297
    • Klein et al, supra note 190, at 297.
  • 371
    • 79952601693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 416
    • CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 416.
  • 372
    • 84963036464 scopus 로고
    • Clark's economics of overhead costs
    • 490 (book review)
    • T.H. Sanders, Clark's Economics of Overhead Costs, 38 Q.J. ECON. 487, 490 (1924) (book review).
    • (1924) Q.J. Econ. , vol.38 , pp. 487
    • Sanders, T.H.1
  • 373
    • 79952598643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 374
    • 0041008590 scopus 로고
    • An analysis of supply
    • A.C. Pigou, An Analysis of Supply, 38 ECON. J. 238 (1928);
    • (1928) Econ. J. , vol.38 , pp. 238
    • Pigou, A.C.1
  • 375
    • 0001726410 scopus 로고
    • The laws of costs under competitive conditions
    • (explaining that under competition market-wide costs are generally constant)
    • see also Piero Sraffa, The Laws of Costs Under Competitive Conditions, 36 ECON. J. 535 (1926) (explaining that under competition market-wide costs are generally constant).
    • (1926) Econ. J. , vol.36 , pp. 535
    • Sraffa, P.1
  • 376
    • 79952612215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pigou elaborated on this work in The Economics of Welfare. PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. H, ch. 11, §§3-12
    • Pigou elaborated on this work in The Economics of Welfare. PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. H, ch. 11, §§3-12.
  • 377
    • 0001932587 scopus 로고
    • The equilibrium of the firm
    • Nicholas Kaldor,The Equilibrium of the Firm,44 ECON.J.60(1934).
    • (1934) Econ.J. , vol.44 , pp. 60
    • Kaldor, N.1
  • 378
    • 79952602084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. Kaldor also concluded that increasing firm costs were inconsistent with perfect competition
    • Id. Kaldor also concluded that increasing firm costs were inconsistent with perfect competition.
  • 379
    • 79952593129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 72-73
    • Id. at 72-73.
  • 380
    • 0004255169 scopus 로고
    • E.A.G. Robinson, also a Professor of Economics at Cambridge, was married to fellow professor Joan Robinson
    • E.A.G. ROBINSON, THE STRUCTURE OF COMPETITIVE INDUSTRY (1931). E.A.G. Robinson, also a Professor of Economics at Cambridge, was married to fellow professor Joan Robinson.
    • (1931) The Structure of Competitive Industry
    • Robinson, E.A.G.1
  • 381
    • 79952598845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • JOAN ROBINSON, supra note 89, at 69
    • See JOAN ROBINSON, supra note 89, at 69.
  • 382
    • 79952604055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROBINSON, supra note 216, at 40-42
    • ROBINSON, supra note 216, at 40-42.
  • 383
    • 79952585572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 115 (citing United States Steel as an example of a firm that gained economies by operating multiple plants scattered across the country)
    • Id. at 115 (citing United States Steel as an example of a firm that gained economies by operating multiple plants scattered across the country).
  • 384
    • 0000046146 scopus 로고
    • The problem of management and the size of the firm
    • Robinson elaborated on this point in
    • Robinson elaborated on this point in Austin Robinson, The Problem of Management and the Size of the Firm, 44 ECON. J. 242 (1934).
    • (1934) Econ. J. , vol.44 , pp. 242
    • Robinson, A.1
  • 385
    • 79952605494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sraffa, supra note 212, at 535-36
    • See Sraffa, supra note 212, at 535-36.
  • 386
    • 79952595861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386.
  • 387
    • 79952589746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18
    • See Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
  • 388
    • 79952589139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, supra note 8 (calling for more empirical study of the structure of the firm, and lamenting "blackboard economics" that reduces the firm to a "black box")
    • See, e.g., Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, supra note 8 (calling for more empirical study of the structure of the firm, and lamenting "blackboard economics" that reduces the firm to a "black box");
  • 389
    • 0242278700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72 ("Mainstream economics, as one sees it in the journals and the textbooks and in the courses taught in economics departments has become more and more abstract over time, and although it purports otherwise, it is in fact little concerned with what happens in the real world.")
    • see also Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72 ("Mainstream economics, as one sees it in the journals and the textbooks and in the courses taught in economics departments has become more and more abstract over time, and although it purports otherwise, it is in fact little concerned with what happens in the real world.").
  • 390
    • 79952589140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 403
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 403.
  • 391
    • 0009428788 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 403-04 relying on (4th ed. 1950)
    • Id. at 403-04 (relying on FRANCIS RALEIGH BATT, LAW OF MASTER AND SERVANT (4th ed. 1950) (1926)).
    • (1926) Law of Master and Servant
    • Batt, F.R.1
  • 392
    • 79952596689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 8-9 (explaining that during his visit to the United States he took very few classes and instead "most of my time was spent in visiting businesses and industrial plants")
    • See Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 8-9 (explaining that during his visit to the United States he took very few classes and instead "most of my time was spent in visiting businesses and industrial plants");
  • 393
    • 79952594153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 13 (noting a visit to Duquesne Power and Light Co. and the viewing of some cost curves that they had constructed)
    • see also id. at 13 (noting a visit to Duquesne Power and Light Co. and the viewing of some cost curves that they had constructed);
  • 394
    • 79952592702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at 13 (visit to General Motors and discussion of Fisher Body works)
    • id. at 13 (visit to General Motors and discussion of Fisher Body works).
  • 395
    • 79952611801 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386-87
    • Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386-87.
  • 396
    • 79952579588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some of Coase's work was more empirical, although not statistical
    • Some of Coase's work was more empirical, although not statistical.
  • 397
    • 0034360870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The acquisition of fisher body by general motors
    • 16-17 (similar to a case study)
    • See, e.g., R.H. Coase, The Acquisition of Fisher Body by General Motors, 43 J.L. & ECON. 15, 16-17 (2000) (similar to a case study);
    • (2000) J.L. & Econ. , vol.43 , pp. 15
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 398
    • 0001011471 scopus 로고
    • The lighthouse in economics
    • see also Ronald H. Coase, The Lighthouse in Economics, 17 J.L. & ECON. 357 (1974).
    • (1974) J.L. & Econ. , vol.17 , pp. 357
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 399
    • 79952613446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18
    • See Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
  • 400
    • 79952580459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Prize in Economics 2009, available at
    • See Press Release, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Prize in Economics 2009, available at http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/2009/ press.html.
  • 401
    • 79952585981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 8-9
    • See WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 8-9.
  • 403
    • 0000409508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead
    • see also Oliver E. Williamson, The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead, 38 J. ECON. LIT. 595 (2000).
    • (2000) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.38 , pp. 595
    • Williamson, O.E.1
  • 404
    • 79952583894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 146-47
    • See supra text accompanying notes 146-47.
  • 405
    • 79952577727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 50-53
    • See supra text accompanying notes 50-53.
  • 406
    • 79952590531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, Problem of Social Cost, supra note 1, at 1-2
    • Coase, Problem of Social Cost, supra note 1, at 1-2.
  • 407
    • 79952611612 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.