메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 99, Issue 2, 2011, Pages 435-514

In defense of bailouts

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79956127904     PISSN: 00168092     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (87)

References (467)
  • 1
    • 79956112911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., CIT Group, and the holding companies for IndyMac andWashington Mutual.
    • E.g., Lehman Brothers, New Century Financial, CIT Group, and the holding companies for IndyMac andWashington Mutual.
    • New Century Financial
    • Brothers, L.1
  • 2
    • 79956080194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., General Motors and Chrysler
    • E.g., General Motors and Chrysler.
  • 3
    • 0042706751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The law and finance of bank and insurance insolvency regulation
    • E.g., IndyMac Federal Savings Bank and Washington Mutual Federal Savings Bank. The FDIC utilizes three separate methods to resolve failed depositary institutions. See, e.g., (discussing liquidations, third-party sales, and reorganizations).discussing liquidations, third-party sales, and reorganizations
    • E.g., IndyMac Federal Savings Bank and Washington Mutual Federal Savings Bank. The FDIC utilizes three separate methods to resolve failed depositary institutions. See, e.g., David A. Skeel, Jr., The Law and Finance of Bank and Insurance Insolvency Regulation, 76 TEX. L. REV. 723, 767-68 (1998) (discussing liquidations, third-party sales, and reorganizations).
    • (1998) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.76 , Issue.723 , pp. 767-768
    • Skeel Jr., D.A.1
  • 4
    • 79956086414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Countrywide Financial,Wachovia, and Morgan Stanley
    • E.g., Countrywide Financial,Wachovia, and Morgan Stanley.
  • 5
    • 79956067790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Bear Stearns
    • E.g., Bear Stearns.
  • 6
    • 79956155961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., American Insurance Group (AIG)
    • E.g., American Insurance Group (AIG).
  • 7
    • 79956087438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-289, § 1117, 122 Stat. 2654 (codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1719(g)); Press Release, U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, Treasury Issues Update on Status of Support for Housing Programs (Dec. 24, 2009) (updated Jan. 5 available at
    • Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-289, § 1117, 122 Stat. 2654 (codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1719(g)); Press Release, U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, Treasury Issues Update on Status of Support for Housing Programs (Dec. 24, 2009) (updated Jan. 5, 2010), available at http://www.financialstability.gov/latest/pr-1052010b.html.
    • (2010)
  • 8
    • 77950489429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The TARP was created under the emergency economic stabilization act of 2008
    • Bailout Recipients, PROPUBLICA, (last visited Aug. 21, , §§ 101-102, 122 Stat. 3765 (2008)
    • Bailout Recipients, PROPUBLICA, http://bailout.propublica.org/main/list/ index (last visited Aug. 21, 2010). The TARP was created under the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343, §§ 101-102, 122 Stat. 3765 (2008).
    • (2010) Pub. L. No. , pp. 110-343
  • 10
    • 79956153758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. N.Y. TIMES, Mar. , at A1 (discussing Obama administration concern about a bailout backlash)
    • See, e.g., Adam Nagourney, Bracing for a Bailout Backlash, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 16, 2009, at A1 (discussing Obama administration concern about a bailout backlash);
    • (2009) Bracing for a Bailout Backlash , vol.16
    • Nagourney, A.1
  • 11
    • 79956103564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 28 at A3 (detailing congressional flaying of Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner for his role in the AIG bailout)
    • Mary Williams Walsh, Drawing Fire, Geithner Backs Rescue of A.I.G., N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 28, 2010, at A3 (detailing congressional flaying of Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner for his role in the AIG bailout).
    • (2010) Drawing Fire, Geithner Backs Rescue of A.I.G.
    • Walsh, M.W.1
  • 12
    • 79956085071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How far will greek contagion spread?
    • Feb. 25 See (noting potential for Greece's economic distress to spread throughout Europe);
    • See Emre Deliveli, How Far Will Greek Contagion Spread?, FORBES.COM (Feb. 25, 2010), http://www.forbes.com/2010/02/25/balkans-greece-turkey-opinion- contributors-emre-deliveli-print. html (noting potential for Greece's economic distress to spread throughout Europe);
    • (2010) Forbes.Com
    • Deliveli, E.1
  • 13
    • 79956156942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Op-Ed., N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 19
    • Paul Krugman, Op-Ed., The Big Squander, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 19, 2009, at A35.
    • (2009) The Big Squander
    • Krugman, P.1
  • 14
    • 79956153064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. TREASURY DEP'T, FINANCIAL REGULATORY REFORM: A NEW FOUNDATION 21-27 hereinafter TREASURY WHITE PAPER];
    • U.S. TREASURY DEP'T, FINANCIAL REGULATORY REFORM: A NEW FOUNDATION 21-27 (2009) [hereinafter TREASURY WHITE PAPER];
    • (2009)
  • 16
    • 79956141874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Witness the European Union effectively flouting its anti-bailout law, Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union art. 125, Mar. 30, , 2010 O.J. (C 83) 99, by structuring the bailout of Greece through bilateral loans coordinated by the EU, rather than made by the EU
    • Witness the European Union effectively flouting its anti-bailout law, Consolidated Version of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union art. 125, Mar. 30, 2010, 2010 O.J. (C 83) 99, by structuring the bailout of Greece through bilateral loans coordinated by the EU, rather than made by the EU.
    • (2010)
  • 19
    • 79951931375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bankruptcy or bailouts?
    • See, e.g. considering bankruptcy versus bailouts solely for companies that are currently eligible to file for bankruptcy
    • See, e.g., Kenneth Ayotte & David A. Skeel, Jr., Bankruptcy or Bailouts?, 35 J. CORP. L. 469 (2010) (considering bankruptcy versus bailouts solely for companies that are currently eligible to file for bankruptcy);
    • (2010) J. Corp. L. , vol.35 , pp. 469
    • Ayotte, K.1    Skeel Jr., D.A.2
  • 20
    • 26444550912 scopus 로고
    • Overt and covert bailouts: Developing a public bailout policy
    • 968-72 distinguishing between overt bailouts that take the form of direct assistance via loans and guarantees and covert bailouts via tax breaks, trade restrictions, tariffs, and quotas, and distinguishing between bailouts and general government subsidies on the basis of bailouts focusing on saving particular firms from collapse, rather than support of industries or economic sectors
    • Cheryl D. Block, Overt and Covert Bailouts: Developing a Public Bailout Policy, 67 IND. L.J. 951, 968-72 (1992) (distinguishing between overt bailouts that take the form of direct assistance via loans and guarantees and covert bailouts via tax breaks, trade restrictions, tariffs, and quotas, and distinguishing between bailouts and general government subsidies on the basis of bailouts focusing on saving particular firms from collapse, rather than support of industries or economic sectors);
    • (1992) Ind. L.J. , vol.67 , pp. 951
    • Block, C.D.1
  • 21
    • 77950467763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulation by deal: The government's response to the financial crisis
    • discussing the government's response to several pending bankruptcies during the most recent financial crisis
    • Steven M. Davidoff & David T. Zaring, Regulation by Deal: The Government's Response to the Financial Crisis, 61 ADMIN. L. REV. 463 (2009) (discussing the government's response to several pending bankruptcies during the most recent financial crisis);
    • (2009) Admin. L. Rev. , vol.61 , pp. 463
    • Davidoff, S.M.1    Zaring, D.T.2
  • 22
    • 79956068315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial crisis containment
    • arguing that financial crisis containment is distinct from regulation, crisis prevention, and resolution and that it involves a standard set of choices
    • Anna Gelpern, Financial Crisis Containment, 41 CONN. L. REV. 1051 (2009) (arguing that financial crisis containment is distinct from regulation, crisis prevention, and resolution and that it involves a standard set of choices);
    • (2009) Conn. L. Rev. , vol.41 , pp. 1051
    • Gelpern, A.1
  • 23
    • 84908946115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The subprime crisis and the link between consumer financial protection and systemic risk
    • arguing that consumer protection has a systemic risk prevention role);
    • Erik F. Gerding, The Subprime Crisis and the Link Between Consumer Financial Protection and Systemic Risk, 4 FIU L. REV. 435 (2009) (arguing that consumer protection has a systemic risk prevention role);
    • (2009) Fiu L. Rev. , vol.4 , pp. 435
    • Gerding, E.F.1
  • 24
    • 79956087950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A requiem for sam's bank
    • discussing systemic risk posed by payment systems
    • Ronald J. Mann, A Requiem for Sam's Bank, 83 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 953 (2008) (discussing systemic risk posed by payment systems);
    • (2008) Chi.-Kent L. Rev. , vol.83 , pp. 953
    • Mann, R.J.1
  • 25
    • 79251577377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the bankruptcy code an adequate mechanism for resolving the distress of systemically important institutions?
    • 450 arguing that bankruptcy provides inadequate tools for dealing with the resolution of systemically significant financial institutions
    • Edward R. Morrison, Is the Bankruptcy Code an Adequate Mechanism for Resolving the Distress of Systemically Important Institutions?, 82 TEMP. L. REV. 449, 450 (2009) (arguing that bankruptcy provides inadequate tools for dealing with the resolution of systemically significant financial institutions);
    • (2009) Temp. L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 449
    • Morrison, E.R.1
  • 26
    • 72649094842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • After the bailout: Regulating systemic moral hazard
    • Karl S. Okamoto, After the Bailout: Regulating Systemic Moral Hazard, 57 UCLA L. REV. 183 (2009);
    • (2009) Ucla L. Rev. , vol.57 , pp. 183
    • Okamoto, K.S.1
  • 27
    • 57149086909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systemic risk
    • attempting to define systemic risk and potential regulatory responses). Professor Block's work is notable as the only theoretical work on bailouts that I have been able to identify that predates the current crisis. Unfortunately, it appears to have gone nearly unnoticed despite being an extremely perceptive taxonomic article noting that bailouts are part of the same genus as subsidies and cataloging varieties of bailouts
    • Steven L. Schwarcz, Systemic Risk, 97 GEO. L.J. 193 (2009) (attempting to define systemic risk and potential regulatory responses). Professor Block's work is notable as the only theoretical work on bailouts that I have been able to identify that predates the current crisis. Unfortunately, it appears to have gone nearly unnoticed despite being an extremely perceptive taxonomic article noting that bailouts are part of the same genus as subsidies and cataloging varieties of bailouts.
    • (2009) Geo. L.J. , vol.97 , pp. 193
    • Schwarcz, S.L.1
  • 30
    • 67349271076 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A theory of systemic risk and design of prudential bank regulation
    • Viral V. Acharya, A Theory of Systemic Risk and Design of Prudential Bank Regulation, 5 J. FIN. STABILITY 224 (2009);
    • (2009) J. Fin. Stability , vol.5 , pp. 224
    • Acharya, V.V.1
  • 31
    • 0002615169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the need for an international lender of last resort
    • Stanley Fischer, On the Need for an International Lender of Last Resort, 13 J. ECON. PERSP. 85 (1999);
    • (1999) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.13 , pp. 85
    • Fischer, S.1
  • 32
    • 40549141676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The lender of last resort: A twenty-first century approach
    • Xavier Freixas et al., The Lender of Last Resort: A Twenty-first Century Approach, 2 J. EUR. ECON. ASS'N 1085 (2004);
    • (2004) J. Eur. Econ. Ass'N , vol.2 , pp. 1085
    • Freixas, X.1
  • 33
    • 0041029533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systemic risk, interbank relations, and liquidity provision by the central bank
    • Xavier Freixas et al., Systemic Risk, Interbank Relations, and Liquidity Provision by the Central Bank, 32 J. MONEY, CREDIT & BANKING 611 (2000);
    • (2000) J. Money, Credit & Banking , vol.32 , pp. 611
    • Freixas, X.1
  • 34
    • 33644973585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bagehot or bailout? an analysis of government responses to banking crises
    • Guillermo Rosas, Bagehot or Bailout? An Analysis of Government Responses to Banking Crises, 50 AM. J. POL. SCI. 175 (2006);
    • (2006) Am. J. Pol. Sci. , vol.50 , pp. 175
    • Rosas, G.1
  • 35
    • 0041727848 scopus 로고
    • The lender of last resort and the federal safety net
    • Anna J. Schwartz, The Lender of Last Resort and the Federal Safety Net, 1 J. FIN. SERVS. RES. 77 (1987);
    • (1987) J. Fin. Servs. Res. , vol.1 , pp. 77
    • Schwartz, A.J.1
  • 36
    • 0009977199 scopus 로고
    • On the lender of last resort
    • Charles P. Kindleberger & Jean-Pierre Laffargue eds
    • Robert M. Solow, On the Lender of Last Resort, in FINANCIAL CRISES: THEORY, HISTORY, AND POLICY (Charles P. Kindleberger & Jean-Pierre Laffargue eds., 1982);
    • (1982) Financial Crises: Theory, History, and Policy
    • Solow, R.M.1
  • 37
    • 21144447349 scopus 로고
    • Planning for the next financial crisis
    • Martin Feldstein ed
    • Lawrence H. Summers, Planning for the Next Financial Crisis, in THE RISK OF ECONOMIC CRISIS 135 (Martin Feldstein ed., 1991);
    • (1991) The Risk of Economic Crisis , vol.135
    • Summers, L.H.1
  • 39
    • 27144543182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allocating bank regulatory powers: Lenders of last resort, deposit insurance, and supervision
    • See, e.g. modeling whether a single regulator will handle bank financial distress better than multiple regulators)
    • See, e.g., Charles M. Kahn & João A.C. Santos, Allocating Bank Regulatory Powers: Lenders of Last Resort, Deposit Insurance, and Supervision, 49 EUR. ECON. REV. 2107 (2005) (modeling whether a single regulator will handle bank financial distress better than multiple regulators);
    • (2005) Eur. Econ. Rev. , vol.49 , pp. 2107
    • Kahn, C.M.1    Santos, J.A.C.2
  • 40
    • 79956086413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • European Banking Center Discussion Paper No. 2010-02), at 20 (modeling whether a central bank or a fiscal authority is the better entity to handle financial crises
    • Rob Nijskens & Sylvester C. W. Eijffinger, The Lender of Last Resort: Liquidity Provision Versus the Possibility of Bail-Out (European Banking Center Discussion Paper No. 2010-02), at 20 (modeling whether a central bank or a fiscal authority is the better entity to handle financial crises);
    • The Lender of Last Resort: Liquidity Provision Versus the Possibility of Bail-Out
    • Nijskens, R.1    Eijffinger, S.C.W.2
  • 41
    • 79956134850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who should decide on emergency liquidity assistance
    • Jan. 16 (considering the trade-off between central banks and deposit insurers as emergency liquidity providers).
    • Jorge Ponce, Who Should Decide on Emergency Liquidity Assistance, VOX (Jan. 16, 2010), http://www.voxeu.com/index. php?q=node/4494 (considering the trade-off between central banks and deposit insurers as emergency liquidity providers).
    • (2010) Vox
    • Ponce, J.1
  • 42
    • 79956076607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Summers, supra note 16, at 136 (summarizing approaches to defining the lender of last resort)
    • See Summers, supra note 16, at 136 (summarizing approaches to defining the lender of last resort).
  • 43
    • 79956098836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Finance theory sometimes employs the term "systematic risk" to refer to market risk that is not specific to an individual firm and for which an investor will not price a firm-specific risk premium
    • Finance theory sometimes employs the term "systematic risk" to refer to market risk that is not specific to an individual firm and for which an investor will not price a firm-specific risk premium.
  • 44
    • 0003470979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. hereinafter G-10 REPORT ON FINANCIAL SECTOR CONSOLIDATION] ("Systemic financial risk is the risk that an event will trigger a loss of economic value or confidence in, and attendant increases in uncertainty about, a substantial portion of the financial system that is serious enough to quite probably have significant adverse effects on the real economy
    • See, e.g., GROUP OF TEN, REPORT ON CONSOLIDATION IN THE FINANCIAL SECTOR 126 (2001) [hereinafter G-10 REPORT ON FINANCIAL SECTOR CONSOLIDATION] ("Systemic financial risk is the risk that an event will trigger a loss of economic value or confidence in, and attendant increases in uncertainty about, a substantial portion of the financial system that is serious enough to quite probably have significant adverse effects on the real economy.");
    • (2001) Group of Ten, Report on Consolidation in the Financial Sector , pp. 126
  • 45
    • 79956111331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulating systemic risk
    • Viral V. Acharya & Matthew Richardson eds. defining systemic risk as the risk that the failure and distress of a significant part of the financial sector reduces the availability of credit, which in turn may adversely affect the real economy
    • Viral V. Acharya et al., Regulating Systemic Risk, in RESTORING FINANCIAL STABILITY: HOW TO REPAIR A FAILED SYSTEM 174, 174 (Viral V. Acharya & Matthew Richardson eds., 2009) (defining systemic risk as the risk that the failure and distress of a significant part of the financial sector reduces the availability of credit, which in turn may adversely affect the real economy);
    • (2009) Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair A Failed System , vol.174 , pp. 174
    • Acharya, V.V.1
  • 46
    • 79956152581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An information market proposal for regulating systemic risk
    • forthcoming (systemic risk is the financial risk imposed on firms without the ability to contract away their exposure
    • Matthew L. Beville et al., An Information Market Proposal for Regulating Systemic Risk, 12 U. PA. J. BUS. L. (forthcoming 2010) (systemic risk is the financial risk imposed on firms without the ability to contract away their exposure);
    • (2010) U. Pa. J. Bus. L. , vol.12
    • Beville, M.L.1
  • 47
    • 70349670890 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systemic risk and the financial crisis: A primer
    • 403 systemic risk is the possibility that an event, such as the failure of an individual firm, will seriously impair other firms or markets and harm the broader economy
    • James Bullard et al., Systemic Risk and the Financial Crisis: A Primer, 91 FED. RES. BANK ST. LOUIS REV. 403, 403 (2009) (systemic risk is the possibility that an event, such as the failure of an individual firm, will seriously impair other firms or markets and harm the broader economy);
    • (2009) Fed. Res. Bank St. Louis Rev. , vol.91 , pp. 403
    • Bullard, J.1
  • 48
    • 85015680735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systemic risk in modern financial systems: Analytics and policy design
    • 156 defining systemic risk as the risk over and above those naturally priced and managed by financial intermediaries themselves, threatening the effective functioning of the financial system as a whole and the economy more broadly
    • Prasanna Gai et al., Systemic Risk in Modern Financial Systems: Analytics and Policy Design, 8 J. RISK FIN. 156, 156 (2007) (defining systemic risk as the risk over and above those naturally priced and managed by financial intermediaries themselves, threatening the effective functioning of the financial system as a whole and the economy more broadly);
    • (2007) J. Risk Fin. , vol.8 , pp. 156
    • Gai, P.1
  • 49
    • 70449609892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial firm bankruptcy and systemic risk
    • 24, 24 ("Systemic risk is the risk that the financial system will fail to function properly because of widespread distress
    • Jean Helwege, Financial Firm Bankruptcy and Systemic Risk, REGULATION, Summer 2009, 24, 24 ("Systemic risk is the risk that the financial system will fail to function properly because of widespread distress.");
    • (2009) Regulation, Summer
    • Helwege, J.1
  • 50
    • 0002518681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bank failures, systemic risk, and bank regulation
    • 20 quoting Alan Greenspan, Remarks at a Conference on Risk Measurement and Systemic Risk, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Nov. 16, 1995)), available at
    • George G. Kaufman, Bank Failures, Systemic Risk, and Bank Regulation, 16 CATO J. 17, 20 n.5 (1996) (quoting Alan Greenspan, Remarks at a Conference on Risk Measurement and Systemic Risk, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Nov. 16, 1995)), available at http://www.cato.org/pubs/journal/ cj16n1/cj16n1-2.pdf;
    • (1996) Cato J. , vol.16 , Issue.5 , pp. 17
    • Kaufman, G.G.1
  • 51
    • 0038333531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What is systemic risk, and do bank regulators retard or contribute to it
    • 371 defining systemic risk as "the risk or probability of breakdowns in an entire system, as opposed to breakdowns in individual parts or components
    • George G. Kaufman & Kenneth E. Scott, What is Systemic Risk, and Do Bank Regulators Retard or Contribute to It, 7 INDEP. REV. 371, 371 (2003) (defining systemic risk as "the risk or probability of breakdowns in an entire system, as opposed to breakdowns in individual parts or components");
    • (2003) Indep. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 371
    • Kaufman, G.G.1    Scott, K.E.2
  • 52
    • 3943108847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assessing systemic risk exposure from banks and GSEs under alternative approaches to capital regulation
    • 123 defining systemic risk as "the potential for a modest economic shock to induce substantial volatility in asset prices, significant reductions in corporate liquidity, potential bankruptcies and efficiency losses
    • Paul Kupiec & David Nickerson, Assessing Systemic Risk Exposure from Banks and GSEs Under Alternative Approaches to Capital Regulation, 28 J. REAL EST. FIN. & ECON. 123, 123 (2004) (defining systemic risk as "the potential for a modest economic shock to induce substantial volatility in asset prices, significant reductions in corporate liquidity, potential bankruptcies and efficiency losses");
    • (2004) J. Real Est. Fin. & Econ. , vol.28 , pp. 123
    • Kupiec, P.1    Nickerson, D.2
  • 53
    • 0013083087 scopus 로고
    • Comment on systemic risk
    • 32 systemic risk is "the likelihood of a sudden, usually unexpected, event that disrupts information in financial markets, making them unable to effectively channel funds to those parties with the most productive investment opportunities
    • Frederic S. Mishkin, Comment on Systemic Risk, 7 RES. FIN. SERVS. PRIV. & PUB. POL'Y 31, 32 (1995) (systemic risk is "the likelihood of a sudden, usually unexpected, event that disrupts information in financial markets, making them unable to effectively channel funds to those parties with the most productive investment opportunities");
    • (1995) Res. Fin. Servs. Priv. & Pub. Pol'Y , vol.7 , pp. 31
    • Mishkin, F.S.1
  • 54
    • 79956150197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at (defining systemic risk as "the risk that (i) an economic shock such as market or institutional failure triggers (through a panic or otherwise) either (X) the failure of a chain of markets or institutions or (Y) a chain of significant losses to financial institutions, (ii) resulting in increases in the cost of capital or decreases in its availability, often evidenced by substantial financial-market price volatility
    • Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 204 (defining systemic risk as "the risk that (i) an economic shock such as market or institutional failure triggers (through a panic or otherwise) either (X) the failure of a chain of markets or institutions or (Y) a chain of significant losses to financial institutions, (ii) resulting in increases in the cost of capital or decreases in its availability, often evidenced by substantial financial-market price volatility.");
    • Schwarcz1
  • 55
    • 79956077139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IMF, Working Paper No. WP/02/55,) (systemic risk is "the risk that an event (shock) will trigger a loss of economic value or confidence in, and attendant increases in uncertainty about, a substantial portion of the financial system that is large enough to, in all probability, have significant adverse effects on the real economy
    • Gianni De Nicoló & Myron L. Kwast, Systemic Risk and Financial Consolidation: Are They Related? 4 (IMF, Working Paper No. WP/02/55, 2002) (systemic risk is "the risk that an event (shock) will trigger a loss of economic value or confidence in, and attendant increases in uncertainty about, a substantial portion of the financial system that is large enough to, in all probability, have significant adverse effects on the real economy");
    • (2002) Systemic Risk and Financial Consolidation: Are They Related? , vol.4
    • Nicoló, G.D.1    Kwast, M.L.2
  • 56
    • 79956103059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 1,), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project-reports/files/PTF-Note-1-Defining-Systemic- Risk-TFCorrection. pdf ("The essence of a systemic risk is a risk that something bad happens in the financial system that is a good deal bigger and worse than the failure of any single institution.")
