-
1
-
-
0003774434
-
-
6th ed. noting that the "new law and economics" began with Ronald Coase's The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960) [hereinafter Coase, Problem of Social Cost]
-
See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 23 (6th ed. 2003) (noting that the "new law and economics" began with Ronald Coase's The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960) [hereinafter Coase, Problem of Social Cost],
-
(2003)
Economic Analysis of Law
, pp. 23
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
2
-
-
0000670301
-
Some thoughts on risk distribution and the law of torts
-
and Guido Calabresi's Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts, 70 YALE L.J. 499 (1961)).
-
(1961)
Yale L.J.
, vol.70
, pp. 499
-
-
Calabresi'S, G.1
-
3
-
-
0042688399
-
Economics at LSE in the 1930s: A Personal View
-
See RONALD H. COASE, Economics at LSE in the 1930s: A Personal View, in ESSAYS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMISTS 208 (1994) [hereinafter COASE, Economics at LSE];
-
(1994)
Essays on Economics and Economists
, pp. 208
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
4
-
-
34250230292
-
The distinctive LSE ethos in the inter-war years
-
21
-
see also A.W. Coats, The Distinctive LSE Ethos in the Inter-War Years, 10 ATLANTIC ECON. J. 18, 21(1982).
-
(1982)
Atlantic Econ. J.
, vol.10
, pp. 18
-
-
Coats, A.W.1
-
5
-
-
79952594333
-
-
Lord Lionel Robbins was chair of political economy at LSE from 1929 until 1961. Coase described Robbins as the most influential figure of all at LSE in the 1930s. COASE, Economics at LSE
-
Lord Lionel Robbins was chair of political economy at LSE from 1929 until 1961. Coase described Robbins as "the most influential figure of all" at LSE in the 1930s. COASE, Economics at LSE,
-
-
-
-
6
-
-
79952582319
-
-
supra note 2, at 211
-
supra note 2, at 211;
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
5844339983
-
On the demise of pigovian economics
-
See Nahid Aslanbeigui, On the Demise of Pigovian Economics, 56 S. ECON. J. 616 (1990);
-
(1990)
S. Econ. J.
, vol.56
, pp. 616
-
-
Aslanbeigui, N.1
-
11
-
-
77949545739
-
Robbins welfare economics: A reappraisal
-
On the relationships of Pigou, Robbins, and Coase, see Nahid Aslanbeigui, Introduction to ARTHUR CECIL PIGOU, THE ECONOMICS OF WELFARE, at li-lx (Transaction Publishers 2002) (1932)
-
Roger E. Backhouse, Robbins and Welfare Economics: A Reappraisal, 31 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 474 (2009). On the relationships of Pigou, Robbins, and Coase, see Nahid Aslanbeigui, Introduction to ARTHUR CECIL PIGOU, THE ECONOMICS OF WELFARE, at li-lx (Transaction Publishers 2002) (1932);
-
(2009)
J. Hist. Econ. Thought
, vol.31
, pp. 474
-
-
Backhouse, R.E.1
-
12
-
-
0347173914
-
Beyond the dark clouds: Pigou and coase on social cost
-
Nahid Aslanbeigui & Steven G. Medema, Beyond the Dark Clouds: Pigou and Coase on Social Cost, 30 HIST. POL. ECON. 601 (1998);
-
(1998)
Hist. Pol. Econ.
, vol.30
, pp. 601
-
-
Aslanbeigui, N.1
Medema, S.G.2
-
13
-
-
79251600688
-
The coase theorem and arthur cecil pigou
-
Herbert Hovenkamp, The Coase Theorem and Arthur Cecil Pigou, 51 ARIZ. L. REV. 633 (2009) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Coase Theorem];
-
(2009)
Ariz. L. Rev.
, vol.51
, pp. 633
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
14
-
-
0040921724
-
Ronald coase, the british tradition, and the future of economic method
-
Steven G. Medema ed
-
Richard O. Zerbe, Jr. & Steven G. Medema, Ronald Coase, the British Tradition, and the Future of Economic Method, in COASEAN ECONOMICS: LAW AND ECONOMICS AND THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS 209 (Steven G. Medema ed, 1998). On Marshall and the Cambridge School,
-
(1998)
Coasean Economics: Law and Economics and the New Institutional Economics
, pp. 209
-
-
Zerbe Jr., R.O.1
Medema, S.G.2
-
15
-
-
79952298986
-
Alfred marshall and the establishment of the cambridge economic tripos
-
see Peter D. Groenewegen, Alfred Marshall and the Establishment of the Cambridge Economic Tripos, 20 HIST. POL. ECON. 627(1988).
-
(1988)
Hist. Pol. Econ.
, vol.20
, pp. 627
-
-
Groenewegen, P.D.1
-
16
-
-
84917106186
-
The nature of the firm: Origin
-
Coase took a Bachelor of Commerce degree at LSE in 1932 and was on its teaching staff from 1935 to 1951, except for an assignment as a government statistician during World War II; he also made a visit to the United States in 1931 and 1932, where he collected observations for his article The Nature of the Firm. See R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm: Origin, 4 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 3 (1988) [hereinafter Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin].
-
(1988)
J.L. Econ. & Org.
, vol.4
, pp. 3
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
17
-
-
0344355338
-
Introductory: LSE and the robbins circle
-
Harvard Univ. Press
-
For a good history of the principal faculty and most famous students at LSE, see the website at http://homepage.newschool.edU/het//schools/lse.htm. For John Hicks's perspective, see JOHN HICKS, Introductory: LSE and the Robbins Circle, in 2 MONEY, INTEREST AND WAGES: COLLECTED ESSAYS ON ECONOMIC THEORY 3 (Harvard Univ. Press 1982).
-
(1982)
Money, Interest and Wages: Collected Essays on Economic Theory
, vol.2
, pp. 3
-
-
Hicks, J.1
-
18
-
-
79952609129
-
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 6 (recalling that in his years at LSE as a student he took no courses in economics and spent most of his time studying law, particularly "industrial law")
-
See Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 6 (recalling that in his years at LSE as a student he took no courses in economics and spent most of his time studying law, particularly "industrial law").
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
79952604853
-
-
Ronald H. Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, The Institutional Structure of Production (Dec. 9, 1991) [hereinafter Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture]
-
See, e.g., Ronald H. Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, The Institutional Structure of Production (Dec. 9, 1991) [hereinafter Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture], available at http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/1991/coase- lecture.html;
-
-
-
-
20
-
-
0242278700
-
The new institutional economics
-
see also Ronald Coase, The New Institutional Economics, 88 AM. ECON. REV. 72 (1998) [hereinafter Coase, New Institutional Economics].
-
(1998)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.88
, pp. 72
-
-
Coase, R.1
-
21
-
-
69849097554
-
New institutional economics
-
Steven N. Durlaf & Lawrence E. Blume eds, 2d ed.
-
See L.J. Alston, New Institutional Economics, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS (Steven N. Durlaf & Lawrence E. Blume eds, 2d ed. 2008), available at http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008- N000170;
-
(2008)
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
-
-
Alston, L.J.1
-
25
-
-
79952581725
-
-
Nonetheless, the old institutionalists continue to publish journals, including The Journal of Economic Issues and the Journal of Institutional Economics. Several scholarly organizations support their work, including the Association for Evolutionary Economics
-
Nonetheless, the old institutionalists continue to publish journals, including The Journal of Economic Issues and the Journal of Institutional Economics. Several scholarly organizations support their work, including the Association for Evolutionary Economics.
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
79952615454
-
-
See ASS'N FOR EVOLUTIONARY ECON, http://www. associationforevolutionaryeconomics.org/ divison.php?page=institutional- economics&sub=associations.
-
Ass'n for Evolutionary Econ
-
-
-
28
-
-
79952610580
-
-
See infra text accompanying notes 123-24
-
See infra text accompanying notes 123-24.
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
79952596888
-
-
See infra Part II
-
See infra Part II.
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
79952583897
-
-
See infra text accompanying notes 162-69
-
See infra text accompanying notes 162-69.
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
0242278700
-
-
This statement seems quite true, notwithstanding that in an essay on new institutional economics, Coase specifically acknowledged the work of our colleagues in law, anthropology, sociology, political science, sociobiology, and other disciplines Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72.
-
This statement seems quite true, notwithstanding that in an essay on new institutional economics, Coase specifically acknowledged "the work of our colleagues in law, anthropology, sociology, political science, sociobiology, and other disciplines." Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72.
-
-
-
-
32
-
-
79952606744
-
-
See infra text accompanying notes 168-69
-
See infra text accompanying notes 168-69.
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
79952613069
-
Coasean markets
-
forthcoming 2011 [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets] published online Dec. 8, 2010
-
See Herbert Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, 31 EUR. J.L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2011) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets] (published online Dec. 8, 2010, available at http://www.springerlink.com/content/65031035h363gl 64/fulltext.pdf).
-
Eur. J.L. & Econ.
, vol.31
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
34
-
-
0001055815
-
The new institutionalism: New but not institutionalist
-
See William Dugger, The New Institutionalism: New but Not Institutionalist, 24 J. ECON. ISSUES 423 (1990) (criticizing New Institutionalism for rejecting earlier commitments to behaviorism, cognition, and the study of nonmarket transfers of resources).
-
(1990)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.24
, pp. 423
-
-
Dugger, W.1
-
35
-
-
79952595211
-
The sveriges riksbank prize in economic sciences in memory of alfred nobel
-
NIE's most prominent spokesperson other than Coase himself, received the Nobel Prize. Oct. 24
-
In 2009 Oliver E. Williamson, NIE's most prominent spokesperson other than Coase himself, received the Nobel Prize. The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2009, NOBELPRIZE.ORG (Oct. 24, 2010), http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/2009.
-
(2010)
Nobelprize.Org
, vol.2009
-
-
Williamson, O.E.1
-
36
-
-
85071381340
-
Harvard, Chicago, and transaction cost economics in antitrust analysis
-
See Herbert Hovenkamp, Harvard, Chicago, and Transaction Cost Economics in Antitrust Analysis, 55 ANTITRUST BULL. 613 (2010).
-
(2010)
Antitrust Bull.
, vol.55
, pp. 613
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
39
-
-
0012498663
-
-
1870-1889
-
See RICHARD S. HOWEY, THE RISE OF THE MARGINAL UTILITY SCHOOL: 1870-1889, at 1-24 (1960) (discussing the origins of marginalist neoclassical economics in the work of William Stanley Jevons in the late 1860s and 1870s).
-
(1960)
The Rise of The Marginal Utility School
, pp. 1-24
-
-
Howey, R.S.1
-
40
-
-
79952584666
-
-
See generally id. (tracing rise of marginalist thought in England, Continental Europe, and the United States)
-
See generally id. (tracing rise of marginalist thought in England, Continental Europe, and the United States).
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
79952600273
-
The origins of marginalism
-
Richard S. Howey, The Origins of Marginalism, 4 HIST. POL. ECON. 281 (1972);
-
(1972)
Hist. Pol. Econ.
, vol.4
, pp. 281
-
-
Howey, R.S.1
-
43
-
-
0001129346
-
Development of utility theory. II
-
George J. Stigler, The Development of Utility Theory. II, 58 J. POL. ECON. 373 (1950).
