메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 84, Issue 4, 2000, Pages 805-862

Knowledge about welfare: Legal realism and the separation of law and economics

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0347664771     PISSN: 00265535     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (14)

References (328)
  • 1
    • 37949014319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ordinalism refers to our inability to make cardinal comparisons of utilities. This concept applies intrapersonally as well as interpersonally if one assumes that people experience declining marginal utility of income. For example, I might be willing to pay $1,000 for good A and $2,000 for good B, thus revealing that I place a monetary value on B that is twice as high as A. But if I also have declining marginal utility of income the first $1,000 out of my pocketbook will be less valuable to me than the second $1,000. In that case the amount of utility I obtain from B is more than twice A, but I do not know how much more.
  • 2
    • 0003917730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an explanation of the problem and a very simplified and non-mathematical proof
    • See generally KENNETH J. ARROW, SOCIAL CHOICE AND INDIVIDUAL VALUE (1951). For an explanation of the problem and a very simplified and non-mathematical proof,
    • SOCIAL CHOICE and INDIVIDUAL VALUE (1951).
    • Arrow, K.J.1
  • 3
    • 37949018633 scopus 로고
    • Arrow's Theorem: Ordinalism and Republican Government
    • see generally Herbert Hovenkamp, Arrow's Theorem: Ordinalism and Republican Government, 75 IOWAL. REV. 949 (1990).
    • (1990) IOWAL. REV. , vol.75 , pp. 949
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 4
    • 0347565248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Incommensurability, Welfare Economics, and the Law
    • Richard Craswell, Incommensurability, Welfare Economics, and the Law, 146 U. PA. L. REV. 1419, 1450 (1998);
    • (1998) 146 U. PA. L. REV. , vol.1419 , pp. 1450
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 5
    • 0043126758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Pragmatism and the Law and Economics Movement
    • see also Thomas F. Cotter, Legal Pragmatism and the Law and Economics Movement, 84 GEO. L.J. 2071, 2090-93 (1996);
    • (1996) 84 GEO. L.J. , vol.2071 , pp. 2090-2093
    • Cotter, T.F.1
  • 6
    • 37949017666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interdependence and Choice in Distributive Justice: The Welfare Conundrum
    • Lee Anne Fennell, Interdependence and Choice in Distributive Justice: The Welfare Conundrum, 1994 WlS. L. REV. 235, 300-20;
    • 1994 WlS. L. REV. , vol.235 , pp. 300-320
    • Fennell, A.1
  • 7
    • 0000247536 scopus 로고
    • Incommensurability and Valuation in Law
    • Cass R. Sunstein, Incommensurability and Valuation in Law, 92 MICH. L. REV. 779, 782-95 (1994);
    • (1994) 92 MICH. L. REV. , vol.779 , pp. 782-795
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 8
    • 37949006760 scopus 로고
    • Impossible Comparisons and Rational Choice Theory
    • Richard Warner, Impossible Comparisons and Rational Choice Theory, 68 S. CAL. L. REV. 1705,1733 (1995).
    • (1995) 68 S. CAL. L. REV. , vol.1705 , pp. 1733
    • Warner, R.1
  • 9
    • 0000163787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Possibility of Social Choice
    • Amartya Sen, The Possibility of Social Choice, 89 AM. ECON. REV. 349, 351 (1999).
    • (1999) 89 AM. ECON. REV. , vol.349 , pp. 351
    • Sen, A.1
  • 10
    • 37949010587 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 359.
  • 11
    • 0000415735 scopus 로고
    • Judging interpersonal interests
    • Jon Elster & Aanund Hylland eds., arguing it is virtually impossible for an actor to have knowledge about other people's mental states without making observations and comparisons with the actor's own mental state;
    • See generally Donald Davidson, Judging interpersonal interests, in FOUNDATIONS OF SOCIAL CHOICE THEORY 195, 203 (Jon Elster & Aanund Hylland eds., 1986) (arguing it is virtually impossible for an actor to have knowledge about other people's mental states without making observations and comparisons with the actor's own mental state);
    • (1986) FOUNDATIONS of SOCIAL CHOICE THEORY , vol.195 , pp. 203
    • Davidson, D.1
  • 12
    • 84925723241 scopus 로고
    • Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour
    • discussing weaknesses in behavior theories based on preference.
    • John C. Harsanyi, Morality and the Theory of Rational Behaviour, 44 SOC. RES. 623, 644-47 (1977) (discussing weaknesses in behavior theories based on preference).
    • (1977) 44 SOC. RES. , vol.623 , pp. 644-647
    • Harsanyi, J.C.1
  • 13
    • 0003110930 scopus 로고
    • Capability and Well-Being
    • Martha Nussbaum & Amartya Sen eds.
    • See, e.g., Amartya Sen, Capability and Well-Being, in THE QUALITY OF LIFE 30 (Martha Nussbaum & Amartya Sen eds., 1993);
    • (1993) THE QUALITY of LIFE , vol.30
    • Sen, A.1
  • 16
    • 0005516564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Individual Preference as the Basis of Social Choice
    • Kenneth J. Arrow et al. eds.
    • Amartya Sen, Individual Preference as the Basis of Social Choice, in 1 SOCIAL CHOICE RE-EXAMINED 15-37 (Kenneth J. Arrow et al. eds., 1997);
    • (1997) SOCIAL CHOICE RE-EXAMINED , vol.1 , pp. 15-37
    • Sen, A.1
  • 17
    • 0042341536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and Economics: Its Glorious Past and Cloudy Future
    • suggesting "that the language of 'preferences' is inadequate for economics" and that dealing with this inadequacy should be part of the agenda of law and economics.
    • cf. Richard A. Epstein, Law and Economics: Its Glorious Past and Cloudy Future, 64 U. CHI. L. REV. 1167, 1174 (1997) (suggesting "that the language of 'preferences' is inadequate for economics" and that dealing with this inadequacy should be part of the agenda of law and economics).
    • (1997) 64 U. CHI. L. REV. , vol.1167 , pp. 1174
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 18
    • 37949003272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sen, supra note 4, at 358. Sen writes: A hopeless destitute with much poverty, or a downtrodden laborer living under exploitative economic arrangements, or a subjugated housewife in a society with entrenched gender inequality, or a tyrannized citizen under brutal authoritarianism, may come to terms with her deprivation. She may take whatever pleasure she can from small achievements, and adjust her desire to take not of feasibility (thereby helping the fulfillment of her adjusted desires). But her success in such adjustment would not make her deprivation go away. The metric of pleasure or desire may sometimes be quite inadequate in reflecting the extent of a person's substantive deprivation. Id.
    • Supra Note , vol.4 , pp. 358
    • Sen1
  • 19
    • 0003612445 scopus 로고
    • THE DESCENT of MAN, and SELECTION
    • London, J. Murray
    • CHARLES DARWIN, THE DESCENT OF MAN, AND SELECTION IN RELATION TO SEX (London, J. Murray 1871).
    • (1871) RELATION to SEX
    • Darwin, C.1
  • 21
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • Ronald Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & ECON. , vol.3 , pp. 1
    • Coase, R.1
  • 24
    • 0009177993 scopus 로고
    • The Marasmus of the ICC: The Commission, the Railroads, and the Public Interest
    • Samuel P. Huntington, The Marasmus of the ICC: The Commission, the Railroads, and the Public Interest, 61 YALE L.J. 467 (1952);
    • (1952) YALE L.J. , vol.61 , pp. 467
    • Huntington, S.P.1
  • 25
    • 0345748321 scopus 로고
    • The Effective Limits of the Administrative Process
    • [hereinafter Jafie, Limits]
    • Louis L. Jaffe, The Effective Limits of the Administrative Process, 67 HARV. L. REV. 1105 (1954) [hereinafter Jafie, Limits];
    • (1954) HARV. L. REV. , vol.67 , pp. 1105
    • Jaffe, L.L.1
  • 26
    • 37949027617 scopus 로고
    • Invective and Investigation in Administrative Law
    • Louis L. Jaffe, Invective and Investigation in Administrative Law, 52 HARV. L. REV. 1201 (1939);
    • (1939) HARV. L. REV. , vol.52 , pp. 1201
    • Jaffe, L.L.1
  • 27
    • 37949035983 scopus 로고
    • The Report of the Attorney General's Committee on Administrative Procedure
    • Louis L. Jaffe, The Report of the Attorney General's Committee on Administrative Procedure, 8 U. CHI. L. REV. 401 (1941);
    • (1941) U. CHI. L. REV. , vol.8 , pp. 401
    • Jaffe, L.L.1
  • 30
    • 0000942437 scopus 로고
    • The Reformation of American Administrative Law
    • Landis had been the author in 1938 of the much more optimistic THE ADMINISTRATIVE PROCESS (1938).
    • Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 HARV. L. REV. 1669, 1677-78 (1975). Landis had been the author in 1938 of the much more optimistic THE ADMINISTRATIVE PROCESS (1938).
    • (1975) 88 HARV. L. REV. , vol.1669 , pp. 1677-1678
    • Stewart, R.B.1
  • 33
    • 37949050347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See discussion infra Part IV.
  • 34
    • 37949054715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See discussion infra Part IV.
  • 35
    • 84935190124 scopus 로고
    • The First Great Law and Economics Movement
    • On this close link prior to the 1930s, see Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law and Economics Movement, 42 STAN. L. REV. 993, 993-1031 (1990).
    • (1990) 42 STAN. L. REV. , vol.993 , pp. 993-1031
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 36
    • 37949041009 scopus 로고
    • rev. ed.
    • The highest marginal tax rate rose significantly during World War I, fell back and began rising during the New Deal until it reached a peak of 94% on incomes exceeding $200,000 during World War II. During the post-war forties the highest marginal rate was around 85%, and during all of the 1950s, it was in the low nineties (91% under the influential 1954 Code). In 1965, it fell to 70% and has been falling since. Further, at no time from 1900 until the beginning of World War II were more than 10% of the population made subject to the tax because the minimum taxable income was so high. During World War II, that number rose dramatically to 57.1% and has generally increased since then. Of course, the complete story is far more complicated. First, the total redistribution effected by the tax depends not only on the highest rate, but also on where the income gradations appeared, and the percentage of taxpayers that had to pay each rate. Further, other provisions in the code may have made actual rates higher or lower than apparent rates. For a summary of the historical data, see RICHARD GOODE, THE INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAX 308 (rev. ed. 1976).