    • Darryll Hendricks, Defining Systemic Risk 1-2 (Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 1, 2009), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project- reports/files/PTF-Note-1-Defining-Systemic-Risk-TFCorrection. pdf ("The essence of a systemic risk is a risk that something bad happens in the financial system that is a good deal bigger and worse than the failure of any single institution.");
    • (2009) Defining Systemic Risk 1-2
    • Hendricks, D.1
  • 57
    • 79956108375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 11,), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project-reports/files/Managing-Systemic-Risks-Final. pdf ("'[A] systemic risk is a risk that an event will trigger a loss of confidence in a substantial portion of the financial system that is serious enough to have adverse consequences for the real economy.'" (quoting Hendricks, supra)
    • Charles Taylor, Managing Systemic Risks 2-3 (Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 11, 2009), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project- reports/files/Managing-Systemic-Risks-Final.pdf ("'[A] systemic risk is a risk that an event will trigger a loss of confidence in a substantial portion of the financial system that is serious enough to have adverse consequences for the real economy.'" (quoting Hendricks, supra));
    • (2009) Managing Systemic Risks 2-3
    • Taylor, C.1
  • 58
    • 79956109952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 4,), available at ("[T]he term 'systemic risk' (what precedes a systemic breakdown) usually refers to the possibility that the failure of a single large firm will cause the failure of others through a contagion-like process in which a cascade of losses flows through an economy.");
    • Peter J. Wallison, The Argument Against a Government Resolution Authority 6 (Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 4, 2009), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/task-force-reports/files/Wallison-resolution-final- TF-Correction.pdf ("[T]he term 'systemic risk' (what precedes a systemic breakdown) usually refers to the possibility that the failure of a single large firm will cause the failure of others through a contagion-like process in which a cascade of losses flows through an economy.");
    • (2009) The Argument Against a Government Resolution Authority , vol.6
    • Wallison, P.J.1
  • 59
    • 78049266911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The reduction of risk in the united states financial system
    • 673 systemic risk is "the risk that the failure of one significant financial institution can cause or significantly contribute to the failure of other significant financial institutions, through the linkages of financial institutions to each other. Systemic risk can also be defined to include the possibility that one exogenous shock may simultaneously cause or contribute to the failure of multiple significant financial institutions.")
    • Hal S. Scott, The Reduction of Risk in the United States Financial System, 33 HARV. J. L. & PUB. POL'Y 671, 673 (2010) (systemic risk is "the risk that the failure of one significant financial institution can cause or significantly contribute to the failure of other significant financial institutions, through the linkages of financial institutions to each other. Systemic risk can also be defined to include the possibility that one exogenous shock may simultaneously cause or contribute to the failure of multiple significant financial institutions.").
    • (2010) Harv. J. L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.33 , pp. 671
    • Scott, H.S.1
  • 60
    • 79956099909 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 204.
    • Schwarcz1
  • 61
    • 79956097511 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note
    • Hendricks, supra note 20.
    • Hendricks1
  • 62
    • 79956110817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • G-10 REPORT ON FINANCIAL SECTOR CONSOLIDATION, supra note 20, at
    • G-10 REPORT ON FINANCIAL SECTOR CONSOLIDATION, supra note 20, at 125;
  • 63
    • 79956082379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also, supra note
    • see also Taylor, supra note 20.
    • Taylor1
  • 64
    • 84928858220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The risk of a financial crisis
    • supra note 16, at
    • E. Gerald Corrigan, The Risk of a Financial Crisis, in THE RISK OF ECONOMIC CRISIS, supra note 16, at 44-45.
    • The Risk of Economic Crisis , pp. 44-45
    • Corrigan, E.G.1
  • 65
    • 79956160600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 20, at
    • Kupiec & Nickerson, supra note 20, at 123.
    • Kupiec1    Nickerson2
  • 66
    • 79956067789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 204.
    • Schwarcz1
  • 67
    • 79956094901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There have been a number of attempts by economists to devise measures and models for systemic risk. These attempts include, by necessity, a definition or conception of systemic risk, often restricted to financial institutions. Whatever the relative merits of these attempts, they can only succeed to the extent of their definition of systemic risk, and their predictive value is unknown. Indeed, if the financial crisis of 2007-2009 has any lessons, it is that financial modeling is very much an art, rather than a science, and a developing one at that. See, e.g., IMF, GLOBAL FINANCIAL STABILITY REPORT: RESPONDING TO THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND MEASURING SYSTEMIC RISKS 111-43 available at
    • There have been a number of attempts by economists to devise measures and models for systemic risk. These attempts include, by necessity, a definition or conception of systemic risk, often restricted to financial institutions. Whatever the relative merits of these attempts, they can only succeed to the extent of their definition of systemic risk, and their predictive value is unknown. Indeed, if the financial crisis of 2007-2009 has any lessons, it is that financial modeling is very much an art, rather than a science, and a developing one at that. See, e.g., IMF, GLOBAL FINANCIAL STABILITY REPORT: RESPONDING TO THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND MEASURING SYSTEMIC RISKS 111-43 (2009), available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2009/01/index.htm;
    • (2009)
  • 68
    • 0034079058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial contagion
    • Franklin Allen & Douglas Gale, Financial Contagion, 108 J. POL. ECON. 1 (2000);
    • (2000) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.108 , pp. 1
    • Allen, F.1    Gale, D.2
  • 70
    • 23844472283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Measuring systemic risk: A risk management approach
    • 2588-98
    • Alfred Lehar, Measuring Systemic Risk: A Risk Management Approach, 29 J. BANKING & FIN. 2577, 2588-98 (2005);
    • (2005) J. Banking & Fin. , vol.29 , pp. 2577
    • Lehar, A.1
  • 71
    • 84871565667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defining systemic risk operationally
    • Kenneth E. Scott et al. eds.
    • John B. Taylor, Defining Systemic Risk Operationally, in ENDING GOVERNMENT BAILOUTS AS WE KNOW THEM (Kenneth E. Scott et al. eds., 2010);
    • (2010) Ending Government Bailouts as we Know Them
    • Taylor, J.B.1
  • 75
    • 77953670551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BIS Working Paper, No. 281, References and further reading may be available for this article. To view references and further reading you must purchase this article. Tobias Adrian & Markus Brunnermeier, Fed. Reserve Bank of N.Y. & Princeton University, CoVaR: Measuring Systemic Risk Contribution, Presentation at 3rd Unicredit Conference on Banking and Finance (Dec. 17-18, 2009) (proposing using the change in value at risk in a system conditional on a bank default to measure systemic risk
    • Xin Huang et al., A Framework for Assessing the Systemic Risk of Major Financial Institutions (BIS Working Paper, No. 281, 2008). References and further reading may be available for this article. To view references and further reading you must purchase this article. Tobias Adrian & Markus Brunnermeier, Fed. Reserve Bank of N.Y. & Princeton University, CoVaR: Measuring Systemic Risk Contribution, Presentation at 3rd Unicredit Conference on Banking and Finance (Dec. 17-18, 2009) (proposing using the change in value at risk in a system conditional on a bank default to measure systemic risk);
    • (2008) A Framework for Assessing the Systemic Risk of Major Financial Institutions
    • Huang, X.1
  • 76
    • 78649853382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Mar. 16, ) (unpublished manuscript), available at (proposing using equity prices to measure joint probability of default)
    • Viral V. Acharya et al., Measuring Systemic Risk (Mar. 16, 2010) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1573171 (proposing using equity prices to measure joint probability of default).
    • (2010) Measuring Systemic Risk
    • Acharya, V.V.1
  • 77
    • 79956085873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 24, at
    • Corrigan, supra note 24, at 44-45.
    • Corrigan1
  • 78
    • 79956066291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at
    • Summers, supra note 16, at 137.
    • Summers1
  • 79
    • 79956109951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. discussing "system-failure" risk for CHIPS, the Clearing House Interbank Payment System used for dollar-denominated international wire-transfers
    • See, e.g., RONALD J. MANN, PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND OTHER FINANCIAL TRANSACTIONS 271-72 (2008) (discussing "system-failure" risk for CHIPS, the Clearing House Interbank Payment System used for dollar-denominated international wire-transfers);
    • (2008) Payment Systems and Other Financial Transactions 271-72
    • Mann, R.J.1
  • 80
    • 21844511554 scopus 로고
    • Regulatory solutions to payment system risks: Lessons from privately negotiated derivatives
    • see also 187 ("Payment system risks were the 'major minor' banking policy issue of the 1980s.")
    • see also David L. Mengle, Regulatory Solutions to Payment System Risks: Lessons from Privately Negotiated Derivatives, 9 J. FIN. SERVS. RESEARCH 187, 187 (1995) ("Payment system risks were the 'major minor' banking policy issue of the 1980s.").
    • (1995) J. Fin. Servs. Research , vol.9 , pp. 187
    • Mengle, D.L.1
  • 81
    • 79956154309 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial crises and the macroeconomy
    • See supra note 16, at, 177-78
    • See Paul A. Volcker, Financial Crises and the Macroeconomy, in THE RISK OF ECONOMIC CRISIS, supra note 16, at 174, 177-78.
    • The Risk of Economic Crisis , pp. 174
    • Volcker, P.A.1
  • 82
    • 79956140227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Professors Argue that bankruptcy is the best method for dealing with a broader range of financial and nonfinancial institutions
    • Professors Kenneth Ayotte and David A. Skeel, Jr. argue that bankruptcy is the best method for dealing with a broader range of financial and nonfinancial institutions.
    • Ayotte, K.1    Skeel Jr., D.A.2
  • 83
    • 79956156941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 15, at 471
    • See Ayotte & Skeel, supra note 15, at 471, 498.
    • Ayotte1    Skeel2
  • 84
    • 79956120803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • approach is based on the "theoretical tools from the corporate finance literature," which leads them to concentrate on aspects of the bankruptcy/bailout trade-off other than the political economy
    • Ayotte and Skeel's approach is based on the "theoretical tools from the corporate finance literature," which leads them to concentrate on aspects of the bankruptcy/bailout trade-off other than the political economy.
    • Ayotte1    Skeel's2
  • 86
    • 79956157478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although the efficiency issues highlighted by corporate finance theory are important, this Article argues that the choice between bankruptcy or bailout is not made on efficiency grounds, but is driven by political economy concerns that reflect social valuations of factors like economic stability and employment that are not typically accounted for in corporate finance theory's efficiency calculus
    • Although the efficiency issues highlighted by corporate finance theory are important, this Article argues that the choice between bankruptcy or bailout is not made on efficiency grounds, but is driven by political economy concerns that reflect social valuations of factors like economic stability and employment that are not typically accounted for in corporate finance theory's efficiency calculus.
  • 87
    • 0004157554 scopus 로고
    • See generally presenting expanded median voter theory
    • See generally ANTHONY DOWNS, AN ECONOMIC THEORY OF DEMOCRACY (1957) (presenting expanded median voter theory);
    • (1957) An Economic Theory of Democracy
    • Downs, A.1
  • 88
    • 0001786352 scopus 로고
    • On the rationale of group decision-making
    • originating the median voter theorem). A second justification exists for using the median voter as the metric
    • Duncan Black, On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making, 56 J. POL. ECON. 23 (1948) (originating the median voter theorem). A second justification exists for using the median voter as the metric.
    • (1948) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.56 , pp. 23
    • Black, D.1
  • 89
    • 79956159572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economist has argued that financial stability is a public good because it is non-rival and non-excludable
    • Economist Robert M. Solow has argued that financial stability is a public good because it is non-rival and non-excludable.
    • Solow, R.M.1
  • 90
    • 79956101978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at. If the median voter believes that there is systemic risk, the value of financial stability as a public good is being diminished for more people than not. While they may not value the good equivalently, it is an indication that economic harms outweigh economic benefits
    • Solow, supra note 16, at 241. If the median voter believes that there is systemic risk, the value of financial stability as a public good is being diminished for more people than not. While they may not value the good equivalently, it is an indication that economic harms outweigh economic benefits.
    • Solow1
  • 91
    • 79956129437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The median voter is likely a woman. Women constitute 51.5% of the U.S. voting age population. U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, 2008, Table 1, Population by Age and Sex: , available at ; Author's Calculations
    • The median voter is likely a woman. Women constitute 51.5% of the U.S. voting age population. U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, 2008, Table 1, Population by Age and Sex: 2008, available at http://www.census.gov/ population/socdemo/gender/2008gender-table1.xls; Author's Calculations.
    • (2008)
  • 92
    • 79956108923 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulators, in particular, often have superior information, but better information that is incomplete can result in misdiagnoses of problems and misapplication of solutions
    • Regulators, in particular, often have superior information, but better information that is incomplete can result in misdiagnoses of problems and misapplication of solutions.
  • 93
    • 77953252575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. noting that then-New York Federal Reserve President Timothy Geithner objected to FDIC Chairwoman Sheila Bair's decision to take over Washington Mutual and not guarantee its unsecured debt)
    • See, e.g., DAVID WESSEL, IN FED WE TRUST: BEN BERNANKE'S WAR ON THE GREAT PANIC 220 (2009) (noting that then-New York Federal Reserve President Timothy Geithner objected to FDIC Chairwoman Sheila Bair's decision to take over Washington Mutual and not guarantee its unsecured debt);
    • (2009) Fed we TrUst: Ben Bernanke's War on The Great Panic , pp. 220
    • Wessel, D.1
  • 94
    • 77952311911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geithner Vents as Overhaul Stumbles
    • Aug., at A1.
    • Damian Paletta & Deborah Solomon, Geithner Vents as Overhaul Stumbles, WALL ST. J., Aug. 4, 2009, at A1.
    • (2009) Wall St. J. , vol.4
    • Paletta, D.1    Solomon, D.2
  • 95
    • 79956100930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36, at
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 272.
    • Wessel1
  • 96
    • 79956066290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 273-74.
    • Wessel1
  • 97
    • 79956120291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 274.
    • Wessel1
  • 98
    • 79956123199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 188-89.
    • Wessel1
  • 99
    • 79956099380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1 FDIC, HISTORY OF THE EIGHTIES-LESSONS FOR THE FUTURE
    • See 1 FDIC, HISTORY OF THE EIGHTIES-LESSONS FOR THE FUTURE 175 n.21 (1997).
    • (1997) , vol.175 , Issue.21
  • 100
    • 79956110311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 174-75.
    • Wessel1
  • 102
    • 79956108374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The United States electoral system does not facilitate median voter responsiveness in presidential elections because of the Electoral College. Staggered Senate elections mute that body's median voter responsiveness. House elections are more median voter responsive, although gerrymandering reduces this responsiveness. This Article does not attempt to take these very real considerations into account because they are larger questions about the nature of the American political system and the key point in this Article about political responsiveness
    • The United States electoral system does not facilitate median voter responsiveness in presidential elections because of the Electoral College. Staggered Senate elections mute that body's median voter responsiveness. House elections are more median voter responsive, although gerrymandering reduces this responsiveness. This Article does not attempt to take these very real considerations into account because they are larger questions about the nature of the American political system and the key point in this Article about political responsiveness.
  • 103
    • 79956139701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See G-10 REPORT ON FINANCIAL SECTOR CONSOLIDATION, supra note 20, at
    • See G-10 REPORT ON FINANCIAL SECTOR CONSOLIDATION, supra note 20, at 126;
  • 104
    • 79956119747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 204;
    • Schwarcz1
  • 106
    • 0003143402 scopus 로고
    • Contagion and competitive intra-industry effects of bankruptcy announcements
    • 46 showing that bankruptcy filings can have both contagion and competitive effects on other firms in the same industry
    • Larry H. P. Lang & René Stulz, Contagion and Competitive Intra-industry Effects of Bankruptcy Announcements, 32 J. FIN. ECON. 45, 46 (1992) (showing that bankruptcy filings can have both contagion and competitive effects on other firms in the same industry).
    • (1992) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.32 , pp. 45
    • Lang, L.H.P.1    Stulz, R.2
  • 107
    • 79956082378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • See, e.g., Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 204.
    • Schwarcz1
  • 108
    • 79956140226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See N.Y. TIMES, July 8, , at A25 (arguing that the government's failure to treat states as macroeconomic players contributed to the slow pace of recovery).
    • See Christopher Edley, Jr., Op-Ed., Let Treasury Rescue the States, N.Y. TIMES, July 8, 2010, at A25 (arguing that the government's failure to treat states as macroeconomic players contributed to the slow pace of recovery).
    • (2010) Op-Ed., Let Treasury Rescue the States
    • Edley Jr., C.1
  • 109
    • 79956063770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oversight of the Federal Government's Intervention at American International Group: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 111th Cong. 12 (statement of Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman of the Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.) ("Conceivably, [AIG's] failure could have resulted in a 1930's-style global financial and economic meltdown, with catastrophic implications for production, income, and jobs.")
    • See Oversight of the Federal Government's Intervention at American International Group: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 111th Cong. 12 (2009) (statement of Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman of the Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.) ("Conceivably, [AIG's] failure could have resulted in a 1930's-style global financial and economic meltdown, with catastrophic implications for production, income, and jobs.").
    • (2009)
  • 110
    • 79956128927 scopus 로고
    • A test case for this is the 1975 bailout of New York City by the federal government., TIME, Dec. 8
    • A test case for this is the 1975 bailout of New York City by the federal government. See Last-Minute Bailout of a City on the Brink, TIME, Dec. 8, 1975.
