메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 78, Issue 1, 2011, Pages 53-69

Patent costs and unlicensed use of patented inventions

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 79955974325     PISSN: 00419494     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (20)

References (110)
  • 1
    • 0346406668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing Inventions
    • See, for example, F. Scott Kieff, Property Rights and Property Rules for Commercializing Inventions, 85 Minn L Rev 697, 703 (2001) (Pubitemid 33648758)
    • (2001) Minnesota Law Review , vol.85 , Issue.3 , pp. 697
    • Kieff, F.S.1
  • 2
    • 0345880106 scopus 로고
    • Intellectual property is still property
    • 108-09
    • Frank H. Easterbrook, Intellectual Property Is Still Property, 13 Harv J L & Pub Pol 108, 108-09 (1990)
    • (1990) Harv J L & Pub Pol , vol.13 , pp. 108
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 3
    • 2442565396 scopus 로고
    • Patents: Monopolies or property rights?
    • 39-1-0
    • Edmund W. Kitch, Patents: Monopolies or Property Rights?, 8 Rsrch L & Econ 31, 39-1-0 (1986).
    • (1986) Rsrch L & Econ , vol.8 , pp. 31
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 4
    • 79955954661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consider also James Bessen and Michael J. Meurer, Patent Failure: How Judges, Bureaucrats, and Lawyers Put Innovators at Risk 2-28 (Princeton 2008) (arguing that the lack of an effective notice system and higher costs for clearing rights make the patent system function less effectively than other property rights regimes)
  • 5
    • 18144362124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property, intellectual property, and free riding
    • 1032, (analogizing intellectual property to land limited by the capacity for nonrivalrous consumption, higher costs, and the iterative nature of creation)
    • Mark A. Lemley, Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding, 83 Tex L Rev 1031, 1032 (2005) (analogizing intellectual property to land limited by the capacity for nonrivalrous consumption, higher costs, and the iterative nature of creation).
    • (2005) Tex L Rev , vol.83 , pp. 1031
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 6
    • 58149527543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Real impediments to academic biomedical research
    • See, for example, Adam B. Jaffe, Josh Lerner, and Scott Stern, eds, 10-11 MIT
    • See, for example, Wesley M. Cohen and John P. Walsh, Real Impediments to Academic Biomedical Research, in Adam B. Jaffe, Josh Lerner, and Scott Stern, eds, 8 Innovation Policy and the Economy 1, 10-11 (MIT 2008)
    • (2008) Innovation Policy and the Economy , vol.8 , pp. 1
    • Cohen, W.M.1    Walsh, J.P.2
  • 9
    • 77957956159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Noncompliance, nonenforcement, nonproblem? rethinking the anticommons in biomedical research
    • I review this literature, 1063-76
    • I review this literature in Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Noncompliance, Nonenforcement, Nonproblem? Rethinking the Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 45 Houston L Rev 1059, 1063-76 (2008).
    • (2008) Houston L Rev , vol.45 , pp. 1059
    • Eisenberg, R.S.1
  • 10
    • 79955976933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Madey v Duke University, 307 F3d 1351, 1362-63 (Fed Cir 2002) (holding that use in academic research infringed a patent). But consider Merck KGaA v Integra Lifesciences I Ltd, 545 US 193, 206-08 (2005) (holding that use in preclinical drug development research fell within 35 USC § 271(e)(1)'s exemption for "uses reasonably related to the development and submission of information under a Federal law which regulates the manufacture, use, or sale of drugs").
  • 11
    • 69849103279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ignoring patents
    • See Mark A. Lemley, Ignoring Patents, 2008 Mich St L Rev 19, 21-22
    • (2008) Mich St L Rev , vol.19 , pp. 21-22
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 14
    • 1842764749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ex ante versus ex post justifications for intellectual property
    • 135-38
    • Mark A. Lemley, Ex Ante versus Ex Post Justifications for Intellectual Property, 71 U Chi L Rev 129, 135-38 (2004).
    • (2004) U Chi L Rev , vol.71 , pp. 129
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 15
    • 79955945734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kieff, 85 Minn L Rev at 710 (cited in note 1)
    • See Kieff, 85 Minn L Rev at 710 (cited in note 1)
  • 16
    • 78649299645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Optimal remedies for patent infringement: A transactional model
    • 1173-75
    • Paul J. Heald, Optimal Remedies for Patent Infringement: A Transactional Model, 45 Houston L Rev 1165, 1173-75 (2008).
