메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 107, Issue 8, 2009, Pages 1479-1500

An information theory of willful breach

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 66749109789     PISSN: 00262234     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (22)

References (71)
  • 1
    • 66749154470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS ch. 16, introductory n. (1981)
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS ch. 16, introductory n. (1981).
  • 3
    • 66749122166 scopus 로고
    • OLIVER WENDELL HOLMES
    • (Mark DeWolfe Howe ed., 1963)
    • (quoting OLIVER WENDELL HOLMES, THE COMMON LAW 236 (Mark DeWolfe Howe ed., 1963) (1881)).
    • (1881) The Common Law , vol.236
  • 5
    • 66749126951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is breach of contract immoral?
    • Steven Shavell, Is Breach of Contract Immoral?, 56 EMORY L.J. 439 (2006).
    • (2006) 56 Emory L.J. , vol.439
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 6
    • 0033192196 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Damage measures for inadvertant [sic] breach of contract
    • Lucian Arye Bebchuk & I.P.L. Png, Damage Measures for Inadvertant [sic] Breach of Contract, 19 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 319, 329 (1999);
    • (1999) 19 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.319 , pp. 329
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1    Png, I.P.L.2
  • 7
    • 67649349232 scopus 로고
    • Unity in tort, contract, and property: The model of precaution
    • Robert Cooter, Unity in Tort, Contract, and Property: The Model of Precaution, 73 CAL. L. REV. 1, 32 (1985);
    • (1985) 73 Cal. L. Rev. , vol.1 , pp. 32
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 8
    • 0008992534 scopus 로고
    • Precontractual investigation as an optimal precaution problem
    • Richard Craswell, Precontractual Investigation as an Optimal Precaution Problem, 17 J. LEGAL STUD. 401, 425-28 (1988).
    • (1988) 17 J. Legal Stud. , vol.401 , pp. 425-428
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 9
    • 84868997630 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39 cmt. a (Tentative Draft No. 4, 2005) ("[Section] 39 describes a disgorgement remedy: a claimant under this Section may recover the defendant's profits from, breach, even if they exceed the provable value to the claimant of the defendant's defaulted performance."). The Restatement (Second) of Contracts also recognizes the role of fault
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39 cmt. a (Tentative Draft No. 4, 2005) ("[Section] 39 describes a disgorgement remedy: a claimant under this Section may recover the defendant's profits from, breach, even if they exceed the provable value to the claimant of the defendant's defaulted performance."). The Restatement (Second) of Contracts also recognizes the role of fault.
  • 10
    • 68949144926 scopus 로고
    • Willfulness: A crucial factor in choosing remedies for breach of contract
    • See Patricia H. Marschall, Willfulness: A Crucial Factor in Choosing Remedies for Breach of Contract, 24 ARIZ. L. REV. 733, 734-737 (1982) (collecting Restatement sections where fault and/or willful/intentional breach play a role).
    • (1982) 24 ARIZ. L. REV. , vol.733 , pp. 734-737
    • Marschall, P.H.1
  • 11
    • 21844526836 scopus 로고
    • The fault lines in contract damages
    • See, e.g., George M. Cohen, The Fault Lines in Contract Damages, 80 VA. L. REV. 1225 (1994);
    • (1994) 80 Va. L. Rev. , vol.1225
    • Cohen, G.M.1
  • 12
    • 66749090300 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When is a willful breach 'Willful'?: The link between definitions and damages
    • Richard Craswell, When is a Willful Breach 'Willful'?: The Link Between Definitions and Damages, 107 MICH. L. REV. 1501, 1502-04 (2009);
    • (2009) 107 Mich. L. Rev. , vol.1501 , pp. 1502-1504
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 14
    • 66749127567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 129 N.E. 889, 891 (N.Y. 1921) (citations omitted)
    • Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 129 N.E. 889, 891 (N.Y. 1921) (citations omitted).
  • 16
    • 66749189706 scopus 로고
    • Fault and breach of contract
    • Jack Beatson & Daniel Friedmann eds.
    • See generally Barry Nicholas, Fault and Breach of Contract, in GOOD FAITH AND FAULT IN CONTRACT LAW 337, 338-340 (Jack Beatson & Daniel Friedmann eds., 1995).