    • (1975) See Last-Minute Bailout of a City on the Brink
  • 111
    • 79956106754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial risks & crises
    • supra note 16, at , 57 ("'It would be a great intellectual exercise [to let Continental Illinois National Bank collapse]. We could finally know whether or not the domino theory is true and whether the collapse of a money-center bank would destroy the economy of the nation.'")
    • Irvine H. Sprauge, Financial Risks & Crises, in THE RISK OF ECONOMIC CRISIS, supra note 16, at 53, 57 ("'It would be a great intellectual exercise [to let Continental Illinois National Bank collapse]. We could finally know whether or not the domino theory is true and whether the collapse of a money-center bank would destroy the economy of the nation.'").
    • The Risk of Economic Crisis , pp. 53
    • Sprauge, I.H.1
  • 112
    • 79956076121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To be sure, there are arguably counter-examples where there was no intervention even in situations that reasonably raised systemic risk concerns, such as Long Term Capital Management, Lehman Brothers, the Russian debt crisis, and the Argentine debt crisis. These examples show that TBTF treatment is very much a product of political climates, rather than a quantifiable measure of risk
    • To be sure, there are arguably counter-examples where there was no intervention even in situations that reasonably raised systemic risk concerns, such as Long Term Capital Management, Lehman Brothers, the Russian debt crisis, and the Argentine debt crisis. These examples show that TBTF treatment is very much a product of political climates, rather than a quantifiable measure of risk.
  • 113
    • 79956072568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is possible to expand the set of default resolution regimes to include large financial firms other than banks. But as Part III explains, doing so does not escape the reality that the applicable regime will be honored only so long as it produces acceptable distributional outcomes
    • It is possible to expand the set of default resolution regimes to include large financial firms other than banks. But as Part III explains, doing so does not escape the reality that the applicable regime will be honored only so long as it produces acceptable distributional outcomes.
  • 114
    • 79956078211 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because the priority system is preset, however, voluntary creditors have some ability to account for bankruptcy risk through their transaction terms.
    • Because the priority system is preset, however, voluntary creditors have some ability to account for bankruptcy risk through their transaction terms.
  • 115
    • 79956159738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TREASURY WHITE PAPER, supra note 12, at
    • TREASURY WHITE PAPER, supra note 12, at 3.
  • 116
    • 79956161720 scopus 로고
    • See The Lockheed Bailout Battle, TIME, Aug. 9
    • See The Lockheed Bailout Battle, TIME, Aug. 9, 1971.
    • (1971)
  • 117
    • 79956161719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See THEBIGMONEY.COM (Nov. 10, 2009, 11:24 AM
    • See James Ledbetter, Lockheed Was NOT the First Bailout, THEBIGMONEY.COM (Nov. 10, 2009, 11:24 AM), http://www.thebigmoney.com/articles/history-lesson/ 2009/11/10/lockheed-was-not-firstbailout.
    • Lockheed Was NOT the First Bailout
    • Ledbetter, J.1
  • 118
    • 0040365238 scopus 로고
    • Is the discount window necessary? A penn central perspective
    • 37-38
    • Charles W. Calomiris, Is the Discount Window Necessary? A Penn Central Perspective, 76 FED. RESERVE BANK OF ST. L. REV. 31, 37-38 (1994).
    • (1994) Fed. Reserve Bank Of St. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 31
    • Calomiris, C.W.1
  • 119
    • 79956106223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 31, at, 176
    • See Volcker, supra note 31, at 174, 176;
    • Volcker1
  • 121
    • 79956137804 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Macroeconomic effects of financial crises
    • supra note 16, at, 172-73
    • William Poole, Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Crises, in THE RISK OF ECONOMIC CRISIS, supra note 16, at 170, 172-73.
    • The Risk of Economic Crisis , pp. 170
    • Poole, W.1
  • 122
    • 77950563870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Payment wars: The merchant-bank struggle for control of payment systems
    • 453-54 See discussing the relationship between Target and Target National Bank)
    • See Adam J. Levitin, Payment Wars: The Merchant-Bank Struggle for Control of Payment Systems, 12 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 425, 453-54 (2007) (discussing the relationship between Target and Target National Bank).
    • (2007) Stan. J.L. Bus. & Fin. , vol.12 , pp. 425
    • Levitin, A.J.1
  • 123
    • 0002474905 scopus 로고
    • Payments finality and risk of settlement failure
    • See (Anthony Saunders & Lawrence J. White eds., the failure of the banks with the largest settlement obligations would produce a disruptive system-wide effect in the United States). A clearinghouse serves as an exchange for banks submitting payment, securities or options trade claims to each other. The banks maintain accounts at the clearinghouse, which are credited and debited depending on whether they are paying or receiving payment.
    • See D. B. Humphrey, Payments Finality and Risk of Settlement Failure, in TECHNOLOGY AND THE REGULATION OF FINANCIAL MARKETS: SECURITIES, FUTURES, AND BANKING 97, 97 (Anthony Saunders & Lawrence J. White eds., 1986) (the failure of the banks with the largest settlement obligations would produce a disruptive system-wide effect in the United States). A clearinghouse serves as an exchange for banks submitting payment, securities or options trade claims to each other. The banks maintain accounts at the clearinghouse, which are credited and debited depending on whether they are paying or receiving payment.
    • (1986) Technology and the Regulation of Financial Markets: Securities, Futures, and Banking , vol.97 , pp. 97
    • Humphrey, D.B.1
  • 124
    • 79956078210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MANN, supra note 30, at
    • See MANN, supra note 30, at 55-56.
  • 125
    • 79956104084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Typically there are numerous payment transactions going both directions between any given pair of clearinghouse member banks. Some clearinghouses will only accept transactions when they are satisfied that the paying institution has sufficient funds in its clearinghouse account to pay. Others, however, allow institutions to overdraw on their accounts, based on the expectation that future transactions will replenish the account or that the institution will do so with its own funds at the end of the business day. Because these overdrafts must be cured by the end of the day, they are called "daylight overdrafts." If a bank were to fail when it had a daylight overdraft, the clearinghouse would be exposed to the loss. While it is unlikely that a single institution's inability to honor a daylight overdraft would result in the failure of a clearinghouse, it is more than a theoretical possibility. The collapse in 1974 of Herstatt, a German bank, nearly brought about the failure of CHIPS, a wire transfer system that does the bulk of international, interbank dollar-denominated transfers.
  • 127
    • 79956097510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MANN, supra note 30, at (describing daylight overdrafts on the FedWire system)
    • See MANN, supra note 30, at 240 (describing daylight overdrafts on the FedWire system);
  • 128
    • 74849139216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. at (discussing system risk in the wire transfer system and noting that one major clearinghouse system, CHIPS, is a private institution without central bank support for "the approximately $1.4 trillion that it transfers each day").
    • id. at 271-72 (discussing system risk in the wire transfer system and noting that one major clearinghouse system, CHIPS, is a private institution without central bank support for "the approximately $1.4 trillion that it transfers each day").
    • (2002) A Financial History of the United States: From the Age of Derivatives into the New Millennium (1970-2001) , pp. 271-272
    • Markham, J.W.1
  • 129
    • 79956083999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clearinghouses often require members to post some form of collateral or margin account and also generally have a right to call on members for additional capital contributions if necessary. Regarding clearinghouses generally, see Craig Pirrong, OTC Derivatives Clearing and the Prevention of the Next Crisis: A Contrarian View (Feb. 15,) (unpublished paper), available at
    • Clearinghouses often require members to post some form of collateral or margin account and also generally have a right to call on members for additional capital contributions if necessary. Regarding clearinghouses generally, see Craig Pirrong, OTC Derivatives Clearing and the Prevention of the Next Crisis: A Contrarian View (Feb. 15, 2010) (unpublished paper), available at http://www. law.columbia.edu/null/download?&exclusive=filemgr.download&file-id= 154777.
    • (2010)
  • 130
    • 70449609892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial firm bankruptcy and systemic risk
    • Argues that counterparty contagion is not a major risk for national banks because they are limited by 12 U.S.C. § 84(a) to lending no more than 15% of their capital to any single counterparty. See Jean Helwege distinguishing between counterparty contagion and information contagion). This analysis ignores the fact that both banks and their counterparties are usually leveraged, which can make even limited losses catastrophic. For example, if a bank has $8 in equity for every $100 in assets, then if the value of those assets declines by more than 8%, the bank will be insolvent. Given that many of those assets are either loans or investments, such a decline in value is quite possible. Similarly, even a delay in repayment can itself be problematic because of liquidity constraints. Moreover, the prerequisite for a bank run is not a bank's actual inability to repay its obligations in a timely fashion, but only a perception that the bank might not be able to repay on time
    • Jean Helwege argues that counterparty contagion is not a major risk for national banks because they are limited by 12 U.S.C. § 84(a) to lending no more than 15% of their capital to any single counterparty. See Jean Helwege, Financial Firm Bankruptcy and Systemic Risk, 32 REG. 24 (2009) (distinguishing between counterparty contagion and information contagion). This analysis ignores the fact that both banks and their counterparties are usually leveraged, which can make even limited losses catastrophic. For example, if a bank has $8 in equity for every $100 in assets, then if the value of those assets declines by more than 8%, the bank will be insolvent. Given that many of those assets are either loans or investments, such a decline in value is quite possible. Similarly, even a delay in repayment can itself be problematic because of liquidity constraints. Moreover, the prerequisite for a bank run is not a bank's actual inability to repay its obligations in a timely fashion, but only a perception that the bank might not be able to repay on time.
    • (2009) Reg. , vol.32 , pp. 24
    • Helwege, J.1
  • 131
    • 79956150478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MERRILL LYNCH & CO., QUARTERLY REPORT (FORM 10-Q) 6-7 (June 27 available at
    • See MERRILL LYNCH & CO., QUARTERLY REPORT (FORM 10-Q) 6-7 (June 27, 2008), available at http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/65100/ 000095012308008850/y64172e10vq.htm#102.
    • (2008)
  • 132
    • 70449609892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Financial firm bankruptcy and systemic risk
    • Id
    • Id.
    • (2009) Reg. , vol.32 , pp. 24
    • Helwege, J.1
  • 133
    • 67650453389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The fundamental principles of financial regulation
    • Brunnermeier also notes that "[t]he domino model of contagion has been examined in numerous simulation studies conducted at central banks, but the universal conclusion has been that the impact of the domino model of contagion is very small. It is only with implausibly large shocks that the simulations generate any meaningful contagion."
    • Markus Brunnermeier et al., The Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation, in 11 GENEVA REPORTS ON THE WORLD ECON. 17 (2009). Brunnermeier also notes that "[t]he domino model of contagion has been examined in numerous simulation studies conducted at central banks, but the universal conclusion has been that the impact of the domino model of contagion is very small. It is only with implausibly large shocks that the simulations generate any meaningful contagion."
    • (2009) Geneva Reports On The World Econ. , vol.11 , pp. 17
    • Brunnermeier, M.1
  • 135
    • 79956145722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When all the banks failed
    • (Columbia Univ.), Spring 2009, at 4
    • Jón Steinsson, When All the Banks Failed, 3 ECON. COLUM. (Columbia Univ.), Spring 2009, at 4, 4;
    • Econ. Colum. , vol.3 , pp. 4
    • Steinsson, J.1
  • 136
    • 79956061674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ice. Sch. Of Bus., Univ. of Ice., and Global Distinguished Professor of Politics, N.Y.U. & Tryggvi Thor Herbertsson, Professor of Econ., Univ. of Reykjavík, and Member of Parliament, System Failure in Iceland and the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, Paper Presented at the 13th Annual Conference of the International Society for New Institutional Economics 22 (June 18-20
    • Thráinn Eggertsson, Professor of Econ., Ice. Sch. Of Bus., Univ. of Ice., and Global Distinguished Professor of Politics, N.Y.U. & Tryggvi Thor Herbertsson, Professor of Econ., Univ. of Reykjavík, and Member of Parliament, System Failure in Iceland and the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, Paper Presented at the 13th Annual Conference of the International Society for New Institutional Economics 22 (June 18-20, 2009).
    • (2009) Professor of Econ.
    • Eggertsson, T.1
  • 137
    • 79956140225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See ANNUAL REPORT 117-18 (last visited Dec. 1, 2010). The collapse of HRE Group also appears to have had an element of obligor contagion. HRE Group's Irish subsidiary, Depfa, had large exposures to Lehman. Germany's KfW, Hypo Real Estate Post Heavy Losses, DEUTSCHEWELLE (Nov. 17, 2008), http://www.dw-world. de/dw/article/0,3799955,00.html
    • See FEDERAL FINANCIAL SUPERVISORY AUTHORITY (BUNDESANSTALT FÜR FINANZDIENSTLEISTUNGSAUFSICHT (BAFIN)), 2008 ANNUAL REPORT 117-18, http://www.bafin.de/cln-179/nn-992932/SharedDocs/ Downloads/EN/Service/ Jahresberichte/2008/annualreport-08-kap5.html (last visited Dec. 1, 2010). The collapse of HRE Group also appears to have had an element of obligor contagion. HRE Group's Irish subsidiary, Depfa, had large exposures to Lehman. Germany's KfW, Hypo Real Estate Post Heavy Losses, DEUTSCHEWELLE (Nov. 17, 2008), http://www.dw-world.de/dw/article/0,3799955,00.html.
    • (2008) Federal Financial Supervisory Authority (Bundesanstalt Für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (Bafin))
  • 138
    • 70350700854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rewriting frankenstein contracts: Workout prohibitions in residential mortgage-backed securities
    • 1081-83
    • Anna Gelpern & Adam J. Levitin, Rewriting Frankenstein Contracts: Workout Prohibitions in Residential Mortgage-Backed Securities, 82 S. CAL. L. REV. 1075, 1081-83 (2009).
    • (2009) S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 1075
    • Gelpern, A.1    Levitin, A.J.2
  • 139
    • 79956088546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Often a CDO's contingent obligation on a CDS would be collateralized, so that if the CDO were unable to pay, its counterparty could look to the collateral for a recovery. Not all CDS obligations are collateralized, however. See TARP Accountability: Use of Federal Assistance by the First TARP Recipients: Hearing Before the H. Fin. Servs. Comm., 111th Cong. 47-48 (2009) (testimony of Lloyd C. Blankfein, Chief Executive Officer and Chairman, Goldman Sachs & Co.) ("[W]ith respect to our dealings with AIG, we were always fully collateralized and had de minimis or no credit risk at any given moment because we exchanged collateral. So we had outstanding positions, as did most people, but we had no credit exposure because we had collateral from them and in some cases other kind of credit mitigants . . . . Sometimes the collateral would lag [the exposures], and we would also take out credit insurance against their exposure.")
    • Often a CDO's contingent obligation on a CDS would be collateralized, so that if the CDO were unable to pay, its counterparty could look to the collateral for a recovery. Not all CDS obligations are collateralized, however. See TARP Accountability: Use of Federal Assistance by the First TARP Recipients: Hearing Before the H. Fin. Servs. Comm., 111th Cong. 47-48 (2009) (testimony of Lloyd C. Blankfein, Chief Executive Officer and Chairman, Goldman Sachs & Co.) ("[W]ith respect to our dealings with AIG, we were always fully collateralized and had de minimis or no credit risk at any given moment because we exchanged collateral. So we had outstanding positions, as did most people, but we had no credit exposure because we had collateral from them and in some cases other kind of credit mitigants . . . . Sometimes the collateral would lag [the exposures], and we would also take out credit insurance against their exposure.").
  • 141
    • 79956155420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • If lehman collapses expect a run on all of the other broker dealers and the collapse of the shadow banking system
    • Sept. 13
    • Nouriel Roubini, If Lehman Collapses Expect a Run on All of the Other Broker Dealers and the Collapse of the Shadow Banking System, RGE MONITOR (Sept. 13, 2008), http://www.roubini.com/roubinimonitor/253567/if-lehman-collapses- expect-a-run-on-all-of-the-other-broker-dealers-and-the-collapse-of-the-shadow- banking-system.
    • (2008) Rge Monitor
    • Roubini, N.1
  • 142
    • 79956128373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at (Feb. 26 unpublished paper), available at
    • Ingimundur Fririksson, The Banking Crisis in Iceland in 2008, at 5 (Feb. 26, 2009) (unpublished paper), available at http://www.bis.org/review/r090226d. pdf.
    • (2009) The Banking Crisis in Iceland in 2008 , pp. 5
    • Frioriksson, I.1
  • 145
    • 79956150477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also , W. MORNING NEWS (Plymouth, U.K.), Oct. 13, , at 11 (£4 billion figure).
    • see also Iceland Learns a Brutal Lesson, W. MORNING NEWS (Plymouth, U.K.), Oct. 13, 2008, at 11 (£4 billion figure).
    • (2008) Iceland Learns a Brutal Lesson
  • 146
    • 79956074009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, supra note 45, at
    • See Lang & Stulz, supra note 45, at 46-47.
    • Lang1    Stulz2
  • 147
    • 79956061133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hawaiian Airlines, Midway Airlines, Sun Country Airlines, United Airlines, US Airways, and Vanguard Airlines all filed for bankruptcy within approximately two years of September 11, 2001. U.S. Airline Bankruptcies & Service Cessations, AIR TRANSPORT ASS'N OF AM., (last visited Fed. 24
    • Hawaiian Airlines, Midway Airlines, Sun Country Airlines, United Airlines, US Airways, and Vanguard Airlines all filed for bankruptcy within approximately two years of September 11, 2001. U.S. Airline Bankruptcies & Service Cessations, AIR TRANSPORT ASS'N OF AM., http://www.airlines.org/ economics/specialtopics/USAirlineBankruptcies.htm (last visited Fed. 24, 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 148
    • 79956127328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Air Transportation Safety and System Stabilization Act, Pub. L. No. 107-42, 115 Stat. 230, Sept. 22, 2001, codified at 49 U.S.C. § 40101
    • Air Transportation Safety and System Stabilization Act, Pub. L. No. 107-42, 115 Stat. 230, Sept. 22, 2001, codified at 49 U.S.C. § 40101 (2006).
    • (2006)
  • 150
    • 79956130478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S&P downgrades thousands of MBS deals to default level
    • Feb. 16
    • Bonnie Sinnock, S&P Downgrades Thousands of MBS Deals to Default Level, NAT'L MORTG. NEWS, Feb. 16, 2009.
    • (2009) Nat'l Mortg. News
    • Sinnock, B.1
  • 151
    • 79956084548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 66, at
    • See Brunnermeier et al., supra note 66, at 14-19.
    • Brunnermeier1
  • 152
    • 79956091110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, The White House, President Obama Calls for New Restrictions on Size and Scope of Financial Institutions To Rein in Excesses and Protect Taxpayers (Jan. 21, available at. But see Paul Davis, Tax Will Mean Little Change at Big Banks, AM. BANKER, Jan. 15, 2010 (arguing that proposed tax on bigness or leverage will have little impact)
    • Press Release, The White House, President Obama Calls for New Restrictions on Size and Scope of Financial Institutions To Rein in Excesses and Protect Taxpayers (Jan. 21, 2010), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/the- press-office/president-obama-calls-new-restrictions-size-and-scopefinancial- institutions-rein-e. But see Paul Davis, Tax Will Mean Little Change at Big Banks, AM. BANKER, Jan. 15, 2010 (arguing that proposed tax on bigness or leverage will have little impact).
    • (2010)
  • 153
    • 77957155933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, supra note
    • Press Release, The White House, supra note 81.
    • The White House , pp. 81
  • 154
    • 77949307533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulating bankers' pay
    • 252
    • See Lucian A. Bebchuk & Holger Spamann, Regulating Bankers' Pay, 98 GEO. L.J. 247, 252 (2010);
    • (2010) Geo. L.J. , vol.98 , pp. 247
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1    Spamann, H.2
  • 155
    • 77954519705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reforming executive compensation: Focusing and committing to the long-term
    • 361
    • Sanjai Bhagat & Roberta Romano, Reforming Executive Compensation: Focusing and Committing to the Long-Term, 26 YALE J. ON REG. 359, 361 (2009);
    • (2009) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.26 , pp. 359
    • Bhagat, S.1    Romano, R.2
  • 157
    • 79956159737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra section III.C
    • See infra section III.C.
  • 158
    • 79956156940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Pew Financial Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 2 available at
    • Alice Rivlin, Systemic Risk and the Role of the Federal Reserve (Pew Financial Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 2, 2009), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project-reports/files/Rivlin-Final-TF-Correction-2. pdf.