-
(1950)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.58
, pp. 373
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
44
-
-
79952610188
-
-
The most prominent classical political economists were Adam Smith, David Ricardo, James Mill and his son John Stuart Mill, Thomas Malthus, and Jean-Baptiste Say
-
The most prominent classical political economists were Adam Smith, David Ricardo, James Mill and his son John Stuart Mill, Thomas Malthus, and Jean-Baptiste Say.
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
79952586200
-
-
BLAUG, supra note 10, at 33-214. On the divide between pre-marginalist and marginalist economics in United States policy
-
See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 33-214. On the divide between pre-marginalist and marginalist economics in United States policy,
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
84979188687
-
The nature of the firm
-
392
-
R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386, 392 (1937) [hereinafter Coase, Nature of the Firm].
-
(1937)
Economica
, vol.4
, pp. 386
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
48
-
-
0347569357
-
Marshall's dilemma: Equilibrium versus evolution
-
1139
-
See Neil Hart, Marshall's Dilemma: Equilibrium Versus Evolution, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 1139, 1139-40 (2003) (discussing tension between evolutionary and engineering models in Marshall's thought).
-
(2003)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.37
, pp. 1139-1140
-
-
Hart, N.1
-
49
-
-
0007131267
-
-
1867-1890, On Jevons's and Marshall's indebtedness to Cournot, see HOWEY, supra note 23, at 80-85.
-
See, e.g., 1 ALFRED MARSHALL, THE EARLY WRITINGS OF ALFRED MARSHALL, 1867-1890, at 38-39 (1975). On Jevons's and Marshall's indebtedness to Cournot, see HOWEY, supra note 23, at 80-85.
-
(1975)
The Early Writings of Alfred Marshall
, pp. 38-39
-
-
Marshall, A.1
-
50
-
-
79952577507
-
-
See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 277-353
-
See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 277-353.
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
79952582318
-
-
Preference transitivity, a condition of rationality, is a logical consistency condition that if someone prefers A over B and B over C, then she must also prefer A over C
-
Preference transitivity, a condition of rationality, is a logical consistency condition that if someone prefers A over B and B over C, then she must also prefer A over C.
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
0000873771
-
The representative firm
-
389
-
See Lionel Robbins, The Representative Firm, 38 ECON. J. 387, 389 (1928) (noting highly abstract nature of business firm in Marshall's Principles);
-
(1928)
Econ. J.
, vol.38
, pp. 387
-
-
Robbins, L.1
-
54
-
-
5844323369
-
The place of marshall's principles in the development of economics
-
John K. Whitaker ed
-
cf. George J. Stigler, The Place of Marshall's Principles in the Development of Economics, in CENTENARY ESSAYS ON ALFRED MARSHALL 8 (John K. Whitaker ed, 1990) (noting that study of the firm in price theory is largely intended to ascertain its behavior as a demander of inputs and a supplier of outputs);
-
(1990)
Centenary Essays on Alfred Marshall
, pp. 8
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
55
-
-
14944367299
-
Monopolization, exclusion, and the theory of the firm
-
Alan J. Meese, Monopolization, Exclusion, and the Theory of the Firm, 89 MINN. L. REV. 743 (2005) (similar).
-
(2005)
Minn. L. Rev.
, vol.89
, pp. 743
-
-
Meese, A.J.1
-
56
-
-
0001731516
-
The institutional structure of production
-
714
-
See Ronald H. Coase, The Institutional Structure of Production, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 713, 714 (1992);
-
(1992)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.82
, pp. 713
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
57
-
-
0001763518
-
The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm
-
377
-
cf. Harold Demsetz, The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm, 26 J.L. & ECON. 375, 377 (1983) ("The chief mission of neoclassical economics [i.e., price theory] is to understand how the price system coordinates the use of resources, not to understand the inner workings of real firms.");
-
(1983)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.26
, pp. 375
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
58
-
-
77958132013
-
The theory of the firm revisited
-
143
-
Harold Demsetz, The Theory of the Firm Revisited, 4 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 141, 143 (1988) (noting extent to which the firm in neoclassical economics is an abstraction).
-
(1988)
J.L. Econ. & Org.
, vol.4
, pp. 141
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
61
-
-
79952593713
-
-
See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 388-92
-
See BLAUG, supra note 10, at 388-92.
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
0003542293
-
-
See DOUGLASS C. NORTH, STRUCTURE AND CHANGE IN ECONOMIC HISTORY 5 (1981). [T]his neoclassical formulation appears to beg all of the interesting questions. The world with which it is concerned is a frictionless one in which institutions do not exist and all change occurs through perfectly operating markets. In short, the costs of acquiring information, uncertainty, and transactions costs do not exist. Id.
-
(1981)
Structure and Change in Economic History
, pp. 5
-
-
North, D.C.1
-
63
-
-
79952585767
-
-
See PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. III, §3, at 138
-
See PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. III, §3, at 138.
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
77953074502
-
The law of vertical integration and the business firm, 18801960
-
863, [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Law of Vertical Integration]
-
see also Herbert Hovenkamp, The Law of Vertical Integration and the Business Firm, 18801960, 95 IOWA L. REV. 863, 871-72 (2010) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Law of Vertical Integration], available at http://papers.ssm.com/ sol3/papers.cftn?abstract-id=1268328 (discussing Marshall's Industry and Trade as an early theory of vertical integration).
-
(2010)
Iowa L. Rev.
, vol.95
, pp. 87172
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
66
-
-
79952605706
-
-
MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 56-59, 799-802 (discussing textile production and markets)
-
See, e.g., MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 56-59, 799-802 (discussing textile production and markets);
-
-
-
-
67
-
-
79952583693
-
-
94-95, 21821, 802-03 (discussing steel production and markets)
-
id. at 94-95, 218-21, 802-03 (discussing steel production and markets).
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
79952580457
-
-
Id. at 589
-
Id. at 589.
-
-
-
-
69
-
-
79952607650
-
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 392 ("[T]he operation of a market costs something and by forming an organization and allowing some authority (an 'entrepreneur') to direct the resources, certain marketing costs are saved.)
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 392 ("[T]he operation of a market costs something and by forming an organization and allowing some authority (an 'entrepreneur') to direct the resources, certain marketing costs are saved.");
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
79952592264
-
-
see also id. at 395 ([A] point must be reached where the loss through the waste of resources is equal to the marketing costs of the exchange transaction in the open market...")
-
see also id. at 395 ("[A] point must be reached where the loss through the waste of resources is equal to the marketing costs of the exchange transaction in the open market...").
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
79952605279
-
-
MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 322
-
MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 322.
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
79952592911
-
-
Id. at 324
-
Id. at 324.
-
-
-
-
74
-
-
79952585075
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
77953057454
-
Neoclassicism and the separation of ownership and control
-
375
-
On this point, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Neoclassicism and the Separation of Ownership and Control, 4 VA. L. & Bus. REV. 373, 375 (2009);
-
(2009)
Va. L. & Bus. Rev.
, vol.4
, pp. 373
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
77
-
-
84924756636
-
Retrospect: Berle and means
-
see also Thomas K. McCraw, In Retrospect: Berle and Means, 18 REV. AM. HIST. 578 (1990).
-
(1990)
Rev. Am. Hist.
, vol.18
, pp. 578
-
-
McCraw, T.K.1
-
78
-
-
0003593983
-
-
supra note 38, 37577, 385-87
-
MARSHALL, INDUSTRY AND TRADE, supra note 38, at 368, 375-77, 385-87.
-
Industry and Trade
, pp. 368
-
-
Marshall1
-
81
-
-
57349178972
-
Charles babbage's influence on the development of alfred marshall's theory of the firm
-
Neil B. Niman, Charles Babbage's Influence on the Development of Alfred Marshall's Theory of the Firm, 30 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 479 (2008).
-
(2008)
J. Hist. Econ. Thought
, vol.30
, pp. 479
-
-
Niman, N.B.1
-
82
-
-
79952603113
-
The appointment of pigou as marshall's successor
-
RONALD H. COASE, 151
-
On Pigou's appointment, see RONALD H. COASE, The Appointment of Pigou as Marshall's Successor, in RONALD H. COASE, ESSAYS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMISTS 151, 151-66(1994).
-
(1994)
Essays on Economics and Economists
, pp. 151-166
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
83
-
-
79952600858
-
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt II, ch. III, §3, at 138
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt II, ch. III, §3, at 138;
-
-
-
-
84
-
-
79751490010
-
-
supra note 4
-
see Hovenkamp, Coase Theorem, supra note 4 (comparing Pigou's broader conception of cost of movement against Coase's conception of transaction costs).
-
Coase Theorem
-
-
Hovenkamp1
-
85
-
-
79952600069
-
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. Ill, §3, at 138-39
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. II, ch. Ill, §3, at 138-39.
-
-
-
-
86
-
-
79952598645
-
-
Id. pt. II, ch. VII, §1, at 158. Guido Calabresi, the other person that Richard Posner cites as a founder of modem law and economics in the United States, also used cost much more broadly in this fashion
-
Id. pt. II, ch. VII, §1, at 158. Guido Calabresi, the other person that Richard Posner cites as a founder of modem law and economics in the United States, also used "cost" much more broadly in this fashion.
-
-
-
-
87
-
-
79952591394
-
-
Calabresi, supra note 1 (speaking not of transaction costs, but rather of such costs as those of running the insurance system, costs of administering the system of enterprise liability, and the like). For Posner's comment crediting Calabresi, see supra note 1
-
See Calabresi, supra note 1 (speaking not of transaction costs, but rather of such costs as those of running the insurance system, costs of administering the system of enterprise liability, and the like). For Posner's comment crediting Calabresi, see supra note 1.
-
-
-
-
88
-
-
0000964163
-
Were the ordinalists wrong about welfare economics?
-
507
-
See, e.g., Robert Cooter & Peter Rappoport, Were the Ordinalists Wrong About Welfare Economics?, 22 J. ECON. LIT. 507, 515-16 (1984).
-
(1984)
J. Econ. Lit.
, vol.22
, pp. 515-516
-
-
Cooter, R.1
Rappoport, P.2
-
90
-
-
0004148224
-
-
Penguin Books 1970
-
See WILLIAM STANLEY JEVONS, THE THEORY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY (Penguin Books 1970) (1871). In the introduction, Jevons stated: The reader will find, again, that there is never, in any single instance, an attempt to compare the amount of feeling in one mind with that in another. I see no means by which such comparison can be accomplished. The susceptibility of one mind may, for what we know, be a thousand times greater than that of another. But, provided that the susceptibility was different in a like ratio in all directions, we should never be able to discover the difference. Every mind is thus inscrutable to every other mind, and no common denominator of feeling seems to be possible. ... [T]he motive in one mind is weighed only against other motives in the same mind never against the motives in other minds. Id. at 85;
-
(1871)
The Theory of Political Economy
-
-
Jevons, W.S.1
-
94
-
-
0003733205
-
-
Cooter Rappoport, supra note 54, at 515 quoting
-
Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 515 (quoting VILFREDO PARETO, COURS D'ECONOMIE POLITIQUE 3 (1896)).
-
(1896)
Cours D'economie Politique
, pp. 3
-
-
Pareto, V.1
-
95
-
-
79952609986
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
96
-
-
79952611613
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
97
-
-
84935190124
-
The first great law and economics movement
-
1053
-
See Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law and Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993, 1053(1990).
-
(1990)
Stan. L. Rev.
