-
1
-
-
0347875743
-
Contracts for Cotton to Arrive: The Case of the Two Ships Peerless
-
For an overview of the origins of the cotton industry's private legal system, see A.W. Brian Simpson, Contracts for Cotton to Arrive: The Case of the Two Ships Peerless, 11 CARDOZO L. REV. 287, 293-314, 321 (1989).
-
(1989)
Cardozo L. Rev.
, vol.11
, pp. 287
-
-
Brian Simpson, A.W.1
-
2
-
-
0345984275
-
-
Email from Linda Mawdsley, Membership Manager, Liverpool Cotton Exchange, to author (Oct. 27, 1997) (noting that the Liverpool Cotton Association trading rules govern approximately fifty percent of international cotton contracts)
-
Email from Linda Mawdsley, Membership Manager, Liverpool Cotton Exchange, to author (Oct. 27, 1997) (noting that the Liverpool Cotton Association trading rules govern approximately fifty percent of international cotton contracts).
-
-
-
-
3
-
-
0345984274
-
-
A cash market for a commodity is one in which the commodity is bought and sold -on any of a variety of payment terms - for actual delivery
-
A cash market for a commodity is one in which the commodity is bought and sold -on any of a variety of payment terms - for actual delivery.
-
-
-
-
4
-
-
0347245190
-
-
Minutes of the American Cotton Shippers Association/American Textile Manufacturers Institute Joint Meeting (1984) (75-80% of the cotton bought by United States mills is subject to the SMRs)
-
Minutes of the American Cotton Shippers Association/American Textile Manufacturers Institute Joint Meeting (1984) (75-80% of the cotton bought by United States mills is subject to the SMRs).
-
-
-
-
5
-
-
0346615504
-
Southern Mill Rules
-
ACSA "is the spokesman for private cotton merchants of the United States." Am. Cotton Shippers Ass'n, Southern Mill Rules, in SOUTHERN MILL RULES FOR BUYING AND SELLING OF AMERICAN COTTON 2 (1996), available at http://www.acsa-cotton.org/ About_ACSA/Search%20Rules/about_acsa.html [hereinafter SMRs]. This rulebook also includes the Rules and Regulations of the Cotton States Arbitration Board [hereinafter CSAB Rules] and an Outline of Services Available for Quality Arbitrations By Cotton States Arbitration Board and Technical Arbitrations By the Board of Appeals Under Southern Mill Rules [hereinafter Outline of Services]. Id.
-
(1996)
Southern Mill Rules for Buying and Selling of American Cotton
, pp. 2
-
-
-
6
-
-
0347245188
-
-
The ATMI is the "trade association for manufacturers of textile mill products . . . [Its] members . . . . process some 75 percent of all domestically grown cotton consumed annually in the United States." Id
-
The ATMI is the "trade association for manufacturers of textile mill products . . . [Its] members . . . . process some 75 percent of all domestically grown cotton consumed annually in the United States." Id.
-
-
-
-
7
-
-
0346615496
-
-
The ACSA and ATMI rules committees meet together at least once a year to consider revising the SMRs. However, because the associations' interests are often antagonistic, and amendments must also be ratified by the membership of both organizations, the revision process is slow. See Letter from R. C. Dickerson, Executive Vice-President and Secretary of ACSA, to R. K. Vincent (January 21, 1952), in connection with SEAB Case No. 61 ("With regard to your suggestions about clarifying some of the Southern Mill Rules, beg to say that this is a long and tedious process . . . it is very difficult to secure any changes and it usually takes a couple of years at least before such changes can be effective.")
-
The ACSA and ATMI rules committees meet together at least once a year to consider revising the SMRs. However, because the associations' interests are often antagonistic, and amendments must also be ratified by the membership of both organizations, the revision process is slow. See Letter from R. C. Dickerson, Executive Vice-President and Secretary of ACSA, to R. K. Vincent (January 21, 1952), in connection with SEAB Case No. 61 ("With regard to your suggestions about clarifying some of the Southern Mill Rules, beg to say that this is a long and tedious process . . . it is very difficult to secure any changes and it usually takes a couple of years at least before such changes can be effective.").
-
-
-
-
8
-
-
0346615491
-
-
These organizations are the Western Cotton Shippers Association ("WCSA"), the Atlantic Cotton Association ("ACA"), the Southern Cotton Association ("SCA"), and the Texas Cotton Association ("TCA"). A fifth organization, the Arkansas-Missouri Cotton Trade Association, existed as late as 1990 but is now defunct. Its former members were absorbed by the other regional associations. In the past, there were also numerous local and regional cotton exchanges. Today, with the exception of the Memphis and Greenwood Exchanges, most are either defunct or have greatly curtailed their activities
-
These organizations are the Western Cotton Shippers Association ("WCSA"), the Atlantic Cotton Association ("ACA"), the Southern Cotton Association ("SCA"), and the Texas Cotton Association ("TCA"). A fifth organization, the Arkansas-Missouri Cotton Trade Association, existed as late as 1990 but is now defunct. Its former members were absorbed by the other regional associations. In the past, there were also numerous local and regional cotton exchanges. Today, with the exception of the Memphis and Greenwood Exchanges, most are either defunct or have greatly curtailed their activities.
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
0347875761
-
-
A modest fee is charged for these services, see MEMPHIS COTTON EXCHANGE BY-LAWS, Art. IV, § 9 (1993) [hereinafter MCE BY-LAWS] (providing that "[i]n all cases of Arbitration concerning cotton, the charges shall be as determined by the Board of Directors")
-
A modest fee is charged for these services, see MEMPHIS COTTON EXCHANGE BY-LAWS, Art. IV, § 9 (1993) [hereinafter MCE BY-LAWS] (providing that "[i]n all cases of Arbitration concerning cotton, the charges shall be as determined by the Board of Directors").
-
-
-
-
11
-
-
0345984270
-
-
See, e.g., id. at Art. IV, § 8 ("Any member refusing to submit to an arbitration when asked forby another member or a nonmember, providing the Arbitration Committee consider [sic] there exist good grounds for an arbitration, or to abide by any award or decision of said Committee when rendered," may be expelled from the Exchange)
-
See, e.g., id. at Art. IV, § 8 ("Any member refusing to submit to an arbitration when asked forby another member or a nonmember, providing the Arbitration Committee consider [sic] there exist good grounds for an arbitration, or to abide by any award or decision of said Committee when rendered," may be expelled from the Exchange).
-
-
-
-
12
-
-
0346615489
-
-
note
-
In earlier years, these organizations sponsored two sets of trade rules and two arbitration boards. One of these boards, the New England Board of Appeals ("NEBoA"), resolved disputes in the New England region. The other, the South Eastern Appeal Board ("SEAB"), resolved disputes in the Southern region. Today, the Board of Appeals ("BoA"), sometimes referred to as the "Southeastern Appeal Board," uses the Southern Mill Rules to resolve all disputes regardless of where in the country they arise. Am. Cotton Shippers Ass'n, Outline of Services, supra note 5. Although these tribunals are referred to as "appeals" boards, they are tribunals of first instance.
-
-
-
-
13
-
-
0345984255
-
-
The BoA requires each litigant who is a member of ACSA or ATMI to pay a filing fee of $400 per case, but refunds the fee to the prevailing party. When cases are filed by nonmembers or their attorneys, a fee of the larger of $800 or the actual cost of the arbitration is charged. Id. at 38
-
The BoA requires each litigant who is a member of ACSA or ATMI to pay a filing fee of $400 per case, but refunds the fee to the prevailing party. When cases are filed by nonmembers or their attorneys, a fee of the larger of $800 or the actual cost of the arbitration is charged. Id. at 38.
-
-
-
-
14
-
-
0347875748
-
-
See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. XI, § 43 (authorizing the CSAB - which is supervised by representatives of both ATMI and ACSA - to arbitrate quality disputes between shippers and mills). In 1972, however, "[t]the Executive Committee [of the CSAB] made arrangements with the Board of Supervising Cotton Examiners . . . now the Quality Control Section, of the U.S. Department of Agriculture in Memphis, to perform [quality] arbitration services for the industry." Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 34
-
See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. XI, § 43 (authorizing the CSAB - which is supervised by representatives of both ATMI and ACSA - to arbitrate quality disputes between shippers and mills). In 1972, however, "[t]the Executive Committee [of the CSAB] made arrangements with the Board of Supervising Cotton Examiners . . . now the Quality Control Section, of the U.S. Department of Agriculture in Memphis, to perform [quality] arbitration services for the industry." Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 34.
-
-
-
-
15
-
-
0346615503
-
-
Supra note 4. This is usually achieved by incorporating the SMRs into the contract
-
Supra note 4. This is usually achieved by incorporating the SMRs into the contract.
-
-
-
-
16
-
-
0346615451
-
-
The importance of these institutions is suggested by, among other things, the fact that the MCE Trading Rules and By-Laws, the SMRs and BoA procedures, and the trading and arbitration rules of the Liverpool Cotton Association are an important focus of the curriculum at the educational institute for new industry participants held at Rhodes College each summer. See infra note 224 and accompanying text
-
The importance of these institutions is suggested by, among other things, the fact that the MCE Trading Rules and By-Laws, the SMRs and BoA procedures, and the trading and arbitration rules of the Liverpool Cotton Association are an important focus of the curriculum at the educational institute for new industry participants held at Rhodes College each summer. See infra note 224 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
17
-
-
0345984260
-
-
note
-
Unless otherwise noted, the expression "MCE arbitration tribunal," refers to the Exchange's "regular standing Arbitration" tribunal. TRADING RULES OF THE MEMPHIS COTTON EXCHANGE, R. 34, cl. 2 [hereinafter MCE TR]. Since the early days of the exchange, this tribunal has handled disputes between members, between members and nonmembers, and even, on occasion, disputes between two nonmembers. In 1995, however, in an attempt to create a public perception of fairness, the MCE established a separate tribunal for disputes involving nonmembers. This tribunal operates under its own, somewhat different procedural rules. The arbitration panel consists of three arbitrators, arbitrators are chosen by agreement of the parties, and there are no appeals. If the claim is for less than $25,000 and the parties agree, only one arbitrator need hear the case. Nonbinding prearbitration mediation is also available if agreed to by the parties. One of the more striking differences between regular MCE arbitrations and these special arbitrations is that the special tribunal's procedures make it easier for parties to get information from one another. See id. at R. 43, cl. 4 ("Upon the request of any party to the arbitration made in writing with notice to the other party, the Chairman of the Rule 43 Arbitration Committee shall issue subpoenas as provided in the Federal Arbitration Act and/or the Tennessee Uniform Arbitration Act."). This provision was considered undesirable by the MCE board but was adopted on the advice of a prominent industry attorney who told the board that it was needed in order to maintain the perception that the tribunal was fair to nonmembers. Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997).
-
-
-
-
18
-
-
0347245191
-
-
note
-
See Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 35. When the arbitrators do not agree, they are authorized to jointly appoint a third arbitrator. From 1975 to 1996, however, the BoA heard twenty-eight cases, none of which required the appointment of a third arbitrator. See BoA opinions 1975-1996.
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
0346615490
-
-
Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 35
-
Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 35.
-
-
-
-
20
-
-
0346615502
-
-
See, e.g., Case Record, MCE Case No. 832 (1985) (noting that multiple hearings were held); Letter from the MCE Vice-President and Secretary, to the Parties (March 11, 1985), in connection with MCE Case No. 832 (informing the parties that they will have to appear in front of the arbitration committee)
-
See, e.g., Case Record, MCE Case No. 832 (1985) (noting that multiple hearings were held); Letter from the MCE Vice-President and Secretary, to the Parties (March 11, 1985), in connection with MCE Case No. 832 (informing the parties that they will have to appear in front of the arbitration committee).
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
0347245186
-
-
MCE arbitrators also take an active role in questioning the parties and witnesses. See, e.g., Questions Reference, typewritten sheets filed with the case record for MCE Case No. 835 (1991) (listing questions for the arbitrators to ask the parties); MCE Case No. 839 (1991) (revealing in the transcript that arbitrators questioned the parties)
-
MCE arbitrators also take an active role in questioning the parties and witnesses. See, e.g., Questions Reference, typewritten sheets filed with the case record for MCE Case No. 835 (1991) (listing questions for the arbitrators to ask the parties); MCE Case No. 839 (1991) (revealing in the transcript that arbitrators questioned the parties).
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
0347245182
-
-
note
-
See Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 36 (nothing that the BoA can "ask either of the parties for additional information or clarification of statements made in their briefs"); see also Memorandum of the Arbitrators (Aug. 24, 1953), in connection with SEAB Case No. 71 (referring to a request for submission of additional information); Letter from ACSA Secretary to Arbitrator (Jan. 23, 1996), in connection with BoA Case No. 139 ("Should you require any further details pertaining to this case, please contact me and I'll make every effort to obtain the information requested"); Letter from Arbitrators to the CSAB Secretary (March 28, 1984), in connection with BoA Case No. 118 (requesting additional information); NEBoA Case No. 280 (1929) (declining to render a judgment pending submission of additional information); Letter from the MCE Executive Vice-President and Secretary, to the Plaintiff's Attorney (March 9, 1988), in connection with MCE Case No. 833 (requesting information about the nature of the plaintiff's business and additional documents).
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
0345984262
-
-
note
-
See SMRS, supra note 5, at Art. VII, § 32 ("Claims for loss in weight or payment for gain in weight must be made within seven business days from receipt of the cotton, or of the last portion of the shipment."); id. at Art. VIII, § 36 ("Notice of claims for variations in invoice tare allowances must be given seller by buyer within twenty business days from receipt of cotton."); id. at Art. VIII, §37 ("All claims for variations in invoice tare allowances must be filed within nine months from receipt of cotton."); id. at Art. IX, § 39 ("Claims as to quality must be made within ten business days from the date of the receipt of the last portion of the shipment except, where cotton is deliverable in monthly installments, the claims shall be based on each separate installment.").
-
-
-
-
24
-
-
0347875753
-
-
MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 34, cl. 1
-
MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 34, cl. 1.
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
0347875764
-
-
note
-
See id. at R. 5, cl. 5 ("[A]any rejection for differences in grade and/or staple will only apply on cotton if it is shipped out of the point of origin or resampled within ninety (90) days from date of payment by Buyer."); id. at R. 18, cl. 1 ("[When cotton is rejected as being of nonstandard density], market difference is to be adjusted between Buyer and Seller provided a claim is made within 10 days from invoice date."); id. at R. 22, cl. 1 ("[R]eplacements must be made within ten days from date of rejections.").
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
0346615488
-
-
BoA Case No. 135 (1992); BoA Case No. 117 (1983); BoA Case No. 121 (1985); MCE Case No. 839 (1991)
-
BoA Case No. 135 (1992); BoA Case No. 117 (1983); BoA Case No. 121 (1985); MCE Case No. 839 (1991).
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
0345984273
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., MCE Case No. 835 (1991) (stating only that "[t]he Arbitration Committee of the Memphis Cotton Exchange based on written evidence supplied by both parties as well as the oral testimony of both parties rules that [Defendant] is not entitled to carrying charges and [Plaintiff] is not entitled to penalties. This decision was the unanimous decision of this Arbitration Committee"); BoA Case No. 139 (1996); BoA Case No. 129 (1990). It is not entirely clear why the format of opinions is so variable. One BoA arbitrator explained that he was not an eloquent man, so when he wrote, the opinions were short, while his fellow arbitrator, with whom he served for many years, was a "wordsmith," educated at Yale (actually, a check of alumni rolls indicated it was Harvard), who liked to go on at length. Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #2, former BoA arbitrator (no date).
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
0347875755
-
-
note
-
The ATMI and the ACSA keep BoA opinions, along with the briefs and evidence submitted, on file for inspection by their members. They occasionally receive requests for further information about cases or copies of the supporting papers. See, e.g., Letter from the Chairman of the Board of [very large] Cotton Company to the ACSA Executive Secretary (June 19, 1967), in connection with BoA Case No. 98 ("I think there is something in the libel laws which prevents you from naming the buyer and the seller in this case, but I think it is proper for you to give the name of the seller on request and I do hereby request that you give us the name of the seller who refuses to be bound by a trade arbitration because an Act of God (crop failure) makes it impossible for him to deliver what another seller has offered to deliver at 8¢ higher."). Such requests are more common when the BoA's opinion does not contain a clear description of the facts found and the reasoning used. Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (no date); see also Entire SMR Case No. 130 Sent To Following Active Members Per [ACSA Executive], BoA Case No. 130 (Feb. 5, 1991) (noting that the entire record of the case was sent to thirty-three members who had requested it, most likely because the opinion was brief and unclear). In earlier years, the associations routinely circulated briefs and supporting evidence with the opinions. See, e.g., ACSA Series A-Circular Letter No. 41 (Dec. 21, 1951) ("We are enclosing herewith for your information and guidance copies of briefs and summary of question [sic] submitted together with decision and minority report in Southeastern Appeals Board Case No. 62. This case is rather involved, but we recommend that it be studied carefully by all shippers to domestic mills."). Although the reasons for this practice are unclear, giving transactors access to the same information as the tribunal makes it easier for them to determine whether the tribunal was impartial. Establishing its impartiality might have been especially important to the BoA, which resolves disputes between defined groups of market participants with often conflicting interests. Today, these supporting materials are only circulated in exceptional circumstances. See, e.g., ACSA Series A-Circular No. 96 (Feb. 25, 1987), addressing BoA Case No. 124 (noting that in addition to the opinion, the association was "also enclosing 'Seller's Statement of Facts' and 'Seller's Argument and Brief.' Supporting documents on pages 15-17 are also provided. We did not deem intervening documentation necessary for reproduction").
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
0347245183
-
-
note
-
Although in important BoA cases, parties' identities become quickly known through gossip, Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (June 1996); infra note 172, the nonpublication of names may nevertheless be desirable from the perspective of industry insiders. BoA opinions often contain information indicating that a firm may be on the verge of financial distress (but not yet within the legal preference period). The practice of not revealing names keeps this information from industry outsiders -such as railroads, truckers, and insurance companies - for as long as possible, while the industry's well-developed gossip networks help to spread it to industry insiders. See infra notes 124-129 and accompanying text (describing these networks). The practice may therefore enable insiders to better protect their positions with the distressed firm, by, for example, cashing out their position. See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. XIX, § 56 (providing, in part that, "[i]f either party to the contract enters bankruptcy or admits insolvency, the other party may cancel the undelivered portion of the contract, with the market difference to be adjusted between the buyer and the seller, with one-half cent per pound penalty against the party in bankruptcy or admitting insolvency").
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
0347875763
-
-
note
-
In the past, BoA opinions sometimes mentioned prior opinions as persuasive or controlling authority. See, e.g., NEBoA Case No. 181 (1924) (citing NEBoA Case No. 97 as controlling authority for the interpretation of Rule 61, defining "receipt of cotton"); NEBoA Case No. 187 (1924) (holding that NEBoA Case No. 60 governs). Arbitrators also occasionally attempted to distinguish earlier cases. See, e.g., NEBoA Case No. 276 (1929) (rejecting an argument based on an earlier decision, and explaining that the opinion cited, "was based on special circumstances and does not apply in this case"). However, references to prior cases gradually became less common and are quite rare today. One case explicitly repudiates the duty of the BoA to consider prior decisions. See SEAB Case No. 75 (1955) (noting that "[t]his Appeal Board has recently stated that it was not bound by previous decisions of the Board). Nevertheless, the long service of certain individuals on the BoA ensures that there is some continuity in the tribunal's decisions. For example, from 1978-1996, the same ACSA representative served in seventeen of the twenty-seven cases decided by the BoA and the same ATMI representative served in fifteen of the cases. Mention of prior decisions was even rarer at the MCE. From 1944-1991, only one MCE opinion mentions a prior case, and even there it is only mentioned because it was raised by one of the parties and the arbitrators give it no weight. See MCE Case No. 786 (1951).
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
0347875756
-
-
note
-
MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. IV, § 5. From 1944 to 1991, only four of the ninety-two decisions rendered by the MCE arbitration tribunal were not unanimous. Of these four decisions, three were appealed. Two of the decisions were affirmed. See MCE App Case No. 28 (1952); MCE App. Case No. 29 (1952). One of the decisions was reversed. See MCE App. Case No. 27 (1947). When an appeal is requested, the "party whose claim differs most from the final award" must pay the actual cost of the appeal. MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. V, § 3.
-
-
-
-
32
-
-
0346615493
-
-
Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 36-38; MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. XV, § 3 ("Any claim [of indebtedness] allowed by the Arbitration Committee and remaining unpaid for ten days may then be pressed for immediate settlement by requesting same in writing to the Secretary . . . and five days shall be allowed for settlement.")
-
Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 36-38; MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. XV, § 3 ("Any claim [of indebtedness] allowed by the Arbitration Committee and remaining unpaid for ten days may then be pressed for immediate settlement by requesting same in writing to the Secretary . . . and five days shall be allowed for settlement.").
-
-
-
-
33
-
-
0346615494
-
-
note
-
Based on information in the moving papers and opinions in all MCE cases decided from 1978-1991, the average time from filing to disposition was thirty-nine days. The longest case took eighty-four days, while the shortest took eleven days. Although the MCE Rules do not dictate a precise time frame for resolving a dispute, the fact that a defendant is given only three days to respond to a claim before the committee is permitted to hear the case ex parte suggests that the Exchange considers prompt dispositions important. MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 34, cl. 1.
-
-
-
-
34
-
-
0346615498
-
-
The MCE rules also attempt to ensure payment by requiring the defendant to post a pre-arbitration bond in the amount of the claim. MCE BY-LAWS, suprcr note 10, at Art. IV, § 4. In the past, strict compliance with the rule was enforced, but today bonds are not always required in practice. Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (no date)
-
The MCE rules also attempt to ensure payment by requiring the defendant to post a pre-arbitration bond in the amount of the claim. MCE BY-LAWS, suprcr note 10, at Art. IV, § 4. In the past, strict compliance with the rule was enforced, but today bonds are not always required in practice. Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (no date).
-
-
-
-
35
-
-
0347245184
-
-
note
-
The SMRs, however, "reserve [to the BoA] the privilege of refusing action on any dispute submitted if it feels the case at point has disagreements not involving SMR[S] or it does not have sufficient evidence to properly judge the issues." Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 35-36; see also ACSA, Series A-Circular Letter No. 40 (1953) (discussing this privilege). This privilege is occasionally exercised. See, e.g., BoA Case No. 123 (1987) (dedining to issue a ruling without giving an explanation); SEAB Case No. 64 (1952) (same); BoA Case No. 115 (1981) (declining jurisdiction on the grounds that the BoA "should not act as a general referee or become an instrument for making general market determinations"); BoA Case No. 114 (1981) ("In the request for a Board of Appeals decision seller did not specify a rule section under which the Board of Appeals might concern itself. Further, the members of the Board of Appeals are not aware of any specific rule section which would appropriately apply to the dispute in question, under which it could determine an allowance as settlement . . . it would be improper for the Board of Appeals to render a decision in this case.").
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
0346615487
-
-
See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. XVII, § 54 ("Buyer and seller shall have the privilege of incorporating any other rules, not in conflict with the spirit of the above rules, in their contracts.")
-
See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. XVII, § 54 ("Buyer and seller shall have the privilege of incorporating any other rules, not in conflict with the spirit of the above rules, in their contracts.").
-
-
-
-
37
-
-
0346615495
-
-
Id. at Art. IV, § 16
-
Id. at Art. IV, § 16.
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
0347875758
-
-
Id. at Art. III, § 13
-
Id. at Art. III, § 13.
-
-
-
-
39
-
-
0345984263
-
-
Id. at Art. III, § 10
-
Id. at Art. III, § 10.
-
-
-
-
40
-
-
0347245189
-
-
note
-
See MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 2, cl. 1 ("These Trading Rules shall apply to all purchases and sales between members of the Memphis Cotton Exchange unless otherwise agreed in writing."). The MCE Trading Rules contain only two mandatory provisions. Id. at R. 31, cl. 1 ("Any exception to these rules can be made by mutual agreement at time of sale excepting Rule 1, Clause 4 and Rule 2."); id. at R. 1, cl. 4 ("Both Buyer and Seller shall be primarily liable to each other for the fulfillment of all contracts.").
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
0345984265
-
-
note
-
Some trade rules, however, would be of questionable validity if included in a contract adjudicated under the Code. First, at times when cotton prices were very low, the trade rules that provide for the payment of a one-half cent per pound penalty might, if included in a contract subject to the Code, have been vulnerable to attack under U.C.C. § 2-718 (1991) and the relevant case law, on the grounds that they were invalid penalties since they were not a genuine attempt to pre-estimate damages. See, e.g., Equitable Lumber Corp. v. IPA Land Dev. Corp., 344 N.E.2d 391 (N.Y. 1976). Today, however, these damage measures, if included in a contract subject to the Code, would most likely be enforceable, since their magnitude is insignificant given world cotton prices. Second, SMR Art. XIX, § 56, SMRs supra note 5, which provides that, "[i]f either party to the contract enters bankruptcy or admits insolvency, the other party may cancel the undelivered portion of the contract, with the market difference to be adjusted between the buyer and the seller, with one-half cent per pound penalty against the party in bankruptcy or admitting insolvency," might be deemed an invalid ipso facto clause under the 1978 Bankruptcy Code.
