메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 95, Issue 3, 2010, Pages 863-918

The law of vertical integration and the business firm: 1880-1960

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 77953074502     PISSN: 00210552     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (21)

References (341)
  • 1
    • 0010821422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (3d ed. 2002) (noting that vertical integration occurs where a single firm develops or acquires the intermediate stages required for production of final output).
    • See Martin Ricketts, The Economics of Business Enterprise: An Introduction to Economic Organization and the Theory of the Firm 217-18 (3d ed. 2002) (noting that vertical integration occurs where a single firm develops or acquires the intermediate stages required for production of final output).
    • The Economics of Business Enterprise: An Introduction to Economic Organization and the Theory of the Firm , pp. 217-218
    • Ricketts, M.1
  • 2
    • 0002011547 scopus 로고
    • The significance of industrial integration
    • For a definition from the earlier part of the twentieth century, when U.S. economists were first discussing the problem, 179, (denning vertical integration as "the functional coordination of one or more units in each of the several successive stages of production, so that they are all operated as a single, unified industrial process")
    • For a definition from the earlier part of the twentieth century, when U.S. economists were first discussing the problem, see Lawrence K. Frank, The Significance of Industrial Integration, 33 J. POL. ECON. 179, 179 (1925) (denning vertical integration as "the functional coordination of one or more units in each of the several successive stages of production, so that they are all operated as a single, unified industrial process").
    • (1925) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.33 , pp. 179
    • Frank, L.K.1
  • 4
    • 77953069372 scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Winslow, U.S. 202, 217, (approving the 1899 merger that created the United Shoe Machinery Company)
    • See United States v. Winslow, 227 U.S. 202, 217 (1913) (approving the 1899 merger that created the United Shoe Machinery Company);
    • (1913) , pp. 227
  • 5
    • 77953052392 scopus 로고
    • United States V. United Shoe Machinery Corporation, (describing the merger and subsequent expansion)
    • CARL KAYSEN, United STATES V. UNITED SHOE Machinery Corporation. An Economic Analysis of an Anti-Trust Case 2-3 (1956) (describing the merger and subsequent expansion).
    • (1956) An Economic Analysis Of An Anti-Trust Case , pp. 2-3
    • Kaysen, C.1
  • 6
    • 77953037142 scopus 로고
    • For a description of the shoe market, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, U.S. 294, 297
    • For a description of the shoe market, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 297 (1962)
    • (1962) , pp. 370
  • 7
    • 77953046569 scopus 로고
    • Witherell & Dobbins Co. v. United Shoe Machinery Co., F. 950, 951 (1st Cir.
    • Witherell & Dobbins Co. v. United Shoe Machinery Co., 267 F. 950, 951 (1st Cir. 1920).
    • (1920) , pp. 267
  • 8
    • 77953035568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 3, at 3-4 (describing the complexities of manufacturing both the machinery necessary to produce shoes and the shoes themselves)
    • See also KAYSEN, supra note 3, at 3-4 (describing the complexities of manufacturing both the machinery necessary to produce shoes and the shoes themselves).
    • Kaysen1
  • 9
    • 85023193375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. at 346
    • Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 346.
    • Brown Shoe , pp. 370
  • 10
    • 77953075714 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 72-73 (noting that both the Justice Department and the Supreme Court launched aggressive campaigns against vertical mergers in the wake of the 1950 amendment to the Clayton Act)
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 72-73 (noting that both the Justice Department and the Supreme Court launched aggressive campaigns against vertical mergers in the wake of the 1950 amendment to the Clayton Act).
  • 11
    • 85023193375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. at 296. For the district court's opinion describing the 1956 merger
    • Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 296. For the district court's opinion describing the 1956 merger,
    • Brown Shoe , pp. 370
  • 12
    • 77953077294 scopus 로고
    • see United States v. Brown Shoe Co., F. Supp. 721,724-27 (D. Mo.
    • see United States v. Brown Shoe Co., 179 F. Supp. 721,724-27 (D. Mo. 1959).
    • (1959) , pp. 179
  • 13
    • 77953052109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 111-14 (noting the incorporation of antitrust principles into vertical-integration analysis)
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 111-14 (noting the incorporation of antitrust principles into vertical-integration analysis).
  • 14
    • 77953029330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the rise of marginalist economics, see MARK Blaug, ECONOMIC THEORY IN Retrospect, chs. 8-11, 15 (5th ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1996)
    • On the rise of marginalist economics, see MARK Blaug, ECONOMIC THEORY IN Retrospect, chs. 8-11, 15 (5th ed., Cambridge Univ. Press 1996),
  • 15
    • 21144473011 scopus 로고
    • The marginalist revolution in legal thought
    • 314-18, (discussing the relationship between Darwinism and the rise of marginalism)
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Legal Thought, 46 VAND. L. Rev. 305, 314-18 (1993) (discussing the relationship between Darwinism and the rise of marginalism).
    • (1993) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 305
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 16
    • 77953069110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United states competition policy in crisis: 1890-1955
    • 322, (discussing the idea of "social control," which tended to normalize and limit industrial excesses)
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, United States Competition Policy in Crisis: 1890-1955, 94 MINN. L. REV. 311, 322 (2009) (discussing the idea of "social control," which tended to normalize and limit industrial excesses).
    • (2009) Minn. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 311
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 18
    • 77953043819 scopus 로고
    • Introduction
    • (Claudia Goldin & Gary D. Libecap eds., (discussing the debatable relationship between government intervention and economic development)
    • Claudia Goldin & Gary D. Libecap, Introduction to THE REGULATED ECONOMY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY 1 (Claudia Goldin & Gary D. Libecap eds., 1994) (discussing the debatable relationship between government intervention and economic development);
    • (1994) The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to Political Economy , vol.1
  • 19
    • 0348198313 scopus 로고
    • Regulation history as politics or markets
    • (reviewing THE REGULATED ECONOMY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY (Claudia Goldin & Gary D. Libecap eds., 1994)).
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Regulation History as Politics or Markets, 12 YALE J. ON REG. 549 (1995) (reviewing THE REGULATED ECONOMY: A HISTORICAL APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY (Claudia Goldin & Gary D. Libecap eds., 1994)).
    • (1995) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.12 , pp. 549
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 20
    • 77953067775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the history of competition policy and antitrust, see generally, ch. 2, THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF ANTITRUST: THE PUBLIC-CHOICE PERSPECTIVE (Fred S. McChesney & William F. Shughart II eds., 1995)
    • On the history of competition policy and antitrust, see generally HERBERT HOVENKAMP, THE ANTITRUST ENTERPRISE: PRINCIPLE AND EXECUTION ch. 2 (2005), THE CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF ANTITRUST: THE PUBLIC-CHOICE PERSPECTIVE (Fred S. McChesney & William F. Shughart II eds., 1995),
    • (2005) The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle And Execution
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 21
    • 77953051580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 22
    • 0002201724 scopus 로고
    • The origins of antitrust: An interest-group perspective
    • Thomas J. DiLorenzo, The Origins of Antitrust: An Interest-Group Perspective, 5 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 73 (1985),
    • (1985) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.5 , pp. 73
  • 23
    • 84977422664 scopus 로고
    • The legislative history of the sherman act re-examined
    • 267
    • Thomas W. Hazlett, The Legislative History of the Sherman Act Re-Examined, 30 ECON. INQUIRY 263, 267 (1992),
    • (1992) Econ. Inquiry , vol.30 , pp. 263
    • Hazlett, T.W.1
  • 24
    • 0042130721 scopus 로고
    • The origin of the sherman act
    • George J. Stigler, The Origin of the Sherman Act, 14 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1985).
    • (1985) J. Legal Stud. , vol.14 , pp. 1
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 25
    • 0345203408 scopus 로고
    • See generally, (revealing how railroad barons sought government regulation when competition forced them to underprice their services)
    • See generally GABRIEL KOLKO, RAILROADS AND REGULATION, 1877-1916 (1965) (revealing how railroad barons sought government regulation when competition forced them to underprice their services).
    • (1965) Railroads And Regulation , pp. 1877-1916
    • Kolko, G.1
  • 26
    • 0000420789 scopus 로고
    • Toward a more general theory of regulation
    • On this theory of regulation, 235-36
    • On this theory of regulation, see Sam Peltzman, Toward a More General Theory of Regulation, 19 J.L. & ECON. 211, 235-36 (1976),
    • (1976) J.L. & Econ. , vol.19 , pp. 211
    • Peltzman, S.1
  • 27
    • 0000191844 scopus 로고
    • The social cost of monopoly and regulation
    • 807
    • Richard A. Posner, The Social Cost of Monopoly and Regulation, 83 J. POL.ECON. 807, 807 (1975).
    • (1975) J. Pol.Econ. , vol.83 , pp. 807
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 28
    • 77953056106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 29
    • 77953057454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neoclassicism and the separation of ownership and control
    • 375, (discussing how the firm's only goal in microeconomics is maximization of value)
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Neoclassicism and the Separation of Ownership and Control, 4 VA. L. & Bus. REV. 373, 375 (2009) (discussing how the firm's only goal in microeconomics is maximization of value);
    • (2009) Va. L. & Bus. Rev. , vol.4 , pp. 373
  • 30
    • 77953037677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 8 (Univ. of Iowa Legal Studies, Working Paper No. 08-29, available at, (discussing how the marginalist revolution turned the corporation into a rational actor, intent on maximizing value)
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Corporate Finance, 1880-1965, at 8 (Univ. of Iowa Legal Studies, Working Paper No. 08-29, 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1141291 (discussing how the marginalist revolution turned the corporation into a rational actor, intent on maximizing value).
    • (2008) The Marginalist Revolution in Corporate Finance, 1880-1965
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 31
    • 84979188687 scopus 로고
    • The nature of the firm
    • 404
    • Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386, 404 (1937).
    • (1937) Economica , vol.4 , pp. 386
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 32
    • 84875463625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On this article and its relation to the rise of modem law and economics, see generally, (Univ. of Iowa Legal Studies, Working Paper No. 10-07, available at
    • On this article and its relation to the rise of modem law and economics, see generally Herbert Hovenkamp, Coase, Institutionalism, and the Origins of Law and Economics (Univ. of Iowa Legal Studies, Working Paper No. 10-07, 2008), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract-id=1538279.
    • (2008) Coase, Institutionalism, and the Origins of Law and Economics
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 33
    • 77953075466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 10, at 320 ("Product differentiation served to limit firms' competition with one another even when they were in the same general market")
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 10, at 320 ("Product differentiation served to limit firms' competition with one another even when they were in the same general market").
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 35
    • 77953041391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 267.
  • 36
    • 0001277766 scopus 로고
    • The division of labor is limited fry the extent ofthe market
    • 185
    • George J. Stigler, The Division of Labor Is Limited fry the Extent ofthe Market, 59 J. POL. EdON. 185,185 (1951).
    • (1951) J. POL. EdON. , vol.59 , pp. 185
    • Stigler, G.J.1
  • 37
    • 0000212177 scopus 로고
    • Economic Change and the Boundaries of the Firm
    • See generally, 642, ("As the market for the final product expands, however, it becomes profitable for the increasing-returns activities to spin off and exploit their economies of scale by aggregating the demands for their services across the industry.").
    • See generally Richard N. Langlois, Economic Change and the Boundaries of the Firm, 144 J. INSTITUTIONAL & THEORETICAL EcON. 635, 642 (1988) ("As the market for the final product expands, however, it becomes profitable for the increasing-returns activities to spin off and exploit their economies of scale by aggregating the demands for their services across the industry.").
    • (1988) J. Institutional & Theoretical Econ. , vol.144 , pp. 635
    • Langlois, R.N.1
  • 39
    • 77953064339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id, 156,373
    • Id. at 147-48,156,373.
  • 40
    • 77953038613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at, see discussion infra text accompanying notes 215-16
    • Id. at 156; see discussion infra text accompanying notes 215-16.
  • 41
    • 77953059088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note
    • Marshall, supra note 20, at 380-81.
    • , vol.20 , pp. 380-381
    • Marshall1
  • 42
    • 77953039704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 559-61.
  • 44
    • 0002011547 scopus 로고
    • The Significance of Industrial Integration
    • (noting how discussion within business and industry was usually concerned with questions about relative economy, profitability, and efficiency)
    • Eg., Lawrence Frank, The Significance of Industrial Integration, 33 J. POL. EOON. 179 (1925) (noting how discussion within business and industry was usually concerned with questions about relative economy, profitability, and efficiency).
    • (1925) J. Pol. Eoon. , vol.33 , pp. 179
    • Lawrence Frank, E.G.1
  • 45
    • 77953031724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On die Harvard School, see Hovenkamp, supra note, (noting how Joe Bain became the most prominent spokesperson for Harvard School structuralism)
    • On die Harvard School, see Hovenkamp, supra note 10, at 348 (noting how Joe Bain became the most prominent spokesperson for Harvard School structuralism).