    • (2008) Houston L Rev , vol.45 , pp. 1165
    • Heald, P.J.1
  • 17
    • 79955972161 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an argument that some free riding may be consistent with adequate R&D incentives, see Lemley, 83 Tex L Rev at 1046-58 (cited in note 1)
    • For an argument that some free riding may be consistent with adequate R&D incentives, see Lemley, 83 Tex L Rev at 1046-58 (cited in note 1).
  • 18
    • 0001563414 scopus 로고
    • The nature and function of the patent system
    • 276-78
    • See Edmund W. Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J L & Econ 265, 276-78 (1977)
    • (1977) J L & Econ , vol.20 , pp. 265
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 19
    • 79955973133 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kieff, 85 Minn L Rev at 726 (cited in note 1)
    • Kieff, 85 Minn L Rev at 726 (cited in note 1).
  • 20
    • 79955954445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • USC §§ 271, 283-84
    • USC §§ 271, 283-84.
  • 21
    • 79955953677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See In re Seagate Technology, LLC, 497 F3d 1360, 1368 (Fed Cir 2007)
    • See In re Seagate Technology, LLC, 497 F3d 1360, 1368 (Fed Cir 2007).
  • 22
    • 79955955898 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See A.C. Aukerman Co v R.L. Chaides Construction Co, 960 F2d 1020, 1028 (Fed Cir 1992)
    • See A.C. Aukerman Co v R.L. Chaides Construction Co, 960 F2d 1020, 1028 (Fed Cir 1992).
  • 23
    • 77956760497 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Principles for patent remedies
    • 518-19
    • See John M. Golden, Principles for Patent Remedies, 88 Tex L Rev 505, 518-19 (2010).
    • (2010) Tex L Rev , vol.88 , pp. 505
    • Golden, J.M.1
  • 24
    • 79955968759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The misunderstood function of disclosure in patent law
    • 404, (noting that willful infringement liability creates perverse incentives to remain ignorant of patents)
    • See Alan Devlin, The Misunderstood Function of Disclosure in Patent Law, 23 Harv J L & Tech 401, 404 (2010) (noting that willful infringement liability creates perverse incentives to remain ignorant of patents).
    • (2010) Harv J L & Tech , vol.23 , pp. 401
    • Devlin, A.1
  • 25
    • 2442452768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Information costs in patent and copyright
    • See, for example, 479-80
    • See, for example, Clarisa Long, Information Costs in Patent and Copyright, 90 Va L Rev 465, 479-80 (2004).
    • (2004) Va L Rev , vol.90 , pp. 465
    • Long, C.1
  • 26
    • 79955964292 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for example, Festo Corp v Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki, 535 US 722, 732 (2002) ("It is true that the doctrine of equivalents renders the scope of patents less certain· . These concerns with the doctrine of equivalents, however, are not new. Each time the court has considered the doctrine, it has acknowledged this uncertainty as the price of ensuring the appropriate incentives for innovation.").
  • 27
    • 79955946754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Process-oriented reforms can provoke considerable opposition, as evidenced by reactions of the patent community to proposed reform of continuation practice in the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO)
    • Process-oriented reforms can provoke considerable opposition, as evidenced by reactions of the patent community to proposed reform of continuation practice in the Patent and Trademark Office (PTO).
  • 28
    • 79955966144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patent continuation applications: How the PTOs proposed new rules undermine an important part of the U.S. Patent system with hundreds of years of history
    • See, for example, 561-65
    • See, for example, Stephen T. Schreiner and Patrick A. Doody, Patent Continuation Applications: How the PTOs Proposed New Rules Undermine an Important Part of the U.S. Patent System with Hundreds of Years of History, 88 J PTO Socy 556, 561-65 (2006).
    • (2006) J PTO Socy , vol.88 , pp. 556
    • Schreiner, S.T.1    Doody, P.A.2
  • 29
    • 79955967874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comparing alternative institutional paths to patent reform
    • 514-15, (discussing the variables that affect the cost of transition to a different legal regime and noting their importance in the patent law context)
    • See also Liza Vertinsky, Comparing Alternative Institutional Paths to Patent Reform, 61 Ala L Rev 501, 514-15 (2010) (discussing the variables that affect the cost of transition to a different legal regime and noting their importance in the patent law context).