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
0345984266
-
-
note
-
The SMRs use the word "reasonable" once. See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. XI, § 47 (requiring the buyer to "exercise all reasonable care of rejected bales"). The MCE Rules use it twice. See MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 43, cl. 2 (requiring complaints filed in arbitration to be written "in reasonable detail"); id. at R. 5, cl. 5 (requiring claims of fraudulently packed cotton or false substitutions to be "presented within a reasonable length of time"). In addition, from 1944-1991, only one MCE opinion used the word "reasonable," and the case was one that involved the proper time for making a claim for fraudulently packed bales, something the MCE rules explicitly state must be done within a "reasonable length of time." Id.; MCE Case No. 760 (1945) (noting that "in reaching its decision [the arbitration panel] could find no evidence of fraudulent packing," and that because the buyer had failed to inspect the cotton for six months, "the elapsed time cannot be termed 'reasonable in this case for making a claim").
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
0345984264
-
-
U.C.C. § 1-106 (1991)
-
U.C.C. § 1-106 (1991).
-
-
-
-
44
-
-
0347875757
-
-
See infra note 135 and accompanying text (discussing the reasons that the market difference measure is under-compensatory, particularly in merchant-to-mill transactions)
-
See infra note 135 and accompanying text (discussing the reasons that the market difference measure is under-compensatory, particularly in merchant-to-mill transactions).
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
0346615500
-
-
note
-
SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. IV, § 18C. See also BoA Case No. 139 (1996) (where the buyer claimed $158,500 in consequential damages in its brief, but this was not mentoned in the arbitrators' opinion and no consequential damages of any kind were awarded). The SMRs further provide that the market price shall be determined from "three bona fide offers on the identical quality and with identical terms to that contracted," given to the aggrieved party and that "[a] buyer's purchase when the seller breaches] . . . shall be based on the lowest of the three offers. [While a] seller's sale [when the buyer breaches] . . . shall be based on the highest of the three offers." Id. In addition, "[t]he party to receive market differences must present [a] detailed settlement amount in writing to the other party within three business days. [And t]he party receiving bona fide settlement invoice must pay with good funds within five business days of receving [sic] such invoice." Id. In ACSSA-ATMI debates over the adoption of the three-quote rule, the shippers "felt it would be better to have an understanding [of the magnitude of damages] at the time [of breach], rather than after the fact, and thus avoid referring matters to the Board of Appeals. Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1976).
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
0346615497
-
-
note
-
See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. V, § 26 (requiring a penalty of one-half cent per pound in addition to interest when the buyer does not pay the draft or invoice within five business days after delivery); id. at Art. XVIII, § 55 (providing that if the seller fails to certify the origin or growth of the cotton, or certifies "growth other than that contracted for and such certification shows the cotton to be of irrigated growth, where raingrown cotton is specified or raingrown cotton where irrigated cotton is specified, the seller shall pay to the buyer a penalty of one cent per pound on that portion of the contract").
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
0347245185
-
-
See MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 22, cl. 2
-
See MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 22, cl. 2.
-
-
-
-
48
-
-
0345984267
-
-
note
-
See id. at R. 11, cl. 1 ("The penalty for failure on the part of the Seller to deliver cotton within the required time under above rules, shall be 10¢, per bale per day minimum to be paid by the Seller to Buyer and in no event shall this penalty exceed 25¢ per bale per day, but any excess over and above the 10¢ per bale per day is to be subject to the Buyer's being able to furnish sufficient proof of loss for such excess.").
-
-
-
-
49
-
-
0345984272
-
-
note
-
Id. at R. 11, cl. 2 ("The penalty for failure on the part of the Buyer to pay for cotton or furnish shipping instructions in accordance with the above rules shall be 10¢ per bale per day plus storage, insurance and interest accumulated against the Seller during delay. Penalties accruing against the Buyer shall be added to the invoice, and those accruing against the Seller shall be deducted from the invoice.").
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
0347875762
-
-
note
-
In addition, the MCE's sensitivity to transactors' possible desire to keep information private is reflected in MCE TR, at R. 11, cl. 1, reprinted in part supra note 48 (providing for late penalties a buyer can get without revealing any firm-specific information, and larger penalties he is permitted to seek if he reveals additional information).
-
-
-
-
51
-
-
0346615501
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Buyer's Brief at 23, BoA Case No. 135 (1992); Seller's Brief at 8, BoA Case No. 135 (1992) (where arguments relating to "good faith" and "bad faith" are made in the briefs but are not taken into account in the arbitration opinion); Buyer's Brief at 2, BoA Case No. 126 (1987) ("[T]here is an obligation of good faith implied in all contracts and in all commercial dealings between buyers and sellers."); Buyer's Brief at 4, BoA Case No. 85 (1961) ("Seller has failed to live up to a contract, made in good faith and binding in every respect.").
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
0345984271
-
-
note
-
From 1944-1990, good faith was mentioned in only one MCE arbitration opinion. See MCE Case No. 816 (1966) (noting that the "[d]efendant acted in good faith and did everything he could to expedite the shipment;" the arbitrators ruled for the defendant but also noted that they were ruling as they did because the mill had agreed to take the cotton at a later time). Similarly, from 1978-1990, the BoA issued eighteen opinions, none of which mentioned "good faith." It is possible, however, that in the few cases where compromise decisions were rendered on the grounds that both parties behaved badly, notions of good faith may have implicitly influenced arbitrator decision making.
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
0347245187
-
-
note
-
BoA Case No. 122 (1987) (where BoA arbitrators considered the result they reached under the rules so unjust that their opinion contained a nonbinding "recommendation" that the Seller give the Buyer a type of offset that many other sellers in the market were giving to their buyers at that time); MCE Case No. 832 (1985) ("This Committee has abided to the best of its ability by the applicable rules of the Memphis Cotton Exchange. It is the feeling of this Committee, however, that a penalty is being imposed unjustly and even though we were committed to follow the rules, it is the very strong feeling of this Committee that, had both parties deligently [sic] and agressively [sic] pursued the committment [sic] of this contract, this Arbitration would not have been necessary. Unfortunately, this was not the case.").
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
0345984269
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., BoA Case No. 137 (1996) ("This Board's opinion is that the contract was poorly handled by both parties under unusual circumstances and that their gross misunderstanding should be shared."); BoA Case No. 130 (1990) ("We feel this transaction was poorly handled by both parties and that blame should be shared."); MCE Case No. 837 (1991) (noting that "[Plaintiff] did not exercise dilligence [sic] in the maintenance of the contract in dispute"); MCE Case No. 822 (1971) (where the committee ruled: "(1) that the Committee take no part in a case involving a transaction which was, as admitted in writing in the evidence submitted, in direct violation of the regulations governing such transactions; (2) that the parties involved would have been wise to settle their differences in this particular case as quickly and as quietly as possible"); MCE Case No. 809 (1960) ("This Committee would like to point out that the risk involved in a contract of this nature is very great tor all concerned.").
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
0346615499
-
-
note
-
This philosophy is reflected in numerous Code provisions and Official Comments. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 1-102 (b) (1991) ("Underlying purposes and policies of this Act are . . . to permit the continued expansion of commercial practices through custom, usage and agreement of the parties . . . ."); id. at § 1-103, § 2-314(2) (a), § 2-504(b), § 2-609(2), § 1-102 cmt. 1; § 1-205 cmt. 1; id. at § 2-202 cmt. 1(b) (explaining that language is to be given the "meaning which arises out of the commercial context in which it was used"); id. at § 2-202 cmt. 2.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
0347875759
-
-
See id. at § 2-208 cmt. 1 ("The parties themselves know best what they have meant by their words of agreement and their action under that agreement is the best indication of what that meaning was.")
-
See id. at § 2-208 cmt. 1 ("The parties themselves know best what they have meant by their words of agreement and their action under that agreement is the best indication of what that meaning was.").
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
0347875760
-
-
Given the expertise of these arbitrators, however, these considerations may enter the moving papers and/or influence the arbitrators' decision-making processes in ways too subtle to detect
-
Given the expertise of these arbitrators, however, these considerations may enter the moving papers and/or influence the arbitrators' decision-making processes in ways too subtle to detect.
-
-
-
-
58
-
-
0345984268
-
-
note
-
When ten merchants who had served as MCE arbitrators were asked: "[I]f the parties could establish that despite what was written in their contract they always behaved in a different way would you apply this different, informal understanding, rather than the relevant trade rule," two said yes, seven said no, and one was uncertain, explaining that it would depend on the identity of the parties. Briefs occasionally make arguments based on course of performance or course of dealing, but these considerations do not appear to influence arbitral decisions. See, e.g., Record, BoA Case No. 122 (1987) (where both briefs contain numerous references to course of performance and course of dealing, but these considerations are not mentioned in the arbitrators' opinion).
-
-
-
-
59
-
-
0345984257
-
-
note
-
However the MCE Trade Rules contain one particularized reference to custom, see MCE TR supra note 17. at R. 23. cl. 1 ("Rules 20, 21, and 22 are in no way to change or nullify the present rules and customs of handling sales of consigned or F.O.B. cotton when sold on actual samples."), and in quality arbitrations conducted by the CSAB, custom may be looked to when there are gaps not covered by the contract or relevant trade rules, see CSAB rules supra note 5, at III, R. 8. ("All arbitrations will be held strictly in accordance with the letter and intent of contract and in case all points of any contract are not covered by the rules . . . such points are to be arbitrated according to the general interpretation of the trade in regard to the same . . . . ").
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
0347419821
-
Merchant Law in a Merchant Court: Rethinking the Code's Search for Immanent Business Norms
-
See Lisa Bernstein, Merchant Law in a Merchant Court: Rethinking the Code's Search for Immanent Business Norms, 144 U. PA. L. REV. 1765 (1996) [hereinafter Merchant Law] (discussing the ways that courts applying the Code permit custom to vary or trump explicit contractual provisions).
-
(1996)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.144
, pp. 1765
-
-
Bernstein, L.1
-
61
-
-
0345984256
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., SEAB Case No. 77 (1956) (noting the buyer's contention that when "mills buy cotton from . . . Group B . . . according to precedent and established custom . . . it is understood to be compressed cotton," but rejecting it on the grounds that "while we recognize that precedent and established custom play a part in any transaction, the terms of the purchase [in this case] were definitely stated as subject to Southern Mill Rules and under Rule XVI, Section 53, DENSITY is covered . . . we therefore think Seller is right"); see also BoA Case No. 94 (1964) ("There were many contentions in very long briefs from both sides. However, this Board can only rule on the contract.").
-
-
-
-
62
-
-
0347245177
-
-
note
-
In one case decided in 1935, the BoA looked to custom to define a term used but not fully defined in the either the contract or the trade rules. See NEBoA Case No. 313 (1935) (holding that because the contract used but did not define the term "Western Growth," and the relevant trade rules did not define it either, "the Board must therefore base this decision on trade custom"); see also NEBoA Case. No. 278 (1929) (noting that the terms of the contract were indefinite, and looking to the "correspondence submitted and the custom of the trade" in rendering its judgment). However, BoA opinions do occasionally refer to custom as an additional justification for a result reached on other grounds, or mention it in passing while attaching no particular significance to it. A similar approach to the role of custom in adjudication is used at the WCSA. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with WCSA Executive (May 28, 1997) ("Whether [custom and usage] are viewed as relevant [in arbitration] depends on whether it relates to a subject about which there is a trade rule. If there is a trade rule on point, the custom is irrelevant. If there is not, then it might be looked to, to fill a gap, assuming that the contract too is silent on the point.").
-
-
-
-
63
-
-
0346615486
-
-
note
-
For example, from 1929-1951, only four of the forty-two opinions issued by the BoA even mentioned custom or usage of trade. See NEBoA Case No. 313 (1935) supra note 62; NEBoA Case No. 308 (1931) (rejecting a buyer's claim that "the custom of the trade requires the Seller to ship bales not pounds" on the grounds that the New England Terms [a precursor to the SMRs] governed the trade and that Rule 27 of those terms "definitely states that cotton shall be delivered on a poundage basis."); NEBoA Case No. 280 (1929) Supplementary Decision (noting, in passing, that something was not a custom and withdrawing the original judgment pending submission of additional information); NEBoA Case No. 278 (1929), supra note 62.
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
0345984253
-
-
note
-
See MCE Case No. 807 (1960) (holding that the plaintiff prevailed since it shipped on a route "usually used by shippers to this destination"); MCE Case No. 791 (1952) (rejecting a position based on custom and deciding the case on the basis of the SMRs); MCE Case No. 793 (1952) ("In ruling on the staple length the committee took into consideration the custom of the Trade in the territory involved . . . . also four affidavits furnished by the plaintiff."). In addition, custom is mentioned in one MCE Appeal, MCE Appeal of Case No. 787 (1952) (where, in affirming the decision below, which made no mention of custom, a custom is mentioned).
-
-
-
-
65
-
-
0346352833
-
Private Commercial Law
-
Peter Newman ed., [hereinafter Bernstein, PALGRAVE]
-
Formalistic adjudicative approaches are not uncommon in merchant-run private commercial law systems. See, e.g., Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60 (describing the formalistic adjudicative approach of the National Grain and Feed Association's merchant arbitration system). See generally Lisa Bernstein, Private Commercial Law, in THE NEW PALGRAVE ENCYCLOPEDIA OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW (Peter Newman ed., 1998) [hereinafter Bernstein, PALGRAVE].
-
(1998)
The New Palgrave Encyclopedia of Economics and the Law
-
-
Bernstein, L.1
-
66
-
-
0346615485
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., BoA Case No. 97 (1967) (revised) ("In most appeal cases, there are statements made by one side or the other, or both, that should in all fairness be taken into consideration in a friendly settlement. However, the Appeal Board must adhere strictly to the rules To deviate therefrom would cause endless confusion and arguments. This Board can rule only upon the written contract."); see also supra note 53 (discussing MCE Case No. 832).
-
-
-
-
67
-
-
0346615482
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #4, retired BoA arbitrator (Mar. 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #4, retired BoA arbitrator (Mar. 1997).
-
-
-
-
68
-
-
0347875750
-
-
note
-
See Outline of Services, supra note 5, at 37 ("Should either party seek to have judgement entered upon the award pursuant to the 9 U.S.C. § 9, they may do so by applying to a court of competent jurisdiction located in Memphis, Tennessee."); MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 43, cl. 1 (noting that when the MCE enters an award "judgment upon the arbitrators' award [in a proceeding under the new arbitration rule, see supra note 17] may be entered in any court having jurisdiction thereof").
-
-
-
-
69
-
-
0346615483
-
-
note
-
MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. IV, § 8. The MCE has also implemented another safeguard against the judgment-proof problem. In addition to paying the annual membership fee members are required to purchase a membership in the Exchange. The By-Laws provide that when a member fails to pay an arbitration award, the prevailing party has a right to make a claim against his membership. If the noncomplying party still refuses to pay, his membership is auctioned off and the award is paid from the proceeds. At one time, these memberships were valued at about $20,000, Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997), although their value appears to have fluctuated widely, at least when sold at forced auctions. See Keyer v. MCE, 135 Tenn. 414, 420 (1916) (noting that an MCE membership sold for $2.500); MCE v. Pope, 13 Tenn. App. 518 (1931) (noting that a MCE membership sold for $4.500); Capps v. Comm'r, 14 T.C.M. (CCH) 505 (1955) (noting that a MCE membership sold for $10,000). Today, however, the value of membership is approximately $2,500, Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997), so this bond offers far less protection than it did in the past.
-
-
-
-
70
-
-
0347875747
-
-
See infra notes 176-178 (discussing how a merchant's membership status in these associations affects mills' willingness to deal with him)
-
See infra notes 176-178 (discussing how a merchant's membership status in these associations affects mills' willingness to deal with him).
-
-
-
-
71
-
-
0347245174
-
-
See infra notes 177-179 and accompanying text (providing evidence that transactors are very reluctant to deal with expelled members)
-
See infra notes 177-179 and accompanying text (providing evidence that transactors are very reluctant to deal with expelled members).
-
-
-
-
72
-
-
0347875746
-
-
note
-
Moreover, even when the noncomplying party is in financial distress, the associations, most notably the shippers' associations, have succeeded in creating an implicit bankruptcy system that increases the likelihood that intra-industry debts, even those that are discharged in whole or in part in the public bankruptcy system, will nevertheless eventually be paid in full. When a member of a cotton shippers' association becomes insolvent or files for bankruptcy, his membership in both his regional association and the ACSA is suspended. ATL. COTTON ASS'N BY-LAWS, Art. VI, § 2 (1995) [hereinafter ACA BY-LAWS]; S. COTTON ASS'N BY-LAWS, Art. 6. § 11 (1995) [hereinafter SCA BY-LAWS]; TEX. COTTON ASS'N BY-LAWS, Art. VI, § 10 (1993) [hereinafter TCA BY-LAWS]; W. COTTON SHIPPERS ASS'N BY-LAWS, Art. VI, § 6 (1994) [hereinafter WCSA BY-LAWS]; see also AM. COTTON SHIPPERS ASS'N BYLAWS, Art. 6, § 2 (1999), available at http://www.acsacotton.org/About_ACSA/ Search%20Rules/about_acsa.html [hereinafter ACSA BY-LAWS]. Members of these associations are then notified of the action through association-promulgated circulars. See, e.g., ACSA Letter to Members (Oct. 19, 1995) (noting that [name of shipper] filed for reorganization "under Chapter 11 of the Federal Bankruptcy Act [and that t]he Southern Cotton Association has suspended the membership of . . . the above firm in accordance to their ByLaws pending further review and any action by their Board of Directors"). If, after going through the public bankruptcy process, a merchant wants to reenter the cotton business, he will, as a practical matter, have to gain readmission to an association. See infra notes 176-178 and accompanying text (discussing transactors' reluctance to deal with someone who has been suspended or expelled from a shippers' association). However, an affirmative vote of a large percentage of both the board of directors and the membership-at-large is required for readmission, and every member has the right both to object to a membership candidate and to publicize the reason for his objection at the association's expense. As a consequence, a former debtor who applies for readmission without arranging to repay his intra-association creditors in full is unlikely to be readmitted, even though the rules provide that readmission is formally contingent "upon establishing, through the presentation of sufficient proof, that all outstanding financial obligations have been fully satisfied or that the repayment schedule for all existing financial obligations is current." ACA BY-LAWS, supra. There have been instances where a former debtor was denied readmission for failure to comply with the repayment norm, subsequently paid his former creditors in full, and was then readmitted. Telephone Interview with SCA and ACA Executive (July 1996) (describing such incidents at the SCA and ACA); Telephone Interview with TCA Executive (no date) (describing such incidents at the TCA); Telephone Interview with Merchant #5 (no date) (explaining that being suspended or expelled has a large impact on a trader's ability to do business, and that to be readmitted to an association, you would have to pay 100% of your debt notwithstanding any legal discharge). This implicit bankruptcy system may also partially mitigate the familiar incentive -which is especially acute in cash commodities markets - for firms to engage in overly risky activity when they are on the verge of insolvency. Because merchants who anticipate wanting to reenter the business after bankruptcy know that they will have to pay all of their intraassociation (and perhaps intra-industry) creditors in full before being readmitted, they are less likely to engage in certain types of overly risky behavior and end-period opportunism than they would be in the absence of the industry's well-organized associations. The industry's PLS, and the behavorial norms it encourages, make it possible to impose a sanction that exceeds the wealth of the party in financial distress (albeit by a finite amount since a transactor can also become judgment proof with respect to reputational harm if he engages in enough wrongdoing that he is unlikely to be readmitted to a shippers' association even if he makes sood his debts). The availability of these nonmonetary sanctions, like the punishment of incarceration rather than, or in addition to, a fine in the criminal context, in turn, mitigates the incentive of a transactor in financial distress to engage in end-period opportunism.
-
-
-
-
73
-
-
0346983825
-
The Arbitration Alternative: A Comparative Analysis of Case Processing Time, Disposition Mode, and Cost in the American Arbitration Association and in the Courts
-
Some of the benefits of the private system could be partially captured through the public system, or through straightforward public legal system reform. Some of the benefits of the PLS's adjudicative procedures, for example, could be obtained if cotton contracts simply provided for American Arbitration Association ("AAA") administered arbitration. However, AAA-administered arbitration is often as costly and delay-prone as litigation. See Herbert M. Kritzer & Jill K. Anderson, The Arbitration Alternative: A Comparative Analysis of Case Processing Time, Disposition Mode, and Cost in the American Arbitration Association and in the Courts, 8 JUST. SYS. J. 6, 18 (1983) (concluding that "[o]ne does not save money by going to the AAA," rather than to state or federal court for claims above $5,000). In addition, because the AAA's general arbitration rules give arbitrators wide-ranging discretion to grant continuances, see AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WHAT EVERY ADVOCATE NEEDS TO KNOW - A COMMENTARY ON THE COMMERCIAL ARBITRATION RULES OF THE AMERICAN ARBITRATION ASSOCIATION 20-21, 27 (1993) (discussing the granting of "postponements" and "extensions of time"), and because unlike cotton industry tribunals, the AAA cannot put any special pressures on parties to comply with its judgments, both preand post-award delay would likely remain a significant problem. It is possible, however, that careful drafting of an arbitration clause and the adoption of special rules regarding the selection of industry-expert arbitrators and the avoidance of delay might reduce or eliminate these problems. At least one of the AAA's industry-specific tribunals has attempted these sorts of reforms. See, e.g., AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WIRELESS INDUSTRY ARBITRATION RULES (1997), available at http://www.adr.org/rules/ commercial/wireless_rules.html (providing the option of "fast-track" arbitration with a "45- day 'time standard' for case completion" in front of a panel staffed by experts who are engaged directly in the telecommunications industry"). Some of the benefits created by the trade rules could also be obtained if detailed association-promulgated, standard-form contracts that contained rule-like provisions and that provided for general commercial arbitration were widely used by transactors in a particular market. However, if the arbitrators interpreting these contracts did so under the Code, which they would be likely to do since they are supposed to apply the law, many of the benefits of the rule-like provisions would be diminished. The Code's nonwaivable duties of good faith and reasonableness, see U.C.C. § 1-102 (1991) ("[T]he obligations of good faith, diligence, reasonableness and care . . . may not be disclaimed by agreement."), as well as its highly contextualized adjudicative approach, together with the AAA's direction to its arbitrators to achieve equitable results, may have the effect of transforming even rule-like contractual provisions into standards and transforming many of the transactors' extralegal understandings into enforceable contractual obligations. In addition, although reversal of arbitration decisions for failure to apply the law is quite rare, particularly when, as in AAA arbitrations, no opinion is written, an arbitral agreement making it clear that the law is not to be enforced would be problematic. See Stephen J. Ware, Default Rules from Mandatory Rules: Privatizing Law Through Arbitration, 83 MINN. L. REV. 703 (1999). In contrast, in the industry tribunals, the arbitrators can simply pledge to uphold the trade rules, and because their reputations are on the line, they are likely to do so, particularly in industries like cotton where arbitrators sign their opinions. Moreover, a party who has lost an arbitration under the trade rules is unlikely to challenge the arbitrators' decision in court, unless an extraordinary sum is involved or he is planning to leave the industry. Bringing such a legal action would likely result in extraordinary reputational harm and perhaps de facto ouster from the industry. As a consequence, even a general commercial arbitration tribunal charged with interpreting detailed standard-form contracts under expedited procedural rules could not provide all of the benefits of a PLS.