    • , vol.10 , pp. 348
  • 47
    • 77953064068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 358.
  • 48
    • 77953063798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 168.
  • 49
    • 77953066982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 168-69.
  • 50
    • 77953051579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 357.
  • 51
    • 77953068035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BAIN, supra note, 358
    • BAIN, supra note 28, at 168, 358.
    • , vol.28 , pp. 168
  • 52
    • 77953064824 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 358.
  • 53
    • 0000827401 scopus 로고
    • Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process
    • See, e.g., (describing "vertical integration⋯ as a means of economizing on the costs of avoiding risks of appropriation of quasi rents in specialized assets by opportunistic individuals")
    • See, e.g., Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford & Annen A. Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & EOON. 297, 299 (1978) (describing "vertical integration⋯ as a means of economizing on the costs of avoiding risks of appropriation of quasi rents in specialized assets by opportunistic individuals").
    • (1978) J.L. & Eoon. , vol.21 , pp. 297-299
    • Klein, B.1    Crawford, R.G.2    Alchian, A.A.3
  • 54
    • 77953057753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BAIN, supra note
    • BAIN, supra note 28, at 358.
    • , vol.28 , pp. 358
  • 55
    • 77953052940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 330.
  • 56
    • 77953042479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 331.
  • 57
    • 77953050782 scopus 로고
    • Frankh. Knighr, Rlsk, Uncirtainryandprofit
    • Frankh. Knighr, Rlsk, Uncirtainryandprofit (1921).
    • (1921)
  • 58
    • 77953078379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, supra note
    • Coase, supra note 14.
  • 59
    • 77953041390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note
    • KNIGHT, supra note 39, at 245;
    • , vol.39 , pp. 245
    • Knight1
  • 60
    • 84977355938 scopus 로고
    • see, Frank Knight on Risk, Uncertainty, and the Farm: A New Interpretation, explaining the use of judgment to deal with uncertainty
    • see Richard N. Langlois & Metin M. Cosgel, Frank Knight on Risk, Uncertainty, and the Farm: A New Interpretation, 31 ECON. INQUIRY 456,462 (1993) (explaining the use of judgment to deal with uncertainty);
    • (1993) Econ. Inquiry , vol.31 , pp. 456-462
    • Richard, N.1    Langlois2    Cosgel, M.M.3
  • 61
    • 84977339736 scopus 로고
    • Knight's "Moral Hazard" Theory of Organization
    • see also, (arguing Knight's "moral hazard" theory is the central feature of the firm)
    • see also Yoram Barzel, Knight's "Moral Hazard" Theory of Organization, 25 ECON. INQUIRY 117, 177 (1987) (arguing Knight's "moral hazard" theory is the central feature of the firm);
    • (1987) Econ. Inquiry , vol.25 , pp. 117
    • Barzel, Y.1
  • 62
    • 84986782815 scopus 로고
    • The coasian and knightian theories of the firm
    • "An alternative, which corresponds to Knight's concept of the firm, is to model the entrepreneur as choosing to bring new goods to market or to use new production processes where the outcome is uncertain.").
    • Donald J. Boudreaux & Randall G. Holcombe, The Coasian and Knightian Theories of the Firm, 10 MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. 147, 148 (1989) ("An alternative, which corresponds to Knight's concept of the firm, is to model the entrepreneur as choosing to bring new goods to market or to use new production processes where the outcome is uncertain.").
    • (1989) MANAGERIAL & DECISION ECON. , vol.10 , pp. 147-148
    • Boudreaux, D.J.1    Holcombe, R.G.2
  • 63
    • 37749008572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Pier Francesco Asso & Luca Fiorito, Was Frank Knight an Institutionalist T, (arguing that Knight was an institutionalist).
    • See Pier Francesco Asso & Luca Fiorito, Was Frank Knight an InstitutionalistT, 20 REV. POL. ECON. 59,60 (2008) (arguing that Knight was an institutionalist).
    • (2008) Rev. Pol. Econ. , vol.20 , pp. 59-60
  • 65
    • 77953053206 scopus 로고
    • Thorstein Veblen, Absentee Ownership and Business Enterprise in Recent Times, On Veblen as a predecessor to Berle and Means
    • Thorstein Veblen, Absentee Ownership and Business Enterprise in Recent Times: THE CASE OF AMERICA 5 (1923). On Veblen as a predecessor to Berle and Means
    • (1923) The Case of America , vol.5
  • 67
    • 77953079773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note, ("Neoclassicism largely disregarded the ownership/control problem by positing that both the firm and its shareholders had only profit-maximization in mind.").
    • See Hovenkamp, Neoclassicism and the Separation of Ownership and Control, supra note 13, at 381 ("Neoclassicism largely disregarded the ownership/control problem by positing that both the firm and its shareholders had only profit-maximization in mind.").
    • Neoclassicism and the Separation of Ownership and Control , vol.13 , pp. 381
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 68
    • 77953071027 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, (explaining how goodwill gained through unbridled vertical integration would quickly result in a monopoly)
    • See, e.g, Commons J.R. Legal Foundations of Capitalism 270, 1942, (explaining how goodwill gained through unbridled vertical integration would quickly result in a monopoly);
    • (1924) Legal Foundations of Capitalism , vol.270
    • Commons, J.R.1
  • 69
    • 77953048196 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration in Aluminum: A Bar to "Effective Competition,"
    • arguing that establishing effective competition requires changing natural industry patterns).
    • Comment, Vertical Integration in Aluminum: A Bar to "Effective Competition," 60 Yale LJ. 1951 arguing that establishing effective competition requires changing natural industry patterns).
    • (1951) Yale LJ. , vol.60 , pp. 294
    • Comment1
  • 70
    • 77953038879 scopus 로고
    • The author of Vertical Integration in Aluminum: A Bar to "Effective Competition," was a Professor at Yale Law School from 1928 to 1948
    • although he trained as an economist rather than a lawyer. In particular, he argued that Alcoa's integration into fabrication served to foreclose that market to independent fabricators. The government's case against Alcoa's exclusionary vertical practices is made in Harold G. Reuschlein, Aluminum and Monopoly: A Phase of an Unsolved Problem, 535-537
    • Hamilton W. The author of Vertical Integration in Aluminum: A Bar to "Effective Competition," was a Professor at Yale Law School from 1928 to 1948 although he trained as an economist rather than a lawyer. In particular, he argued that Alcoa's integration into fabrication served to foreclose that market to independent fabricators. The government's case against Alcoa's exclusionary vertical practices is made in Harold G. Reuschlein, Aluminum and Monopoly: A Phase of an Unsolved Problem 87 U. PA. L. Rev. 509 535-37 1939.
    • (1939) U. PA. L. Rev. , vol.87 , pp. 509
    • Hamilton, W.1
  • 71
    • 74349091598 scopus 로고
    • (discussing the evils of vertical integration in the oil industry);
    • See also, Rostow E.V., A NATIONAL POLICY FOR THE On. INDUSTRY 71-76, (discussing the evils of vertical integration in the oil industry);
    • (1948) A NATIONAL POLICY FOR THE On. INDUSTRY , pp. 71-76
    • Rostow, E.V.1
  • 72
    • 0001891346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Corporate finance, the theory of the fam, and organizations
    • On this point, see
    • On this point, see Patrick Bolton & David S. Scharfstein, Corporate Finance, the Theory of the Fam, and Organizations,]. ECON. PERSP., Fall 1998, at 95.
    • (1998) ECON. PERSP., Fall , pp. 95
    • Bolton, P.1    Scharfstein, D.S.2
  • 73
    • 77953048748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying note
    • See infra text accompanying note 73.
  • 74
    • 77953051578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase moved to the United States in 1951 and became affiliated with the University of Chicago in 1964.
    • Coase moved to the United States in 1951 and became affiliated with the University of Chicago in 1964.
  • 75
    • 77953068298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See BAIN, supra note
    • See BAIN, supra note 28.
  • 76
    • 84917106186 scopus 로고
    • The Nature of the Firm: Origin
    • R.H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm: Origin, 4 J.L. EOON. & ORG. 3,4 (1988).
    • (1988) 4 J.L. EOON. & ORG. , vol.3 , pp. 4
    • Coase, R.H.1
  • 77
    • 77953065882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 14, at
    • Coase, supra note 14, at 404.
    • Coase1
  • 78
    • 77953037677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 13 (stating that the marginalist concept of the corporation entirely separated corporate decision-making from all human preference, unless those preferences were simply asserted to maximize value)
    • See generally Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Corporate Finance, 1880-1965, supra note 13 (stating that the marginalist concept of the corporation entirely separated corporate decision-making from all human preference, unless those preferences were simply asserted to maximize value).
    • The Marginalist Revolution in Corporate Finance, 1880-1965
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 79
    • 0002781788 scopus 로고
    • Theories of the firm: Marginalist, behavioral, managerial
    • On the debate over marginalism and profit-maximization as explanatory devices for the business firm
    • On the debate over marginalism and profit-maximization as explanatory devices for the business firm, see Fritz Machlup, Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral, Managerial, 57 AM. ECON. REV. 1, 2-6 (1967).
    • (1967) 57 AM. ECON. REV. , vol.1 , pp. 2-6
    • Machlup, F.1
  • 80
    • 0004192228 scopus 로고
    • (arguing for a more institutionalist behavioral theory of the firm)
    • See generally RICHARD M. CYERT & JAMES G. MARCH, A BEHAVIORAL THEORY OF THE FIRM (1963) (arguing for a more institutionalist behavioral theory of the firm).
    • (1963) A BEHAVIORAL THEORY OF THE FIRM
    • Cyert, R.M.1    March, J.G.2
  • 81
    • 0004010763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (3d ed.) (explaining that vertical integration lacks anticompetitive consequences when both markets are competitive)
    • E.g., 3B Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶¶ 756-62 (3d ed. 2006) (explaining that vertical integration lacks anticompetitive consequences when both markets are competitive);
    • (2006) Antitrust Law , pp. 756-762
    • Areeda, P.E.1    Hovenkamp, H.2
  • 82
    • 9944242970 scopus 로고
    • Vertical integration and the sherman act: The legal history of an economic misconception
    • (noting that the law has "consistently condemned" vertical integration)
    • Robert Bork, Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act: The Legal History of an Economic Misconception, 22 U. CHI. L. REV. 157, 159 (1954) (noting that the law has "consistently condemned" vertical integration).
    • (1954) 22 U. CHI. L. REV. , vol.157 , pp. 159
    • Bork, R.1
  • 83
    • 77953048195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 28
    • BAIN, supra note 28, at 168-69.
    • Bain1
  • 84
    • 77953071603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 1-2 (describing the example of the village cobbler)
    • See supra text accompanying notes 1-2 (describing the example of the village cobbler).
  • 85
    • 77953072110 scopus 로고
    • See generally United Shoe Mach. Corp. v. United States, 258 U.S. 451, (condemning anticompetitive lease agreements)
    • See generally United Shoe Mach. Corp. v. United States, 258 U.S. 451 (1922) (condemning anticompetitive lease agreements); United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295 (D. Mass. 1953), aff'd mem., 347 U.S. 521 (1954) (similar).
    • (1922)
  • 86
    • 77953066179 scopus 로고
    • United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295 (D. Mass.), aff'd mem., 347 U.S. 521 (1954) (similar).
    • United States v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 110 F. Supp. 295 (D. Mass. 1953), aff'd mem., 347 U.S. 521 (1954) (similar).
    • (1953)
  • 87
    • 77953074330 scopus 로고
    • Vertical integration: Impact of the antitrust laws upon combinations of successive stages of production and distribution
    • G. E. Hale, Vertical Integration: Impact of the Antitrust Laws upon Combinations of Successive Stages of Production and Distribution, 49 COLUM. L. REV. 921,922 (1949).
    • (1949) 49 COLUM. L. REV. , vol.921 , pp. 922
    • Hale, G.E.1
  • 88
    • 84974465495 scopus 로고
    • Explaining vertical integration: Lessons from the American automobile industry
    • (explaining the early evolution of automobile industry)
    • See Richard N. Langlois & Paul L. Robertson, Explaining Vertical Integration: Lessons from the American Automobile Industry, 49 J. ECON. HIST. 361, 365 (1989) (explaining the early evolution of automobile industry).
    • (1989) 49 J. ECON. HIST. , vol.361 , pp. 365
    • Langlois, R.N.1    Robertson, P.L.2
  • 90
    • 77953049595 scopus 로고
    • International harvester
    • See generally, Aug.
    • See generally International Harvester, FORTUNE, Aug. 1933, at 21.
    • (1933) FORTUNE , pp. 21
  • 91
    • 0004321711 scopus 로고
    • (2d ed.), (relating the offenses to Medieval price-control policies)
    • See 4 WILLIAM S. HOLDSWORTH, A HISTORY OF ENGLISH LAW 375-79 (2d ed. 1937) (relating the offenses to Medieval price-control policies);
    • (1937) A HISTORY OF ENGLISH LAW 375-79
    • Holdsworth, W.S.1
  • 92
    • 54049087211 scopus 로고
    • Forestalling, regrating and engrossing
    • (discussing relevant eighteenth-century evenis). Technically, the crime of regrating involved the purchasing of commodities from their producers and then reselling them within four miles from the point of purchase. Id. at 377.