    • (2009) Systemic Risk and the Role of the Federal Reserve
    • Rivlin, A.1
  • 159
    • 79956074008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra section II.E
    • See infra section II.E.
  • 160
    • 79956114977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra section II.D
    • See infra section II.D.
  • 161
  • 162
    • 77950310789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The case against shareholder empowerment
    • 675-88
    • See William W. Bratton & Michael L. Wachter, The Case Against Shareholder Empowerment, 158 U. PA. L. REV. 653, 675-88 (2010).
    • (2010) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.158 , pp. 653
    • Bratton, W.W.1    Wachter, M.L.2
  • 164
    • 79956132776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 20, at
    • See Taylor, supra note 20, at 3.
    • Taylor1
  • 165
    • 79956087437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Too Big To Fail: The Role for Bankruptcy and Antitrust Law in Financial Regulation Reform: Hearing Before the H. Judiciary Subcomm. on Commercial and Admin. Law, 111th Cong. 105-27 (2009) [hereinafter Too Big To Fail] (statement of Christopher L. Sagers, Associate Professor of Law, Cleveland State University) (antitrust regulation); id. at 140-56 (2009) (statement of Robert Weissman, President, Public Citizen) (antitrust regulation); Brunnermeier et al., supra note 66, at 33 (capital charges and Pigouvian taxation); Davis Wessel, Three Theories on Solving the 'Too Big to Fail' Problem, WALL ST. J., Oct. 28, 2009, at A2 (view of Bank of England Governor Mervyn King and former Treasury Secretary George Schultz on reducing the size of banks); Simon Johnson, Bring In the Antitrust Division (On Banking), BASELINE SCENARIO (Apr. 16, 2009, 6:02 AM), http://baselinescenario. com/2009/04/16/bring-in-the-antitrust- division-on-banking/ (antitrust enforcement to reduce the size of large financial institutions).
  • 166
    • 79956082377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 66, at
    • Brunnermeier et al., supra note 66, at 33.
    • Brunnermeier1
  • 167
    • 84920077689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remarks at Vanderbilt University: September 11, the Federal Reserve, and the Financial System (Feb. 5, 2003) (transcript available at
    • Roger W. Ferguson, Jr., Vice Chairman, Fed. Reserve Bd., Remarks at Vanderbilt University: September 11, the Federal Reserve, and the Financial System (Feb. 5, 2003) (transcript available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/ boarddocs/speeches/2003/20030205/default.htm).
    • Vice Chairman, Fed. Reserve Bd.
    • Ferguson Jr., R.W.1
  • 168
    • 77956893586 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity
    • 15 The fall of 2008 did witness a run on traditional banks for uninsured deposits
    • See Douglas W. Diamond & Philip H. Dybvig, Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity, 24 FED. RESERVE BANK OF MINNEAPOLIS Q. REV. 14, 15 (2000). The fall of 2008 did witness a run on traditional banks for uninsured deposits.
    • (2000) Fed. Reserve Bank Of Minneapolis Q. Rev. , vol.24 , pp. 14
    • Diamond, D.W.1    Dybvig, P.H.2
  • 169
    • 85011655177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007-2008
    • See Markus K. Brunnermeier, Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-2008, J. ECON. PERSP., Winter 2009, at 77, 90.
    • (2009) J. Econ. Persp., Winter , vol.77 , pp. 90
    • Brunnermeier, S.M.K.1
  • 171
    • 79956159037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The collapse of the asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) market in 2008 illustrates a similar problem. Commercial paper is a short-term debt obligation. Banks are required to hold specific levels of capital in relation to the loans they make (held as assets on their balance sheets). This means that the more loans a bank makes, the more capital it must hold. Raising capital is expensive because it dilutes equity (and hence return on equity). If a bank can sell the loans it holds for cash, however, it does not need to raise as much capital. In order to reduce capital requirements, many traditional financial institutions entered into structured transactions in which they sold loan assets to off-balance sheet subsidiaries they created. These off-balance sheet subsidiaries are called structured investment vehicles (SIVs), and are not subject to any legal capital requirements whatsoever. The SIVs pay for the loan assets by issuing commercial paper. The commercial paper is called asset-backed because it is collateralized by the specific pool of assets held by the SIV. The SIVs are known as ABCP conduits. Because the SIVs' assets have long-term maturities, but the SIVs' liabilities are short-term commercial paper, this arrangement only works as long as the SIVs are able to constantly refinance their ABCP. If demand for ABCP slumps, the SIVs face a liquidity crisis because they will be unable to pay off existing commercial paper obligations through refinancings, much less purchase additional loan assets from banks. ABCP conduits serve as a shadow banking system, and they too are vulnerable to runs. If ABCP buyers get spooked, then refinancings become difficult, and holders of ABCP scramble to sell their holdings, which causes the price of ABCP to drop, meaning SIVs must issue even more paper to refinance the same amount of debt. The result looks like a run, with the SIVs caught in an asset-liability duration mismatch. It only takes the failure of a couple of SIVs for the entire market to become skittish and fail.
  • 172
    • 79956143983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 96, at (describing the failure of auction-rate securities)
    • KRUGMAN, supra note 96, at 158-61 (describing the failure of auction-rate securities).
    • Krugman1
  • 173
    • 0003832227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (describing market-wide panic triggered by the failure of Long-Term Capital Management, a hedge fund); Andrei Shleifer & Robert W. Vishny, The Limits of Arbitrage, 52 J. FIN. 35, 37 (1997) (noting the possibility of investor runs on hedge funds and mutual funds); Tom Sullivan, Better Disclosure, Courtesy of Madoff, BARRON'S, Jan. 26, 2009, at 45, 45 (noting the risk of investor runs on hedge funds via redemption requests)
    • ROGER LOWENSTEIN, WHEN GENIUS FAILED: THE RISE AND FALL OF LONG-TERM CAPITAL MANAGEMENT (2000) (describing market-wide panic triggered by the failure of Long-Term Capital Management, a hedge fund); Andrei Shleifer & Robert W. Vishny, The Limits of Arbitrage, 52 J. FIN. 35, 37 (1997) (noting the possibility of investor runs on hedge funds and mutual funds); Tom Sullivan, Better Disclosure, Courtesy of Madoff, BARRON'S, Jan. 26, 2009, at 45, 45 (noting the risk of investor runs on hedge funds via redemption requests).
    • (2000) When Genius Failed: The Rise and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management
    • Lowenstein, R.1
  • 174
    • 79956154308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Money market mutual funds are a subset of mutual funds that invest in high quality, liquid assets, such as commercial paper, short-term bonds, repo agreements, and shares of other money market mutual funds. See 17 C.F.R. § 270.2a-7 (regulating money market mutual funds and defining related terms).
    • Money market mutual funds are a subset of mutual funds that invest in high quality, liquid assets, such as commercial paper, short-term bonds, repo agreements, and shares of other money market mutual funds. See 17 C.F.R. § 270.2a-7 (2010) (regulating money market mutual funds and defining related terms).
    • (2010)
  • 176
    • 70350729647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 0 (Yale Int'l Center for Fin., Working Paper No. 09-14, ), available at
    • Gary Gorton & Andrew Metrick, Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo, at 0 (Yale Int'l Center for Fin., Working Paper No. 09-14, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1440752;
    • (2009) Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo
    • Gorton, G.1    Metrick, A.2
  • 177
    • 79956158518 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At 33-34 (Paper for the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta's 2009 Financial Markets Conference: Financial Innovation and Crisis,), available at
    • Gary Gorton, Slapped in the Face by the Invisible Hand: Banking and the Panic of 2007, at 33-34 (Paper for the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta's 2009 Financial Markets Conference: Financial Innovation and Crisis, 2009), available at
    • (2009) Slapped in the Face by the Invisible Hand: Banking and the Panic of 2007
    • Gorton, G.1
  • 178
    • 79956129950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CDS or TRS protection buyers can attempt to sell their coverage at a discount if they are worried about the ability of the protection seller to make good on its obligations. Similarly, they can demand that the protection seller post more collateral to cover the exposure. See Gretchen Morgenson & Louise Story, Testy Conflict With Goldman Helped Push A.I.G. to Precipice, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 7, at A1 (detailing Goldman Sachs' demands for its CDS protection seller, AIG, to post additional collateral). Demands for additional collateral are tantamount to a run
    • CDS or TRS protection buyers can attempt to sell their coverage at a discount if they are worried about the ability of the protection seller to make good on its obligations. Similarly, they can demand that the protection seller post more collateral to cover the exposure. See Gretchen Morgenson & Louise Story, Testy Conflict With Goldman Helped Push A.I.G. to Precipice, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 7, 2010, at A1 (detailing Goldman Sachs' demands for its CDS protection seller, AIG, to post additional collateral). Demands for additional collateral are tantamount to a run.
    • (2010)
  • 179
    • 84866636036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The world of banks, bigger can be better
    • Oct. 20, at A21 (noting that banks benefit from economies of scale resulting in cheaper financial services, globally integrated capital markets, and the ability to supply financial intermediation on the scale needed by global corporations)
    • See Charles Calomiris, Editorial, In the World of Banks, Bigger Can Be Better, WALL ST. J., Oct. 20, 2009, at A21 (noting that banks benefit from economies of scale resulting in cheaper financial services, globally integrated capital markets, and the ability to supply financial intermediation on the scale needed by global corporations).
    • (2009) Wall St. J.
    • Calomiris, C.1
  • 180
    • 84860212769 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 12, 2009), available at (discussing the role of networks in the financial crisis)
    • See generally Ross A. Hammond, Systemic Risk in the Financial System: Insights from Network Science 1 (Pew Fin. Reform Project, Briefing Paper No. 12, 2009), available at http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project-reports/files/EP- HammondNetworks-final-TF-Correction.pdf (discussing the role of networks in the financial crisis).
    • Systemic Risk in the Financial System: Insights from Network Science 1
    • Hammond, R.A.1
  • 181
    • 44649197264 scopus 로고
    • Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure
    • 308
    • Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305, 308 (1976).
    • (1976) J. Fin. Econ. , vol.3 , pp. 305
    • Jensen, M.C.1    Meckling, W.H.2
  • 182
    • 79956127845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bad and good securitization
    • Fall 23
    • Susan M. Wachter et al., Bad and Good Securitization, 13 WHARTON REAL EST. REV., no. 2, Fall 2009, at 23, 23.
    • (2009) Wharton Real Est. Rev. , vol.13 , Issue.2 , pp. 23
    • Wachter, S.M.1
  • 183
    • 79956139177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Feb. 14, at BU1 (quoting Professor Edward J. Kane saying that, "People talk about systemic risk, but they have no metric of measuring it")
    • See Gretchen Morgenson, Future Bailouts of America, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 14, 2010, at BU1 (quoting Professor Edward J. Kane saying that, "People talk about systemic risk, but they have no metric of measuring it").
    • (2010) Future Bailouts of America, N.Y. Times
    • Morgenson, G.1
  • 184
    • 79956108373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. , supra note
    • See, e.g., Rivlin, supra note 85.
    • Rivlin1
  • 185
    • 79956077137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A systemic risk regulator would also suffer from the problem that it would be impossible to tell if it were doing its job well until and unless it failed. It would be impossible to determine if the regulator's actions headed off systemic risk or merely quashed innocent economic activity
    • A systemic risk regulator would also suffer from the problem that it would be impossible to tell if it were doing its job well until and unless it failed. It would be impossible to determine if the regulator's actions headed off systemic risk or merely quashed innocent economic activity.
  • 186
    • 79956115509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Equipping Financial Regulators with the Tools Necessary to Monitor Systemic Risk: Hearing Before the S. Banking Subcomm. on Sec. and Int'l Trade and Fin., 111th Cong. 4-5 (statement of Daniel K. Tarullo, member, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys
    • But see Equipping Financial Regulators with the Tools Necessary to Monitor Systemic Risk: Hearing Before the S. Banking Subcomm. on Sec. and Int'l Trade and Fin., 111th Cong. 4-5 (2010) (statement of Daniel K. Tarullo, member, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.).
    • (2010)
  • 187
    • 79956074007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GROUP OF THIRTY, FINANCIAL REFORM: A FRAMEWORK FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY 28, available at . Notably, the connection between proprietary trading and deposit-taking was not at the core of this crisis
    • See GROUP OF THIRTY, FINANCIAL REFORM: A FRAMEWORK FOR FINANCIAL STABILITY 28 (2009), available at http://www.group30.org/pubs/reformreport.pdf. Notably, the connection between proprietary trading and deposit-taking was not at the core of this crisis;
    • (2009)
  • 189
    • 79956127844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Through the Looking Glass (Steagall): Banks, Broker Dealers, and the Volcker Rule
    • Jan. 27, (criticizing focus of Paul Volker's proposals as misplaced for failing to cover shadow banking).
    • See Raj Date, Through the Looking Glass (Steagall): Banks, Broker Dealers, and the Volcker Rule, CAMBRIDGE WINTER CENTER FOR FIN. INST. POL'Y (Jan. 27, 2010), http://www.cambridgewinter.org/Cambridge-Winter/Archives/ Entries/2010/1/27-THROUGH-THE-LOOKING-GLASS-(STEAGALL)-files/ looking-glass-steagall-012710-1.pdf (criticizing focus of Paul Volker's proposals as misplaced for failing to cover shadow banking).
    • (2010) Cambridge Winter Center For Fin. Inst. Pol'y
    • Date, R.1
  • 190
    • 79956078209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 92, at (testimony of Michael S. Barr, Assistant Secretary of the Treasury);
    • Too Big To Fail, supra note 92, at 22 (testimony of Michael S. Barr, Assistant Secretary of the Treasury);
    • Too Big To Fail , pp. 22
  • 191
    • 80055051346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The corporate structure of international financial conglomerates: Complexity and its implications for safety and soundness
    • (Allen N. Berger et al. eds., );
    • Richard Herring & Jacopo Carmassi, The Corporate Structure of International Financial Conglomerates: Complexity and Its Implications for Safety and Soundness, in OXFORD HANDBOOK OF BANKING 195, 226 (Allen N. Berger et al. eds., 2009);
    • (2009) Oxford Handbook Of Banking , vol.195 , pp. 226
    • Herring, R.1    Carmassi, J.2
  • 192
    • 77952713281 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The known, the unknown, and the unknowable in financial policy: An application to the subprime crisis
    • 403-04
    • Richard J. Herring, The Known, the Unknown, and the Unknowable in Financial Policy: An Application to the Subprime Crisis, 26 YALE J. ON REG. 391, 403-04 (2009);
    • (2009) Yale J. On Reg. , vol.26 , pp. 391
    • Herring, R.J.1
  • 193
    • 79956092104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Restoring American Financial Stability Act of , S. 3217, 111th Cong. § 115(d)(1) (2010)
    • see also Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010, S. 3217, 111th Cong. § 115(d)(1) (2010).
    • (2010)
  • 195
    • 79956117497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Supervising and Resolving Large Financial Institutions, Speech at the Institute of International Bankers Conference on Cross-Border Insolvency Issues ( Nov. 10transcript available at
    • Daniel K. Tarullo, Member, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., Supervising and Resolving Large Financial Institutions, Speech at the Institute of International Bankers Conference on Cross-Border Insolvency Issues (Nov. 10, 2009) (transcript available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/ tarullo20091110a.htm).
    • (2009) Member, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.
    • Tarullo, D.K.1
  • 196
    • 79956131007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 69, at (discussing securitization structures as an example of contractual bankruptcy regimes)
    • Gelpern & Levitin, supra note 69, at 1118-24 (discussing securitization structures as an example of contractual bankruptcy regimes).
    • Gelpern1    Levitin2
  • 197
    • 84878140059 scopus 로고
    • Debtor's choice: A menu approach to corporate bankruptcy
    • 112 discussing how in a contractual bankruptcy system, optimal structures may change over time
    • Cf. Robert K. Rasmussen, Debtor's Choice: A Menu Approach to Corporate Bankruptcy, 71 TEX. L. REV. 51, 112 (1992) (discussing how in a contractual bankruptcy system, optimal structures may change over time).
    • (1992) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 51
    • Rasmussen, C.R.K.1
  • 198
    • 79956084547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A lack of resolution
    • See David Zaring, A Lack of Resolution, 60 EMORY L.J. 99 (2010).
    • (2010) Emory L.J. , vol.60 , pp. 99
    • Zaring, D.1
  • 199
    • 79956123198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Variously given as "Respica te, hominem te memento" or "Memento mori."
    • Variously given as "Respica te, hominem te memento" or "Memento mori."
  • 200
    • 79956133787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Too Big To Fail, supra note 92, at 5 (testimony of Michael S. Barr, Assistant Secretary of the Treasury)
    • Too Big To Fail, supra note 92, at 3, 5 (testimony of Michael S. Barr, Assistant Secretary of the Treasury);
  • 201
    • 79956152580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 20, at
    • Taylor, supra note 20, at 6.
    • Taylor1
  • 205
  • 206
    • 79956076120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York Financial Guarantee Company Law, NY CLS §§ 6901-6903 . State insurance regulators' ability to regulate insurance companies' derivatives activities was preempted in 2000 by the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, which did not substitute an alternative system of federal regulation. See Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, §§ 101(12) 105, 117, 407 (excluding covered bank swap agreements from CFTC jurisdiction), codified at 7 U.S.C. §§ (1a)(12) (definitions), 2(g) (exclusion of OTC swaps from federal regulation), 16(e)(2) (preemption of state law)
    • See, e.g., New York Financial Guarantee Company Law, NY CLS §§ 6901-6903 (2010). State insurance regulators' ability to regulate insurance companies' derivatives activities was preempted in 2000 by the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, which did not substitute an alternative system of federal regulation. See Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, §§ 101(12) 105, 117, 407 (excluding covered bank swap agreements from CFTC jurisdiction), codified at 7 U.S.C. §§ (1a)(12) (definitions), 2(g) (exclusion of OTC swaps from federal regulation), 16(e)(2) (preemption of state law).
    • (2010)
  • 207
    • 79956161137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 120, at (discussing alternatives to Basel II capital adequacy regime for banks)
    • TARULLO, supra note 120, at 225-58 (discussing alternatives to Basel II capital adequacy regime for banks).
    • Tarullo1
  • 208
    • 79956138695 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 222-23.
    • Schwarcz1
  • 209
  • 210
    • 79956061673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 66, at
    • Brunnermeier et al., supra note 66, at 39-48;
    • Brunnermeier1
  • 211
    • 79956088476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • Schwarcz, supra note 15, at 225-30.
    • Schwarcz1
  • 212
    • 79956108922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 120, at
    • TARULLO, supra note 120, at 231-45;
    • Tarullo1
  • 213
    • 0041744792 scopus 로고
    • Preferred Sources of Market Discipline
    • Douglas D. Evanoff, Preferred Sources of Market Discipline, 10 YALE J. ON REG. 347, 355 (1993); (Pubitemid 24821760)
    • (1993) Yale journal on regulation , vol.10 , Issue.2 , pp. 347
    • Evanoff, D.D.1
  • 214
    • 0002361414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Subordinated debt as bank capital: A proposal for regulatory reform
    • Douglas D. Evanoff & Larry D. Wall, Subordinated Debt as Bank Capital: A Proposal for Regulatory Reform, 24 FED. RESERVE BANK OF CHIC. ECON. PERSP. 40 (2000);
    • (2000) Fed. Reserve Bank Of Chic. Econ. Persp. , vol.24 , pp. 40
    • Evanoff, D.D.1    Wall, L.D.2
  • 215
    • 0006327038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Fed. Reserve Bank of ChicagoWorking Paper No. 2000-07) [hereinafter Bank Capital Reform]
    • Douglas D. Evanoff & Larry D. Wall, Subordinated Debt and Bank Capital Reform (Fed. Reserve Bank of ChicagoWorking Paper No. 2000-07) [hereinafter Bank Capital Reform].
    • Subordinated Debt and Bank Capital Reform
    • Evanoff, D.D.1    Wall, L.D.2
  • 216
    • 79956155419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 66, at
    • Brunnermeier et al., supra note 66, at 36;
    • Brunnermeier1
  • 217
    • 79956074532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Squam Lake Working Group on Fin. Stability, An Expedited Resolution Mechanism for Distressed Financial Firms: Regulatory Hybrid Securities (Council on Foreign Relations, Center for Geoeconomic Studies Working Paper, April available at. These proposals have many resemblances to the automated bankruptcy proposal of Barry Adler that would feature "chameleon equity"-debt that automatically converts into equity upon the triggering of various financial conditions
    • Squam Lake Working Group on Fin. Stability, An Expedited Resolution Mechanism for Distressed Financial Firms: Regulatory Hybrid Securities (Council on Foreign Relations, Center for Geoeconomic Studies Working Paper, April 2009), available at http://www.cfr.org/content/publications/attachments/Squam-Lake- Working-Paper3.pdf. These proposals have many resemblances to the automated bankruptcy proposal of Barry Adler that would feature "chameleon equity"-debt that automatically converts into equity upon the triggering of various financial conditions.
