메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 57, Issue 1, 2004, Pages 1-38

Do intergovernmental organizations promote peace?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

CONFLICT MANAGEMENT; ORGANIZATIONAL FRAMEWORK; PEACE PROCESS;

EID: 24144481279     PISSN: 00438871     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1353/wp.2005.0008     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (196)

References (124)
  • 1
    • 0040676472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985"
    • See, for example
    • See, for example, Bruce Russett, John R. Oneal, and David Davis, "The Third Leg of the Kantian Tripod for Peace: International Organizations and Militarized Disputes, 1950-1985," International Organization 52, no. 3 (1998);
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.3
    • Russett, B.1    Oneal, J.R.2    Davis, D.3
  • 3
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October)
    • See John R. Oneal and Bruce Russett, "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992," World Politics 52 (October 1999);
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 4
    • 0035632134 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict"
    • Erik Gartzke, Quan Li, and Charles Boehmer, "Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict," International Organization 55, no. 2 (2001).
    • (2001) International Organization , vol.55 , Issue.2
    • Gartzke, E.1    Li, Q.2    Boehmer, C.3
  • 5
    • 21844491800 scopus 로고
    • "The False Promise of International Institutions"
    • John Mearsheimer, "The False Promise of International Institutions," International Security 19, no. 3 (1995);
    • (1995) International Security , vol.19 , Issue.3
    • Mearsheimer, J.1
  • 6
    • 0031400090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate"
    • Randall L. Schweller and David Preiss, "A Tale of Two Realisms: Expanding the Institutions Debate," Mershon International Studies Review 41, no. 1 (1997).
    • (1997) Mershon International Studies Review , vol.41 , Issue.1
    • Schweller, R.L.1    Preiss, D.2
  • 7
    • 85008779563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Organizations"
    • And for reviews of and perspectives on the literature, see
    • And for reviews of and perspectives on the literature, see Lisa L. Martin and Beth A. Simmons, "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Organizations," International Organization 52, no. 4 (1998).
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.4
    • Martin, L.L.1    Simmons, B.A.2
  • 10
    • 84976161933 scopus 로고
    • "International Regimes: Toward a New Theory of Institutions"
    • (October)
    • Oran R. Young, "International Regimes: Toward a New Theory of Institutions," World Politics 39 (October 1986);
    • (1986) World Politics , vol.39
    • Young, O.R.1
  • 11
    • 0002965999 scopus 로고
    • "The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard Cases and Critical Variables"
    • James M. Rosenau and Ernst-Otto Czempiel, eds., (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • idem, "The Effectiveness of International Institutions: Hard Cases and Critical Variables," in James M. Rosenau and Ernst-Otto Czempiel, eds., Governance without Government (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992);
    • (1992) Governance Without Government
    • Young, O.R.1
  • 12
    • 84971736924 scopus 로고
    • "Continuity and Transformation in the World Polity: Toward a Neorealist Synthesis"
    • (January)
    • John Gerard Ruggie, "Continuity and Transformation in the World Polity: Toward a Neorealist Synthesis," World Politics 35 (January 1983);
    • (1983) World Politics , vol.35
    • Ruggie, J.G.1
  • 13
    • 84859116189 scopus 로고
    • "The False Promise of Realism"
    • idem, "The False Promise of Realism," International Security 20, no. 1 (1995);
    • (1995) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.1
    • Ruggie, J.G.1
  • 14
    • 0000547301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Citizenship in a Changing Global Order"
    • Rosenau and Czempiel
    • James M. Rosenau, "Citizenship in a Changing Global Order," in Rosenau and Czempiel, Governance without Government;
    • Governance Without Government
    • Rosenau, J.M.1
  • 15
    • 84861908067 scopus 로고
    • "Constructing International Politics"
    • and Alexander Wendt, "Constructing International Politics," International Security 20, no. 1 (1995).