, vol.42
, pp. 993
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
98
-
-
79952599057
-
The present position of economics, inaugural lecture at cambridge university
-
Feb. 24, 1885, 131
-
Alfred Marshall, The Present Position of Economics, Inaugural Lecture at Cambridge University (Feb. 24, 1885), in 1 J. INSTITUTIONAL ECON. 121, 131 (2005);
-
(2005)
J. Institutional Econ.
, vol.1
, pp. 121
-
-
Marshall, A.1
-
100
-
-
79952608690
-
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 89
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 89.
-
-
-
-
103
-
-
0005160493
-
Some aspects of welfare economies
-
292
-
Arthur C. Pigou, Some Aspects of Welfare Economies, 41 AM. ECON. REV. 287, 292 (1951).
-
(1951)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.41
, pp. 287
-
-
Pigou, A.C.1
-
104
-
-
79952592912
-
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 91.
-
PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. I, ch. VIII, §3, at 91.
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
79952587507
-
-
Id. at 18-19
-
Id. at 18-19.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
79952599456
-
-
Pigou, supra note 65, at 292 (emphasis in original)
-
Pigou, supra note 65, at 292 (emphasis in original).
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
0003736757
-
-
supra note 68, at bk. II, ch. iii, §3
-
MARSHALL, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS, supra note 68, at bk. II, ch. iii, §3, at 67-68 ("This brings us to consider the term Necessaries. It is common to distinguish necessaries, comforts, and luxuries; the first class including all things required to meet wants which must be satisfied, while the latter consist of things that meet wants of a less urgent character. But here again there is a troublesome ambiguity. When we say that a want must be satisfied, what are the consequences which we have in view if it is not satisfied? Do they include death? Or do they extend only to the loss of strength and vigour? In other words, are necessaries the things which are necessary for life, or those which are necessary for efficiency?").
-
Principles of Economics
, pp. 67-68
-
-
Marshall1
-
110
-
-
79952593715
-
-
The distinction is developed in Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 513-14
-
The distinction is developed in Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 513-14.
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
37949051459
-
A statistical method for measuring marginal utility and testing the justice of a progressive income tax
-
Jacob H. Hollander ed
-
Irving Fisher, A Statistical Method for Measuring "Marginal Utility" and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax, in ECONOMIC ESSAYS CONTRIBUTED IN HONOR OF JOHN BATES CLARK 181 (Jacob H. Hollander ed, 1927) [hereinafter Fisher, Statistical Method];
-
(1927)
Economic Essays Contributed in Honor of John Bates Clark
, pp. 181
-
-
Fisher, I.1
-
113
-
-
79952578583
-
-
Fisher, Statistical Method, supra note 73, at 159
-
Fisher, Statistical Method, supra note 73, at 159;
-
-
-
-
114
-
-
34547358954
-
Retrospectives: Edgeworth 's hedonimeter and the quest to measure utility
-
215
-
see David Colander, Retrospectives: Edgeworth 's Hedonimeter and the Quest to Measure Utility, 21 J. ECON. PERSP. 215, 219-21 (2007) (discussing Fisher's model) .
-
(2007)
J. Econ. Persp.
, vol.21
, pp. 219-221
-
-
Colander, D.1
-
115
-
-
0004260377
-
-
See, e.g., JOHN R. COMMONS, THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH 10 (1893) ("To the poor man all the marginal increments may afford high satisfaction, because his supplies are limited; but to the rich man the marginal increments may give little satisfaction. Yet each, though on different levels, endeavours to make the marginal increments in all lines equal.");
-
(1893)
The Distribution of Wealth
, pp. 10
-
-
Commons, J.R.1
-
116
-
-
79952592484
-
-
§6, at 132 3d ed.
-
F.W. TAUSSIG, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS ch. 9, §6, at 132 (3d ed. 1921) ("The principle of diminishing utility, if applied unflinchingly, leads to the conclusion that inequality of incomes brings a less sum of human well-being than equality of incomes, and that the greater the inequality, the less the approach to the maximum.");
-
(1921)
Principles of Economics Ch. 9
-
-
Taussig, F.W.1
-
117
-
-
79952584274
-
-
GEORGE P. WATKINS, WELFARE AS AN ECONOMIC QUANTITY 185-90 (1915) (arguing that total social utility would increase if incomes were leveled somewhat and the right to inherit severely curtailed);
-
(1915)
Welfare as an Economic Quantity
, pp. 185-190
-
-
Watkins, G.P.1
-
118
-
-
37949009312
-
The ultimate standard of value
-
J.B. Clark, The Ultimate Standard of Value, 1 YALE REV. 258 (1892) (arguing that social welfare is a function of aggregated individual utilities);
-
(1892)
Yale Rev.
, vol.1
, pp. 258
-
-
Clark, J.B.1
-
119
-
-
1542456089
-
The scope of political economy
-
Simon N. Patten, The Scope of Political Economy, 2 YALE REV. 264 (1893) (arguing that homogeneity of wealth and property tends to increase total utility);
-
(1893)
Yale Rev.
, vol.2
, pp. 264
-
-
Patten, S.N.1
-
120
-
-
0039781391
-
The utility concept in value theory and its critics
-
pts. 1 & 2, 638, 644
-
Jacob Viner, The Utility Concept in Value Theory and Its Critics (pts. 1 & 2), 33 J. POL. ECON. 369, 638, 644 (1925) ("Changes in the relative distribution of income as between different classes will bring about changes in the amount of welfare, even though the aggregate real income of the community remains the same.").
-
(1925)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.33
, pp. 369
-
-
Viner, J.1
-
121
-
-
79952606315
-
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139-40 (emphasis in original)
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139-40 (emphasis in original);
-
-
-
-
122
-
-
0001059988
-
Interpersonal comparisons of utility: A comment
-
see also Lionel Robbins, Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility: A Comment, 48 ECON. J. 635 (1938).
-
(1938)
Econ. J.
, vol.48
, pp. 635
-
-
Robbins, L.1
-
123
-
-
79952581724
-
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 139.
-
-
-
-
124
-
-
79952585982
-
-
Id. at 137
-
Id. at 137.
-
-
-
-
125
-
-
79952576881
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
126
-
-
26444502901
-
The limits of preference-based legal policy
-
4, 6-10, 22-24
-
On this point, see Herbert Hovenkamp, The Limits of Preference-Based Legal Policy, 89 Nw. U. L. REV. 4, 6-10, 22-24, 29-40 (1994).
-
(1994)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.89
, pp. 29-40
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
127
-
-
79952603115
-
-
Viner, supra note 75, at 657
-
Viner, supra note 75, at 657.
-
-
-
-
128
-
-
60949940121
-
Concept of normal price in value and distribution
-
67
-
F.H. Knight, The Concept of Normal Price in Value and Distribution, 32 Q.J. ECON. 66, 67 (1917).
-
(1917)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.32
, pp. 66
-
-
Knight, F.H.1
-
129
-
-
84919387812
-
Traditional economic theory
-
Discussion, 145
-
Irving Fisher, Frank H. Knight & Carl E. Parry, Discussion, Traditional Economic Theory, 11 AM. ECON. REV. 143, 145 (1921).
-
(1921)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.11
, pp. 143
-
-
Fisher, I.1
Knight, F.H.2
Parry, C.E.3
-
130
-
-
84963062664
-
The production function and the theory of capital
-
See Joan Robinson, The Production Function and the Theory of Capital, 21 REV. ECON. STUD. 81 (1953);
-
(1953)
Rev. Econ. Stud.
, vol.21
, pp. 81
-
-
Robinson, J.1
-
131
-
-
0242379960
-
The production function
-
67
-
see also Joan Robinson, The Production Function, 65 ECON. J. 67, 67 (1955) (using illustration of the production function of a robin as measured by the number of grubs caught in relation to the number of robin-minutes worked).
-
(1955)
Econ. J.
, vol.65
, pp. 67
-
-
Robinson, J.1
-
132
-
-
79952576499
-
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 135-37
-
E.g., ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 135-37.
-
-
-
-
133
-
-
79952612006
-
-
See Infra Text Accompanying Notes 96-97
-
See infra text accompanying notes 96-97.
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
79952597088
-
-
id. at 54142 (seed)
-
id. at 54142 (seed).
-
-
-
-
136
-
-
79952601099
-
-
Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 528
-
Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54, at 528.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
79952608256
-
-
Oct. 25
-
A woman did not receive the Nobel Prize in Economics until 2009, when it was given to Elinor Ostrom. Noble Prize Awarded Women, NOBLEPRIZE.ORG (Oct. 25, 2010), http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/lists/women.html.
-
(2010)
Noble Prize Awarded Women
-
-
Ostrom, E.1
-
140
-
-
21144473011
-
The marginalist revolution in legal thought
-
305
-
See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Legal Thought, 46 VAND. L. REV. 305, 305-06 (1993).
-
(1993)
Vand. L. Rev.
, vol.46
, pp. 305-306
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
141
-
-
79952583896
-
-
HOWEY, supra note 23, at 1-35
-
See HOWEY, supra note 23, at 1-35.
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
79952601695
-
Natura non facit saltum in alfred marshall (and Charles Darwin)
-
59
-
On Alfred Marshall and Darwin, see Geoffrey Fishburn, Natura Non Facit Saltum in Alfred Marshall (and Charles Darwin), 40 HIST. ECON. REV. 59, 59 (2004) ("Nature does not make a leap.");
-
(2004)
Hist. Econ. Rev.
, vol.40
, pp. 59
-
-
Fishburn, G.1
-
143
-
-
0347569357
-
Marshall's dilemma: Equilibrium versus evolution
-
Neil Hart, Marshall's Dilemma: Equilibrium versus Evolution, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 1139 (2003). On uses of Darwin by early American economists,
-
(2003)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.37
, pp. 1139
-
-
Hart, N.1
-
144
-
-
0041187326
-
Evolutionary models in jurisprudence
-
see Herbert Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models in Jurisprudence, 64 TEX. L. REV. 645 (1985) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models];
-
(1985)
Tex. L. Rev.
, vol.64
, pp. 645
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
145
-
-
84935190124
-
The first great law & economics movement
-
Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993 (1990). More generally,
-
(1990)
Stan. L. Rev.
, vol.42
, pp. 993
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
148
-
-
0011036471
-
Social darwinism revisited
-
Bernard Bailyn, Donald Fleming & Stephan Themstrom eds
-
see also Donald C. Bellomy, "Social Darwinism" Revisited, in 1 PERSPECTIVES IN AMERICAN HISTORY 1 (Bernard Bailyn, Donald Fleming & Stephan Themstrom eds, 1984) (noting how Social Darwinism has been caricatured);
-
(1984)
PerspectIves in American History
, vol.1
, pp. 1
-
-
Bellomy, D.C.1
-
149
-
-
67349198642
-
Origins of the myth of social darwinism: The ambiguous legacy of richard hofstadter's social darwinism in American thought
-
Thomas C. Leonard, Origins of the Myth of Social Darwinism: The Ambiguous Legacy of Richard Hofstadter's Social Darwinism in American Thought, 71 J. ECON. BEHAV. & ORG. 37 (2009).
-
(2009)
J. Econ. Behav. & Org.
, vol.71
, pp. 37
-
-
Leonard, T.C.1
-
150
-
-
79952613066
-
-
HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 6-7
-
See HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 6-7.
-
-
-
-
151
-
-
84935560114
-
-
See DOROTHY ROSS, THE ORIGINS OF AMERICAN SOCIAL SCIENCE 156-62 (1991). Ross uses the term "liberal exceptionalism" rather than "Reform Darwinism." Importantly, Reform Darwinism, by whatever name it is called, also led to eugenics and the use of controlled breeding or sterilization to improve the human race, along with exclusion of certain immigrants and other racist policies that quickly became classified as horrific after the rise of Adolf Hitler.