-
(1983)
Just. Sys. J. 6
, vol.8
, pp. 18
-
-
Kritzer, H.M.1
Anderson, J.K.2
-
74
-
-
0346983825
-
-
Some of the benefits of the private system could be partially captured through the public system, or through straightforward public legal system reform. Some of the benefits of the PLS's adjudicative procedures, for example, could be obtained if cotton contracts simply provided for American Arbitration Association ("AAA") administered arbitration. However, AAA-administered arbitration is often as costly and delay-prone as litigation. See Herbert M. Kritzer & Jill K. Anderson, The Arbitration Alternative: A Comparative Analysis of Case Processing Time, Disposition Mode, and Cost in the American Arbitration Association and in the Courts, 8 JUST. SYS. J. 6, 18 (1983) (concluding that "[o]ne does not save money by going to the AAA," rather than to state or federal court for claims above $5,000). In addition, because the AAA's general arbitration rules give arbitrators wide-ranging discretion to grant continuances, see AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WHAT EVERY ADVOCATE NEEDS TO KNOW - A COMMENTARY ON THE COMMERCIAL ARBITRATION RULES OF THE AMERICAN ARBITRATION ASSOCIATION 20-21, 27 (1993) (discussing the granting of "postponements" and "extensions of time"), and because unlike cotton industry tribunals, the AAA cannot put any special pressures on parties to comply with its judgments, both preand post-award delay would likely remain a significant problem. It is possible, however, that careful drafting of an arbitration clause and the adoption of special rules regarding the selection of industry-expert arbitrators and the avoidance of delay might reduce or eliminate these problems. At least one of the AAA's industry-specific tribunals has attempted these sorts of reforms. See, e.g., AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WIRELESS INDUSTRY ARBITRATION RULES (1997), available at http://www.adr.org/rules/ commercial/wireless_rules.html (providing the option of "fast-track" arbitration with a "45- day 'time standard' for case completion" in front of a panel staffed by experts who are engaged directly in the telecommunications industry"). Some of the benefits created by the trade rules could also be obtained if detailed association-promulgated, standard-form contracts that contained rule-like provisions and that provided for general commercial arbitration were widely used by transactors in a particular market. However, if the arbitrators interpreting these contracts did so under the Code, which they would be likely to do since they are supposed to apply the law, many of the benefits of the rule-like provisions would be diminished. The Code's nonwaivable duties of good faith and reasonableness, see U.C.C. § 1-102 (1991) ("[T]he obligations of good faith, diligence, reasonableness and care . . . may not be disclaimed by agreement."), as well as its highly contextualized adjudicative approach, together with the AAA's direction to its arbitrators to achieve equitable results, may have the effect of transforming even rule-like contractual provisions into standards and transforming many of the transactors' extralegal understandings into enforceable contractual obligations. In addition, although reversal of arbitration decisions for failure to apply the law is quite rare, particularly when, as in AAA arbitrations, no opinion is written, an arbitral agreement making it clear that the law is not to be enforced would be problematic. See Stephen J. Ware, Default Rules from Mandatory Rules: Privatizing Law Through Arbitration, 83 MINN. L. REV. 703 (1999). In contrast, in the industry tribunals, the arbitrators can simply pledge to uphold the trade rules, and because their reputations are on the line, they are likely to do so, particularly in industries like cotton where arbitrators sign their opinions. Moreover, a party who has lost an arbitration under the trade rules is unlikely to challenge the arbitrators' decision in court, unless an extraordinary sum is involved or he is planning to leave the industry. Bringing such a legal action would likely result in extraordinary reputational harm and perhaps de facto ouster from the industry. As a consequence, even a general commercial arbitration tribunal charged with interpreting detailed standard-form contracts under expedited procedural rules could not provide all of the benefits of a PLS.
-
(1993)
What Every Advocate Needs to Know - A Commentary on the Commercial Arbitration Rules of the American Arbitration Association
, pp. 20-21
-
-
-
75
-
-
0346983825
-
-
Some of the benefits of the private system could be partially captured through the public system, or through straightforward public legal system reform. Some of the benefits of the PLS's adjudicative procedures, for example, could be obtained if cotton contracts simply provided for American Arbitration Association ("AAA") administered arbitration. However, AAA-administered arbitration is often as costly and delay-prone as litigation. See Herbert M. Kritzer & Jill K. Anderson, The Arbitration Alternative: A Comparative Analysis of Case Processing Time, Disposition Mode, and Cost in the American Arbitration Association and in the Courts, 8 JUST. SYS. J. 6, 18 (1983) (concluding that "[o]ne does not save money by going to the AAA," rather than to state or federal court for claims above $5,000). In addition, because the AAA's general arbitration rules give arbitrators wide-ranging discretion to grant continuances, see AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WHAT EVERY ADVOCATE NEEDS TO KNOW - A COMMENTARY ON THE COMMERCIAL ARBITRATION RULES OF THE AMERICAN ARBITRATION ASSOCIATION 20-21, 27 (1993) (discussing the granting of "postponements" and "extensions of time"), and because unlike cotton industry tribunals, the AAA cannot put any special pressures on parties to comply with its judgments, both preand post-award delay would likely remain a significant problem. It is possible, however, that careful drafting of an arbitration clause and the adoption of special rules regarding the selection of industry-expert arbitrators and the avoidance of delay might reduce or eliminate these problems. At least one of the AAA's industry-specific tribunals has attempted these sorts of reforms. See, e.g., AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WIRELESS INDUSTRY ARBITRATION RULES (1997), available at http://www.adr.org/rules/ commercial/wireless_rules.html (providing the option of "fast-track" arbitration with a "45-day 'time standard' for case completion" in front of a panel staffed by experts who are engaged directly in the telecommunications industry"). Some of the benefits created by the trade rules could also be obtained if detailed association-promulgated, standard-form contracts that contained rule-like provisions and that provided for general commercial arbitration were widely used by transactors in a particular market. However, if the arbitrators interpreting these contracts did so under the Code, which they would be likely to do since they are supposed to apply the law, many of the benefits of the rule-like provisions would be diminished. The Code's nonwaivable duties of good faith and reasonableness, see U.C.C. § 1-102 (1991) ("[T]he obligations of good faith, diligence, reasonableness and care . . . may not be disclaimed by agreement."), as well as its highly contextualized adjudicative approach, together with the AAA's direction to its arbitrators to achieve equitable results, may have the effect of transforming even rule-like contractual provisions into standards and transforming many of the transactors' extralegal understandings into enforceable contractual obligations. In addition, although reversal of arbitration decisions for failure to apply the law is quite rare, particularly when, as in AAA arbitrations, no opinion is written, an arbitral agreement making it clear that the law is not to be enforced would be problematic. See Stephen J. Ware, Default Rules from Mandatory Rules: Privatizing Law Through Arbitration, 83 MINN. L. REV. 703 (1999). In contrast, in the industry tribunals, the arbitrators can simply pledge to uphold the trade rules, and because their reputations are on the line, they are likely to do so, particularly in industries like cotton where arbitrators sign their opinions. Moreover, a party who has lost an arbitration under the trade rules is unlikely to challenge the arbitrators' decision in court, unless an extraordinary sum is involved or he is planning to leave the industry. Bringing such a legal action would likely result in extraordinary reputational harm and perhaps de facto ouster from the industry. As a
-
(1997)
Wireless Industry Arbitration Rules
-
-
-
76
-
-
0346983825
-
Default Rules from Mandatory Rules: Privatizing Law Through Arbitration
-
Some of the benefits of the private system could be partially captured through the public system, or through straightforward public legal system reform. Some of the benefits of the PLS's adjudicative procedures, for example, could be obtained if cotton contracts simply provided for American Arbitration Association ("AAA") administered arbitration. However, AAA-administered arbitration is often as costly and delay-prone as litigation. See Herbert M. Kritzer & Jill K. Anderson, The Arbitration Alternative: A Comparative Analysis of Case Processing Time, Disposition Mode, and Cost in the American Arbitration Association and in the Courts, 8 JUST. SYS. J. 6, 18 (1983) (concluding that "[o]ne does not save money by going to the AAA," rather than to state or federal court for claims above $5,000). In addition, because the AAA's general arbitration rules give arbitrators wide-ranging discretion to grant continuances, see AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WHAT EVERY ADVOCATE NEEDS TO KNOW - A COMMENTARY ON THE COMMERCIAL ARBITRATION RULES OF THE AMERICAN ARBITRATION ASSOCIATION 20-21, 27 (1993) (discussing the granting of "postponements" and "extensions of time"), and because unlike cotton industry tribunals, the AAA cannot put any special pressures on parties to comply with its judgments, both preand post-award delay would likely remain a significant problem. It is possible, however, that careful drafting of an arbitration clause and the adoption of special rules regarding the selection of industry-expert arbitrators and the avoidance of delay might reduce or eliminate these problems. At least one of the AAA's industry-specific tribunals has attempted these sorts of reforms. See, e.g., AM. ARBITRATION ASS'N, WIRELESS INDUSTRY ARBITRATION RULES (1997), available at http://www.adr.org/rules/ commercial/wireless_rules.html (providing the option of "fast-track" arbitration with a "45- day 'time standard' for case completion" in front of a panel staffed by experts who are engaged directly in the telecommunications industry"). Some of the benefits created by the trade rules could also be obtained if detailed association-promulgated, standard-form contracts that contained rule-like provisions and that provided for general commercial arbitration were widely used by transactors in a particular market. However, if the arbitrators interpreting these contracts did so under the Code, which they would be likely to do since they are supposed to apply the law, many of the benefits of the rule-like provisions would be diminished. The Code's nonwaivable duties of good faith and reasonableness, see U.C.C. § 1-102 (1991) ("[T]he obligations of good faith, diligence, reasonableness and care . . . may not be disclaimed by agreement."), as well as its highly contextualized adjudicative approach, together with the AAA's direction to its arbitrators to achieve equitable results, may have the effect of transforming even rule-like contractual provisions into standards and transforming many of the transactors' extralegal understandings into enforceable contractual obligations. In addition, although reversal of arbitration decisions for failure to apply the law is quite rare, particularly when, as in AAA arbitrations, no opinion is written, an arbitral agreement making it clear that the law is not to be enforced would be problematic. See Stephen J. Ware, Default Rules from Mandatory Rules: Privatizing Law Through Arbitration, 83 MINN. L. REV. 703 (1999). In contrast, in the industry tribunals, the arbitrators can simply pledge to uphold the trade rules, and because their reputations are on the line, they are likely to do so, particularly in industries like cotton where arbitrators sign their opinions. Moreover, a party who has lost an arbitration under the trade rules is unlikely to challenge the arbitrators' decision in court, unless an extraordinary sum is involved or he is planning to leave the industry. Bringing such a legal action would likely result in extraordinary reputational harm and perhaps de facto ouster from the industry. As a consequence, even a general commercial arbitration tribunal charged with interpreting detailed standard-form contracts under expedited procedural rules could not provide all of the benefits of a PLS.
-
(1999)
Minn. L. Rev.
, vol.83
, pp. 703
-
-
Ware, S.J.1
-
77
-
-
0347245152
-
-
note
-
By reducing the cost of dispute resolution and increasing the likelihood that arbitral awards will be paid, the procedural rules, together with the shipper association membership rules, see infra note 167 and accompanying text, may make transactors more willing to initiate new trading relationships since they will be better protected in the event of nonperformance.
-
-
-
-
78
-
-
0347875729
-
-
note
-
For example, if a small merchant were forced to contract with a large mill under the public legal system, the small merchant might decline to file even a meritorious claim, knowing that legal costs are generally high and that the mill's in-house legal staff would be able to use many delaying tactics that, combined with the delay inherent in the judicial process, might put him out of business. As a consequence, large firms would, in effect, be unable to make legally enforceable promises to small firms.
-
-
-
-
79
-
-
0347875744
-
-
note
-
By reducing the cost of dispute resolution, the PLS transforms some meritorious claims that would have had a negative expected value in the public system, and therefore would most likely not have been filed, into positive expected value claims. As a consequence, the system makes it possible to enter into smaller contracts that are more likely to be performed, since each party has a credible threat to go to arbitration if they are not. The ability to enter into smaller-sized transactions not only helps small firms compete with larger ones, but is also beneficial to mills. When a mill is able to purchase smaller amounts from multiple suppliers, it is better able to diversify away the risk of inadvertent breach, a risk that remains significant even when merchants take the optimal amount of care. See infra text accompanying notes 216-219.
-
-
-
-
80
-
-
0003082964
-
A Model in Which Suits Are Brought for Their Nuisance Value
-
For example, because cotton tribunals do not permit unrestrained party-initiated discovery, transactors have no incentive to bring the type of nonmeritorious suit that if brought in the public legal system might nonetheless result in a settlement since the defendant would have an incentive to settle for any amount below the discovery costs that the plaintiff could credibly threaten to impose on him before incurring significant costs herself. See David Rosenberg & Steven Shavell, A Model in Which Suits Are Brought for Their Nuisance Value, 5 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 3 (1985). Moreover, because these tribunals endeavor to keep the existence of a dispute secret, at least until a judgment is rendered, the arbitral process discourages the filing of suits solely for the settlement value that is created by their cloud on title effect, that is, for the harm that the mere existence of a lawsuit causes to someone's reputation during the pendancy of the dispute. See Edward Bernstein, Law & Economics and the Structure of Value Adding Contracts: A Contract Lawyer's View of the Law & Economics Literature, 74 U. OR. L. REV. 189 (1995) (discussing the cloud on title theory of the nuisance suit). Even though the existence of a dispute sometimes leaks out through gossip, because disputes are resolved faster, the monetary effect of the cloud will be much smaller. In addition, industry arbitrators' reluctance to grant continuances or postponements of hearings and decisions, limits the ability of a party to use the threat of delay to persuade his adversary to accept a lower settlement.
-
(1985)
Int'l Rev. L. & Econ.
, vol.5
, pp. 3
-
-
Rosenberg, D.1
Shavell, S.2
-
81
-
-
0012489741
-
Law & Economics and the Structure of Value Adding Contracts: A Contract Lawyer's View of the Law & Economics Literature
-
For example, because cotton tribunals do not permit unrestrained party-initiated discovery, transactors have no incentive to bring the type of nonmeritorious suit that if brought in the public legal system might nonetheless result in a settlement since the defendant would have an incentive to settle for any amount below the discovery costs that the plaintiff could credibly threaten to impose on him before incurring significant costs herself. See David Rosenberg & Steven Shavell, A Model in Which Suits Are Brought for Their Nuisance Value, 5 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 3 (1985). Moreover, because these tribunals endeavor to keep the existence of a dispute secret, at least until a judgment is rendered, the arbitral process discourages the filing of suits solely for the settlement value that is created by their cloud on title effect, that is, for the harm that the mere existence of a lawsuit causes to someone's reputation during the pendancy of the dispute. See Edward Bernstein, Law & Economics and the Structure of Value Adding Contracts: A Contract Lawyer's View of the Law & Economics Literature, 74 U. OR. L. REV. 189 (1995) (discussing the cloud on title theory of the nuisance suit). Even though the existence of a dispute sometimes leaks out through gossip, because disputes are resolved faster, the monetary effect of the cloud will be much smaller. In addition, industry arbitrators' reluctance to grant continuances or postponements of hearings and decisions, limits the ability of a party to use the threat of delay to persuade his adversary to accept a lower settlement.
-
(1995)
U. Or. L. Rev.
, vol.74
, pp. 189
-
-
Bernstein, E.1
-
82
-
-
0347875728
-
-
See Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("When a little guy [merchant] isn't paid, he may suffer huge financial harm.")
-
See Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("When a little guy [merchant] isn't paid, he may suffer huge financial harm.").
-
-
-
-
83
-
-
0000218023
-
Relational Contracts and the Courts
-
Alan Schwartz, Relational Contracts and the Courts, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 271 (1992) (defining and discussing the distinction between observable and verifiable information).
-
(1992)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.21
, pp. 271
-
-
Schwartz, A.1
-
84
-
-
0347245148
-
-
Encouraging more complete contracts reduces the number of unprovided-for contingencies, and may therefore reduce the number of disputes
-
Encouraging more complete contracts reduces the number of unprovided-for contingencies, and may therefore reduce the number of disputes.
-
-
-
-
85
-
-
0347875731
-
-
note
-
Information costs are the costs to a transactor of understanding the terms of a particular transaction. When deals are concluded against the background of detailed standardized defaults, and variations are prominently noted in the special remarks section of a confirmation, transactors bear the costs of learning the meaning of the defaults only once and in an individual transaction need only take note of the modified terms. When transactors understand the terms of their contracts, they are less likely to seek legal advice before entering into deals, thus reducing legal costs.
-
-
-
-
86
-
-
0346475042
-
Social Norms and Default Rules Analysis
-
Relational costs are costs that arise from the fact that, in many contexts, transactors approach the task of reaching an agreement "with an idea of how similar transactions are usually structured; they have in their minds an implicit form contract made up of clauses such as price that are commonly negotiated, boilerplate provisions, and legal default rules [and extralegal provisions]. A party may be wary of suggesting too many deviations from the implicit form contract since these might be interpreted as a signal that he is a less reliable or more contentious trading partner than the average market participant. . . . [T]his signal might, in turn, lead the other party to either propose additional provisions or demand a price adjustment to compensate him for the added perceived risk that a dispute will arise. It might also increase the risk of transaction breakdown as well as the likelihood that the transaction will not be consummated by the relevant deadline." Lisa Bernstein, Social Norms and Default Rules Analysis, 3 S. CAL. INTERDISC. L.J. 59, 71-72 (1993). Avoiding relational costs is particularly important in merchant-to-mill transactions where the value of the transaction as a whole is strongly affected by the ability of the transactors to cooperate during its execution.
-
(1993)
S. Cal. Interdisc. L.J.
, vol.3
, pp. 59
-
-
Bernstein, L.1
-
87
-
-
0347245151
-
-
See infra notes 192-196 and accompanying text (describing the ways the associations try to educate member transactors about the content of the rules)
-
See infra notes 192-196 and accompanying text (describing the ways the associations try to educate member transactors about the content of the rules).
-
-
-
-
88
-
-
84928222934
-
The Limits of Expanded Choice: An Analysis of the Interactions between Express and Implied Contract Terms
-
See Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, The Limits of Expanded Choice: An Analysis of the Interactions Between Express and Implied Contract Terms, 73 CAL. L. REV. 261 (1985).
-
(1985)
Cal. L. Rev.
, vol.73
, pp. 261
-
-
Goetz, C.J.1
Scott, R.E.2
-
89
-
-
0003172533
-
Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation Versus Conflict Strategies
-
Another advantage of industry-provided trade rules over individually drafted contracts is that they may enable transactors in the market as a whole to overcome coordination problems. Evolutionary game theory models suggest that, in an environment where two coordination achieving norms are initially available, coordination will be achieved over time even when each market transactor independently decides which norm to follow. However, there is nothing in these models to suggest that these individual choices will necessarily lead to the adoption of the more efficient norm. Which norm will ultimately win out depends, among other things, on the initial distribution of norm-following strategies selected by members of the relevant group at the time the game begins. In such situations, if the less efficient norm wins out, it is likely to retain its dominance since the norm will constitute a Nash equilibrium. See Jack Hirshleifer, Evolutionary Models in Economics and Law: Cooperation Versus Conflict Strategies, 4 RES. L. & ECON. 1, 13 (1982). In the cotton industry, where coordination of terms and behavior is important, the centralized provision of trade rules increases the pace at which norm convergence is achieved, and when transactors wind up locked into an inefficient norm, trade rule changes can provide the exogenous shock that moves transactors to the more efficient equilibrium. An examination of trade rule amendments in numerous industries that have PLSs demonstrates that adapting to technological innovations and other changes that require a coordinated response from market participants is a very common reason for trade rule amendments. One of the interesting features of these evolutionary equilibria is that the proportion of the initial population adopting a particular norm does not have to be notably large for the norm to become an evolutionary Nash equilibrium. This suggests that in a market where large firms such as cotton mills have a preference for a particular norm and choose to follow it, they may constitute a high enough proportion of the initial population of traders to ensure that the norm is adopted market-wide. This may be a reason that an industry as a whole may be better off if its rules are made through a legislative process in which each firm, regardless of its size, has one vote, thereby more nearly equalizing the effect of firm size on the rules creation process.
-
(1982)
Res. L. & Econ.
, vol.4
, pp. 1
-
-
Hirshleifer, J.1
-
90
-
-
0345984234
-
-
note
-
This benefit is more substantial in the exchanges and shippers' associations, in which (at least at the time the initial sets of rules were adopted) most transactors were buyers one day and sellers the next, than it is with respect to the SMRs, which govern merchant-to-mill disputes. A review of the minutes of the joint ACSA-ATMI annual meetings devoted to SMR revisions, from 1947 to 1990, suggests that changing the SMRs is a long and arduous process rife with interest group politics. Nevertheless, over that same time period, sixty-six amendments to the rules (some important, others not) were passed. The availability of well-tailored trade rules may, however, have the undesirable effect of reducing the rate of contract innovation through individually drafted contractual provisions. The cost of drafting new provisions will be nearly the same as it would have been were the contract to have been governed by the legal system, while the marginal benefit of including an innovative term may be smaller since the trade rules are already well suited to the transactions they govern. This effect may be reinforced if the terms supplied by the trade rules become part of an embedded reference transaction that transactors become increasingly unwilling to depart from. On the other hand, industry tribunals' willingness to give effect to contractual language increases the incentive to draft and include innovative provisions.
-
-
-
-
91
-
-
0345984236
-
-
note
-
As both mills and merchants have grown into larger, more complex entities, this feature of the system has become increasingly important. In many contracting relationships, the people who enter into the agreements are not the same people that perform them (such as shipping clerks, truckers, and loading dock managers). In such situations, it makes sense for companies to give their employees the authority to make one-time adjustments where it seems desirable to do so. For example, if a truck arrives an hour after closing one Friday, and the loading dock manager happens to be around finishing some paper work, it would be desirable for him to agree to permit unloading of the truck - it does not cost him much and it saves the merchant the cost of paying the trucker to stay with the load over the weekend. If, however, the loading dock manager thought that by agreeing to unload in this particular instance, he would be giving the trucker the right to require him or another loading dock employee to keep the loading dock open late on another Friday, he might not agree to unload the truck. Although under the Code, one act does not constitute a course of performance one loading dock employee might not know if another employee had agreed to a similar adjustment the previous Friday, or if another employee would agree to a similar adjustment the next Friday, thereby enabling the trucker to claim that failure to accept a late delivery on a Friday was a breach of contract by the mill (assuming the mill did not issue a written notice that no late deliveries would be accepted again and that strict compliance was required). Alternatively, the loading dock manager could simply be instructed by the company to have the trucker sign a waiver as a condition of unloading. However, such an approach might undermine the "good old boy" aspect of the relationship, which plays an important role in reducing the types of frictions that increase the cost of performance. In addition, a system of written waivers would impose administrative costs on the firm. If these intra-firm transaction costs were high enough, firms might simply instruct their agents not to make these types of accommodations, thereby introducing considerable rigidity into contracting relationships as compared to the situation created by the PLS where these adjustments can be made by agents on the ground without creating costly risks for their principals. For a more complete discussion of the inflexibility costs introduced by the Code's course of dealing and course of performance provisions, see generally Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60.
-
-
-
-
92
-
-
0347875727
-
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997).
-
-
-
-
93
-
-
0346615452
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #12 (June 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #12 (June 1997).
-
-
-
-
94
-
-
0347245149
-
-
note
-
The PLSs' adoption of bright-line trade rules that leave less discretion to the adjudicator than the Code does may help to reduce arbitral bias by making it easier to catch and therefore less likely to occur. The effectiveness of bright-line rules in constraining bias depends, in part, on the type of bias to be resisted. If, for example, the arbitrators themselves are assumed to be neutral actors who are subject to pressure by industry interest groups, being able to justify their decisions on the grounds that the result was "required" by a clear rule (and thus not a matter of individual choice) may help them withstand this type of pressure. A desire to reduce the incentives of various groups to apply this type of pressure may be one of the reasons that arbitral opinions are not accorded precedential value, and that rule-making authority is clearly allocated to the associations' private legislatures. If, however, the arbitrators themselves are assumed to have a preference for rendering biased judgments, rule-like provisions will impose only weak constraints. Fact-finding can often be manipulated to make outcomes appear dictated by the rules themselves. As a consequence, a desire to demonstrate the impartiality of the tribunal may be a partial explanation for the BoA's old practice of circulating the evidence and arguments submitted to arbitrators together with its written opinion. See supra note 28. Another feature of the system, the fact that BoA arbitrators are not permitted to know the names of the parties, is also a way of reducing the likelihood of bias against a particular individual. It is not, however, particularly helpful in reducing another type of bias that might arise in this tribunal, namely industry-segment bias - since the Board does know which party is the merchant and which is the mill. Nevertheless, the circulation of BoA's opinions may discourage the Board from systematically favoring one segment over another, since this would become apparent to industry participants, who might then opt not to include BoA arbitration provisions, or the SMRs, in their contracts. At the MCE, the norm of consensus in arbitral decision making (from 1944-1991, only four of the ninety-two cases decided were not unanimous) and the use of seven-arbitrator panels may also be ways of attempting to constrain arbitral bias.
-
-
-
-
95
-
-
0347875725
-
-
See, e.g., FRANK A. RICHARDS, THE MARKETING OF COTTON AND THE FINANCING OF COTTON MERCHANTS 3 (1949) ("The classification [of cotton] is . . . an art, not a science."); JOHN A. TODD, THE MARKETING OF COTTON: FROM THE GROWER TO THE SPINNER 102 (1934) ("The value of cotton is judged by its grade, length and strength of staple and character . . . Grade is largely a question of appearance, and judgment is a matter of a good eye . . .[b]ut it is in judging the staple that expert knowledge is particularly necessary . . . There is no absolute opinion on staple, however, experts often differing over the same sample; indeed, the same bale will often appear to vary every time it is sampled."). In 1981, however, a more objective grading technique known as High Volume Instrument (HVI) Classing was introduced. The cost of HVI classing has limited its use in small and medium-sized private transactions, but it is widely used in grading cotton subject to government-sponsored programs. COTTON COUNCIL INT'L 1996 COTTON USA BUYERS GUIDE 13 (1996).