    • (1995) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.1
    • Wendt, A.1
  • 18
    • 84974265413 scopus 로고
    • "Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions"
    • (October)
    • Robert Axelrod and Robert O. Keohane, "Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions," World Politics 38 (October 1985);
    • (1985) World Politics , vol.38
    • Axelrod, R.1    Keohane, R.O.2
  • 19
    • 84971748261 scopus 로고
    • "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory"
    • Robert Powell, "Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory," American Political Science Review 85, no. 4 (1991);
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85 , Issue.4
    • Powell, R.1
  • 20
    • 84971736578 scopus 로고
    • "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation"
    • Duncan Snidal, "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review 85, no. 3 (1991);
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85 , Issue.3
    • Snidal, D.1
  • 21
    • 84909412905 scopus 로고
    • "The Promise of Institutionalist Theory"
    • Robert O. Keohane and Lisa Martin, "The Promise of Institutionalist Theory," International Security 20, no. 1 (1995);
    • (1995) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.1
    • Keohane, R.O.1    Martin, L.2
  • 22
    • 5944234719 scopus 로고
    • "The Promise of Collective Security"
    • Charles A. Kupchan and Clifford A. Kupchan, "The Promise of Collective Security," International Security 20, no. 1 (1995);
    • (1995) International Security , vol.20 , Issue.1
    • Kupchan, C.A.1    Kupchan, C.A.2
  • 23
    • 0031987392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Why States Act through Formal International Organizations"
    • Duncan Snidal and Kenneth Abbott, "Why States Act through Formal International Organizations," Journal of Conflict Resolution 42, no. 1 (1998);
    • (1998) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.42 , Issue.1
    • Snidal, D.1    Abbott, K.2
  • 25
    • 84971736578 scopus 로고
    • "Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation"
    • Snidal (fn. 5) points out that contrasting predictions of absolute and relative gains depend on the number of actors involved
    • Snidal (fn. 5) points out that contrasting predictions of absolute and relative gains depend on the number of actors involved.
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85 , Issue.3
    • Snidal, D.1
  • 26
    • 34248247318 scopus 로고
    • "The Relative-Gains Problem for International Cooperation"
    • For an informative debate, see comments by
    • For an informative debate, see comments by Joseph M. Grieco, Robert Powell, and Duncan Snidal, "The Relative-Gains Problem for International Cooperation," American Political Science Review 87, no. 3 (1993).
    • (1993) American Political Science Review , vol.87 , Issue.3
    • Grieco, J.M.1    Powell, R.2    Snidal, D.3
  • 27
    • 0141815564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Relative Gains Concerns When the Number of States in the International System Increases"
    • See also
    • See also James S. Mosher, "Relative Gains Concerns When the Number of States in the International System Increases," Journal of Conflict Resolution 47, no. 5 (2003);
    • (2003) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.47 , Issue.5
    • Mosher, J.S.1
  • 28
    • 0037938738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Motivations for Choice: The Salience of Relative Gains in International Relations"
    • and David L. Rousseau, "Motivations for Choice: The Salience of Relative Gains in International Relations," Journal of Conflict Resolution 46, no. 3 (2002).
    • (2002) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.46 , Issue.3
    • Rousseau, D.L.1
  • 29
    • 0030088566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Simulating International Cooperation under Anarchy: The Effects of Symmetric and Asymmetric Noise"
    • Subsequent research suggests that the shadow of the future can actually inhibit cooperation. See
    • Subsequent research suggests that the shadow of the future can actually inhibit cooperation. See Curtis S. Signorino, "Simulating International Cooperation under Anarchy: The Effects of Symmetric and Asymmetric Noise," Journal of Conflict Resolution 40, no. 1 (1996);
    • (1996) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.40 , Issue.1
    • Signorino, C.S.1
  • 30
    • 0032355311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation"
    • James D. Fearon, "Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation," International Organization 52, no. 2 (1998);
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.2
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 31
    • 2942572639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Time Horizons and Multilateral Enforcement in International Cooperation"
    • J. Samuel Barkin, "Time Horizons and Multilateral Enforcement in International Cooperation," International Studies Quarterly 48, no. 2 (2004).