    • (1976) THE INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAX , vol.308
    • Goode, R.1
  • 37
    • 37949020181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture Co., 350 F.2d 445,448-50 (D.C. Cir. 1965); GRANT GlLMORE, THE DEATH OF CONTRACT (1974).
  • 38
    • 37949037687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally Herbert Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Legal Thought, 46 VAND. L. REV. 305 (1993).
  • 39
    • 2942689241 scopus 로고
    • The Pure Theory of Taxation III
    • See, e.g., F.Y. Edgcworth, The Pure Theory of Taxation III, 7 ECON. J. 550 (1897);
    • (1897) ECON. J. , vol.7 , pp. 550
    • Edgcworth, F.Y.1
  • 40
    • 84963003100 scopus 로고
    • The Theory of Distribution
    • On Edgeworth and his influence on incipient law and economics in the United States
    • F.Y. Edgeworth, The Theory of Distribution, 18 Q.J. ECON. 159 (1904). On Edgeworth and his influence on incipient law and economics in the United States,
    • (1904) Q.J. ECON. , vol.18 , pp. 159
    • Edgeworth, F.Y.1
  • 41
  • 42
    • 37949026549 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., HENRY STEEL COMMAGER, THE AMERICAN MIND 41 (1950);
    • (1950) THE AMERICAN MIND , vol.41
  • 53
    • 0031330473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and Morals in Classical Legal Thought
    • On the relationship between economics and morals in classical legal thought, see generally Herbert Hovenkamp, Law and Morals in Classical Legal Thought, 82 IOWAL. REV. 1427 (1997).
    • (1997) IOWAL. REV. , vol.82 , pp. 1427
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 56
    • 0041187326 scopus 로고
    • Evolutionary Models in Jurisprudence
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models in Jurisprudence, 64 TEXAS L. REV. 645 (1985).
    • (1985) TEXAS L. REV. , vol.64 , pp. 645
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 57
    • 37949027490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the strongest statement of the thesis that Social Darwinism dominated Gilded Age American thought, see HOFSTADTER, supra note 23.
    • Supra Note , vol.23
    • Hofstadter1
  • 60
    • 37949044615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROSS, supra note 24, at 257-302, 390-470.
    • Supra Note , vol.24 , pp. 257-302
    • Ross1
  • 62
    • 0012234442 scopus 로고
    • Johnson Reprint Corp. 1968
    • LESTER FRANK WARD, DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY (Johnson Reprint Corp. 1968) (1883);
    • (1883) DYNAMIC SOCIOLOGY
    • Ward, L.F.1
  • 64
    • 37949004239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Reform Darwinism, see Hovenkamp, supra note 26, at 671-83;
    • Supra Note , vol.26 , pp. 671-683
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 79
    • 37949001721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 64-84.
  • 85
    • 0009949357 scopus 로고
    • Augustus M. Kelley Publishers 1967
    • in the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See generally JOHN BATES CLARK, THE PHILOSOPHY OF WEALTH 5690 (Augustus M. Kelley Publishers 1967) (1886);
    • (1886) THE PHILOSOPHY of WEALTH , pp. 5690
    • Clark, J.B.1
  • 87
    • 0003746324 scopus 로고
    • James Dingwall & Bert Hoselitz trans., 1981
    • Carl Menger's PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS (James Dingwall & Bert Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. On the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics,
    • (1871) PRINCIPLES of ECONOMICS
    • Menger, C.1
  • 88
    • 37949017371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see FURNER, supra note 26, at 50-57;
    • Supra Note , vol.26 , pp. 50-57
    • Furner1
  • 89
    • 37949037461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROSS, supra note 30, at 104-05;
    • Supra Note , vol.30 , pp. 104-105
    • Ross1
  • 91
    • 37949036388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • emphasis omitted.
    • JETONS, supra note 35, at 1 (emphasis omitted).
    • Supra Note , vol.35 , pp. 1
    • Jetons1
  • 92
    • 37949029898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 1-2.
  • 93
    • 37949037542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id.
  • 94
    • 37949001816 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "[W]hen the person remains satisfied with the distribution he has made, it follows that... an increment of commodity would yield exactly as much utility in one use as in another." Id. at 59.
  • 98
    • 37949014059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For illustrations, see id. at 311-12.
  • 99
    • 37949050501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, in deciding what inputs to use in making a product, the firm maximizes its profits by using each input up to a point that its marginal cost is identical to the marginal cost of every other input. If labor and machinery are alternative inputs into a product and the current cost of labor is $5 per unit of value produced while the current cost of machinery is $4, the firm will invest in more machinery and less labor until the two are equalized. See id. at 313.
  • 100
  • 105
    • 0005947799 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Concept of Workable Competi-tion
    • See generally, e.g., J.M. Clark, Toward a Concept of Workable Competi-tion, 30 AM. ECON. REV. 241 (1940).
    • (1940) AM. ECON. REV. , vol.30 , pp. 241
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 107
    • 37949008530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See infra text accompanying notes 62-84.
  • 108
    • 34147109849 scopus 로고
    • Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice
    • See, e.g., Hovenkamp, supra note 18, at 1002-05; Jan.-Mar.
    • See, e.g., Hovenkamp, supra note 18, at 1002-05; Edwin R.A. Seligman, Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice, PUBLICATION AM. ECON. ASS"N, Jan.-Mar. 1894, at 1,132-33.
    • (1894) Publication Am. Econ. Assn , pp. 1
    • Seligman, E.R.A.1
  • 109
    • 37949005467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 335-45; see also infra notes 56-61 and accompanying text
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 335-45; see also infra notes 56-61 and accompanying text.
  • 110
    • 0001417422 scopus 로고
    • The Path of the Law
    • See Oliver W. Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 HARV. L. REV. 457, 462 (1897).
    • (1897) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 457
    • Holmes, O.W.1
  • 111
    • 37949056583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the wage-fund doctrine in the United States, see HOVENKAMP, supra note 25, at 193-98
    • On the wage-fund doctrine in the United States, see HOVENKAMP, supra note 25, at 193-98.
  • 112
    • 37949050820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • That is, assuming that the marginal productivity of labor declines, the employer paying $1.00 per hour would continue to hire workers as long as the last worker hired contributed $1.00 or more; but if constrained to pay $1.10 per hour, the employer would stop hiring additional workers at the point that the marginal contribution was $1.10 The employer might simply produce less, or might make a somewhat larger investment in machinery or other alternatives to labor.
  • 113
    • 37949004086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 346-58
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 346-58.
  • 114
    • 37949008325 scopus 로고
    • Holmes and Evolution: Legal Process as Artificial Intelligence
    • Hovenkamp, supra note 26, at 656-64; Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 335-45
    • See E. Donald Elliott, Holmes and Evolution: Legal Process as Artificial Intelligence, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 113, 140 (1984); Hovenkamp, supra note 26, at 656-64; Hovenkamp, supra note 21, at 335-45.
    • (1984) J. Legal Stud. , vol.13 , pp. 113
    • Elliott, E.D.1
  • 115
    • 37949035372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 25, at 241-307
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 25, at 241-307.
  • 117
    • 37949008662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See McCRAW, supra note 13, at 153-221. See generally LANDIS, supra note 12; Jafie, Limits, supra note 13
    • See McCRAW, supra note 13, at 153-221. See generally LANDIS, supra note 12; Jafie, Limits, supra note 13.
  • 118
    • 0011674694 scopus 로고
    • See generally ARROW, supra note 2; BUCHANAN & TULLOCK, supra note 15. On public choice and social choice theory
    • See generally ARROW, supra note 2; BUCHANAN & TULLOCK, supra note 15. On public choice and social choice theory, see generally DANIEL A. FARBER & PHILIP P. FRICKEY, LAW AND PUBLIC CHOICE: A CRITICAL INTRODUCTION (1991);
    • (1991) Law and Public Choice: A Critical Introduction
    • Farber, D.A.1    Frickey, P.P.2
  • 120
    • 37949026001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, e.g., Coase, supra note 11
    • See generally, e.g., Coase, supra note 11.
  • 121
    • 0002408195 scopus 로고
    • Perfect Competition, Historically Contemplated
    • See George Stigler, Perfect Competition, Historically Contemplated, 65 J. POL. ECON. 1, 14-17 (1957).
    • (1957) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.65 , pp. 1
    • Stigler, G.1
  • 122
    • 37949036400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hayekian Socialism
    • For a rather extreme statement, see Richard A. Epstein, Hayekian Socialism, 58 MD. L. REV. 271 (1999).
    • (1999) MD. L. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 271
    • Epstein, R.A.1
  • 123
    • 37949010418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 129-37 and accompanying text (discussing ordinalism and progressive welfare economics)
    • See infra notes 129-37 and accompanying text (discussing ordinalism and progressive welfare economics).
  • 125
    • 0012271941 scopus 로고
    • ECONOMICS AND ETHICS: A STUDY IN SOCIAL VALUES (1929)
    • In comparison, see the thought of British institutionalist economist John A. Hobson in ECONOMICS OF DISTRIBUTION (1900) and ECONOMICS AND ETHICS: A STUDY IN SOCIAL VALUES (1929).
    • (1900) Economics of Distribution
    • Hobson, J.A.1
  • 126
    • 37949029212 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On Seligman's work on the theory of taxation and the progressive income tax, see Hovenkamp, supra note 18, at 1002-09.
  • 127
    • 84963015081 scopus 로고
    • Social Elements in the Theory of Value
    • See Edwin R.A. Seligman, Social Elements in the Theory of Value, 15 Q.J. ECON. 321, 322-27 (1901);
    • (1901) Q.J. Econ. , vol.15 , pp. 321
    • Seligman, E.R.A.1
  • 130
    • 37949016283 scopus 로고
    • Economics and the Law
    • Supp.