-
(1949)
The Marketing of Cotton and the Financing of Cotton Merchants
, pp. 3
-
-
Richards, F.A.1
-
96
-
-
79956985451
-
-
See, e.g., FRANK A. RICHARDS, THE MARKETING OF COTTON AND THE FINANCING OF COTTON MERCHANTS 3 (1949) ("The classification [of cotton] is . . . an art, not a science."); JOHN A. TODD, THE MARKETING OF COTTON: FROM THE GROWER TO THE SPINNER 102 (1934) ("The value of cotton is judged by its grade, length and strength of staple and character . . . Grade is largely a question of appearance, and judgment is a matter of a good eye . . .[b]ut it is in judging the staple that expert knowledge is particularly necessary . . . There is no absolute opinion on staple, however, experts often differing over the same sample; indeed, the same bale will often appear to vary every time it is sampled."). In 1981, however, a more objective grading technique known as High Volume Instrument (HVI) Classing was introduced. The cost of HVI classing has limited its use in small and medium-sized private transactions, but it is widely used in grading cotton subject to government-sponsored programs. COTTON COUNCIL INT'L 1996 COTTON USA BUYERS GUIDE 13 (1996).
-
(1934)
The Marketing of Cotton: from the Grower to the Spinner
, pp. 102
-
-
Todd, J.A.1
-
97
-
-
0347875730
-
-
note
-
See COTTON COUNCIL INT'L 1996 COTTON USA BUYERS GUIDE § 6 (1996) (describing the sixty-nine varieties of American Upland Cotton, together with their staple lengths, micronaire ranges, and fiber lengths, as well as "25 color grades and five categories of below grade color" and "seven leaf grades . . . [and] one below leaf grade category").
-
-
-
-
98
-
-
0346615453
-
-
note
-
A sale "'on sample' means the sale of particular bales by the samples drawn from them; that is, the purchaser receives the specific bales represented by the samples he selects." TODD, supra note 91, at 95. Other methods of designating quality include: a sale "on type" which "is practically equivalent to sale on private brands. The type samples are not offered as representing specific bales, but as the type of cotton the merchant can deliver," and sale "on description," which "means the sale of cotton with a certain designated grade and staple, without the presentation of samples." Id.
-
-
-
-
99
-
-
0346615454
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #8 (July 1996)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #8 (July 1996).
-
-
-
-
100
-
-
0345984235
-
-
note
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #4, retired BoA arbitrator (Mar. 1997). Oral contracts are enforceable irrespective of their size. See SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. I, § 2 (noting that a contract may be formed orally but "all contracts for the sale of cotton must be confirmed promptly in writing by both parties to the contract"); MCE TR, supra note 17, at R.1, cl. 1, 3 ("A contract for the sale of cotton shall be deemed final when the price, quantity, quality, time and place, or places, of delivery and terms of sale have been agreed upon between the Buyer and Seller and no contract can be rescinded without the mutual consent of both parties thereto" but "[w]ritten confirmations of all sales shall be presented or mailed by Sellers to member Buyers within twenty-four hours after the sale is made."). However, it is difficult to establish the existence of an oral contract since arbitrators are reluctant to rule on the basis of conflicting oral testimony alone.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
0347245143
-
Cotton Merchants and Cowboys - Diamonds and Denim
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #5 (no date); see also Telephone Interview with Merchant #6 (no date) (noting that the cotton industry is "a community of people who are in the business of trading with one another, which requires that more integrity must exist. . . [you] don't need explicit contract[s] or confirmation to backup what you said. What you say is key to the buyer . . . face to face, telephone conversation, fax machines, long distance, by voice; you have to be able to know the person you are dealing with [and] in markets of our size this is possible"); Cotton Merchants and Cowboys - Diamonds and Denim, THE COTTON DIGEST INT'L, Vo.l 74, No. 1 (1999) 10, 12 ("The Cowboy and the Cotton Merchant are also honest and loyal. . . . [With the cowboy, a]ll you had in life was your word, your handshake, and the image you portrayed. The cotton merchant today lives by these same rules, his word is his bond in trading, and if he does not perform on his obligations, he quickly finds himself where no one will trade with him (or ride with him as we say out West)).
-
(1999)
The Cotton Digest Int'l
, vol.74
, Issue.1
, pp. 10
-
-
-
102
-
-
0347875724
-
-
Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE #8 (Aug. 13, 1997) ("[P]erformance on fulfilling contracts is what determines reputation - basically quality, on-time delivery.")
-
Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE #8 (Aug. 13, 1997) ("[P]erformance on fulfilling contracts is what determines reputation - basically quality, on-time delivery.").
-
-
-
-
103
-
-
0346615445
-
-
For more examples of these costs, see infra notes 135-136 and accompanying text
-
For more examples of these costs, see infra notes 135-136 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
104
-
-
0347245140
-
-
Moreover, mills typically pay merchants ten days to two weeks after delivery, leaving merchants to finance this cash gap, which in turn makes a mill's reputation for prompt payment very important to the merchant
-
Moreover, mills typically pay merchants ten days to two weeks after delivery, leaving merchants to finance this cash gap, which in turn makes a mill's reputation for prompt payment very important to the merchant.
-
-
-
-
105
-
-
0345984224
-
-
See, e.g., FRANKLIN W. RYAN, THE COTTON MILL SALE-NOTE: AN ANLYSIS FROM THE VIEWPOINT OF BANK CREDIT ADMINISTRATION, 5 (1921) (explaining that when a bank lends to a merchant there is "an indirect credit extention to the cotton mill. The bank lends to the merchant to enable him to sell cotton to the mill on credit. The bank looks to the merchant primarily for the final payment of the loan but the biggest element in the loan is the moral risk and the mill management is an important facror in the moral risk when the cotton is stored in the mill's own warehouse as is the usual procedure").
-
(1921)
The Cotton Mill Sale-Note: An Anlysis from the Viewpoint of Bank Credit Administration
, pp. 5
-
-
Ryan, F.W.1
-
106
-
-
0347245145
-
-
Telephone Interview with MCE Merchant #10 (no date)
-
Telephone Interview with MCE Merchant #10 (no date).
-
-
-
-
107
-
-
0347245146
-
-
note
-
See Cotton Financing, typewritten pages with the card of C.W. Butler III, First Vice-President, National Bank of Commerce Memphis, stapled to it; see also RICHARDS, supra note 91, at 37-38 ("As the cotton business is highly specialized, the merchant's experience and competence are important factors to be considered," and "[m]any bankers make a regular practice of extending more liberal credit to established, reputable merchants than they ordinarily extend to borrowers in other types of business ventures.").
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
0347245139
-
-
Telephone Interview with TCA Executive (no date) ("In this business, you just won't deal with folks you don't know; you need a really large price differential to take a chance.")
-
Telephone Interview with TCA Executive (no date) ("In this business, you just won't deal with folks you don't know; you need a really large price differential to take a chance.").
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
0345984229
-
-
note
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date) ("Mills get a reputation about how flexible they are when certain circumstances arise [and] a merchant considers this very valuable business knowledge, this information about how flexible a mill will be. Some mills are more stringent about adjustments, and are very strict about demanding exact conformity to the contract. These mills have to pay more for cotton than mills who are willing to be more flexible. The market knows."); Telephone Interview with Merchant #7 (June 1997) ("Reputation is figured discreetly into the price someone has to pay for goods."); Telephone Interview with Merchant #8 (July 1996) ("One's reputation is an integral part of the price another is willing to pay for his goods . . . If a merchant has a bad reputation, there are mills who won't deal with him, and other mills who might deal with him, but only at a discounted price.").
-
-
-
-
110
-
-
0346615446
-
-
note
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997) (explaining that mills who refused to work with merchants after severe weather affected the micronaire of a crop that had been sold for forward delivery "found that now merchants do not want to enter into long-term contracts with the[se] mills although they are still willing to enter into shorter-term contracts with them"); Telephone Interview with Merchant #9 (July 1996) (noting that the influence of reputation on the selection of contracting partners depends on the length of the contract).
-
-
-
-
111
-
-
0346615447
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #1 (July 17, 1997) (citing "laying down on a contract, bankruptcy, [and] not paying a debt," as actions that would lead him not to deal with someone); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #2 (July 18,1997) (explaining that you get a bad reputation when you "book a head and can't pay for it," or when you "lay down on a contract"); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #4 (Aug. 8, 1997) (explaining that "past history determines reputation," adding that he wouldn't deal with someone who would "lay down on the contract"); Email from merchant participant to author, to Cotton-L Listserv (Sep. 29, 1997, 2:33:26 PM) ("A cotton merchant or buyer who has a good reputation is one that honors his word, whether it be in writing or is oral. He does what he said he'd do. If something goes to arbitration in a dispute, he agrees to go along with the decision. He expects to be treated fairly. A bad reputation comes from not honoring one's word, lying, or failing to fullfil [sic] on a commitement [sic]. This can be done by either of the parties involved. An example is changing the class on cotton traded to reflect a quality difference. Another is selling one type of cotton, and knowingly delivering another quality that has a different value.").
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
0347245141
-
-
note
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date) ("Reputation is key. I care about how long someone has been in the business, and I care about whether, if there is a problem, they come to me immediately and try to work it out."); Telephone Interview with Merchant #12 (June 1997) ("A mill's reputation for being flexible is factored directly into the price; a much higher price is charged to those who are not flexible."); see also supra text accompanying notes 87-89.
-
-
-
-
113
-
-
0345984225
-
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #2, former BoA arbitrator (no date) ("When I deal with an honest man, I know whatever happens we can work it out. If a guy has a tarnished reputation, I can't count on this and Will not deal with him!")
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #2, former BoA arbitrator (no date) ("When I deal with an honest man, I know whatever happens we can work it out. If a guy has a tarnished reputation, I can't count on this and Will not deal with him!").
-
-
-
-
114
-
-
0347245144
-
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #8 (Aug. 13, 1997) supra note 97
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #8 (Aug. 13, 1997) supra note 97.
-
-
-
-
115
-
-
0345984212
-
-
See, e.g., SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. IV, § 21 ("All contracts for the sale of cotton must be filled and received by the parties making the contracts."); MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 9, cl. 1 ("No order for the delivery of cotton is transferable without the knowledge and consent of Seller.")
-
See, e.g., SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. IV, § 21 ("All contracts for the sale of cotton must be filled and received by the parties making the contracts."); MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 9, cl. 1 ("No order for the delivery of cotton is transferable without the knowledge and consent of Seller.").
-
-
-
-
116
-
-
0346615448
-
-
note
-
Another consideration that might have motivated the industry to actively promote the availability of NLSs in the early days of the PLS is that prior to 1920, arbitration awards were not legally enforceable, so the reputational harm of being known as a we cher and being expelled from an association was the only force that the associations could harness to induce transactors to comply with arbitral awards.
-
-
-
-
119
-
-
0345984228
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #9 (July 1996)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #9 (July 1996).
-
-
-
-
120
-
-
0345984231
-
-
Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997).
-
-
-
-
121
-
-
0346615442
-
-
TEXTILE WORLD, May
-
Despite the weakening of these social and communal forces, industry publications continue to romanticize the values of the south. See, e.g., Mac Isaacs, Editorial, Despite It All, People Are Still the Industry's Most Important Asset, TEXTILE WORLD, May 1999, at 9 (observing that the "senseless acts of violence [in Littleton, Colorado] turns [sic] one's thoughts to yesteryear in the annals of this great textile industry. Time was, in those days of family owned and operated companies and mill villages, the company not only provided employment, but offered safe havens that met the needs of most families as well . . . Above all, [there was] a genuine care and concern").
-
(1999)
Despite it All, People Are Still the Industry's Most Important Asset
-
-
Isaacs, M.1
-
122
-
-
0347875722
-
-
See, e.g., EVERETT R. COOK, MEMPHIS: COTTON'S MARKET PLACE 11, 12 (1942) (describing the 1931 origins of the MCE sponsored cotton carnival, which by 1942 had grown to "include an Indian fight with De Soto on the levee, a parade taking for its theme 'Way Down South', a pet parade, a marathon race. . . . [and a] horse drawn carriage . . . holding the King and Queen . . . [that] ranks now only next to the New Orleans Mardi Gras in its spectacular exhibition and attendance"). During Carnival's heyday, "[t]he arrival of the royal couple at the river front" would be "followed by a series of parades . . . interspersed by beauty pageants, sporting competitions, luncheons, fashions [sic] shows, and public and private dances." Robert McLean, Cotton Carnival and Cotton Makers Jubilee: Memphis Society in Black and White 8 (1994) (unpublished thesis, George Mason University). All of this glittering activity was sustained by "[t]he business and social elite from the tri-state area," many of them cotton men, of course. These, "joined by local residents, fellow members in one of Carnival's 'secret societies,'. . . sponsor[ed] many of Carnival's events, especially those not open to the public." Id. at 3. Over time, however, the Cotton Carnival began a decline, suffering from "charges of class and racial elitism." Id. at 170. For the next three decades after the death of Martin Luther King Jr. in Memphis, the process of dissolution continued. "The concept of mock royalty by those who in many ways, were in charge of the 'kingdom,' became ludicrous. Carnival ceased to entertain and instead became the embodiment of the divisions -social, economic, and racial - that prevented the city from developing." Id. at 148. Today, the Carnival is scarcely a visible presence.
-
(1942)
Memphis: Cotton's Market Place
, pp. 11
-
-
Cook, E.R.1
-
123
-
-
0347875719
-
-
See, e.g., EVERETT R. COOK, MEMPHIS: COTTON'S MARKET PLACE 11, 12 (1942) (describing the 1931 origins of the MCE sponsored cotton carnival, which by 1942 had grown to "include an Indian fight with De Soto on the levee, a parade taking for its theme 'Way Down South', a pet parade, a marathon race. . . . [and a] horse drawn carriage . . . holding the King and Queen . . . [that] ranks now only next to the New Orleans Mardi Gras in its spectacular exhibition and attendance"). During Carnival's heyday, "[t]he arrival of the royal couple at the river front" would be "followed by a series of parades . . . interspersed by beauty pageants, sporting competitions, luncheons, fashions [sic] shows, and public and private dances." Robert McLean, Cotton Carnival and Cotton Makers Jubilee: Memphis Society in Black and White 8 (1994) (unpublished thesis, George Mason University). All of this glittering activity was sustained by "[t]he business and social elite from the tri-state area," many of them cotton men, of course. These, "joined by local residents, fellow members in one of Carnival's 'secret societies,'. . . sponsor[ed] many of Carnival's events, especially those not open to the public." Id. at 3. Over time, however, the Cotton Carnival began a decline, suffering from "charges of class and racial elitism." Id. at 170. For the next three decades after the death of Martin Luther King Jr. in Memphis, the process of dissolution continued. "The concept of mock royalty by those who in many ways, were in charge of the 'kingdom,' became ludicrous. Carnival ceased to entertain and instead became the embodiment of the divisions -social, economic, and racial - that prevented the city from developing." Id. at 148. Today, the Carnival is scarcely a visible presence.
-
(1994)
Cotton Carnival and Cotton Makers Jubilee: Memphis Society in Black and White
, pp. 8
-
-
McLean, R.1
-
124
-
-
0345984230
-
-
By 1979, over eighty cotton wives clubs existed nationwide. Letter from the Club President, to Friends of Memphis Cotton Wives (Oct. 17, 1980)
-
By 1979, over eighty cotton wives clubs existed nationwide. Letter from the Club President, to Friends of Memphis Cotton Wives (Oct. 17, 1980).
-
-
-
-
125
-
-
0347875721
-
-
note
-
Forrest Orren Lax, The Memphis Cotton Exchange From Beginning to Decline 128 (1970) (unpublished thesis, Memphis State University) ("Because the Memphis Cotton Exchange was composed of the most influential men in Memphis it was easily the most important institution in the city. For many years the Exchange was not only an organization of cotton men but also civic minded men who used the Exchange to help the city. City problems were discussed in many Exchange meetings with little mention of cotton. At times one gets the impression that the Memphis Cotton Exchange 'was' the city of Memphis . . . . It was probably the first organization in Memphis to actively participate in charity drives for the poor of the city. It certainly was a leader in combating disease in Memphis. Many victims of floods also had reason to hold the Exchange in high esteem.").
-
-
-
-
126
-
-
0346615444
-
-
Newsletter WCSA, Feb. 1
-
See, e.g., Convention News, Newsletter (WCSA, Feb. 1, 1984) (billing the special offering for "the ladies" as a "very exciting presentation of music, gowns and dance").
-
(1984)
Convention News
-
-
-
127
-
-
0347875715
-
Bits and Pieces about ACSA Presidents and Personalities
-
May 12
-
For example the Cotton Digest International has maintained a focus on industry personalities. In the past, typical covers displayed the portraits of association executives, and a short bio was printed somewhere in each issue. An edition of the Digest devoted to the Diamond Anniversary of ACSA included a history of the association - a list of its presidents with photographs - and a quiz entitled Bits and Pieces About ACSA Presidents and Personalities COTTON DIGEST INT'L 37, Vol. 58, No. 12 (May 12, 1984). Questions from the quiz included the following: "Which ACSA President graciously accepted the President's gift of a silver service, returned home and turned it in for a pair of bird dogs? ; Which ACSA President corrected extensively while reading a resolution from the Chair, threw his penci down in disgust and said, 'O.K., some of you educated sons-of-bitches write it'?" For several years a column called Facts, Fiction and Rumors reported retirement regrets, see, e.g., Facts, Fiction and Rumors, COTTON DIGEST INT'L 38, Vol. 50, No. 33 (April 8, 1978) (mourning the loss of WCSA's executive vice-president, Dick Doan, who "is hanging them up after more than a decade of service on the job. He'll be missed! When Dick (and his wife) arranged a convention, they included wax for the dance floor"), tidbits on social events, see, e.g., id. (exclaiming: "Man, this is (or was) a busy week-end. Conventions in Costa Mesa, Charleston, Austin, followed a few days with meetings in San Francisco and Hot Springs. A man could stay loaded (from drinks) and broke (from expenses) trying to make all ot them"), and legislative rumors, see, e.g., id. ("As for farm bill changes, looks like Secretary Bergland and the administration are trying to 'cut them off at the pass,' with the 10 per cent acreage diversion plan. But congress will be back this week, and they'll have the final word on farm legislation."). In earlier years, the magazine Textile Industries had a column called Personal Notes about Men You Know containing similar sorts of information.
-
(1984)
Cotton Digest Int'l
, vol.58
, Issue.12
, pp. 37
-
-
-
128
-
-
0345984223
-
Facts, Fiction and Rumors
-
note
-
For example the Cotton Digest International has maintained a focus on industry personalities. In the past, typical covers displayed the portraits of association executives, and a short bio was printed somewhere in each issue. An edition of the Digest devoted to the Diamond Anniversary of ACSA included a history of the association - a list of its presidents with photographs - and a quiz entitled Bits and Pieces About ACSA Presidents and Personalities COTTON DIGEST INT'L 37, Vol. 58, No. 12 (May 12, 1984). Questions from the quiz included the following: "Which ACSA President graciously accepted the President's gift of a silver service, returned home and turned it in for a pair of bird dogs? ; Which ACSA President corrected extensively while reading a resolution from the Chair, threw his penci down in disgust and said, 'O.K., some of you educated sons-of-bitches write it'?" For several years a column called Facts, Fiction and Rumors reported retirement regrets, see, e.g., Facts, Fiction and Rumors, COTTON DIGEST INT'L 38, Vol. 50, No. 33 (April 8, 1978) (mourning the loss of WCSA's executive vice-president, Dick Doan, who "is hanging them up after more than a decade of service on the job. He'll be missed! When Dick (and his wife) arranged a convention, they included wax for the dance floor"), tidbits on social events, see, e.g., id. (exclaiming: "Man, this is (or was) a busy week-end. Conventions in Costa Mesa, Charleston, Austin, followed a few days with meetings in San Francisco and Hot Springs. A man could stay loaded (from drinks) and broke (from expenses) trying to make all ot them"), and legislative rumors, see, e.g., id. ("As for farm bill changes, looks like Secretary Bergland and the administration are trying to 'cut them off at the pass,' with the 10 per cent acreage diversion plan. But congress will be back this week, and they'll have the final word on farm legislation."). In earlier years, the magazine Textile Industries had a column called Personal Notes about Men You Know containing similar sorts of information.
-
(1978)
Cotton Digest Int'l
, vol.50
, Issue.33
, pp. 38
-
-
-
129
-
-
0347245131
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #8 (July 1996); Telephone Interview with Mill Association Executive (Oct. 1996) ("The identity of merchants is important. [There is] tremendous loyalty between mills and merchants who literally know one another and are friends who work together in their relationship.")
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #8 (July 1996); Telephone Interview with Mill Association Executive (Oct. 1996) ("The identity of merchants is important. [There is] tremendous loyalty between mills and merchants who literally know one another and are friends who work together in their relationship.").
-
-
-
-
130
-
-
0347875716
-
-
AUGUSTA CHRON., June 21
-
See supra text accompanying notes 113-119; Donna Rogers, Original Blackboard Discovered During Restoration, AUGUSTA CHRON., (June 21, 1996), available at http://www.cris.com/~pgarber/exchange.html. ("Besides serving as a place of business, [until the 1920s, the Augusta Cotton Exchange] was a place to play checkers, gamble and visit during the day and witness cockfights and bet on football games after hours - a man's getaway, because women were not allowed."); MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #6 (Jun. 17, 1997) (listing "social benefit" as a main benefit of MCE membership); Wayne Risher, Museum may be in Future of Cotton Exchange, COM. APPEAL, Feb. 11, 1999, at CC1 (describing the MCE as "a rule-making body and a social organization," and noting that it was "a big component of the story of why Memphis is what it is, socially and economically").
-
(1996)
Original Blackboard Discovered during Restoration
-
-
Rogers, D.1
-
131
-
-
0345984217
-
-
COM. APPEAL, Feb. 11
-
See supra text accompanying notes 113-119; Donna Rogers, Original Blackboard Discovered During Restoration, AUGUSTA CHRON., (June 21, 1996), available at http://www.cris.com/~pgarber/exchange.html. ("Besides serving as a place of business, [until the 1920s, the Augusta Cotton Exchange] was a place to play checkers, gamble and visit during the day and witness cockfights and bet on football games after hours - a man's getaway, because women were not allowed."); MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #6 (Jun. 17, 1997) (listing "social benefit" as a main benefit of MCE membership); Wayne Risher, Museum may be in Future of Cotton Exchange, COM. APPEAL, Feb. 11, 1999, at CC1 (describing the MCE as "a rule-making body and a social organization," and noting that it was "a big component of the story of why Memphis is what it is, socially and economically").
-
(1999)
Museum May be in Future of Cotton Exchange
-
-
Risher, W.1
-
132
-
-
0346615441
-
-
See Risher, supra note 123; SAN DIEGO UNION TRIB., April 25
-
See Risher, supra note 123; Times Change for Memphis Cotton Mart, SAN DIEGO UNION TRIB., April 25, 1989, at AA10 (noting that in the past, "buyers and sellers packed into the downtown Cotton Exchange [in Memphis] to haggle over prices or trade gossip").
-
(1989)
Times Change for Memphis Cotton Mart
-
-
-
133
-
-
0345984226
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date).
-
-
-
-
134
-
-
0347245138
-
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997).
-
-
-
-
135
-
-
0347245137
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #5 (no date)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #5 (no date).
-
-
-
-
136
-
-
0345984214
-
-
Email from Association Administrator, to Mary LaBrec (Nov. 15, 2000, 9:45:21); see also Telephone Interview with Merchant #6 (no date) ("We [the cotton industry] learn about [transactors' reputations] from constantly talking with people and trading with people. Information is passed word of mouth from friend to friend. We all know if there is a problem person.")
-
Email from Association Administrator, to Mary LaBrec (Nov. 15, 2000, 9:45:21); see also Telephone Interview with Merchant #6 (no date) ("We [the cotton industry] learn about [transactors' reputations] from constantly talking with people and trading with people. Information is passed word of mouth from friend to friend. We all know if there is a problem person.").
-
-
-
-
137
-
-
0345984222
-
-
note
-
Several private publications aided in this effort. One such publication was The International Cotton Buyer and Cotton Seller and Reference Book, which, according to an advertisement for the work, furnished "information regarding the financial responsibility of cotton shippers and exporters in America, as well as the selling agents and merchants abroad," but did not, like many similar publications in this or other industries, "depend upon correspondence or run lists of dead names. We send high-priced and competent men to every town in the South with enough cotton to sustain one shipper or exporter. These men procure the information necessary to the rating of these shippers or exporters while on the ground." COTTON FACTS 210 (1926). Another such publication, The American Wool and Cotton Reporter's Guide, also provided credit-related information. The 1950 edition included information on many companies including the number of employees, the amount of capital, balance sheets, and earning statements, as well as each company's name, address, products, and company contacts.