    • (2004) International Studies Quarterly , vol.48 , Issue.2
    • Barkin, J.S.1
  • 32
    • 84972218484 scopus 로고
    • "Intergovernmental Organization and the Preservation of Peace, 1816-1964: Some Bivariate Relationships"
    • J. David Singer and Michael Wallace, "Intergovernmental Organization and the Preservation of Peace, 1816-1964: Some Bivariate Relationships," International Organization 24, no. 3 (1970);
    • (1970) International Organization , vol.24 , Issue.3
    • Singer, J.D.1    Wallace, M.2
  • 33
    • 84971871416 scopus 로고
    • "Intergovernmental Organization in the Global System, 1815-1964: A Quantitative Description"
    • Michael Wallace and J. David Singer, "Intergovernmental Organization in the Global System, 1815-1964: A Quantitative Description," International Organization 24, no. 2 (1970);
    • (1970) International Organization , vol.24 , Issue.2
    • Wallace, M.1    Singer, J.D.2
  • 35
    • 84976161933 scopus 로고
    • "International Regimes: Toward a New Theory of Institutions"
    • (October)
    • Young (fn. 4, 1992);
    • (1992) World Politics , vol.39
    • Young, O.R.1
  • 37
    • 85008779563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Theories and Empirical Studies of International Organizations"
    • And for reviews of and perspectives on the literature, see provide a review of the extensive case study literature
    • Martin and Simmons (fa. 3) provide a review of the extensive case study literature.
    • (1998) International Organization , vol.52 , Issue.4
    • Martin, L.L.1    Simmons, B.A.2
  • 38
    • 0038522802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations"
    • John R. Oneal, Bruce Russett, and Michael L. Berbaum, "Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations," International Studies Quarterly 47, no. 3 (2003);
    • (2003) International Studies Quarterly , vol.47 , Issue.3
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2    Berbaum, M.L.3
  • 39
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October)
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 2);
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 43
    • 84973956151 scopus 로고
    • "National Entanglements in Governmental Organizations"
    • However, Harold Jacobson, William M. Reisinger, and Todd Mathers use an inappropriate dependent variable, whereas Domke relies on disaggregated probit estimates for each year; see
    • However, Harold Jacobson, William M. Reisinger, and Todd Mathers use an inappropriate dependent variable, whereas Domke relies on disaggregated probit estimates for each year; see Jacobson, Reisinger, and Mathers, "National Entanglements in Governmental Organizations," American Political Science Review 80, no. 1 (1986).
    • (1986) American Political Science Review , vol.80 , Issue.1
    • Jacobson, H.1    Reisinger, W.M.2    Mathers, T.3
  • 44
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October)
    • Oneal and Russett (fh. 2);
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 50
    • 84972159336 scopus 로고
    • "Rationalist Explanations for War"
    • James D. Fearon, "Rationalist Explanations for War," International Organization 49, no. 3 (1995).
    • (1995) International Organization , vol.49 , Issue.3
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 51
    • 84936012425 scopus 로고
    • "Capabilities, Uncertainty, and Resolve: A Limited Information Model of Crisis Bargaining"
    • See also
    • See also James D. Morrow, "Capabilities, Uncertainty, and Resolve: A Limited Information Model of Crisis Bargaining," American Journal of Political Science 33, no. 2 (1989).
    • (1989) American Journal of Political Science , vol.33 , Issue.2
    • Morrow, J.D.1
  • 52
    • 0141587923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Exploring the Bargaining Model of War"
    • For reviews of the rationalist literature on bargaining and war, see
    • "For reviews of the rationalist literature on bargaining and war, see Dan Reiter, "Exploring the Bargaining Model of War," Perspectives on Politics 1, no. 1 (2003);
    • (2003) Perspectives on Politics , vol.1 , Issue.1
    • Reiter, D.1
  • 53
    • 0036404908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Bargaining Theory and International Conflict"
    • and Robert Powell, "Bargaining Theory and International Conflict," AnnualReview of Political Science 5 (2002).
    • (2002) Annual Review of Political Science , vol.5
    • Powell, R.1
  • 54
    • 0043225614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Rationalist Explanations for War?"
    • For a critique, see
    • For a critique, see Jonathan Kirshner, "Rationalist Explanations for War?" Security Studies 10, no. 1 (2000).
