-
5
-
-
66749162844
-
Restatement (second) of contracts ch. 11
-
RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS ch. 11, introductory note, at 309-312 (1981).
-
(1981)
Introductory Note, at
, pp. 309-312
-
-
-
7
-
-
84868974848
-
The doctrine of unjust enrichment and the doctrine of unilateral mistake both have compound liability rules that hinge on the standard. for unjust enrichment, see
-
RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS §153(b).
-
The doctrine of unjust enrichment and the doctrine of unilateral mistake both have compound liability rules that hinge on the "reason to know" standard. For unjust enrichment, see Day v. Caton, 119 Mass. 513 (1876); for unilateral mistake, see RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS §153(b).
-
(1876)
Day V. Caton, 119 Mass.
, vol.513
-
-
-
9
-
-
66749096285
-
-
Id.
-
Id.
-
-
-
10
-
-
66749178658
-
-
This statement must be qualified to the extent that the promisor can establish an excuse owing to the fact that the risk in question was not allocated in the contract.
-
This statement must be qualified to the extent that the promisor can establish an excuse owing to the fact that the risk in question was not allocated in the contract.
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
66749189412
-
-
129 N.E. 889 (N.Y. 1921).
-
(1921)
129 N.E.
, vol.889
-
-
-
15
-
-
66749163817
-
The willful transgressor must accept the penalty of his transgression
-
As Cardozo famously stated
-
As Cardozo famously stated, "the willful transgressor must accept the penalty of his transgression." Jacob & Youngs, 129 N.E. at 891.
-
Jacob & Youngs, 129 N.E. at
, pp. 891
-
-
-
16
-
-
66749170311
-
-
(Irwin, J., dissenting).
-
Peevyhouse, 382 P.2d at 115 (Irwin, J., dissenting).
-
Peevyhouse, 382 P.2d at
, pp. 115
-
-
-
17
-
-
84868987012
-
Craswell
-
" "The word ... "wilful" ... is seldom accompanied by any discussion of its meaning or classification of the cases that should fall within it.' " quoting 5 ARTHUR LINTON CORBIN, CORBIN ON CONTRACTS § 1123
-
See Craswell, supra note 2, at 1502 (" "The word ... "wilful" ... is seldom accompanied by any discussion of its meaning or classification of the cases that should fall within it.' " (quoting 5 ARTHUR LINTON CORBIN, CORBIN ON CONTRACTS § 1123 (1951)));
-
(1951)
Supra Note
, vol.2
, pp. 1502
-
-
-
19
-
-
57649109460
-
-
Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Market Damages, Efficient Contracting, and the Economic Waste Fallacy, 108 COLUM. L. REV. 1610 (2008).
-
(2008)
Market Damages, Efficient Contracting, and the Economic Waste Fallacy, 108 COLUM. L. REV.
, vol.1610
-
-
Schwartz, A.1
Scott, R.E.2
-
20
-
-
66749134930
-
-
note
-
The standard construction contract contains a separate promise by the contractor to correct any defective construction. This promise remains binding even after substantial performance of the contract. See e.g., AMERICAN INSTITUTE OF ARCHITECTS, AIA DOCUMENT A201-1997: GENERAL CONDITIONS OF THE CONTRACT FOR CONSTRUCTION (1997).
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
66749189734
-
This argument is formally set out in Schwartz & Scott
-
This argument is formally set out in Schwartz & Scott, supra note 15, at 1652-1657
-
Supra Note
, vol.15
, pp. 1652-1657
-
-
-
22
-
-
84868987012
-
Craswell
-
("The builder in Kent used the wrong brand of pipe, apparently by accident .... ")
-
See Craswell, supra note 2, at 1502 ("The builder in Kent used the wrong brand of pipe, apparently by accident .... ");
-
Supra Note
, vol.2
, pp. 1502
-
-
-
24
-
-
66749144373
-
-
(characterizing the contractor's behavior as negligent but justifying the result on other grounds).
-
But see Thel & Siegelman, supra note 14, at 1526-27 (characterizing the contractor's behavior as negligent but justifying the result on other grounds).
-
Supra Note
, vol.14
, pp. 1526-1527
-
-
Thel1
Siegelman2
-
25
-
-
84868984919
-
Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v
-
(McLaughlin, J., dissenting) ("[N]o examination ... was made by the plaintiff, the subcontractor, defendant's architect, or anyone else, of any of the pipe except the first delivery, until after the building had been completed.").