-
(1991)
The Origins Of American Social Science
, pp. 156-162
-
-
Ross, D.1
-
154
-
-
0011593973
-
The political economy of immigration restriction in the United States
-
1890 to 1921, Claudia Goldin and Gary D. Libecap eds
-
see Claudia Goldin, The Political Economy of Immigration Restriction in the United States, 1890 to 1921, in THE REGULATED ECONOMY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY 223 (Claudia Goldin and Gary D. Libecap eds, 1994);
-
(1994)
The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to Political Economy
, pp. 223
-
-
Goldin, C.1
-
155
-
-
33645806734
-
Retrospectives: Eugenics and economics in the progressive Era
-
Thomas C Leonard, Retrospectives: Eugenics and Economics in the Progressive Era, 19 J. ECON. PERSP. 207 (2005).
-
(2005)
J. Econ. Persp.
, vol.19
, pp. 207
-
-
Leonard, T.C.1
-
159
-
-
79952604056
-
-
HOFSTADTER, supra note 94
-
HOFSTADTER, supra note 94.
-
-
-
-
160
-
-
79952614133
-
-
See id.; see also BANNISTER, supra note 97
-
See id.; see also BANNISTER, supra note 97;
-
-
-
-
165
-
-
84928841903
-
The political economy of substantive due process
-
379
-
See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Political Economy of Substantive Due Process, 40 STAN. L. REV. 379, 417-20 (1988) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Political Economy];
-
(1988)
Stan. L. Rev.
, vol.40
, pp. 417-420
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
166
-
-
0040001176
-
The survival of the fittest and the origins of social darwinism
-
223
-
see also Gregory Claeys, The "Survival of the Fittest" and the Origins of Social Darwinism, 61 J. HIST. IDEAS 223, 223-24 (2000). Reform Darwinist Lester Frank Ward made plain his belief that so-called Social Darwinism was not a biological doctrine at all, but rather emanated from classical political economy.
-
(2000)
J. Hist. Ideas
, vol.61
, pp. 223-224
-
-
Claeys, G.1
-
167
-
-
10044295245
-
Social and biological struggles
-
292
-
See Lester F. Ward, Social and Biological Struggles, 13 AM. J. SOC. 289, 292 (1907).
-
(1907)
Am. J. Soc.
, vol.13
, pp. 289
-
-
Ward, L.F.1
-
168
-
-
79952583467
-
-
See Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54. The only allusion to the theory of evolution occurs in a footnote discussing Pareto that refers to his conception of material welfare as "some Spencerian ideas of evolutionary fitness." Id. at 516 n.22
-
See Cooter & Rappoport, supra note 54. The only allusion to the theory of evolution occurs in a footnote discussing Pareto that refers to his conception of material welfare as "some Spencerian ideas of evolutionary fitness." Id. at 516 n.22.
-
-
-
-
169
-
-
0037344986
-
Darwinism and institutional economics
-
85
-
See Geoffrey M. Hodgson, Darwinism and Institutional Economics, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 85, 91-95 (2003).
-
(2003)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.37
, pp. 91-95
-
-
Hodgson, G.M.1
-
170
-
-
79952579014
-
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 78-79 ("The main postulate of the theory of value is the fact that individuals can arrange their preferences in an order, and in fact do so.")
-
ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 78-79 ("The main postulate of the theory of value is the fact that individuals can arrange their preferences in an order, and in fact do so.").
-
-
-
-
171
-
-
79952586402
-
-
See id. at 91-92 ("[I]n a state of equilibrium the relative significance of divisible commodities is equal to their price does involve the assumption that each final choice is consistent with every other, in the sense that if I prefer A to B and B to C, I also prefer A to C ....").
-
See id. at 91-92 ("[I]n a state of equilibrium the relative significance of divisible commodities is equal to their price does involve the assumption that each final choice is consistent with every other, in the sense that if I prefer A to B and B to C, I also prefer A to C ....").
-
-
-
-
172
-
-
79952615648
-
-
See Robbins's famous definition of economics: Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses. Id. at 16
-
See Robbins's famous definition of economics: "Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses." Id. at 16.
-
-
-
-
174
-
-
77949561217
-
Defining economics: The long road to acceptance of the robbins definition
-
see also Roger E. Backhouse & Steve G. Medema, Defining Economics: The Long Road to Acceptance of the Robbins Definition, 76 ECONOMICA 805 (2009);
-
(2009)
Economica
, vol.76
, pp. 805
-
-
Backhouse, R.E.1
Medema, S.G.2
-
175
-
-
77949647520
-
Effective tension in robbins' economic methodology
-
D. Wade Hands, Effective Tension in Robbins' Economic Methodology, 76 ECONOMICA 831 (2009);
-
(2009)
Economica
, vol.76
, pp. 831
-
-
Wade Hands, D.1
-
176
-
-
4744370322
-
Origins of lionel robbins's essay on the nature and significance of economic science
-
Susan Howson, The Origins of Lionel Robbins's Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, 36 HIST. POL. ECON. 413 (2004);
-
(2004)
Hist. Pol. Econ.
, vol.36
, pp. 413
-
-
Howson, S.1
-
178
-
-
0001574498
-
Competition, cooperation, and conflict in economics and biology
-
238
-
On the connection, see J. Hirshleifer, Competition, Cooperation, and Conflict in Economics and Biology, 68 AM. ECON. REV. 238, 241 (1978);
-
(1978)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.68
, pp. 241
-
-
Hirshleifer, J.1
-
179
-
-
0003172533
-
Evolutionary models in economics and law: Cooperation versus conflict strategies
-
Jack Hirshleifer, Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation Versus Conflict Strategies, 4 RES. L. & ECON. 1 (1982).
-
(1982)
Res. L. & Econ.
, vol.4
, pp. 1
-
-
Hirshleifer, J.1
-
180
-
-
0004269732
-
-
Cambridge University Press 1992
-
See T.R. MALTHUS, AN ESSAY ON THE PRINCIPLE OF POPULATION (Cambridge University Press 1992) (1798). On the extent of Darwin's borrowings from Malthus, as well as other political economists, and the extent to which later economists relied on Darwin,
-
(1798)
An Essay on the Principle of Population
-
-
Malthus, T.R.1
-
181
-
-
0007256786
-
Biological analogies in the theory of the firm: Comment
-
see Armen A. Alchian, Biological Analogies in the Theory of the Firm: Comment, 43 AM. ECON. REV. 600 (1953)
-
(1953)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.43
, pp. 600
-
-
Alchian, A.A.1
-
182
-
-
0000433523
-
Biological analogies in the theory of the firm
-
(responding to Edith Tilton Penrose, Biological Analogies in the Theory of the Firm, 42 AM. ECON. REV. 804 (1952));
-
(1952)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.42
, pp. 804
-
-
Penrose, E.T.1
-
183
-
-
0015029748
-
Darwin, malthus and selection
-
Sandra Herbert, Research Note, Darwin, Malthus and Selection, 4 J. HIST. BIOLOGY 209 (1971);
-
(1971)
J. Hist. Biology
, vol.4
, pp. 209
-
-
Herbert, S.1
Note, R.2
-
184
-
-
0042835889
-
Darwin, malthus, and the theory of natural selection
-
Peter Vorzimmer, Darwin, Malthus, and the Theory of Natural Selection, 30 J. HIST. IDEAS 527 (1969);
-
(1969)
J. Hist. Ideas
, vol.30
, pp. 527
-
-
Vorzimmer, P.1
-
186
-
-
0041636182
-
Darwin and political economy: The connection reconsidered
-
see also Scott Gordon, Darwin and Political Economy: The Connection Reconsidered, 22 J. HIST. BIOLOGY 437 (1989).
-
(1989)
J. Hist. Biology
, vol.22
, pp. 437
-
-
Gordon, S.1
-
187
-
-
33846352506
-
The road not taken: How psychology was removed from economics, and how it might be brought back
-
See Luigino Bruni & Robert Sugden, The Road Not Taken: How Psychology Was Removed from Economics, and How It Might Be Brought Back, 117 ECON. J. 146 (2007).
-
(2007)
Econ. J.
, vol.117
, pp. 146
-
-
Bruni, L.1
Sugden, R.2
-
192
-
-
0012234442
-
-
(Johnson Reprint Corp. 1968) [hereinafter WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY]
-
LESTER FRANK WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY (Johnson Reprint Corp. 1968) (1883) [hereinafter WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY];
-
(1883)
Dynamic Sociology
-
-
Ward, L.F.1
-
193
-
-
26444574206
-
-
[hereinafter WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS].
-
LESTER F. WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS (1913) [hereinafter WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS].
-
(1913)
Glimpses of the Cosmos
-
-
Ward, L.F.1
-
196
-
-
0013089330
-
-
Morris Janowitz ed
-
ROBERT E.L. FARIS, CHICAGO SOCIOLOGY, 1920-1932 (Morris Janowitz ed, 1967);
-
(1967)
Chicago Sociology
, pp. 1920-1932
-
-
Faris, R.E.L.1
-
197
-
-
79952577312
-
-
HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 64-84
-
HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 64-84;
-
-
-
-
199
-
-
79952577726
-
-
For further development, see Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models, supra note 93, at 654-61, 671-83.
-
For further development, see Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models, supra note 93, at 654-61, 671-83.
-
-
-
-
200
-
-
79952601286
-
-
See HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 38-44 (discussing Spencer's beliefs).
-
See HOFSTADTER, supra note 94, at 38-44 (discussing Spencer's beliefs).
-
-
-
-
201
-
-
79952591609
-
-
See, e.g., COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 199-226
-
See, e.g., COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 199-226;
-
-
-
-
203
-
-
79952585571
-
-
supra note 112, at
-
3 WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS, supra note 112, at 35;
-
Glimpses of the Cosmos
, pp. 35
-
-
-
204
-
-
79952598230
-
-
supra note 112, at
-
see also 1 WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY, supra note 112, at 542.
-
Dynamic Sociology
, pp. 542
-
-
-
205
-
-
79952585571
-
-
supra note 112, at
-
4 WARD, GLIMPSES OF THE COSMOS, supra note 112, at 354.
-
Glimpses of the Cosmos
, pp. 354
-
-
-
206
-
-
79952596889
-
-
Id. at 355.
-
Id. at 355.
-
-
-
-
207
-
-
79952613445
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
208
-
-
0141529374
-
Natural selection, social selection, and heredity
-
90
-
JOHN R. COMMONS, Natural Selection, Social Selection, and Heredity, 18 ARENA 90, 90 (1897),
-
(1897)
Arena
, vol.18
, pp. 90
-
-
Commons, J.R.1
-
209
-
-
79952589330
-
-
43-49 (Malcolm Rutherford & Warren J. Samuels eds, 1996).
-
reprinted in 1 JOHN R. COMMONS: SELECTED ESSAYS 43, 43-49 (Malcolm Rutherford & Warren J. Samuels eds, 1996).