    • (2000) Security Studies , vol.10 , Issue.1
    • Kirshner, J.1
  • 55
    • 85039369672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The notion that igos are selective in their mediation efforts is contrasted by normative and institutional incentives to intervene. Unlike peacekeeping, say, where the investment is high, organizing talks, pressuring delegates, brokering deals, informing parties, and promoting sanctions are all relatively low-cost actions. These activities are often explicitly encouraged by IGO charters, members, and interested publics. Indeed, the proliferation of security IGOs, the bulk of which are unequipped to impose peace, would appear peculiar if they were not meant to conduct such activities.
  • 56
    • 0003610021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Formal models serve, among other things, to tie tests of implications of an argument to untested elements of a theory. See (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
    • Formal models serve, among other things, to tie tests of implications of an argument to untested elements of a theory. See Rebecca B. Morton, Methods and Models: A Guide to the Empirical Analysis of Formal Models in Political Science (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999).
    • (1999) Methods and Models: A Guide to the Empirical Analysis of Formal Models in Political Science
    • Morton, R.B.1
  • 57
    • 85039369970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • States can have no incentive to dispute benefits that cannot be denied to the loser or third parties. If players value relative gains, however, war can result from nonrivalrous goods.
  • 58
    • 0034340203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Conflict without Misperception or Incomplete Information: How the Future Matters"
    • Fearon's list is not exhaustive. Risk acceptance can motivate contests, as can a consumtion value for war. There is also a broader set of commitment problems that is assumed away by Fearon's modeling framework. See, for example
    • Fearon's list is not exhaustive. Risk acceptance can motivate contests, as can a consumtion value for war. There is also a broader set of commitment problems that is assumed away by Fearon's modeling framework. See, for example, Michelle R. Garfinkel and Stergios Skaperdas, "Conflict without Misperception or Incomplete Information: How the Future Matters," Journal of Conflict Resolution 44, no. 6 (2000);
    • (2000) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.44 , Issue.6
    • Garfinkel, M.R.1    Skaperdas, S.2
  • 59
    • 0037309160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States"
    • Still, Fearon's characterization of war is coherent, widely addressed in the literature, and tractable
    • Branislav Slantchev, "The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States," American Political Science Review 97, no. 1 (2003).
    • (2003) American Political Science Review , vol.97 , Issue.1
    • Slantchev, B.1
  • 60
    • 0006087607 scopus 로고
    • (New York: Macmillan), "The likelihood of an agreement was greatly assisted by a proposal emanating from Senator Frye that the United States should offer financial compensation in exchange for the Philippines"
    • David F. Trask, The War with Spain in 1898 (New York: Macmillan, 1981), 445-66.
    • (1981) The War With Spain in 1898 , pp. 445-466
    • Trask, D.F.1
  • 62
    • 85039376088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • States often have incentives to seek to generate indivisibilities. Commitment increased bargaining power by making it harder to compromise. Third parties could allow states to extract themlseves from commitments. Blaming an IGO for having to renege on a promise may free a leader from domestic audience costs, for exxample. It is also possible, however, that IGOs increase oppourtunites for generating indivisilities. IGOs allow leaders to formalize agreements that are later binding (or at least impinging) on domestic politics. We do not explore these issues here.
  • 63
    • 0346669845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Explaining the Intractability of Territorial Conflict"
    • Commitment problems and indivisibilities may be more prevalent in intrastate conflict, where settlements often include a loss of autonomy for one of the competing parties or where any settlement implies recognition, which is part of the stakes in the contest. See
    • Commitment problems and indivisibilities may be more prevalent in intrastate conflict, where settlements often include a loss of autonomy for one of the competing parties or where any settlement implies recognition, which is part of the stakes in the contest. See Barbara F. Walter, "Explaining the Intractability of Territorial Conflict," International Studies Review 5, no. 4 (2003);
    • (2003) International Studies Review , vol.5 , Issue.4
    • Walter, B.F.1
  • 67
    • 0033415640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "How Could Trade Affect Conflict?"
    • For a succinct and highly intuitive account of the bargaining argument, see also
    • For a succinct and highly intuitive account of the bargaining argument, see also James D. Morrow, "How Could Trade Affect Conflict?" Journal of Peace Research 36, no. 4 (1999).