-
-
-
-
138
-
-
0347245134
-
-
note
-
http://www.acsa-cotton.org/Become_a_Member/become_a_member.html; see also TCA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. VII, § 7-8, 10 (authorizing the creation of a "Bureau for Exchange of Confidential Information," requiring that "[a]ll members of the Association shall hereafter report to the Secretary. . . any unsatisfactory transaction had with any person, firm or corporation engaged in the business of buying or selling cotton . . . and upon request of the Secretary . . . members shall furnish any and all information which they may have touching the credit, qualifications, character and general reputation of any such persons, firms or corporations," and granting all members access to the information); REPORT OF THE SEC'Y TO FIFTH ANNUAL CONVENTION OF THE ATL. COTTON ASS'N (April 2-3, 1928) ("I wish to take this opportunity of suggesting that when our members take on a connection with a firm with whom they are not thoroughly familiar that they make inquiry of the Association regarding them. Precaution of this nature will probably result to the benefit of our members."); REPORT OF THE SEC'Y TO THE SIXTH ANNUAL CONVENTION OF ATL. COTTON ASS'N (April 2-3, 1929) (noting in connection with the previous year's suggestion that members contact the association for reputation-related information that, "[m]any of our members have made inquiries, which have resulted to their benefit").
-
-
-
-
139
-
-
0346615439
-
-
note
-
When asked how they got information about mills' reputations many merchants mentioned bankers. See, e.g., MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #4 May 30, 1997) ("Agents, my competitors, the subjects [sic] competitors, banks, trade journals."); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #4 (Aug. 8, 1997) ("[M]y banker."); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #5 (Aug. 8, 1997) ("[B]ank references.").
-
-
-
-
140
-
-
0347875720
-
-
note
-
Mill Survey, Respondent #1 (Aug. 11, 1997) (Reputation "means everything to me. A merchant with a bad reputation has little chance at business with me. No time has not changed the importance - that was part of my learning as I grew up"); Mill Survey, Respondent #4 (Aug. 6, 1997) (reputation is a "high priority and this has not changed over time"). Some older transactors, however, feel that the importance of reputation has diminished as the social ties that preserved business relationships and encouraged transactors to amicably resolve disputes have begun to disintegrate. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with Merchant #3 (no date) (observing that in the 1940s, "reputation counted for more. Today there is more emphasis on price. Back then, everyone knew our prices were higher but wanted to do business with us anyhow. We were the Tiffany of the cotton business").
-
-
-
-
141
-
-
0000079986
-
Opting out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Association Executive (Nov. 1996). It is difficult to trace the demise of the purely handshake-based trade with any precision. However, an executive of the SCA noted that until 1987, most members traded on a handshake whereas now they tend to use written contracts. She attributed the shift not to any breakdown in reputation but rather to an increased bankruptcy rate in the mill sector, and merchants' realization that legally enforceable contracts were needed to preserve their rights in bankruptcy. See Telephone Interview with SCA Executive (no date). Similarly, in the diamond industry, where handshakes and intonation of the phrase "mazel U'bracha" (luck and blessings) have traditionally been used to seal deals, written consignment agreements are now sometimes used to protect the consignor's rights in the event the consignee goes bankrupt. The writings are still viewed as unnecessary as between the two parties to the agreement. Lisa Bernstein, Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry, 21 J. LEGAL STUD. 115, 121-22 (1992) [hereinafter Diamonds].
-
(1992)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.21
, pp. 115
-
-
Bernstein, L.1
-
142
-
-
0345984216
-
-
note
-
The records in MCE cases reveal instances where damage to reputation appears to have been used as a threat by one or both of the parties. See, e.g., Letter between Parties indirectly involved in the case (Mar. 1, 1980), from MCE Case No. 831 (1980) ("With regard to the Quality settlement, we assure you to do best to settle pending amicably while still maintaining your reputation well in [foreign textile company's] group, i.e. . . [foreign names], meantime, we wish that you will do utmost to push your ginners friend to settle best possible too, so that your reputation will be well maintained well in this market.") An additional communication (dated March 7) records this request: "Pls tk actn to protct ur reputatn."); Letter from Defendant, to MCE Executive Vice President and Secretary (Nov. 26, 1973), in connection with MCE Case No. 825 (1973) (Where "one of the contracts in question was called to [Defendant's] attention," and the Plaintiff told the Defendant that "we would have to take the cotton or he [Plaintiff] could not show his face on the street. He further stated that [Defendant's Memphis Rep] would not be able to trade on the street. We agreed to take the cotton and he proceeded to invoice us cotton on all our contracts"). Similar allusions to social and business reputation harm can be found in moving papers submitted to the BoA. See, e.g., Seller's Brief at 4, BoA Case No. 94 (1964) (quoting a copy of a letter from Seller to Buyer (July 27, 1964): "I believe that we should settle this dispute as gentlemen considering what is right and wrong and arriving at the dictates of our conscience . . . I would like to point out the fact that, as far as I as an individual am concerned, the outcome of our dispute placed with the Appeal Board will have very little effect on my personal life. This also is true as far as you as an individual are concerned. The real crux of the matter is - are we able to settle our differences man to man or do we have to ask outsiders who have absolutely no interest in neither [sic] your business nor my business to settle our difficulties . . . I appeal to you again to consider this dispute in the light of right and wrong and let us get along with properly being friends and business associates. This thing has caused wounds much too deep than mere money will ever justify").
-
-
-
-
143
-
-
0347245135
-
-
note
-
In merchant-to-mill transactions, both mills and merchants often suffer significant consequential damages that are not recompensed under trade rule damage measures if the other breaches. First, if a merchant delivers defective goods and the defect is not detected before the cotton is used, the cotton may damage machinery (which due to technological changes is becoming more sensitive to even small deviations in quality) and slow down the production process. See, e.g., BoA Case No. 127 (1989) (where the "Buyer allege[d] losses resulting from increased labor costs, slow down of operations, and inferior yarn," and while ruling on other grounds, the arbitrators noted that the "Southern Mill Rules do not provide for damages of this nature"). Second, if a merchant delivers late, a mill might be forced to suspend or curtail its production (while continuing to meet its payroll) due to the increasing prevalence of just-in-time inventory methods. Third, because merchants operate on a tight cash-flow margin, if a mill refuses a shipment, or accepts it and refuses or delays payment, the merchant may be forced to suspend or curtail its operations. Finally, whichever transactor arranged for the transportation will have to make good to the carrier, another unrecompensed and often unsalvageable expense. See Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) (When asked why breach, even with payment of market-difference damages, upsets someone, he explained that "most of the contracts in the cash market involve a merchant buyer who has or will contract with an end-user, or are transactions directly to end-users. These end-users need to get trucks and rail cars and scheduling unloading at particular times, all of which is very complex").
-
-
-
-
144
-
-
0345984221
-
-
note
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #9 (July 1996). The rules of several shippers' associations and exchanges show a similar hostility to the idea that breach, even when accompanied by the voluntary payment of damages, is acceptable commercial behavior. For example, following several provisions setting out penalties for late delivery and payment, the MCE Rules state that: It is not contemplated in prescribing these penalties [for delay] that either Buyer or Seller shall intentionally be the cause of delays in carrying out the delivery
-
-
-
-
145
-
-
0347875717
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date).
-
-
-
-
146
-
-
0346615435
-
-
Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (Mar. 25, 1997); see also Telephone Interview with Merchant #3 (no date) ("Your word is your bond, and any departures from this way of looking at things bring uncertainty to the process; uncertainty of any kind is viewed as very undesirable.")
-
Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (Mar. 25, 1997); see also Telephone Interview with Merchant #3 (no date) ("Your word is your bond, and any departures from this way of looking at things bring uncertainty to the process; uncertainty of any kind is viewed as very undesirable.").
-
-
-
-
147
-
-
0345984218
-
-
See infra note 150 (describing the industry's renegotiation norms in some detail)
-
See infra note 150 (describing the industry's renegotiation norms in some detail).
-
-
-
-
148
-
-
0347875711
-
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997).
-
-
-
-
149
-
-
0347875709
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #4, retired BoA arbitrator (Mar. 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #4, retired BoA arbitrator (Mar. 1997).
-
-
-
-
150
-
-
0347245126
-
-
Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (no date)
-
Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (no date).
-
-
-
-
151
-
-
0347245127
-
-
Since lost profit is a key component of fully compensatory expectation damages, and it is calculated by reference to revenues less costs, discovery is needed to ensure accuracy. In the absence of discovery, a plaintiff would have an incentive to introduce evidence that overstated revenue and understated costs in ways that would be difficult, if not impossible, to detect
-
Since lost profit is a key component of fully compensatory expectation damages, and it is calculated by reference to revenues less costs, discovery is needed to ensure accuracy. In the absence of discovery, a plaintiff would have an incentive to introduce evidence that overstated revenue and understated costs in ways that would be difficult, if not impossible, to detect.
-
-
-
-
152
-
-
84863770535
-
-
5th ed. (discussing the wide variety of information relevant to proving lost profit under the numerous valuation methods accepted by some courts); 2 ROY RYDEN ANDERSON, DAMAGES UNDER THE UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE § 11:27 (1991)
-
See generally ROBERT L. DUNN, MASS. CONTINUING LEGAL EDUC., INC., RECOVERY OF DAMAGES FOR LOST PROFITS (5th ed. 1998) (discussing the wide variety of information relevant to proving lost profit under the numerous valuation methods accepted by some courts); 2 ROY RYDEN ANDERSON, DAMAGES UNDER THE UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE § 11:27 (1991).
-
(1998)
Mass. Continuing Legal Educ., Inc., Recovery of Damages for Lost Profits
-
-
Dunn, R.L.1
-
153
-
-
0346615412
-
-
The SMRs require the aggrieved party to get three actual price quotes within three days and give the breaching party five days to respond with payment. See supra note 45
-
The SMRs require the aggrieved party to get three actual price quotes within three days and give the breaching party five days to respond with payment. See supra note 45.
-
-
-
-
154
-
-
0038564044
-
The Secrecy Interest in Contract Law
-
For a detailed discussion of how the existence of a "secrecy interest" might affect transactors' litigation decisions, contracting decisions, breach-or-perform decisions, and suit or settlement decisions, as well as the desirability of various damage measures, liquidated damages, and specific performance, see Omri Ben-Shahar & Lisa Bernstein, The Secrecy Interest in Contract Law, 109 YALE L.J. 1885 (2000).
-
(2000)
Yale L.J.
, vol.109
, pp. 1885
-
-
Ben-Shahar, O.1
Bernstein, L.2
-
155
-
-
0347245125
-
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #11 (2000) (describing mills' and merchants' profit margins as "very private information")
-
Telephone Interview with Merchant #11 (2000) (describing mills' and merchants' profit margins as "very private information").
-
-
-
-
156
-
-
0347245129
-
-
note
-
Similarly because many merchant-to-merchant contracts are between competitors, a merchant would not want to reveal his profit margin or, more importantly, the identity ot the mills and other merchants to whom he sells, both pieces of information that would be needed to properly calculate the expectation measure. See Telephone Interview with WCSA Executive (July 1996) ("The arbitrators at the WCSA do write opinions, but these opinions are only given to the parties. The Board has, on numerous occasions, considered and rejected proposals to publicize arbitration results. . . . [taking the position that] because most disputes are among competitors, and most deals are kept secret, so should the results of arbitrations."). Although liquidated damages clauses might seem to provide an alternative solution to this problem, the process of bargaining for them often reveals information. See Ben-Shahar & Bernstein, supra note 146, at 1902-04 (discussing the information-revelation and secrecy-compromising effects of bargaining for liquidated damages clauses, and demonstrating that, while they are not as severe as those associated with seeking expectation damages, they may nevertheless be significant).
-
-
-
-
157
-
-
0347245130
-
-
note
-
Alternatively, the industry could try to set the damage measure (perhaps through manipulation of the per-pound penalty) at some approximation of "average expectation damages" so as to provide more efficient breach or perform incentives. Indeed, it is possible that this was the original intent of SMR drafters. However, as the minutes of the ATMI-ACSA Joint Meetings from 1947-1990 suggest, raising the penalty amount has proved to be extraordinarily difficult, since an increase would be more beneficial to mills than to merchants. As a consequence, augmenting these monetary remedies with NLSs may have been the best available way to increase the sanction faced by a would-be breacher. For an extended discussion of the desirability of awarding average expectation damages in a context where one or both transactors have a secrecy interest, see Ben-Shahar & Bernstein, supra note 146, at 1894-96.
-
-
-
-
158
-
-
0347245128
-
-
note
-
In theory, the use of NLSs to supplement monetary sanctions may lead to inefficiently high levels of performance, because it is difficult for the transactor imposing them to accuretely calibrate their size. In practice, however, in the cash cotton trade high levels of contractual perfomance are considered desirable by market participants and voluntary renegotiation is considered appropriate (though not obligatory), in the contexts where the gains from efficient breach are likely to be the largest and most frequent. More specifically, the cost of renegotiation is lowest in situations where breach is efficient due to an increase in the seller's cost of performance that is attributable to a market-wide or regional event, like bad weather that makes cotton of a particular quality largely unavailable. As one merchant explained, "[y]ou don't breach with a mill. There are exceptions; if you contract for a particular kind of cotton a year in advance, and then everyone knows little of the quality was produced, there will be an adjustment." Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997). In such situations, because the event that triggered the increase in the cost of performance is both outside the seller's control and observable to the buyer, requesting renegotiation is not perceived to be opportunistic and is not damaging to a seller's reputation. See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Renée Liu with MCE Merchant #15 (Aug. 1997) (noting hat he is willing to "renegotiate if the quality of cotton [contracted for] is not grown"); Posting of Participant, to Cotton-L@listserv.aol.com (Jan. 27, 1998) ("Most of the cotton we book is on a 75% pre-harvest fixation, and the merchants are typically very understanding about crop failures or failure to plant due to weather as long as they are notified as early as possiand mills entered into contracts to deliver cotton of a particular micronaire (a feature of quality) that turned out not to be plentiful in the crop due to weather conditions. This rewere, however, some mills that either could not or would not make these types of adjustments. As a consequence, merchants became reluctant to enter into long-term contracts with these mills, although they remained willing to enter into short-term contracts with them. Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997). On the other hand, proposing renegotiation when an opportunity to sell to a higher valuing purchaser arises is considered more problematic, perhaps because he amount being offered by the higher valuing user is largely unobservable to the original buyer. See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #3 (Aug. 8, 1997) (explaining that he "would not renegotiate a contract because the seller found a better price. Word is important"); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchan #4 (Aug. 8, 1997) (explaining that he "wouldn't renegotiate because the seller [farmer] found a better price because I have already sold the cotton elsewhere and am obliged to deliver it "). However, profitable opportunies to sell to a higher valuing purchaser are uncommon. See Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #2 (July 18, 1997) (noting that the opportunity to make money by selling to a higher valuing purchaser "doesn't happen very often"). Cotton is generally available on spot markets. When it is not, as the price increases, the value of the good increases to all purchasers simultaneously, making breach and resale to a higher valuing third-party largely unprofitable after the payment of damages. Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date). Although most transactors strongly condemn routine renegotiations that are proposed to facilitate sale to a third-party, in the rare instance where the gains from renegotiation in such contexts are particularly large, transactors do in fact renegotiate, typically splitting the surplus, especially where they have a long-standing relationships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #7 (Aug. 8, 1997) (expressing reluctance to be bought out of a contract, but noting that he "guess[es]" that he would be willing to be bought out in some circumstances, but adding that "[i]t depends on the person or relationship. If the person was a constant pain to deal with, I wouldn't. But with a good relationship, I'd be more willing"); Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date) (discussing a time when a new employee of his sold cotton very cheaply, someone else offered a lot more for it, and they renegotiated). In sum, despite the strong condemnation of unilateral breach, voluntary adjustments are not uncommon. As one transactor explained, "the reason for . . . requesting an adjustment is key. If there is a good reason, a shortage, financial problem, etc., the other guy will typically work with you on the problem.
-
-
-
-
159
-
-
0347875708
-
-
note
-
Indeed, a comparison of the importance of reputation-based and other NLSs in diamond, cotton, and grain markets (all of which are governed by PLSs) suggests that the importance of these sanctions is closely linked to the importance to the value of a standard transaction of provisions that condition on information that is observable but not verifiable. Although the types of events that can disrupt a cotton or grain transaction are similar, reputation is far more important in the cotton market. As one merchant observed, "[r]eputation is still as important to doing business [in the cotton industry] as it was 30 years ago, far more so than in grain." Telephone Interview with Merchant #7 (no date); see also Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60 (presenting a case study of contracting relationships in the grain and feed markets). Unlike grain, which can be objectively graded, cotton is graded on a highly subjective basis. Cotton buyers must therefore rely more heavily than grain buyers on a seller's integrity for delivering the quality promised, especially where the sale is concluded over the phone. Even when cotton is sold on USDA type, the seller's reputation may remain important to the buyer since there are nuanced aspects of quality that are not fully taken into account in official descriptions. More generally, until the introduction of the more objective HVI classing method a few years ago, even a more detailed contract description of the quality of cotton promised would not have been even a partial substitute for the seller's reputation for accurately describing goods. Reputation is even more important in diamond markets than cotton markets, at least in part because there are even more aspects of a diamond contract that cannot be adequately dealt with through state-contingent contracting. For example, it may not even be possible to describe a rough diamond with sufficient precision to "enable a third party neutral to determine whether or not the stone contracted one day is actually delivered another day; yet a buyer will know if the stone delivered is not the stone contracted for. In a diamond transaction, reputation is also used to bond the seller's warranty that the stone has not undergone one of several treatments to disguise flaws. Although these flaws can be detected through laboratory tests, the tests are too expensive to use in every transaction. See Bernstein, Diamonds, supra note 133, at 115.
-
-
-
-
160
-
-
0030551184
-
Why Hold-Ups Occur: The Self Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships
-
See Benjamin Klein, Why Hold-Ups Occur: The Self Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships, 34 ECON. INQUIRY 444, 455 (1996) (arguing that there is a "fundamental complementarity between court enforcement and private enforcement. . . . The two enforcement mechanisms work better together than either of them do separately").
-
(1996)
Econ. Inquiry
, vol.34
, pp. 444
-
-
Klein, B.1
-
161
-
-
0346615432
-
-
note
-
In the absence of NLSs, if only monetary damages were available, interior contract provisions might not be performed, because while breach of interior provisions imposes costs on the promisee, these costs are small in relation to the value of the transaction (and perhaps the contracting relationship) to the parties, making any threat to sue if such a provision is violated incredible. As a consequence, breach of these provisions would be common and a lot of contractual value would be lost. However, when NLSs are available, and can be imposed even after a transaction has been completed (and at a much lower cost than money damages), the threat to impose them for breach of an interior provision is more likely to be credible, and the provision is therefore more likely to be complied with.
-
-
-
-
162
-
-
0346615434
-
-
note
-
Although reputation-based NLSs in the cotton industry are strong, they would not create nearly as much value in the absence of the PLS and would not, standing alone, be able to support efficient levels of trade or induce efficient breach-or-perform decisions. The PLS's money damages, while under-compensatory, do succeed in bonding the price-risk aspect of cotton contracts by ensuring that a mere change in the price level will not make breach attractive. Given the volatility in cotton prices over the length of a typical relationship, it wouW be difficult, if not impossible, for the industry to create reputation-based NLSs that were strong enough to control the price-nsk aspect of transactors' behavior. Moreover, the existence of the PLS puts a check on the amount of damage baseless gossip can cause, since at a certain point, the person being gossiped about can defend himself by pointing out that because the gossiper has not taken him to arbitration, his actions could not have been so bad.
-
-
-
-
163
-
-
0347875707
-
-
note
-
Despite the small number of cases arbitrated by the MCE, its member merchants consider arbitration to be an important benefit. When twenty-two MCE members were asked whether arbitration was an important benefit of membership in the exchange, ten answered "yes" and twelve did not reply to the question.
-
-
-
-
164
-
-
0345984213
-
-
note
-
The SCA and the ACA arbitration tribunals each hear less than one case per year, Telephone Interview with SCA and ACA Executive (Oct. 2000); the WCSA arbitration tribunal hears three to four cases a year, Telephone Interview with Merchant #8 (no date); and from 1993-95, the TCA heard about three cases per year, Telephone Interview with TCA Executive (no date).
-
-
-
-
165
-
-
0345984187
-
-
note
-
See Telephone Interview with Merchant #6 (no date) ("I've been in the business near sixty years and there are only two or three people I won't deal with anymore, and they are people who were marginal to begin with."). See generally BUSH, supra note 113, at 436-37 ("Over the generations, the cotton business has been exceptionally honorable, with the trite but true aphorism of a man's word being his bond applying equally to mills and agents, merchants and fanners. . . . considering the tens of thousands of transactions taking place in any given year, and the millions of bales sold, transgressions were remarkably rare. As a result, the cotton business operated in an aura of trust without which it could ill function: two parties to a contract could make commitments at a firm price as much as a year or more in advance, and there was never any question that both parties would live up to the letter and spirit of the contract, thus enabling each other to plan future actions within an established framework.").
-
-
-
-
166
-
-
0347875705
-
-
See supra note 150 and accompanying text
-
See supra note 150 and accompanying text.
-
-
-
-
167
-
-
0346615415
-
-
See supra notes 73-87 and accompanying text (discussing several features of the PLS that encourage settlement and decrease the likelihood that misunderstandings will arise).
-
See supra notes 73-87 and accompanying text (discussing several features of the PLS that encourage settlement and decrease the likelihood that misunderstandings will arise).
-
-
-
-
168
-
-
0346615431
-
-
note
-
There are numerous sources of execution costs savings in repeat-dealing relationships. For example, when a merchant has sold to a mill for years, and the mill's quality needs have remained stable, the merchant will know the quality range of cotton that the mill will be able to use. As a consequence, if the merchant consistently delivers quality in this range, the mill many no longer feel the need to spend the money to class (that is, to grade and inspect) its deliveries. This can result in significant cost savings, some of which are passed on to the merchant in the form of a higher price. Telephone Ineterview with Merchant #11 (no date). Another important component of execution costs is coordination costs. As one mill buyer explained, these costs are now more important due to consolidation on the merchant and mill sides of the business, which has given rise to a "need to coordinate more in terms of deliveries since there are coordination problems . . . [you n]eed greater precision in getting bales from warehouse to mill . . . as mills have become larger, the timing and scheduling of deliveries has become a more complex operation, and this is now part of the merchant's reputation." Telephone Interview with Mill Representative #1 (Apr. 2, 1997). The significance of the problems caused by lack of coordination and/or standardization in delivery times and practices is also evident from the minutes of the annual ACSA-ATMI joint meettings. The need for some rules and regularities in this area is aregular subject of discussion, and while no rules on the subject have been adopted, both associations have repeatedly agreed to circularize their members about the contours fo acceptable behavior. See, e.g., Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1976) (where the ACSA again requested cooperation from the ATMI in "urging their members to receive cotton five days a week, thus utilizing to a greater degree our transportation facilities," and the mill's representatives responed that they were glad to recircularize this message). Finally, as compared to dealing with a new transactor, an additional advantage of dealing with the same firm on a repeat basis is that it may be easier to detect finacial distress. When a firm is familiar with another firm's payment patterns in situations where it is nit in distress, and understands more about other aspects of its operations, it is more likely to be detect deviations from its usual practices that indicate financial trouble.
-
-
-
-
169
-
-
0001786246
-
The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs
-
For more formal discussions of the emergence of cooperation and compliance with arbital awards in historical merchant-run PLSs, see Paul R. Milligram et al., The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 J. ECON. AND POL. 1 (1990) (describing the institutions that resolved disputes and enforced arbital judgments in the medieval Champagne fairs and demonstrating that "[e]ven in a community in which any particular pair of people meet rarely, it is still possible . . . for an individual's reputation in the group as a whole to serve as a bond for his good and honest behavior toward each individual member"); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994) (drawing on formal models of repeat play games to explain the operation of merchant guilds in the late medieval period).
-
(1990)
J. Econ. and Pol.
, vol.2
, pp. 1
-
-
Milligram, P.R.1
-
170
-
-
84924196668
-
Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The case of the Merchant Guild
-
For more formal discussions of the emergence of cooperation and compliance with arbital awards in historical merchant-run PLSs, see Paul R. Milligram et al., The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, 2 J. ECON. AND POL. 1 (1990) (describing the institutions that resolved disputes and enforced arbital judgments in the medieval Champagne fairs and demonstrating that "[e]ven in a community in which any particular pair of people meet rarely, it is still possible . . . for an individual's reputation in the group as a whole to serve as a bond for his good and honest behavior toward each individual member"); Avner Greif et al., Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The case of the Merchant Guild, 102 J. POL. ECON. 745 (1994) (drawing on formal models of repeat play games to explain the operation of merchant guilds in the late medieval period).
-
(1994)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.102
, pp. 745
-
-
Greif, A.1
-
171
-
-
0347245124
-
-
note
-
In addition, the ability of the aggrieved transactor to credibly threaten to seek a monetary recovery through an arbitration proceeding reduces the short-term benefit of defection. It therefore reduces the incentive to engage in opportunistic behavior, as well as the magnitude of the reputational penalty required to induce cooperation.
-
-
-
-
172
-
-
0001457802
-
The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance
-
For a more formal discussion of self-enforcing contracts, see generally Benjamin Klein & Keith B. Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. POL. ECON. 615 (1981).