    • Wendell Herbruck, Forestalling, Regrating and Engrossing, 27 MICH. L. REV. 365, 378-80 (1929) (discussing relevant eighteenth-century evenis). Technically, the crime of regrating involved the purchasing of commodities from their producers and then reselling them within four miles from the point of purchase. Id. at 377.
    • (1929) MICH. L. REV. , vol.27 , pp. 365
    • Herbruck, W.1
  • 94
    • 77953076197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 27 Edw. 3, c. 3, § 2 (1353) (Eng.) (death penalty for forestalling), repealed by 38 Edw. 3, c. 6, § 1 (1363) (Eng.)
    • 27 Edw. 3, c. 3, § 2 (1353) (Eng.) (death penalty for forestalling), repealed by 38 Edw. 3, c. 6, § 1 (1363) (Eng.).
  • 96
    • 77953073774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 62
    • See Herbruck, supra note 62, at 367-79.
    • Herbruck1
  • 97
    • 77953070775 scopus 로고
    • See e.g., Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 346, (condemning a vertical merger by clearly non-dominant firms)
    • See e.g., Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 346 (1962) (condemning a vertical merger by clearly non-dominant firms).
    • (1962)
  • 98
    • 77953065653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 44, at 335-60;
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 44, at 335-60;
    • Hovenkamp1
  • 99
  • 100
    • 0039316717 scopus 로고
    • The classical corporation in American legal thought
    • 1687
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Classical Corporation in American Legal Thought, 76 GEO. L.J. 1593, 1669-70, 1687 (1988).
    • (1988) 76 GEO. L.J. , vol.1593 , pp. 1669-1670
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 101
    • 77953062659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 82-85
    • See infra text accompanying notes 82-85.
  • 102
    • 77953038334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On this point, see 1, supra note 55, ¶ 102
    • On this point, see 1 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 55, ¶ 102.
    • Areeda1    Hovenkamp2
  • 103
    • 77953053978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clayton Act, ch. 323, § 7,38 Stat 730 (1914) (current version at 15 U.S.G § 18)
    • Clayton Act, ch. 323, § 7,38 Stat 730 (1914) (current version at 15 U.S.G § 18 (2006)).
    • (2006)
  • 104
    • 77953075465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 82-84
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 82-84.
  • 105
    • 0004210414 scopus 로고
    • For an excellent survey of the political environment at the time, see generally
    • For an excellent survey of the political environment at the time, see generally JOSEPH C. PALAMOUNTAIN JR., The Politics of Distribution (1955).
    • (1955) The Politics of Distribution
    • Palamountain Jr., J.C.1
  • 106
    • 0345839622 scopus 로고
    • (describing the background of the Act); Hugh C. Hansen, Robinson-Potman Law: A Review and Analysis, 51 FORDHAM L. Rev. 1113, 1119 n.33 (1983) (explaining that the counsel for the U.S. Wholesale Grocers' Association "is credited with drafting most of the Act")
    • See FREDERICK M. ROWE, PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER THE ROBINSON-PATMAN ACT 3-25 (1962) (describing the background of the Act); Hugh C. Hansen, Robinson-Potman Law: A Review and Analysis, 51 FORDHAM L. Rev. 1113, 1119 n.33 (1983) (explaining that the counsel for the U.S. Wholesale Grocers' Association "is credited with drafting most of the Act").
    • (1962) PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER THE ROBINSON-PATMAN ACT 3-25
  • 107
    • 77953065369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Ark. Wholesale Grocers' Ass'n v. FTC, 18 F.2d 866 (8th Cir. 1927) (condemning the grocers' association boycott of suppliers who sold to chain-store retailers at the same price as they sold to the defendant wholesalers, thus limiting the latter's markup and placing their own purchaser/retailers at a disadvantage)
    • See generally Ark. Wholesale Grocers' Ass'n v. FTC, 18 F.2d 866 (8th Cir. 1927) (condemning the grocers' association boycott of suppliers who sold to chain-store retailers at the same price as they sold to the defendant wholesalers, thus limiting the latter's markup and placing their own purchaser/retailers at a disadvantage);
  • 108
    • 22544452104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The anti-chain store movement, localist ideology, and the remnants of the progressive constitution, 1920-1940
    • United States v. S. Cal. Wholesale Grocers' Ass'n, 7 F.2d 944 (S.D. Cal. 1925) (similar Justice Department suit). Much of the history is recounted in
    • United States v. S. Cal. Wholesale Grocers' Ass'n, 7 F.2d 944 (S.D. Cal. 1925) (similar Justice Department suit). Much of the history is recounted in Richard C. Schragger, The Anti-Chain Store Movement, Localist Ideology, and the Remnants of the Progressive Constitution, 1920-1940, 90 IOWA L. REV. 1011 (2005).
    • (2005) 90 IOWA L. REV. , vol.1011
    • Schragger, R.C.1
  • 109
    • 77953065368 scopus 로고
    • Natural Industrial Recovery Act, ch. 90, 48 Stat 195 (1933), invalidated by A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495
    • Natural Industrial Recovery Act, ch. 90, 48 Stat 195 (1933), invalidated by A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935).
    • (1935)
  • 110
    • 77953056926 scopus 로고
    • See Amendment to the Antitrust Laws, ch. 690, 50 Stat. 693 (creating a "fair trade" exemption from the Sherman Act)
    • See Amendment to the Antitrust Laws, ch. 690, 50 Stat. 693 (1937) (creating a "fair trade" exemption from the Sherman Act);
    • (1937)
  • 111
    • 77953061096 scopus 로고
    • Act of July 14, 1952, ch. 745, 66 Stat. 631 (adding the exemption to the Federal Trade Commission Act)
    • Act of July 14, 1952, ch. 745, 66 Stat. 631 (1952) (adding the exemption to the Federal Trade Commission Act).
    • (1952)
  • 112
    • 77953052655 scopus 로고
    • (discussing various taxes levied against chain stores in the)
    • See PALAMOUNTAIN, supra note 74, at 159-87 (discussing various taxes levied against chain stores in the 1930s);
    • (1930) , pp. 159-187
    • Palamountain1
  • 113
    • 77953032899 scopus 로고
    • Louis K. Ugett Co. v. Lee, 288 U.S. 517, 540-41, (upholding a state tax that was graduated according to the number of stores a firm owned)
    • see also Louis K. Ugett Co. v. Lee, 288 U.S. 517, 540-41 (1933) (upholding a state tax that was graduated according to the number of stores a firm owned);
    • (1933)
  • 114
    • 0011027414 scopus 로고
    • (3d ed.) (discussing the chain taxes enacted in many states during the 1920s through the 1940s as well as various other anti-chain legislation from that time period)
    • Godfrey M. Lebhar, Chain Stores in America, 1859-1962, at 125-55 (3d ed. 1963) (discussing the chain taxes enacted in many states during the 1920s through the 1940s as well as various other anti-chain legislation from that time period);
    • (1963) Chain Stores in America, 1859-1962 , pp. 125-155
    • Lebhar, G.M.1
  • 115
    • 77953053448 scopus 로고
    • Food distribution in the United States, the struggle between independents and chains
    • (discussing the local backlash to the growth of chain grocers and the state-chain-tax movement during the early 1930s)
    • Carl H. Fulda, Food Distribution in the United States, the Struggle Between Independents and Chains, 99 U. Pa. L. REV. 1051, 1076-82 (1951) (discussing the local backlash to the growth of chain grocers and the state-chain-tax movement during the early 1930s);
    • (1951) 99 U. PA. L. REV. , vol.1051 , pp. 1076-1082
    • Fulda, C.H.1
  • 116
    • 77953064338 scopus 로고
    • Store wars: The chain tax movement
    • (discussing certain economic variables that led some states to introduce franchise taxes and explaining why they did not have a major long-term impact)
    • Thomas W. Ross, Store Wars: The Chain Tax Movement, 29 J.L. & ECON. 125, 137 (1986) (discussing certain economic variables that led some states to introduce franchise taxes and explaining why they did not have a major long-term impact).
    • (1986) 29 J.L. & ECON. , vol.125 , pp. 137
    • Ross, T.W.1
  • 117
    • 0035649367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The choice of organizational form in gasoline retailing and the cost of laws that limit that choice
    • (discussing the introduction of state divorcement legislation, as well as other legislation and litigation aimed at limiting refiner-owned gas stations)
    • See Asher A. Blass & Dennis W. Carlton, The Choice of Organizational Form in Gasoline Retailing and the Cost of Laws that Limit that Choice, 44 J.L. & ECON. 511, 511-12 (2001) (discussing the introduction of state divorcement legislation, as well as other legislation and litigation aimed at limiting refiner-owned gas stations);
    • (2001) 44 J.L. & ECON. , vol.511 , pp. 511-512
    • Blass, A.A.1    Carlton, D.W.2
  • 118
    • 0034369347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulatory restrictions on vertical integration and control: The competitive impact of gasoline divorcement policies
    • (discussing the history and purpose of divorcement legislation)
    • Michael G. Vita, Regulatory Restrictions on Vertical Integration and Control: The Competitive Impact of Gasoline Divorcement Policies, 18 J. REG. ECON. 217,217-18 (2000) (discussing the history and purpose of divorcement legislation).
    • (2000) 18 J. REG. ECON. , vol.217 , pp. 217-218
    • Vita, M.G.1
  • 120
    • 77953067261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Case history of the American business franchise
    • (discussing Congress's reasons for passing the Automobile Dealers Day in Court Act)
    • see also David Gumick & Steve Vieux, Case History of the American Business Franchise, 24 OKLA. CITY. U. L. REV. 37, 54-55 (1999) (discussing Congress's reasons for passing the Automobile Dealers Day in Court Act).
    • (1999) 24 OKLA. CITY. U. L. REV. , vol.37 , pp. 54-55
    • Gumick, D.1    Vieux, S.2
  • 121
    • 0043150533 scopus 로고
    • Section 7 of the clayton act and the merging of law and economics
    • (discussing the broad range of anticompetitive influences under which Congress amended section seven of the Clayton Act)
    • See Derek C. Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 HARV. L. Rev. 226, 234-36 (1960) (discussing the broad range of anticompetitive influences under which Congress amended section seven of the Clayton Act);
    • (1960) 74 HARV. L. Rev. , vol.226 , pp. 234-236
    • Bok, D.C.1
  • 122
    • 0347100903 scopus 로고
    • Derek bok and the merger of law and economics
    • (discussing the anticompetitive political influence present in the legislative history of Congress's amendment of section seven of the Clayton Act and Bok's response thereto)
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics, 21 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM 515, 524-28 (1988) (discussing the anticompetitive political influence present in the legislative history of Congress's amendment of section seven of the Clayton Act and Bok's response thereto).
    • (1988) 21 U. MICH. J.L. REFORM , vol.515 , pp. 524-528
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 123
    • 77953078378 scopus 로고
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962).
    • (1962)
  • 124
    • 77954645522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IP and antitrust: Reformation and harm
    • United States v. Brown Shoe Co., 179 F. Supp. 721, 738 (E.D. Mo. 1959). The Federal Trade Commission took the same position. See In re Foremost Dairies, Inc., 60 F.T.C. 944, 1084 (1962) (concluding that efficiencies resulting from a merger were bad because they gave post-merger firms a "decisive advantage ⋯ over ⋯ smaller rivals"). On the Brown Shoe decision and the subsequent revolution in antitrust policy
    • United States v. Brown Shoe Co., 179 F. Supp. 721, 738 (E.D. Mo. 1959). The Federal Trade Commission took the same position. See In re Foremost Dairies, Inc., 60 F.T.C. 944, 1084 (1962) (concluding that efficiencies resulting from a merger were bad because they gave post-merger firms a "decisive advantage ⋯ over ⋯ smaller rivals"). On the Brown Shoe decision and the subsequent revolution in antitrust policy, see Christina Bohannan & Herbert Hovenkamp, IP and Antitrust: Reformation and Harm, 51 B.C. L. REV. (forthcoming 2010).
    • (2010) 51 B.C. L. REV.
    • Bohannan, C.1    Hovenkamp, H.2
  • 125
    • 77953078067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416,429 (2d Cir. 1945) ("Throughout the history of these statutes it has been constantly assumed that one of their purposes was to perpetuate and preserve, for its own sake and in spite of possible cost, an organization of industry in small units which can effectively compete with each other.")
    • United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F.2d 416,429 (2d Cir. 1945) ("Throughout the history of these statutes it has been constantly assumed that one of their purposes was to perpetuate and preserve, for its own sake and in spite of possible cost, an organization of industry in small units which can effectively compete with each other.").