    • (1999) Journal of Peace Research , vol.36 , Issue.4
    • Morrow, J.D.1
  • 68
    • 0033435543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "War Is in the Error Term"
    • The asymmetric information argument is not theoretically sufficient to explain war. A sufficient account of the causes of war requires that researchers access the private information of competing states
    • Erik Gartzke, "War Is in the Error Term," International Organization 53, no. 3 (1999). The asymmetric information argument is not theoretically sufficient to explain war. A sufficient account of the causes of war requires that researchers access the private information of competing states.
    • (1999) International Organization , vol.53 , Issue.3
    • Gartzke, E.1
  • 69
    • 84972159336 scopus 로고
    • "Rationalist Explanations for War"
    • provides a formal proof. We use Fearon as the basis for our theory
    • Fearon (fn. 17) provides a formal proof We use Fearon as the basis for our theory. Robert Powell, In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International Politics (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999);
    • (1995) International Organization , vol.49 , Issue.3
    • Fearon, J.D.1
  • 71
    • 3042722111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Inefficient Use of Power: Costly Conflict with Complete Information"
    • idem, "The Inefficient Use of Power: Costly Conflict with Complete Information" American Political Science Review 98, no. 2 (2004).
    • (2004) American Political Science Review , vol.98 , Issue.2
    • Powell, R.1
  • 73
    • 0037309160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States"
    • offer alternative bargaining framworks in which commitment problems are a more important cause of war and contests can occur under full information. Which charaterization of bargaining is most general empirically remains a subject of debate. Note, however, that alternative conceptions hinge on assumptions about the sequence of offers in bargaining. Since states often negotiate about how they will negotiaye (structure is endogenous), and since a satisfactory theory of this aspect of bargaining has yet to be introduced to international relations, we adopt the simplest model of bargaining as a place of departutre. The theory we supply is shown here to better explain observed behavior than conventional liberal or realist alternatives
    • and Slantchev (fn. 22) offer alternative bargaining framworks in which commitment problems are a more important cause of war and contests can occur under full information. Which charaterization of bargaining is most general empirically remains a subject of debate. Note, however, that alternative conceptions hinge on assumptions about the sequence of offers in bargaining. Since states often negotiate about how they will negotiaye (structure is endogenous), and since a satisfactory theory of this aspect of bargaining has yet to be introduced to international relations, we adopt the simplest model of bargaining as a place of departutre. The theory we supply is shown here to better explain observed behavior than conventional liberal or realist alternatives.
    • (2003) American Political Science Review , vol.97 , Issue.1
    • Slantchev, B.1
  • 74
    • 85039380434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The security dilemma makes clear the zero-sum nature of dynamics in the balance of power. However, realists have failed to extend the insight to diplomatic bargaining. Factors that alter the likely outcomes of contests should alter the demands of diplomats in roughly the same fashion.
  • 75
    • 85039375260 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Changing the payoffs in the chicken game alters play only if changes are ordinal. The effect is stronger in a bargaining game, where competitors set payoffs endogenously through their offers.
  • 76
    • 36148999472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Peace-Making and Conflict Resolution"
    • A review of the traditional literature on the effects of third-party mediation can be found in Walter Carlesnaes Thomas Risse, and Beth Simmons, eds., (London: Sage)
    • "A review of the traditional literature on the effects of third-party mediation can be found in Lilach Gilady and Bruce Russett, "Peace-Making and Conflict Resolution," in Walter Carlesnaes, Thomas Risse, and Beth Simmons, eds., Handbook of International Relations (London: Sage, 2002).
    • (2002) Handbook of International Relations
    • Gilady, L.1    Russett, B.2
  • 77
    • 18744401879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Might of the Pen: A Reputational Theory of Communication in International Disputes"
    • For a discussion of credible diplomacy, see
    • For a discussion of credible diplomacy, see Anne Sartori, "The Might of the Pen: A Reputational Theory of Communication in International Disputes," International Organization 55, no. 3 (2002).