    • John H. Gray, Economics and the Law, 5 AM. ECON. REV. 3, 20-23 (Supp. 1915) (arguing that policy economics should be concerned with group needs rather than individual preferences);
    • (1915) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.5 , pp. 3
    • Gray, J.H.1
  • 131
    • 37949046356 scopus 로고
    • Value and Its Measurement
    • D.I. Green, Value and Its Measurement, 7 YALE REV. 383 (1899);
    • (1899) Yale Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 383
    • Green, D.I.1
  • 132
    • 37949042868 scopus 로고
    • The Philosophical Basis of Economics, A Word to the Sociologists
    • cf. Sidney Sherwood, The Philosophical Basis of Economics, A Word to the Sociologists, 10 ANNALS AM. ACAD. POL. & SOC. SCI. 206, 207 (1897) (arguing that the sociologists' theory of value, as presently developed, was too imprecise to be used by economists).
    • (1897) Annals Am. Acad. Pol. & Soc. Sci. , vol.10 , pp. 206
    • Sherwood, S.1
  • 133
    • 0039781391 scopus 로고
    • The Utility Concept in Value Theory and Its Critics: II. the Utility Concept in Welfare Economics
    • For a recap of the debate, see Jacob Viner, The Utility Concept in Value Theory and Its Critics: II. The Utility Concept in Welfare Economics, 33 J. POL. ECON. 638 (1925).
    • (1925) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.33 , pp. 638
    • Viner, J.1
  • 134
    • 37949011982 scopus 로고
    • Analysis of Cost of Production
    • Indeed, its lack of a social component caused some diehard classicists to continue to defend classical theories of value against the marginalist onslaught. See generally Silas M. Macvane, Analysis of Cost of Production, 1 Q.J. ECON. 481, 483 (1887);
    • (1887) Q.J. Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 481
    • Macvane, S.M.1
  • 135
    • 37949008079 scopus 로고
    • Marginal Utility and Value
    • Silas M. Macvane, Marginal Utility and Value, 7 Q.J. ECON. 255 (1893).
    • (1893) Q.J. Econ. , vol.7 , pp. 255
    • Macvane, S.M.1
  • 136
    • 37949037195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Seligman, supra note 66, at 322-23
    • See Seligman, supra note 66, at 322-23.
  • 137
    • 11244313414 scopus 로고
    • The Theory of Progressive Taxation
    • Jan. Seligman, supra note 50, at 13233. For fuller discussion, see Hovenkamp, supra note 18, at 1002-05
    • See Edwin R.A. Seligman, The Theory of Progressive Taxation, PUBLICATION AM. EGON. ASS'N, Jan. 1893, at 52; Seligman, supra note 50, at 13233. For fuller discussion, see Hovenkamp, supra note 18, at 1002-05.
    • (1893) Publication Am. Egon. Assn , pp. 52
    • Seligman, E.R.A.1
  • 139
    • 0040168515 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory
    • Supp.
    • See, e.g., Wal ton Hamilton, The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 309, 316 (Supp. 1919) (arguing for a "theory of motives ... in harmony with the conclusions of modern social psychology");
    • (1919) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 309
    • Hamilton, W.1
  • 140
    • 37949047867 scopus 로고
    • Human Behavior and Economics: A Survey of Recent Literature
    • Wesley C. Mitchell, Human Behavior and Economics: A Survey of Recent Literature, 29 Q.J. EGON, l, 2 (1914) (criticizing the view that economic theory rests "upon the simple facts of preference or choice, and the psychological explanation of these preferences or choices is... a matter of indifference to our science");
    • (1914) Q.J. Egon , vol.29 , pp. 2
    • Mitchell, W.C.1
  • 141
    • 0040168517 scopus 로고
    • The Rationality of Economic Activity 1
    • Wesley C. Mitchell, The Rationality of Economic Activity 1,18 J. POL. ECON. 97, 103,109-13 (1910) (taking issue with the economist's supposition of the rationality of human action and arguing that psychology and sociology suggested the contrary).
    • (1910) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.18 , pp. 97
    • Mitchell, W.C.1
  • 142
    • 0003784636 scopus 로고
    • See MARSHALL, supra note 41, at 18-19 (arguing that a pound's worth of satisfaction to an ordinary poor man is a much greater thing than a pound's worth of satisfaction to an ordinary rich man); 4th ed.
    • See MARSHALL, supra note 41, at 18-19 (arguing that a pound's worth of satisfaction to an ordinary poor man is a much greater thing than a pound's worth of satisfaction to an ordinary rich man); ARTHUR C. PlGOU, ECONOMICS OF WELFARE 89 (4th ed. I960) (arguing that "[a]ny transference of income from a relatively rich man to a relatively poor man of similar temperament, since it enables more intense wants to be satisfied at the expense of less intense wants, must increase the aggregate sum of satisfaction");
    • (1960) Economics of Welfare , pp. 89
    • Pgou, A.C.1
  • 143
    • 0039895070 scopus 로고
    • 3d ed.
    • FRANK WILLIAM TAUSSIG, PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS 132 (3d ed. 1921) ("The principle of diminishing utility, if applied unflinchingly, leads to the conclusion that inequality of incomes brings a less sum of human well-being than equality of incomes, and that the greater the inequality, the less the approach to the maximum.");
    • (1921) Principles of Economics , pp. 132
    • Taussig, F.W.1
  • 144
    • 37949009312 scopus 로고
    • The Ultimate Standard of Value
    • John Bates Clark, The Ultimate Standard of Value, 1 YALE REV. 258 (1893) (arguing that social welfare is a function of aggregated individual utilities);
    • (1893) Yale Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 258
    • Clark, J.B.1
  • 145
    • 1542456089 scopus 로고
    • The Scope of Political Economy
    • Simon N. Patten, The Scope of Political Economy, 2 YALE REV. 264, 266 (1894) (arguing that homogeneity of wealth and property tends to increase total utility); Viner, supra note 66, at 644 (1925) ("Changes in the relative distribution of income as between different classes will bring about changes in the amount of welfare, even though the aggregate real income of the community remains the same.").
    • (1894) Yale Rev. , vol.2 , pp. 264
    • Patten, S.N.1
  • 146
    • 0040411311 scopus 로고
    • Economic Theory in an Era of Social Readjustment
    • Supp.
    • See generally John Maurice Clark, Economic Theory in an Era of Social Readjustment, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 280 (Supp. 1919);
    • (1919) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 280
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 147
    • 0001773584 scopus 로고
    • Economics and Modern Psychology
    • John Maurice Clark, Economics and Modern Psychology, 26 J. POL. ECON. 1, 7 (1918) [hereinafter Clark, Economics and Modern Psychology].
    • (1918) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 1
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 148
    • 84963057294 scopus 로고
    • The Concept of Value: A Rejoinder
    • See John Maurice Clark, The Concept of Value: A Rejoinder, 29 Q.J. ECON. 709, 712 (1915);
    • (1915) Q.J. Econ. , vol.29 , pp. 709
    • Clark, J.M.1
  • 149
    • 37948999249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 73
    • see also Clark, Economics and Modern Psychology, supra note 73, at 10 ("In proportion as scientific research progresses, minimum standards of welfare will become more and more matters of social knowledge and less and less matters of individual taste - but only minimum standards relating to those necessities which are generally accepted as such.");
    • Economics and Modern Psychology , pp. 10
    • Clark1
  • 150
    • 0141863734 scopus 로고
    • The Emancipation of Economics
    • Lawrence K. Frank, The Emancipation of Economics, 14 AM. ECON. REV. 17 (1924);
    • (1924) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.14 , pp. 17
    • Frank, L.K.1
  • 151
    • 0040762630 scopus 로고
    • Psychology in Economic Theory
    • A.J. Snow, Psychology in Economic Theory, 32 J. POL. ECON. 487 (1924).
    • (1924) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.32 , pp. 487
    • Snow, A.J.1
  • 152
    • 37949010100 scopus 로고
    • Price Economics Versus Welfare Economics
    • See Frank A. Fetter, Price Economics Versus Welfare Economics, 10 All. ECON. REV. 467,476-79 (1920).
    • (1920) All. Econ. Rev. , vol.10 , pp. 467
    • Fetter, F.A.1
  • 153
    • 37949051459 scopus 로고
    • A Statistical Method for Measuring "Marginal Utility" and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax
    • H. Hollander ed.
    • See Irving Fisher, A Statistical Method for Measuring "Marginal Utility" and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax, in ECONOMIC ESSAYS CONTRIBUTED IN HONOR OF JOHN BATES CLARK 157, 171 (H. Hollander ed., 1927).
    • (1927) Economic Essays Contributed In Honor Of John Bates Clark , pp. 157
    • Fisher, I.1
  • 154
    • 0039758253 scopus 로고
    • The Prospects of Economics
    • Rexford Guy Tugwell ed.
    • Jacob Wesley Glair Mitchell, The Prospects of Economics, in THE TREND OF ECONOMICS 1,31 (Rexford Guy Tugwell ed., 1924).
    • (1924) The Trend of Economics , pp. 1
    • Wesley, J.1    Mitchell, G.2
  • 155
    • 37949006320 scopus 로고
    • The Effect of the Consumption of Wealth on the Economic Welfare of Society
    • Henry C. Adams ed.
    • See Simon N. Patten, The Effect of the Consumption of Wealth on the Economic Welfare of Society, in SCIENCE ECONOMIC DISCUSSION 123 (Henry C. Adams ed., 1886);
    • (1886) Science Economic Discussion , pp. 123
    • Patten, S.N.1
  • 158
    • 37949034958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROSS, supra note 30
    • ROSS, supra note 30.
  • 159
    • 37949040418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 329
    • See id. at 329.
  • 160
    • 37949030813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 330
    • See id. at 330.
  • 161
    • 37949044898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 331
    • See id. at 331.
  • 162
    • 37949028169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 7d.at332
    • 7d.at332.