-
(1981)
J. Pol. Econ.
, vol.89
, pp. 615
-
-
Klein, B.1
Leffler, K.B.2
-
173
-
-
0347245099
-
-
See generally SHIELDS MCILWAINE, MEMPHIS DOWN IN DIXIE 293 (1948) ("A man's word had to be good on Front Street and that's still true. But until recent years the Memphis trade couldn't have been conducted on any other basis, since there were no written contracts or legal binders. A trader simply said to a factor, 'I'll take that stuff at nine and a quarter.' The factor jotted it down in his memorandum: 1500 bales, 91/4; the buyer, the same in his. Or they trusted their memories until the sale was put in the account books. And woe unto the man who claimed to have misunderstood the oral sale or was found guilty of dishonest dealing. Mr. Bill remembers that the Exchange expelled a man, and that the trade ostracized him, for selling reginnings for regular cotton.").
-
(1948)
Memphis Down in Dixie
, pp. 293
-
-
Mcilwaine, S.1
-
174
-
-
0345984193
-
-
Telephone Interview with Large Merchant, Merchant #7 (June 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with Large Merchant, Merchant #7 (June 1997).
-
-
-
-
175
-
-
0347875685
-
-
Email from Large Cotton Merchant, to the author (Oct. 30, 2000) ("Reputation is EVERYTHING . . . The cotton industry is a very small industry. Within any sector and any region, a substantial number of the industry is personally acquainted. So initial reports move by word of mouth.")
-
Email from Large Cotton Merchant, to the author (Oct. 30, 2000) ("Reputation is EVERYTHING . . . The cotton industry is a very small industry. Within any sector and any region, a substantial number of the industry is personally acquainted. So initial reports move by word of mouth.").
-
-
-
-
176
-
-
0346615414
-
-
note
-
The membership applications used by associations and exchanges require applicants to be sponsored by several current members. See, e.g., SCA Application For Membership, attached to SCA Directors' Letter No. 106 - 1983/84 (Mar. 21, 1983) (requiring each applicant to be sponsored by three members in good standing, or five members if the applicant has been in business for less than one year). Applicants are also required to establish that they are of good character and commercial standing, and to provide detailed financial information. For example, the TCA application requires applicants to, among other things, answer the following questions: (1) "State your experience in the cotton industry, include firms you have been associated with or employed by, functions performed, reasons for leaving such employment, and references who may be contacted regarding your experience and qualifications;" (2) "Have you ever filed for reorganization under any of the several chapter proceedings of the Federal Bankruptcy Act? . . . Explain the status of any such proceeding . . . Are there any unpaid past due claims, or claims in controversy, now outstanding against you? (If so, please give particulars)." In addition, the form asks the applicant for "[t]he name of your bank," and the "name of the bank officer authorized by you to discuss your financial ability to engage in the cotton business." TCA Application For Membership, attached to SCA Directors' Letter No. 106 - 1983/84 (Mar. 21, 1983). Similar application forms are used by other associations.
-
-
-
-
177
-
-
0347245100
-
-
MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #5 (no date)
-
MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #5 (no date).
-
-
-
-
178
-
-
0345984192
-
-
note
-
MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #3 (May 27, 1997); see also Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #1 (no date) (noting that membership in an exchange gives a merchant an "aura of respectability," and "lend[s] strength to [his] reputation," in part because the "standards are reasonably high for membership, so [it] is evidence of a company with high standards, integrity"); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #6 (Aug. 8, 1997) (an important benefit of association membership is "to define who you do business with . . . The exchanges encourage members to do business only with other members"); Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #7 (Aug. 8, 1997) ("[Membership] gives [you] some legitimacy.").
-
-
-
-
179
-
-
0347875689
-
-
Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #6 (Aug. 8, 1997)
-
Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #6 (Aug. 8, 1997).
-
-
-
-
180
-
-
0345984190
-
-
note
-
The membership rules also create an incentive for some nonmembers who are dealing with members to be true to their word. Because association membership is a valuable business asset, most nonmembers hope to be admitted to membership. However, because only a few votes are needed to block a candidate's admission, see MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. VII, § 1, nonmembers are particularly wary of breaching contracts with members. As a consequence, a member dealing with a nonmember also has a reasonable expectation that the nonmember will behave honorably at the outset of a contracting relationship.
-
-
-
-
181
-
-
0347875691
-
-
note
-
See Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date) (noting that at the MCE, although "opinions may not be published or any information about the arbitration given out. . .it [the result] does become generally known"); Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (no date) (same). At the MCE, seven arbitrators hear each case, which ensures that 7.7% of the ninety member firms learn the result. In addition, the nine officers and directors who sit on the board will also know the results. If these board members are all from different companies, 17.7% of member firms will learn the information even though it is not published and even if no gossiping occurs.
-
-
-
-
182
-
-
0347875690
-
-
note
-
In addition, association circulars sometimes report suspensions for reasons other than failure to arbitrate or comply with an award, see, e.g., ACA Circular Letter No. 18 -1992/1993 (Apr. 7, 1993) (reporting an ACA suspension for non-payment of bale fees), or resignations under suspicious circumstances, see Letter to ACSA Members from General Counsel (Aug. 20, 1996) (advising that the resignation of [name of a shipper] "came within two days of their being advised that pending quality and weight claims, on shipments to the People's Republic of China, had been brought to the attention of ACSA by the U.S. agent of the buyer and that 'if requested an immediate review will be undertaken by the Rules, By-Laws & Fair Practices Committee pursuant to ACSA Special Rule 18' "). The Southern Cotton Shippers Association [early name of the SCA] also adopted the practice of publishing the names of members delinquent in paying dues. See, e.g., Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (April 28, 1943).
-
-
-
-
183
-
-
0345984188
-
-
ACSA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. 6, § 2
-
ACSA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. 6, § 2.
-
-
-
-
184
-
-
0346615413
-
-
SCA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. 6, § 1
-
SCA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. 6, § 1.
-
-
-
-
185
-
-
0347875686
-
-
See Telephone Interview with Merchant #5 (no date) (noting that "being suspended has a tremendous impact on a trader's ability to do business. Mills do not want to take the added risk of non-delivery; no one would")
-
See Telephone Interview with Merchant #5 (no date) (noting that "being suspended has a tremendous impact on a trader's ability to do business. Mills do not want to take the added risk of non-delivery; no one would").
-
-
-
-
186
-
-
0347875687
-
-
Some firms, however, steadfastly refuse to deal with nonmembers of any kind. Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #9 (Aug. 13, 1997) ("We shy away from nonmembers of one of the associations or exchanges.")
-
Some firms, however, steadfastly refuse to deal with nonmembers of any kind. Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #9 (Aug. 13, 1997) ("We shy away from nonmembers of one of the associations or exchanges.").
-
-
-
-
187
-
-
0345984191
-
-
note
-
Of thirteen mills surveyed, twelve said that they would be willing to deal with a nonmember of a shippers' association or exchange, one said he probably would not. Of those who would deal with a nonmember, three mentioned that they would want more informa-tion before doing so, and all but one said they cared about whether the merchants they dealt with were members of a shippers' association. In contrast, when asked whether they would deal with a merchant who had been expelled by a shippers' association, six mills said they would not, three said that they would be unlikely to, two said that it would depend on the reason for the expulsion, one did not answer the question, and one said that he certainly would not deal with someone who had been expelled from the Liverpool Cotton Association, but did not comment on domestic associations. The reputational harm of being expelled from a shippers' organization is augmented by the fact that most foreign buyers will not buy from a merchant who is not a member in good standing of the ACSA or one of its federated associations. As a consequence, a transactor who is expelled for a domestic default will also lose his international business. See, e.g., Letter from the ACSA Executive VP and Secretary to the WCSA Executive VP and Secretary (Jan. 5, 1981) ("[M]any importing countries look to the ACSA members for their supply of cotton . . . The ACSA sends a copy of its membership list and changes therein and its list of exporting members to domestic and foreign cotton organizations and this is constructive notice to these organizations of our current membership. A number of foreign countries require a certificate from some of our exporting firms that they are a member in good standing of the ACSA before they will be considered for tenders, sales of cotton, etc."). On occasion, however, a transactor will continue to deal with someone who has been suspended, if it is the only way he can expect to be paid. This is most common when the reason for the suspension is bankruptcy and the transactor thinks he will get more in a reorganization if he helps the debtor remain a going concern. See Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date) (describing a situation in which, in an effort to obtain some payment, a large merchant continued dealing with a small merchant after he had been expelled for non-payment of an arbitration award).
-
-
-
-
188
-
-
0345984189
-
-
note
-
Mill Survey, Respondent #1 (Aug. 11, 1997). One of the main differences between contemporary PLSs and the historical PLSs whose operations have been rigorously modeled by game theorists, see supra note 161, is that the antitrust laws prevent contemporary PLSs from adopting rules that punish transactors who deal with transactors who have themselves been expelled or suspended from the group for bad behavior. This limitation on secondary boycotts weakens the enforcement mechanism sustaining cooperation, but has two partially offsetting advantages. First, if secondary boycotts were available, the effective size of the sanction created by suspension or expulsion would increase and associations would likely limit the situations in which they could be imposed to those where the risk of erroneously imposing them is low, such as non-payment of an arbitral award. If the sanction remained available for all of the offenses that currently lead to its imposition, see infra note 183, it is likely that increased procedural safeguards would be demanded before it would be imposed. Adding these safeguards to the PLS, however, would likely erode some of its speed, cost, and secrecy-preserving benefits. In the absence of the secondary boycott, market transactors' individual attitudes towards dealing with the individual in question determine the magnitude of the sanction, placing a check on the power of the arbitrators. If transactors think a decision was improper, they can continue to deal with the sanctioned transactor as before. Second, in contemporary commodities markets that move as fast as the cotton markets, if a transactor viewed himself as being at an absolute end-game stage relevant to the market as a whole forever, he would have an incentive to engage in extraordinarily risky behavior that might lead to widespread harm if it did not result in financial gains, behavior that he might not engage in if he thought that over time he could restore his good name and reenter the business.
-
-
-
-
189
-
-
0347875688
-
-
note
-
The TCA, for example, restricts its information service to members. See TCA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. VII, § 9 ("All information so received by the Association . . . [under the rules relating to the information bureau] shall not be divulged or disseminated except to members. . .and shall be by them treated as confidential."). Similarly, transactors who are expelled from the ACA must also forgo the use the association's debt collection bureau. See ACA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. VI, § 1(a) (describing the operation and benefits of this bureau).
-
-
-
-
190
-
-
0346615410
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview with Merchant #3 (no date) (noting that "sometimes [BoA] disputes stay quiet; some are well known"); Telephone Interview with Merchant #11 (2000) (same); Telephone Interview with Merchant #1 (no date) (explaining that at the MCE, "opinions may not be published or any information about the arbitration given out, yet it does become generally known"); see also supra note 172 (discussing how many MCE members learn about outcomes due to their roles in association affairs).
-
-
-
-
191
-
-
0347245097
-
-
note
-
See supra notes 53-54 (providing examples of BoA decisions that criticize transactors' business conduct). Being mentioned in a negative light in an arbitration opinion is likely to cause more reputational harm than being mentioned in a negative light in a court opinion. Unlike court opinions which are written, if at all, five or six years after a dispute arises, making their reputation-related information of little predictive value, arbitration opinions are rendered very quickly, so any information they reveal will be viewed as current and relevant. In addition, arbitrators' opinions are more likely to cause reputational harm than court opinions, since they are written by highly respected industry members who understand the ins and outs of the business.
-
-
-
-
192
-
-
0345984185
-
-
note
-
Joining an association further increases the value of the reputation bond a transactor posts in each transaction, since by becoming a member he exposes himself to the sanctions of suspension and expulsion with their attendant reputational and material consequences, for certain types of commercial behavior that are prohibited by the association By-Laws but not necessarily actionable in a claim for breach of contract. Most association by-laws prohibit certain types of "fraudulent trading practices" and other sorts of uncommercial conduct and suspend or expel those who engage in them. Conduct for which these sanctions can be imposed includes "the adulteration or misrepresentation of the official USDA class in the form of green cards, computer printouts, or tag lists . . . [T]he shipment of Foreign Cotton against any contract specifying U.S. growth . . . [T]he shipment of reginned, blended or recleaned cotton which reginning, blending or recleaning shall have taken place after its original baling, unless specified and described as such in the contract," TRADING RULES OF THE WESTERN COTTON SHIPPERS ASSOCIATION § 2, R. 2 (1994) [hereinafter WCSA TR], as well as "conduct inconsistent with just and equitable principles of trade or of misconduct or of fraudulent breach of contract or of wilfully violating the Constitution, By-Laws or Rules of this Exchange." MCE CONST., Art. IX, § 1. When a complaint alleging fraudulent practices is filed the board of directors holds a hearing. If two-thirds of the board members present find that the rules have been violated, the accused is suspended or expelled from the association. The accused then has a right to appeal in a hearing before the whole Association, but three-fourths of the votes cast are required for reversal. WCSA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art. VI, § 1. Claims of fraudulent breach are infrequent, see, e.g., Telephone Interview with SCA and ACA Executive (Aug. 1996) (noting that over the past five years, only one person was expelled from the association for fraudulent breach of contract, when he shipped "gin motes" (trash) in place of bales), perhaps because they do not result in the aggrieved party obtaining a monetary recovery. Nevertheless, they may have a strong deterrent value because the penalty for violating them is high.
-
-
-
-
193
-
-
0347245098
-
-
note
-
The reputation bond enhancing effects of exchange membership were even stronger in the past when social ties among members were even stronger and most business among members was done fact-to-face on an exchange floor. In those days, membership made even more aspects of a transactor's business behavior observable to other transactors, and the fact that members saw one another every day increased the speed with which gossip was transmittedthereby increasing the strength of reputation-based NLSs for misbehavior. See MCILWAINE, supra note 164, at 302 ("The hundred and seventy-five members of the Exchange see each other every day. About nine or ten o'clock in the morning they drop into the Exchange to get the quotations off the board and read the cables. The factors or sellers then go to their firms and the buyers make the rounds of the sample rooms. The pace is slow. Like Robert Frost's New England farmer they've got time to talk. During the off season, afternoon sessions of dominoes and checkers with occasional night sessions of poker and 'craps' weld the men into a sort of cotton fraternity. They have a common life of work and play - and also a common stock of traditional pranks like an initiation."). In addition, in these earlier times, an expelled transactor would also lose access to information that at the time was too expensive for transactors to purchase individually, but today can be obtained cheaply, such as crop reports, weather forecasts, spot prices, and futures prices. See Interview by Mary LaBrec with MCE Executive (July 27, 1999) (explaining that in the early days of the industry, the cost of the information wire carrying quotations from New York and Liverpool alone necessitated a cooperative investment in an exchange).
-
-
-
-
194
-
-
0003631618
-
-
Most formal, game theoretic explanations of the emergence of cooperation in repeat play contexts are based on the assumption (which, as the text indicates, holds in the cotton industry) that transactors view their contracting relationships as being indeterminate in length. See ERIC RASMUSEN, GAMES AND INFORMATION 121-23 (1989).
-
(1989)
Games and Information
, pp. 121-123
-
-
Rasmusen, E.1
-
195
-
-
0347875678
-
-
note
-
See Telephone Interview by Renée Liu with MCE Merchant #17 (Aug. 1997) (noting that his father dealt with a "certain handful of people . . . stayed with them. That's what's desired." He [the son] would "shop" until he got the price he wanted, but "stick with the same people"); Telephone Interview by Renée Liu with MCE Merchant #12, buyer for mills (July 21, 1997) (stating that he dealt with "the same merchants all the time - approximately 26 or so").
-
-
-
-
196
-
-
0347245093
-
-
note
-
Conversely, a transactor's incentive to engage in opportunism when dealing with someone nearing retirement may be similarly constrained by a desire to retain the firm's business when it is passed down to the son. See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Renée Liu with MCE Merchant #17 (Aug. 1997) (explaining that he "deal[t] with people who [his] father dealt with," people that he had "known for almost [his] entire life," and that he knew who to do business with since he "paid attention" to who his father dealt with).
-
-
-
-
197
-
-
0347875682
-
-
note
-
MACILWAINE, supra note 164, at 293 (noting that a merchant who had worked on Cotton Row for forty years explained "I wouldn't have been in any other business. I never cheated anybody in a deal, and most cotton men can say the same . . . It's interesting, fine business for any man. When I retired I was made an honorary life member of the Exchange. I'm proud of that, I can tell you"); see also SCA BY-LAWS, supra note 72, at Art.I, Sec. 1 (d) (creating the status "honorary member").
-
-
-
-
198
-
-
0347245095
-
Texas Firm Receives Cotton Champion Award
-
Feb. TEXAS FIRM RECEIVES COTTON CHAMPION AWARD
-
See supra note 118 (discussing the Cotton Wives Clubs). More recently, the Cotton Wives have reconstituted themselves into state and regional associations of "Cotton Women." Although the stated purpose of these groups is to assist the National Cotton Council with its "Grown and Made in the USA" consumer awareness campaign, they have continued many of the Cotton Wives' Clubs more traditional activities. Recently, the Cotton Women's Committee co-sponsored the first ever U.S. Cotton Champion Award, an updated replacement for the old Maid of Cotton Pageant. See Texas Firm Receives Cotton Champion Award, COTTON DIGEST INT'L (Feb. 2000), available at http://www.utexas.edu/ depts/bbr/natfiber/natnews/2000/Apr.2000.nat.htm#TEXAS FIRM RECEIVES COTTON CHAMPION AWARD.
-
(2000)
Cotton Digest Int'l
-
-
-
200
-
-
0003610904
-
-
See, e.g., AVINASH K. DIXIT & BARRY NALEBUFF, THINKING STRATEGICALLY: THE COMPETITIVE EDGE IN BUSINESS, POLITICS, AND EVERYDAY LIFE 106-15 (1991) (explaining why a pure tit-for-tat strategy is so vulnerable to cooperative breakdown and suggesting some ways that it can be modified to make cooperation more likely to endure).
-
(1991)
Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics, and Everyday Life
, pp. 106-115
-
-
Dixit, A.K.1
Nalebuff, B.2
-
201
-
-
0345984179
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Report of the Committee on Rules, By-Laws and Fair Practices, Adopted at the 43rd Annual Convention of the ACSA, San Francisco (1967) ("Your Committee wishes to acquaint the membership with the 'INTERPRETATION OF RULE 9 OF THE ASSOCIATION'S SPECIAL RULES' passed this year by the Board of Directors, a copy of which is attached hereto."); Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1951) (where, in response to a complaint by the mill representatives of trouble caused by the use of cement sacks, camouflage cloth, and similar materials for bale coverings, the meeting unanimously resolved that ACSA "circularize its members and [other cotton groups] . . . calling attention to Southern Mill Rule 37-A and to the fact that the Cotton Committee of the American Cotton Manufacturers Institute, Inc., according to its interpretation, states that Rule 37-A is being violated; that cement sacks, camouflage cloth, etc., do not come within the provisions of this Rule; and that no cotton bagging does come within the provisions of the Rule except that specified in U.S. Government Specification . . . that further no allowances would be paid except for bagging meeting this government specification" ); Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1974) (where ACSA agreed to circularize its members to "draw[] attention to responsibility of the respective parties on all 'on-call' sales"); Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1969) (noting that both ACSA and ATMI agreed to circularize their membership to remind them of the requirements of CSAB Rule 14 concerning size and representative quality of samples for arbitration). In addition, from time to time the rules are republished and sent to the memberships of both ACSA and ATMI. In the past, strips of paper that could be pasted into old rulebooks over revised rules were mailed to members between reprintings of the rules. The MCE also has a Committee on Trade, which has the duty "to consider, and from time to time report, such rules and regulations regarding the purchase, sale, transfer, etc., of cotton, as will be convenient to all parties concerned, and thereby facilitate and increase business." MCE BY-LAWS, supra note 10, at Art. IX, § 1. Circulars are sent out to the membership to acquaint them with amendments passed by the Board of Directors. See, e.g., To the Members, MCE Circular, Dec. 17, 1951 (reporting the rewrite of a rule, its effective date, and the rationale for the change).
-
-
-
-
202
-
-
0346615408
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1970) (noting that both associations committed themselves to circularizing their memberships about the changes in Rule 23 and Rule 26); Letter to All Members, ACSA Series A-Circular Letter No. 43 (Dec. 21, 1970) ("Six changes in the Southern Mill Rules were approved . . . Please place these [copies of the new rules] in your copy of the rule book for ready reference."); Letter to All Members, ACSA Series A-Circular Letter, No. 5 (June 18, 1969) (reporting that at the 45th Annual Convention, Rule 5 and Rule 6 were amended and the following new Rule 11 was added: "RULE 11: THE SPECIAL RULES WILL APPLY ONLY WHERE A U.S. GROWTH IS SPECIFIED IN THE SALES CONTRACT. THE SPECIAL RULES WILL NOT APPLY WITH RESPECT TO YEAR OF GROWTH"). The associations also undertake systematic efforts to inform members about rules changes. After each ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting on the SMRs, a report is distributed to the members of both associations.
-
-
-
-
203
-
-
0347875684
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Cotton Traders To Change Rules, COM. APPEAL, June 9, 1992, at B5 (reporting that "[c]otton trading rules that apply to members of the Memphis Cotton Exchange will change from Rule 3 to Rule 5 . . . . Under Rule 3 . . . cotton merchants or brokers pay warehousing costs. . . . Rule 5 . . . shifts those costs to cotton growers"); Exchange to Keep Cotton Sales Rule, COM. APPEAL, Sept. 26, 1991, at B8 (noting that unlike the MCE. the Greenwood Exchange had no plans to change its trading rules); Charles Conner, Agricultural Briefs, COM. APPEAL, Mar. 8, 1992, at C4 (discussing the change from Rule 3 to Rule 5 trading and changes in the "Rule 19 penalty for light-weight bales").
-
-
-
-
204
-
-
0345984184
-
-
note
-
The WCSA Rules, for example, contain a nonbinding note that follows the rules dealing with the quality of tender. The note states that "[b]uyers and sellers should be careful to agree among themselves as to the tolerances of qualities deliverable under the contact, when the quality is guaranteed through as stated. While it is almost impossible to preclude variances of qualities in a shipment from the quality stated, sellers should be cognizant of buyers' expectations in this regard, and in keeping with fair and reasonable practices of the trade, should disclose to buyer any severe variance in quality of the intended shipment." WCSA TR, supra note 183, at § II, R. 1, cl. 1.
-
-
-
-
205
-
-
0346615405
-
-
See, e.g., Letter to All Members, ACSA Series A-Circular Letter, No. 5 (June 18, 1969) circulated with a copy of the amended rules ("We wish to call forcefully to the attention of the membership the practices which are listed in the Special Rules and to advise that principals of firms review these rules with their employees.")
-
See, e.g., Letter to All Members, ACSA Series A-Circular Letter, No. 5 (June 18, 1969) circulated with a copy of the amended rules ("We wish to call forcefully to the attention of the membership the practices which are listed in the Special Rules and to advise that principals of firms review these rules with their employees.").
-
-
-
-
206
-
-
0347875679
-
-
See supra note 54
-
See supra note 54.
-
-
-
-
207
-
-
0345984180
-
-
note
-
ATMI and ACSA have each gone to great lengths to persuade the other organization to circularize its members asking (but not requiring) them to act in particular ways or to comply with particular rules. This suggests that each believes that these nonbinding recommendations have enough force to add at least some value to transactions. See, e.g., Minutes of The ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1981) (where the ATMI expressed its reluctance to approve any changes to Rules #22, 46 or 47, but pledged instead to "attempt to influence all mills to hve up to [Rule #22] as written," by publicizing the rule in "Textile Trends," [an association sponsored publication] and indicated that it was also wilhng to consider a special mailing "on the matter" from the Chairman to mill principals); Minutes ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1976) (where ACSA "requested cooperation again from the ATMI in urging their members to reveive cotton five days a week, thus utilizing to a greater degree our transportation facilities," and the mill representatives responded that they would be glad to recircularize this meggase); Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1974) (where ACSA "again requested that the ATMI circulate a memorandum to its members pointing out the problems incurred by some shippers by failure of the mill to properly care for rejections." and ATMI responded that it would be "happy to do this again, as it was definitely the responsibility of the mills to properly care for rejections"); Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1973) (where ATMI agreed to circularize its membership about returning rejected bales to the shippers in the same condition in which they had arrived): Minutes of the ACSA-ATMI Joint Meeting (1966) (where ATMI and ACSA failed to agree on a rule dealing with Friday delivery, but the ATMI agreed to try to enhst "the cooperation of everyone" by circularizing its own membership on the subject).
-
-
-
-
208
-
-
0347875680
-
-
note
-
The importance of resolving this type of disagreement quickly is reflected in the MCE trading rules. See MCE TR, supra note 17, at R. 34, cl. 2 ("In any case relating to the classification and delivery of cotton where it is shown that an immediate decision is desirable the President . . . may . . . appoint a special committee of three members with full power to waive all bond and formalities and render an immediate decision."). In addition, in merchant-to-mill transactions, the availability of CSAB arbitration creates an incetive or merchants not to make opportunistic use of the cure provision in the SMRs. When the CSAB determines goods to be nonconforming, gossip based on this verified fact can be at least mildly damaging, thereby increasing the cost of cure to the breaching party and giving him an increased incentive to avoid intentionally sending nonconforming goods in the first place.