    • (2002) International Organization , vol.55 , Issue.3
    • Sartori, A.1
  • 78
    • 84974269569 scopus 로고
    • "The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice"
    • IGOs must also convince states of the veracity of information. Paradoxically, a third-party intent only on averting a contest may be less effective than a biased actor with preferences over the outcome of bargaining. Randall Calvert demonstrates that information from biased political sources can be informative
    • IGOs must also convince states of the veracity of information. Paradoxically, a third-party intent only on averting a contest may be less effective than a biased actor with preferences over the outcome of bargaining. Randall Calvert demonstrates that information from biased political sources can be informative; Calvert, "The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice," Journal of Politics 47, no. 2 (1985).
    • (1985) Journal of Politics , vol.47 , Issue.2
    • Calvert, R.1
  • 79
    • 0142230571 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation"
    • Andrew Kydd extends this logic to the context of third-party mediation of interstate conflicts; In a subsequent paper, Kydd points out that reputation can be used to make unbiased mediators more credible, though the balance between costs and credibility is critical
    • Andrew Kydd extends this logic to the context of third-party mediation of interstate conflicts; Kydd, "Which Side Are You On? Bias, Credibility, and Mediation," American Journal of Political Science 47, no. 4 (2003). In a subsequent paper, Kydd points out that reputation can be used to make unbiased mediators more credible, though the balance between costs and credibility is critical.
    • (2003) American Journal of Political Science , vol.47 , Issue.4
    • Kydd, A.1
  • 80
    • 33645586447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Honest Broker: Mediation and Mistrust"
    • See (Manuscript, Harvard University, Cambridge, July)
    • See Andrew Kydd, "The Honest Broker: Mediation and Mistrust" (Manuscript, Harvard University, Cambridge, July 2004).
    • (2004)
    • Kydd, A.1
  • 81
    • 8744273610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Asymmetric Information, Mediation and Conflict Management"
    • Similarly, Robert W. Rauchhaus relaxes the assumption that mediators prefer peace; (Manuscript, University of California, Santa Barbara)
    • Similarly, Robert W. Rauchhaus relaxes the assumption that mediators prefer peace; Rauchhaus, "Asymmetric Information, Mediation and Conflict Management" (Manuscript, University of California, Santa Barbara, 2003).
    • (2003)
    • Rauchhaus, R.W.1
  • 82
    • 0003656791 scopus 로고
    • Secret threats lack the consequences often viewed as critical to successful deterrence. See (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Uncertainty about third-party actions could increase the onset of disputes
    • Secret threats lack the consequences often viewed as critical to successful deterrence. See Robert Powell, Nuclear Deterrence Theory: The Search for Credibility (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990). Uncertainty about third-party actions could increase the onset of disputes.
    • (1990) Nuclear Deterrence Theory: The Search for Credibility
    • Powell, R.1
  • 83
    • 85039365503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Neutral third parties, while arguably less effective at information arbitrage, are likely to be more effective at intervention and constraint. Biased IGOs may fail to constrain their favored faction, leading to more extractive demands and a higher risk of war.
  • 84
    • 0346382244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Cheap Talk and Burning Money"
    • Actors can autonomously reveal resolve through costly actions, but "burning money" also weakens bargaining power. We should see such actions only when the reduction in uncertainty leads to payoffs exceeding the cost in resources and the loss of leverage. See (Manuscript, Northwestern University, Evanston, Ill., and the California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, Calif.)
    • Actors can autonomously reveal resolve through costly actions, but "burning money" also weakens bargaining power. We should see such actions only when the reduction in uncertainty leads to payoffs exceeding the cost in resources and the loss of leverage. See David Austen-Smith and Jeffrey S. Banks, "Cheap Talk and Burning Money" (Manuscript, Northwestern University, Evanston, Ill., and the California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, Calif, 1998).
    • (1998)
    • Austen-Smith, D.1    Banks, J.S.2
  • 86
    • 85039366277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "All results mentioned but not published in the study are available from the authors.
  • 87
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October). We collected data on institutionalization for 297 IGOS, coding 198 as "minimal," 52 as "structured," and 47 as "interventionist." Details for defunct IGOs are often unavailable
    • "Oneal and Russett (fn. 2). We collected data on institutionalization for 297 IGOS, coding 198 as "minimal," 52 as "structured," and 47 as "interventionist." Details for defunct IGOs are often unavailable.