-
Selected Essays
, pp. 43
-
-
Commons, J.R.1
-
210
-
-
0040762629
-
Commons's legal economic theory
-
88
-
See generally R.A. Gonce, John R. Commons's Legal Economic Theory, 5 J. ECON. ISSUES 80, 88 (1971) (discussing Commons's attempt to integrate a theory of artificial selection into economics);
-
(1971)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.5
, pp. 80
-
-
Gonce, R.A.1
John, R.2
-
211
-
-
0002246090
-
On the nature of economic evolution: John R. commons and the metaphor of artificial selection
-
Lars Magnusson ed., (same).
-
Yngve Ramstad, On the Nature of Economic Evolution: John R. Commons and the Metaphor of Artificial Selection, in EVOLUTIONARY AND NEO-SCHUMPETERIAN APPROACHES TO ECONOMICS 65 (Lars Magnusson ed., 1994) (same).
-
(1994)
Evolutionary and Neo-Schumpeterian Approaches to Economics
, pp. 65
-
-
Ramstad, Y.1
-
212
-
-
79952610365
-
-
See BERNARD & BERNARD, supra note 112, at 611-69 (discussing the rise of social science in American colleges);
-
See BERNARD & BERNARD, supra note 112, at 611-69 (discussing the rise of social science in American colleges);
-
-
-
-
214
-
-
79952590348
-
-
FARIS, supra note 112, at 3-37
-
FARIS, supra note 112, at 3-37;
-
-
-
-
217
-
-
79952604647
-
-
Ross, supra note 96, at 91-99.
-
Ross, supra note 96, at 91-99.
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
79952594332
-
-
See ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 87-88 (addressing critique that preferences cannot be observed, but that behavior can be, so behaviorism would provide a better tool for economic analysis).
-
See ROBBINS, supra note 55, at 87-88 (addressing critique that preferences cannot be observed, but that behavior can be, so behaviorism would provide a better tool for economic analysis).
-
-
-
-
219
-
-
79952585573
-
-
Id. at 87.
-
Id. at 87.
-
-
-
-
220
-
-
79952598644
-
-
BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700.
-
BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700.
-
-
-
-
221
-
-
0039758248
-
The socializing of theoretical economics
-
Rexford Guy Tugwell ed.
-
See John Maurice Clark, The Socializing of Theoretical Economics, in THE TREND OF ECONOMICS 73 (Rexford Guy Tugwell ed., 1924) [hereinafter Clark, Socializing];
-
(1924)
The Trend of Economics
, pp. 73
-
-
Clark, J.M.1
-
222
-
-
0040168515
-
The institutional approach to economic theory
-
Supp.
-
Walton H. Hamilton, The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 309 (Supp. 1919);
-
(1919)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.9
, pp. 309
-
-
Hamilton, W.H.1
-
223
-
-
0039165689
-
Experimental economics
-
Rexford Guy Tugwell ed
-
Rexford Guy Tugwell, Experimental Economics, in THE TREND OF ECONOMICS 371 (Rexford Guy Tugwell ed, 1924);
-
(1924)
The Trend of Economics
, vol.371
-
-
Tugwell, R.G.1
-
224
-
-
79952584470
-
-
see also Ross, supra note 112, at 407-08
-
see also Ross, supra note 112, at 407-08;
-
-
-
-
225
-
-
24944432809
-
The transformation of U.S. economics, 1920-1960, viewed through a survey of journal articles
-
Supp.
-
Roger E. Backhouse, The Transformation of U.S. Economics, 1920-1960, Viewed Through a Survey of Journal Articles, 30 HIST. POL. ECON. 85 (Supp. 1998);
-
(1998)
Hist. Pol. Econ.
, vol.30
, pp. 85
-
-
Backhouse, R.E.1
-
226
-
-
0141685780
-
Commons and the foundations of institutional economics
-
Geoffrey M. Hodgson, John R. Commons and the Foundations of Institutional Economics, 37 J. ECON. ISSUES 547 (2003);
-
(2003)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.37
, pp. 547
-
-
Hodgson, G.M.1
John, R.2
-
227
-
-
0039384695
-
Understanding institutional economics: 1918-1929
-
Malcolm Rutherford, Understanding Institutional Economics: 1918-1929, 22 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 277 (2000).
-
(2000)
J. Hist. Econ. Thought
, vol.22
, pp. 277
-
-
Rutherford, M.1
-
228
-
-
79952594331
-
-
For a good analysis, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
-
For a good analysis, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
-
-
-
-
229
-
-
0003359437
-
The limitations of marginal utility
-
[hereinafter Veblen, Limitations]
-
See Thorstein Veblen, The Limitations of Marginal Utility, 17 J. POL. ECON. 620 (1909) [hereinafter Veblen, Limitations];
-
(1909)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.17
, pp. 620
-
-
Veblen, T.1
-
230
-
-
84898535750
-
The preconceptions of economic science (pt. 3)
-
Thorstein Veblen, The Preconceptions of Economic Science (pt. 3), 14 Q.J. ECON. 240 (1900);
-
(1900)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.14
, pp. 240
-
-
Veblen, T.1
-
231
-
-
33748687275
-
Why is economics not an evolutionary science?
-
Thorstein Veblen, Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?, 12 Q.J. ECON. 373 (1898).
-
(1898)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.12
, pp. 373
-
-
Veblen, T.1
-
235
-
-
0003620618
-
-
On Veblen, institutionalism, and the business corporation
-
THORSTEIN VEBLEN, THE THEORY OF THE LEISURE CLASS (1899). On Veblen, institutionalism, and the business corporation,
-
(1899)
The Theory of the Leisure Class
-
-
Veblen, T.1
-
236
-
-
85028739126
-
Veblen, berle and the modern corporation
-
see Forest G. Hill, Veblen, Berle and the Modern Corporation, 26 AM. J. ECON. Soc. 279 (1967).
-
(1967)
Am. J. Econ. Soc.
, vol.26
, pp. 279
-
-
Hill, F.G.1
-
237
-
-
79952612824
-
-
supra note 126, at
-
VEBLEN, ABSENTEE OWNERSHIP, supra note 126, at 101 n. 1.
-
Absentee Ownership
, Issue.1
, pp. 101
-
-
Veblen1
-
238
-
-
79952577729
-
-
See Hamilton, supra note 124, at 316.
-
See Hamilton, supra note 124, at 316.
-
-
-
-
239
-
-
0141863734
-
The emancipation of economics
-
See Lawrence K. Frank, The Emancipation of Economics, 14 AM. ECON. REV. 17 (1924).
-
(1924)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.14
, pp. 17
-
-
Frank, L.K.1
-
241
-
-
0039989904
-
American institutionalism and the history of economics
-
178
-
See Malcolm Rutherford, American Institutionalism and the History of Economics, 19 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 178, 178-79 (1997);
-
(1997)
J. Hist. Econ. Thought
, vol.19
, pp. 178-179
-
-
Rutherford, M.1
-
242
-
-
0012532721
-
Veblen's evolutionary programme: A promise unfulfilled
-
see also Malcolm Rutherford, Veblen's Evolutionary Programme: A Promise Unfulfilled, 22 CAMBRIDGE J. ECON. 463 (1998).
-
(1998)
Cambridge J. Econ.
, vol.22
, pp. 463
-
-
Rutherford, M.1
-
244
-
-
0141863731
-
Waging war against mechanical man: The knight-copeland controversy over behaviorism in economics
-
Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds
-
See, e.g., Pier Franceso Asso & Luca Fiorito, Waging War Against Mechanical Man: The Knight-Copeland Controversy over Behaviorism in Economics, in 21-A RESEARCH IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT AND METHODOLOGY 65 (Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds, 2003);
-
(2003)
A Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology
, vol.21
, pp. 65
-
-
Asso, P.F.1
Fiorito, L.2
-
245
-
-
0012589267
-
Economic theory and the natural science point of view
-
University of Chicago economist Frank Knight, who toyed with various aspects of institutionalism throughout his career, was very critical of behaviorism because its list of "instincts" defied rigorous analysis.
-
Morris A. Copeland, Economic Theory and the Natural Science Point of View, 21 AM. ECON. REV. 67 (1931). University of Chicago economist Frank Knight, who toyed with various aspects of institutionalism throughout his career, was very critical of behaviorism because its list of "instincts" defied rigorous analysis.
-
(1931)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.21
, pp. 67
-
-
Copeland, M.A.1
-
246
-
-
84951549673
-
Ethics and the economic interpretation
-
467 ("If instincts are to be scientifically useful, it must surely be possible to get some idea of their number and identity. But there has always been substantially unanimous disagreement on this point. Logically the choice seems to lie between a meaningless single instinct to do things-in-general and the equally meaningless hypothesis of a separate instinct for every possible act").
-
See Frank H. Knight, Ethics and the Economic Interpretation, 36 Q.J. ECON. 454, 467 (1922) ("If instincts are to be scientifically useful, it must surely be possible to get some idea of their number and identity. But there has always been substantially unanimous disagreement on this point. Logically the choice seems to lie between a meaningless single instinct to do things-in-general and the equally meaningless hypothesis of a separate instinct for every possible act").
-
(1922)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.36
, pp. 454
-
-
Knight, F.H.1
-
247
-
-
0000520990
-
Economics and psychology: Lessons for our own day from the early twentieth century
-
On behaviorism in American institutionalism, see generally Shira B. Lewin, Economics and Psychology: Lessons for Our Own Day from the Early Twentieth Century, 34 J. ECON. LITERATURE 1293 (1996);
-
(1996)
J. Econ. Literature
, vol.34
, pp. 1293
-
-
Lewin, S.B.1
-
248
-
-
0034412430
-
Institutionalism between the wars
-
298 For a very good discussion of the development of behaviorist psychology among institutionalists as an alternative to neoclassical marginal utility theory
-
Malcolm Rutherford, Institutionalism Between the Wars, 34 J. ECON. ISSUES 291, 298 (2000). For a very good discussion of the development of behaviorist psychology among institutionalists as an alternative to neoclassical marginal utility theory,
-
(2000)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.34
, pp. 291
-
-
Rutherford, M.1
-
249
-
-
79952580241
-
-
Univ. of Siena Dep't of Political Econ., Working Paper No. 373, available at
-
see Pier Francesco Asso & Luca Fiorito, Human Nature and Economic Institutions: Instinct, Psychology, Behaviorism and the Development of American Institutionalism (Univ. of Siena Dep't of Political Econ., Working Paper No. 373, 2002), available at http://papers.ssm.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id= 433763;
-
(2002)
Human Nature and Economic Institutions: Instinct, Psychology, Behaviorism and the Development of American Institutionalism
-
-
Asso, P.F.1
Fiorito, L.2
-
250
-
-
79952614130
-
-
see also Ross, supra note 96, at 414-15 (describing tumultuous meeting of American Economics Association in 1927, where a large majority of economists reacted against the use of empirical analysis to revise economic theory as a throwback to German-style historicism).
-
see also Ross, supra note 96, at 414-15 (describing tumultuous meeting of American Economics Association in 1927, where a large majority of economists reacted against the use of empirical analysis to revise economic theory as a throwback to German-style historicism).
-
-
-
-
253
-
-
79952599868
-
Fact research in law administration
-
A few examples include Charles E. Clark, Fact Research in Law Administration, 2 CONN. B.J. 211 (1928);
-
(1928)
Conn. B.J.
, vol.2
, pp. 211
-
-
Clark, C.E.1
-
254
-
-
37949045178
-
A factual study of bankruptcy administration and some suggestions
-
William O. Douglas & J. Howard Marshall, A Factual Study of Bankruptcy Administration and Some Suggestions, 32 COLUM. L. REV. 25 (1932);
-
(1932)
Colum. L. Rev.