  • 126
    • 84928841903 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of substantive due process
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 397 (1911) (condemning resale-price-maintenance contracts); Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 59 (1905) (striking down the maximum-hours provision applied to bakers). Justice Holmes dissented in both cases, (discussing the effect of the Fourteenth Amendment)
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 397 (1911) (condemning resale-price-maintenance contracts); Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 59 (1905) (striking down the maximum-hours provision applied to bakers). Justice Holmes dissented in both cases. See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Political Economy of Substantive Due Process, 40 STAN. L. REV. 379, 395-98 (1988) (discussing the effect of the Fourteenth Amendment).
    • (1988) 40 STAN. L. REV. , vol.379 , pp. 395-98
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 127
    • 77953049598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 98, 100 (discussing why legal policy was so hostile towards vertical agreements)
    • See infra text accompanying notes 98, 100 (discussing why legal policy was so hostile towards vertical agreements).
  • 128
    • 77953030934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 14, at
    • Coase, supra note 14, at 394-95.
    • Coase1
  • 129
    • 0000589044 scopus 로고
    • Production, information costs, and economic organization
    • For an example of this view
    • For an example of this view, see Armen A. Alchian & Harold Demsetz, Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, 62 AM. ECON. REV. 777, 794 (1972).
    • (1972) 62 AM. ECON. REV. , vol.777 , pp. 794
    • Alchian, A.A.1    Demsetz, H.2
  • 130
    • 24044435412 scopus 로고
    • The theory of the firm revisited
    • (stating that greater weight must be given to information costs in order to create a more complete theory of the firm)
    • See also Harold Demsetz, The Theory of the Firm Revisited, in OWNERSHIP, CONTROL, and THE FIRM: ORGANIZATION OF ECONOMIC AcnviTV 144, 147 (1990) (stating that greater weight must be given to information costs in order to create a more complete theory of the firm).
    • (1990) OWNERSHIP, CONTROL, and THE FIRM: ORGANIZATION OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY , vol.144 , pp. 147
    • Demsetz, H.1
  • 131
    • 77953076747 scopus 로고
    • Cf. Henry v. A.B. Dick Co., 224 U.S. 1, 31, (declining to apply the firt-sale doctrine to A.B. Dick's tying of its paper, ink, and stencils to the use of its patented mimeograph machine)
    • Cf. Henry v. A.B. Dick Co., 224 U.S. 1, 31 (1912) (declining to apply the firt-sale doctrine to A.B. Dick's tying of its paper, ink, and stencils to the use of its patented mimeograph machine).
    • (1912)
  • 132
    • 77953057453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra text accompanying notes 195-97
    • See infra text accompanying notes 195-97.
  • 133
    • 77953039974 scopus 로고
    • Standard Oil Co. of Gal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 316, (Douglas, J., dissenting)
    • Standard Oil Co. of Gal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 316 (1949) (Douglas, J., dissenting).
    • (1949)
  • 134
    • 77953066447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 135
    • 0041149049 scopus 로고
    • Id. at 318-20. Douglas was referring to, (Osmond K. Fraenkel ed.)
    • Id. at 318-20. Douglas was referring to LOUIS D. BRANDEIS, THE CURSE OF BIGNESS (Osmond K. Fraenkel ed., 1934).
    • (1934) THE CURSE OF BIGNESS
    • Brandeis, L.D.1
  • 137
    • 77953073503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 334-38
    • Id. at 334-38.
  • 138
    • 77953030935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 375,499
    • Id. at 375,499.
  • 139
    • 77953076748 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 499
    • Id. at 499.
  • 141
    • 77953047346 scopus 로고
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373,405,409
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373,405,409 (1911).
    • (1911)
  • 142
    • 77953040546 scopus 로고
    • 55 U.S. (14 How.) ("[W]hen the machine passes to the hands of the purchaser, it is no longer within the limits of the [patent] monopoly.'')
    • Bloomer v. McQuewan, 55 U.S. (14 How.) 539, 549 (1853) ("[W]hen the machine passes to the hands of the purchaser, it is no longer within the limits of the [patent] monopoly.'').
    • (1853) , vol.539 , pp. 549
    • Bloomer1    McQuewan2
  • 143
    • 77953055870 scopus 로고
    • 84 U.S. (17 Wall.) 460
    • Adams v. Burke, 84 U.S. (17 Wall.) 453,460 (1873).
    • (1873) , pp. 453
    • Adams1    Burke2
  • 144
    • 77953049313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 457.
  • 145
    • 77953074332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 128 S. Cl 2109, reaffirming a broad first-sale rule for patents
    • See Quanta Computer, Inc. v. LG Elec., Inc., 128 S. Cl 2109, 2117 (2008) (reaffirming a broad first-sale rule for patents).
    • (2008) Quanta Computer, Inc. v. LG Elec., Inc. , pp. 2117
  • 146
    • 77953058292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note characterizing the first-sale doctrine as a common-law property rule
    • See generally GRAY, supra note 99 (characterizing the first-sale doctrine as a common-law property rule).
    • Gray1
  • 147
    • 77953070150 scopus 로고
    • Earl of Huntington v. Lord Mountjoy (Mountjoy's Case), (C.P.D.) (holding that an easement in gross could be divided only if co-owners operated it as "one stock"). The rule was followed in the United States in Miller v. Lutheran Conference & Camp Ass'n, 200 A. 646, 652 (Pa. 1938) (granting a recreational license to use lake required "common consent" by co-owners in partnership)
    • See Earl of Huntington v. Lord Mountjoy (Mountjoy's Case), (1583) 123 Eng. Rep. 488 (C.P.D.) (holding that an easement in gross could be divided only if co-owners operated it as "one stock"). The rule was followed in the United States in Miller v. Lutheran Conference & Camp Ass'n, 200 A. 646, 652 (Pa. 1938) (granting a recreational license to use lake required "common consent" by co-owners in partnership).
    • (1583) 123 Eng. Rep. , pp. 488
  • 148
    • 77953060813 scopus 로고
    • 254 S.W.2d 701 (Ky) (holding that an owner of an easement benefiting a defined parcel of land could divide the parcel and each co-owner could share the easement)
    • E.g., Martin v. Music, 254 S.W.2d 701 (Ky. 1953) (holding that an owner of an easement benefiting a defined parcel of land could divide the parcel and each co-owner could share the easement).
    • (1953)
    • Martin1    Music2
  • 150
    • 77953078997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • discussion infra text accompanying notes
    • See discussion infra text accompanying notes 112-13.
  • 151
    • 77953036622 scopus 로고
    • 210 U.S. 339
    • Bobbs-Merrill Co. v. Straus, 210 U.S. 339,349-51 (1908).
    • (1908) , pp. 349-51
    • Bobbs-Merrill, C.1    Straus2
  • 152
    • 77953079772 scopus 로고
    • Halue Erminie Rives,The Castaway
    • Halue Erminie Rives,The Castaway (1904).
    • (1904)
  • 153
    • 77953039148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 210 U.S.
    • Bobbs-Merrill Co. v. Straw, 210 US. 339,349-51(1908).
    • Bcbbs-MertM, C.1
  • 154
    • 77953080318 scopus 로고
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, The Court was referring to Lord Chief Justice Edward Coke's Commentary upon Littleton (1628), typically cited as Coke on Littleton, which was Volume 1 of Coke's Institutes of the Lowes of England. That volume was a largely verbatim copy of Sir Thomas Littleton's Tenures, first printed in 1481 or 1482. The Court quoted the following: [That if someone] be possessed of a horse or any other chattel, real or personal, and give his whole interest, or property therein, upon condition that the donee or vendee shall not alien the same, the same is void, because his whole interest and property is out of him, so as he hath no possibility of reverter; and it is against trade and traffic and bargaining and contracting between man and man
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 404-05 (1911). The Court was referring to Lord Chief Justice Edward Coke's Commentary upon Littleton (1628), typically cited as Coke on Littleton, which was Volume 1 of Coke's Institutes of the Lowes of England. That volume was a largely verbatim copy of Sir Thomas Littleton's Tenures, first printed in 1481 or 1482. The Court quoted the following: "' [That if someone] be possessed of a horse or any other chattel, real or personal, and give his whole interest, or property therein, upon condition that the donee or vendee shall not alien the same, the same is void, because his whole interest and property is out of him, so as he hath no possibility of reverter; and it is against trade and traffic and bargaining and contracting between man and man.'"
    • (1911) , pp. 404-05
  • 155
    • 77953059677 scopus 로고
    • Dr. Miles, 220 U.S. at quotingjohn D. Park & Sons Co. v. Hartman, 153 F. 24, 42 (6th Cir) (referencing 1 COKE ON LITTLETON bk. 3, ch. 5, § 360, at 223 (n.p. 1628))). The Court also referenced John Chipman Gray's Restraints on Alienation of Property. See supra note 99 and accompanying text Gray's book never mentioned patented or copyrighted goods. GRAY, supra note 99
    • Dr. Miles, 220 U.S. at 404-05 (quotingjohn D. Park & Sons Co. v. Hartman, 153 F. 24, 42 (6th Cir. 1907) (referencing 1 COKE ON LITTLETON bk. 3, ch. 5, § 360, at 223 (n.p. 1628))). The Court also referenced John Chipman Gray's Restraints on Alienation of Property. See supra note 99 and accompanying text Gray's book never mentioned patented or copyrighted goods. GRAY, supra note 99.
    • (1907) , pp. 404-05
  • 156
    • 77953071026 scopus 로고
    • note
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365, 380 (1967) ("But to allow this freedom where the manufacturer has parted with dominion over the goods-the usual marketing situation-would violate the ancient rule against restraints on alienation and open the door to exclusivity of outlets and limitation of territory further than prudence permits."). The dissent cited Coke on Littleton and accused the majority of embracing a legal rule "merely on grounds of its antiquity." Id. at 391 (Stewart, J., dissenting in part).
    • (1967) , pp. 380
  • 157
    • 77953053205 scopus 로고
    • 433 U.S. 36 (White, J., concurring)
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 67-68 (1977) (White, J., concurring).
    • (1977) Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc. , pp. 67-68
    • Cont'l, T.V.1
  • 158
    • 77953080319 scopus 로고
    • DickCo.,224U.S. 1
    • Henryv.A.B.DickCo.,224U.S. 1,11-12 (1912).
    • (1912) , pp. 11-12
    • Henryv, A.B.1
  • 159
    • 77953032001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 7d.at46
    • 7d.at46.
  • 160
    • 77953063212 scopus 로고
    • Motion Picture Patents Co. v. Universal Film Mfg. Co., 243 U.S. 502, On the centrality of this decision to both the antitrust law of contractual vertical integration and the developing doctrine of patent "misuse,'' see Christina Bohannan, IP Misuse as Foreclosure 4-6 (Univ. of Iowa Legal Studies, Working Paper No. 0941, 2009)
    • Motion Picture Patents Co. v. Universal Film Mfg. Co., 243 U.S. 502, 518-19 (1917). On the centrality of this decision to both the antitrust law of contractual vertical integration and the developing doctrine of patent "misuse,'' see Christina Bohannan, IP Misuse as Foreclosure 4-6 (Univ. of Iowa Legal Studies, Working Paper No. 0941, 2009), available at http://ssm.com/ sol3/papers.cfin?abstract=1474407.
    • (1917) , pp. 518-519
  • 161
    • 77953055044 scopus 로고
    • While not the earliest inventor, Edison was one of the earliest commercial developers of the sprocketed-projector take-up wheel and film with little holes on the side that engaged the sprocket, thus permitting the film to run smoothly and eliminating the jerkiness that often appeared in very early motion pictures. Ownership of the technology itself was disputed. See Charles Musser, The Emergence of Cinema: The American Screen to 1907
    • While not the earliest inventor, Edison was one of the earliest commercial developers of the sprocketed-projector take-up wheel and film with little holes on the side that engaged the sprocket, thus permitting the film to run smoothly and eliminating the jerkiness that often appeared in very early motion pictures. Ownership of the technology itself was disputed. See Charles Musser, The Emergence of Cinema: The American Screen to 1907, at 130-80 (1994).
    • (1994) , pp. 130-80
  • 165
    • 77953043299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Motion Picture Patents Co., 243U.S.
    • Motion Picture Patents Co., 243U.S. at 516.
  • 166
    • 77953040545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 118, at (describing the origins of the misuse doctrine)
    • Bohannan, supra note 118, at 4-5 (describing the origins of the misuse doctrine).
    • Bohannan1
  • 167
    • 0043079963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Classical contract theory reached its apex in
    • Classical contract theory reached its apex in Samuel Williston's treatise, The Law of Contracts.
    • The Law of Contracts
    • Williston's, S.1
  • 170
    • 77953064067 scopus 로고
    • Nonlegal sanctions in commercial relationships
    • David Chamey, Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships, 104 HARV. L. Rev. 373, 392-93 (1990);
    • (1990) 104 Harv. L. Rev. 373 , pp. 392-93
    • Chamey, D.1
  • 172
    • 0000073663 scopus 로고
    • Contracts: Adjustment of long-term economic relations under classical, neoclassical, and relational contract law
    • Ian R. MacNeil, Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations Under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law, 72 Nw. U. L. REV. 854,857 (1978).