-
Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 129 N.E. 889, 892 (McLaughlin, J., dissenting) ("[N]o examination ... was made by the plaintiff, the subcontractor, defendant's architect, or anyone else, of any of the pipe except the first delivery, until after the building had been completed.").
-
Kent, 129 N.E.
, vol.889
, pp. 892
-
-
-
26
-
-
66749118005
-
-
note
-
Note that we must assume, per Cardozo, that the failure to install the contract-specified pipe was, in fact, a breach. This assumption is supported in the case by the architect's refusal to give his certificate.
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
66749107094
-
-
See id. at 1413.
-
Id. at
, pp. 1413
-
-
-
31
-
-
66749174295
-
-
Id. at 1625-1627
-
Id. at
, pp. 1625-1627
-
-
-
32
-
-
66749152266
-
-
Id. at 1659 & n. 123.
-
Id. at
, vol.123
, pp. 1659
-
-
-
33
-
-
66749136661
-
-
App. Div. (applying cost of completion where contractor intentionally omitted styrofoam insulation and footing drains required by the plans).
-
Roudis v. Hubbard, 574 N.Y.S.2d 95 (App. Div. 1991) (applying cost of completion where contractor intentionally omitted styrofoam insulation and footing drains required by the plans).
-
(1991)
574 N.Y.S.2d
, vol.95
-
-
Hubbard, R.V.1
-
34
-
-
66749181417
-
-
S.D. Tex.
-
See, e.g., S. Nat'l Bank, of Houston v. TRI Fin. Corp., 317 F. Supp. 1173,1185 (S.D. Tex. 1970),
-
(1970)
S. Nat'l Bank, of Houston V. TRI Fin. Corp., 317 F. Supp.
, vol.1173
, pp. 1185
-
-
-
35
-
-
84868961106
-
-
5th Cir. ("Defendant had neither breached nor indicated an intention to do so; having not yet been injured by any breach of defendant's, plaintiff had no damages to mitigate.").
-
aff'd in part, rev 'd in part sub nom. S. Nat'l Bank of Houston v. Crateo, Inc., 458 F.2d 688 (5th Cir. 1972) ("Defendant had neither breached nor indicated an intention to do so; having not yet been injured by any breach of defendant's, plaintiff had no damages to mitigate.").
-
(1972)
Aff'd in Part, Rev 'D in Part Sub Nom. S. Nat'l Bank of Houston V. Crateo, Inc., 458 F.2d
, vol.688
-
-
-
36
-
-
66749149094
-
The classic article is Robert Cooter
-
The classic article is Robert Cooter, Unity in Tort, Contract, and Property: The Model of Precaution, 73 CAL. L. REV. 1, 11-19 (1985).
-
(1985)
Unity in Tort, Contract, and Property: the Model of Precaution, 73 CAL. L. REV.
, vol.1
, pp. 11-19
-
-
-
39
-
-
85075685760
-
-
Under an award of full expectancy, the promisee will recover her full valuation, and thus she is motivated to invest in the subject matter of the contract until her marginal gain equals her marginal cost. But the promisee does not consider that performance would be inefficient in some ex post states of the world. In these states, the promisee's investment is a social waste. See, e.g., (concluding that under expectation damages buyers will choose a greater-thanefficient level of reliance).
-
Under an award of full expectancy, the promisee will recover her full valuation, and thus she is motivated to invest in the subject matter of the contract until her marginal gain equals her marginal cost. But the promisee does not consider that performance would be inefficient in some ex post states of the world. In these states, the promisee's investment is a social waste. See, e.g., William. P. Rogerson, Efficient Reliance and Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 15 RAND J. EcoN. 39, 47 (1984) (concluding that under expectation damages buyers will choose a greater-thanefficient level of reliance).
-
(1984)
Efficient Reliance and Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 15 RAND J. EcoN.
, vol.39
, pp. 47
-
-
Rogerson, W.P.1
-
40
-
-
66749091277
-
The discussion that follows draws on
-
The discussion that follows draws on ROBERT E. SCOTT & JODY S. KRAUS, CONTRACT LAW AND THEORY 815-818 (4th ed. 2007).