, vol.32
, pp. 25
-
-
Douglas, W.O.1
Howard Marshall, J.2
-
255
-
-
37949057402
-
An institutional approach to the law of commercial banking
-
Underhill Moore & Theodore S. Hope, Jr., An Institutional Approach to the Law of Commercial Banking, 38 YALE L.J. 703 (1929);
-
(1929)
Yale L.J.
, vol.38
, pp. 703
-
-
Moore, U.1
Hope Jr., T.S.2
-
256
-
-
1842639071
-
Legal and institutional methods applied to the debiting of direct discounts
-
555, 752, 928, 1055, 1219 (series of articles describing empirical studies).
-
Underhill Moore & Gilbert Sussman, Legal and Institutional Methods Applied to the Debiting of Direct Discounts, 40 YALE L.J. 381, 555, 752, 928, 1055, 1219 (1931) (series of articles describing empirical studies).
-
(1931)
Yale L.J.
, vol.40
, pp. 381
-
-
Moore, U.1
Sussman, G.2
-
257
-
-
0347664771
-
Knowledge about welfare: Legal realism and the separation of law and economics
-
[hereinafter Hovenkamp, Knowledge About Welfare]
-
On the relationship between institutionalism and American legal realism, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Knowledge About Welfare: Legal Realism and the Separation of Law and Economics, 84 MINN. L. REV. 805 (2000) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Knowledge About Welfare];
-
(2000)
Minn. L. Rev.
, vol.84
, pp. 805
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
260
-
-
0004327857
-
-
Beacon Press (1944) ("In spite of the chorus of academic incantations so persistent in the nineteenth century, gain and profit made on exchange never before played an important part in human economy.")
-
KARL POLANYI, THE GREAT TRANSFORMATION 45-69 (Beacon Press 2001) (1944) ("In spite of the chorus of academic incantations so persistent in the nineteenth century, gain and profit made on exchange never before played an important part in human economy.");
-
(2001)
The Great Transformation
, pp. 45-69
-
-
Polanyi, K.1
-
261
-
-
0001902356
-
The corporation versus the market
-
397, (comparing Coase's and Polanyi's concepts of exchange)
-
see also John Adams, The Corporation Versus the Market, 26 J. ECON. ISSUES 397, 397-98 (1992) (comparing Coase's and Polanyi's concepts of exchange);
-
(1992)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.26
, pp. 397-398
-
-
Adams, J.1
-
262
-
-
84974253454
-
Karl polanyi's concept of non-market trade
-
Abraham Rotstein, Karl Polanyi's Concept of Non-Market Trade, 30 J. ECON. HIST. 117 (1970).
-
(1970)
J. Econ. Hist.
, vol.30
, pp. 117
-
-
Rotstein, A.1
-
263
-
-
55249093479
-
Karl Polanyi and american institutionalism: A strange case of convergence
-
Kari PolanyiLevitt ed
-
On Polanyi and institutionalism, see Walter C. Neale, Karl Polanyi and American Institutionalism: A Strange Case of Convergence, in THE LIFE AND WORK OF KARL POLANYI 145 (Kari PolanyiLevitt ed, 1990);
-
(1990)
The Life and Work oOf Karl Polanyi
, pp. 145
-
-
Neale, W.C.1
-
264
-
-
79952612823
-
-
Stanford Univ. Working Paper, available at (comparing coercive and exchange economies and identifying secure property rights and contract enforceability as the distinguishing factors).
-
see also Avner Greif, Coercion and Exchange: How Did Markets Evolve? (Stanford Univ. Working Paper, 2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1304204 (comparing coercive and exchange economies and identifying secure property rights and contract enforceability as the distinguishing factors).
-
(2008)
Coercion and Exchange: How Did Markets Evolve?
-
-
Greif, A.1
-
266
-
-
79952579805
-
-
See POLANYI, supra note 138, at 45-69.
-
See POLANYI, supra note 138, at 45-69.
-
-
-
-
267
-
-
79952584868
-
-
See id.
-
See id.
-
-
-
-
268
-
-
0141752178
-
An institutional analysis of the law
-
480, (using cultural anthropology to account for institutions of private property and contract). On this point, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
-
See, e.g., Lawrence K. Frank, An Institutional Analysis of the Law, 24 COLUM. L. REV. 480, 482-84 (1924) (using cultural anthropology to account for institutions of private property and contract). On this point, see HODGSON, supra note 10.
-
(1924)
Colum. L. Rev.
, vol.24
, pp. 482-484
-
-
Frank, L.K.1
-
269
-
-
79952581262
-
-
See Veblen, Limitations, supra note 126.
-
See Veblen, Limitations, supra note 126.
-
-
-
-
270
-
-
79952615455
-
-
On Clark's marginalism, see infra Part III.D.
-
On Clark's marginalism, see infra Part III.D.
-
-
-
-
271
-
-
0004197282
-
-
(Transaction Publishers 4th prtg. 1990) [hereinafter COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS].
-
In particular, see JOHN R. COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS: ITS PLACE IN POLITICAL ECONOMY (Transaction Publishers 4th prtg. 1990) (1934) [hereinafter COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS].
-
(1934)
Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy
-
-
Commons, J.R.1
-
272
-
-
79952593917
-
-
Joseph Schumpeter's critique was particularly harsh, notwithstanding his own sympathy with historical methods generally. He lumped the institutionalists together with practical nonacademic economists who wrote about policy and had no use for theory
-
Joseph Schumpeter's critique was particularly harsh, notwithstanding his own sympathy with historical methods generally. He lumped the institutionalists together with practical nonacademic economists who wrote about policy and had no use for theory:
-
-
-
-
273
-
-
79952595860
-
-
note (Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter ed, Oxford Univ. Press rev. ed. 1996) (internal citation omitted).
-
They... looked upon 'marginalism' as a sort of speculative philosophy or as a new sectarian 'ism' which it was precisely their business to eliminate by what they considered truly scientific and realistic research. Hence they passed, in methodological and programmatic pronouncements, all sorts of sweeping judgments upon it. On the surface, the result was bedlam, especially in Germany and in the United States - a multitude of discordant voices, all of which seemed to testify to the presence of an impasse. JOSEPH A. SCHUMPETER, HISTORY OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 954 (Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter ed, Oxford Univ. Press rev. ed. 1996) (1954) (internal citation omitted).
-
(1954)
History of Economic Analysis
, pp. 954
-
-
Schumpeter, J.A.1
-
274
-
-
79952600651
-
-
Cf. COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 227-46 (1950) (lengthy discussion of Veblen, while John Bates Clark is barely mentioned and incorrectly identified as a "classical economist")
-
Cf. COMMAGER, supra note 99, at 227-46 (1950) (lengthy discussion of Veblen, while John Bates Clark is barely mentioned and incorrectly identified as a "classical economist");
-
-
-
-
275
-
-
0004229723
-
-
(much greater treatment of Veblen than Clark)
-
RICHARD HOFSTADTER, THE AGE OF REFORM (1955) (much greater treatment of Veblen than Clark);
-
(1955)
The Age of Reform
-
-
Hofstadter, R.1
-
276
-
-
79952601098
-
-
WHITE, supra note 99 (lengthy discussion of Veblen but no reference to John Bates Clark or Irving Fisher).
-
WHITE, supra note 99 (lengthy discussion of Veblen but no reference to John Bates Clark or Irving Fisher).
-
-
-
-
277
-
-
79952580244
-
-
See, e.g., BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700-03 (briefly describing American institutionalism).
-
See, e.g., BLAUG, supra note 10, at 700-03 (briefly describing American institutionalism).
-
-
-
-
278
-
-
79952606743
-
-
See supra notes 85-87 and accompanying text (arguing that Robbins narrowed the scope of economics so as to exclude psychology)
-
See supra notes 85-87 and accompanying text (arguing that Robbins narrowed the scope of economics so as to exclude psychology);
-
-
-
-
279
-
-
0033446524
-
The scope, method and significance of original institutional economics
-
231
-
James Ronald Stanfield, The Scope, Method and Significance of Original Institutional Economics, 33 J. ECON. ISSUES 231, 233-36 (1999).
-
(1999)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.33
, pp. 233-236
-
-
Stanfield, J.R.1
-
283
-
-
84935190124
-
The first great law & economics movement
-
see also Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993 (1990).
-
(1990)
Stan. L. Rev.
, vol.42
, pp. 993
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
284
-
-
0001814852
-
Coercion and distribution in a supposedly non-coercive state
-
Robert L. Hale, Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State, 38 POL. SCI. Q. 470 (1923);
-
(1923)
Pol. Sci. Q.
, vol.38
, pp. 470
-
-
Hale, R.L.1
-
285
-
-
79952594552
-
-
see also Frank, supra note 141, at 481-89 (describing evolution of coercion in historical cultures, including legal mies among other structural norms and taboos).
-
see also Frank, supra note 141, at 481-89 (describing evolution of coercion in historical cultures, including legal mies among other structural norms and taboos).
-
-
-
-
288
-
-
79952577944
-
-
BERLE & MEANS, supra note 46.
-
BERLE & MEANS, supra note 46.
-
-
-
-
289
-
-
79952598231
-
-
The writings of Oliver E. Williamson are representative of NIE. See, e.g., WILLIAMSON, supra note 9, at 12, 26, 45, 220, 251, 371
-
The writings of Oliver E. Williamson are representative of NIE. See, e.g., WILLIAMSON, supra note 9, at 12, 26, 45, 220, 251, 371;
-
-
-
-
291
-
-
79952588925
-
-
WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 3, 6, 24, 254.
-
WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 3, 6, 24, 254.
-
-
-
-
293
-
-
79952593714
-
-
Id. For some of those sympathetic with institutionalism, such as Richard T. Ely and Robert L. Hale, even bargaining transactions were seen as coercive because they tended to reinforce pre-existing distributions of power and increased the maldistribution of wealth in the process.
-
Id. For some of those sympathetic with institutionalism, such as Richard T. Ely and Robert L. Hale, even bargaining transactions were seen as coercive because they tended to reinforce pre-existing distributions of power and increased the maldistribution of wealth in the process.
-
-
-
-
294
-
-
79952601284
-
-
See, e.g., ELY, supra note 150; Hale, supra note 151. These views eventually found their way into judicial decision making and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts.
-
See, e.g., ELY, supra note 150; Hale, supra note 151. These views eventually found their way into judicial decision making and the Restatement (Second) of Contracts.
-
-
-
-
295
-
-
0003726851
-
-
(describing the destruction of contract theory at the hands of legal realists, such as Benjamin Cardozo and Arthur L. Corbin, and the incorporation of these views into the Second Restatement of Contracts).
-
See GRANT GILMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (1974) (describing the destruction of contract theory at the hands of legal realists, such as Benjamin Cardozo and Arthur L. Corbin, and the incorporation of these views into the Second Restatement of Contracts).
-
(1974)
The Death of Contract
-
-
Gilmore, G.1
-
296
-
-
0004197282
-
-
supra note 144, at ("From this universal principle of collective action in control of individual action by different kinds of sanctions arise the ethical and legal relations of rights, duties, no-rights, no-duties, and the economic relations not only of Security, Conformity, Liberty, and Exposure, but also of Assets and Liabilities.").
-
See COMMONS, INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS, supra note 144, at 72 ("From this universal principle of collective action in control of individual action by different kinds of sanctions arise the ethical and legal relations of rights, duties, no-rights, no-duties, and the economic relations not only of Security, Conformity, Liberty, and Exposure, but also of Assets and Liabilities.").