    • (1978) 72 Nw. U. L. Rev. 854 , pp. 857
    • MacNeil, I.R.1
  • 173
    • 77953058818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • sources cited supra note 123 (describing classical contract law and legal thought); cf. Stewart Macaulay, Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 Am. SOC. Rev. 55, 62 (1963) ("[Relatively contractual methods are used to make adjustments in ongoing transactions and to settle disputes.")
    • See sources cited supra note 123 (describing classical contract law and legal thought); cf. Stewart Macaulay, Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28 Am. SOC. Rev. 55, 62 (1963) ("[Relatively contractual methods are used to make adjustments in ongoing transactions and to settle disputes.").
  • 174
    • 77953031489 scopus 로고
    • 57 U.S. (16 How.) 479, (describing the arrangement). McCormick later changed to a more centralized distribution system with wholly owned outlets. On the company's history, see CHANDLER, supra note 95, at 305-07, 402-08 (discussing the company's success in using a centralized distribution system), and DlCKE, supra note 81, at 18-19 (same)
    • See Seymour v. McCormick, 57 U.S. (16 How.) 479, 490 (1854) (describing the arrangement). McCormick later changed to a more centralized distribution system with wholly owned outlets. On the company's history, see CHANDLER, supra note 95, at 305-07, 402-08 (discussing the company's success in using a centralized distribution system), and DlCKE, supra note 81, at 18-19 (same).
    • (1854) Bureaucracy And The Labor Process: The Transformation of U.S. Industry, 1860-1920 , pp. 490
    • Clawson, D.1
  • 175
    • 0043243961 scopus 로고
    • dark solved the problem by taking McCormick's idea several stages further. 'Why not rent a sewing machine to the housewife and apply the rental fee to the purchase price of the machine?'"); Andrew B. Jack, The Channels of Distribution for an Innovation: The Sewing-Machine Industry in America, 1860-1865, 9 EXPLORATIONS IN ENTREPRENEURIAL HIST. 113, 114 (1957) (discussing the successful launch of the Wheeler & Wilson Co., the Grover and Backer Co., and I.M. Singer & Co
    • Ruth Brandon, A Capitalist Romance: Singer and the Sewing Machine 117 (1977) ("dark solved the problem by taking McCormick's idea several stages further. 'Why not rent a sewing machine to the housewife and apply the rental fee to the purchase price of the machine?'"); Andrew B. Jack, The Channels of Distribution for an Innovation: The Sewing-Machine Industry in America, 1860-1865, 9 EXPLORATIONS IN ENTREPRENEURIAL HIST. 113, 114 (1957) (discussing the successful launch of the Wheeler & Wilson Co., the Grover and Backer Co., and I.M. Singer & Co.).
    • (1977) A Capitalist Romance: Singer and the Sewing Machine , pp. 117
    • Brandon, R.1
  • 176
    • 77953041944 scopus 로고
    • 84 U.S. (17WaU.) 453, For a fuller statement of the facts, see generally Adams v. Burks, 1 F. Cas. 100 (CC.D. Mass. 1871) (No. 50)
    • See Adams v. Burke, 84 U.S. (17WaU.) 453,457 (1873). For a fuller statement of the facts, see generally Adams v. Burks, 1 F. Cas. 100 (CC.D. Mass. 1871) (No. 50).
    • (1873) , pp. 457
    • Adams1    Burke2
  • 177
    • 77953075933 scopus 로고
    • 22 F. 434, (C.C. Pa). Contra McKay v. Wooster, 16 F. Cas. 183,185 (C.C.D. Cal. 1873) (No. 8847) (permitting good, a patented container for transporting eggs, to be resold in exclusive territory of a different licensee, but relying on construction of grant language rather than first-sale rule)
    • Hatch v. Adams, 22 F. 434, 438 (C.C. Pa. 1884). Contra McKay v. Wooster, 16 F. Cas. 183,185 (C.C.D. Cal. 1873) (No. 8847) (permitting good, a patented container for transporting eggs, to be resold in exclusive territory of a different licensee, but relying on construction of grant language rather than first-sale rule).
    • (1884) , pp. 438
    • Hatch1    Adams2
  • 178
    • 77953044730 scopus 로고
    • Franchising-changing legal skirmish lines or armageddon? Some observations from the foxhole
    • Norman D. Axelrad, Franchising-Changing Legal Skirmish Lines or Armageddon? Some Observations from the Foxhole, 26 BUS. LAW. 695, 699 (1971);
    • (1971) 26 Bus. Law. 695 , pp. 699
    • Axelrad, N.D.1
  • 179
    • 77953041943 scopus 로고
    • 246 F. 764, 768 (5th Cir) (finding an open-ended agreement requiring Dodge to sell automobiles to franchisee not void for lack of mutuality). On the Ford Motor Company's early experiences, see DlCKE, supra note 81
    • see also Ellis v. Dodge Bros., 246 F. 764, 768 (5th Cir. 1917) (finding an open-ended agreement requiring Dodge to sell automobiles to franchisee not void for lack of mutuality). On the Ford Motor Company's early experiences, see DlCKE, supra note 81, at 59-74.
    • (1917) , pp. 59-74
    • Ellis1    Dodge, Bros.2
  • 180
    • 77953034556 scopus 로고
    • (Martin Mendelsohn ed.) (discussing that major franchising growth occurred after World War II)
    • See MARTIN MENDELSOHN, INTERNATIONAL FRANCHISING: AN OVERVIEW 4-5 (Martin Mendelsohn ed., 1984) (discussing that major franchising growth occurred after World War II).
    • (1984) International Franchising: An Overview , pp. 4-5
    • Mendelsohn, M.1
  • 182
  • 183
    • 77953061379 scopus 로고
    • Oscar Schlegel Mfg. Co. v. Peter Cooper's Glue Factory, 132 N.E. 148, (N.Y.) (holding a contract invalid where it imposed no obligations on buyer)
    • See, e.g., Oscar Schlegel Mfg. Co. v. Peter Cooper's Glue Factory, 132 N.E. 148, 149 (N.Y. 1921) (holding a contract invalid where it imposed no obligations on buyer).
    • (1921) , pp. 149
  • 184
    • 77953030129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 246 F. at (holding a contract valid as to mutuality where buyer had to meet requirements); E.C. Dailey Co. v. Clark Can Co., 87 N.W. 761, 762 (Mich. 1901) (upholding a contract where buyer could only purchase requirements from seller)
    • See, e.g., Ellis, 246 F. at 766-67 (holding a contract valid as to mutuality where buyer had to meet requirements); E.C. Dailey Co. v. Clark Can Co., 87 N.W. 761, 762 (Mich. 1901) (upholding a contract where buyer could only purchase requirements from seller).
    • Ellis1
  • 185
    • 77953044087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hufftnan v. Paige-Detroit Motor Car Co., 262 F. 116, (8th dr. 1919) (holding an open-ended franchise contract terminable at will for insufficient mutuality of obligation)
    • See, e.g., Hufftnan v. Paige-Detroit Motor Car Co., 262 F. 116, 116 (8th dr. 1919) (holding an open-ended franchise contract terminable at will for insufficient mutuality of obligation);
  • 186
    • 77953042740 scopus 로고
    • Oakland Motor Car Co. v. Ind. Auto. Co., 201 F. 499, (7th Cir.) (holding that a contractual provision allowing cancellation for just cause was too indefinite to be valid)
    • Oakland Motor Car Co. v. Ind. Auto. Co., 201 F. 499, 499-500 (7th Cir. 1912) (holding that a contractual provision allowing cancellation for just cause was too indefinite to be valid).
    • (1912) , pp. 499-500
  • 187
    • 77953033468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moon Motor Car Co. of N.Y. v. Moon Motor Car Co., 29 F.2d 3, 4 (2d Cir. 1928) (holding that the contract had sufficient mutuality of obligation and distinguishing Huffman and Oakland)
    • But see Moon Motor Car Co. of N.Y. v. Moon Motor Car Co., 29 F.2d 3, 4 (2d Cir. 1928) (holding that the contract had sufficient mutuality of obligation and distinguishing Huffman and Oakland).
  • 188
    • 53249087383 scopus 로고
    • The effect of options on consideration
    • discussing lack of mutuality in open-ended franchise agreements)
    • See also Arthur L. Corbin, The Effect of Options on Consideration, 34 YALE L.J. 571, 586 (1925) (discussing lack of mutuality in open-ended franchise agreements);
    • (1925) 34 Yale L.J. 571 , pp. 586
    • Corbin, A.L.1
  • 189
    • 77953075170 scopus 로고
    • Options and consideration in automobile dealership agreements
    • (examining courts' refusal to grant relief in open-ended franchise contracts)
    • Note, Options and Consideration in Automobile Dealership Agreements, 22 Va. L. REV. 324, 324 (1936) (examining courts' refusal to grant relief in open-ended franchise contracts).
    • (1936) 22 Va. L. Rev. 324 , pp. 324
  • 190
    • 77953065652 scopus 로고
    • Buick Motor Co. v. Thompson, 75 S.E. 354
    • E.g, Buick Motor Co. v. Thompson, 75 S.E. 354, 356 (Ga. 1912);
    • (1912) , pp. 356
  • 191
    • 77953057176 scopus 로고
    • Erskine v. Chevrolet Motors Co., 117 S.E. 706, (asserting the importance of information costs)
    • see also Erskine v. Chevrolet Motors Co., 117 S.E. 706, 710 (N.C. 1923) (asserting the importance of information costs).
    • (1923) , vol.710
  • 192
    • 77953037419 scopus 로고
    • Buggs v. Ford Motor Co., 113 F.2d 618 (7th Cir.), cert, denied, 311 U.S.
    • E.g., Buggs v. Ford Motor Co., 113 F.2d 618 (7th Cir.), cert, denied, 311 U.S. 688 (1940).
    • (1940) , pp. 688
  • 193
    • 77953071025 scopus 로고
    • Ford Motor Co. v. Kirkmyer Motor Co., 65 F.2d 1001
    • Ford Motor Co. v. Kirkmyer Motor Co., 65 F.2d 1001, 1006 (4th Cir. 1933);
    • (1933) , pp. 1006
  • 194
    • 77953052939 scopus 로고
    • 116 F.2d 675, (2d Cir.) (noting the problem of adhesion contracts, but refusing to address it judicially in the absence of legislation)
    • see also Bushwick-Decatur Motors, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 116 F.2d 675, 677 (2d Cir. 1940) (noting the problem of adhesion contracts, but refusing to address it judicially in the absence of legislation).
    • (1940) Inc. v. Ford Motor Co. , pp. 677
    • Motors, B.-D.1
  • 195
    • 77953066178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. §
    • 15 U.S.C. § 14 (2006).
    • (2006) , pp. 14
  • 196
    • 77953068297 scopus 로고
    • On the congressional concern, see H.R. REP. No. 63-1168
    • On the congressional concern, see H.R. REP. No. 63-1168, at 11-12 (1914).
    • (1914) , pp. 11-12
  • 197
    • 77953058289 scopus 로고
    • Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston Co., 258 U.S. The common law generally refused to condemn such arrangements. See, e.g., Chi., St Louis & New Orleans R.R. Co. v. Pullman S. Car Co., 139 U.S. 79, 89-91 (1891) (applying the common law and upholding exclusive-dealing agreement in Pullman sleeping cars); Brown v. Rounsavell, 78 111. 589, 590 (1875) (upholding a merchant's agreement to deal exclusively in seller's sewing machines and accessories in exchange for a thirty-percent discount)
    • Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane-Houston Co., 258 U.S. 346, 355-57 (1922). The common law generally refused to condemn such arrangements. See, e.g., Chi., St Louis & New Orleans R.R. Co. v. Pullman S. Car Co., 139 U.S. 79, 89-91 (1891) (applying the common law and upholding exclusive-dealing agreement in Pullman sleeping cars); Brown v. Rounsavell, 78 111. 589, 590 (1875) (upholding a merchant's agreement to deal exclusively in seller's sewing machines and accessories in exchange for a thirty-percent discount).
    • (1922) , vol.346 , pp. 355-57
  • 198
    • 77953069618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Standard Fashion Co., 258 U.S.
    • Standard Fashion Co., 258 U.S. at 351-53.
  • 199
    • 77953074898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id. at 357.
  • 200
    • 77953071602 scopus 로고
    • Standard Oil Co. of N.Y. v. Fed. Trade Comtn'n, 273 F. The Supreme Court agreed with the Second Circuit in Federal Trade Commission v. Sinclair Co., 261 U.S. 463 (1923). See also DlCKE, supra note 81, at 85-86, 115 (discussing the history of gasoline franchising)
    • Standard Oil Co. of N.Y. v. Fed. Trade Comtn'n, 273 F. 478, 480 (2d Cir. 1921). The Supreme Court agreed with the Second Circuit in Federal Trade Commission v. Sinclair Co., 261 U.S. 463 (1923). See also DlCKE, supra note 81, at 85-86, 115 (discussing the history of gasoline franchising).