  • 163
    • 37949033215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. at 338-39. Ross illustrated: There were many styles of gold-washing on the Sacramento in 1849; but one style was gradually found to be more convenient than the others, and became after a while the standard way of washing out gold, which newcomers adopted as a matter of course. A like weeding out of inferior individual practices brings to light a standard form of pot or tool or weapon, a standard mode of tilling or breeding, a standard sex relation or education of the young, which is uniform for all, possesses authority, and may be termed a culture element.... Once an element has emerged triumphant from this rivalry, it becomes fixed in custom and remains thus shielded from competition, until, perhaps, it is confronted with a different practice or belief that has won the favor of some other group. Then deadly comparisons are made, and weeding out begins again. Id.
  • 167
    • 26444502901 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Preference-Based Legal Policy
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Limits of Preference-Based Legal Policy, 89 NW. U. L. REV. 4,84-90 (1994).
    • (1994) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.89 , pp. 4
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 168
    • 37949002644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 170
    • 0000964163 scopus 로고
    • Were the Ordinalists Wrong about Welfare Economics?
    • see also Robert Cooter & Peter Rappoport, Were the Ordinalists Wrong About Welfare Economics?, 22 J. ECON. LIT. 507 (1984); Hovenkamp, supra note 18, at 1033-47.
    • (1984) J. Econ. Lit. , vol.22 , pp. 507
    • Cooter, R.1    Rappoport, P.2
  • 171
    • 37949044755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 129-37
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 129-37.
  • 172
    • 37949041310 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See DAVID WlGDOR, ROSCOE POUND 111-14 (1974). Pound needs a new biography that is somewhat more critical, that explores more deeply the intellectual origins of Pound's pre-1930s thought, and that evaluates more fully Pound's 1930s relationship with the Legal Realists.
  • 173
    • 0010394575 scopus 로고
    • Liberty of Contract
    • See, e.g., Roscoe Pound, Liberty of Contract, 18 YALE L.J. 454 (1909) [hereinafter Pound, Liberty of Contract};
    • (1909) Yale L.J. , vol.18 , pp. 454
    • Pound, R.1
  • 174
    • 0000465195 scopus 로고
    • Mechanical Jurisprudence
    • Roscoe Pound, Mechanical Jurisprudence, 8 COLUM. L. REV. 605 (1908) [hereinafter Pound, Mechanical Jurisprudence].
    • (1908) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.8 , pp. 605
    • Pound, R.1
  • 175
    • 37949017814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Pound, Liberty of Contract, supra note 91, at 455-56. Pound relied for his critique of the classicists on HENRY ROGERS SEAGER, INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS (3d ed. 1907), replaced in later years by his more influential PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS (1913). Seager was trained in the German Historical School but was a fairly orthodox marginalist and among the more conservative of the Progressive economists.
  • 177
    • 37948999436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See WlGDOR, supra note 90, at 113
    • See WlGDOR, supra note 90, at 113.
  • 178
    • 0040521344 scopus 로고
    • Pound cited SEAGER, supra note 92, and the work of other Progressive Era sociologists, including EDWARD A. ROSS, SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY (1908),
    • (1908) Social Psychology
    • Ross, E.A.1
  • 181
    • 37949021599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 91
    • cited in Pound, Liberty of Contract, supra note 91, at 454 n.3.
    • Liberty of Contract , Issue.3 , pp. 454
    • Pound1
  • 183
    • 37949040759 scopus 로고
    • The German Free Law Movement as the Source of American Legal Realism
    • On Pound and German historicism and the German "free law" movement, which sought to identify "social interests" that the law should protect, see James E. Herget & Stephen Wallace, The German Free Law Movement as the Source of American Legal Realism, 73 VA. L. REV. 399, 42228 (1987). On the German historical school and legal thought generally, see id. at 405-06.
    • (1987) Va. L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 399
    • Herget, J.E.1    Wallace, S.2
  • 184
    • 37949021846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RUDOLF VON JHERING, LAW AS A MEANS TO AN END 332-33 (Isaac Husik trans., 1913). On Jhering's influence on Pound, see Herget & Wallace, supra note 96, at 407-10; WlGDOR, supra note 90, at 114-18.
    • See, e.g., RUDOLF VON JHERING, LAW AS A MEANS TO AN END 332-33 (Isaac Husik trans., 1913). On Jhering's influence on Pound, see Herget & Wallace, supra note 96, at 407-10; WlGDOR, supra note 90, at 114-18.
  • 185
    • 33845810526 scopus 로고
    • Legislation as a Social Function
    • See, e.g., Roscoe Pound, Legislation as a Social Function, 18 AM. J. SOC. 755, 762 (1913);
    • (1913) Am. J. Soc. , vol.18 , pp. 755
    • Pound, R.1
  • 186
    • 37949025748 scopus 로고
    • Making Law and Finding Law
    • Roscoe Pound, Making Law and Finding Law, 82 CENTRAL L.J. 351, 358 (1916);
    • (1916) Central L.J. , vol.82 , pp. 351
    • Pound, R.1
  • 187
    • 0038947064 scopus 로고
    • Problems and the Courts
    • Roscoe Pound, The Scope and Purpose of Sociological Jurisprudence (pts. 1-3), 24 HARV. L. REV. 591 (1911), 25 HARV. L. REV. 140 (1912), 25 HARV. L. REV. 490 (1912) [hereinafter Pound, Scope and Purpose]
    • Roscoe Pound, The Scope and Purpose of Sociological Jurisprudence (pts. 1-3), 24 HARV. L. REV. 591 (1911), 25 HARV. L. REV. 140 (1912), 25 HARV. L. REV. 490 (1912) [hereinafter Pound, Scope and Purpose]; Roscoe Pound, Soda; Problems and the Courts, 18 AM. J. SOC. 331, 341 (1912).
    • (1912) Am. J. Soc. , vol.18 , pp. 331
    • Pound, R.1
  • 188
    • 37949036146 scopus 로고
    • Public Law and Private Law
    • However, later in his career Pound moved to the right and objected to what he saw as Legal Realism's use of the social sciences to subordinate all concern for the individual to various question about public goods and values. See generally, e.g., Roscoe Pound, Public Law and Private Law, 24 CORNELL L.Q. 469 (1939).
    • (1939) Cornell L.Q. , vol.24 , pp. 469
    • Pound, R.1
  • 189
    • 37949041820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Pound seems hostile toward economics as a general matter, and generally understood "economics" in legal analysis to refer to interest group politics. See, e.g., Roscoe Pound, The Economic Interpretation and the Law of Torts, 53 HARV. L. REV. 365, 383 (1940) (identifying the "economic interpretation" as the theory of how the rise and fall of various economically or politically powerful interests explains changes in tort law, and then arguing that such analysis accounts for only a small part of the law of torts).
  • 190
    • 37949021027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Pound, Scope and Purpose (pt. 3), supra note 98, at 489, 516 (listing the characteristics of Sociological Jurisprudence).
    • See, e.g., Pound, Scope and Purpose (pt. 3), supra note 98, at 489, 516 (listing the characteristics of Sociological Jurisprudence).
  • 191
    • 37949042443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Hovenkamp, supra note 18.
    • See generally Hovenkamp, supra note 18.
  • 192
    • 0010061125 scopus 로고
    • Law and Economics
    • See, e.g., John R. Commons, Law and Economics, 34 YALE L.J. 371, 374 (1925).
    • (1925) Yale L.J. , vol.34 , pp. 371
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 193
    • 37949030265 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Stigler, supra note 62.
    • See generally Stigler, supra note 62.
  • 194
    • 84963060379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Edward Ross, The Sociological Frontier of Economics, 13 Q.J. ECON. 386 (1898).
    • See generally Edward Ross, The Sociological Frontier of Economics, 13 Q.J. ECON. 386 (1898).
  • 195
    • 37949032925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 394.
    • See id. at 394.
  • 196
    • 37949046827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See JOHN DEWEY, INDIVIDUALISM, OLD AND NEW 9, 135, 168-71 (1930); John Dewey, Theory of Valuation, in 2 INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF UNIFIED SCIENCE 19-50 (1930). Compare the work of Clarence Ayres, a younger Progressive who did not start writing until the 1940s but then became a prominent dissenter from neoclassicism. Ayres also believed that one could measure social value through productivity tests - for example, conducting experiments on the importance of milk for infants and then coming up with a social value function that would inform the state policymaker about how many resources should be committed to guaranteeing its availability. See CLARENCE E. AYRES, THE INDUSTRIAL ECONOMY 305 (1952).
  • 197
    • 37949000671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 151-95 and accompanying text.
    • See infra notes 151-95 and accompanying text.
  • 198
    • 37949006164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., GUNNAR MYRDAL, THE POLITICAL ELEMENT IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF ECONOMIC THEORY 102 (1953). See generally I.M.D. LITTLE, CRITIQUE OF WELFARE ECONOMICS (1950); J.R. Hicks, The Foundations of Welfare Economics, 49 ECON. J. 696 (1939); Nicholas Kaldor, Welfare Propositions of Economies and Inter-personal Comparisons of Utility, 49 ECON. J. 549 (1939).
    • See, e.g., GUNNAR MYRDAL, THE POLITICAL ELEMENT IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF ECONOMIC THEORY 102 (1953). See generally I.M.D. LITTLE, CRITIQUE OF WELFARE ECONOMICS (1950); J.R. Hicks, The Foundations of Welfare Economics, 49 ECON. J. 696 (1939); Nicholas Kaldor, Welfare Propositions of Economies and Inter-personal Comparisons of Utility, 49 ECON. J. 549 (1939).
  • 199
    • 37949037631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On Veblen, see LEONARD DENTE, VEBLEN'S THEORY OF SOCIAL CHANGE (1977); JOSEPH DORFMAN, THORSTEIN VEBLEN AND His AMERICA (1934); STEPHEN EDGELL, VEBLEN: SOCIAL THEORIST AND SOCIAL CRITIC (1987); J.A. HOBSON, VEBLEN (1937); DAVID RIESMAN, THORSTEIN VEBLEN (1953); DAVID SECKLER, THORSTEIN VEBLEN AND THE INSTITUTIONALISTS (1975); BEN B. SELIGMAN, MAIN CURRENTS IN MODERN ECONOMICS 129-58 (1962).