    • (2009)
  • 218
    • 84914977180 scopus 로고
    • Financial and political theories of american corporate bankruptcy
    • 312 A bank-specific variation of this can be found in Evanoff, supra note 129, at 359 (proposing that banks have mandatory subordinated debt in capital structure, which would convert to equity once the bank's capital fell to a trigger level)
    • Barry E. Adler, Financial and Political Theories of American Corporate Bankruptcy, 45 STAN L. REV. 311, 312 (1993). A bank-specific variation of this can be found in Evanoff, supra note 129, at 359 (proposing that banks have mandatory subordinated debt in capital structure, which would convert to equity once the bank's capital fell to a trigger level).
    • (1993) Stan L. Rev. , vol.45 , pp. 311
    • Adler, B.E.1
  • 219
    • 79956139700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 12 C.F.R. § 1.3 (limiting banks' single-firm exposures in investment securities).
    • See, e.g., 12 C.F.R. § 1.3 (2010) (limiting banks' single-firm exposures in investment securities).
    • (2010)
  • 220
    • 79956114468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Uninsured, wholesale depositors do have a monitoring incentive, but the market discipline imposed by depositors is primarily ex post and often comes in the form of a run. An example of this is the case of the 1984 failure of Continental Illinois National Bank, when uninsured depositors transferred out their funds as they became concerned with Continental Illinois's exposure to Mexican sovereign debt and Penn Square Bank participations. See TARULLO, supra note 120, at
    • Uninsured, wholesale depositors do have a monitoring incentive, but the market discipline imposed by depositors is primarily ex post and often comes in the form of a run. An example of this is the case of the 1984 failure of Continental Illinois National Bank, when uninsured depositors transferred out their funds as they became concerned with Continental Illinois's exposure to Mexican sovereign debt and Penn Square Bank participations. See TARULLO, supra note 120, at 37.
  • 222
    • 79956128926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 83 and accompanying text
    • See supra note 83 and accompanying text.
  • 224
    • 79956154307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra section IV.Bs
    • See infra section IV.B.
  • 225
    • 79956107869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aug. 31, University of Pennsylvania Institute for Law & Economics Research Paper No. 10-15, Georgetown Public Law Research Paper No. 10-60, Georgetown Law and Economics Research Paper No. 10-16, available at
    • See Adam J. Levitin & Susan M. Wachter, Explaining the Housing Bubble, Aug. 31, 2010, University of Pennsylvania Institute for Law & Economics Research Paper No. 10-15, Georgetown Public Law Research Paper No. 10-60, Georgetown Law and Economics Research Paper No. 10-16, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1669401.
    • (2010) Explaining the Housing Bubble
    • Levitin, A.J.1    Wachter, S.M.2
  • 226
    • 79956141333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The form of the regulator is itself critical to its efficacy. Consider the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) created by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. See infra section II.I for a discussion of the FSOC's structure. The FSOC arguably suffers from an organizational structure that dilutes responsibility and accountability while also being vulnerable to inaction. The two most important types of FSOC powers-designation of a nonbank financial company as systemically important, and therefore subject to prudential regulation by the Federal Reserve Board, and actions to mitigate systemic risk-both require a two-thirds majority vote (as well as the affirmative vote of its chairperson, the Secretary of the Treasury, in the first instance)
    • The form of the regulator is itself critical to its efficacy. Consider the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) created by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. See infra section II.I for a discussion of the FSOC's structure. The FSOC arguably suffers from an organizational structure that dilutes responsibility and accountability while also being vulnerable to inaction. The two most important types of FSOC powers-designation of a nonbank financial company as systemically important, and therefore subject to prudential regulation by the Federal Reserve Board, and actions to mitigate systemic risk-both require a two-thirds majority vote (as well as the affirmative vote of its chairperson, the Secretary of the Treasury, in the first instance).
  • 227
    • 79956087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 113, 124 Stat. 1376 to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5323). This structure means that the FSOC will act as a consensus body (seven of ten votes will be needed if all members are present), but it also means that a minority of regulators or the Treasury Secretary alone can block actions, and sets the stage for vote trading
    • See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 113, 124 Stat. 1376, 1398 (2010) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5323). This structure means that the FSOC will act as a consensus body (seven of ten votes will be needed if all members are present), but it also means that a minority of regulators or the Treasury Secretary alone can block actions, and sets the stage for vote trading.
    • (2010) Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act , pp. 1398
    • Wall, D.-F.1
  • 228
    • 79956117494 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is systemic risk council "set up for failure"?
    • Aug. 2
    • See Cheyenne Hopkins & Donna Borak, Is Systemic Risk Council "Set Up For Failure"?, AM. BANKER, Aug. 2, 2010, at 1.
    • (2010) Am. Banker , pp. 1
    • Hopkins, C.1    Borak, D.2
  • 229
    • 79956087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 111-203, Titles I-II, 124 Stat., 1376-520
    • See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, Titles I-II, 124 Stat. 1376, 1376-520 (2010).
    • (2010) Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act , pp. 1376
    • Wall, D.-F.1
  • 232
    • 79956087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. §§ 151-156 (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. §§ 5341-5342, 1833b, 5 U.S.C. §§ 3132, 5314, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5343-5344, 5346)
    • See id. §§ 151-156 (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. §§ 5341-5342, 1833b, 5 U.S.C. §§ 3132, 5314, 12 U.S.C. §§ 5343-5344, 5346).
    • (2010) Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act , pp. 5314
    • Wall, D.-F.1
  • 234
    • 79956087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. §§ 112(a)(1)(B), 115, 124 Stat. 1376, 1395, 1403 (2010) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. §§ 5322, 5325)
    • See id. §§ 112(a)(1)(B), 115, 124 Stat. 1376, 1395, 1403 (2010) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. §§ 5322, 5325).
    • (2010) Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act , pp. 5314
    • Wall, D.-F.1
  • 236
    • 79956111326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 12 U.S.C. §§ 1844-1850
    • 12 U.S.C. §§ 1844-1850 (2006).
    • (2006)
  • 237
    • 79956128370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a nonbank financial company to be covered, two-thirds of the FSOC, including the Treasury Secretary, must concur with a determination that "material financial distress" to the firm or "the nature, scope, size, scale, concentration, interconnectedness, or mix of the activities of the U.S. nonbank financial company, could pose a threat to the financial stability of the United States." See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 113(a)(1), 124 Stat. 1376, 1410 (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5331).
    • For a nonbank financial company to be covered, two-thirds of the FSOC, including the Treasury Secretary, must concur with a determination that "material financial distress" to the firm or "the nature, scope, size, scale, concentration, interconnectedness, or mix of the activities of the U.S. nonbank financial company, could pose a threat to the financial stability of the United States." See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 113(a)(1), 124 Stat. 1376, 1410 (2010) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5331).
    • (2010)
  • 238
    • 79956087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pub. L. No. 111-203, §§ 165(b)(1)(A), (d)(6), 124 Stat. 1376, 1423 (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5365) (nonbinding resolution plan).
    • See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, §§ 165(b)(1)(A), (d)(6), 124 Stat. 1376, 1423 (2010) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5365) (nonbinding resolution plan).
    • (2010) Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act
    • Wall, D.-F.1
  • 243
    • 79956067785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dodd-Frank also imposes concentration limits on financial firms. See id. § 622 (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1852) (imposing 10% concentration limit).
    • Dodd-Frank also imposes concentration limits on financial firms. See id. § 622 (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1852) (imposing 10% concentration limit).
  • 245
    • 79956087946 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 165(b)(1)(A), (D)(6) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1851) (nonbinding resolution plan).
    • See id. § 165(b)(1)(A), (D)(6) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1851) (nonbinding resolution plan).
    • (2010) Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act
    • Wall, D.-F.1
  • 250
    • 84960577846 scopus 로고
    • The allocation of credit and financial collapse
    • 469 ("Historical examinations of financial markets . . . emphasize their propensity for instability and collapse.")
    • See N. Gregory Mankiw, The Allocation of Credit and Financial Collapse, 101 Q. J. ECON. 455, 469 (1986) ("Historical examinations of financial markets . . . emphasize their propensity for instability and collapse.").
    • (1986) Q. J. Econ. , vol.101 , pp. 455
    • Mankiw, N.G.1
  • 251
    • 0000981546 scopus 로고
    • The uneasy case for corporate reorganization
    • See generally Douglas G. Baird, The Uneasy Case for Corporate Reorganization, 15 J. LEG. STUDIES 127 (1986);
    • (1986) J. Leg. Studies , vol.15 , pp. 127
    • Baird, D.G.1
  • 252
    • 0039081268 scopus 로고
    • Bankruptcy, non-bankruptcy entitlement, and the creditors' bargain
    • Thomas H. Jackson, Bankruptcy, Non-bankruptcy Entitlement, and the Creditors' Bargain, 91 YALE L.J. 857 (1982).
    • (1982) Yale L.J. , vol.91 , pp. 857
    • Jackson, T.H.1
  • 253
    • 79956107313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • See Gelpern, supra note 15, at 1051.
    • Gelpern1
  • 254
  • 255
    • 79956095914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 1067-68.
    • Gelpern1
  • 256
    • 0001114148 scopus 로고
    • Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the great depression
    • 263
    • See Ben S. Bernanke, Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression, 73 AM. ECON. REV. 257, 263 (1983).
    • (1983) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 257
    • Bernanke, B.S.1
  • 258
    • 79956081789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • , supra note 15, at
    • Gelpern, supra note 15, at 1076-78.
    • Gelpern1
  • 259
    • 79956139697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider for example, the failure of AIG. When it became clear that AIG was unable to pay all of its obligations as they came due, creditors faced losses under the relevant default resolution systems (state insurance company resolution or bankruptcy depending on the entity within the AIG structure). Under the applicable default regime, some of the losses would have been allocated to Goldman Sachs and to Société Générale, among many others. AIG needed to post $4.1 billion in CDS collateral to Société Générale and $2.5 billion to Goldman Sachs, as well as make CDS payments of $6.9 billion and $5.6 billion, respectively. See AIG, Attachment A-Collateral Postings Under AIGFP CDS and Attachment B-Maiden Lane III Payments to AIGFP CDS Counterparties (2010), http://www.aig.com/ aigweb/internet/en/files/CounterpartyAttachments031809- tcm385-155645.pdf. If AIG had not been bailed out and losses had been imposed on Goldman and Générale, it could have set off another round of crises. This new round would not have been because of AIG, but because of the uncertainty as to Goldman and Générale's soundness; the market would have had to gauge whether Goldman and Générale could absorb the losses from AIG without themselves defaulting, and, if Goldman or Générale were to default, who would end up bearing the losses. Alternatively, if the method for resolution of AIG were not clear, it is uncertain how the losses at AIG would be allocated. In such a situation, not just Goldman or Générale, but also many other firms that dealt with or were suspected of dealing with AIG, would be anathema to the market, and this, in turn, could have second-order effects on their trading partners. The first situation is uncertainty from certainty, the later is uncertainty from uncertainty or panic. The first situation can ultimately be tamed but not the latter. Resolution systems enable the movement from the second situation to the first.
    • (2010)
  • 260
    • 79956136231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 U.S.C. §§ 701-06, 721-27, 741-53, 761-63, 765-67, 781-82, 784 (2006 & Supp. I), 11 U.S.C.A. §§ 707, 764, 783 (West 2004 & Supp. 2010). The Securities Investor Protection Corporation (SIPC) has a right of intervention in stockbroker liquidations under Chapter 7. § 742
    • 11 U.S.C. §§ 701-06, 721-27, 741-53, 761-63, 765-67, 781-82, 784 (2006 & Supp. I 2007), 11 U.S.C.A. §§ 707, 764, 783 (West 2004 & Supp. 2010). The Securities Investor Protection Corporation (SIPC) has a right of intervention in stockbroker liquidations under Chapter 7. § 742.
    • (2007)
  • 261
    • 77950515558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When a securities brokerage goes broke
    • See generally Daniel J. Morse, When a Securities Brokerage Goes Broke, 25 AM. BANKR. INST. J. 34 (2006).
    • (2006) Am. Bankr. Inst. J. , vol.25 , pp. 34
    • Morse, D.J.1
  • 262
    • 79956061130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • §§ 1101-16, 1121-29, 1141-46, 1161-74 (2006 & Supp. I). Small firms are sometimes also eligible for Chapter 13 bankruptcy or for state law assignments for the benefit of creditors or compositions.
    • §§ 1101-16, 1121-29, 1141-46, 1161-74 (2006 & Supp. I 2007). Small firms are sometimes also eligible for Chapter 13 bankruptcy or for state law assignments for the benefit of creditors or compositions.
    • (2007)
  • 263
    • 79956063768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 12 U.S.C. §§ 1811-12, 1814-16, 1819, 1820A, 1821A, 1825-27, 1828A-31n, 1831 p-1-31t, 1831v-33c, 1833f-35A (2006, Supp. I 2007 & Supp. II 2008); 12 U.S.C.A. §§ 1813, 1817-18, 1820, 1821, 1822-24, 1828, 1831o, 1831u, 1833e (West 2004 & Supp.
    • 12 U.S.C. §§ 1811-12, 1814-16, 1819, 1820A, 1821A, 1825-27, 1828A-31n, 1831 p-1-31t, 1831v-33c, 1833f-35A (2006, Supp. I 2007 & Supp. II 2008); 12 U.S.C.A. §§ 1813, 1817-18, 1820, 1821, 1822-24, 1828, 1831o, 1831u, 1833e (West 2004 & Supp. 2010).
    • (2010)
  • 264
    • 79956082929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 4617
    • § 4617.
  • 265
    • 79956112405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Because the priority system is preset, however, voluntary creditors have some ability to account for bankruptcy risk through their transaction terms
    • Because the priority system is preset, however, voluntary creditors have some ability to account for bankruptcy risk through their transaction terms.
  • 266
    • 79956106220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are occasional 100-cent bankruptcy cases, but they are by far the exception, and often the payment in full to creditors is due to changed circumstances (such as a leap in commodity prices). Even in 100-cent cases, however, creditors are not paid on time
    • There are occasional 100-cent bankruptcy cases, but they are by far the exception, and often the payment in full to creditors is due to changed circumstances (such as a leap in commodity prices). Even in 100-cent cases, however, creditors are not paid on time.
  • 267
    • 79956090063 scopus 로고
    • Additionally, a firm can be resolved through private ordering not involving government funds, including using state assignment for the benefit of creditor (ABC) laws. The leading example of this is the resolution of Long-Term Capital Management in 1998, which was a federally orchestrated, but entirely private, resolution. See LOWENSTEIN, supra note 99. The bailout of Chrysler in 1979 also has some aspects of a private ordering. Although the government authorized loan guarantees, they did not kick in until a private ordering of creditors was achieved. See Chrysler Corporation Loan Guarantee Act of 1979, Pub. L. 96-185 (decodified). On a different level, securitization using bankruptcyremote entities creates its own self-executing resolution scheme with senior-subordinate structures and (almost) no noncontractual creditors
    • Additionally, a firm can be resolved through private ordering not involving government funds, including using state assignment for the benefit of creditor (ABC) laws. The leading example of this is the resolution of Long-Term Capital Management in 1998, which was a federally orchestrated, but entirely private, resolution. See LOWENSTEIN, supra note 99. The bailout of Chrysler in 1979 also has some aspects of a private ordering. Although the government authorized loan guarantees, they did not kick in until a private ordering of creditors was achieved. See Chrysler Corporation Loan Guarantee Act of 1979, Pub. L. 96-185 (1979) (decodified). On a different level, securitization using bankruptcyremote entities creates its own self-executing resolution scheme with senior-subordinate structures and (almost) no noncontractual creditors.
    • (1979)
  • 268
    • 79956061132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 69, at
    • See Gelpern & Levitin, supra note 69, at 1121-24.
    • Gelpern1    Levitin2
  • 269
    • 79956107314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at (identifying common patterns of crisis response)
    • See Gelpern, supra note 15, at 1056 (identifying common patterns of crisis response).
    • Gelpern1
  • 270
    • 79956090582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 U.S.C. §§ 507, 725-726, 1129
    • 11 U.S.C. §§ 507, 725-726, 1129 (2006).
    • (2006)
  • 271
    • 79956065251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 507
    • § 507.
  • 272
    • 79956129436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 12 U.S.C. §§ 1815(e)(2)(C), 1821(d)(11)
    • 12 U.S.C. §§ 1815(e)(2)(C), 1821(d)(11) (2006).
    • (2006)
  • 273
    • 79956152579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 69, at (discussing bankruptcy as transparent political distribution in contrast to the private ordering of securitization)
    • Gelpern & Levitin, supra note 69, at 1121-24 (discussing bankruptcy as transparent political distribution in contrast to the private ordering of securitization).
    • Gelpern1    Levitin2
  • 274
    • 84923737163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • explaining the concept of a veil of ignorance
    • See JOHN RAWLS, A THEORY OF JUSTICE 118-23 (1999) (explaining the concept of a veil of ignorance).
    • (1999) A Theory Of Justice 118-23
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 275
    • 79956115508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is in no way to minimize the influence of interest groups in the routine creation of public policy
    • This is in no way to minimize the influence of interest groups in the routine creation of public policy.
  • 276
    • 79956095422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The case for an orderly resolution regime for systemically-important financial institutions
    • Oct. 21
    • See generally Rodgin Cohen & Morris Goldstein, The Case for an Orderly Resolution Regime for Systemically-Important Financial Institutions, THE PEW ECONOMIC POLICY GROUP: PROJECT REPORTS (Oct. 21, 2009), http://www.pewfr.org/admin/project-reports/files/Cohen-Goldstein-FINAL- TFCorrection.pdf;
    • (2009) The Pew Economic Policy Group: Project Reports
    • Cohen, R.1    Goldstein, M.2
  • 277
    • 79956080751 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at ("A systemic risk regulator is needed because a judicially administered process cannot move with sufficient speed and expertise in response to rapidly changing economic conditions.")
    • see also Morrison, supra note 15, at 450 ("A systemic risk regulator is needed because a judicially administered process cannot move with sufficient speed and expertise in response to rapidly changing economic conditions.").
    • Morrison1
  • 278
    • 79956129435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sometimes lesser steps, such as moral suasion to encourage privately ordered resolutions, are attempted first. See supra note 175 and accompanying text
    • Sometimes lesser steps, such as moral suasion to encourage privately ordered resolutions, are attempted first. See supra note 175 and accompanying text.
  • 279
    • 79956073478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Summary of discussion
    • supra note 16, at 179
    • Paul Krugman, Summary of Discussion, in THE RISK OF ECONOMIC CRISIS, supra note 16, at 179, 181.
    • The Risk of Economic Crisis , pp. 181
    • Krugman, P.1
  • 280
    • 79956132774 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15 (arguing that there is a choice between bankruptcy and bailouts)
    • But see Ayotte & Skeel, supra note 15 (arguing that there is a choice between bankruptcy and bailouts).
    • Ayotte1    Skeel2
  • 282
    • 77954939357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Systemic risk & chapter 11
    • 447 (arguing that Chapter 11 can be used to resolve systemically important firms and that "the fear of [C]hapter 11 is largely misguided and too often reflective of outdated notions of [C]hapter 11"); Mark J. Roe, The Derivative Market's Payment Priorities as Financial Crisis Accelerator, 63 STAN. L. REV. (forthcoming Mar. 2011), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1567075 (arguing that derivatives safe harbors from bankruptcy automatic stay should be limited)
    • Stephen J. Lubben, Systemic Risk & Chapter 11, 82 TEMP. L. REV. 433, 447 (2009) (arguing that Chapter 11 can be used to resolve systemically important firms and that "the fear of [C]hapter 11 is largely misguided and too often reflective of outdated notions of [C]hapter 11"); Mark J. Roe, The Derivative Market's Payment Priorities as Financial Crisis Accelerator, 63 STAN. L. REV. (forthcoming Mar. 2011), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1567075 (arguing that derivatives safe harbors from bankruptcy automatic stay should be limited).