    • (1921) , pp. 478-480
  • 201
    • 77953056389 scopus 로고
    • Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, (applying aggressive antitrust rules to gasoline exclusive dealing even though the covered market shares were relatively small)
    • See, e.g., Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 302 (1949) (applying aggressive antitrust rules to gasoline exclusive dealing even though the covered market shares were relatively small);
    • (1949) , pp. 302
  • 202
    • 77953029331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 82-84 and accompanying text
    • see supra notes 82-84 and accompanying text.
  • 203
    • 77953072967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • prior to MacPheryon v. Buick Motor Co., 111 N.E. 1050 (N.Y. 1916), a manufacturer could avoid breach-of-warranty claims for a defective product if the good had been sold first to a dealer
    • For example, prior to MacPheryon v. Buick Motor Co., 111 N.E. 1050 (N.Y. 1916), a manufacturer could avoid breach-of-warranty claims for a defective product if the good had been sold first to a dealer.
  • 204
    • 77953073776 scopus 로고
    • Joslyn v. Cadillac Auto. Co., 177 F. 863, (classifying franchisees as vendees); Isbell v. Anderson Carriage Co., 136 N.W. 457, 457-58 (Mich. 1912). (classifing franchisees as purchasers)
    • See, e.g., Joslyn v. Cadillac Auto. Co., 177 F. 863, 867 (6th Cir. 1910) (classifying franchisees as vendees); Isbell v. Anderson Carriage Co., 136 N.W. 457, 457-58 (Mich. 1912). (classifing franchisees as purchasers).
    • (1910) , pp. 867
  • 205
    • 77953076746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra notes 129-30 and accompanying text (discussing how the first-sale doctrine peiforms an antitrust function)
    • See supra notes 129-30 and accompanying text (discussing how the first-sale doctrine peiforms an antitrust function).
  • 206
    • 77953074616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Gen. Elec. Co., 272 U.S. 476, 481-83 (1926)
    • United States v. Gen. Elec. Co., 272 U.S. 476, 481-83 (1926).
  • 207
    • 77953036101 scopus 로고
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S.
    • Dr. Miles Med. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 394-98 (1911).
    • (1911) , vol.373 , pp. 394-98
  • 208
    • 77953040819 scopus 로고
    • The Court reached the same conclusion in Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrant-Houston Co., 258 U.S.
    • The Court reached the same conclusion in Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrant-Houston Co., 258 U.S. 346, 354-55 (1922).
    • (1922) , vol.346 , pp. 354-55
  • 209
    • 77953033720 scopus 로고
    • Straus v. Victor Talking Mach. Co., 243 U.S.
    • Straus v. Victor Talking Mach. Co., 243 U.S. 490, 494-96 (1917).
    • (1917) , vol.490 , pp. 494-96
  • 210
    • 77953075464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Ford Motor Co. v. Union Motor Sales Co., 244 F. 156 (6th Cir. 1917) (holding that Ford could not by agreement "license" the patents in its cars to car dealers on the condition that the dealers adhere to Ford's stipulated resale prices; such a license was a mere subterfuge in order to avoid the resale-price-maintenance rule)
    • See generally Ford Motor Co. v. Union Motor Sales Co., 244 F. 156 (6th Cir. 1917) (holding that Ford could not by agreement "license" the patents in its cars to car dealers on the condition that the dealers adhere to Ford's stipulated resale prices; such a license was a mere subterfuge in order to avoid the resale-price-maintenance rule).
  • 211
    • 77953044982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Straus, 243 U.S. at 500-01
    • Straus, 243 U.S. at 500-01.
  • 212
    • 77953041083 scopus 로고
    • Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of Cal., 377 U.S.
    • Simpson v. Union Oil Co. of Cal., 377 U.S. 13, 24 (1964).
    • (1964) , vol.13 , pp. 24
  • 213
    • 77953064337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 20-22
    • Id. at 20-22.
  • 214
    • 77953029332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See DlCKE, supra note 81, at 3 ("By the late 1950s perceptive entrepreneurs realized that, to use a popular example, there was more money to be made selling hamburger stands than in selling hamburgers.")
    • See DlCKE, supra note 81, at 3 ("By the late 1950s perceptive entrepreneurs realized that, to use a popular example, there was more money to be made selling hamburger stands than in selling hamburgers.").
  • 215
    • 77953061378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Kypta v. McDonald's Corp., 671 F.2d 1282, 1286 (11th Cir. 1982) (rejecting the claim that the franchisor unlawfully tied the license of its name and trademark to the restaurant lease)
    • See, e.g., Kypta v. McDonald's Corp., 671 F.2d 1282, 1286 (11th Cir. 1982) (rejecting the claim that the franchisor unlawfully tied the license of its name and trademark to the restaurant lease);
  • 216
    • 77953049867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principe v. McDonald's Corp., 631 F.2d 303, 308 (4th Cir. 1980) (same), cert, denied, 451 U.S. 970 (1981)
    • Principe v. McDonald's Corp., 631 F.2d 303, 308 (4th Cir. 1980) (same), cert, denied, 451 U.S. 970 (1981).
  • 217
    • 77953061644 scopus 로고
    • E.g., Siegel v. Chicken Delight, Inc., 448 F.2d 43, 47-48 (9th Cir. 1971) (condemning an arrangement under which franchisor did not charge franchise fee but required franchisee to take various supplies at prices higher than the market rate), cert, denied, 405 U.S.
    • E.g., Siegel v. Chicken Delight, Inc., 448 F.2d 43, 47-48 (9th Cir. 1971) (condemning an arrangement under which franchisor did not charge franchise fee but required franchisee to take various supplies at prices higher than the market rate), cert, denied, 405 U.S. 955 (1972).
    • (1972) , pp. 955
  • 218
    • 53249120565 scopus 로고
    • Automobile dealer franchises: Vertical integration by contract
    • For a catalog and description of the statutes, see
    • For a catalog and description of the statutes, see Friedrich Kessler, Automobile Dealer Franchises: Vertical Integration by Contract, 66 YALE LJ. 1135,1169 & n.224 (1957).
    • (1957) 66 Yale L.J. , vol.1135 , pp. 1169-224
    • Kessler, F.1
  • 219
    • 77953046050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 220
    • 77953052654 scopus 로고
    • E.g., available at
    • E.g., Fed. Trade Comm'n, Annual Report 24-25 (1939), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/annualreports/arl939.pdf;
    • (1939) Fed. Trade Comm'n, Annual Report , pp. 24-25
  • 221
    • 77953036884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also PALAMOUNTAIN, supra note 74, at 136 (discussing the discovery that statutes regulating the franchising process were the result of dealer collusion)
    • see also PALAMOUNTAIN, supra note 74, at 136 (discussing the discovery that statutes regulating the franchising process were the result of dealer collusion).
  • 222
    • 77953042223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Automobile Dealers' Day in Court Act, Pub. L, No. 1026, 70 Stat 1125 (1956) (codified at 15 U.S.C. §§);
    • Automobile Dealers' Day in Court Act, Pub. L, No. 1026, 70 Stat 1125 (1956) (codified at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1221-1225 (2006));
    • (2006) , pp. 1221-1225
  • 223
    • 77953073502 scopus 로고
    • The automobile dealer franchise act of 1956
    • see (discussing the Act's relationship to antitrust law).
    • see Donald P. McHugh, The Automobile Dealer Franchise Act of 1956, 2 ANTITRUST BULL. 353, 354 (1957) (discussing the Act's relationship to antitrust law).
    • (1957) 2 Antitrust Bull. , vol.353 , pp. 354
    • McHugh, D.P.1
  • 224
    • 77953055334 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. REP. No. 2850, at 3 (1956)
    • H.R. REP. No. 2850, at 3 (1956).
  • 225
    • 77953032627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Automobile Dealers' Day in Court Act pmbl
    • Automobile Dealers' Day in Court Act pmbl.
  • 226
    • 77953071311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ROWE, supra note 75, at 3-35 (discussing the background and legislative history of the Robinson-Patman Act)
    • See ROWE, supra note 75, at 3-35 (discussing the background and legislative history of the Robinson-Patman Act);
  • 227
    • 77953033161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • PALAMOUNTAIN, supra note 74, at 169-222
    • PALAMOUNTAIN, supra note 74, at 169-222;
  • 228
    • 77953032897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schragger, supra note 76, at 1011 (discussing the anti-chain movement and the loss of progressive constitutionalism since the New Deal)
    • Schragger, supra note 76, at 1011 (discussing the anti-chain movement and the loss of progressive constitutionalism since the New Deal).
  • 231
    • 0039128314 scopus 로고
    • The class experience of mass consumption: Workers as consumers in interwar america
    • (Richard Wrightman Fox & T.J.Jackson Leans eds.,).
    • Iizabeth Cohen, The Class Experience of Mass Consumption: Workers as Consumers in Interwar America, in THE Power of Culture: Critical Essays in American History 135,149 (Richard Wrightman Fox & T.J.Jackson Leans eds., 1993).
    • (1993) THE Power of Culture: Critical Essays in American History , vol.135 , pp. 149
    • Cohen, I.1
  • 233
    • 0004177332 scopus 로고
    • see, (arguing that when large chain stores push down prices, they do so at the expense of small, family-owned stores).
    • see ELLIUS W. HAWLEY, THE NEW DEAL AND THE PROBLEM OF MONOPOLY 248-50 (1966) (arguing that when large chain stores push down prices, they do so at the expense of small, family-owned stores).
    • (1966) The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly , pp. 248-250
    • Hawley, E.W.1
  • 234
    • 77953056392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FED. TRADE COMM'N, supra note 167, at 57-58,85-97
    • See FED. TRADE COMM'N, supra note 167, at 57-58,85-97.
  • 235
    • 0004010763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 14 (2d ed. ) ("The concern of [the] original §2 was predatory pricing in which those paying the low price are the long-term victims.").
    • See 14 HERBERT HOVENKAMP, ANTITRUST Law ¶ 2361 (2d ed. 2006) ("The concern of [the] original §2 was predatory pricing in which those paying the low price are the long-term victims.").
    • (2006) Antitrust Law , pp. 2361
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 236
    • 77953051837 scopus 로고
    • E.g., Standard Oil Co. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n, 340 U.S.
    • E.g., Standard Oil Co. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n, 340 U.S. 231, 249-50 (1951);
    • (1951) , vol.231 , pp. 249-250
  • 237
    • 77953039147 scopus 로고
    • Myers v. Shell Oil Co., 96 F. Supp. 670, 673 (S.D. Cal.)
    • Myers v. Shell Oil Co., 96 F. Supp. 670, 673 (S.D. Cal. 1951);
    • (1951)
  • 238
    • 77953077581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goodyear Tire & Rubber Co., 22 F.T.C. 232, 237 (1936) (holding that it was unlawful to charge Sears a lower price for similar tires sold to branded Goodyear dealers)
    • Goodyear Tire & Rubber Co., 22 F.T.C. 232, 237 (1936) (holding that it was unlawful to charge Sears a lower price for similar tires sold to branded Goodyear dealers).
  • 240
    • 77953055046 scopus 로고
    • The robinson-patman act and antitrust policy: A time for reappraisal
    • (questioning the efficacy of the Robinson-Patman Act)
    • Philip Elman, The Robinson-Patman Act and Antitrust Policy: A Time for Reappraisal, 42 WASH. L. REV. 1, 11-13 (1966) (questioning the efficacy of the Robinson-Patman Act);
    • (1966) 42 Wash. L. Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 11-13
    • Elman, P.1
  • 241
    • 77953049865 scopus 로고
    • The FTC's administration of the anti-price discrimination law: A paradox of antitrust policy
    • (arguing that the Robinson-Patman Act is not a true antitrust measure because it "arose from efforts to shelter traditional distribution channels from competition");
    • Frederick Rowe, The FTC's Administration of the Anti-Price Discrimination Law: A Paradox of Antitrust Policy, 64 COLUM. L. REV. 415,416 (1964) (arguing that the Robinson-Patman Act is not a true antitrust measure because it "arose from efforts to shelter traditional distribution channels from competition");
    • (1964) 64 Colum. L. Rev. , vol.415 , pp. 416
    • Rowe, F.1
  • 242
    • 77953050781 scopus 로고
    • The good faith defense of the robinson-patman act: A new restriction appraised
    • Note, (stating that "giving to the vertically-integrated distributor a competitive advantage unrelated to his performance ⋯ frustrates die antitrust laws' attempt to promote efficiency").
    • Note, The Good Faith Defense of the Robinson-Patman Act: A New Restriction Appraised, 66 YALE L.J. 935, 943 (1957) (stating that "giving to the vertically-integrated distributor a competitive advantage unrelated to his performance ⋯ frustrates die antitrust laws' attempt to promote efficiency").