    • On Veblen, see LEONARD DENTE, VEBLEN'S THEORY OF SOCIAL CHANGE (1977); JOSEPH DORFMAN, THORSTEIN VEBLEN AND His AMERICA (1934); STEPHEN EDGELL, VEBLEN: SOCIAL THEORIST AND SOCIAL CRITIC (1987); J.A. HOBSON, VEBLEN (1937); DAVID RIESMAN, THORSTEIN VEBLEN (1953); DAVID SECKLER, THORSTEIN VEBLEN AND THE INSTITUTIONALISTS (1975); BEN B. SELIGMAN, MAIN CURRENTS IN MODERN ECONOMICS 129-58 (1962).
  • 201
    • 37949052979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally supra notes 110-11. Both Veblen and Schumpeter also criticized the importance that neoclassicism assigned to the concept of an equilibrium. Both believed that the essence of markets and exertions of preference is change, and that the study of change was far more important than the study of equilibrium.
  • 203
    • 84980151295 scopus 로고
    • Thorstein Veblen's Theory of Evolutionary Change
    • Stephen Edgell, Thorstein Veblen's Theory of Evolutionary Change, 34 AM. J. ECON. & SOC. 267 (1975).
    • (1975) Am. J. Econ. & Soc. , vol.34 , pp. 267
    • Edgell, S.1
  • 204
    • 0347108433 scopus 로고
    • Veblen and Hayek on Instincts and Evolution
    • See generally Charles G. Leathers, Veblen and Hayek on Instincts and Evolution, 12 J. HIST. ECON. THOUGHT 162 (1990).
    • (1990) J. Hist. Econ. Thought , vol.12 , pp. 162
    • Leathers, C.G.1
  • 205
    • 0003359437 scopus 로고
    • The Limitations of Marginal Utility
    • Thorstein Veblen, The Limitations of Marginal Utility, 17 J. POL. ECON. 620, 626 (1909);
    • (1909) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.17 , pp. 620
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 206
    • 84881866629 scopus 로고
    • What Was Wrong with the Old Institutional Economics? (And What Is Still Wrong with the "New"?)
    • see also Richard N. Langlois, What Was Wrong with the Old Institutional Economics? (And What Is Still Wrong with the "New"?), 1 REV. POL. ECON. 3 (1989).
    • (1989) Rev. Pol. Econ. , vol.1 , pp. 3
    • Langlois, R.N.1
  • 207
    • 84939628466 scopus 로고
    • The Socialist Economics of Karl Marx and His Followers
    • Thorstein Veblen, The Socialist Economics of Karl Marx and His Followers, 21 Q.J. ECON. 299,308 (1907).
    • (1907) Q.J. Econ. , vol.21 , pp. 299
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 208
    • 37949048513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Veblen, supra note 115, at 627. To any modern scientist interested in economic phenomena, the chain of cause and effect in which any given phase of human culture is involved, as well as the cumulative changes wrought in the fabric of human conduct itself by the habitual activity of mankind, are matters of more engrossing and more abiding interest than the method of inference by which an individual is presumed invariably to balance pleasure and pain under given conditions that are presumed to be normal and invariable. Id.
  • 209
    • 33748687275 scopus 로고
    • Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?
    • See Thorstein Veblen, Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?, 12 Q.J. ECON. 373 (1898);
    • (1898) Q.J. Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 373
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 210
    • 84898535750 scopus 로고
    • The Preconceptions of Economic Science (pt. 3)
    • see also Thorstein Veblen, The Preconceptions of Economic Science (pt. 3), 14 Q.J. ECON. 240 (1900);
    • (1900) Q.J. Econ. , vol.14 , pp. 240
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 211
    • 84963028485 scopus 로고
    • Professor dark's Economics
    • Thorstein Veblen, Professor dark's Economics, 22 Q.J. ECON. 147 (1908).
    • (1908) Q.J. Econ. , vol.22 , pp. 147
    • Veblen, T.1
  • 212
    • 0000238538 scopus 로고
    • Thorstein Veblen and Post-Darwinian Economics
    • On this point, see Geoffrey M. Hodgson, Thorstein Veblen and Post-Darwinian Economics, 16 CAMBRIDGE J. ECON. 285,292 (1992).
    • (1992) Cambridge J. Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 285
    • Hodgson, G.M.1
  • 213
    • 37949014779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See THORSTEIN VEBLEN, The Evolution of the Scientific Point of View, 10 UNIV. CAL. CHRON. (n.d.), reprinted in THE PLACE OF SCIENCE IN MODERN CIVILIZATION AND OTHER ESSAYS 32, 37 (Transaction Publishers 1990) (1919).
  • 214
    • 37949027431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra notes 151-61 and accompanying text.
    • See infra notes 151-61 and accompanying text.
  • 215
    • 37949017543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • THORSTEIN VEBLEN, THE THEORY OF THE LEISURE CLASS 131 (Houghton Mifilin Co. 1973) (1899)
    • THORSTEIN VEBLEN, THE THEORY OF THE LEISURE CLASS 131 (Houghton Mifilin Co. 1973) (1899);
  • 216
    • 0000354917 scopus 로고
    • Thorstein Veblen and the Processes of Institutional Change
    • see also Malcolm Rutherford, Thorstein Veblen and the Processes of Institutional Change, 16 HIST. POL. ECON. 331 (1984);
    • (1984) Hist. Pol. Econ. , vol.16 , pp. 331
    • Rutherford, M.1
  • 217
    • 11244306774 scopus 로고
    • Some Recent Interpretations of Thorstein Veblen's Theory of Institutional Change
    • Rick Tilman, Some Recent Interpretations of Thorstein Veblen's Theory of Institutional Change, 21J. ECON. ISSUES 683 (1987).
    • (1987) J. Econ. Issues , vol.21 , pp. 683
    • Tilman, R.1
  • 218
    • 84882046185 scopus 로고
    • On the Concept of Social Value
    • See generally Joseph A. Schumpeter, On the Concept of Social Value, 23 Q.J. ECON. 213 (1909). A year earlier he had published DAS WESEN UND HAUPTINHALT DER THEORETISCHEN NATIONALöKONOMIE (1908) [NATURE AND ESSENCE OF THEORETICAL ECONOMICS], which was never translated.
    • (1909) Q.J. Econ. , vol.23 , pp. 213
    • Schumpeter, J.A.1
  • 219
    • 0003895696 scopus 로고
    • Schumpeter's writing was stark and to the point: At the outset it is useful to emphasize the individualistic character of the methods of pure theory. Almost every modern writer starts with wants and their satisfaction, and takes utility more or less exclusively as the basis of his analysis. Without expressing any opinion about this modus procedendi, I wish to point out that, as far as it is. used, it unavoidably implies considering individuals as independent units or agencies. For only individuals can feel wants.... [M]arginal utilities do not depend on what society as such has, but on what individual members have. Nobody values bread according to the quantity of it which is to be found in his country or in the world, but everybody measures the utility of it according to the amount that he has himself, and this in turn depends on his general means. Schumpeter, supra note 123, at 214. On methodological individualism in economics, see MARK BLAUG, THE METHODOLOGY OF ECONOMICS 129-56,227-31 (1980);
    • (1980) The Methodology of Economics , pp. 129-156
    • Blaug, M.1
  • 221
    • 21144480576 scopus 로고
    • Efficiency and Individualism
    • On methodological individualism in law and economics, and its relation to interpersonal utility comparisons, see generally Gary Lawson, Efficiency and Individualism, 42 DUKE L.J. 53 (1992). Methodological individualism in philosophy and the other social sciences long antedates Schumpeter, although it was not much debated during the Progressive Era.
    • (1992) Duke L.J. , vol.42 , pp. 53
    • Lawson, G.1
  • 222
    • 34047197292 scopus 로고
    • The Inadequacy of the Principle of Methodological Individualism
    • See generally Leon J. Goldstein, The Inadequacy of the Principle of Methodological Individualism, 53 J. PHIL. 801 (1956);
    • (1956) J. Phil. , vol.53 , pp. 801
    • Goldstein, L.J.1
  • 223
    • 85050415921 scopus 로고
    • Methodological Individualism Reconsidered
    • Steven Lukes, Methodological Individualism Reconsidered, 19 BRIT. J. SOC. 119 (1968);
    • (1968) Brit. J. Soc. , vol.19 , pp. 119
    • Lukes, S.1
  • 224
    • 85056007540 scopus 로고
    • Societal Facts
    • Maurice Mandelbaum, Societal Facts, 6 BRIT. J. SOC. "305 (1955);
    • (1955) Brit. J. Soc. , vol.6 , pp. 305
    • Mandelbaum, M.1
  • 225
    • 0346115974 scopus 로고
    • Methodological Individualism and Social Explanation
    • Richard Miller, Methodological Individualism and Social Explanation, 45 PHIL. SCI. 387 (1978);
    • (1978) Phil. Sci. , vol.45 , pp. 387
    • Miller, R.1
  • 226
    • 0001701765 scopus 로고
    • Historical Explanation in the Social Sciences
    • J.W.N. Watkins, Historical Explanation in the Social Sciences, 8 BRIT. J. PHIL. SCI. 104 (1957);
    • (1957) Brit. J. Phil. Sci. , vol.8 , pp. 104
    • Watkins, J.W.N.1
  • 227
    • 34047229697 scopus 로고
    • Ideal Types and Historial Explanation
    • J.W.N. Watkins, Ideal Types and Historial Explanation, 3 BRIT. J. PHIL. SCI. 22 (1952).
    • (1952) Brit. J. Phil. Sci. , vol.3 , pp. 22
    • Watkins, J.W.N.1
  • 228
    • 37949010355 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schumpeter, supra note 123, at 215
    • Schumpeter, supra note 123, at 215.
  • 229
    • 37949041658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 216
    • Id. at 216.
  • 230
    • 37749036412 scopus 로고
    • The Nature of Economic Science in Some Recent Discussion
    • See generally Frank H. Knight, The Nature of Economic Science in Some Recent Discussion, 24 AM. ECON. REV. 225 (1934).