    • (2010) Ala L Rev , vol.61 , pp. 501
    • Vertinsky, L.1
  • 30
    • 79955961098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Long, 90 Va L Rev at 506 (cited in note 14)
    • See Long, 90 Va L Rev at 506 (cited in note 14).
  • 31
    • 79955978645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bessen and Meurer, Patent Failure at 147-55 (cited in note 1)
    • Bessen and Meurer, Patent Failure at 147-55 (cited in note 1).
  • 32
    • 79955965570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bessen and Meurer note that effective reform will require structural changes that may not be politically feasible today
    • Bessen and Meurer note that effective reform will require structural changes that may not be politically feasible today.
  • 33
    • 79955957580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 25-27
    • Id at 25-27.
  • 34
    • 79955967498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lemley, 2008 Mich St L Rev at 31-34 (cited in note 4). For an analysis suggesting similar problems in the context of real property
    • Lemley, 2008 Mich St L Rev at 31-34 (cited in note 4). For an analysis suggesting similar problems in the context of real property
  • 35
    • 45249104151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property rules, liability rules, and uncertainty about property rights
    • 1296-97
    • see Stewart E. Sterk, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Uncertainty about Property Rights, 106 Mich L Rev 1285, 1296-97 (2008).
    • (2008) Mich L Rev , vol.106 , pp. 1285
    • Sterk, S.E.1
  • 36
    • 79955971456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cohen and Walsh, Real Impediments at 12 (cited in note 2)
    • See Cohen and Walsh, Real Impediments at 12 (cited in note 2)
  • 38
    • 79955960727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cohen and Walsh, Access-or Not at 18-19 (cited in note 21)
    • Cohen and Walsh, Access-or Not at 18-19 (cited in note 21).
  • 39
    • 66749098395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • User innovator community norms: At the boundary between academic and industry research
    • 2250
    • Katherine J. Strandburg, User Innovator Community Norms: At the Boundary between Academic and Industry Research, 11 Fordham L Rev 2237, 2250 (2009).
    • (2009) Fordham L Rev , vol.11 , pp. 2237
    • Strandburg, K.J.1
  • 40
    • 79955945170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norms and the sharing of research materials and tacit knowledge
    • Dreyfuss, Frist, and Zimmerman, eds, (cited in note 21)
    • See also Katherine J. Strandburg, Norms and the Sharing of Research Materials and Tacit Knowledge, in Dreyfuss, Frist, and Zimmerman, eds, Working within the Boundaries of Intellectual Property 85, 88-92 (cited in note 21).
    • Working Within the Boundaries of Intellectual Property , vol.85 , pp. 88-92
    • Strandburg, K.J.1
  • 41
    • 79955961625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strandburg, 77 Fordham L Rev at 2252-57 (cited in note 23)
    • Strandburg, 77 Fordham L Rev at 2252-57 (cited in note 23).
  • 42
    • 79955964294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cohen and Walsh, Real Impediments at 20-21 (cited in note 2)
    • Cohen and Walsh, Real Impediments at 20-21 (cited in note 2).
  • 43
    • 79955953321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strandburg, 77 Fordham L Rev at 2266-67 (cited in note 23)
    • Strandburg, 77 Fordham L Rev at 2266-67 (cited in note 23).
  • 44
    • 77749261619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Property as process: How innovation markets select innovation regimes
    • 410-11
    • See Jonathan M. Barnett, Property as Process: How Innovation Markets Select Innovation Regimes, 119 Yale L J 384, 410-11 (2009).
    • (2009) Yale L J , vol.119 , pp. 384
    • Barnett, J.M.1
  • 45
    • 79955964090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id at 434
    • See id at 434.
  • 46
    • 79955967313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barnett identifies historical examples in patent pools and other arrangements for mutual forbearance from enforcement of intellectual property rights relating to automotive technology, semiconductors, information technology, and biotechnology
    • Barnett identifies historical examples in patent pools and other arrangements for mutual forbearance from enforcement of intellectual property rights relating to automotive technology, semiconductors, information technology, and biotechnology.
  • 47
    • 79955963490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 434-37
    • Id at 434-37.
  • 48
    • 79955951367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • addition to the costs of coordination and lobbying to achieve legislative change, legislative change to reverse propertization could potentially expose the government to liability in takings actions.
    • In addition to the costs of coordination and lobbying to achieve legislative change, legislative change to reverse propertization could potentially expose the government to liability in takings actions.