    • (1957) 66 Yale L.J. , vol.935 , pp. 943
  • 243
    • 77953049596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 14 HOVENKAMP, supra note 169,1 2312
    • See 14 HOVENKAMP, supra note 169,1 2312.
  • 244
    • 77953071024 scopus 로고
    • Standard Oil Co. v. Brown, 238 F.2d 54, 57 (5th Cir.);
    • Standard Oil Co. v. Brown, 238 F.2d 54, 57 (5th Cir. 1956);
    • (1956)
  • 245
    • 77953060812 scopus 로고
    • Gasoline marketing and the robinson-patman act
    • Enter. Indus, v. Tex. Co., 136 F. Supp. 420, 421 (D. Conn. 1955), rev'don other grounds, 240 F.2d 457 (2d Cir.), cert, denied, 353 U.S. 965 (1957). For a full canvas, see Note
    • Enter. Indus, v. Tex. Co., 136 F. Supp. 420, 421 (D. Conn. 1955), rev'don other grounds, 240 F.2d 457 (2d Cir.), cert, denied, 353 U.S. 965 (1957). For a full canvas, see Note, Gasoline Marketing and the Robinson-Patman Act, 82 YALE L.J. 1706(1973).
    • (1973) 82 Yale L.J. , pp. 1706
  • 246
    • 77953060526 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Bordon Co., 347 U.S.
    • United States v. Bordon Co., 347 U.S. 514, 515 (1954);
    • (1954) , vol.514 , pp. 515
  • 247
    • 77953056390 scopus 로고
    • In re The Great Ad. & Pac. Tea Co., 26 F.T.C.
    • In re The Great Ad. & Pac. Tea Co., 26 F.T.C. 486,486 (1938).
    • (1938) , vol.486 , pp. 486
  • 248
    • 77953057175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ROWE, supra note 75, at 536
    • ROWE, supra note 75, at 536.
  • 249
    • 77953051039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 538
    • Id. at 538.
  • 250
    • 77953058288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 538-540
    • Id. at 538-40.
  • 251
    • 77953044086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 541
    • Id. at 541.
  • 252
    • 77953029065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 541-42
    • Id. at 541-42.
  • 253
    • 77953081123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Standani Oil Co. of Cal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 293 (1949) (finding a violation of section 3 of the Clayton Act).
    • E.g., Standani Oil Co. of Cal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 293 (1949) (finding a violation of section 3 of the Clayton Act).
  • 254
    • 77953042222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§
    • Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1-2 (2006).
    • (2006) , pp. 1-2
  • 255
    • 77953055590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the details of the cartel, see HOVENKAMP, supra note 44, at 331-48 (stating that the organization imposing the maintenance of resale prices represented ninety percent of the wholesale drug trade at the time of the cartel)
    • On the details of the cartel, see HOVENKAMP, supra note 44, at 331-48 (stating that the organization imposing the maintenance of resale prices represented ninety percent of the wholesale drug trade at the time of the cartel).
  • 256
    • 77953059379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007) (discussing the use of resale price maintenance in Dr. Afifejas a cartel facilitator (relying on HOVENKAMP, supra note 11, at 186-88))
    • See generally Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007) (discussing the use of resale price maintenance in Dr. Afifejas a cartel facilitator (relying on HOVENKAMP, supra note 11, at 186-88)).
  • 257
    • 77953067774 scopus 로고
    • 220 U.S.(applying rule of reason to a resale-price-maintenance claim).
    • Leegin overruled Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 406-07 (1911) (applying rule of reason to a resale-price- maintenance claim).
    • (1911) Leegin Overruled Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co. , vol.373 , pp. 406-07
  • 258
    • 77953029858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 118-20 (noting that certain groups tried to monopolize the film industry using Thomas Edison's projector and film patents)
    • See supra text accompanying notes 118-20 (noting that certain groups tried to monopolize the film industry using Thomas Edison's projector and film patents).
  • 259
    • 0004010763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the development of the case law, see 8
    • On the development of the case law, see 8 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, Antitrust Law ¶¶ 1620-1627 (2d ed. 2000).
    • (2000) Antitrust Law , pp. 1620-1627
    • Areeda, P.E.1    Hovenkamp, H.2
  • 260
    • 0002917143 scopus 로고
    • Why do manufacturers want fair trade?
    • On this point, see (stating the free-rider explanation for resale price maintenance)
    • On this point, see Lester Telser, Why Do Manufacturers Want Fair Trade?, 3 J.L. & ECON. 86,87 (1960) (stating the free-rider explanation for resale price maintenance).
    • (1960) 3 J.L. & Econ. , vol.86 , pp. 87
    • Telser, L.1
  • 261
    • 77953077018 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin, 551 U.S. at 887 (overruling Dr. Miles, 220 U.S. at 373 (applying the rule of reason to a resale-price-maintenance claim))
    • Leegin, 551 U.S. at 887 (overruling Dr. Miles, 220 U.S. at 373 (applying the rule of reason to a resale-price-maintenance claim)).
  • 262
    • 77953051038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Int'l Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392 (1947). On the development of tying law's per se rule, see 9 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 184, ¶¶ 1720-1722
    • Int'l Salt Co. v. United States, 332 U.S. 392 (1947). On the development of tying law's per se rule, see 9 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 184, ¶¶ 1720-1722.
  • 263
    • 77953074331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the lack of any foreclosure in many of these early decisions, see Bohannan, supra note 118, at 25-27
    • On the lack of any foreclosure in many of these early decisions, see Bohannan, supra note 118, at 25-27.
  • 264
    • 77953053447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Int'l Salt Co., 332 U.S. at 396-97
    • Int'l Salt Co., 332 U.S. at 396-97.
  • 265
    • 77953056674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 396
    • Id. at 396.
  • 266
    • 77953037139 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Loew's, Inc., 371 U.S.
    • United States v. Loew's, Inc., 371 U.S. 38, 45-46 (1962).
    • (1962) , vol.38 , pp. 45-46
  • 267
    • 77953044487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • III. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S.
    • III. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28,45-46 (2006).
    • (2006) , vol.28 , pp. 45-46
  • 268
    • 77953049597 scopus 로고
    • Siegel v. Chicken Delight, Inc., 448 F.2d 43, 51-52 (9th Cir. 1971), cert, denied, 405 U.S.
    • Siegel v. Chicken Delight, Inc., 448 F.2d 43, 51-52 (9th Cir. 1971), cert, denied, 405 U.S. 955 (1972).
    • (1972) , pp. 955
  • 269
    • 77953067260 scopus 로고
    • Former Enters, v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S.
    • Former Enters, v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 508-09 (1969);
    • (1969) , vol.495 , pp. 508-509
  • 270
    • 77953058817 scopus 로고
    • see also United States v. Gen. Motors Corp., 121 F.2d 376, 400-01 (7th Cir. 1941) (condemning tying of General Motors' own financing to financed purchases of its automobiles), cert, denied, 314 U.S.
    • see also United States v. Gen. Motors Corp., 121 F.2d 376, 400-01 (7th Cir. 1941) (condemning tying of General Motors' own financing to financed purchases of its automobiles), cert, denied, 314 U.S. 618 (1941).
    • (1941) , vol.618
  • 271
    • 77953069112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gen. Motors Corp., 34 F.T.C. 58, 86 (1941), modified, 34 F.T.C. 84 (1942) (forbidding General Motors from requiring its dealers to use only its parts). On tying claims in the automobile industry, see Kessler, supra note 159, at 1161
    • See Gen. Motors Corp., 34 F.T.C. 58, 86 (1941), modified, 34 F.T.C. 84 (1942) (forbidding General Motors from requiring its dealers to use only its parts). On tying claims in the automobile industry, see Kessler, supra note 159, at 1161.
  • 272
    • 77953046831 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S.
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365,382 (1967).
    • (1967) , vol.365 , pp. 382
  • 273
    • 77953032628 scopus 로고
    • Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S.
    • Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145,153 (1968).
    • (1968) , vol.145 , pp. 153
  • 274
    • 77953053707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 275
    • 77953030392 scopus 로고
    • Vertical integration by the newspaper monopolist
    • See (explaining how high newspaper-carrier prices disadvantage newspapers).
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Vertical Integration by the Newspaper Monopolist, 69 IOWA L. Rev. 451, 456, 458-59 (1984) (explaining how high newspaper-carrier prices disadvantage newspapers).
    • (1984) 69 Iowa L. Rev. , vol.451-456 , pp. 458-59
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 276
    • 77953041388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., PaschaU v. Kan. City Star Co., 727 F.2d 692, 704 (8th Cir. 1984) (en bane) (holding that the newspaper did not unlawfully monopolize distribution market by terminating contracts with independent carriers and switching to an employee-distribution scheme), cert, denied, 469 U.S. 872 (1984)
    • See, e.g., PaschaU v. Kan. City Star Co., 727 F.2d 692, 704 (8th Cir. 1984) (en bane) (holding that the newspaper did not unlawfully monopolize distribution market by terminating contracts with independent carriers and switching to an employee-distribution scheme), cert, denied, 469 U.S. 872 (1984).
  • 278
    • 77953051282 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365,367 (1967)
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365,367 (1967).
    • V. Arnold1
  • 279
    • 77953050173 scopus 로고
    • Brief of the United States, United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (No. 25), 1967 WL 129568
    • Brief of the United States, United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967) (No. 25), 1967 WL 129568.
    • (1967)
    • V. Arnold1
  • 280
    • 77953031210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 46-50
    • Id. at 46-50.
  • 281
    • 77953072968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 50-51
    • Id. at 50-51.
  • 282
    • 77953037675 scopus 로고
    • The Next Step in the Antitrust Treatment of Restricted Distribution: Per Se Legality
    • Richard A. Posner, The Next Step in the Antitrust Treatment of Restricted Distribution: Per Se Legality, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 6, 7-8 (1981);
    • (1981) 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 6 , pp. 7-8
    • Richard, A.P.1
  • 283
    • 77953062197 scopus 로고
    • 734c, at 262 () (explaining that vertically imposed territorial restrictions, even by a monopolist, are not presumed unlawful; no citation to Schwinn)
    • see also 3 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & DONALD F. TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW I 734c, at 262 (1978) (explaining that vertically imposed territorial restrictions, even by a monopolist, are not presumed unlawful; no citation to Schwinn).
    • (1978)
    • Phillip, E.A.1    Donald, F.T.2    Antitrust, L.I.3
  • 284
    • 77953053706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 36-37 (1977)
    • Cont'l T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 36-37 (1977).
  • 286
    • 77953068296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 182 and accompanying text (discussing the details of the Dr. Miles cartel)
    • See supra note 182 and accompanying text (discussing the details of the Dr. Miles cartel).
  • 287
    • 77953038333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying notes 195-98 (discussing Albrechi's per se rule against maximum-price restraints)
    • See supra text accompanying notes 195-98 (discussing Albrechi's per se rule against maximum-price restraints).
  • 288
    • 77953064336 scopus 로고
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S
    • Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294,343-44 (1962).
    • (1962) , vol.294 , pp. 343-44
  • 289
    • 77953059970 scopus 로고
    • Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics
    • Celler-Kefauver Act, Pub. L. No. 81-899, 64 Stat 1125 (1950) (rewriting section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1946)). On the legislative history, see, and Hovenkamp, supra note 82, at
    • Celler-Kefauver Act, Pub. L. No. 81-899, 64 Stat 1125 (1950) (rewriting section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1946)). On the legislative history, see Derek C. Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 HARV. L. REV. 226, 249 (1960), and Hovenkamp, supra note 82, at 521-22.
    • (1960) 74 HARV. L. REV. 226 , vol.249 , pp. 521-22
    • Derek, C.B.1
  • 290
    • 77953064822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States at 136-37, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962) (No. 4), 1961 WL 101890
    • Brief for the United States at 136-37, Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962) (No. 4), 1961 WL 101890.
  • 291
    • 77953053204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (footnotes omitted)
    • Id. (footnotes omitted).
  • 292
    • 77953043018 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Am. Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106,187-88
    • United States v. Am. Tobacco Co., 221 U.S. 106,187-88 (1911).
    • (1911)
  • 293
    • 77953079771 scopus 로고
    • Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 76-77
    • Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 76-77 (1911).
    • (1911)
  • 294
    • 77953063211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Standard Oil Co., 47 F.2d 288, 309-11 (E.D. Mo. 1931) (praising vertical integration in petroleum for its efficiency)
    • See, e.g., United States v. Standard Oil Co., 47 F.2d 288, 309-11 (E.D. Mo. 1931) (praising vertical integration in petroleum for its efficiency).
  • 295
    • 77953044488 scopus 로고
    • United States v. U.S. Steel Corp., 251 U.S. 417, 442
    • United States v. U.S. Steel Corp., 251 U.S. 417, 442 (1920).
    • (1920)
  • 296
    • 77953071859 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Eastman Kodak Co., 226 F. 62,79-80 (W.D.N.Y.)