    • (1934) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.24 , pp. 225
    • Knight, F.H.1
  • 231
    • 37949031253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schumpeter, supra note 123, at 220-22.
    • See Schumpeter, supra note 123, at 220-22.
  • 232
    • 0001059988 scopus 로고
    • Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility
    • See ROBBINS, supra note 88, at 136-47. See generally
    • See ROBBINS, supra note 88, at 136-47. See generally Lionel Robbins, Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility, 48 ECON. J. 635 (1938). Schumpeter had already observed a generation before Robbins's essay: A most interesting assumption would be that, at a given time and in a given place, individual utility curves for each commodity do not differ very much from each other. To-day [sic] we do not assume anything of this sort, but fashion, imitation, etc., might support such an hypothesis, the importance of which it is needless to emphasize. Schumpeter, supra note 123, at 219 n.2.
    • (1938) Econ. J. , vol.48 , pp. 635
    • Robbins, L.1
  • 234
    • 37949048216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., ALFRED JULES AVER, LANGUAGE, TRUTH AND LOGIC 5-16 (1936).
    • See, e.g., ALFRED JULES AVER, LANGUAGE, TRUTH AND LOGIC 5-16 (1936).
  • 235
    • 0005950609 scopus 로고
    • Scope and Method of Economics
    • Hicks, supra note 109; Kaldor, supra note 109
    • See, e.g., LITTLE, supra note 109, at 55-58. See generally R.F. Harrod, Scope and Method of Economics, 48 ECON. J. 383 (1938); Hicks, supra note 109; Kaldor, supra note 109.
    • (1938) Econ. J. , vol.48 , pp. 383
    • Harrod, R.F.1
  • 236
    • 0742297398 scopus 로고
    • Bentham's Felicific Calculus
    • Wesley C. Mitchell, Bentham's Felicific Calculus, 33 POL. SCI. Q. 161 (1918) (quoting a manuscript in 3 HALEVY, RADICALISME PHILOSOPHIQUE 431).
    • (1918) Pol. Sci. Q. , vol.33 , pp. 161
    • Mitchell, W.C.1
  • 237
    • 37949028778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Id. Bentham argued that the problem of interpersonal utility comparisons was significant and made any calculus of interpersonal pain and pleasure impossible, but that social science could probably proceed on the basis of somewhat less precise interpersonal utility comparisons.
  • 238
    • 37949004349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The name ordinalism derives from the fact that one can still compare utilities ordinally by observing exchange. For example, if we see A trade two apples for one of B's pears, we can still say that A receives less utility from one additional apple than from one additional pear, but we cannot put any unit (such as inches or pounds) on this measure that we can assume applies equally to both A and B. That is, cardinal measurement is impossible.
  • 239
    • 37949034593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, the works by Watson, Pavlov, Weiss, Dewey, Bagley & Colvin, McDougall, and Meyer cited in supra note 32.
    • See, for example, the works by Watson, Pavlov, Weiss, Dewey, Bagley & Colvin, McDougall, and Meyer cited in supra note 32.
  • 240
    • 37949033518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This was fundamentally the analysis of WARD, supra note 30.
    • This was fundamentally the analysis of WARD, supra note 30.
  • 241
    • 0039727710 scopus 로고
    • See THOMAS M. COOLEY, A TREATISE ON THE LAW OF TORTS 688 (1879) (addressing the place of motive in the law of torts); HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 137.
    • (1879) A Treatise On The Law of Torts , pp. 688
    • Cooley, T.M.1
  • 242
    • 0004264409 scopus 로고
    • On Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr., and the external standard, see generally HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 110-13, 135-41
    • OLIVER WENDELL HOLMES, JR., THE COMMON LAW (1881). On Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr., and the external standard, see generally HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 110-13, 135-41;
    • (1881) The Common Law
    • Holmes Jr., O.W.1
  • 244
    • 0042997026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Holmes and the Romantic Mind
    • Cotter, supra note 3
    • Cotter, supra note 3; Anne C. Dailey, Holmes and the Romantic Mind, 48 DUKE L.J. 429,452-56 (1998);
    • (1998) Duke L.J. , vol.48 , pp. 429
    • Dailey, A.C.1
  • 245
    • 0001429259 scopus 로고
    • Holmes and Legal Pragmatism
    • Thomas C. Grey, Holmes and Legal Pragmatism, 41 STAN. L. REV. 787 (1989);
    • (1989) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 787
    • Grey, T.C.1
  • 246
    • 37949056463 scopus 로고
    • Oliver Wendell Holmes and External Standards of Criminal and Tort Liability: Application of Theory on the Massachusetts Bench
    • William A. Lundquist, Comment, Oliver Wendell Holmes and External Standards of Criminal and Tort Liability: Application of Theory on the Massachusetts Bench, 28 BUFF. L. REV. 607,608-10 (1979).
    • (1979) Buff. L. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 607
    • Lundquist, W.A.1
  • 247
    • 37949058005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 110.
    • See HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 110.
  • 248
    • 37949049017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally SAMUEL WILLISTON, l THE LAW OF CONTRACTS (1920). In 1 THE LAW OF CONTRACTS § 20, Williston notes actual consent is not an element of contract, but merely the expression of consent, and concludes: The parol evidence rule which is of such far reaching importance in determining the existence and meaning of contracts is based on the assumption that where a written memorial of the transaction is made its terms are conclusive. Such a rule is inconsistent with the view that the mental attitude or assent of the parties is the ultimate juridical fact to be established. Williston then concluded that the intent to contract was not a part of the law of contract, see id. § 21; that legal consideration cannot be determined by the intent of the parties, see id. §§ 101,104; and that the statute of frauds must be broadly construed, see id. §§ 448-84,525-38.
  • 249
    • 37949034955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 2 ELIZABETH FLOWER & MURRAY G. MURPHY, A HISTORY OF PHILOSOPHY IN AMERICA chs. 10-15 (1977).
    • See 2 ELIZABETH FLOWER & MURRAY G. MURPHY, A HISTORY OF PHILOSOPHY IN AMERICA chs. 10-15 (1977).
  • 250
    • 37949002094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally 5 CHARLES S. PEIRCE, THE COLLECTED PAPERS OF CHARLES SANDERS PEIRCE 358 (Charles Hartshorne & Paul Weiss eds., 1934, 1935) (reprinting CHARLES S. PEIRCE, THE FIXATION OF BELIEF (1877)); id. at 388 (reprinting CHARLES PEIRCE, HOW TO MAKE OUR IDEAS CLEAR (1878)).
  • 251
    • 84937186301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hegel and the Autonomy of Contract Law
    • See ROSS, supra note 24, at 252-53, 327-30, 405-07. Good recent writing includes Dailey, supra note 139, and Chad McCracken, Note, Hegel and the Autonomy of Contract Law, 77 TEX. L. REV. 719 (1999).
    • (1999) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 719
    • McCracken, C.1
  • 252
    • 37949015379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 88-89 and accompanying text.
    • See supra notes 88-89 and accompanying text.
  • 253
    • 37949003741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, e.g., JOHN DEWEY, THE QUEST FOR CERTAINTY (1929).
    • See generally, e.g., JOHN DEWEY, THE QUEST FOR CERTAINTY (1929).
  • 254
    • 37949021247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ARROW, supra note 2, at 59-73.
    • See ARROW, supra note 2, at 59-73.
  • 256
    • 37949053182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Hovenkamp, supra note 86.
    • See generally Hovenkamp, supra note 86.
  • 257
    • 26444504709 scopus 로고
    • Rationality in Law & Economics
    • But see Herbert Hovenkamp, Rationality in Law & Economics, 60 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 293, 333-36 (1992) (stating that even proposals respecting public goods are subject to Arrovian cycling and failure of equilibrium).
    • (1992) Geo. Wash. L. Rev. , vol.60 , pp. 293
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 258
    • 34047165114 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Character of Pecuniary Valuation
    • In addition to the work of Veblen, Commons, Seligman, and Mitchell cited previously, see Charles H. Cooley, The Institutional Character of Pecuniary Valuation, 18 AM. J. SOC. 543, 546-50 (1913);
    • (1913) Am. J. Soc. , vol.18 , pp. 543
    • Cooley, C.H.1
  • 259
    • 0012589267 scopus 로고
    • Economic Theory and the Natural Science Point of View
    • Morris A. Copeland, Economic Theory and the Natural Science Point of View, 21 AM. ECON. REV. 67, 68 (1931);
    • (1931) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.21 , pp. 67
    • Copeland, M.A.1
  • 260
    • 84963003156 scopus 로고
    • Some Positive Contributions of the Institutional Concept
    • Lionel D. Edie, Some Positive Contributions of the Institutional Concept, 41 Q.J. ECON. 405,420-21 (1927).
    • (1927) Q.J. Econ. , vol.41 , pp. 405
    • Edie, L.D.1
  • 261
    • 2142775908 scopus 로고
    • The First Two Decades of the American Economic Association
    • See A.W. Coats, The First Two Decades of the American Economic Association, 50 AM. ECON. REV. 555 (1960);
    • (1960) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 555
    • Coats, A.W.1
  • 262
    • 37949007703 scopus 로고
    • The Founding and Early History of the American Economic Association
    • Supp.
    • Richard T. Ely, The Founding and Early History of the American Economic Association, 26 AM. ECON. REV. 141 (Supp. 1936).
    • (1936) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.26 , pp. 141
    • Ely, R.T.1
  • 263
    • 37949040716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally HENRY STEELE COMMAGER, THE AMERICAN MIND 227-46 (1950) (containing lengthy discussion of Veblen while John Bates Clark, who is mentioned once, is incorrectly lumped with the classical economists); RICHARD HOFSTADTER, THE AGE OF REFORM (1955) (containing three mentions of Veblen; none of Clark); MORION WHITE, SOCIAL THOUGHT IN AMERICA: THE REVOLT AGAINST FORMALISM (1947) (containing numerous references to Veblen; none to Clark or Fisher).