  • 49
    • 79955965940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 420 n 82, citing Congressional Budget Office, Cost Estimate: S 1145, Patent Reform Act of 2007 (Feb 18, 2008), online at, (visited Sept 3, 2010). Legal scholars are not in agreement on the application of the Takings Clause to patents
    • Id at 420 n 82, citing Congressional Budget Office, Cost Estimate: S 1145, Patent Reform Act of 2007 (Feb 18, 2008), online at http://cbo.gov/ ftpdocs/89xx/doc8981/s1145.pdf (visited Sept 3, 2010). Legal scholars are not in agreement on the application of the Takings Clause to patents.
  • 50
    • 0346883553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do federal uses of intellectual property implicate the fifth amendment?
    • Compare, 529-32, (reviewing cases and finding a "muddle")
    • Compare Thomas F. Cotter, Do Federal Uses of Intellectual Property Implicate the Fifth Amendment?, 50 U Fla L Rev 529, 529-32 (1998) (reviewing cases and finding a "muddle")
    • (1998) U Fla L Rev , vol.50 , pp. 529
    • Cotter, T.F.1
  • 51
    • 34548613272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patents as constitutional private property: The historical protection of patents under the takings clause
    • With, 690-91, (arguing that nineteenth-century courts embraced patents as constitutional property protected under the Takings Clause)
    • With Adam Mossoff, Patents as Constitutional Private Property: The Historical Protection of Patents under the Takings Clause, 87 BU L Rev 689, 690-91 (2007) (arguing that nineteenth-century courts embraced patents as constitutional property protected under the Takings Clause).
    • (2007) BU L Rev , vol.87 , pp. 689
    • Mossoff, A.1
  • 52
    • 79955965750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Heald, 45 Houston L Rev at 1166-68 (cited in note 6). Heald sees information costs and transaction costs as essential to justifying intellectual property; without these costs, we could rely upon contracts to pay for innovation. See id at 1166
    • See Heald, 45 Houston L Rev at 1166-68 (cited in note 6). Heald sees information costs and transaction costs as essential to justifying intellectual property; without these costs, we could rely upon contracts to pay for innovation. See id at 1166.
  • 53
    • 79955975353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 1172 ("Draconian penalties would most likely stimulate excessive searching for rights holders by potential users and would induce users to enter into unnecessary precautionary licenses or not innovate at all.")
    • Id at 1172 ("Draconian penalties would most likely stimulate excessive searching for rights holders by potential users and would induce users to enter into unnecessary precautionary licenses or not innovate at all.").
  • 54
    • 79955947884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an earlier argument that researchers should be allowed to use patented inventions in biomedical research without ex ante permission, but subject to an ex post reach-through royalty remedy based on the ultimate commercial success of resulting products
    • For an earlier argument that researchers should be allowed to use patented inventions in biomedical research without ex ante permission, but subject to an ex post reach-through royalty remedy based on the ultimate commercial success of resulting products
  • 55
    • 0346409372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • No 'dilettante affair': Rethinking the experimental use exception to patent infringement for biomedical research tools
    • see Janice M. Mueller, No "Dilettante Affair": Rethinking the Experimental Use Exception to Patent Infringement for Biomedical Research Patents, 76 Wash L Rev 1, 54-58 (2001). (Pubitemid 33689359)
    • (2001) Wisconsin Law Review , vol.76 , Issue.1 , pp. 1
    • Mueller, J.M.1
  • 56
    • 43449122777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Worthless patents
    • See, for example, 1530-19
    • See, for example, Kimberly A. Moore, Worthless Patents, 20 Berkeley Tech L J 1521, 1530-19 (2005)
    • (2005) Berkeley Tech L J , vol.20 , pp. 1521
    • Moore, K.A.1
  • 57
    • 0032359895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ariel pakes, and jonathan putnam, how to count patents and value intellectual property: Uses of patent renewal and application data
    • 428
    • Jean O. Lanjouw, Ariel Pakes, and Jonathan Putnam, How to Count Patents and Value Intellectual Property: Uses of Patent Renewal and Application Data, 46 J Indust Econ 405, 428 (1998).
    • (1998) J Indust Econ , vol.46 , pp. 405
    • Lanjouw, J.O.1
  • 58
    • 79955950242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In order to maintain a patent in effect, it is necessary to pay increasing maintenance fees to the PTO that are due 3.5 years, 7.5 years, and 11.5 years after issuance of the patent. 35 USC § 41(b). For large firms these fees are currently set at $980, $2,480, and $4,410, respectively.