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 88
    • 0032220433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable"
    • Nathaniel Beck, Jonathan N. Katz, and Richard Tucker, "Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable," American Journal of Political Science 42, no. 4 (1998).
    • (1998) American Journal of Political Science , vol.42 , Issue.4
    • Beck, N.1    Katz, J.N.2    Tucker, R.3
  • 89
    • 0030327035 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816-1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns"
    • "Daniel Jones, Stuart Bremer, and J. David Singer, "Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816-1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns," Conflict Management and Peace Science 15, no. 2 (1996);
    • (1996) Conflict Management and Peace Science , vol.15 , Issue.2
    • Jones, D.1    Bremer, S.2    Singer, J.D.3
  • 90
    • 84965432227 scopus 로고
    • "Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816-1976: Procedure, Patterns, and Insights"
    • Charles S. Gochman and Zeev Maoz, "Militarized Interstate Disputes, 18 16-1976: Procedure, Patterns, and Insights," Journal of Conflict Resolution 28, no. 4 (1984).
    • (1984) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.28 , Issue.4
    • Gochman, C.S.1    Maoz, Z.2
  • 91
    • 0003981939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Dyadic Militarized Interstate Disputes (DYMID 1. 1) Dataset, Version 1.1"
    • (Code-book, Department of Political Science, Tel Aviv University)
    • Zeev Maoz, "Dyadic Militarized Interstate Disputes (DYMID 1. 1) Dataset, Version 1.1" (Code-book, Department of Political Science, Tel Aviv University, 1999).
    • (1999)
    • Maoz, Z.1
  • 92
    • 0038831393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Research Design and Estimator Choices in the Analysis of Interstate Dyads: When Decisions Matter"
    • For a usefill discussion of the debate over onset and ongoing MIDs, see
    • "For a usefill discussion of the debate over onset and ongoing MIDs, see D. Scott Bennett and Allan Stam, "Research Design and Estimator Choices in the Analysis of Interstate Dyads: When Decisions Matter," Journal of Conflict Resolution 44, no. 5 (2000).
    • (2000) Journal of Conflict Resolution , vol.44 , Issue.5
    • Bennett, D.S.1    Stam, A.2
  • 93
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October). Replication is approximate given idiosyncrasies in data and coding
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 2). Replication is approximate given idiosyncrasies in data and coding.
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 94
    • 84972218484 scopus 로고
    • "Intergovernmental Organization and the Preservation of Peace, 1816-1964: Some Bivariate Relationships"
    • COW data are reported in five-year intervals
    • "Wallace and Singer (fn. 8). cow data are reported in five-year intervals. We interpolate missing values, as do Oneal and Russett (fn. 2).
    • (1970) International Organization , vol.24 , Issue.3
    • Singer, J.D.1    Wallace, M.2
  • 95
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October). We interpolate missing values, as do
    • We interpolate missing values, as do Oneal and Russett (fn. 2).
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 96
    • 0042358607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Union of International Associations, (Munich: K.G. Saur, various years)
    • "Union of International Associations, Yearbook of International Organizations (Munich: K.G. Saur, various years).
    • Yearbook of International Organizations
  • 98
    • 0013264456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Kant We All Just Get Along? Motive, Opportunity, and the Origins of the Democratic Peace"
    • Affinity provides annual measures of the similarity of dyadic voting positions in the General Assembly (1946-96). Data construction is discussed elsewhere. See
    • Affinity provides annual measures of the similarity of dyadic voting positions in the General Assembly (1946-96). Data construction is discussed elsewhere. See Erik Gartzke, "Kant We All Just Get Along? Motive, Opportunity, and the Origins of the Democratic Peace," American Journal of Political Science 42, no. 1 (1998);
    • (1998) American Journal of Political Science , vol.42 , Issue.1
    • Gartzke, E.1
  • 99
  • 100
    • 0034400615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Clashes in the Assembly"
    • We use the United States as the reference country to convert dyadic values to monadic values. We also examined a variable based on nominate coding of state ideal points used in Designation of ideal points involves additional assumptions about state utilities that are not immune to controversy and that yield nonintuitive results in our analysis
    • We use the United States as the reference country to convert dyadic values to monadic values. We also examined a variable based on nominate coding of state ideal points used in Erik Vocten, "Clashes in the Assembly," International Organization 54, no. 2 (2000). Designation of ideal points involves additional assumptions about state utilities that are not immune to controversy and that yield nonintuitive results in our analysis.