  • 264
    • 37949056549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Recent examples taking marginalism into account are BARBARA H. FRIED, THE PROGRESSIVE ASSAULT ON LAISSEZ FAIRE: ROBERT HALE AND THE FIRST LAW AND ECONOMICS MOVEMENT (1998); ROSS, supra note 24; Hovenkamp, supra note 21.
  • 265
    • 37949050886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROSS, supra note 30.
    • See ROSS, supra note 30.
  • 266
    • 37948999926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JOHN R. COMMONS, LEGAL FOUNDATIONS OF CAPITALISM 67-68, 121 (1924).
    • See JOHN R. COMMONS, LEGAL FOUNDATIONS OF CAPITALISM 67-68, 121 (1924).
  • 267
    • 37949003997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally ADOLPH A. BERLE, JR. & GARDINER C. MEANS, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE PROPERTY (1932); ROBERT S. BROOKINGS, INDUSTRIAL OWNERSHIP: ITS ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE (1925); THORSTEIN VEBLEN, ABSENTEE OWNERSHIP AND BUSINESS ENTERPRISE IN RECENT TIMES: THE CASE OF AMERICA (1923).
  • 268
    • 37949040977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally BERLE & MEANS, supra note 157.
    • See generally BERLE & MEANS, supra note 157.
  • 269
    • 37949051387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 173-74.
    • See infra text accompanying notes 173-74.
  • 271
    • 85011512436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Law and Neoclassical Economics: Science, Politics, and the Reconfiguration of American Tort Law Theory
    • James R. Hackney, Jr., Law and Neoclassical Economics: Science, Politics, and the Reconfiguration of American Tort Law Theory, 15 LAW HIST. REV. 275 (1997);
    • (1997) Law Hist. Rev. , vol.15 , pp. 275
    • Hackney Jr., J.R.1
  • 272
    • 85000523127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Intellectual Roots of the Law and Economics Movement
    • James J. Heckman, The Intellectual Roots of the Law and Economics Movement, 15 LAW HIST. REV. 327 (1997);
    • (1997) Law Hist. Rev. , vol.15 , pp. 327
    • Heckman, J.J.1
  • 273
    • 0001593458 scopus 로고
    • Law and Economics in the United States: A Brief Historical Survey
    • Hovenkamp, supra note 18
    • Hovenkamp, supra note 18; Herbert Hovenkamp, Law and Economics in the United States: A Brief Historical Survey, 19 CAMBRIDGE J. ECON. 331 (1995).
    • (1995) Cambridge J. Econ. , vol.19 , pp. 331
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 274
    • 0042341534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Future of Law and Economics: Looking Forward
    • See also the interesting panel discussion in Douglas G. Baird, The Future of Law and Economics: Looking Forward, 64 U. CHI. L. REV. 1129 (1997).
    • (1997) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 1129
    • Baird, D.G.1
  • 275
    • 37949032690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Paul T. Homan, An Appraisal of Institutional Economics, 22 AM. ECON. REV. 10, 10-17 (1932); Institutional Economics, 22 AM. ECON. REV. 105-16 (Supp. 1932) (panel discussion).
    • See, e.g., Paul T. Homan, An Appraisal of Institutional Economics, 22 AM. ECON. REV. 10, 10-17 (1932); Institutional Economics, 22 AM. ECON. REV. 105-16 (Supp. 1932) (panel discussion).
  • 276
    • 0040363136 scopus 로고
    • From Sociological Jurisprudence to Realism: Jurisprudence and Social Change in Early Twentieth-Century America
    • On Legal Realism, see HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 169-92. See generally GARY JAN AICHELE, LEGAL REALISM AND TWENTIETH-CENTURY AMERICAN JURISPRUDENCE: THE CHANGING CONSENSUS (1990)
    • On Legal Realism, see HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 169-92. See generally GARY JAN AICHELE, LEGAL REALISM AND TWENTIETH-CENTURY AMERICAN JURISPRUDENCE: THE CHANGING CONSENSUS (1990); G. Edward White, From Sociological Jurisprudence to Realism: Jurisprudence and Social Change in Early Twentieth-Century America, 58 VA. L. REV. 999 (1972).
    • (1972) Va. L. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 999
    • White, G.E.1
  • 277
    • 0348198485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Legal Realism: Toward a Naturalized Jurisprudence
    • A particularly good analysis of legal realism's basic analytic approach, less cluttered by au currant ideology than many others, is Brian Leiter, Rethinking Legal Realism: Toward a Naturalized Jurisprudence, 76 TEX. L. REV. 267 (1997).
    • (1997) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 267
    • Leiter, B.1
  • 279
    • 0347330236 scopus 로고
    • Between-the-Wars Social Thought: Karl Llewellyn, Legal Realism, and the Uniform Commercial Code in Context
    • On the institutional nature of the Legal Realists' economics, see Allen R. Kamp, Between-the-Wars Social Thought: Karl Llewellyn, Legal Realism, and the Uniform Commercial Code in Context, 59 ALB. L. REV. 325 (1995);
    • (1995) Alb. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 325
    • Kamp, A.R.1
  • 281
    • 0040404476 scopus 로고
    • Some Realism about Realism-Responding to Dean Pound
    • See Karl N. Llewellyn, Some Realism About Realism-Responding to Dean Pound, 44 HARV. L. REV. 1222, 1237 (1931).
    • (1931) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 1222
    • Llewellyn, K.N.1
  • 282
    • 37949029375 scopus 로고
    • The Call for a Realist Jurisprudence
    • Llewellyn was responding to Roscoe Pound, The Call for a Realist Jurisprudence, 44 HARV. L. REV. 697 (1931).
    • (1931) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.44 , pp. 697
    • Pound, R.1
  • 283
    • 84897316465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reconstructing the Origins of Realistic Juris-prudence: A Prequel to the Llewellyn-Pound Exchange over Legal Realism
    • On the indebtedness of the Legal Realists (particularly Llewellyn) to Pound, and the stormy relations that developed later, see generally HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 169-92; N.E.H. Hull, Reconstructing the Origins of Realistic Juris-prudence: A Prequel to the Llewellyn-Pound Exchange Over Legal Realism, 1989 DUKE L.J. 1302;
    • Duke L.J. , vol.1989 , pp. 1302
    • Hull, N.E.H.1
  • 284
    • 37949004971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some Realism about the Llewellyn-Pound Exchange over Realism: The Newly Uncovered Private Correspondence, 1927-1931
    • N.E.H. Hull, Some Realism about the Llewellyn-Pound Exchange Over Realism: The Newly Uncovered Private Correspondence, 1927-1931, 1987 WIS. L. REV. 921.
    • Wis. L. Rev. , vol.1987 , pp. 921
    • Hull, N.E.H.1
  • 285
    • 37949032615 scopus 로고
    • Law Enforcement-An Attempt at Social Dissection
    • See generally Thurman W. Arnold, Law Enforcement-An Attempt at Social Dissection, 42 YALE L.J. 1 (1932);
    • (1932) Yale L.J. , vol.42 , pp. 1
    • Arnold, T.W.1
  • 286
    • 37949057402 scopus 로고
    • An Institutional Approach to the Law of Commercial Banking
    • Underbill Moore Theodore S. Hope, Jr., An Institutional Approach to the Law of Commercial Banking, 38 YALE L.J. 703 (1929);
    • (1929) Yale L.J. , vol.38 , pp. 703
    • Moore, U.1    Hope, T.S.2
  • 287
    • 0039040010 scopus 로고
    • Law and Learning Theory: A Study in Legal Control
    • Underbill Moore & Charles Callahan, Law and Learning Theory: A Study in Legal Control, 53 YALE L.J. 1 (1943).
    • (1943) Yale L.J. , vol.53 , pp. 1
    • Moore, U.1    Callahan, C.2
  • 288
    • 37949057848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally KARL N. LLEWELLYN & E. ADAMSON HOEBEL, THE CHEYENNE WAY (1941); Huntington Cairns, Law and Anthropology, 31 COLUM. L. REV. 32 (1931).
    • See generally KARL N. LLEWELLYN & E. ADAMSON HOEBEL, THE CHEYENNE WAY (1941); Huntington Cairns, Law and Anthropology, 31 COLUM. L. REV. 32 (1931).
  • 289
    • 37949045710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally JEROME FRANK, LAW AND THE MODERN MlND (1930).
    • See generally JEROME FRANK, LAW AND THE MODERN MlND (1930).
  • 290
    • 37949012625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Karl N. Llewellyn, A Realistic Jurisprudence-The Next Step, 30 COLUM. L. REV. 431 (1930).
    • See generally Karl N. Llewellyn, A Realistic Jurisprudence-The Next Step, 30 COLUM. L. REV. 431 (1930).
  • 291
    • 37949024143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally FRANK, supra note 167; Charles E. Clark, Fact Research in Law Administration, 2 CONN. B.J. 211 (1928); John Dickinson, Legal Rules: Their Function in the Process of Decision, 79 U. PA. L. REV. 833 (1931)
    • See generally FRANK, supra note 167; Charles E. Clark, Fact Research in
  • 292
    • 37949045178 scopus 로고
    • A Factual Study of Bankruptcy Administration and Some Suggestions
    • William O. Douglas & J. Howard Marshall, A Factual Study of Bankruptcy Administration and Some Suggestions, 32 COLUM. L. REV. 25 (1932).
    • (1932) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.32 , pp. 25
    • Douglas, W.O.1    Howard Marshall, J.2
  • 293
    • 37949006002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, e.g., Karl N. Llewellyn, What Price Contract?-An Essay in Perspective, 40 YALE L.J. 704 (1931).
    • See generally, e.g., Karl N. Llewellyn, What Price Contract?-An Essay in Perspective, 40 YALE L.J. 704 (1931).
  • 294
    • 37949030964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, e.g., Robert L. Hale, Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State, 38 POL. SCI. Q. 470 (1923).
    • See generally, e.g., Robert L. Hale, Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State, 38 POL. SCI. Q. 470 (1923).