    • (2009) Temp. L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 433
    • Lubben, S.J.1
  • 283
    • 79956148118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 U.S.C. § 362(b)(6) (commodity contracts, forward contracts, and securities contracts), (7) (repurchase agreements), (17) (swap agreements), (27) (master netting agreements)
    • 11 U.S.C. § 362(b)(6) (commodity contracts, forward contracts, and securities contracts), (7) (repurchase agreements), (17) (swap agreements), (27) (master netting agreements) (2006).
    • (2006)
  • 284
    • 79956142422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A proposal for chapter 10: Reorganization for "too big to fail" companies
    • Mar. (proposing a new Chapter 10 process for TBTF nonfinancial firms that would generally not affect ordinary course vendors)
    • See, e.g., George W. Kuney & Michael St. James, A Proposal for Chapter 10: Reorganization for "Too Big To Fail" Companies, 28 AM. BANKR. INSTIT. J., Mar. 2009, at 1 (proposing a new Chapter 10 process for TBTF nonfinancial firms that would generally not affect ordinary course vendors).
    • (2009) Am. Bankr. Instit. J. , vol.28 , pp. 1
    • Kuney, G.W.1    James, M.S.2
  • 286
    • 77954890333 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The bankruptcy code without safe harbors
    • suggesting that Bankruptcy Code safe harbors for derivates should be narrowed rather than repealed
    • See, e.g., Stephen J. Lubben, The Bankruptcy Code Without Safe Harbors, 84 AM. BANKR. L.J. 123 (2010) (suggesting that Bankruptcy Code safe harbors for derivates should be narrowed rather than repealed);
    • (2010) Am. Bankr. L.J. , vol.84 , pp. 123
    • Lubben, S.J.1
  • 287
    • 77954890221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Derivatives and bankruptcy: The flawed case for special treatment
    • arguing for the need to distinguish the bankruptcy treatment of derivatives based on whether they are used for speculation and for hedging
    • Stephen J. Lubben, Derivatives and Bankruptcy: The Flawed Case for Special Treatment, 12 U. PA. J. BUS. L. 61 (2009) (arguing for the need to distinguish the bankruptcy treatment of derivatives based on whether they are used for speculation and for hedging).
    • (2009) U. Pa. J. Bus. L. , vol.12 , pp. 61
    • Lubben, S.J.1
  • 288
    • 79956115507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Chrysler is much smaller than GM, many key suppliers of GM are also dependent upon Chrysler business, so if Chrysler were liquidated, GM could have lost suppliers that could not easily be resourced
    • Although Chrysler is much smaller than GM, many key suppliers of GM are also dependent upon Chrysler business, so if Chrysler were liquidated, GM could have lost suppliers that could not easily be resourced.
  • 289
    • 79956093700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, White House Office of the Press Secretary, Fact Sheet: Financing Assistance To Facilitate the Restructuring of Auto Manufacturers To Attain Financial Viability (Dec. 19), available at
    • Press Release, White House Office of the Press Secretary, Fact Sheet: Financing Assistance To Facilitate the Restructuring of Auto Manufacturers To Attain Financial Viability (Dec. 19, 2008), available at http://www.cfr.org/ publication/18070/fact-sheet.html.
    • (2008)
  • 290
    • 79956123735 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, SEPTEMBER OVERSIGHT REPORT: THE USE OF TARP FUNDS IN THE SUPPORT AND REORGANIZATION OF THE DOMESTIC AUTOMOTIVE INDUSTRY 8-9 , available at
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, SEPTEMBER OVERSIGHT REPORT: THE USE OF TARP FUNDS IN THE SUPPORT AND REORGANIZATION OF THE DOMESTIC AUTOMOTIVE INDUSTRY 8-9 (2009), available at http://cop.senate.gov/documents/cop-090909-report.pdf.
    • (2009)
  • 291
    • 77954890221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Derivatives and bankruptcy: The flawed case for special treatment
    • Id. at 14
    • Id. at 14, 20-21.
    • (2009) U. Pa. J. Bus. L. , vol.12 , pp. 20-21
    • Lubben, S.J.1
  • 292
    • 79956138693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11 U.S.C. § 363(b) (providing that the trustee or debtor in possession, "after notice and a hearing, may use, sell, or lease, other than in the ordinary course of business, property of the estate").
    • 11 U.S.C. § 363(b) (2006) (providing that the trustee or debtor in possession, "after notice and a hearing, may use, sell, or lease, other than in the ordinary course of business, property of the estate").
    • (2006)
  • 293
    • 79956117495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, supra note 194, at 19-20.
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, supra note 194, at 14-15, 19-20.
  • 294
    • 77149120441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No big deal: The GM and chrysler cases in context
    • arguing that the GM and Chrysler bankruptcies were not exceptional and that, in the absence of realistic alternative bidders for the companies, the 363 sales must be accepted as maximizing value); cf. BFP v. Resolution Trust Corp., 511 U.S. 531, 545 (1994) (upholding a nonjudicial foreclosure sale as establishing reasonably equivalent value to defeat a fraudulent conveyance action).
    • See Stephen J. Lubben, No Big Deal: The GM and Chrysler Cases in Context, 83 AM. BANKR. L.J. 531 (2009) (arguing that the GM and Chrysler bankruptcies were not exceptional and that, in the absence of realistic alternative bidders for the companies, the 363 sales must be accepted as maximizing value); cf. BFP v. Resolution Trust Corp., 511 U.S. 531, 545 (1994) (upholding a nonjudicial foreclosure sale as establishing reasonably equivalent value to defeat a fraudulent conveyance action).
    • (2009) Am. Bankr. L.J. , vol.83 , pp. 531
    • Lubben, S.J.1
  • 295
    • 79956121346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, supra note 194, at, 31.
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, supra note 194, at 27-28, 31.
  • 296
    • 79956062175 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 198, at
    • See Lubben, supra note 198, at 532;
    • Lubben1
  • 297
    • 77949988576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assessing the chrysler bankruptcy
    • 728
    • Mark J. Roe & David Skeel, Assessing the Chrysler Bankruptcy, 108 MICH. L. REV. 727, 728 (2010);
    • (2010) Mich. L. Rev. , vol.108 , pp. 727
    • Roe, M.J.1    Skeel, D.2
  • 298
    • 79956090581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Colum. Law and Econ. Research Paper No. 365, Dec. 30, available at
    • Edward R. Morrison, Chrysler, GM and the Future of Chapter 11 (Colum. Law and Econ. Research Paper No. 365, Dec. 30, 2009), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract-id=1529734.
    • (2009) Chrysler, GM and the Future of Chapter 11
    • Morrison, E.R.1
  • 299
    • 79956089566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, H.R. 4173, 111th Cong. Preamble
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, H.R. 4173, 111th Cong. Preamble (2010).
    • (2010)
  • 304
    • 79956136232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (requiring liquidation). If a buyer cannot be found, however, the entity cannot be reorganized to maintain its going concern value or guarantee its future provision of services to counterparties and communities
    • (requiring liquidation). If a buyer cannot be found, however, the entity cannot be reorganized to maintain its going concern value or guarantee its future provision of services to counterparties and communities.
  • 308
    • 79956074530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 202(a)(1)(A)
    • Id. § 202(a)(1)(A).
  • 311
    • 79956140686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 210(a)(8)
    • Id. § 210(a)(8).
  • 314
    • 79956090581 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. § 210(a)(11) (avoidance powers), (a)(12) (setoff), (a)(6) (D'Oench Duhme avoidance powers, D'oench, Duhme & Co. v. FDIC, 315 U.S. 447 (1942)), (a)(1)(I) (incorporating general noninsolvency law, which include fraudulent transfer statutes)
    • Id. § 210(a)(11) (avoidance powers), (a)(12) (setoff), (a)(6) (D'Oench Duhme avoidance powers, D'oench, Duhme & Co. v. FDIC, 315 U.S. 447 (1942)), (a)(1)(I) (incorporating general noninsolvency law, which include fraudulent transfer statutes).
    • (2009) Chrysler, GM and the Future of Chapter 11
    • Morrison, E.R.1
  • 323
    • 79956150196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at ("The moral hazard argument is that intervention skews the risk and reward trade-off in the minds of many investors by reducing both the likelihood and the scope of future losses.")
    • KINDLEBERGER & ALIBER, supra note 16, at 204 ("The moral hazard argument is that intervention skews the risk and reward trade-off in the minds of many investors by reducing both the likelihood and the scope of future losses.").
    • Kindleberger1    Aliber2
  • 324
    • 79956075070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • available at (finding statistically significantly lower spreads on TBTF banks' bonds over Treasury bonds relative to other banks' bonds over Treasury bonds);
    • DONALD P. MORGAN & KEVIN J. STIROH, TOO BIG TO FAIL AFTER ALL THESE YEARS tbl. 1 (2005), available at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff- reports/sr220.pdf (finding statistically significantly lower spreads on TBTF banks' bonds over Treasury bonds relative to other banks' bonds over Treasury bonds);
    • (2005) Too Big To Fail After All These Years Tbl. , vol.1
    • Morgan, D.P.1    Stiroh, K.J.2
  • 326
    • 79956158517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • finding GSE to Treasury bond spread was 25-29 basis points less than for AA-rated banking sector bonds
    • J. REAL ESTATE FIN. & ECON. 129, 146 (2002) (finding GSE to Treasury bond spread was 25-29 basis points less than for AA-rated banking sector bonds);
    • (2002) J. Real Estate Fin. & Econ. , vol.129 , pp. 146
  • 327
    • 0141786777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Debt spreads between gses and other corporations
    • Nothaft finding 22-30 basis point funding advantage relative to AA-rated bonds).
    • Frank Nothaft et al., Debt Spreads Between GSEs and Other Corporations, 25 J. REAL ESTATE FIN. & ECON. 151, 167, tbl. 9 (2002) (finding 22-30 basis point funding advantage relative to AA-rated bonds).
    • (2002) J. Real Estate Fin. & Econ. , vol.25 , pp. 151
    • Nothaft, F.1
  • 328
    • 79956124277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at
    • See Summers, supra note 16, at 136.
    • Summers1
  • 329
    • 79956090062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Substantial literature exists on LOLR in the international context, and a smaller one on the domestic context. This Article addresses bailout mechanisms only in the U.S. domestic context, although the principles elucidated generally apply to any domestic bailout. Internationally, the choice between ad hoc and institutionalized bailouts is somewhat different. There is an institutional structure that includes the International Monetary Fund, World Bank, and other international financial institutions, but some individual national governments have also contributed to the bailouts of foreign states
    • Substantial literature exists on LOLR in the international context, and a smaller one on the domestic context. This Article addresses bailout mechanisms only in the U.S. domestic context, although the principles elucidated generally apply to any domestic bailout. Internationally, the choice between ad hoc and institutionalized bailouts is somewhat different. There is an institutional structure that includes the International Monetary Fund, World Bank, and other international financial institutions, but some individual national governments have also contributed to the bailouts of foreign states.
  • 330
    • 79956112908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is also possible to have a private LOLR
    • It is also possible to have a private LOLR.
  • 331
    • 0043245524 scopus 로고
    • The lender of last resort: Alternative views and historical experience
    • Jan.-Feb. , 24.
    • See, e.g., Michael D. Bordo, The Lender of Last Resort: Alternative Views and Historical Experience, ECON. REV. (FED. RES. BANK RICHMOND). Jan.-Feb. 1990, at 18, 24.
    • (1990) Econ. Rev. (Fed. Res. Bank Richmond) , pp. 18
    • Bordo, M.D.1
  • 332
    • 79956156441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Chrysler and Long Term Capital Management bailouts saw private capital act as LOLRs, and historically, private clearinghouses have served a LOLR function, at least for their members, enabling their members to provide liquidity to nonmember firms. It is questionable, however, whether a private LOLR is truly the lender of last resort or whether it is merely the lender of next-to-last resort. If a private bailout fails, the severity of the crisis is likely to be such that government will step in as LOLR
    • The Chrysler and Long Term Capital Management bailouts saw private capital act as LOLRs, and historically, private clearinghouses have served a LOLR function, at least for their members, enabling their members to provide liquidity to nonmember firms. It is questionable, however, whether a private LOLR is truly the lender of last resort or whether it is merely the lender of next-to-last resort. If a private bailout fails, the severity of the crisis is likely to be such that government will step in as LOLR.
  • 333
    • 79956100460 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Op-Ed. The big squander
    • Nov. 20, ("Government officials . . . forgot that if you want to govern effectively you have [to] retain the trust of the people. And by treating the financial industry . . . with kid gloves, they have squandered that trust.")
    • Paul Krugman, Op-Ed. The Big Squander, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 20, 2009, at A35 ("Government officials . . . forgot that if you want to govern effectively you have [to] retain the trust of the people. And by treating the financial industry . . . with kid gloves, they have squandered that trust.").
    • (2009) N.Y. Times
    • Krugman, P.1
  • 334
    • 79956109950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at . Throughout the nineteenth century, there were repeated instances when the Treasury provided liquidity assistance to the banking sector by accepting less sound collateral, by early payment on government debt, or by providing a market for specie
    • KINDLEBERGER & ALIBER, supra note 16, at 231. Throughout the nineteenth century, there were repeated instances when the Treasury provided liquidity assistance to the banking sector by accepting less sound collateral, by early payment on government debt, or by providing a market for specie.
    • Kindleberger1    Aliber2
  • 336
    • 79956158002 scopus 로고
    • The sole exception I have been able to identify is a bailout of New York City in by the United States Treasury
    • The sole exception I have been able to identify is a bailout of New York City in 1914 by the United States Treasury.
    • (1914)
  • 338
    • 79956122470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at
    • KINDLEBERGER & ALIBER, supra note 16, at 232.
    • Kindleberger1    Aliber2
  • 339
    • 79956074005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 231, at
    • See SILBER, supra note 231, at 116-30.
    • Silber1
  • 340
    • 79956148117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at
    • KINDLEBERGER & ALIBER, supra note 16, at 236.
    • Kindleberger1    Aliber2
  • 341
    • 84928448667 scopus 로고
    • Can mexico break the vicious circle of "stop-go" policy?: An institutional overview
    • 605 Treasury has, at times, used other funds for bailout purposes, arguably acting illegally
    • James H. Street, Can Mexico Break the Vicious Circle of "Stop-Go" Policy?: An Institutional Overview, 20 J. ECON. ISSUES 601, 605 (1986). Treasury has, at times, used other funds for bailout purposes, arguably acting illegally.
    • (1986) J. Econ. Issues , vol.20 , pp. 601
    • Street, J.H.1
  • 342
    • 0040370315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note, adventures in the zone of twilight: Separation of powers and national economic security in the mexican bailout
    • 1311-15 arguing that the Clinton administration's use of the Exchange Stabilization Fund in 1995 to bail out Mexico was illegal
    • See Russell Dean Covey, Note, Adventures in the Zone of Twilight: Separation of Powers and National Economic Security in the Mexican Bailout, 105 YALE L.J. 1311, 1311-15 (1996) (arguing that the Clinton administration's use of the Exchange Stabilization Fund in 1995 to bail out Mexico was illegal).
    • (1996) Yale L.J. , vol.105 , pp. 1311
    • Covey, R.D.1
  • 343
    • 77950489429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emergency economic stabilization act of 2008
    • Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343, § 101(a)(1), 122 Stat. 3765, 3767 (2008). The Act defines a financial institution as any institution, including, but not limited to, any bank, savings association, credit union, security broker or dealer, or insurance company, established and regulated under the laws of the United States or any State, territory, or possession of the United States . . . and having significant operations in the United States, but excluding any central bank of, or institution owned by, a foreign government. Id. § 3(5). The Treasury interpreted the TARP's restriction to asset purchases from "financial institutions" liberally to include auto manufacturers GM and Chrysler, and not just their financing arms. CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, supra note 194, at 70-79 (discussing whether the Treasury was acting within the scope of its legal authority when it assisted GM and Chrysler). Similarly, Congress arguably expected that once TARP funds were repaid, they would be retired. The Treasury, however, has indicated that it believes that TARP can be used as a revolving fund with repaid TARP funds being relent rather than being retired.
    • Pub. L. No. , pp. 110-343
  • 344
    • 79956126274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emergency economic stabilization act of 2008
    • See id. at
    • See id. at 170.
    • Pub. L. No. , pp. 170
  • 345
    • 79956127843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The War Finance Corporation (1918-1939), the Emergency Fleet Corporation (1917-1936), and the U.S. Housing Corporation, Federal Home Loan Banks, Fannie Mae (itself an outgrowth of RFC) and various federal farm loan programs have at various times offered targeted support to particular industries, but have never functioned as generic LOLRs
    • The War Finance Corporation (1918-1939), the Emergency Fleet Corporation (1917-1936), and the U.S. Housing Corporation, Federal Home Loan Banks, Fannie Mae (itself an outgrowth of RFC) and various federal farm loan programs have at various times offered targeted support to particular industries, but have never functioned as generic LOLRs.
  • 346
    • 79956113908 scopus 로고
    • Reconstruction finance corporation act
    • 47 Stat. 5
    • Reconstruction Finance Corporation Act, Pub. L. No. 72-2, 47 Stat. 5 (1932).
    • (1932) Pub. L. No. , pp. 72-72
  • 347
    • 79956113908 scopus 로고
    • Reconstruction finance corporation act
    • Id. § 5
    • Id. § 5.
    • (1932) Pub. L. No. , pp. 72-72
  • 348
    • 79956132274 scopus 로고
    • Emergency relief and construction act
    • § 210, 47 Stat. 709
    • Emergency Relief and Construction Act, Pub. L. No. 302, § 210, 47 Stat. 709, 715 (1932).
    • (1932) Pub. L. No. , vol.302 , pp. 715
  • 349
    • 79956068313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two studies of the political economy of the RFC have adduced little evidence of congressional influence over its activities
    • Two studies of the political economy of the RFC have adduced little evidence of congressional influence over its activities.
  • 350
    • 0038625441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political economy of reconstruction finance corporation assistance during the great depression
    • 109 (finding little evidence of congressional influence on RFC assistance between 1932 and 1933)
    • See Joseph R. Mason, The Political Economy of Reconstruction Finance Corporation Assistance During the Great Depression, 40 EXPLORATIONS IN ECON. HIST. 101, 109 (2003) (finding little evidence of congressional influence on RFC assistance between 1932 and 1933);
    • (2003) Explorations In Econ. Hist. , vol.40 , pp. 101
    • Mason, J.R.1
  • 351
    • 79956076606 scopus 로고
    • (Apr.) (unpublished working paper) (on file with author) (finding no evidence of direct political influence from Congress on RFC assistance between 1933 and 1935, but suggesting possible executive branch and Senate Banking Committee influence). This is not surprising;
    • Randall S. Kroszner, The Political-Economy of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation's Bail-out of the U.S. Banking System During the Great Depression, (Apr. 1994) (unpublished working paper) (on file with author) (finding no evidence of direct political influence from Congress on RFC assistance between 1933 and 1935, but suggesting possible executive branch and Senate Banking Committee influence). This is not surprising;
    • (1994) The Political-Economy of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation's Bail-out of the U.S. Banking System During the Great Depression
    • Kroszner, R.S.1
  • 352
    • 79956137300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The primary influence on RFC activities would presumably be the executive branch. Neither study claims that the RFC was in any way immune from executive branch political considerations. To the contrary, it was very much a tool of Roosevelt administration policy
    • The primary influence on RFC activities would presumably be the executive branch. Neither study claims that the RFC was in any way immune from executive branch political considerations. To the contrary, it was very much a tool of Roosevelt administration policy.
  • 353
    • 79956066818 scopus 로고
    • Federal reserve act
    • 63-43, § 13, 38 Stat. 251
    • Federal Reserve Act, Pub. L. No. 63-43, § 13, 38 Stat. 251, 263 (1913).
    • (1913) Pub. L. No , pp. 263
  • 354
    • 79956078764 scopus 로고
    • The industrial advance program of the federal reserve system
    • 230
    • James C. Dolley, The Industrial Advance Program of the Federal Reserve System, 50 Q.J. ECON. 229, 230 (1936).
    • (1936) Q.J. Econ. , vol.50 , pp. 229
    • Dolley, J.C.1
  • 355
    • 79956105709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In addition to the ability to rediscount, the Fed had other emergency lending powers. First, the Federal Reserve Board was permitted to suspend the gold reserve requirement of reserve banks. This removed an important limitation on reserve bank lending to member banks
    • In addition to the ability to rediscount, the Fed had other emergency lending powers. First, the Federal Reserve Board was permitted to suspend the gold reserve requirement of reserve banks. This removed an important limitation on reserve bank lending to member banks.