-
(2007)
Contract Law And Theory
, Issue.4
, pp. 815-818
-
-
Scott, R.E.1
Kraus, J.S.2
-
43
-
-
84868968565
-
-
The Uniform Commercial Code permits the promisee to wait a following the repudiation, and thus also fails a comparative fault analysis. U.C.C. §
-
The Uniform Commercial Code permits the promisee to wait a "commercially reasonable time" following the repudiation, and thus also fails a comparative fault analysis. U.C.C. § 2610(a) (2004).
-
(2004)
, vol.2610
-
-
-
44
-
-
66749114579
-
-
In principle, the arguments outlined here might also be applied to contracts made by commercially unsophisticated parties. But defending an extension of the argument to such cases would require additional analysis to take into account a range of considerations that I do not undertake here.
-
In principle, the arguments outlined here might also be applied to contracts made by commercially unsophisticated parties. But defending an extension of the argument to such cases would require additional analysis to take into account a range of considerations that I do not undertake here.
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
66749093831
-
-
My argument that the law properly attends to the revealed preferences of commercial parties can be supported on both efficiency and autonomy grounds. And, to be sure, moral theorists may offer other normative arguments in favor of strict liability.
-
My argument that the law properly attends to the revealed preferences of commercial parties can be supported on both efficiency and autonomy grounds. And, to be sure, moral theorists may offer other normative arguments in favor of strict liability.
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
66749159947
-
-
note
-
Under conditions of uncertainty, contracts will be incomplete in the sense that information costs will make it impossible to distinguish ex ante the ex post states of the world that call for different obligations. See, e.g.,
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
84934453985
-
-
One solution is for the parties to renegotiate the contract once uncertainties are resolved. But renegotiation raises the risk of a hold up; and this, in turn, undermines the incentives for parties to make specific investments in the first place. For discussion, see
-
One solution is for the parties to renegotiate the contract once uncertainties are resolved. But renegotiation raises the risk of a hold up; and this, in turn, undermines the incentives for parties to make specific investments in the first place. For discussion, see Oliver Hart & John Moore, Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, 98 J. POL. ECON. 1119 (1990), and
-
(1990)
Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, 98 J. POL. ECON.
, pp. 1119
-
-
Hart, O.1
Moore, J.2
-
56
-
-
66749136068
-
Space within which a court has discretion in interpreting the contract. for discussion, see
-
The options available to the parties are even broader than the stark choice between rules and standards. With the aid of interpretation maxims, parties can design combinations of precise and vague terms that define more exactly the
-
The options available to the parties are even broader than the stark choice between rules and standards. With the aid of interpretation maxims, parties can design combinations of precise and vague terms that define more exactly the "space" within which a court has discretion in interpreting the contract. For discussion, see Scott & Triantis, Anticlpating Litigation, supra note 35, at 848-856
-
Anticlpating Litigation, Supra Note 35, at
, pp. 848-856
-
-
Scott1
Triantis2
-
59
-
-
66749110116
-
-
(asserting reputations work well in small trading communities, where information about others' actions is common knowledge and boycotts of bad actors are readily enforced).
-
See Schwartz & Scott, supra note 39, at 557 (asserting reputations work well in small trading communities, where information about others' actions is common knowledge and boycotts of bad actors are readily enforced).
-
Supra Note
, vol.39
, pp. 557
-
-
Schwartz1
Scott2
-
60
-
-
0030551184
-
-
Retaliation has its limits: the threat that the other party will no longer deal with the promisor may be insufficient to induce performance if parties come to realize that the relationship is soon to terminate.
-
Retaliation has its limits: the threat that the other party will no longer deal with the promisor may be insufficient to induce performance if parties come to realize that the relationship is soon to terminate. See, e.g., Benjamin Klein, Why Hold-Ups Occur: The Self-Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships, 34 ECON. INQUIRY 444 (1996).
-
(1996)
Why Hold-Ups Occur: the Self-Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships, 34 ECON. INQUIRY
, pp. 444
-
-
Klein, B.1
-
61
-
-
0000773694
-
-
This substantial body of experimental evidence shows that individuals respond cooperatively to generous acts and, conversely, punish noncooperative behavior. Moreover, individuals will repay generosity and punish selfishness even if doing so is costly and yields neither present nor future material rewards. See, e.g.
-
This substantial body of experimental evidence shows that individuals respond cooperatively to generous acts and, conversely, punish noncooperative behavior. Moreover, individuals will repay generosity and punish selfishness even if doing so is costly and yields neither present nor future material rewards. See, e.g., Ernst Fehr & Klaus M. Schmidt, A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation, 114 Q.J. ECON. 817 (1999);
-
(1999)
A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation, 114 Q.J. ECON.