  • 295
    • 37949035222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Morton Horwitz's conclusion that Legal Realists pursued their attack on the legitimacy of the market with a degree of insight, brilliance, and social passion that has never been equaled since certainly captures their basic attitude towards classical political economy, but it misstates their focus. See HORWITZ, supra note 25, at 195. This may be a projection of the Critical Legal Studies scholarship onto the Realists, but in any event, Horwitz discusses only Hale and Dawson, neither of whom were among the most prominent Legal Realists. Further, Hale's influential essay, Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State, 38 POL. Sci. Q. 470 (1923), is not so much an attack on the legitimacy of the market as it is a call for a new understanding of the market that was more sensitive to its coercive features. For example, he chastised the orthodox defense of liberty of contract because it contrasted the supposed liberty of the market against the coercion of state interference. See id. In fact, Hale argued, the relevant choice was between two types of coercion, market coercion or coercion by government decision. See, e.g., id. at 470 (contending laissez faire systems . themselves are permeated with coercive restrictions of individual freedom and the restrictions are inconsistent with equal opportunity or preservation of the rights of others). This new understanding was generally consistent with the view of neoclassical economists that the classicists had exaggerated the degree of freedom that markets permitted. See HOVENKAMP, supra note 25, at 226-30 (labor); id. at 268-95 (competition and antitrust). But see Richard Epstein, The Assault That Failed: The Progressive Critique of Laissez Faire, 97 MICH. L. REV. 1697 (1999); Richard A. Epstein, Life Boats, Desert Islands, and the Poverty of Modern Jurisprudence, 68 MISS. L.J. 861 (1999).
  • 296
    • 37949022111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See LAURA KALMAN, LEGAL REALISM AT YALE, 1927-1960, at 153-54 (1986) (describing Yale curriculum in the 1940s). See generally John Henry Schlegel, American Legal Realism and Empirical Social Science: From the Yale Experience, 28 BUFF. L. REV. 459 (1979).
    • See LAURA KALMAN, LEGAL REALISM AT YALE, 1927-1960, at 153-54 (1986) (describing Yale curriculum in the 1940s). See generally John Henry Schlegel, American Legal Realism and Empirical Social Science: From the Yale Experience, 28 BUFF. L. REV. 459 (1979).
  • 297
    • 37949051921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See generally, e.g., Underhill Moore & Theodore S. Hope, Jr., An Institutional Approach to the Law of Commercial Banking, 38 YALE L.J. 703 (1929) (taking a Commons-like approach in grouping organizations by the nature of the transactions they make); Underhill Moore & Gilbert Sussman, Legal and Institutional Methods Applied to the Debiting of Direct Discounts-HI. The Connecticut Studies, 40 YALE L.J. 752 (1931). For other articles in the Legal and Institutional Methods Applied to the Debiting of Direct Discounts series by Moore and Sussman, see 40 YALE L.J. 381,555, 752,928,1055,1219 (1931). For an accounting of Moore's research methodology, see John Henry Schlegel, American Legal Realism and Empirical Social Science: The Singular Case of Underhill Moore, 29 BUFF. L. REV. 195, 244-250 (1980); see also William Clark et al., The Business Failures Project-A Problem in Methodology, 39 YALE L.J. 1013 (1930) (discussing a study of bankruptcy administration); William O. Douglas, A Functional Approach to the Law of Business Associations, 23 ILL. L. REV. 673 (1929); Douglas & Marshall, supra note 169 (discussing the process and flaws of a scientific study of the causes of bankruptcy).
  • 298
    • 37949004502 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., FRIED, supra note 154, at 10-15.
    • See, e.g., FRIED, supra note 154, at 10-15.
  • 299
    • 36749095897 scopus 로고
    • Bargaining, Duress and Economic Liberty
    • Hale, supra note 172
    • See generally Robert L. Hale, Bargaining, Duress and Economic Liberty, 43 COLUM. L. REV. 603 (1943); Hale, supra note 172;
    • (1943) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.43 , pp. 603
    • Hale, R.L.1
  • 300
    • 37949032231 scopus 로고
    • Value to the Taker in Condemnation Cases
    • Robert L. Hale, Value to the Taker in Condemnation Cases, 31 COLUM. L. REV. 1 (1931).
    • (1931) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.31 , pp. 1
    • Hale, R.L.1
  • 301
    • 84979127509 scopus 로고
    • Robert Hale and the Economy of Legal Force
    • For further discussion about Hale, see FRIED, supra note 154; Neil Duxbury, Robert Hale and the Economy of Legal Force, 53 MOD. L. REV. 421 (1990);
    • (1990) Mod. L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 421
    • Duxbury, N.1
  • 302
    • 33847393380 scopus 로고
    • The Economy as a System of Power and Its Legal Bases: The Legal Economics of Robert Lee Hale
    • Schlegel, supra note 174, at 209 & n.70.
    • Warren J. Samuels, The Economy as a System of Power and Its Legal Bases: The Legal Economics of Robert Lee Hale, 27 U. MIAMI L. REV. 261 (1973); Schlegel, supra note 174, at 209 & n.70.
    • (1973) U. Miami L. Rev. , vol.27 , pp. 261
    • Samuels, W.J.1
  • 303
    • 0040168515 scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory
    • Supp.
    • See generally Walton H. Hamilton, The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 309 (Supp. 1919).
    • (1919) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 309
    • Hamilton, W.H.1
  • 304
    • 37949011528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 314-15.
    • See id. at 314-15.
  • 305
    • 37949001330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 312-13.
    • See id. at 312-13.
  • 306
    • 37949057873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 64-84 and accompanying text.
    • See supra notes 64-84 and accompanying text.
  • 307
    • 37949003178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hamilton, supra note 177, at 316-17.
    • See Hamilton, supra note 177, at 316-17.
  • 308
    • 37949002567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally MARSHALL, supra note 40.
    • See generally MARSHALL, supra note 40.
  • 309
    • 37949005203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lewis H. Haney, Economic Theory-Discussion, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 320,321 (Supp. 1919).
    • See Lewis H. Haney, Economic Theory-Discussion, 9 AM. ECON. REV. 320,321 (Supp. 1919).
  • 310
    • 37949056595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 311
    • 37949024635 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 312
    • 37949048562 scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Legal Institutions Upon Economics
    • See Karl N. Llewellyn, The Effect of Legal Institutions Upon Economics, 15 AMER. ECON. REV. 665,666 (1925).
    • (1925) Amer. Econ. Rev. , vol.15 , pp. 665
    • Llewellyn, K.N.1
  • 313
    • 37949018730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 668.
    • Id. at 668.
  • 314
    • 37949018869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 673-75. Llewellyn concluded that in the one area that he had studied, motion picture distribution contracts, standardized forms had been very successful in reducing legal costs. See id. at 674.
    • See id. at 673-75. Llewellyn concluded that in the one area that he had studied, motion picture distribution contracts, standardized forms had been very successful in reducing legal costs. See id. at 674.
  • 315
    • 37949037827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 671-72.
    • See id. at 671-72.
  • 316
    • 37949036241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 674-76.
    • See id. at 674-76.
  • 317
    • 37949027585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a discussion of Coasian institutionalism, see generally R.H. COASE, THE INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION 9 (1991)
    • For a discussion of Coasian institutionalism, see generally R.H. COASE, THE INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION 9 (1991);
  • 319
    • 84979188687 scopus 로고
    • The Nature of the Firm
    • However, the origins can be found in R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386 (1937);
    • (1937) Economica , vol.4 , pp. 386
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 321
    • 37949020835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 186-90 and accompanying text.
    • See supra notes 186-90 and accompanying text.
  • 322
    • 37949010541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally, e.g., FRANK, supra note 167.
    • See generally, e.g., FRANK, supra note 167.
  • 323
    • 37949041232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., HENRY M. HART, JR. & ALBERT SACKS, THE LEGAL PROCESS: BASIC PROBLEMS IN THE MAKING AND APPLICATION OF LAW (William N. Eskridge, Jr., & Philip P. Frickey eds., 1994) (prepared from 1958 tentative edition). This work was heavily influenced by Legal Realism and consumed by the institutionalist approach to law. In this regard, the Legal Realists were indebted to Pound, who also wrote more about legal institutions and legal process than about substantive law. See generally, e.g., Roscoe Pound, Courts and Legislation, 7 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 361 (1915); Roscoe Pound, Justice According to Law (pts. 1-3), 13 COLUM. L. REV. 696 (1913), 14 COLUM. L. REV. 1,103 (1914); supra notes 91, 98-100, 163. On the Legal Realists increasing concern with procedure, see Schlegel, supra note 173, at 495-519. On Hart and Sacks, see ANTHONY J. SEBOK, LEGAL POSITIVISM IN AMERICAN JURISPRUDENCE 129-78,315-17 (1998).
  • 325
    • 37949036158 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for example, the 1950 Celler-Kefauver amendments to the anti-merger statute, 15 U.S.C. §18 (1994); see also H.R. REP. No. 81-1191, at 2-3 (1949) (discussing goals of merger policy as protecting smaller firms from larger, lower cost rivals). The new merger policy, designed to prevent small high cost firms from being gobbled up by larger, more efficient firms was hailed as a triumph of law and economics. Cf. Derek Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 HARV. L. REV. 226, 226-31, 238-48 (1960); Herbert Hovenkamp, Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics, 21 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM 515,521-22 (1988).
  • 326
    • 37949008706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally ARROW, supra note 2; BUCHANAN & TULLOCK, supra note 15.
    • See generally ARROW, supra note 2; BUCHANAN & TULLOCK, supra note 15.
  • 327
    • 37949053279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Coase, supra note 11.
    • See generally Coase, supra note 11.
  • 328
    • 37949004160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally GORDON TULLOCK, ECONOMICS OF INCOME REDISTRIBUTION, 111-50 (1983); GORDON TULLOCK, THE ECONOMICS OF SPECIAL PRIVILEGE AND RENT SEEKING (1989).
    • See generally GORDON TULLOCK, ECONOMICS OF INCOME REDISTRIBUTION, 111-50 (1983); GORDON TULLOCK, THE ECONOMICS OF SPECIAL PRIVILEGE AND RENT SEEKING (1989).


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.