    • (1995) Good Faith and Fault in Contract Law , vol.337 , pp. 338-340
    • Nicholas, B.1
  • 17
    • 66749119139 scopus 로고
    • Divergence in search of a rationale
    • Brace Chapman & Michael Trebilcock, Punitive Damages: Divergence in Search of a Rationale, 40 ALA. L. REV. 741, 764-72 (1989);
    • (1989) 40 Ala. L. Rev. , vol.741 , pp. 764-772
    • Chapman, B.1    Trebilcock, M.2    Damages, P.3
  • 18
    • 0041812393 scopus 로고
    • The efficient breach fallacy
    • Daniel Friedmann, The Efficient Breach Fallacy, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 13-23 (1989);
    • (1989) 18 J. Legal Stud. , vol.1 , pp. 13-23
    • Friedmann, D.1
  • 19
    • 84925976807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Efficient breach of contract: Circles in the sky
    • lan. R. Macneil, Efficient Breach of Contract: Circles in the Sky, 68 VA. L. REV. 947 (1982).
    • 68 Va. L. Rev. , vol.947 , pp. 1982
    • Macneil, L.R.1
  • 20
    • 0043193271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Private commercial law in the cotton industry: Creating cooperation through rules, norms, and institutions
    • See Lisa Bernstein, Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Creating Cooperation Through Rules, Norms, and Institutions, 99 MICH. L. REV. 1724, 1733-1734 (2001).
    • (2001) 99 Mich. L. Rev. , vol.1724 , pp. 1733-1734
    • Bernstein, L.1
  • 21
    • 66749095710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cohen, supra note 6, at 1230;
    • Supra Note , vol.6 , pp. 1230
    • Cohen1
  • 25
    • 66749142656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See FH 20/82 Adras Bldg. Material Ltd. v. Harlow & Jones Gmbh [1988] IsrSC 42(1) 221
    • See FH 20/82 Adras Bldg. Material Ltd. v. Harlow & Jones Gmbh [1988] IsrSC 42(1) 221,
  • 30
    • 84868973940 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N. Y. TIMES, Aug. 23, at Al. A common sentiment reported is that "overbooking is a conscious fraud, in that the seller has sold a contract knowing that it might not honor that contract." Posting of Dan to (Aug. 23, 2008, 07:23 EST). One passenger is quoted as saying, "If flights are being overbooked, then what does that say about how the airline runs their business?"
    • See, e.g., Micheline Maynard & Michelle Higgins, As Overbooked Flights Rise, So Do Payoffs for the Bumped, N. Y. TIMES, Aug. 23, 2008, at Al. A common sentiment reported is that "overbooking is a conscious fraud, in that the seller has sold a contract knowing that it might not honor that contract." Posting of Dan to http://community.nytimes.com/article/comments/ 2008/08/23/ business/23bump.html?permid=7 (Aug. 23, 2008, 07:23 EST). One passenger is quoted as saying, "If flights are being overbooked, then what does that say about how the airline runs their business?"
    • (2008) As Overbooked Flights Rise, so Do Payoffs for the Bumped
    • Maynard, M.1    Higgins, M.2
  • 32
    • 66749084710 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mkt. St. Assoes. Ltd. P'ship v. Frey, 941 F.2d 588, 593 (7th. Cir. 1991)
    • See Mkt. St. Assoes. Ltd. P'ship v. Frey, 941 F.2d 588, 593 (7th. Cir. 1991).
  • 33
    • 0011670776 scopus 로고
    • Economic analysis of punitive damages
    • Robert D. Cooter, Economic Analysis of Punitive Damages, 56 S. CAL. L. REV. 79, 7980 (1982) (explaining that intentional wrongdoing reveals information about illicit gains derived by the wrongdoer, requiring higher sanction to deter);
    • (1982) 56 S. Cal. L. Rev. , vol.79 , pp. 7980
    • Cooter, R.D.1
  • 34
    • 0346366197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Punitive damages: An economic analysis
    • A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysis, 111 HARV. L. REV. 869 (1998) (providing an imperfect-detection rationale for punitive damages in tort law).
    • (1998) 111 Harv. L. Rev. , vol.869
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 35
    • 66749171389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Craswell, supra note 6 (arguing that expected damages for breach are often too low, due to a below 100 percent probability of suit among other things, and that courts may be justified in characterizing a breach as willful in order to raise damages to the efficient level);
    • Supra Note , vol.6
    • Craswell1
  • 36
    • 84928448312 scopus 로고
    • Note, damage measurements for bad faith breach of contract: An economic analysis
    • Linda Curtis, Note, Damage Measurements for Bad Faith Breach of Contract: An Economic Analysis, 39 STAN. L. REV. 161 (1986) (explaining that supercompensatory damages are an efficient response to imperfect enforcement, resulting from either imperfect detection or from high, litigation costs that reduce the probability of suit even when the breach is detected).