  • 59
    • 79955952811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PTO, Fee Schedule, online at, (visited Dec 21, 2011)
    • See PTO, Fee Schedule, online at http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/qs/ ope/fee2009september15.htm (visited Dec 21, 2011).
  • 60
    • 79955976332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scholars have examined data on maintenance fee payments to make inferences about patent value
    • Scholars have examined data on maintenance fee payments to make inferences about patent value.
  • 61
    • 79955948472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bessen and Meurer, Patent Failure at 99-104 (cited in note 1) (reviewing the literature)
    • See Bessen and Meurer, Patent Failure at 99-104 (cited in note 1) (reviewing the literature)
  • 62
    • 33746331551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A study of patent mortality rates: Using statistical analysis to rate and value patent assets
    • 320, (presenting a twofold approach to predicting the future value of an individual patent based on a statistical survey of historical maintenance fee records and a comparative ranking of existing patents based on their likelihood of high or low maintenance rates); sources cited in note 34
    • Jonathan A. Barney, A Study of Patent Mortality Rates: Using Statistical Analysis to Rate and Value Patent Assets, 30 AIPLA Q J 317, 320 (2002) (presenting a twofold approach to predicting the future value of an individual patent based on a statistical survey of historical maintenance fee records and a comparative ranking of existing patents based on their likelihood of high or low maintenance rates); sources cited in note 34.
    • (2002) AIPLA Q J , vol.30 , pp. 317
    • Barney, J.A.1
  • 63
    • 78650138160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *16-17 unpublished manuscript, Feb, online at, (visited Sept 3, 2010). They estimate the average costs of obtaining a patent to be approximately $22,000
    • Jonathan S. Masur and David Fagundes, Costly Intellectual Property *16-17 (unpublished manuscript, Feb 2010), online at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1441987 (visited Sept 3, 2010). They estimate the average costs of obtaining a patent to be approximately $22,000.
    • (2010) Costly Intellectual Property
    • Masur, J.S.1    Fagundes, D.2
  • 64
    • 79955953130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at *17
    • Id at *17.
  • 65
    • 79955974484 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at *18. Masur and Fagundes note that even if patent applicants could overcome initial rejections
    • Id at *18. Masur and Fagundes note that even if patent applicants could overcome initial rejections, higher prosecution costs select against such patents because some patent applicants might abandon their claims rather than incur those costs.
  • 66
    • 79955978049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at *53-54. Other scholars take a different view of the political economy of patent law
    • Id at *53-54. Other scholars take a different view of the political economy of patent law.
  • 67
    • 77649241228 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political economy of patent policy reform in the united states
    • Consider, 179-207, (reviewing changes in the patent system in the 1970s and 1980s and concluding that while some were well grounded in objective analyses of the problems at hand and what could be accomplished, others were not)
    • Consider F.M. Scherer, The Political Economy of Patent Policy Reform in the United States, 7 J Telecom & High Tech L 167, 179-207 (2009) (reviewing changes in the patent system in the 1970s and 1980s and concluding that while some were well grounded in objective analyses of the problems at hand and what could be accomplished, others were not).
    • (2009) J Telecom & High Tech L , vol.7 , pp. 167
    • Scherer, F.M.1
  • 68
    • 79955979972 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Determining the value of an infringer's activities is another information cost problem for owners, who may not know the value to the infringer of using the patented technology rather than an alternative. But owners can make broad distinctions between commercial and academic users, or between profitable and unprofitable firms.
  • 69
    • 79955975541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, the Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984 ("Hatch-Waxman Act"), Pub L No 98-417, 98 Stat 1585, codified as amended in various sections of Titles 15, 21, 35, and 42, lowers information costs and assertion costs for owners of drug patents facing possible infringement by generic competitors. The Hatch-Waxman Act requires firms that seek regulatory approval for generic versions of patented products to give notice to patent owners, thereby relieving owners of the cost burden of monitoring potential infringers. See 21 USC § 355(j). The Hatch-Waxman Act also defers regulatory approval of generic products during the patent term and provides for an automatic thirty-month stay of regulatory approval during litigation of infringement claims, thereby relieving patent owners of the cost of seeking preliminary relief in the courts.
  • 70
    • 79955967682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 21 USC § 355(q)(1)(G); Eisenberg, 45 Houston L Rev at 1089 (cited in note 2)
    • See 21 USC § 355(q)(1)(G); Eisenberg, 45 Houston L Rev at 1089 (cited in note 2).