, vol.817
-
-
Fehr, E.1
Schmidt, K.M.2
-
64
-
-
66749092658
-
-
For a review of the literature, see Ernst Fehr & Klaus M. Schmidt, Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity-Evidence and Economic Applications (Univ. of Zurich Inst, for Empirical Research in Econ., Working Paper No. 75, 2001).
-
Matthew Rabin, Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics, 83 AM. ECON. REV. 1281 (1993). For a review of the literature, see Ernst Fehr & Klaus M. Schmidt, Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity-Evidence and Economic Applications 2-3 (Univ. of Zurich Inst, for Empirical Research in Econ., Working Paper No. 75, 2001).
-
(1993)
Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics, 83 AM. ECON. REV.
, vol.1281
, pp. 2-3
-
-
Rabin, M.1
-
66
-
-
66749084103
-
In complex interactions, a failure to cooperate may not be observable immediately, or else a cooperative response may be mistakenly interpreted as a defection from cooperative norms
-
In complex interactions, a failure to cooperate may not be observable immediately, or else a cooperative response may be mistakenly interpreted as a defection from cooperative norms. Robert E. Scott, Conflict and Cooperation in Long-Term Contracts, 75 CAL. L. REV. 2005, 2050-53 (1987).
-
(1987)
Conflict and Cooperation in Long-Term Contracts, 75 CAL. L. REV.
, vol.2005
, pp. 2050-2053
-
-
Scott, R.E.1
-
67
-
-
84929917357
-
A disinterested adjudicator may be in better position to sort out complex behavior, detect a breach, and, by imposing a predetermined sanction, forestall attempts by the aggrieved party to respond disproportionately
-
A disinterested adjudicator may be in better position to sort out complex behavior, detect a breach, and, by imposing a predetermined sanction, forestall attempts by the aggrieved party to respond disproportionately. ROBERT E. SCOTT & PAUL B. STEPHAN, THE LIMITS OF LEVIATHAN: CONTRACT THEORY AND THE ENFORCEMENT OF INTERNATIONAL LAW 100 (2006).
-
(2006)
The Limits Of Leviathan: Contract Theory And The Enforcement Of international Law
, vol.100
-
-
Scott, R.E.1
Stephan, P.B.2
-
68
-
-
66749137268
-
A number of studies have confirmed the crowding-out hypothesis. for discussion see
-
Other recent experiments also show that if there is some probability of continued transactions, then, legal enforcement that is limited to the verifiable dimensions of the agreement will enhance cooperation in the dimensions of the agreement that are nonverifiable.
-
A number of studies have confirmed the crowding-out hypothesis. For discussion see Scott, supra note 42, at 1688-92. Other recent experiments also show that if there is some probability of continued transactions, then, legal enforcement that is limited to the verifiable dimensions of the agreement will enhance cooperation in the dimensions of the agreement that are nonverifiable.
-
Supra Note 42, at
, pp. 1688-1692
-
-
Scott1
-
74
-
-
84868987902
-
-
Alliance Agreement between E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. and EarthShell Corp. Jul. 25
-
Alliance Agreement between E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. and EarthShell Corp. (Jul. 25, 2002), available at http://contracts.onecle.com/ earthshell/dupont.collab.2002.07.25.shtml.
-
(2002)
-
-
-
78
-
-
66749099758
-
-
Id. at 21, 36. Delaware was a distant second to New York, with, about 15 percent of the parties choosing its law. No other state accounted for even 10 percent of the choices of law
-
Id. at 21, 36. Delaware was a distant second to New York, with, about 15 percent of the parties choosing its law. No other state accounted for even 10 percent of the choices of law.
-
-
-
-
79
-
-
66749188005
-
-
Id. at 21
-
Id. at 21.
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
66749116889
-
-
Id. at 21
-
Id. at 21.
-
-
-
-
82
-
-
66749170880
-
-
Id. at 1. 59
-
Id. at 1. 59. See
-
-
-
-
83
-
-
84868981134
-
Cohen, fault lines
-
("But we have already seen that strict liability is a myth.").
-
Cohen, Fault Lines, supra note 1, at 1312 ("But we have already seen that strict liability is a myth.").
-
Supra Note 1, at
, pp. 1312
-
-
|