    • (1986) 39 Stan. L. Rev. , pp. 161
    • Curtis, L.1
  • 37
    • 66749163375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The "underlying pattern" theory also distinguishes our account from Cooter's information-based theory. See Cooter, supra note 17. Here, the information that is revealed is not the gain enjoyed by the wrongdoer, but the likelihood that this gain appears systematically in a variety of contexts.
    • Supra Note , vol.17
    • Cooter1
  • 38
    • 66749155611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The supracompensatory damages rule increases the contract price that the promisee pays. The promisee is happy to pay this higher price to the extent that she is paying for added incentives to avoid other, undetected breaches. She may be less happy to pay a higher price to bolster the promisor's incentives to pay taxes.
  • 39
    • 66749088317 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We later discuss the implications of relaxing this assumption. See infra note 24.
    • Infra Note , vol.24
  • 40
    • 66749179036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The total expected social value is a measure of all the pecuniary effects attributed to the promisor's investment. in this model, the total expected social value includes the cost of the investment and the net value of performance that is expected to arise.
  • 41
    • 66749141663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Recall that q is the probability of the Good state of nature and thus by definition it cannot be greater than 1.
  • 42
    • 66749093217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The argument becomes more nuanced when the cost of S quality exceeds the cost of M quality also with High effort. See supra note 18 and accompanying text. In this case, the undetectability of M quality reduces the expected cost of both Low effort and High effort (i.e., even with High effort the promisor will inefficiently choose M quality). Still, this undesirable effect will generally be larger for Low effort, since High effort can be expected to reduce the difference between the ex post costs of 5 quality and M quality.
    • Supra Note , vol.18
  • 43
    • 66749188836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If q • 086, then D > 75. In this scenario, the promisor will prefer to perform. M at a cost of 75 rather than T and pay damages. For such high q, the promisor will always have a lower expected cost for L-effort, and the distortion cannot be corrected. The reason, in the model, is that the promisor who invested L still has the option to incur the high cost of performance, in which case there will be no occasion for the court to impose punitive damages.
  • 44
    • 66749128717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Craswell, supra note 6, at 1502-1507
    • Supra Note , vol.6 , pp. 1502-1507
    • Craswell1
  • 45
    • 66749164951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Russe! dean covey, exorcizing wechsler's ghost: The influence of the model penal code on death penalty sentencing jurisprudence
    • See, e.g., Russe! Dean Covey, Exorcizing Wechsler's Ghost: The Influence of the Model Penal Code on Death Penalty Sentencing Jurisprudence, 31 HASTINGS CONST. L.Q. 189, 235 (2004) (noting that under the character theory of punishment, "the purpose of retribution is not to proportion the punishment to the evil of the act, but rather to proportion the punishment to the evil of the character to whom, the act is attributed");
    • (2004) 31 Hastings Const. L.Q. , vol.189 , pp. 235
  • 46
    • 66749170288 scopus 로고
    • The meaning of deserved punishment: An essay on choice, character, and responsibility
    • Samuel H. Pillsbury, The Meaning of Deserved Punishment: An Essay on Choice, Character, and Responsibility, 67 IND. L.J. 719, 733 (1992) ("[Character] theory rests on the idea that in punishing we judge not only the action but also the person revealed by the action.").
    • (1992) 67 Ind. L.J. , vol.719 , pp. 733
    • Pillsbury, S.H.1
  • 47
    • 66749094398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See POSNER, supra note 3, at 118-122
    • Supra Note , vol.3 , pp. 118-122
    • Posner1
  • 48
    • 66749171944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Walgreen Co. v. Sara Creek Prop. Co., 966 F.2d 273 (7th Cir. 1992)
    • See Walgreen Co. v. Sara Creek Prop. Co., 966 F.2d 273 (7th Cir. 1992);
  • 49
    • 85075685760 scopus 로고
    • Efficient reliance and damage measures for breach of contract
    • William P. Rogerson, Efficient Reliance and Damage Measures for Breach of Contract, 15 RAND. J. ECON. 39 (1984).
    • (1984) 15 Rand. J. Econ. , vol.39
    • Rogerson, W.P.1
  • 50
    • 84972438169 scopus 로고
    • Character, choice and moral agency: The relevance of character to our moral culpability judgments
    • Spring
    • See, e.g., Peter Arenella, Character, Choice and Moral Agency: The Relevance of Character to our Moral Culpability Judgments, Soc. PHIL. & POL'Y, Spring 1990, at 59;
    • (1990) Soc. Phil. & Pol'y , pp. 59
    • Arenella, P.1
  • 51
    • 66749090666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 27 and accompanying text.