  • 71
    • 4243124519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rational ignorance at the patent office
    • 1499
    • See Mark A. Lemley, Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office, 95 Nw U L Rev 1495, 1499 (2001).
    • (2001) Nw U L Rev , vol.95 , pp. 1495
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 72
    • 79955947512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mark Lemley estimates that patent examiners have an average of eighteen hours to spend on a patent application, including the time spent reading the application, reading the submitted prior art, searching for and reading prior art in databases accessible to the PTO, comparing that prior art to the application, writing an office action, reading and responding to the response to office action, iterating the last two steps at least one and often more times, conducting an interview with the applicant, and ensuring that the diagrams and claims are in form for allowance.
  • 73
    • 79955954230 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 1496 n 3
    • Id at 1496 n 3.
  • 74
    • 0345818393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collusion and collective action in the patent system: A proposal for patent bountie
    • For a description of the patent examination process
    • For a description of the patent examination process, see John R. Thomas, Collusion and Collective Action in the Patent System: A Proposal for Patent Bounties, 2001 U 111 L Rev 305, 312-16.
    • (2001) U 111 L Rev , vol.305 , pp. 312-316
    • Thomas, J.R.1
  • 75
    • 69849111692 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Understanding patent-quality mechanisms
    • 2153
    • See R. Polk Wagner, Understanding Patent-Quality Mechanisms, 157 U Pa L Rev 2135, 2153 (2009)
    • (2009) U Pa L Rev , vol.157 , pp. 2135
    • Wagner, R.P.1
  • 76
    • 33847699268 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who's afraid of the APA? What the patent system can learn from administrative law
    • 316-17
    • Stuart Minor Benjamin and Arti K. Rai, Who's Afraid of the APA? What the Patent System Can Learn from Administrative Law, 95 Georgetown L J 269, 316-17 (2007)
    • (2007) Georgetown L J , vol.95 , pp. 269
    • Benjamin, S.M.1    Rai, A.K.2
  • 77
    • 1842527447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ending abuse of patent continuations
    • 75, Examiners may also boost their compensation by granting patents quickly
    • Mark A. Lemley and Kimberly A. Moore, Ending Abuse of Patent Continuations, 84 BU L Rev 63, 75 (2004). Examiners may also boost their compensation by granting patents quickly.
    • (2004) BU L Rev , vol.84 , pp. 63
    • Lemley, M.A.1    Moore, K.A.2
  • 78
    • 82955165296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • *12-18 (unpublished manuscript, May 2008), online at (visited Sept 3, 2010)
    • See Gajan Retnasaba, Why It Is Easier to Get a Patent in September *12-18 (unpublished manuscript, May 2008), online at http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1121132 (visited Sept 3, 2010).
    • Why It Is Easier to Get A Patent in September
    • Retnasaba, G.1
  • 79
    • 79955956727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See PTO, § 706 (Sept 2007), online at, (visited Oct 16, 2010)
    • See PTO, Manual of Patent Examining Procedures § 706 (Sept 2007), online at http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/pac/mpep/mpep-e8r6-0700.pdf (visited Oct 16, 2010).
    • Manual of Patent Examining Procedures
  • 80
    • 79955946501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Although patent applicants have an obligation to disclose prior art that they know about, 35 CFR § 1.56, they have no obligation to conduct a prior art search, and may be well advised not to do so. Conducting a prior art search not only increases the risk of rejection, but it also increases the risk of future findings of inequitable conduct for failure to disclose a reference that a court deems material to patentability. Thomas, 2001 U 111 L Rev at 314-15 (cited in note 44).
  • 81
    • 79955969907 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See 35 USC § 134. Mark Lemley and Bhaven Sampat found in a recent study that although 86.5 percent of the first office actions by the PTO on patent applications were nonfinal rejections, relatively few of these rejections became final. Instead, 73.1 percent of the patents that issue never receive a final rejection.
  • 82
    • 84855951125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Examining patent examination
    • online at, (visited Sept 3, 2010)
    • Mark A. Lemley and Bhaven Sampat, Examining Patent Examination, 2010 Stan Tech L Rev 2, 3-5, online at http://stlr.stanford.edu/2010/05/examining-patent- examination (visited Sept 3, 2010).