-
Institutional Economics
, pp. 72
-
-
Commons1
-
299
-
-
33846535805
-
The institutional economics of John R. commons: Complement and substitute for neoclassical economic theory
-
3
-
Bruce E. Kaufman, The Institutional Economics of John R. Commons: Complement and Substitute for Neoclassical Economic Theory, 5 SOCIO-ECON. REV. 3, 22-34 (2007);
-
(2007)
Socio-Econ. Rev.
, vol.5
, pp. 22-34
-
-
Kaufman, B.E.1
-
300
-
-
0001223444
-
Commons's institutional economics
-
Malcolm Rutherford, J.R. Commons's Institutional Economics, 17 J. ECON. ISSUES 721 (1983).
-
(1983)
J. Econ. Issues
, vol.17
, pp. 721
-
-
Malcolm Rutherford, J.R.1
-
301
-
-
0010061125
-
Law and economics
-
John R. Commons, Law and Economics, 34 YALE L.J. 371 (1925).
-
(1925)
Yale L.J.
, vol.34
, pp. 371
-
-
Commons, J.R.1
-
302
-
-
0003932268
-
Ronald Coase and american institutionalism
-
51, Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds
-
On the relationship between Commons, Coase, and The Nature of the Firm, see Steven G. Medema, Ronald Coase and American Institutionalism, in 14 RESEARCH IN THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT AND METHODOLOGY 51, 68-70 (Warren J. Samuels & Jeff E. Biddle eds, 1996).
-
(1996)
Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology
, vol.14
, pp. 68-70
-
-
Medema, S.G.1
-
303
-
-
79952595654
-
-
note
-
An excellent but typically overlooked example is Lawrence Kelso Frank, whose 1924 Columbia Law Review article, An Institutionalist Analysis of Law, described the evolution of property and contract as social norms, much like tribal taboos, but which had become much more social (rather than individual) as a result of the revolution in "machine production," which Frank believed gave rise to legal mies that emphasized cooperation more than individualism.
-
-
-
-
304
-
-
79952584271
-
-
See Frank, supra note 141. Frank argued that the movement for the new Restatements of the law, which were just underway at the time of his writing, were an effort to bridge the hyper-individualistic tendencies of nineteenth-century law with the realities of coordinated production in the machine age. He saw this as a failed attempt to "pour new wine into old bottles."
-
See Frank, supra note 141. Frank argued that the movement for the new Restatements of the law, which were just underway at the time of his writing, were an effort to bridge the hyper-individualistic tendencies of nineteenth-century law with the realities of coordinated production in the machine age. He saw this as a failed attempt to "pour new wine into old bottles."
-
-
-
-
305
-
-
79952594550
-
-
Id. at 491-92. He ultimately concluded that legislative rather than common law rules were the preferred route for legal change.
-
Id. at 491-92. He ultimately concluded that legislative rather than common law rules were the preferred route for legal change.
-
-
-
-
306
-
-
79952576684
-
-
Id. at 495.
-
Id. at 495.
-
-
-
-
307
-
-
0000156633
-
The chicago school of antitrust analysis
-
928 (speaking of viewing all of antitrust law through the lens of "price theory").
-
The phrase, somewhat misplaced, comes from Richard A. Posner, The Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 925, 928 (1979) (speaking of viewing all of antitrust law through the lens of "price theory").
-
(1979)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.127
, pp. 925
-
-
Posner, R.A.1
-
314
-
-
0011224145
-
-
(unpublished manuscript), available at (explaining how developmental policy is determined by institutionalism).
-
Douglass C North, The New Institutional Economics and Development (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/ NewInstE.North.pdf (explaining how developmental policy is determined by institutionalism).
-
The New Institutional Economics and Development
-
-
North, D.C.1
-
315
-
-
79952588128
-
-
See supra notes 50-51 and accompanying text
-
See supra notes 50-51 and accompanying text;
-
-
-
-
316
-
-
79952583051
-
-
see also Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
-
see also Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
-
-
-
-
317
-
-
79952598436
-
-
See supra notes 43-70 and accompanying text.
-
See supra notes 43-70 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
319
-
-
79952598017
-
-
see supra note 39 and accompanying text.
-
see supra note 39 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
320
-
-
79952608059
-
The integration of industry in the United States
-
108 (describing the development of vertical integration by English store owners). For an overview of vertical integration during this period
-
See, e.g., William Franklin Willoughby, The Integration of Industry in the United States, 16 Q.J. ECON. 94, 108 (1902) (describing the development of vertical integration by English store owners). For an overview of vertical integration during this period,
-
(1902)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.16
, pp. 94
-
-
Willoughby, W.F.1
-
322
-
-
84862857817
-
The antitrust movement and the rise of industrial organization
-
[hereinafter Hovenkamp, Antitrust Movement]
-
Herbert Hovenkamp, The Antitrust Movement and the Rise of Industrial Organization, 68 TEX. L. REV. 105 (1989) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Antitrust Movement];
-
(1989)
Tex. L. Rev.
, vol.68
, pp. 105
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
326
-
-
0002011547
-
The significance of industrial integration
-
Lawrence K. Frank, The Significance of Industrial Integration, 33 J. POL. ECON. 179 (1925).
-
(1925)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.33
, pp. 179
-
-
Frank, L.K.1
-
327
-
-
79952614547
-
-
174. Id. at 179-80.
-
174. Id. at 179-80.
-
-
-
-
328
-
-
79952583694
-
-
Id. at 180 ("[T]he machine process split up production into an ever growing number of separate processes, separate because of the invention of new techniques and new machines for performing each step in the formerly unified handicraft operations.").
-
Id. at 180 ("[T]he machine process split up production into an ever growing number of separate processes, separate because of the invention of new techniques and new machines for performing each step in the formerly unified handicraft operations.").
-
-
-
-
329
-
-
79952586848
-
-
note
-
Id. at 185-86 ("For undoubtedly vertical integration is an attempt to bring together under one management the separate stages of the industrial process which technically require unified direction and control. Since this technical requirement cannot effectively nor continuously be met through buying and selling of goods between separately owned stages, however ingeniously and elaborately those pecuniary operations be conducted, it has become both feasible and desirable to bring a number of consecutive stages of production under one managerial control.").
-
-
-
-
330
-
-
79952608693
-
-
Id. at 190.
-
Id. at 190.
-
-
-
-
331
-
-
0041163978
-
Soundings in non-euclidian economics
-
John Maurice Clark, Soundings in Non-Euclidian Economics, 11 AM. ECON. REV. SUPP. 132 (1921).
-
(1921)
Am. Econ. Rev. Supp.
, vol.11
, pp. 132
-
-
Clark, J.M.1
-
333
-
-
77953069110
-
United States competition policy in crisis: 1890-1955
-
311, [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Competition Policy].
-
see Herbert Hovenkamp, United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955, 94 MINN. L. REV. 311, 323-24 (2009) [hereinafter Hovenkamp, Competition Policy].
-
(2009)
Minn. L. Rev.
, vol.94
, pp. 323-324
-
-
Hovenkamp, H.1
-
334
-
-
79952583895
-
-
Clark, Socializing, supra note 124.
-
Clark, Socializing, supra note 124.
-
-
-
-
335
-
-
0005947799
-
Toward a concept of workable competition
-
241
-
J.M. Clark, Toward a Concept of Workable Competition, 30 AM. ECON. REV. 241, 241-43 (1940);
-
(1940)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.30
, pp. 241-243
-
-
Clark, J.M.1
-
336
-
-
22944431922
-
-
supra note 179, at 323
-
see Hovenkamp, Competition Policy, supra note 179, at 323, 342-43.
-
Competition Policy
, pp. 342-343
-
-
Hovenkamp1
-
338
-
-
79952611195
-
-
Id. at 13.
-
Id. at 13.
-
-
-
-
339
-
-
84953304793
-
-
supra note 25, at
-
See HOVENKAMP, ENTERPRISE, supra note 25, at 308-22;
-
Enterprise
, pp. 308-322
-
-
Hovenkamp1
-
340
-
-
0020365518
-
Decreasing average cost and competition: A new look at the addyston pipe case
-
see also George Bittlingmayer, Decreasing Average Cost and Competition: A New Look at the Addyston Pipe Case, 25 J.L. & ECON. 201 (1982);
-
(1982)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.25
, pp. 201
-
-
Bittlingmayer, G.1
-
341
-
-
84985407497
-
The economic problem of fixed costs and what legal research can contribute
-
The cost controversy culminated in the 1930s in a debate that gave rise to modem theories of imperfect competition.
-
George Bittlingmayer, The Economic Problem of Fixed Costs and What Legal Research Can Contribute, 14 LAW & SOC. INQUIRY 739 (1989). The cost controversy culminated in the 1930s in a debate that gave rise to modem theories of imperfect competition.
-
(1989)
Law & Soc. Inquiry
, vol.14
, pp. 739
-
-
Bittlingmayer, G.1
-
342
-
-
0346002471
-
The cost controversy: Pigouvian economics in disequilibrium
-
See Nahid Aslanbeigui, The Cost Controversy: Pigouvian Economics in Disequilibrium, 3 EUR. J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 275 (1996);
-
(1996)
Eur. J. Hist. Econ. Thought
, vol.3
, pp. 275
-
-
Aslanbeigui, N.1
-
343
-
-
2142781475
-
On the methodological foundation of modern microeconomics: Frank knight and the "cost controversy" in the 1920s
-
Roberto Marchionatti, On the Methodological Foundation of Modern Microeconomics: Frank Knight and the "Cost Controversy" in the 1920s, 35 HIST. POL. ECON. 49 (2003).
-
(2003)
Hist. Pol. Econ.
, vol.35
, pp. 49
-
-
Marchionatti, R.1
-
344
-
-
79952583052
-
-
supra note 182, at ix (introducing the book as "a study of discrepancies between an ever fluctuating demand and a relatively inelastic fund of productive capacity, resulting in wastes of partial idleness, and many other economic disturbances. Unused capacity is its central theme").
-
CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at ix (introducing the book as "a study of discrepancies between an ever fluctuating demand and a relatively inelastic fund of productive capacity, resulting in wastes of partial idleness, and many other economic disturbances. Unused capacity is its central theme").
-
Overhead Costs
-
-
Clark1
-
345
-
-
79952588129
-
-
note
-
Frank made similar observations in Institutionalist Analysis. Frank, supra note 141, at 491. He noted that, historically, under hand-production there was a close relationship between output and prices because production was responsive to demand virtually on a unitby-unit basis. By contrast, machine production led for the need of machines that kept running at high output regardless of demand. This fact, plus the offsetting correctives made by managers, led to booms and busts as industries swung between over- and underproduction. Joseph Schumpeter's massive study of business cycles came almost two decades later but developed many of the same points with copious historical examples.
-
-
-
-
347
-
-
33748329567
-
Schumpeter's business cycles as business history
-
231
-
See Thomas K. McCraw, Schumpeter's Business Cycles as Business History, 80 BUS. HIS. REV. 231,231 (2006).
-
(2006)
Bus. His. Rev.
, vol.80
, pp. 231
-
-
McCraw, T.K.1
-
348
-
-
79952583052
-
-
supra note 182, at
-
CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 258-97.
-
Overhead Costs
, pp. 258-297
-
-
Clark1
-
349
-
-
79952597504
-
-
Id. at 318-34.