-
-
-
-
209
-
-
0345984176
-
-
SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. III, § 9 ("All cotton rejected by buyer against contract must be replaced by delivery of an equal quantity as the cotton rejected, and of the quality of cotton specified in the contract, within fourteen business days of mutual agreement regarding rejections, or of final decision by arbitration as herein provided for.")
-
SMRs, supra note 5, at Art. III, § 9 ("All cotton rejected by buyer against contract must be replaced by delivery of an equal quantity as the cotton rejected, and of the quality of cotton specified in the contract, within fourteen business days of mutual agreement regarding rejections, or of final decision by arbitration as herein provided for.").
-
-
-
-
210
-
-
0345984181
-
-
For a more technical discussion of this type of strategy, known as "contrite tit-fortat" see ROBERT AXELROD, THE COMPLEXITY OF COOPERATION: AGENT-BASED MODELS OF COMPETITION AND COLLABORATION 34 (1987) (noting that a contrite tit-forfat strategy is one that "has three states: 'contrite,' 'content' and 'provoked.' I [the strategy begins in content with cooperation and stays there unless there is a unilateral defection. If it was the victim while content, it becomes provoked and defects until a cooperation from the other player causes it to become content. If it was the defector while content, it becomes contrite and cooperates. When contrite, it becomes content only after it has successfully cooperated").
-
(1987)
The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration
, vol.34
-
-
Axelrod, R.1
-
211
-
-
0347245090
-
-
Telephone Interview with WCSA Executive (July 1996) (opining that most traders view quality disputes as just a routine part of doing business)
-
Telephone Interview with WCSA Executive (July 1996) (opining that most traders view quality disputes as just a routine part of doing business).
-
-
-
-
212
-
-
0347245094
-
-
note
-
See DIXIT & NALEBUFF, supra note 191 (discussing the conditions under which modified tit-for-tat strategies are desirable); AXELROD, supra note 201, at 34 (explaining that in a repeat play prisoner's dilemma in a noisy envirmental, reciprocal strategies can be improved upon by incorporating "generosity," that is, by "allowing some percentage of the other player's defections to go unpunished").
-
-
-
-
213
-
-
0346615407
-
-
note
-
The "tat" move dictated by these more forgiving strategies - typically either refusing to deal for a specified period of time, or terminating the relationship after a series of defections - is a form of bilateral NLS that is unlikely to be imposed in an opportunistic manner. Because the execution cost saving of a repeat-dealing relationship accure to both transactors, neither has an incentive to suspend or terminate the relationship unless the other has done something that suggests that he will behave poorly in the future. Thus, while these sanctions can lead to deadweight losses when they are mistakenly imposed (an action more forgiving versions of tit-for-tat strategies are designed to reduce), they are unlikely to be opportunistically imposed.
-
-
-
-
214
-
-
0347875681
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Record, BoA Case No. 136 (1995) (revealing that the seller modified the payment schedule numerous times and that the buyer consistently failed to meet the modified schedule, leading the seller to file a claim in arbitration); Record, BoA Case No. 121 (1985) (where the buyer gave the seller many extensions on delivry before filing for arbitration).
-
-
-
-
215
-
-
0346615406
-
-
note
-
When mill representatives were asked what they did when a dispute arose, most stated that they would try to work it out with merchat, see, e.g., Mill Survey, Respondent #5 (Aug. 8, 1997) ("Work out with merchant."); Mill Survey, Respondent #4 (Aug. 6, 1997) ("[T]ry an amicable settlement; go to arbitration when all else fails."); Mill Survey, Respondent #3 (July 28,1997) ("[T]ry to work it out."); Mill Survey, Respondent #7 (July 31, 1997) ("We try to work things out between ourselves. If not we will go to arbitration."); Anonymous Mill Survey (July 31, 1997) ("Contact individual in which [sic] agreement was made and discuss all facts pertaining to the dispute and try to seek a reasonable agreement for both parties. To take a merchant to arbitration would be the result of absolute disregard of a contract or verbal agreement. Circumstances requiring arbitration would be for extremely poor performance, non-delivery of cotton and failure to make compensation.").
-
-
-
-
216
-
-
0346615404
-
-
note
-
A significant percentage of the disputes reaching the BoA appear to be absolute end-game disputes, that is, disputes where the parties do not intend to deal with one another in the future. Between 1975 and 1996, for example, 54% of the cases heard by the BoA, were clearly absolute end-game disputes. Most commonly, the event triggering the end-game was the insolvency or financial distress of a party, the closing of a cotton office, a change of control of one of the entities involved, or the retirement of a person directly involved in the transaction, all events that upset settled expectations. Another 18% of the cases involved disputes that might fairly be classified as end-game. They involved disputes over the effects of a government subsidy program that made large sums turn on who had possession of cotton on a particular day. These cases were ones in which an event took the contract out of the self-enforcing range and made it worthwhile for one of the parties to end the contracting relationship. The remaining 27% of the cases involved primarily factual disputes about late payment and late delivery.
-
-
-
-
217
-
-
0345984178
-
-
note
-
A look at the opinions, written evidence, and moving papers (but not necessarily the transcripts which were mostly unavailable), in all MCE cases from 1944-1990 provides evidence that transactors routinely make forgiving adjustments - they accept late payment or late delivery, extend the time for payment or delivery, cancel deals, or accept substitute goods - and that the filing of a claim in arbitration is often preceded by several such adjustments. See also sources cited supra note 205.
-
-
-
-
218
-
-
0347245091
-
-
note
-
See, e.g., Telephone Interview by Connie Rogers with MCE Merchant #9 (Aug. 13, 1997) (noting that in "a friendly arbitration, [with] both sides a little wrong and a little right, the animosity may wear off after a few months and they'll probably deal with each other again"); Letter from Defendant, to MCE Executive Vice-President and Secretary (Mar. 15, 1976), in connection with MCE Case No. 828 ("[The plaintiff] and I have been friends a long time and regardless of the outcome we expect to remain such.").
-
-
-
-
219
-
-
0346615402
-
-
note
-
For example, in response to the question, "If you go to arbitration against a merchant and he complies with the award, will you do business with him in the future? If so, would you do so immediately?", one mill answered, "should we go to arbitration and it was settled and the award complied with we would likely do business again - probably we would wait one or two seasons," Mill Survey, Respondent #5 (Aug. 8, 1997); another said, "yes . . . would wait a year or two," Mill Survey, Respondent #7 (July 31, 1997); and another said, "I would carefully weigh the situation and depending on the seriousness determine the time factor for relations to be re-established." Anonymous Mill Survey (July 31, 1997).
-
-
-
-
220
-
-
0347245092
-
-
note
-
The fact that transactors are aware of this approach and can therefore adjust their reliance on extralegal understandings in accordance with their view of their likelihood that they will be voluntarily performed, together with the short statute of limitations at the MCE and the other deadlines for objections written into the rules, help to mitigate the likehood of the types of opportunism that such an adjudicative approach might lead to. For example, a buyer who always takes late delivery under a contract then suddenly wants to end the relationship and tries to sue for past deviations will not be able to go very far back in time if he chooses to do so.
-
-
-
-
221
-
-
0347875677
-
-
note
-
The BoA has also consistently refused to uphold oral modifications of written contracts. See SEAB Case No. 80 (1957) (where the seller claimed that Buyer's employee said that Seller "could take all the time needed to make delivery;" the Board held that this doe not enter into this case since the contracts specify a definite delivery date, and if there had been any different agreements they should have been embodied in the contracts"); SEAB Case No. 66 (1953) ("The Appeal Board is interested only in the contract or in written statements affecting the conditions of said contract. We do not find any changes agreed to in writing altering the original contract."); SEAB Case No. 56 (1950) (noting the seller's contention that an employee of the buyer orally agreed to a modification of the contract, the arbitrators held that "[i]t is our opinion that the terms of the contract stand for themselves and the conditions set forth therein are the only conditions which would pertain to the fulfillment of the contract"). In addition, the BoA does not look to evidence from precontractual negotiations to determine the scope of the parties agreement. See NEBoA Case No. 318 (1940) ("The Board . . . finds the parties both bound by the terms of the signed purchase orders and that prior negotiations are not entitled to consideration as the terms of the purchase orders with respect to grade and staple are not ambiguous."). The MCE arbitrators take a similar approach. See MCE Case No. 789 (1952) (concluding "[t]hat while the trade was originally [orally] made under Rule 7 of the Exchange Trading Rules, which rule provides that payment shall be made free of Exchange in Memphis funds or the equivalent, and that exchange to final destination shall be deducted from the invoice, due to the fact that seller's written confirmation made a change in the exchange provision and as buyer made no objection to the change outlined in said written confirmation, the written confirmation became a mutually agreeable contract and buyer is bound by its terms"). These aspects of the tribunals' adjudicative approaches increase transactors' confidence that extra legal aspects of their behavior and communications will not be transformed into legally enforceable commitments.
-
-
-
-
222
-
-
0347245085
-
-
For a more detailed discussion of how formalistic adjudication can support flexible contractual relations in its shadow, see Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60
-
For a more detailed discussion of how formalistic adjudication can support flexible contractual relations in its shadow, see Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60.
-
-
-
-
223
-
-
0345984177
-
-
note
-
Spreading negative gossip takes time and a transactor must be judicious in deciding whether to do it. A transactor who spreads negative gossip too often, or is too harsh in his judgements, risks being viewed as being difficult
-
-
-
-
224
-
-
0347875674
-
-
note
-
Another advantage of this approach is that it will often result in willful breaches being punished more severely than inadvertent breaches. In contexts like cotton transactions, where the risk of inadvertent breach even after optimal precautions have been taken is high, and where absent successful renegotiation, transactors want performance, not payment for nonperformance, see supra notes 135-137 and accompanying text, they might find it desirable to impose high monetary sanctions for willful breach and moderate sanctions for inadvertent breach -in an effort to encourage performance without encouraging overinvestment in precautions against breach. However, a legal system (whether private or public) that imposed different monetary sanctions on willful and inadvertent breach would face formidable barriers to implementing such an approach. First, in any one case, the willfulness or nonwillfulness of a breach may not be verifiable by a tribunal, or even observable to the parties. Nevertheless, over a period of time and a series of breaches, the wilfulness or inadvertence of his transactional partner's actions may become clearer to an aggrieved party. As a consequence, given the inability of a judge or arbitration panel to distinguish between willful and inadvertent breach in a particular case, the higher measure of damages would, in practice, have to be available for all breaches. Such an increase in the damage measure, however, would likely lead to an over-investment in precautions against inadvertent breach. Second, given that the industry has adopted something akin to the perfect tender rule with cure (albeit within the industry's designated allowances on a variety of quality dimensions) buyers can nonetheless usually find a way to claim breach under the rules. As a consequence, if very large monetary damages were available in arbitration, buyers might have an incentive to declare breach in many situations where they would otherwise simply have accepted the goods. In contrast, where hybrid monetary and NLSs are used to sanction willful breach, a lower level of monetary sanctions can be combined with a NLS imposed only after the willfulness or nonwillfulness of breach becomes clear, thereby decoupling the amount "paid" by the breaching party (the monetary damages ordered by the arbitrator plus the NLS imposed by the aggrieved party), from the amount "received" by the aggrieved party (the monetary recovery plus any small deterrence advantage of imposing the NLS, less any cost of imposing the NLS, see infra notes 227-229 and accompanying text), which in turn eliminates (or at a minimum greatly reduces) the aggrieved party s incentive to declare breach when there is a minor nonconformity in tender simply to get the larger monetary recovery. There is a great deal of evidence that extent of gossip (and hence the magnitude of the NLS imposed) is highly dependent on transactors' perceptions of the willfulness or nonwillfulness of the behavior at issue. See MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #4 (May 30, 1997) (When asked whether and under what conditions he would spread negative gossip, a merchant replied, "sometimes yes: when defendant refused to honor I'd publicize that fact. Sometimes no: when an honest mistake was made, I wouldn't talk"); MCE Merchant Survey, Respondent #3 (May 27, 1997) (noting that he had been involved in two arbitrations. "One case involved a party who did not deliver in a timely manner," but because the breaching party "did not understand the importance, [he] would probably deal with him again in time," and he did not gossip after the arbitration. In contrast, the second case dealt with "a party who was looking for any loop-hole to avoid a financia loss." In this instance, he did talk about the case. He explained that, "in the case of willful non-fulfillment . . . [I talked] as [I] did not want this party to continue his poor practices"). Moreover, this system of decoupled hybrid sanctions is particularly well suited to ferreting out opportunistic transactors and transactors who act in what one industry executive called "the arbitrage way," rather than the "gentlemen's way." Telephone Interview with ACSA Executive (no date). It confront such a person with escalating sanctions, both because each instance of gossip gains credibility from the one after it (especially if it is from a different person), and because as a person gradually acquires a bad reputation, transactors are likely to watch the person more carefully, thereby detecting more instances of wrongdoing.
-
-
-
-
225
-
-
0347245087
-
-
note
-
The best verifiable term for a contract may be quite similar across relationships since the factors that determine verifiability are unlikely to be vastly different in different transactions. In contrast, what is observable, varies a great deal from relationship to relationship and even varies over time within a given relationship. As a consequence, transactors may always find it desirable to use the same or substantially the same written provisions while varying their extralegal understandings depending on who they are dealing with and the stage of their contracting relationship.
-
-
-
-
226
-
-
0346615401
-
-
note
-
It is important to note that even in selecting the terms conditioning on verifiable information that they view as most desirable in the event that a dispute requiring third-party adjudication arises (a so-called end-game situation of one sort or another, see Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60), transactors may, in some instances, be influenced, at least in part, by their desire to provide the most desirable terms for the relationship-preserving phase of their interactions as well. To see why, consider transactors' choice between two provisions: provision A, that conditions on information that is verifiable but not observable, and provision B, that conditions on information that is both verifiable and observable. Further assume that the cost of verifying the information under provision B is greater than the cost of verifying the necessary information under provision A. If only the end-game were to be considered, provision A would be better (assuming that in end-game the two provisions had the same payoff if performed, and would give rise to the same damages if breached) since the information it conditions on can be obtained at a lower cost. However, in their every-day-repeat dealings, provision A would present difficulties. Because transactors would have difficulty figuring out whether the provision had been satisfied (something that by definition would not be observable to them), its use might therefore increase the likelihood that an instance of performance would be misclassified as an instance of breach and lead to the breakdown of the relationship. As a consequence, while provision A would be cheaper to invoke if a dispute arose, the probability of a dispute arising would be higher. In contrast, while the cost of adjudication if a dispute arose is higher under provision B, the risk of breakdown would be much lower since the information provision B conditions on is observable to the transactors. Taking the risk of breakdown and the benefits of avoiding it into account, the transactors might prefer to include provision B in the contract.
-
-
-
-
227
-
-
0347245088
-
-
Mill Survey, Respondent #1 (Aug. 11, 1997)
-
Mill Survey, Respondent #1 (Aug. 11, 1997).
-
-
-
-
228
-
-
0347875675
-
-
note
-
Mill Survey, Respondent #5 (Aug. 8, 1997); ); see also Telephone Interview by Renée Liu with Mill #12 (Oct. 7, 1997) (noting that there are differences between everyday practices and the SMRs in that "payments are looked at loosely . . . fixation term is obsolete . . . time deadlines [are] often winked at . . . wouldn't buy in cotton sometimes [even if delivery is late] if we didn't need it badly . . . [we] dance around that"); Telephone Interview by Renée Liu with Mill #13 (Oct. 8, 1997) (noting that the biggest variation from the rules relates to payments); Mill Survey, Respondent #5 (Aug. 8, 1997) (explaining that these differences relate to "late delivery, late payment, notification of claims"); Mill Survey, Respondent #6 (July 30, 1997) (noting that most divergences between SMRs and practice "have evolved through the continued partnership of vendor - customer").
-
-
-
-
229
-
-
0347875673
-
-
See, e.g., Record, BoA Case No. 139 (1976) (illustrating the existence of multiple separate and overlapping contracts between the parties)
-
See, e.g., Record, BoA Case No. 139 (1976) (illustrating the existence of multiple separate and overlapping contracts between the parties).
-
-
-
-
230
-
-
0347875668
-
-
See generally Klein, supra note 152 (exploring the creation and use of private enforcement capital)
-
See generally Klein, supra note 152 (exploring the creation and use of private enforcement capital).
-
-
-
-
231
-
-
0346615403
-
-
See AXELROD, EVOLUTION, supra note 190 (discussing steps that increase the stability of cooperation)
-
See AXELROD, EVOLUTION, supra note 190 (discussing steps that increase the stability of cooperation).
-
-
-
-
232
-
-
0347245089
-
-
note
-
Cotton industry institutions go to great lengths to instill a sense of solidarity or joint purpose in their members. See, e.g., Dr. Orley B. Caudill, Interviewer, An Oral History with Mr. W.D. Lawson, III, Mississippi Oral History Program of the University of Southern Mississippi, Vol. 126 at 15 (1980) ("We would have meetings as merchants, in fact we think we were better organized than any group there because we even had meetings before meetings. We were in constant communication with one another. Being a smaller group, we could do this and we spoke with one voice."). To encourage international solidarity, cotton firms around the world have long educated each other's apprentices or "squidges." See BUSH, supra note 113, at 13 (relating that "[a]mong the firm's half-dozen samplers and sample-room porters, there's nearly always one foreign squidge; this is a time-honored practice in all cotton houses and has made the cotton world a club. Family connection often plays a part").
-
-
-
-
233
-
-
0347875676
-
-
note
-
The industry sponsors a college for new members that encourages young traders to inquire closely into the reputations of their trading partners. See Neal P. Gillen, Resolution of Contract Disputes in the Commerce of Cotton Within and Without the U.S., Lecture at Rhodes College (July 20, 1995) (transcript on file with author) ("I urge each of you to deal only with those who you know and trust. If you do not know the producer, the ginner, merchant, or textile mill, check them out thoroughly. If the price or terms are too good to be true, they usually are. This is a competitive business, and when your contract price and terms are significantly better than the norm in the market, something usually goes wrong and the losses far exceed the potential profit you thought you would realize."). In addition, in many large firms, retired traders come in a few days a week to serve as mentors and teachers to younger traders.
-
-
-
-
234
-
-
0347875672
-
-
AXELROD, supra note 190, at 139
-
AXELROD, supra note 190, at 139.
-
-
-
-
235
-
-
0347245086
-
-
note
-
Given that reputation-based NLSs such as strong negative gossip are costly for an aggrieved party to impose and result in no direct pecuniary benefit to her, it is important to explore why, apart from a strong retributive instinct (something that is present in many instances), her threat to impose them could ever be credible. Consider a situation in which a buyer (B) is trying to decide whether to impose such a sanction on a breaching seller (S). If B imposes the sanction, it has two distinct effects. First, it imposes a cost on S without resulting in any direct pecuniary benefit to B. Second, and perhaps more important, B signals to the market that she is likely to be willing ti impose such sanctions on those who breach contracts with her in the future. B's signal in this context is credible prescisely because the sanction is costly for her to impose and results in no pecuniary gain to her. It would therefore be irrational for her to impose the sanction if she didn't plan to stay in the market long enough to reap the benefits of the enhanced "deterrence" she has purchased. As a consequence, when B inposes such a NLS, she signals to the market that she cares about obtaining performance rather than a remedy for nonperformance. However, when B imposes a NLS, she also signals to the relevant pool of market transactors that she is more expensive to deal with than previously thought. As a consequence, B's decision to impose a NLS in one transaction will affect her future transactional opportunities. To more clearly understand how B's future opportunities will be affected, consider a situation where a B transacts with Ss who all select their level of precaution against inadvertent breach at the firm, rather than at the transaction, level. This approach to precaution is common in the cotton industry. Most merchant firms keep different levels of inventory, have different degrees of diversification of their supply bases, and use a variety of different modes of transportation, each with its own assocaited risk of delay and quality harm, making their precaution levels largely exogenous as to any one contract, and only imperfectly observable to market participants. Further, assume that in any one instance of breach, B will have difficulty accurately distinguishing inadvertent breach after optimal precautions have been taken from the type of willful breach that transactors view as "laying down on a contract" and strongly indicative of a propensity to behave badly in any of a number of ways in the future. In such a situation, B will reason that if she imposes the NLS and sends the associated signal to the market, not all Ss will respond to it in the same way. Merchant firms who take a low level of precaution ("bad types"), will now view dealing with her as being a great deal more costly and while merchant-firms who take a high level of precaution ("good types"), will also view dealing with her as more costly, the expected increment of added cost to them is lower. Because the "good types" take more precaution, their probability of inadvertent breach is lower than it is for the bad types, so the expected value of the increased sanction is less for good types than it is for the bad types. The "good types" will therefore be more willing than the "bad types" to deal with B. From the perspective of the "good types," the fact that they face higher sanctions in dealing with B creates a benefit for them - since in order to obtain a higher price, they are faced with the challenge of establishing that they are "good types." Although a S's reputation is partially, though imperfectly, revealed through the information about his reputation circulating in the market (and perhaps his association membership status), the ability of a S to communicate his "good type" status more credibly by willingly assuming the risk of a higher sanction is certainly furthered through the sorting engendered by B's imposition of the NLS. Once this sorting takes place, and a B who has imposed a quasi-multilateral NLS returns to the market to buy again, she will face a situation where fewer people will want to deal with her since she is now more costly to deal with (the "sorting effect"). However, those Ss who do want to deal with her will be disproportionately good types - those with a lower probability of breach (the "quality effect"). In market contexts where the "quality effect" dominates the "sorting effect," B's decision to impose the NLS against S can, up to a point, increase the value of the subsequent contracts she enters into with this and other S's, thereby making it worthwhile for her to bear the cost of imposing the sanction. In cotton markets, the "quality effect" should dominate the "sorting effect."
-
-
-
-
236
-
-
0347245083
-
-
note
-
If, however, the aggrieved party would get the benefit described supra note 226, from imposing the NLS of $L, the minimum amount she would accept for settling rather than litigating, collecting damages, and imposing the NLS would be $D plus some additional increment representing the nonpecuniary benefit of imposing the NLS less the cost of doing so.
-
-
-
-
237
-
-
0346615399
-
-
note
-
Although the magnitude and structure of the hybrid sanctions available in the industry could be replicated though an ordinary decoupling scheme in which a portion of any recovery is paid to the association's treasury, the incentives created by the association's recourse to hybrid monetary and nonlegal sanctions would not be replicated. The decoupled monetary sanction would not succeed in bonding interior contractual promises nor would it create any additional incentive for the parties to enter into a subsequent transaction and thereby potentially restore their cooperative dealings. In addition, the absence of the NLSs would make it difficult for the transactors to vary their written agreements through credible extralegal understandings.
-
-
-
-
238
-
-
0346615398
-
-
This might have been more important in the past when both merchant and mill concerns were smaller and emotions were an important reason disputes went to arbitration
-
This might have been more important in the past when both merchant and mill concerns were smaller and emotions were an important reason disputes went to arbitration.
-
-
-
-
239
-
-
0347875670
-
-
note
-
MCE Case No 840 (1991); see also MCE Case No. 827 (1975) (holding, in the context of a multi-person and multi-country string trade, that the gin, not the defendant merchants was at fault and directing the defendant to "give full support to [the plaintiff] in their efforts to collect this claim"). Sometimes MCE arbitrators try to pressure the parties to work out their problems before a hearing. See undated memo in case file for MCE Case No. 838 (1991) (noting that "[a]t Meeting on August - 13, [sic] 1991, the firms were asked by the committee to please make every attempt to deliver, class, and accept the cotton due on this con-tract [sic]." They were talked to by several members of the committee and given a "two week deadline").
-
-
-
-
240
-
-
0347245081
-
-
Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997)
-
Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997).
-
-
-
-
241
-
-
24244470593
-
-
COM. APPEAL, May 11
-
See Perre Magness, Memphis History Woven in Cotton, COM. APPEAL, May 11, 2000, at CC2 (noting that the MCE was organized in 1873, and that by 1900, the "Exchange absolutely controlled the cotton dealings of the Memphis merchant and provided for arbitration of any differences that arose among its members over sales delivery, or character of the cotton prescribed in sales contracts").