    • United States v. Eastman Kodak Co., 226 F. 62,79-80 (W.D.N.Y. 1915).
    • (1915)
  • 297
    • 77953040270 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Corn Prods. Refining Co., 234 F. 964,984-90 (S.D.N.Y.)
    • United States v. Corn Prods. Refining Co., 234 F. 964,984-90 (S.D.N.Y. 1916).
    • (1916)
  • 298
    • 77953044729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1013; Eastman Kodak Co., 226 F. at 80
    • Id. at 1013; Eastman Kodak Co., 226 F. at 80.
  • 299
    • 77953048473 scopus 로고
    • see HOVENKAMP, supra note 44, ch. 12 (discussing the history, purpose, and effect of the development of railroad regulation)
    • Munn v. Illinois, 94 U.S. 113, 135-36 (1876); see HOVENKAMP, supra note 44, ch. 12 (discussing the history, purpose, and effect of the development of railroad regulation).
    • (1876) 94 U.S. 113 , pp. 135-36
    • Munn, V.I.1
  • 301
    • 77953031209 scopus 로고
    • Organized in a vertical manner, they operate all stages of the productive process."). But see HAWLEY, supra note 167, at 218-20 (presenting the potential benefits of integration
    • See also David Lynch, The Concentration of economic Power 132 (1946) ("Organized in a vertical manner, they operate all stages of the productive process."). But see HAWLEY, supra note 167, at 218-20 (presenting the potential benefits of integration).
    • (1946) The Concentration of economic Power 132
    • David, L.1
  • 302
    • 77953072111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2d ed., MIT Press 1988) (1971) (describing the economic climate during the Depression
    • See ALFRED E. KAHN, THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION 9-10 (2d ed., MIT Press 1988) (1971) (describing the economic climate during the Depression).
    • THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION 9-10
    • Alfred, E.K.1
  • 303
    • 77953055589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Temp. Nat'l Econ. Comm., Investigation of Concentration of Economic Power Monograph No. 39, 1941) (describing how integration has handicapped smaller business in the oil industry
    • See Roy C. Cook, Control of the Petroleum Industry by Major Oil Companies 51-52 (Temp. Nat'l Econ. Comm., Investigation of Concentration of Economic Power Monograph No. 39, 1941) (describing how integration has handicapped smaller business in the oil industry).
    • Control of the Petroleum Industry by Major Oil Companies 51-52
    • Roy, C.C.1
  • 305
    • 77953038878 scopus 로고
    • ROSTOW, supra note 46, at 117. Rostow later became the dean of Yale Law School, from
    • ROSTOW, supra note 46, at 117. Rostow later became the dean of Yale Law School, from 1955 to 1965.
    • (1955)
  • 307
    • 77953047345 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131, 174 (citations omitted)
    • United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131, 174 (1948) (citations omitted).
    • (1948)
  • 309
    • 77953054242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 10, at 344 (describing that in "sharp contrast" to the First New Deal, the Second New Deal ushered in antitrust policies that were "highly suspicious of any form of agreement among rivals and increasingly hostile toward both dominant firms and vertical integration
    • See Hovenkamp, supra note 10, at 344 (describing that in "sharp contrast" to the First New Deal, the Second New Deal ushered in antitrust policies that were "highly suspicious of any form of agreement among rivals and increasingly hostile toward both dominant firms and vertical integration").
  • 310
    • 77953063210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 341 (describing how Edward Chamberlin's model of monopolistic competition "solved the ruinous competition puzzle by illustrating how firms in product differentiated markets would shift their efforts into repositioning their products rather than producing more
    • See id. at 341 (describing how Edward Chamberlin's model of monopolistic competition "solved the ruinous competition puzzle by illustrating how firms in product differentiated markets would shift their efforts into repositioning their products rather than producing more").
  • 311
    • 77953074042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CHAMBERUN, supra note 229, at 123
    • CHAMBERUN, supra note 229, at 123.
  • 312
    • 0003882668 scopus 로고
    • While Bain was Harvard trained and became the principal spokesperson for the Harvard School industrial organization theory in the 1950s, he spent most of his academic career at the University of California, Berkeley
    • Joe S. Bain, Barriers to New Competition: Their Character and Consequences in MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 142-43, 212 (1956). While Bain was Harvard trained and became the principal spokesperson for the Harvard School industrial organization theory in the 1950s, he spent most of his academic career at the University of California, Berkeley.
    • (1956) Barriers to New Competition: Their Character and Consequences in MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 142-43 , vol.212
    • Joe, S.B.1
  • 313
    • 77953061643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 144-66
    • Id. at 144-66.
  • 314
    • 77953075463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 212
    • Id. at 212.
  • 315
    • 77953032000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 316
    • 77953037949 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice, 1968 Merger Guidelines 9-10 available at. These Guidelines were drafted while Donald F. Turner was head of the Department's Antitrust Division and issued on his last day in office
    • U.S. Dep't of Justice, 1968 Merger Guidelines 9-10 (1968), available at http://www. usdoj.gov/atr/hmerger/11247.pdf. These Guidelines were drafted while Donald F. Turner was head of the Department's Antitrust Division and issued on his last day in office.
    • (1968)
  • 317
    • 77953070776 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. 218, 227. There the Court claimed: The fact that these restraints occur in a setting described by the appellees as a vertically integrated enterprise does not necessarily remove the ban of the Sherman Act⋯ Such a restraint may result as readily from a conspiracy among those who are affiliated or integrated under common ownership as from a conspiracy among those who are otherwise independent
    • United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. 218, 227 (1947). There the Court claimed: The fact that these restraints occur in a setting described by the appellees as a vertically integrated enterprise does not necessarily remove the ban of the Sherman Act⋯ Such a restraint may result as readily from a conspiracy among those who are affiliated or integrated under common ownership as from a conspiracy among those who are otherwise independent.
    • (1947)
  • 318
    • 77953055045 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. This "intraenterprise conspiracy" doctrine was later overruled by the Supreme Court in Coppenoeld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 752 (1984). See 7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 184, \ 1463 (discussing the evolution and demise of the "intraenterprise conspiracy" doctrine between Yellow Cab Co. and Coppenveld Corp.
    • Id. This "intraenterprise conspiracy" doctrine was later overruled by the Supreme Court in Coppenoeld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 752 (1984). See 7 AREEDA & HOVENKAMP, supra note 184, \ 1463 (discussing the evolution and demise of the "intraenterprise conspiracy" doctrine between Yellow Cab Co. and Coppenveld Corp.).
  • 319
    • 77953067527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Motion Picture Industry-A Pattern of Control
    • United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131, 131-32 (1948). The problem had already been cited during the New Deal. See, (noting the disadvantaged position of independent exhibitors of motion pictures in comparison with affiliated exhibitors)
    • United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131, 131-32 (1948). The problem had already been cited during the New Deal. See Daniel Bertrand et al., The Motion Picture Industry-A Pattern of Control (Temp. Nat'l Econ. Comm., Investigation of Concentration of Economic Power Monograph No. 43,1941) (noting the disadvantaged position of independent exhibitors of motion pictures in comparison with affiliated exhibitors).
    • Temp. Nat'l Econ. Comm., Investigation of Concentration of Economic Power Monograph No. 43,1941
    • Daniel, B.1
  • 320
    • 77953032896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. at 226-27
    • Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. at 226-27.
  • 321
    • 77953074041 scopus 로고
    • United States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.S. 495, 495
    • United States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.S. 495, 495 (1948);
    • (1948)
  • 322
    • 77953081122 scopus 로고
    • The Columbia Steel Case: New Light on Old Antitrust Problems
    • discussing the problems of antitrust law that arise from vertical integration)
    • see also Note, The Columbia Steel Case: New Light on Old Antitrust Problems, 58 YALE L.J. 764, 768 (1949) (discussing the problems of antitrust law that arise from vertical integration).
    • (1949) 58 YALE L.J. 764 , vol.768
  • 323
    • 77953042221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. at 226-27
    • Yellow Cab Co., 332 U.S. at 226-27.
  • 324
    • 77953039426 scopus 로고
    • United States v. N.Y. Great Atl. & Pac. Tea Co., 173 F.2d 79,85 (7th Cir.
    • United States v. N.Y. Great Atl. & Pac. Tea Co., 173 F.2d 79,85 (7th Cir. 1949).
    • (1949)
  • 325
    • 77953062658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. N.Y. Great Ad. & Pac. Tea Co., 67 F. Supp. 626, 641 (E.D. 111. 1946) (explaining that the government accused the defendant of predation)
    • See United States v. N.Y. Great Ad. & Pac. Tea Co., 67 F. Supp. 626, 641 (E.D. 111. 1946) (explaining that the government accused the defendant of predation).
  • 326
    • 77953051577 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bork, supra note 55, at 181
    • Bork, supra note 55, at 181.
  • 327
    • 77953048747 scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States at 2, United States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.S. 495 (No. 461), 1948 WL 47544 (emphasis added)
    • Brief for the United States at 2, United States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.S. 495 (1948) (No. 461), 1948 WL 47544 (emphasis added).
    • (1948)
  • 328
    • 77953040269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally U.S. Dep'T OF JUSTICE, supra note 237 (outlining the U.S. Department of Justice's hostility toward vertical mergers
    • See generally U.S. Dep'T OF JUSTICE, supra note 237 (outlining the U.S. Department of Justice's hostility toward vertical mergers).
  • 329
    • 77953078660 scopus 로고
    • United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586,588
    • United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.S. 586,588 (1957).
    • (1957)
  • 330
    • 77953068034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.at588-9
    • Id.at588-9.
  • 331
    • 77953029064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for the United States at 113, du Pont, 353 U.S. 586 (No. 3) (emphasis omitted), 1956 WL 88967
    • Brief for the United States at 113, du Pont, 353 U.S. 586 (No. 3) (emphasis omitted), 1956 WL 88967.
  • 332
    • 77953073775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief for Appellee Gen. Motors Corp. at 171, du Pont, 353 U.S. 586 (No. 3), 1956 WL 88968
    • Brief for Appellee Gen. Motors Corp. at 171, du Pont, 353 U.S. 586 (No. 3), 1956 WL 88968.
  • 333
    • 77953063209 scopus 로고
    • Compare United States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.S. 495 (holding that excluding competition via vertical integration does not necessarily violate the Sherman Act), with H.R. REP. No. 81-1191, at 11 (1949) (noting that the amendment of section 7 of the Clayton Act was intended to "make it clear that the bill applies to all types of mergers and acquisitions, vertical and conglomerate as well as horizontal")
    • Compare United States v. Columbia Steel Co., 334 U.S. 495 (1948) (holding that excluding competition via vertical integration does not necessarily violate the Sherman Act), with H.R. REP. No. 81-1191, at 11 (1949) (noting that the amendment of section 7 of the Clayton Act was intended to "make it clear that the bill applies to all types of mergers and acquisitions, vertical and conglomerate as well as horizontal").
    • (1948)
  • 334
    • 77953058040 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the Court's solution to the retroactivity problem, see du Pont, 353 U.S. at 590
    • For the Court's solution to the retroactivity problem, see du Pont, 353 U.S. at 590.
  • 335
    • 84960611501 scopus 로고
    • The Nature of the Firm: Influence
    • asserting that his two articles had two separate aims)
    • See Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm: Influence, 4 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 33, 34 (1988) (asserting that his two articles had two separate aims).
    • (1988) 4 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 33 , vol.34
    • Ronald, H.C.1
  • 336
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • Ronald H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960).
    • (1960) 3J.L. & ECON. , vol.1
    • Ronald, H.C.1
  • 337
    • 77953031488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Coase Theorem and Arthur Cecil Pigou
    • discussing Arthur Cecil Pigou's influence on Ronald Coase and the transaction-costs model
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, The Coase Theorem and Arthur Cecil Pigou, 51 Ariz. L. REV. 633, 633 (2009) (discussing Arthur Cecil Pigou's influence on Ronald Coase and the transaction-costs model).
    • (2009) 51 Ariz. L. REV. 633 , vol.633
    • Herbert, H.1
  • 338
    • 77953076459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, supra note 254, at 33
    • Coase, supra note 254, at 33.
  • 339
    • 0003965377 scopus 로고
    • (using Coase's ideas of transaction costs and uncertainty); Klein, Crawford & Alchian, supra note 35, at 298 (1978) (citing Coase's article, The Nature of the Firm, as fundamental and aiming to expand on Coase's ideas)
    • See generally OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST Implications (1975) (using Coase's ideas of transaction costs and uncertainty); Klein, Crawford & Alchian, supra note 35, at 298 (1978) (citing Coase's article, The Nature of the Firm, as fundamental and aiming to expand on Coase's ideas).
    • (1975) Markets And Hierarchies: Analysis And Antitrust Implications
    • Oliver, E.W.1
  • 340
    • 77953066981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877,877
    • Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877,877 (2007).
    • (2007)
  • 341
    • 77953043300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 903
    • Id. at 903.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.