    • (2010) Stan Tech L Rev , vol.2 , pp. 3-5
    • Lemley, M.A.1    Sampat, B.2
  • 83
    • 79955971103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consider Barnett, 119 Yale L J at 399 figure 2 (cited in note 27) (picturing "Patented assets" as a subset entirely contained within the larger set of "Patentable assets")
    • Consider Barnett, 119 Yale L J at 399 figure 2 (cited in note 27) (picturing "Patented assets" as a subset entirely contained within the larger set of "Patentable assets").
  • 84
    • 79955960365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for example, In re Lee, 277 F3d 1338, 1342-44 (Fed Cir 2002): The agency tribunal must set forth its findings and the grounds thereof, as supported by the agency record, and explain its application of the law to the found facts· . It must be based on objective evidence of record· . Deferential judicial review under the Administrative Procedure Act does not relieve the agency of its obligation to develop an evidentiary basis for its findings. To the contrary, the Administrative Procedure Act reinforces this obligation.
  • 85
    • 79955952633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for example, In re Zurko, 258 F3d 1379, 1385 (Fed Cir 2001): [T]he deficiencies of the cited references cannot be remedied by the Board's general conclusions about what is "basic knowledge" or "common sense" to one of ordinary skill in the art· . This assessment of basic knowledge and common sense was not based on any evidence in the record and, therefore, lacks substantial evidence support.
  • 86
    • 79955961274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 550 US 398 (2007)
    • 550 US 398 (2007).
  • 87
    • 79955975156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 403 ("Rigid preventative rules that deny recourse to common sense are neither necessary under, nor consistent with, this Court's case law.")
    • Id at 403 ("Rigid preventative rules that deny recourse to common sense are neither necessary under, nor consistent with, this Court's case law.").
  • 88
    • 79955974485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 USC §§ 102-03
    • 35 USC §§ 102-03.
  • 89
    • 79955964089 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Thomas, 2001 U 111 L Rev at 318 (cited in note 44)
    • See Thomas, 2001 U 111 L Rev at 318 (cited in note 44).
  • 90
    • 79955944633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Previously issued patents are a particularly poor measure of the prior art in fields that are relatively new to the patent system, such as information technology and business methods, making it especially difficult for the PTO to make cost-effective assessments of patentability in these fields.
  • 91
    • 79955952809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 35 USC § 282
    • See 35 USC § 282.
  • 92
    • 79955971104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hybritech Inc v Monoclonal Antibodies, Inc, 802 F2d 1367, 1375 (Fed Cir 1986)
    • Hybritech Inc v Monoclonal Antibodies, Inc, 802 F2d 1367, 1375 (Fed Cir 1986).
  • 93
    • 79955949852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lemley, 95 Nw U L Rev at 1514 (cited in note 43) ("[T]he fundamental fact remains that litigation of a few patents is a far more efficient way of determining validity than giving a detailed ex ante examination of all patents.")
    • See Lemley, 95 Nw U L Rev at 1514 (cited in note 43) ("[T]he fundamental fact remains that litigation of a few patents is a far more efficient way of determining validity than giving a detailed ex ante examination of all patents.").
  • 94
    • 79955949198 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 1527
    • Id at 1527.
  • 95
    • 79955968553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Apart from avoiding search costs, awareness of patents may subject users to enhanced damages for willful infringement. See Thomas, 2001 U 111 L Rev at 314-15 (cited in note 44); text accompanying note 10
    • Apart from avoiding search costs, awareness of patents may subject users to enhanced damages for willful infringement. See Thomas, 2001 U 111 L Rev at 314-15 (cited in note 44); text accompanying note 10.
  • 96
    • 0013276156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bargaining over the transfer of proprietary research tools: Is this market failing or emerging?
    • Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, Diane Leenheer Zimmerman, and Harry First, eds, 231 Oxford
    • See Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Bargaining over the Transfer of Proprietary Research Tools: Is This Market Failing or Emerging?, in Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, Diane Leenheer Zimmerman, and Harry First, eds, Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property: Innovation Policy for the Knowledge Society 223, 225, 231 (Oxford 2001).
    • (2001) Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property: Innovation Policy for the Knowledge Society , vol.223 , pp. 225
    • Eisenberg, R.S.1
  • 97
    • 15744379741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Controlling opportunistic and anti-competitive intellectual property litigation
    • 517
    • See Michael J. Meurer, Controlling Opportunistic and Anti-competitive Intellectual Property Litigation, 44 BC L Rev 509, 517 (2003).