-
(2000)
Magness, Memphis History Woven in Cotton
-
-
Perre1
-
242
-
-
0347875667
-
-
note
-
Over the past ten years, however, technological advancements and other market changes have occurred that may, over the long run, undermine the ability of industry institutions to promote cooperation. Changes in mill production methods have made certain types of flexibility much more costly. New mill equipment is more sensitive to small differences in cotton quality. Mills producing certain types of goods have therefore become much more exacting and much less flexible about the precise quality of goods delivered. In addition, as mills have adopted just-in-time inventory methods, on-time delivery has become more important. Even small delivery delays can cause costly shut downs of production runs. This change in inventory control methods, combined with other technological innovations that have greatly increased the productivity of mill runs, has increased the cost of responding flexibly to quality shortfalls by negotiating a price adjustment, or to delays by accepting goods late and waiving applicable fines. It has resulted in a situation where even short shut downs can lead to large losses. As the cost of flexibility increases, the likelihood that cooperation, once established, will break down also increases, particularly where, as in cotton trading, the probability of certain types of inadvertent breach is high. Another change that may affect the likelihood that cooperative relationships will arise and endure is the introduction of the relatively objective High Volume Instrument ("HVI") method of grading cotton. Although HVI classing is too expensive to use on every bale, its cost is going down and it may soon supplant reputation as the more desirable bond of quality. Since the need to rely on reputation to bond quality made the marginal cost of relying on it to bond additional obligations quite small, when HVI classing becomes inexpensive enough to use in everyday transactions, the marginal cost of using reputation to bond other aspects of these transactions will increase and it is possible that a rapid shift to more formal contracting methods will result. On the other hand, because HVI reduces misclassification risk, it may make existing cooperative relationships somewhat more stable. Finally, the move from small firms to huge concerns with multiple agents buying and selling for their accounts may also undermine the maintenance of cooperation by making agents less willing to be conciliatory when disputes arise. As one merchant who had been in the business for a long time explained, today "people are more insistent on proving that they are right even when they are wrong, primarily since there is a perceived need to cover your tail within your own company since jobs are no longer life-long as they used to be." Telephone Interview with Merchant #9 (July 1996).
-
-
-
-
243
-
-
0039548966
-
Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships
-
For a discussion of these considerations in commercial behavior, see generally David Charny, Nonlegal Sanctions in Commercial Relationships, 104 HARV. L. REV. 373 (1990).
-
(1990)
Harv. L. Rev.
, vol.104
, pp. 373
-
-
Charny, D.1
-
244
-
-
30744448520
-
Fairness, Character and Efficiency in Firms
-
This point is forcefully made in Robert Cooler & Melvin Eisenberg, Fairness, Character and Efficiency in Firms, 149 U. PA. L. REV. 1717 (2001).
-
(2001)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.149
, pp. 1717
-
-
Cooler, R.1
Eisenberg, M.2
-
245
-
-
0347873755
-
The Questionable Empirical Basis of Article 2's Incorporation Strategy: A Preliminary Study
-
For example, under the Federal Arbitration Act and most state arbitration acts, arbitrators are bound to decide cases by applying the law. See Ware, supra note 73. As a consequence, in industries where social bonds are not strong enough to prevent recourse to the courts, PLSs cannot adopt written rules that conflict with the UCC, something that the study of merchant-run PLSs suggests that it might be highly desirable for them to do. See Bernstein, PALGRAVE, supra note 65; Bernstein, Merchant Law, supra note 60; Lisa Bernstein, The Questionable Empirical Basis of Article 2's Incorporation Strategy: A Preliminary Study, 66 U. CHI. L. REV. 710 (1999).
-
(1999)
U. Chi. L. Rev.
, vol.66
, pp. 710
-
-
Bernstein, L.1
-
246
-
-
0009126486
-
Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis
-
There are a number of reasons to think that the cotton industry's PLS is socially desirable from an economic point of view. First, absent information problems or externalities, neither of which are present in this industry, ex ante agreements to resolve disputes through binding alternative dispute resolution generally increase social welfare. See Steven Shavell, Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1996). The presence of coercion or duress is another reason that ex ante agreements to use ADR may not be socially beneficial. Although the fact that most cotton associations require their members to arbitrate disputes with other members as a condition of membership might be viewed as coercive, because transactors view other, unrelated association benefits as nearly indispensable, the available evidence suggests that industry participants not only view arbitration as a desirable alternative to litigation, but also consider it one of the primary benefits of trade association membership. Second, the PLS and the other institutional arrangements that support it appear to promote transactional efficiency without creating barriers to entry or other serious anticompetitive effects. Although an industry's decision to rely on reputation-based nonlegal sanctions does create some barriers to entry, since it takes time to establish a reputation, the availability of association membership, which provides newer transactors with a valuable piece of non-relationship-specific reputational capital, lowers these barriers. In addition, from the time of their founding until the present, these associations have gone to great lengths to increase the size of their memberships, consistent with the goal of ensuring that only transactors of good repute were admitted. See, e.g., President's Address, Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (Apr. 18, 1936) ("Each member should make it his business to see that all of the responsible cotton men in his locality are informed as to the benefits which the shippers' associations have secured not only for their own members but for the trade as a whole. This is another matter which the incoming administration would do well to specialize on."); Minutes of the SCA Annual Meeting (Apr. 5, 1957) ("The Southern Cotton Association is designed to effectuate a cohesiveness of our segment in our territory. The groundwork for that lines [sic] in keeping our enrollment at a high level. The best 'weapon of enrollment' we can employ is the member-to-prospect contact. Let's make use of it."); Minutes of the ACA Fall Board of Directors' Meeting (Oct. 11, 1980) ("The Secretary advised the Directors that he had secured the names of nonmembers of the Association and had requested various members by regions to make the necessary contacts in an effort to build-up our membership."); ACA Circular Letter No. 10 - 1994/1995 (Sept. 27, 1994) (exhorting members to assist in recruiting new members). Moreover, the only association that explicitly limits the size of its membership is the MCE whose By-Laws provide for a maximum of 132 members. MCE CONST., Art. VI, § 1. In the past, this limit imposed a binding constraint that led to a secondary market in memberships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("In the old days the value of membership might be tens of thousands of dollars."). In recent decades, however, this ceiling has not restricted admissions The Exchange currently has only ninety member firms, and the tremendous consolidation that has taken place in the industry over the past two decades suggests that this membership limit is unlikely to impose a meaningful constraint in the future. Third, most of the group and individual benefits created by the system - such as the reduction in the caseload of the public courts, the reduction in the deadweight cost of disputing, and the emergence of cooperation - are also socially desirable. Fourth, the existence of these domestic institutions, which are part of a network of institutions that operate all over the world, facilitates international trade. In the absence of these institutions many transactions involving developing and formerly socialist countries might not occur because of the risk of hold-up, the weakened force of bilateral reputation bonds and nonlegal sanctions, and the difficulties of obtaining and enforcing judgments. In addition the cost of dealing with foreign transactors, even in countries with well-developed legal systems would also be quite high if the deals were governed by public legal systems. Enforcement problems would remain and the applicable laws would still have to be determined by complex choice of law and jurisdictional rules. In addition, a merchant dealing in many countries would have to learn the law in all of them.
-
(1996)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.24
, pp. 1
-
-
Shavell, S.1
-
247
-
-
0003722920
-
-
There are a number of reasons to think that the cotton industry's PLS is socially desirable from an economic point of view. First, absent information problems or externalities, neither of which are present in this industry, ex ante agreements to resolve disputes through binding alternative dispute resolution generally increase social welfare. See Steven Shavell, Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1996). The presence of coercion or duress is another reason that ex ante agreements to use ADR may not be socially beneficial. Although the fact that most cotton associations require their members to arbitrate disputes with other members as a condition of membership might be viewed as coercive, because transactors view other, unrelated association benefits as nearly indispensable, the available evidence suggests that industry participants not only view arbitration as a desirable alternative to litigation, but also consider it one of the primary benefits of trade association membership. Second, the PLS and the other institutional arrangements that support it appear to promote transactional efficiency without creating barriers to entry or other serious anticompetitive effects. Although an industry's decision to rely on reputation-based nonlegal sanctions does create some barriers to entry, since it takes time to establish a reputation, the availability of association membership, which provides newer transactors with a valuable piece of non-relationship-specific reputational capital, lowers these barriers. In addition, from the time of their founding until the present, these associations have gone to great lengths to increase the size of their memberships, consistent with the goal of ensuring that only transactors of good repute were admitted. See, e.g., President's Address, Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (Apr. 18, 1936) ("Each member should make it his business to see that all of the responsible cotton men in his locality are informed as to the benefits which the shippers' associations have secured not only for their own members but for the trade as a whole. This is another matter which the incoming administration would do well to specialize on."); Minutes of the SCA Annual Meeting (Apr. 5, 1957) ("The Southern Cotton Association is designed to effectuate a cohesiveness of our segment in our territory. The groundwork for that lines [sic] in keeping our enrollment at a high level. The best 'weapon of enrollment' we can employ is the member-to-prospect contact. Let's make use of it."); Minutes of the ACA Fall Board of Directors' Meeting (Oct. 11, 1980) ("The Secretary advised the Directors that he had secured the names of nonmembers of the Association and had requested various members by regions to make the necessary contacts in an effort to build-up our membership."); ACA Circular Letter No. 10 - 1994/1995 (Sept. 27, 1994) (exhorting members to assist in recruiting new members). Moreover, the only association that explicitly limits the size of its membership is the MCE whose By-Laws provide for a maximum of 132 members. MCE CONST., Art. VI, § 1. In the past, this limit imposed a binding constraint that led to a secondary market in memberships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("In the old days the value of membership might be tens of thousands of dollars."). In recent decades, however, this ceiling has not restricted admissions The Exchange currently has only ninety member firms, and the tremendous consolidation that has taken place in the industry over the past two decades suggests that this membership limit is unlikely to impose a meaningful constraint in the future. Third, most of the group and individual benefits created by the system - such as the reduction in the caseload of the public courts, the reduction in the deadweight cost of disputing, and the emergence of cooperation - are also socially desirable. Fourth, the existence of these domestic institutions, which are part of a network of institutions that operate all over the world, facilitates international trade. In the absence of these institutions many transactions involving developing and formerly socialist countries might not occur because of the risk of hold-up, the weakened force of bilateral reputation bonds and nonlegal sanctions, and the difficulties of obtaining and enforcing judgments. In addition the cost of dealing with foreign transactors, even in countries with well-developed legal systems would also be quite high if the deals were governed by public legal systems. Enforcement problems would remain and the applicable laws would still have to be determined by complex choice of law and jurisdictional rules. In addition, a merchant dealing in many countries would have to learn the law in all of them.
-
(1988)
Antitrust Analysis: Problems, Text, Cases
, pp. 160
-
-
Areeda, P.1
Kaplow, L.2
-
248
-
-
84917002050
-
Alternative Dispute Resolution: Panacea or Anathema?
-
There are a number of reasons to think that the cotton industry's PLS is socially desirable from an economic point of view. First, absent information problems or externalities, neither of which are present in this industry, ex ante agreements to resolve disputes through binding alternative dispute resolution generally increase social welfare. See Steven Shavell, Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1996). The presence of coercion or duress is another reason that ex ante agreements to use ADR may not be socially beneficial. Although the fact that most cotton associations require their members to arbitrate disputes with other members as a condition of membership might be viewed as coercive, because transactors view other, unrelated association benefits as nearly indispensable, the available evidence suggests that industry participants not only view arbitration as a desirable alternative to litigation, but also consider it one of the primary benefits of trade association membership. Second, the PLS and the other institutional arrangements that support it appear to promote transactional efficiency without creating barriers to entry or other serious anticompetitive effects. Although an industry's decision to rely on reputation-based nonlegal sanctions does create some barriers to entry, since it takes time to establish a reputation, the availability of association membership, which provides newer transactors with a valuable piece of non-relationship-specific reputational capital, lowers these barriers. In addition, from the time of their founding until the present, these associations have gone to great lengths to increase the size of their memberships, consistent with the goal of ensuring that only transactors of good repute were admitted. See, e.g., President's Address, Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (Apr. 18, 1936) ("Each member should make it his business to see that all of the responsible cotton men in his locality are informed as to the benefits which the shippers' associations have secured not only for their own members but for the trade as a whole. This is another matter which the incoming administration would do well to specialize on."); Minutes of the SCA Annual Meeting (Apr. 5, 1957) ("The Southern Cotton Association is designed to effectuate a cohesiveness of our segment in our territory. The groundwork for that lines [sic] in keeping our enrollment at a high level. The best 'weapon of enrollment' we can employ is the member-to-prospect contact. Let's make use of it."); Minutes of the ACA Fall Board of Directors' Meeting (Oct. 11, 1980) ("The Secretary advised the Directors that he had secured the names of nonmembers of the Association and had requested various members by regions to make the necessary contacts in an effort to build-up our membership."); ACA Circular Letter No. 10 - 1994/1995 (Sept. 27, 1994) (exhorting members to assist in recruiting new members). Moreover, the only association that explicitly limits the size of its membership is the MCE whose By-Laws provide for a maximum of 132 members. MCE CONST., Art. VI, § 1. In the past, this limit imposed a binding constraint that led to a secondary market in memberships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("In the old days the value of membership might be tens of thousands of dollars."). In recent decades, however, this ceiling has not restricted admissions The Exchange currently has only ninety member firms, and the tremendous consolidation that has taken place in the industry over the past two decades suggests that this membership limit is unlikely to impose a meaningful constraint in the future. Third, most of the group and individual benefits created by the system - such as the reduction in the caseload of the public courts, the reduction in the deadweight cost of disputing, and the emergence of cooperation - are also socially desirable. Fourth, the existence of these domestic institutions, which are part of a network of institutions that operate all over the world, facilitates international trade. In the absence of these institutions many transactions involving developing and formerly socialist countries might not occur because of the risk of hold-up, the weakened force of bilateral reputation bonds and nonlegal sanctions, and the difficulties of obtaining and enforcing judgments. In addition the cost of dealing with foreign transactors, even in countries with well-developed legal systems would also be quite high if the deals were governed by public legal systems. Enforcement problems would remain and the applicable laws would still have to be determined by complex choice of law and jurisdictional rules. In addition, a merchant dealing in many countries would have to learn the law in all of them.
-
(1986)
Harv. L. Rev.
, vol.99
, pp. 668
-
-
Edwards, H.T.1
-
249
-
-
34548637846
-
Against Settlement
-
There are a number of reasons to think that the cotton industry's PLS is socially desirable from an economic point of view. First, absent information problems or externalities, neither of which are present in this industry, ex ante agreements to resolve disputes through binding alternative dispute resolution generally increase social welfare. See Steven Shavell, Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1996). The presence of coercion or duress is another reason that ex ante agreements to use ADR may not be socially beneficial. Although the fact that most cotton associations require their members to arbitrate disputes with other members as a condition of membership might be viewed as coercive, because transactors view other, unrelated association benefits as nearly indispensable, the available evidence suggests that industry participants not only view arbitration as a desirable alternative to litigation, but also consider it one of the primary benefits of trade association membership. Second, the PLS and the other institutional arrangements that support it appear to promote transactional efficiency without creating barriers to entry or other serious anticompetitive effects. Although an industry's decision to rely on reputation-based nonlegal sanctions does create some barriers to entry, since it takes time to establish a reputation, the availability of association membership, which provides newer transactors with a valuable piece of non-relationship-specific reputational capital, lowers these barriers. In addition, from the time of their founding until the present, these associations have gone to great lengths to increase the size of their memberships, consistent with the goal of ensuring that only transactors of good repute were admitted. See, e.g., President's Address, Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (Apr. 18, 1936) ("Each member should make it his business to see that all of the responsible cotton men in his locality are informed as to the benefits which the shippers' associations have secured not only for their own members but for the trade as a whole. This is another matter which the incoming administration would do well to specialize on."); Minutes of the SCA Annual Meeting (Apr. 5, 1957) ("The Southern Cotton Association is designed to effectuate a cohesiveness of our segment in our territory. The groundwork for that lines [sic] in keeping our enrollment at a high level. The best 'weapon of enrollment' we can employ is the member-to-prospect contact. Let's make use of it."); Minutes of the ACA Fall Board of Directors' Meeting (Oct. 11, 1980) ("The Secretary advised the Directors that he had secured the names of nonmembers of the Association and had requested various members by regions to make the necessary contacts in an effort to build-up our membership."); ACA Circular Letter No. 10 - 1994/1995 (Sept. 27, 1994) (exhorting members to assist in recruiting new members). Moreover, the only association that explicitly limits the size of its membership is the MCE whose By-Laws provide for a maximum of 132 members. MCE CONST., Art. VI, § 1. In the past, this limit imposed a binding constraint that led to a secondary market in memberships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("In the old days the value of membership might be tens of thousands of dollars."). In recent decades, however, this ceiling has not restricted admissions The Exchange currently has only ninety member firms, and the tremendous consolidation that has taken place in the industry over the past two decades suggests that this membership limit is unlikely to impose a meaningful constraint in the future. Third, most of the group and individual benefits created by the system - such as the reduction in the caseload of the public courts, the reduction in the deadweight cost of disputing, and the emergence of cooperation - are also socially desirable. Fourth, the existence of these domestic institutions, which are part of a network of institutions that operate all over the world, facilitates international trade. In the absence of these institutions many transactions involving developing and formerly socialist countries might not occur because of the risk of hold-up, the weakened force of bilateral reputation bonds and nonlegal sanctions, and the difficulties of obtaining and enforcing judgments. In addition the cost of dealing with foreign transactors, even in countries with well-developed legal systems would also be quite high if the deals were governed by public legal systems. Enforcement problems would remain and the applicable laws would still have to be determined by complex choice of law and jurisdictional rules. In addition, a merchant dealing in many countries would have to learn the law in all of them.
-
(1984)
Yale L.J.
, vol.93
, pp. 1073
-
-
Fiss, O.M.1
-
250
-
-
84928838440
-
The New Jersey Alternative Procedure for Dispute Resolution: Vanguard of a 'Better Way?,'
-
There are a number of reasons to think that the cotton industry's PLS is socially desirable from an economic point of view. First, absent information problems or externalities, neither of which are present in this industry, ex ante agreements to resolve disputes through binding alternative dispute resolution generally increase social welfare. See Steven Shavell, Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1996). The presence of coercion or duress is another reason that ex ante agreements to use ADR may not be socially beneficial. Although the fact that most cotton associations require their members to arbitrate disputes with other members as a condition of membership might be viewed as coercive, because transactors view other, unrelated association benefits as nearly indispensable, the available evidence suggests that industry participants not only view arbitration as a desirable alternative to litigation, but also consider it one of the primary benefits of trade association membership. Second, the PLS and the other institutional arrangements that support it appear to promote transactional efficiency without creating barriers to entry or other serious anticompetitive effects. Although an industry's decision to rely on reputation-based nonlegal sanctions does create some barriers to entry, since it takes time to establish a reputation, the availability of association membership, which provides newer transactors with a valuable piece of non-relationship-specific reputational capital, lowers these barriers. In addition, from the time of their founding until the present, these associations have gone to great lengths to increase the size of their memberships, consistent with the goal of ensuring that only transactors of good repute were admitted. See, e.g., President's Address, Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (Apr. 18, 1936) ("Each member should make it his business to see that all of the responsible cotton men in his locality are informed as to the benefits which the shippers' associations have secured not only for their own members but for the trade as a whole. This is another matter which the incoming administration would do well to specialize on."); Minutes of the SCA Annual Meeting (Apr. 5, 1957) ("The Southern Cotton Association is designed to effectuate a cohesiveness of our segment in our territory. The groundwork for that lines [sic] in keeping our enrollment at a high level. The best 'weapon of enrollment' we can employ is the member-to-prospect contact. Let's make use of it."); Minutes of the ACA Fall Board of Directors' Meeting (Oct. 11, 1980) ("The Secretary advised the Directors that he had secured the names of nonmembers of the Association and had requested various members by regions to make the necessary contacts in an effort to build-up our membership."); ACA Circular Letter No. 10 - 1994/1995 (Sept. 27, 1994) (exhorting members to assist in recruiting new members). Moreover, the only association that explicitly limits the size of its membership is the MCE whose By-Laws provide for a maximum of 132 members. MCE CONST., Art. VI, § 1. In the past, this limit imposed a binding constraint that led to a secondary market in memberships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("In the old days the value of membership might be tens of thousands of dollars."). In recent decades, however, this ceiling has not restricted admissions The Exchange currently has only ninety member firms, and the tremendous consolidation that has taken place in the industry over the past two decades suggests that this membership limit is unlikely to impose a meaningful constraint in the future. Third, most of the group and individual benefits created by the system - such as the reduction in the caseload of the public courts, the reduction in the deadweight cost of disputing, and the emergence of cooperation - are also socially desirable. Fourth, the existence of these domestic institutions, which are part of a network of institutions that operate all over the world, facilitates international trade. In the absence of these institutions many transactions involving developing and formerly socialist countries might not occur because of the risk of hold-up, the weakened force of bilateral reputation bonds and nonlegal sanctions, and the difficulties of obtaining and enforcing judgments. In addition the cost of dealing with foreign transactors, even in countries with well-developed legal systems would also be quite high if the deals were governed by public legal systems. Enforcement problems would remain and the applicable laws would still have to be determined by complex choice of law and jurisdictional rules. In addition, a merchant dealing in many countries would have to learn the law in all of them.
-
(1988)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.136
, pp. 1723
-
-
O'Hara, J.V.1
-
251
-
-
84874816001
-
Adjudication as a Private Good
-
There are a number of reasons to think that the cotton industry's PLS is socially desirable from an economic point of view. First, absent information problems or externalities, neither of which are present in this industry, ex ante agreements to resolve disputes through binding alternative dispute resolution generally increase social welfare. See Steven Shavell, Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis, 24 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1996). The presence of coercion or duress is another reason that ex ante agreements to use ADR may not be socially beneficial. Although the fact that most cotton associations require their members to arbitrate disputes with other members as a condition of membership might be viewed as coercive, because transactors view other, unrelated association benefits as nearly indispensable, the available evidence suggests that industry participants not only view arbitration as a desirable alternative to litigation, but also consider it one of the primary benefits of trade association membership. Second, the PLS and the other institutional arrangements that support it appear to promote transactional efficiency without creating barriers to entry or other serious anticompetitive effects. Although an industry's decision to rely on reputation-based nonlegal sanctions does create some barriers to entry, since it takes time to establish a reputation, the availability of association membership, which provides newer transactors with a valuable piece of non-relationship-specific reputational capital, lowers these barriers. In addition, from the time of their founding until the present, these associations have gone to great lengths to increase the size of their memberships, consistent with the goal of ensuring that only transactors of good repute were admitted. See, e.g., President's Address, Minutes of the SCSA Annual Meeting (Apr. 18, 1936) ("Each member should make it his business to see that all of the responsible cotton men in his locality are informed as to the benefits which the shippers' associations have secured not only for their own members but for the trade as a whole. This is another matter which the incoming administration would do well to specialize on."); Minutes of the SCA Annual Meeting (Apr. 5, 1957) ("The Southern Cotton Association is designed to effectuate a cohesiveness of our segment in our territory. The groundwork for that lines [sic] in keeping our enrollment at a high level. The best 'weapon of enrollment' we can employ is the member-to-prospect contact. Let's make use of it."); Minutes of the ACA Fall Board of Directors' Meeting (Oct. 11, 1980) ("The Secretary advised the Directors that he had secured the names of nonmembers of the Association and had requested various members by regions to make the necessary contacts in an effort to build-up our membership."); ACA Circular Letter No. 10 - 1994/1995 (Sept. 27, 1994) (exhorting members to assist in recruiting new members). Moreover, the only association that explicitly limits the size of its membership is the MCE whose By-Laws provide for a maximum of 132 members. MCE CONST., Art. VI, § 1. In the past, this limit imposed a binding constraint that led to a secondary market in memberships. See, e.g., Telephone Interview with MCE Executive (Feb. 1997) ("In the old days the value of membership might be tens of thousands of dollars."). In recent decades, however, this ceiling has not restricted admissions The Exchange currently has only ninety member firms, and the tremendous consolidation that has taken place in the industry over the past two decades suggests that this membership limit is unlikely to impose a meaningful constraint in the future. Third, most of the group and individual benefits created by the system - such as the reduction in the caseload of the public courts, the reduction in the deadweight cost of disputing, and the emergence of cooperation - are also socially desirable. Fourth, the existence of these domestic institutions, which are part of a network of institutions that operate all over the world, facilitates international trade. In the absence of these institutions many transactions involving developing and formerly socialist countries might not occur because of the risk of hold-up, the weakened force of bilateral reputation bonds and nonlegal sanctions, and the difficulties of obtaining and enforcing judgments. In addition the cost of dealing with foreign transactors, even in countries with well-developed legal systems would also be quite high if the deals were governed by public legal systems. Enforcement problems would remain and the applicable laws would still have to be determined by complex choice of law and jurisdictional rules. In addition, a merchant dealing in many countries would have to learn the law in all of them.
-
(1979)
J. Legal Stud.
, vol.8
, pp. 255
-
-
Landes, W.M.1
Posner, R.A.2
-
252
-
-
0347875660
-
-
note
-
Although at present, industry-run PLSs do not, standing alone, create antitrust problems, the availability of the antitrust laws to ensure that the associations do not engage in anticompetitive behavior may be important. In addition, state arbitration laws that require some minimal procedural protections before an award is enforceable also enhance the functioning of private systems. However, there are some types of regulatory oversight that are viewed as socially desirable for reasons having nothing to do with commercial law that may make it more difficult for new industries to create PLSs that are also able to capture all the benefits associated with a strong infrastructure of trade. For example, antidiscrimination laws make it more difficult, if not impossible, to maintain socially, ethnically, or gender-homogenous associations, especially when those groups command economic power.
-
-
-
|