    • (2000) International Organization , vol.54 , Issue.2
    • Vocten, E.1
  • 101
    • 85039383224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We also created an alternative measure of IGO member contentiousness by inverting and summing qualities. The resulting variables correlate highly with the IGO institutionalization variables.
  • 102
    • 85039371617 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In future research we plan to explore selection effects in IGOS using a different unit of analysis.
  • 103
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October)
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 2).
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 104
    • 84970399719 scopus 로고
    • "Transitions to Democracy: Tracking Democracy's 'Third Wave' with the Polity III Data"
    • Keith Jaggers and Ted R. Gurr, "Transitions to Democracy: Tracking Democracy's 'Third Wave' with the Polity III Data," Journal of Peace Research 32, no. 4 (1995).
    • (1995) Journal of Peace Research , vol.32 , Issue.4
    • Jaggers, K.1    Gurr, T.R.2
  • 108
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October). We use Oneal and Russett's data and statistical model to establish a baseline for comparison. The changes in data and variable construction mentioned previously are reported in subsequent tables. We also replicated all regressions using the ReLogit procedure, but found no substantive differences in results
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 2). We use Oneal and Russett's data and statistical model to establish a baseline for comparison. The changes in data and variable construction mentioned previously are reported in subsequent tables. We also replicated all regressions using the ReLogit procedure, but found no substantive differences in results.
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 109
    • 0035618101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Explaining Rare Events in International Relations"
    • See Gary King and Langche Zcng, "Explaining Rare Events in International Relations," International Organization 55, no. 3 (2001);
    • (2001) International Organization , vol.55 , Issue.3
    • King, G.1    Zeng, L.2
  • 110
    • 4544259831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Logistic Regression in Rare Events Data"
    • idem, "Logistic Regression in Rare Events Data," Political Analysis 98 (2001).
    • (2001) Political Analysis , vol.98
    • King, G.1    Zeng, L.2
  • 112
    • 0033383284 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Kantian Peace: The Pacific Benefits of Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations 1885-1992"
    • (October)
    • Oneal and Russett (fn. 2);
    • (1999) World Politics , vol.52
    • Oneal, J.R.1    Russett, B.2
  • 114
    • 85039382876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Aggregating memberships at the level of the dyad is far from ideal. We use the dyad as the unit of analysis to facilitate comparison of our results with other quantitative studies of IGOs.
  • 117
    • 0037309160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States"
    • Still, Fearon's characterization of war is coherent, widely addressed in the literature, and tractable
    • Slantchev (fn. 22).
    • (2003) American Political Science Review , vol.97 , Issue.1
    • Slantchev, B.1
  • 119
    • 0004218210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (New York: Random House)
    • Richard Holbrooke, To End a War (New York: Random House, 1998).
    • (1998) To End a War
    • Holbrooke, R.1
  • 120
    • 85039367198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Game-theoretic models often include the status quo as an outcome. We treat the status quo as a special case of the equilibrium in which the bargain in the game equals the bargain ex ante.
  • 121
    • 85039365425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Having A sweeten its offer by making an arbitrarily small concession ε leads B to strictly prefer d to fighting. However, this clutters the model while yielding no new substantive conclusions.
  • 122
    • 85039378718 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Actors may be limited in their ability to optimize by the bounded nature of parameter values or by constraints imposed by third parties (assuming opponents are restrained from altering demands).
  • 123
    • 85039388100 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This result depends on the inability of B to make a counteroffer. In an iterated game, B could use the vulnerability of A to extract additional concessions, much as A does to B in proposition 1.
  • 124
    • 85039387531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Using 1 as the upper bound would both allow that the third party is more eager for a contest than A (not likely) and eliminate the possibility that I values the stakes more than A.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.