-
Id. at 318-34.
-
-
-
-
350
-
-
79952578164
-
-
Id. at ix.
-
Id. at ix.
-
-
-
-
351
-
-
0000827401
-
Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process
-
(applying transaction cost economics to problems of vertical contracting)
-
See, e.g., Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford & Armen A. Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297 (1978) (applying transaction cost economics to problems of vertical contracting);
-
(1978)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.21
, pp. 297
-
-
Klein, B.1
Crawford, R.G.2
Alchian, A.A.3
-
352
-
-
79952613067
-
-
WILLIAMSON, supra note 42 (same).
-
WILLIAMSON, supra note 42 (same).
-
-
-
-
353
-
-
79952583052
-
-
supra note 182, at 403-07.
-
CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 23-24, 403-07.
-
Overhead Costs
, pp. 23-24
-
-
Clark1
-
354
-
-
79952579803
-
-
Id. at 386.
-
Id. at 386.
-
-
-
-
355
-
-
79952612214
-
-
Id. at 402.
-
Id. at 402.
-
-
-
-
356
-
-
79952588330
-
-
Cf. WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 31-33.
-
Cf. WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 31-33.
-
-
-
-
357
-
-
79952583052
-
-
supra note 182, at
-
CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 136-37.
-
Overhead Costs
, pp. 136-137
-
-
Clark1
-
358
-
-
79952601691
-
-
Id. at 137 ("[A]nother gain from integration arises, in the shape of great reliability in the supplying of materials. The two concerns adapt their process to each other, and the supply of materials, both in quality and regularity, can be more carefully suited to the needs of the user....").
-
Id. at 137 ("[A]nother gain from integration arises, in the shape of great reliability in the supplying of materials. The two concerns adapt their process to each other, and the supply of materials, both in quality and regularity, can be more carefully suited to the needs of the user....").
-
-
-
-
359
-
-
79952598642
-
-
M at 137.
-
M at 137
-
-
-
-
360
-
-
79952586637
-
-
Id. at 119-22
-
Id. at 119-22.
-
-
-
-
361
-
-
79952602688
-
-
Id. at 399-400
-
Id. at 399-400.
-
-
-
-
362
-
-
79952611800
-
-
Id. at 138
-
Id. at 138.
-
-
-
-
363
-
-
79952605045
-
-
Id. at 137-38
-
Id. at 137-38.
-
-
-
-
364
-
-
79952597306
-
-
Id. at 138
-
Id. at 138.
-
-
-
-
365
-
-
79952593541
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
366
-
-
67649495819
-
Integration in marketing
-
Id. at 138-39 citing
-
Id. at 138-39 (citing Lewis H. Haney, Integration in Marketing, 10 AM. ECON. REV. 528 (1920)).
-
(1920)
Am. Econ. Rev.
, vol.10
, pp. 528
-
-
Haney, L.H.1
-
367
-
-
79952578384
-
-
Id. at 140
-
Id. at 140.
-
-
-
-
368
-
-
79952614783
-
-
Id. at 139
-
Id. at 139.
-
-
-
-
369
-
-
79952613270
-
-
Id. at 140-41
-
Id. at 140-41.
-
-
-
-
370
-
-
79952583695
-
-
Klein et al, supra note 190, at 297
-
Klein et al, supra note 190, at 297.
-
-
-
-
371
-
-
79952601693
-
-
CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 416
-
CLARK, OVERHEAD COSTS, supra note 182, at 416.
-
-
-
-
372
-
-
84963036464
-
Clark's economics of overhead costs
-
490 (book review)
-
T.H. Sanders, Clark's Economics of Overhead Costs, 38 Q.J. ECON. 487, 490 (1924) (book review).
-
(1924)
Q.J. Econ.
, vol.38
, pp. 487
-
-
Sanders, T.H.1
-
373
-
-
79952598643
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
-
374
-
-
0041008590
-
An analysis of supply
-
A.C. Pigou, An Analysis of Supply, 38 ECON. J. 238 (1928);
-
(1928)
Econ. J.
, vol.38
, pp. 238
-
-
Pigou, A.C.1
-
375
-
-
0001726410
-
The laws of costs under competitive conditions
-
(explaining that under competition market-wide costs are generally constant)
-
see also Piero Sraffa, The Laws of Costs Under Competitive Conditions, 36 ECON. J. 535 (1926) (explaining that under competition market-wide costs are generally constant).
-
(1926)
Econ. J.
, vol.36
, pp. 535
-
-
Sraffa, P.1
-
376
-
-
79952612215
-
-
Pigou elaborated on this work in The Economics of Welfare. PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. H, ch. 11, §§3-12
-
Pigou elaborated on this work in The Economics of Welfare. PIGOU, supra note 4, pt. H, ch. 11, §§3-12.
-
-
-
-
377
-
-
0001932587
-
The equilibrium of the firm
-
Nicholas Kaldor,The Equilibrium of the Firm,44 ECON.J.60(1934).
-
(1934)
Econ.J.
, vol.44
, pp. 60
-
-
Kaldor, N.1
-
378
-
-
79952602084
-
-
Id. Kaldor also concluded that increasing firm costs were inconsistent with perfect competition
-
Id. Kaldor also concluded that increasing firm costs were inconsistent with perfect competition.
-
-
-
-
379
-
-
79952593129
-
-
Id. at 72-73
-
Id. at 72-73.
-
-
-
-
380
-
-
0004255169
-
-
E.A.G. Robinson, also a Professor of Economics at Cambridge, was married to fellow professor Joan Robinson
-
E.A.G. ROBINSON, THE STRUCTURE OF COMPETITIVE INDUSTRY (1931). E.A.G. Robinson, also a Professor of Economics at Cambridge, was married to fellow professor Joan Robinson.
-
(1931)
The Structure of Competitive Industry
-
-
Robinson, E.A.G.1
-
381
-
-
79952598845
-
-
JOAN ROBINSON, supra note 89, at 69
-
See JOAN ROBINSON, supra note 89, at 69.
-
-
-
-
382
-
-
79952604055
-
-
ROBINSON, supra note 216, at 40-42
-
ROBINSON, supra note 216, at 40-42.
-
-
-
-
383
-
-
79952585572
-
-
Id. at 115 (citing United States Steel as an example of a firm that gained economies by operating multiple plants scattered across the country)
-
Id. at 115 (citing United States Steel as an example of a firm that gained economies by operating multiple plants scattered across the country).
-
-
-
-
384
-
-
0000046146
-
The problem of management and the size of the firm
-
Robinson elaborated on this point in
-
Robinson elaborated on this point in Austin Robinson, The Problem of Management and the Size of the Firm, 44 ECON. J. 242 (1934).
-
(1934)
Econ. J.
, vol.44
, pp. 242
-
-
Robinson, A.1
-
385
-
-
79952605494
-
-
See Sraffa, supra note 212, at 535-36
-
See Sraffa, supra note 212, at 535-36.
-
-
-
-
386
-
-
79952595861
-
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386.
-
-
-
-
387
-
-
79952589746
-
-
Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18
-
See Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
-
-
-
-
388
-
-
79952589139
-
-
See, e.g., Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, supra note 8 (calling for more empirical study of the structure of the firm, and lamenting "blackboard economics" that reduces the firm to a "black box")
-
See, e.g., Coase, Nobel Prize Lecture, supra note 8 (calling for more empirical study of the structure of the firm, and lamenting "blackboard economics" that reduces the firm to a "black box");
-
-
-
-
389
-
-
0242278700
-
-
Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72 ("Mainstream economics, as one sees it in the journals and the textbooks and in the courses taught in economics departments has become more and more abstract over time, and although it purports otherwise, it is in fact little concerned with what happens in the real world.")
-
see also Coase, New Institutional Economics, supra note 8, at 72 ("Mainstream economics, as one sees it in the journals and the textbooks and in the courses taught in economics departments has become more and more abstract over time, and although it purports otherwise, it is in fact little concerned with what happens in the real world.").
-
-
-
-
390
-
-
79952589140
-
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 403
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 403.
-
-
-
-
391
-
-
0009428788
-
-
Id. at 403-04 relying on (4th ed. 1950)
-
Id. at 403-04 (relying on FRANCIS RALEIGH BATT, LAW OF MASTER AND SERVANT (4th ed. 1950) (1926)).
-
(1926)
Law of Master and Servant
-
-
Batt, F.R.1
-
392
-
-
79952596689
-
-
See Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 8-9 (explaining that during his visit to the United States he took very few classes and instead "most of my time was spent in visiting businesses and industrial plants")
-
See Coase, Nature of the Firm: Origin, supra note 5, at 8-9 (explaining that during his visit to the United States he took very few classes and instead "most of my time was spent in visiting businesses and industrial plants");
-
-
-
-
393
-
-
79952594153
-
-
id. at 13 (noting a visit to Duquesne Power and Light Co. and the viewing of some cost curves that they had constructed)
-
see also id. at 13 (noting a visit to Duquesne Power and Light Co. and the viewing of some cost curves that they had constructed);
-
-
-
-
394
-
-
79952592702
-
-
id. at 13 (visit to General Motors and discussion of Fisher Body works)
-
id. at 13 (visit to General Motors and discussion of Fisher Body works).
-
-
-
-
395
-
-
79952611801
-
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386-87
-
Coase, Nature of the Firm, supra note 26, at 386-87.
-
-
-
-
396
-
-
79952579588
-
-
Some of Coase's work was more empirical, although not statistical
-
Some of Coase's work was more empirical, although not statistical.
-
-
-
-
397
-
-
0034360870
-
The acquisition of fisher body by general motors
-
16-17 (similar to a case study)
-
See, e.g., R.H. Coase, The Acquisition of Fisher Body by General Motors, 43 J.L. & ECON. 15, 16-17 (2000) (similar to a case study);
-
(2000)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.43
, pp. 15
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
398
-
-
0001011471
-
The lighthouse in economics
-
see also Ronald H. Coase, The Lighthouse in Economics, 17 J.L. & ECON. 357 (1974).
-
(1974)
J.L. & Econ.
, vol.17
, pp. 357
-
-
Coase, R.H.1
-
399
-
-
79952613446
-
-
See Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18
-
See Hovenkamp, Coasean Markets, supra note 18.
-
-
-
-
400
-
-
79952580459
-
-
Press Release, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Prize in Economics 2009, available at
-
See Press Release, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Prize in Economics 2009, available at http://nobelprize.org/nobel-prizes/economics/laureates/2009/ press.html.
-
-
-
-
401
-
-
79952585981
-
-
See WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 8-9
-
See WILLIAMSON, supra note 42, at 8-9.
-
-
-
-
403
-
-
0000409508
-
The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead
-
see also Oliver E. Williamson, The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead, 38 J. ECON. LIT. 595 (2000).
-
(2000)
J. Econ. Lit.
, vol.38
, pp. 595
-
-
Williamson, O.E.1
-
404
-
-
79952583894
-
-
See supra text accompanying notes 146-47
-
See supra text accompanying notes 146-47.
-
-
-
-
405
-
-
79952577727
-
-
See supra text accompanying notes 50-53
-
See supra text accompanying notes 50-53.
-
-
-
-
406
-
-
79952590531
-
-
Coase, Problem of Social Cost, supra note 1, at 1-2
-
Coase, Problem of Social Cost, supra note 1, at 1-2.
-
-
-
-
407
-
-
79952611612
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
|