    • (2003) BC L Rev , vol.44 , pp. 509
    • Meurer, M.J.1
  • 98
    • 79955955988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, it is possible that an exhaustive search for prior art will be unavailing. Technology users may have a better sense than examiners of whether a claimed invention was already practiced in the technological community prior to the inventor's activities, making it more likely that nondocumentary prior art will be uncovered after issuance than during prosecution.
  • 99
    • 79955962476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is also possible that owners and users will deploy these signals in a misleading fashion for tactical reasons in bargaining
    • It is also possible that owners and users will deploy these signals in a misleading fashion for tactical reasons in bargaining.
  • 100
    • 0040078326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economics of patents: Lessons from recent U.S. patent reform
    • 141-44, (reviewing the literature)
    • See Nancy T. Gallini, The Economics of Patents: Lessons from Recent U.S. Patent Reform, 16 J Econ Persp 131, 141-44 (2002) (reviewing the literature).
    • (2002) J Econ Persp , vol.16 , pp. 131
    • Gallini, N.T.1
  • 101
    • 79955972370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 132
    • Id at 132.
  • 102
    • 79955957767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id at 141
    • Id at 141.
  • 103
    • 79955956919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Heald, 45 Houston L Rev at 1187-91 (cited in note 6). See also notes 31-33 and accompanying text
    • Heald, 45 Houston L Rev at 1187-91 (cited in note 6). See also notes 31-33 and accompanying text.
  • 104
    • 33845900231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Independent invention as a defense to patent infringement
    • 484-92, Compare (arguing that independent invention should be a defense to patent infringement), with Heald, 45 Houston L Rev at 1187 (cited in note 6) (arguing for a limited remedy when independent invention is more cost-effective than transacting)
    • Compare Samson Vermont, Independent Invention as a Defense to Patent Infringement, 105 Mich L Rev 475, 484-92 (2006) (arguing that independent invention should be a defense to patent infringement), with Heald, 45 Houston L Rev at 1187 (cited in note 6) (arguing for a limited remedy when independent invention is more cost-effective than transacting).
    • (2006) Mich L Rev , vol.105 , pp. 475
    • Vermont, S.1
  • 105
    • 34250169852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should patent infringement require proof of copying?
    • 1532
    • Mark A. Lemley, Should Patent Infringement Require Proof of Copying?, 105 Mich L Rev 1525, 1532 (2007).
    • (2007) Mich L Rev , vol.105 , pp. 1525
    • Lemley, M.A.1
  • 106
    • 79955960153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 10 and accompanying text
    • See note 10 and accompanying text.
  • 107
    • 69849114403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Copying in patent law
    • 1443
    • Christopher A. Cotropia and Mark A. Lemley, Copying in Patent Law, 87 NC L Rev 1421, 1443 (2009).
    • (2009) NC L Rev , vol.87 , pp. 1421
    • Cotropia, C.A.1    Lemley, M.A.2
  • 108
    • 79955974102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even willful infringement does not require proof that the defendant derived the invention from the patent holder, only that the defendant infringed the patent recklessly, meaning that the defendant "acted despite an objectively high likelihood that its actions constituted infringement of a valid patent." In re Seagate Technology, LLC, 497 F3d 1360, 1371 (Fed Cir 2007).
  • 109
    • 34547794065 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As John Golden explains, "[a] patent holder who practices the invention commercially or otherwise competes with the infringer may be able to use internal knowledge and experience, as well as greater familiarity with the nature of a business like the potential infringer's, to make more informed guesses about the potential infringer's cost-benefit analysis." John M. Golden, "Patent Trolls" and Patent Remedies, 85 Tex L Rev 2111, 2132-33 (2007).
  • 110
    • 74049103030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Extreme value or trolls on top? the characteristics of the most-litigated patents
    • 26, (finding that nonpracticing entities filed 80 percent of the lawsuits involving the set of patents that were litigated eight times or more between 2000 and 2007)
    • See John R. Allison, Mark A. Lemley, and Joshua Walker, Extreme Value or Trolls on Top? The Characteristics of the Most-Litigated Patents, 158 U Pa L Rev 1, 26 (2009) (finding that nonpracticing entities filed 80 percent of the lawsuits involving the set of patents that were litigated eight times or more between 2000 and 2007).
    • (2009) U Pa L Rev , vol.158 , pp. 1
    • Allison, J.R.1    Lemley, M.A.2    Walker, J.3


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.