  • 356
    • 79956078764 scopus 로고
    • The industrial advance program of the federal reserve system
    • Id. at Second, during 1930-1931, the Board was permitted to suspend the single-borrower lending limitation of 20% when the collateral posted were government securities
    • Id. at 231-32. Second, during 1930-1931, the Board was permitted to suspend the single-borrower lending limitation of 20% when the collateral posted were government securities.
    • (1936) Q.J. Econ. , vol.50 , pp. 231-232
    • Dolley, J.C.1
  • 357
    • 79956078764 scopus 로고
    • The industrial advance program of the federal reserve system
    • Id. at
    • Id. at 232.
    • (1936) Q.J. Econ. , vol.50 , pp. 232
    • Dolley, J.C.1
  • 358
    • 79956128925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This expansion of discounting authority occurred as part of legislation that authorized the Reconstruction Finance Corporation, which was previously authorized only to lend to financial firms, to make industrial loans.
    • Emergency Relief and Construction Act, § 210. This expansion of discounting authority occurred as part of legislation that authorized the Reconstruction Finance Corporation, which was previously authorized only to lend to financial firms, to make industrial loans.
    • Emergency Relief and Construction Act , pp. 210
  • 359
    • 79956128925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. The original draft bills envisioned the Fed as playing this industrial lending role, with the RFC as backup lender, but the final legislation reversed the roles, making the RFC the primary lender and authorizing the Fed to make loans only when no other source of credit could be found. David Fettig, Fed. Res. Bank of Minneapolis, Lender of More Than Last Resort: Recalling Section 13(b) and the Years When the Federal Reserve Opened Its Discount Window to Business, REGION: BANKING & POL'Y ISSUESMAG., Dec. 2002, at 14, 44, available at. The reason for the shift is not clear.
    • Id. The original draft bills envisioned the Fed as playing this industrial lending role, with the RFC as backup lender, but the final legislation reversed the roles, making the RFC the primary lender and authorizing the Fed to make loans only when no other source of credit could be found. David Fettig, Fed. Res. Bank of Minneapolis, Lender of More Than Last Resort: Recalling Section 13(b) and the Years When the Federal Reserve Opened Its Discount Window to Business, REGION: BANKING & POL'Y ISSUESMAG., Dec. 2002, at 14, 44, available at http://www.minneapolisfed.org/pubs/region/02-12/ lender.pdf. The reason for the shift is not clear.
    • Emergency Relief and Construction Act , pp. 210
  • 360
    • 79956086412 scopus 로고
    • Industrial advances act of june 19
    • Stat. 1105. In 1933, the Fed's lending authority was further expanded to allow the Fed to make ninety-day advances to nonbanks if secured by direct obligations of the United States government
    • Industrial Advances Act of June 19, 1934, Pub. L. No. 73-417, 48 Stat. 1105. In 1933, the Fed's lending authority was further expanded to allow the Fed to make ninety-day advances to nonbanks if secured by direct obligations of the United States government.
    • (1934) Pub. L. No. 73-417 , vol.48
  • 361
    • 79956138192 scopus 로고
    • See Emergency Banking Relief Act of March 9 Stat. 1
    • See Emergency Banking Relief Act of March 9, 1933, Pub. L. No. 73-1, 48 Stat. 1 (1933).
    • (1933) Pub. L. No. 73-1 , vol.48
  • 362
    • 79956118038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Small business investment act of 1958
    • Small Business Investment Act of 1958, Pub. L. No. 85-699, 72 Stat. 689.
    • Pub. L. No. 85-699 , vol.72 , pp. 689
  • 363
    • 3342943381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal deposit insurance corporation improvement act of 1991
    • § 473, 105 Stat. 2236, 2386. The removal of the "merely investments" language proved crucial, as it would have greatly impeded the Fed's efforts to support investment banks
    • Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991, Pub. L. No. 102-242, § 473, 105 Stat. 2236, 2386. The removal of the "merely investments" language proved crucial, as it would have greatly impeded the Fed's efforts to support investment banks in 2008.
    • (2008) Pub. L. No. , pp. 102-242
  • 364
    • 79956077136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36, at . Section 13(3) now reads that "[i]n unusual and exigent circumstances" the Fed may "discount for any individual, partnership, or corporation, notes, drafts, and bills of exchange that are indorsed or otherwise secured to the satisfaction of the Federal Reserve bank: Provided, That before discounting any such note, draft, or bill of exchange for an individual, partnership, or corporation the Federal reserve bank shall obtain evidence that such individual, partnership, or corporation is unable to secure adequate credit accommodations from other banking institutions
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 161. Section 13(3) now reads that "[i]n unusual and exigent circumstances" the Fed may "discount for any individual, partnership, or corporation, notes, drafts, and bills of exchange that are indorsed or otherwise secured to the satisfaction of the Federal Reserve bank: Provided, That before discounting any such note, draft, or bill of exchange for an individual, partnership, or corporation the Federal reserve bank shall obtain evidence that such individual, partnership, or corporation is unable to secure adequate credit accommodations from other banking institutions."
    • Wessel1
  • 365
  • 366
    • 79956125745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Factors affecting efforts to limit payments to aig counterparties: Hearing before the H. comm. On gov't oversight & reform
    • statement of Thomas C. Baxter, Jr., Executive Vice President and General Counsel, Federal Reserve Bank of New York) (noting that the Fed does not have legal authority to guarantee obligations).
    • See Factors Affecting Efforts To Limit Payments to AIG Counterparties: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Gov't Oversight & Reform, 111th Cong. 8 (2010) (statement of Thomas C. Baxter, Jr., Executive Vice President and General Counsel, Federal Reserve Bank of New York) (noting that the Fed does not have legal authority to guarantee obligations).
    • (2010) 111th Cong. , vol.8
  • 367
    • 79956146822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal deposit insurance corporation improvement act of 1991
    • § 473, 105 Stat.
    • Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991, Pub. L. No. 102-242, § 473, 105 Stat. 2386.
    • Pub. L. No. 102-242 , pp. 2386
  • 368
    • 79956160311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 245, at
    • Fettig, supra note 245, at 18.
    • Fettig1
  • 369
  • 370
  • 371
    • 79956078207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36, at
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 160.
    • Wessel1
  • 372
    • 77952271734 scopus 로고
    • A new paradigm for financial regulation: Getting from here to there
    • 427
    • Stephen J. Friedman & Connie M. Friesen, A New Paradigm for Financial Regulation: Getting from Here to There, 3 MD. L. REV. 413, 427 n.99 (1984);
    • (1984) Md. L. Rev. , vol.3 , Issue.99 , pp. 413
    • Friedman, S.J.1    Friesen, C.M.2
  • 373
    • 0345792362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Faith and magic: Investor beliefs and government neutrality
    • Henry T.C. Hu, Faith and Magic: Investor Beliefs and Government Neutrality, 78 TEX. L. REV. 777, 874 (2000);
    • (2000) TEX. L. REV. 777 , vol.78 , pp. 874
    • Hu, H.T.C.1
  • 374
    • 84945383745 scopus 로고
    • Factoring accounts receivable in france: some legal aspects and american comparisons
    • Sidney Posel, Factoring Accounts Receivable in France: Some Legal Aspects and American Comparisons, 57 TUL. L. REV. 292, 298 n.17 (1982);
    • (1982) Tul. L. Rev. 292 , vol.57 , Issue.17 , pp. 298
    • Posel, S.1
  • 375
    • 0036035532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The transformation of the U.S. Financial services industry, 1975-2000: Competition, consolidation, and increased risks
    • Arthur E. Wilmarth, Jr., The Transformation of the U.S. Financial Services Industry, 1975-2000: Competition, Consolidation, and Increased Risks, 2002 U. ILL. L. REV. 215, 304.
    • (2002) U. Ill. L. Rev. , vol.215 , pp. 304
    • Wilmarth Jr., A.E.1
  • 376
    • 79956083998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 254, at
    • Wilmarth, supra note 254, at 303-10.
    • Wilmarth1
  • 377
    • 79956098301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FED. RESERVE BD., PERIODIC REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 129(B) OF THE EMERGENCY ECONOMIC STABILIZATION ACT OF 2008: UPDATE ON OUTSTANDING LENDING FACILITIES AUTHORIZED BY THE BOARD UNDER SECTION 13(3) OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT: December 29, PERIODIC REPORT, at 2-3 [hereinafter FRB], available at Notably, the invocation of section 13(3) was not announced when the TSLF was unveiled
    • FED. RESERVE BD., PERIODIC REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 129(B) OF THE EMERGENCY ECONOMIC STABILIZATION ACT OF 2008: UPDATE ON OUTSTANDING LENDING FACILITIES AUTHORIZED BY THE BOARD UNDER SECTION 13(3) OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT: December 29, 2008, PERIODIC REPORT, at 2-3 [hereinafter FRB], available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/129periodic update08252009.pdf. Notably, the invocation of section 13(3) was not announced when the TSLF was unveiled.
    • (2008)
  • 378
    • 79956128372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36, at
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 161-62.
    • Wessel1
  • 379
    • 79956075604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Minutes of the board of governors of the federal reserve system
    • Mar. 14 (authorizing extension of nonrecourse credit to JPMorgan Chase Bank to provide financing to Bear Stearns under section 13(3) powers). Ultimately, the deal involved the Fed making a bridge loan to Bear Stearns directly, as well as making a senior secured nonrecourse loan to a new company, Maiden Lane LLC, a special purpose vehicle (SPV) formed (and owned) by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
    • Minutes of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD: NEWS & EVENTS (Mar. 14, 2008), http://www.federalreserve.gov/ newsevents/press/other/other 20080627a1.pdf (authorizing extension of nonrecourse credit to JPMorgan Chase Bank to provide financing to Bear Stearns under section 13(3) powers). Ultimately, the deal involved the Fed making a bridge loan to Bear Stearns directly, as well as making a senior secured nonrecourse loan to a new company, Maiden Lane LLC, a special purpose vehicle (SPV) formed (and owned) by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
    • (2008) Federal Reserve Board: News & Events
  • 380
    • 79956158001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256. The shift in transaction structure from the originally authorized direct loan to JPMorgan Chase to a loan to an SPV reflected concern that the deal would be seen as the Fed purchasing Bear Stearn's securities outright, which section 13(3) did not authorize. Therefore, the Fed took a page from the structured finance transactions that marked the housing bubble and loaned on a nonrecourse basis to an SPV that held the securities and pledged them as collateral
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256. The shift in transaction structure from the originally authorized direct loan to JPMorgan Chase to a loan to an SPV reflected concern that the deal would be seen as the Fed purchasing Bear Stearn's securities outright, which section 13(3) did not authorize. Therefore, the Fed took a page from the structured finance transactions that marked the housing bubble and loaned on a nonrecourse basis to an SPV that held the securities and pledged them as collateral.
  • 381
    • 79956105190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wessel, supra note 36, at Maiden Lane LLC acquired $28.8 billion of the less liquid assets of Bear Stearns in order to facilitate JPMorgan Chase's purchase of Bear Stearns
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 168-69. Maiden Lane LLC acquired $28.8 billion of the less liquid assets of Bear Stearns in order to facilitate JPMorgan Chase's purchase of Bear Stearns.
  • 382
    • 79956072027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at 3-4.
  • 384
    • 79956067788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Primary Dealer Credit Facility, created March 17, permits the Federal Reserve to enter into repurchase (repo) agreements) with the investment banks that serve as the primary dealers for U.S. government securities. Primary Dealer Credit Facility, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD: MONETARY POLICY, (last visited Aug. 22, 2010). Under the repo agreements, the investment banks sell the Fed securities, and the Fed agrees to sell them back later, but at a markup. Economically, the transaction is equivalent to a secured loan made by the Fed to the investment banks, with the markup being the interest and the securities serving as collateral. The Fed thus served as the repo investor of last resort
    • The Primary Dealer Credit Facility, created March 17, 2008, permits the Federal Reserve to enter into repurchase (repo) agreements) with the investment banks that serve as the primary dealers for U.S. government securities. Primary Dealer Credit Facility, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD: MONETARY POLICY, http://www.federalreserve.gov/ monetarypolicy/pdcf.htm (last visited Aug. 22, 2010). Under the repo agreements, the investment banks sell the Fed securities, and the Fed agrees to sell them back later, but at a markup. Economically, the transaction is equivalent to a secured loan made by the Fed to the investment banks, with the markup being the interest and the securities serving as collateral. The Fed thus served as the repo investor of last resort.
    • (2008)
  • 385
    • 79956076605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 36, at. The facility was terminated February 1
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 170-71. The facility was terminated February 1, 2010.
    • (2010) , pp. 170-171
    • Wessel1
  • 386
    • 79956097504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Credit and liquidity programs and the balance sheet: Lending to primary dealers
    • last visited Oct. 13
    • See Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet: Lending to Primary Dealers, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD: MONETARY POLICY, www.federalreserve.gov/ monetarypolicy/bst-lendingprimary.htm (last visited Oct. 13, 2010).
    • (2010) Federal Reserve Board: Monetary Policy
  • 387
    • 79956083483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at Unlike the Fed's 13(3) authority, which is theoretically limitless in dollar amounts given the Fed's ability to print currency, Treasury's TARP authority is limited to the $800 billion appropriated by Congress; nevertheless, Treasury has indicated that it believes repaid TARP funds can be relented rather than be retired
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at 5. Unlike the Fed's 13(3) authority, which is theoretically limitless in dollar amounts given the Fed's ability to print currency, Treasury's TARP authority is limited to the $800 billion appropriated by Congress; nevertheless, Treasury has indicated that it believes repaid TARP funds can be relented rather than be retired.
  • 389
    • 79956140222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at. The CPFF created an LLC authorized to purchase commercial paper (unsecured and asset-backed) directly from commercial paper issuers
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at 6. The CPFF created an LLC authorized to purchase commercial paper (unsecured and asset-backed) directly from commercial paper issuers.
  • 390
    • 79956102541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • last visited Oct. 13
    • The MMIFF authorized senior secured funding to a series of LLCs established with private sector capital to enable the purchase from money market mutual funds of short-term CDs and commercial paper issued by highly rated financial institutions. The program enhanced money market liquidity, enabling money markets to honor redemption requests without selling assets at fire-sale prices. Credit and Liquidity Programs and the Balance Sheet: Other Lending Facilities, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD: MONETARY POLICY, http://www.federalreserve. gov/monetarypolicy/bst-lendingother. htm (last visited Oct. 13, 2010).
    • (2010) Federal Reserve Board: Monetary Policy
  • 391
    • 79956098300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The TALF issued nonrecourse loans against asset-backed securities
    • The TALF issued nonrecourse loans against asset-backed securities.
  • 393
    • 79956150476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at (detailing support to AIG). Support for AIG included: an $85 billion line of credit from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY); the purchase by Maiden Lane II, LLC, a special purpose subsidiary of the FRBNY, of MBS from AIG insurance subsidiaries to provide liquidity to their investment securities lending programs
    • FRB, PERIODIC REPORT, supra note 256, at 7-10 (detailing support to AIG). Support for AIG included: an $85 billion line of credit from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY);
  • 394
    • 79956126800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The purchase by Maiden Lane II, LLC, a special purpose subsidiary of the FRBNY, of MBS from AIG insurance subsidiaries to provide liquidity to their investment securities lending programs; and the purchase at market value of $62.1 billion by Maiden Lane III, LLC, another special purpose subsidiary of the FRBNY, of various CDOs on which AIG had underwritten CDS protection, in exchange for termination of the CDS by the CDO sellers, which were permitted to keep the collateral AIG had posted to date
    • The purchase by Maiden Lane II, LLC, a special purpose subsidiary of the FRBNY, of MBS from AIG insurance subsidiaries to provide liquidity to their investment securities lending programs; and the purchase at market value of $62.1 billion by Maiden Lane III, LLC, another special purpose subsidiary of the FRBNY, of various CDOs on which AIG had underwritten CDS protection, in exchange for termination of the CDS by the CDO sellers, which were permitted to keep the collateral AIG had posted to date.
  • 395
    • 79956080193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wessel, supra note 36, at
    • WESSEL, supra note 36, at 170-71.
  • 396
    • 79956153062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act amends section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act to clarify that the Fed's section 13(3) power may only be used to provide broad-based liquidity support programs for the market, rather than support for individual firms, and that section 13(3) may not be used to support insolvent firms. Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 1101, 124 Stat. 1376, 2114
    • The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act amends section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act to clarify that the Fed's section 13(3) power may only be used to provide broad-based liquidity support programs for the market, rather than support for individual firms, and that section 13(3) may not be used to support insolvent firms. Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 1101, 124 Stat. 1376, 2114 (2010).
    • (2010)
  • 397
    • 79956159731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • My thinking on the liquidity-solvency divide has been greatly influenced by Professor Anna Gelpern and her blog posts on "illinquency."
    • My thinking on the liquidity-solvency divide has been greatly influenced by Professor Anna Gelpern and her blog posts on "illinquency."
  • 398
    • 79956062172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another thing: Illiquency
    • Oct. 14
    • See, e.g., Anna Gelpern, . . . and Another Thing: Illiquency, THE CONGLOMERATE (Oct. 14, 2008), http://www.theconglomerate.org/2008/10/anna- gelpern-an.html;
    • (2008) The Conglomerate
    • Gelpern, A.1
  • 399
    • 79956094253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • T.A.R.P. R.I.P.: Illiquency watch
    • (Nov. 14, 12:31 AM)
    • Anna Gelpern, T.A.R.P. R.I.P.: Illiquency Watch, CREDIT SLIPS (Nov. 14, 2008, 12:31 AM), http://www.creditslips. org/creditslips/2008/11/tarp-rip- illiqu.html.
    • (2008) Credit Slips
    • Gelpern, A.1
  • 400
    • 79956094896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note
    • See Covey, supra note 235.
    • Covey1
  • 401
    • 79956094252 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 13
    • See supra note 13.
  • 402
    • 79956155958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 20, at
    • Wallison, supra note 20, at 7.
    • Wallison1
  • 403
    • 79956125348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at 179
    • Summers, supra note 16, at 179, 182.
    • Summers1
  • 404
    • 79956065249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra section I.A.
    • See supra section I.A.
  • 405
    • 79956104081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comparisons between agency and congressional accountability often reference comparative transparency and deliberativeness of the bodies. These analyses are almost always conducted with the assumption of agency action through notice-and-comment rulemaking. Bailout authorization, however, is generally done on an expedited, urgent, or even emergency basis
    • Comparisons between agency and congressional accountability often reference comparative transparency and deliberativeness of the bodies. These analyses are almost always conducted with the assumption of agency action through notice-and-comment rulemaking. Bailout authorization, however, is generally done on an expedited, urgent, or even emergency basis.
  • 406
    • 0347664773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Presidential administration
    • 2331-37
    • See, e.g., Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 114 HARV. L. REV. 2245, 2331-37 (2001);
    • (2001) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.114 , pp. 2245
    • Kagan, E.1
  • 407
    • 34548665380 scopus 로고
    • The president and the administration
    • Lawrence Lessig & Cass R. Sunstein, The President and the Administration, 94 COLUM. L. REV. 1, 102-03 (1994);
    • (1994) Colum. L. Rev. 1 , vol.94 , pp. 102-103
    • Lessig, L.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 408
    • 0010916703 scopus 로고
    • The role of the judiciary in implementing an agency theory of government
    • 1280-85
    • Richard J. Pierce, Jr., The Role of the Judiciary in Implementing an Agency Theory of Government, 64 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1239, 1280-85 (1989).
    • (1989) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 1239
    • Pierce Jr., R.J.1
  • 409
    • 0042028060 scopus 로고
    • Some normative arguments for the unitary executive
    • 58-70
    • Steven G. Calabresi, Some Normative Arguments for the Unitary Executive, 48 ARK. L. REV. 23, 58-70 (1995);
    • (1995) Ark. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 23
    • Calabresi, S.G.1
  • 410
    • 77958405926 scopus 로고
    • Prodelegation: Why administrators should make political decisions
    • 95-96
    • Jerry L. Mashaw, Prodelegation: Why Administrators Should Make Political Decisions, 1 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 81, 95-96 (1985);
    • (1985) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.1 , pp. 81
    • Mashaw, J.L.1
  • 411
    • 84873091177 scopus 로고
    • 467 U.S. 837 ("While agencies are not directly accountable to the people, the Chief Executive is, and it is entirely appropriate for this political branch of government to make such policy choices.")