    • Supra Note , vol.27
  • 52
    • 66749186367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 129 N.E. 889, 890 (N.Y. 1921)
    • See Jacob & Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 129 N.E. 889, 890 (N.Y. 1921).
  • 55
    • 66749151636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jacob & Youngs, 129 N.E. at 892
    • See Jacob & Youngs, 129 N.E. at 892.
  • 56
    • 66749103471 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., POSNER, supra note 3, at 121.
    • Supra Note , vol.3 , pp. 121
    • Posner1
  • 57
    • 0009037768 scopus 로고
    • Contract remedies, renegotiation, and the theory of efficient breach
    • See, e.g., Richard Craswell, Contract Remedies, Renegotiation, and the Theory of Efficient Breach, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 629 (1988).
    • (1988) 61 S. Cal. l. Rev. , vol.629
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 58
    • 66749166765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Groves v. John Wunder Co., 286 N.W 235 (Minn. 1939)
    • See, e.g., Groves v. John Wunder Co., 286 N.W 235 (Minn. 1939);
  • 59
    • 66749120373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal & Mining Co., 382 P.2d 109 (Okla. 1962)
    • Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal & Mining Co., 382 P.2d 109 (Okla. 1962).
  • 60
    • 66749152242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Anderson v. Cont'l Ins. Co., 271 N.W.2d 368 (Wis. 1978)
    • See, e.g., Anderson v. Cont'l Ins. Co., 271 N.W.2d 368 (Wis. 1978).
  • 61
    • 84868984520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See JOSEPH M. PERILLO, 11 CORBIN ON CONTRACTS: DAMAGES § 592 (rev. ed. 2005) (explaining that the classification into tort law is meant to serve the purpose of increasing damages)
    • See JOSEPH M. PERILLO, 11 CORBIN ON CONTRACTS: DAMAGES § 592 (rev. ed. 2005) (explaining that the classification into tort law is meant to serve the purpose of increasing damages).
  • 62
    • 66749104812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Campbell v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 65 P.3d 1134, 1147-57 (Utah 2001), rev'd, 538 U.S. 408 (2003)
    • Campbell v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 65 P.3d 1134, 1147-57 (Utah 2001), rev'd, 538 U.S. 408 (2003).
  • 63
    • 66749101772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1151 (quoting Crookston v. Fire Ins. Exch., 860 P.2d 937, 941 (Utah 1993))
    • Id. at 1151 (quoting Crookston v. Fire Ins. Exch., 860 P.2d 937, 941 (Utah 1993)).
  • 64
    • 66749091257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1143
    • Id. at 1143.
  • 65
    • 66749139831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hangarter v. Provident Life and Ace. Ins. Co., 373 F.3d 998, 1011 (9th Cir. 2004)
    • Hangarter v. Provident Life and Ace. Ins. Co., 373 F.3d 998, 1011 (9th Cir. 2004).
  • 66
    • 66749167906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co. v. Campbell, 538 U.S. 408, 422-423 (2003) (emphasis added)
    • State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co. v. Campbell, 538 U.S. 408, 422-423 (2003) (emphasis added).
  • 67
    • 66749158802 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For exemplary damages in banking and employment cases, see PERILLO, supra note 39, at 386-387
    • Supra Note , vol.39 , pp. 386-387
    • Perillo1
  • 68
    • 84868998905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 345 (1981); RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39 (Tentative Draft No. 4, 2005)
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 345 (1981); RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39 (Tentative Draft No. 4, 2005).
  • 69
    • 84868998906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39, illus. 7, 9
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF RESTITUTION AND UNJUST ENRICHMENT § 39, illus. 7, 9.
  • 70
    • 66749134915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The proposed rule would also apply to cases of unintentional breach. See id. at illus. 14. This can be justified if the breach, while unintentional ex post, is the product of intentionally low ex ante investments in quality control, which could generate multiple undetected breaches
    • The proposed rule would also apply to cases of unintentional breach. See id. at illus. 14. This can be justified if the breach, while unintentional ex post, is the product of intentionally low ex ante investments in quality control, which could generate multiple undetected breaches.
  • 71
    • 66749108376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at illus. 8, 10
    • Id. at illus. 8, 10.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.