    • see also Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 865-66 (1984) ("While agencies are not directly accountable to the people, the Chief Executive is, and it is entirely appropriate for this political branch of government to make such policy choices.").
    • (1984) U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc. , pp. 865-866
    • Chevron1
  • 412
    • 68049084094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Administrative law's federalism: Preemption, delegation, and agencies at the edge of federal power
    • 1983 ("Because of legislative inertia, Congress passes statutes infrequently . . . . Agencies, through both congressional and presidential influences, are more apt to be influenced by current political pressures because political influences on agencies are ongoing and flexible.")
    • Brian Galle & Mark Seidenfeld, Administrative Law's Federalism: Preemption, Delegation, and Agencies at the Edge of Federal Power, 57 DUKE L.J. 1933, 1983 (2008) ("Because of legislative inertia, Congress passes statutes infrequently . . . . Agencies, through both congressional and presidential influences, are more apt to be influenced by current political pressures because political influences on agencies are ongoing and flexible.").
    • (2008) Duke L.J. , vol.57 , pp. 1933
    • Galle, B.1    Seidenfeld, M.2
  • 413
    • 79956085067 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 12 U.S.C. § 241 (2006).
    • (2006) U.S.C. , vol.12 , pp. 241
  • 414
    • 1842760927 scopus 로고
    • Political accountability in a system of checks and balances: the case of presidential review of rulemaking
    • 200
    • Peter M. Shane, Political Accountability in a System of Checks and Balances: The Case of Presidential Review of Rulemaking, 48 ARK. L. REV. 161, 200 (1995);
    • (1995) Ark. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 161
    • Shane, P.M.1
  • 415
    • 0003209140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Differences in legislative voting behavior between winning and losing house incumbents
    • (David W. Brady et al. eds.) (claiming that representatives who take more extreme positions than their constituents increase their probability of electoral defeat)
    • see David W. Brady et al., Differences in Legislative Voting Behavior Between Winning and Losing House Incumbents, in CONTINUITY AND CHANGE IN HOUSE ELECTIONS 178, 181-89 (David W. Brady et al. eds., 2000) (claiming that representatives who take more extreme positions than their constituents increase their probability of electoral defeat);
    • (2000) Continuity And Change In House Elections , vol.178 , pp. 181-189
    • Brady, D.W.1
  • 416
    • 0010460819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Representation of constituency ideology in congress
    • (David W. Brady et al. eds.,) (asserting that members of Congress "lose votes-and sometimes elections-if they stray too far ideologically [from their constituents' positions]")
    • Robert S. Erkson & Gerald C. Wright, Representation of Constituency Ideology in Congress, in CONTINUITY AND CHANGE IN HOUSE ELECTIONS 149, 177 (David W. Brady et al. eds., 2000) (asserting that members of Congress "lose votes-and sometimes elections-if they stray too far ideologically [from their constituents' positions]").
    • (2000) Continuity and Change in House Elections , vol.49 , pp. 177
    • Erkson, R.S.1    Wright, G.C.2
  • 417
    • 79956115504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ire at Wall St. Is Now Factor in House Race, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 28, at A1
    • David M. Halbfinger, Ire at Wall St. Is Now Factor in House Race, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 28, 2009, at A1; Raymond Hernandez & Thomas Kaplan, Connecticut Senator Draws Voters' Ire for Payout Role, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 20, 2009, at A1; Adam Nagourney, Dodd Is Said To Decide Against Re-election Bid, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 6, 2010, at A1.
    • (2009)
    • Halbfinger, D.M.1
  • 418
    • 79956144670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 275, at
    • Galle & Seidenfeld, supra note 275, at 1979-80.
    • Galle1    Seidenfeld2
  • 419
    • 79956116007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Money, power, and politics: Governance models and campaign finance regulation
    • 46-47
    • See, e.g., Ronald A. Cass, Money, Power, and Politics: Governance Models and Campaign Finance Regulation, 6 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 1, 46-47 (1998);
    • (1998) Sup. Ct. Econ. Rev. , vol.6 , pp. 1
    • Cass, R.A.1
  • 420
    • 0009209420 scopus 로고
    • Term limits
    • 479-80
    • Linda Cohen & Matthew Spitzer, Term Limits, 80 GEO. L.J. 477, 479-80 (1992);
    • (1992) Geo. L.J. , vol.80 , pp. 477
    • Cohen, L.1    Spitzer, M.2
  • 421
    • 0347738685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Are term limits undemocratic?
    • Einer Elhauge, Are Term Limits Undemocratic?, 64 U. CHI. L. REV. 83, 154-55 (1997). (Pubitemid 127445760)
    • (1997) University of Chicago Law Review , vol.64 , Issue.1 , pp. 83
    • Elhauge, E.1
  • 422
    • 79956086410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • See Davidoff & Zaring, supra note 15, at 468.
    • Davidoff1    Zaring2
  • 423
    • 79956074529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Press Release, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (June 27,), available at (announcing the release of the minutes from March 14 and 16, 2008 Board meetings)
    • See Press Release, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (June 27, 2008), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevent/press/others/ 20080627a.htm (announcing the release of the minutes from March 14 and 16, 2008 Board meetings).
    • (2008)
  • 424
    • 79956110815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OFFICE OF THE SPECIAL INSPECTOR GENERAL FOR THE TROUBLED ASSET RELIEF PROGRAM, FACTORS AFFECTING EFFORTS TO LIMIT PAYMENTS TO AIG COUNTERPARTIES 21 [hereinafter SPECIAL INSPECTOR GENERAL FOR TARP], available at
    • OFFICE OF THE SPECIAL INSPECTOR GENERAL FOR THE TROUBLED ASSET RELIEF PROGRAM, FACTORS AFFECTING EFFORTS TO LIMIT PAYMENTS TO AIG COUNTERPARTIES 21 (2009) [hereinafter SPECIAL INSPECTOR GENERAL FOR TARP], available at http://www.sigtarp.gov/reports/audit/2009/Factors-Affecting-Efforts-to-Limit- Payments-to-AIG-Counterparties.pdf.
    • (2009)
  • 425
    • 79956096945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oversight of the Federal Government's Intervention at American International Group: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 111th Cong. 70-77 (statement of Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.)
    • Oversight of the Federal Government's Intervention at American International Group: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 111th Cong. 70-77 (2009) (statement of Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.).
    • (2009)
  • 427
    • 79956156440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, THE AIG RESCUE, ITS IMPACT ON MARKETS, AND THE GOVERNMENT'S EXIT STRATEGY 42, available at
    • CONG. OVERSIGHT PANEL, THE AIG RESCUE, ITS IMPACT ON MARKETS, AND THE GOVERNMENT'S EXIT STRATEGY 42 (2010), available at http://cop.senate.gov/ documents/cop-061010-report.pdf.
    • (2010)
  • 430
    • 79956103058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15, at
    • Morrison, supra note 15, at 462.
    • Morrison1
  • 431
    • 79956098299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H. FIN. SERVS. COMM., REPUBLICAN PLAN FOR REFORMING THE FINANCIAL REGULATORY SYSTEM 5, available at (proposing that Treasury be required to sign off on Federal Reserve actions taken under section 13(3))
    • H. FIN. SERVS. COMM., REPUBLICAN PLAN FOR REFORMING THE FINANCIAL REGULATORY SYSTEM 5 (2009), available at http://republican.financialservice. house.gov/images/stories/fscrepregreformplan.pdf (proposing that Treasury be required to sign off on Federal Reserve actions taken under section 13(3)).
    • (2009)
  • 432
    • 79956123732 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. (proposing to allow Congress alone to override Federal Reserve actions taken under section 13(3) within ninety days, after which the Fed would be required to unwind all transactions within an additional ninety days)
    • Id. (proposing to allow Congress alone to override Federal Reserve actions taken under section 13(3) within ninety days, after which the Fed would be required to unwind all transactions within an additional ninety days).
    • Morrison1
  • 433
    • 77950511873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crisis governance in the administrative state: 9/11 and the financial meltdown of 2008
    • 1623-33 noting nondelegation doctrine issues with the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008)
    • See Eric A. Posner & Adrian Vermeule, Crisis Governance in the Administrative State: 9/11 and the Financial Meltdown of 2008, 76 U. CHI. L. REV. 1613, 1623-33 (2010) (noting nondelegation doctrine issues with the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008).
    • (2010) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 1613
    • Posner, E.A.1    Vermeule, A.2
  • 434
    • 79956062686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16, at (arguing against discount window lending by LOLR in favor of open-market operations)
    • FRIEDMAN, supra note 16, at 38 (arguing against discount window lending by LOLR in favor of open-market operations);
    • Friedman1
  • 435
    • 0009161107 scopus 로고
    • Financial deregulation, monetary policy, and central banking
    • Arguing that discount window lending by LOLR is redundant and incapable of affecting the monetary supply)
    • Marvin Goodfriend & Robert G. King, Financial Deregulation, Monetary Policy, and Central Banking, FED. RESERVE BANK OF RICH. ECON. REV. 1, 10-13 (1988) (arguing that discount window lending by LOLR is redundant and incapable of affecting the monetary supply);
    • (1988) Fed. Reserve Bank Of Rich. Econ. Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 10-13
    • Goodfriend, M.1    King, R.G.2
  • 436
    • 79956138691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 290, at (proposing restricting section 13(3) to allow support only for market sectors, not specific firms)
    • see also H. FIN. SERVS. COMM., supra note 290, at 5 (proposing restricting section 13(3) to allow support only for market sectors, not specific firms).
    • H. Fin. Servs. Comm. , pp. 5
  • 437
    • 79956138691 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 290, at (proposing that all expenditures under section 13(3) go on Treasury's balance sheet, rather than on the Fed's)
    • H. FIN. SERVS. COMM., supra note 290, at 5 (proposing that all expenditures under section 13(3) go on Treasury's balance sheet, rather than on the Fed's).
    • H. Fin. Servs. Comm. , pp. 5
  • 438
    • 79956139174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 292, at (noting the limitation on judicial review of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of
    • See Posner & Vermeule, supra note 292, at 1633 (noting the limitation on judicial review of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008).
    • (2008) , pp. 1633
    • Vermeule, P.1
  • 439
    • 79956087947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted that I served as Special Counsel to the Congressional Oversight Panel from December 2008-May
    • It should be noted that I served as Special Counsel to the Congressional Oversight Panel from December 2008-May 2010.
    • (2010)
  • 440
    • 79956141871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 20, at
    • Wallison, supra note 20, at 7-8.
    • Wallison1
  • 441
    • 79956070473 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 241 (fourteen-year term for governors)
    • See 12 U.S.C. § 241 (2006) (fourteen-year term for governors);
    • (2006) U.S.C. , vol.12
  • 442
    • 79956151532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • id. § 242 (removal only for cause)
    • id. § 242 (2006) (removal only for cause).
    • (2006) U.S.C.
  • 443
    • 79956137297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. § 1812(c), amended by Pub. L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (six-year term for FDIC board members).
    • See id. § 1812(c), amended by Pub. L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010) (six-year term for FDIC board members).
    • (2010) U.S.C.
  • 444
    • 84890575504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dodd-frank wall street reform and consumer protection act
    • See, e.g., § 202, 124 Stat. 1376, 1444 . Dodd-Frank provides for the Treasury Secretary to petition the District Court for the District of Columbia to appoint the FDIC as receiver for a failed covered financial company. The court must grant the petition unless it finds that the Treasury Secretary's determination that a covered financial company is in default or danger of default was arbitrary and capricious.
    • See, e.g., Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 202, 124 Stat. 1376, 1444 (2010). Dodd-Frank provides for the Treasury Secretary to petition the District Court for the District of Columbia to appoint the FDIC as receiver for a failed covered financial company. The court must grant the petition unless it finds that the Treasury Secretary's determination that a covered financial company is in default or danger of default was arbitrary and capricious.
    • (2010) Pub. L. No. , pp. 111-203
  • 445
    • 84890575504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dodd-frank wall street reform and consumer protection act
    • Id. The review must be concluded within twenty-four hours or the Treasury Secretary's petition for the appointment of a receiver shall be automatically granted
    • Id. The review must be concluded within twenty-four hours or the Treasury Secretary's petition for the appointment of a receiver shall be automatically granted.
    • (2010) Pub. L. No. , pp. 111-203
  • 446
    • 84890575504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dodd-frank wall street reform and consumer protection act
    • Id. § 202(a)(1)(A)(v)
    • Id. § 202(a)(1)(A)(v).
    • (2010) Pub. L. No. , pp. 111-203
  • 447
    • 79956145719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Emergency economic stabilization act of 2008
    • 122 Stat. 3765
    • Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-343, 122 Stat. 3765.
    • Pub. L. No. 110-343
  • 448
    • 79956139696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra section IV.A.2
    • See supra section IV.A.2.
  • 449
    • 79956098833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Both ad hoc and LOLR regimes can be combined with haircut mechanisms. Mandating haircuts in a congressionally authorized bailout could raise potential Fifth Amendment takings issues, at least if applied to preexisting secured creditors
    • Both ad hoc and LOLR regimes can be combined with haircut mechanisms. Mandating haircuts in a congressionally authorized bailout could raise potential Fifth Amendment takings issues, at least if applied to preexisting secured creditors.
  • 450
    • 79957528237 scopus 로고
    • U.S. 70, 81-82 (holding that liens that existed prior to enactment of the 1978 Bankruptcy Code could not be avoided under a subsequently enacted statute)
    • See United States v. Sec. Indus. Bank, 459 U.S. 70, 81-82 (1982) (holding that liens that existed prior to enactment of the 1978 Bankruptcy Code could not be avoided under a subsequently enacted statute);
    • (1982) See United States v. Sec. Indus. Bank , vol.459
  • 451
    • 84876554882 scopus 로고
    • Stock land bank v. Radford
    • 594-602 striking down the Frazier-Lemke Act of 1934 as a taking because of the interference with rights of secured creditors)
    • Louisville Joint Stock Land Bank v. Radford, 295 U.S. 555, 594-602 (1935) (striking down the Frazier-Lemke Act of 1934 as a taking because of the interference with rights of secured creditors).
    • (1935) U.S. , vol.295 , pp. 555
    • Joint, L.1
  • 452
    • 79956094251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III
    • See supra Part III.
  • 453
    • 79956097503 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AIG received three subsequent rounds of bailouts: a $40 billion TARP investment in preferred shares, part of which was used to repay the Federal Reserve Bank of New York; liquidity support for its securities lending program from Maiden Lane II, LLC, a special purpose subsidiary of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York;
    • AIG received three subsequent rounds of bailouts: a $40 billion TARP investment in preferred shares, part of which was used to repay the Federal Reserve Bank of New York; liquidity support for its securities lending program from Maiden Lane II, LLC, a special purpose subsidiary of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York;
  • 454
    • 79956160308 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • And the purchase at market value of CDOs on which AIG had sold CDS protection in exchange for the CDS being terminated and the counterparties keeping all collateral that had been posted by AIG for the decline in the CDOs' value from face value. The negotiations regarding haircuts for AIG counterparties occurred in the context of this fourth round of bailout, but the issue existed starting with the first round of the AIG bailout
    • And the purchase at market value of CDOs on which AIG had sold CDS protection in exchange for the CDS being terminated and the counterparties keeping all collateral that had been posted by AIG for the decline in the CDOs' value from face value. The negotiations regarding haircuts for AIG counterparties occurred in the context of this fourth round of bailout, but the issue existed starting with the first round of the AIG bailout.
  • 455
    • 79956092607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 283 (giving a timeline of the AIG bailout and detailing the actions of Congress, the Federal Reserve, and the Treasury during that time)
    • See generally SPECIAL INSPECTOR GENERAL FOR TARP, supra note 283 (giving a timeline of the AIG bailout and detailing the actions of Congress, the Federal Reserve, and the Treasury during that time).
    • Special Inspector General for Tarp
  • 456
    • 79956079680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a subsidiary question of how to price for the government's credit risk in recoupment as well as whether penalty rates should apply to what is essentially a government loan to the critical counterparties
    • There is a subsidiary question of how to price for the government's credit risk in recoupment as well as whether penalty rates should apply to what is essentially a government loan to the critical counterparties.
  • 457
    • 79956110307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These critical counterparties would almost always be business entities, rather than individuals; a firm's employees would not be forced to accept government loans
    • These critical counterparties would almost always be business entities, rather than individuals; a firm's employees would not be forced to accept government loans.
  • 458
    • 79956078763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ex post taxation of specific firms could raise concerns about the tax being an unconstitutional bill of attainder. Ex post bailout taxes have made their appearance in this current crisis, with a proposed bank tax
    • Ex post taxation of specific firms could raise concerns about the tax being an unconstitutional bill of attainder. Ex post bailout taxes have made their appearance in this current crisis, with a proposed bank tax.
  • 459
    • 79956154851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taxing banks for the bailout
    • Jan. 15
    • See Jackie Calmes, Taxing Banks for the Bailout, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 15, 2010, at B1;
    • (2010) N.Y. Times
    • Calmes, J.1
  • 460
    • 79956063226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Press Release, White House Office of the Press Secretary, President Obama Proposes Financial Crisis Responsibility Fee To Recoup Every Last Penny for American Taxpayers (Jan. 14,), available at. A bailout recoupment tax would ensure that taxpayers do not directly bear the fiscal burden of a bailout. Of course, if the tax is imposed on a less-than-perfectly-competitive industry, such as financially services, some of the cost will eventually be borne by taxpayers in the form of higher prices
    • Press Release, White House Office of the Press Secretary, President Obama Proposes Financial Crisis Responsibility Fee To Recoup Every Last Penny for American Taxpayers (Jan. 14, 2010), available at http://www. whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/president-obama-proposes-financial-crisis- responsibility-fee-recoup-everylast-penn. A bailout recoupment tax would ensure that taxpayers do not directly bear the fiscal burden of a bailout. Of course, if the tax is imposed on a less-than-perfectly-competitive industry, such as financially services, some of the cost will eventually be borne by taxpayers in the form of higher prices.
    • (2010)
  • 461
    • 79956067250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Drama behind a $250 billion banking deal
    • Oct. 15, atA1 (describing Treasury's offer to purchase shares of major banks as "a take it or take it offer")
    • Mark Landler & Eric Dash, Drama Behind a $250 Billion Banking Deal, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 15, 2008, atA1 (describing Treasury's offer to purchase shares of major banks as "a take it or take it offer").
    • (2008) N.Y. Times
    • Landler, M.1    Dash, E.2
  • 462
    • 79956069346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is a critical issue of pricing, but that is well beyond the scope of this Article. The LOLR literature features a debate about whether pricing should be at penalty rates or not in order to discourage use of LOLR facilities
    • There is a critical issue of pricing, but that is well beyond the scope of this Article. The LOLR literature features a debate about whether pricing should be at penalty rates or not in order to discourage use of LOLR facilities.
  • 463
    • 0004058553 scopus 로고
    • (Batoche Books 2001) ("Very large loans at very high rates are the best remedy for the worst malady of the money market when a foreign drain is added to a domestic drain."). For force-placed investment, another justification must be found for penalty pricing because there is no choice in whether to accept the funding
    • See WALTER BAGEHOT, LOMBARD STREET: A DESCRIPTION OF THE MONEY MARKET 56 (Batoche Books 2001) (1873) ("Very large loans at very high rates are the best remedy for the worst malady of the money market when a foreign drain is added to a domestic drain."). For force-placed investment, another justification must be found for penalty pricing because there is no choice in whether to accept the funding.
    • (1873) Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market 56
    • Bagehot, W.1
  • 464
    • 79956161712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, would the government slash jobs if necessary? Would the government demand particular corporate policies? Would the government want management to take a hard-line position about unionization or collective bargaining agreement negotiation?
    • For example, would the government slash jobs if necessary? Would the government demand particular corporate policies? Would the government want management to take a hard-line position about unionization or collective bargaining agreement negotiation?
  • 465
    • 79956099908 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recognizing this economic reality might also avoid lurking Takings Clause issues, as the government would be taking the call option, but would have given equivalent value via the bailout
    • Recognizing this economic reality might also avoid lurking Takings Clause issues, as the government would be taking the call option, but would have given equivalent value via the bailout.
  • 466
    • 79956085871 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g. §§ 365(c), 541(c)(1)
    • See, e.g., 11 U.S.C. §§ 365(c), 541(c)(1) (2006).
    • (2006) U.S.C. , vol.11
  • 467


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.